Abstract
In a simple environment with heterogeneous agents, we demonstrate that the central bank delivers a higher inflation rate than when population is homogeneous. This tendency to choose a higher level of inflation than efficiency dictates is due to the efficiency-vs-equity trade-off that the central bank faces in this heterogeneous economy: up to a certain level, inflation decreases inequality. Optimal delegation involves appointing a central bank that puts a higher weight on the utility of the high-productivity workers than society does. This effect of delegation that improves the macroeconomic outcome disappears as homogeneity is restored. However, the inflation level under optimal delegation does not reach the efficiency level.
Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
We realize that our results depend on the type of heterogeneity we use, which is a difference in workers’ labor productivity.
We recognize the restrictiveness of our assumption that the proportion of each type of workers is fixed.
Note that having leisure in the utility function is essential to having this trade-off between equity and efficiency. Without it, i.e. when \(\kappa =0\), any equilibrium outcome would be Pareto efficient.
The Friedman rule is at odds with practice of central banks around the world; many leading ones have adopted inflation targets somewhere between 2 and 3.5%. In richer environments than ours, Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2010) and Di Bartolomeo et al. (2015) showed how inflation rates above the Friedman rule level may arise.
References
Ahn S, Kaplan G, Moll B, Winberry T, Wolf C (2018) When inequality matters for macro and macro matters for inequality. In: NBER macroeconomic annual, vol 32, University of Chicago Press, Chicago
Alesina A, Stella A (2010) The politics of monetary policy. In: Friedman B, Woodford M (eds) Handbook of monetary economics, vol 3B. Elsevier, Amsterdam
Bewley T (1983) A difficulty with the optimum quantity of money. Econometrica 51:1485–1504
Blancheton B (2016) Central bank independence in a historical perspective: myth, lessons and a new model. Econ Modell 52:101–107
Carlsson M, Westermark A (2016) Labor market frictions and optimal steady-state inflation. J Monet Econ 78:67–79
Carroll C (2013) Representing consumption and saving without a representative consumer. CFS Working Paper 464
Chari VV, Christiano L, Eichenbaum P (1998) Expectation traps and discretion. J Econ Theory 81:462–492
Chari VV, Kehoe P (1999) Optimal fiscal and monetary policy. In: Taylor J, Woodford M (eds) Handbook of macroeconomics, vol 1. Elsevier, Amsterdam
Chen BL, Hsu YS, Lu CH (2011) Friedman meets Becker and Mulligan in a monetary neoclassical growth model. J Econ 104:99–126
Christiano L, Trabandt M, Walentin K (2010) DSGE models for monetary policy analysis. In: Friedman B, Woodford M (eds) Handbook of monetary economics, vol 3A. Elsevier, Amsterdam
Coibion O, Gorodnichenko Y, Wieland J (2012) The optimal inflation rate in New Keynesian models: should central banks raise their inflation targets in light of the zero lower bound? Rev EconStud 79:1371–1406
Di Bartolomeo G, Tirelli P, Acocella N (2015) The comeback of inflation as an optimal public finance tool. Int J Cent Bank 11:43–70
Dornbusch R, Giovannini A (1990) Monetary policy in the open economy. In: Friedman B, Hahn F (eds) Handbook of monetary economics, vol 2. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ
Friedman M (1969) The optimum quantity of money. In: The optimum quantity of money and other essays. Aldine Publishing Company, Chicago
Gomme P (2015) Measuring the welfare costs of inflation in a life-cycle model. J Econ Dyn Control 57:132–144
Heathcote J, Storesletten K, Violante G (2009) Quantitative macroeconomics with heterogeneous households. Ann Rev Econ 1:319–354
Huggett M (1993) The risk-free rate in heterogeneous-agent incomplete-insurance economies. J Econ Dyn Control 17:953–969
Krusell P, Smith AA (2006) Quantitative macroeconomic models with heterogeneous agents. In: Blundell R, Newey W, Persson T (eds) Advances in economics and econometrics: theory and applications. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
Lucas RE Jr (1973) Some international evidence on output-inflation tradeoffs. Am Econ Rev 63:326–334
Menna L, Tirelli P (2017) Optimal inflation to reduce inequality. Rev Econ Dyn 24:79–94
Molico M (2006) The distribution of money and prices in search equilibrium. Int Econ Rev 47:701–722
Rios-Rull J-V (1995) Models with heterogeneous agents. In: Cooley TF (ed) Frontiers of business cycle research. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ
Rogoff K (1985) The optimal degree of commitment to an intermediate target. Q J Econ 100:1169–1190
Semmler W, Zhang W (1985) Monetary and fiscal policy interactions in the Euro area. Empirica 31:205–227
Schmitt-Grohé S, Uribe M (2010) The optimal rate of inflation. In: Friedman B, Woodford M (eds) Handbook of monetary economics, vol 3B. Elsevier, Amsterdam
Schmitt-Grohé S, Uribe M (2012) Foreign demand for domestic currency and the optimal rate of inflation. J Money Credit Bank 44:1207–1224
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Additional information
Publisher's Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
The author thanks the journal editor and two anonymous referees for their valuable comments and suggestions, which greatly improved the quality of this paper.
Appendix
Appendix
1.1 Properties of the equilibrium: homogenous case
We have the following first-order conditions:
Step 1: Stationarity of equilibrium. We first will establish that the maximum-welfare equilibrium is stationary. In this homogeneous environment, equilibrium aggregate and individual money holdings coincide, i.e. \(M_t=M_t^a\), and there is no borrowing and lending in equilibrium; therefore we have
Then from the CIA and budget constraints (1)–(2) it follows that
Conditions (A.1), (A.4), (A.3) and the functional form of the utility function (9) imply
Conditions (A.2), (A.6) and the functional form of the utility function (9) imply
By dividing (A.4) by (A.5) and using (A.3) we obtain
which together with (A.7) yields
This means that employment \(n_t\) is uniquely determined by \(a_{t+1}\) alone. In other words, we can think of employment as a function of \(a_{t+1}\), i.e. \(n_t = n_t(a_{t+1})\). From this and (A.8) we have consumption as a function of \(a_{t+1}\) too: \(c_t = c_t(a_{t+1})\).
Then the CB’s problem in period t becomes a static problem of maximization of
by choosing optimal \(a_{t+1}\). Therefore \(a_{t+1}\) is stationary, i.e. \(a_{t+1}=a\). This implies stationarity of employment, consumption and the rest of variables.
Step 2: Friedman rule. Condition (A.1) and stationarity yield
Let us now turn to the efficient allocation, which is found as a solution to the following problem: \( \max u(c,n) \quad \text{ s.t } \quad c=wn \,. \) The first-order condition:
Comparing (A.11) with the (due to stationarity of equilibrium) stationary version of (A.2), we conclude that in the maximum-welfare equilibrium,
-
\(R_t = R = 1\) (the Friedman rule holds);
-
the money growth rate is constant and \(a_t = a = \beta -1\) [this follows from (A.10)].
1.2 Proof of Proposition 1
Step 1. From (3) and (9) we obtain
Rearranging and summing over i yields
which together with (5), (7) and (8) result in
Step 2. From (6) it follows that
Combining this with (7) yields
Step 3. From (4) and (9) we have \(\frac{1-n_{it}}{\kappa c_{it}}=\frac{R_t}{w_i}\). This and the use of (A.13) result in
Note that it follows from (A.12) that \(\frac{c_{h,t+1}}{c_{h,t}}=\frac{c_{l,t+1}}{c_{lt}}\) and thus \(\frac{c_{h,t+1}}{c_{l,t+1}} = \frac{c_{ht}}{c_{lt}}\), i.e. this ratio stays constant over time. Let the common value of this ratio be denoted \(\phi \):
Then from this and (A.16) we obtain
Step 4. Combining the goods market clearing condition \(\sum _j \alpha _j c_{jt} = \sum _j \alpha _j w_j n_{jt}\) [which follows from (5)–(8)] with (A.16) yields
For a given value of \(\phi \), Eqs. (A.18) and (A.19) are a system of two equations with two unknowns, \(n_{ht}\) and \(n_{lt}\), the solution to which is two functions of \(a_{t+1}\), i.e. \(n_{it}=n_{it}(a_{t+1})\). Then consumption \(c_{it}\) can be found as functions of \(a_{t+1}\) as well, i.e. \(c_{it}=c_{it}(a_{t+1})\).
Then the problem of CB reduces to a sequence of static problems whereby at each period t, the weighted utility
is maximized by choosing \(a_{t+1}\). Thus, \(a_{t+1}\) is stationary: \(a_{t+1}=a^*\). This implies stationarity of emplyment and consumption values: \(n_{it}=n_{it}(a^*)=n_i\) and \(c_{it}=c_{it}(a^*)=c_i\) The stationarity of \(m_{it}\) follows from (A.15). Then stationarity of \(p_t\) and \(R_t\) come from (6) and (A.13) respectively. The stationarity of the term \(b_{i,t}\) follows from (5). Thus we have established stationarity of the maximum-welfare equilibrium. It may seem that all these stationary values depend on \(\phi \). However, we can pin down the value of \(\phi \) by requiring that \(b_{it}=0\) in a stationary equbibrium (otherwise one type of agents would owe a positive amount to the other type and never return the debt).
1.3 Proof of Claim 1
From (11), using the functional form of the utility function \(u(c,n) = \ln c + \kappa \ln (1-n)\) assumed in (9) we obtain
Using this to eliminate \(c_i\) and (13) will result in a system of 3 equations with 3 unknowns: \(p, n_h\), and \(n_l\). Solving it yields
where
The derivative of \(n_i\) with respect to a is
Similarly, using this and (A.20) we get
where \( \mathcal {C}_i = (w_i\kappa ^2+\bar{w}\beta \kappa )(a+1)^2 + 2\beta \kappa (w_i-\bar{w})(a+1) + \beta ^2(w_i-\bar{w}) \,. \) For \(i=h\), clearly \(\mathcal {C}_h > 0\) since \(a+1 \ge \beta >0\) as \(w_h > \bar{w}\). Thus, \(c_h'(a)<0\).
In case of \(i=l\), determining the sign of \(\mathcal {C}_l\) is not straightforward. Since \(\mathcal {C}_l\) is a quadratic function of a, for large enough values of a, its sign will be positive. Let us assess its value at the lower bound \(a=\beta -1\). It is easy to show that \( \mathcal {C}_l|_{a=\beta -1} = \beta ^2 \left\{ w_l \kappa ^2 + [\beta \bar{w}-2\alpha _h(w_h-w_l)]\kappa -\alpha _h(w_h-w_l) \right\} , \) where \(\bar{w}={\scriptstyle \sum }\alpha _i w_i\). The quadratic equation \( w_l \kappa ^2 + [\beta \bar{w}-2\alpha _h(w_h-w_l)]\kappa -\alpha _h(w_h-w_l) = 0 \) with respect to \(\kappa \) has only one positive root \(\tilde{\kappa }\). Since \(c_l'(a)\) and \(\mathcal {C}_l\) have opposite signs it is clear that \(c_l'|_{a=\beta -1} > 0\) for \(\kappa \in (0,\tilde{\kappa })\).
1.4 Proof of Claim 2
Step 1. Using the functional form (9) of the utility function as well as the relationship between equilibrium consumption and labor (A.20) we have \( U_i'(a) = \frac{c_i'}{c_i} -\frac{\kappa \, n_i'}{n_i} = -\, (1+\kappa )\frac{n_i'}{1-n_i} - \frac{1}{1+a}.\) Then using (A.21), (A.22) and (A.23) we obtain
Step 2. We will find the value of \(U_i'\) at \(a=\beta -1\): \( U_i'(\beta -1) = \frac{\kappa +1}{\beta }\cdot \frac{\bar{w}-w_i}{w_i(\kappa +1)+\bar{w}(\beta -1)} \,. \) Thus, \( U_h'(\beta -1) <0 \,, \quad U_l'(\beta -1) >0 \,. \)
Step 3.\(U_i'\) can be written in this form: \( U_i'(a) = \frac{A_2}{A_0+A_1a}\cdot \frac{1}{B_{i0}+B_{i1}a} - \frac{1}{1+a} \,, \) where
Then
Since \(\mathcal {M}_i>0\), the sign of \(U_i'\) is the same as that of \(\mathcal {N}_i(a)\). Note that \(\mathcal {N}_i(a)\) is a parabola that reaches its maximum at
Let us show that \(\tilde{a}_h < \beta -1\). To simplify notation, let us use \(\xi \) to denote \(\bar{w}/w_h\). Then we need to show that \( \frac{\kappa +\beta }{2}\cdot \frac{\beta \xi -2}{\beta \xi +\kappa } < \beta -1 \,, \) which holds if and only if \( (\kappa +\beta )(\beta \xi -2) < (2\beta -2)(\kappa +\beta \xi ) \,. \) The latter is equivalent to
which obviously holds as \(\xi =\bar{w}/w_h<1\). Therefore the function \(\mathcal {N}_h(a)\) is decreasing for \(a \ge \beta -1\). And since \(U_h'(\beta -1)<0\) and thus \(\mathcal {N}_h(\beta -1)<0\), it is clear that \(\mathcal {N}_h(a)<0\) for \(a \ge \beta -1\), and thus
Let us turn to \(U_l'(a)\). Since \(\mathcal {N}_l(a)\) is a parabola which eventually becomes negative for large values of a, and \(\mathcal {N}_l(\beta -1)>0\), the equation \(\mathcal {N}_l(\beta -1)=0\) has a unique solution for \(a \ge \beta -1\). Let us denote it by \(a^*\). Since both \(U_i'(a)<0\) for \(a>a^*\), it is reasonable to assume that \( a \in [\underline{a},\overline{a}] = [\beta -1,a^*] \,. \) Then indeed \( U_h'(a)<0 \,, \,\, U_l'(a)>0 \,, \,\, \text{ for } \text{ all }\,\, a \ge \beta -1 \,. \)
1.5 Proof of Proposition 2
We will demonstrate that \(\mathcal {C}_h/\mathcal {C}_l\) is a decreasing function of a. From (15) and (16) it follows that
As \(w_h>w_l\), the derivative of this ratio with respect to a:
1.6 Proof of Claim 3
The solution to the problem is characterized by the following equations:
These three equations together with the goods market clearing condition \({\scriptstyle \sum }\alpha _i c_i = {\scriptstyle \sum }\alpha _i w_i n_i\) yield the following solution:
[we made use of (A.22)] with the following property: \( c_h = \frac{\delta _h}{\delta _l}\cdot \frac{\alpha _l}{\alpha _h}\, c_l \,. \)
Compare the F.O.C.s (10) and (11) of a competitive equilibrium with (A.24) and (A.25). For a competitive equilibrium allocation to be Pareto efficient, it should satisfy the following conditions:
Suppose it satisfies (A.27). Since the function \(\delta \rightarrow (1-\delta )/\delta \) takes on all positive values when \(\delta \in (0,1)\) there exists \(\delta _h\in (0,1)\) such that (A.26) is satisfied.
1.7 Proof of Proposition 4
Step 1. For a fixed level of money growth a, the social planner first chooses T that maximizes \(\alpha _h u\big (c_h-T,n_h\big )+\alpha _l u\big (c_l+T\cdot \frac{\alpha _h}{\alpha _l},n_l\big )\), which leads to the condition
Let T(a) be the optimal choice of lump-sum transfer T. And let
Combining (A.28), (9), and (16) yields
where \(n_i\) is as in (15).
Step 2. Let us show that
where \(V'_{\alpha }(a)\) as in (22). From (A.29) and (22) we have
Given that \(c_i>0\), it can be shown that the last expression in (A.31) is negative if and only if
It is easy to show that consumption of the high type is larger than that of the low type; from (16) and (15) it follows that
Thus, (A.32) holds if and only if
Using (16) we get
From (15) and (A.23) we obtain
where \(\mathcal {B}_i = w_i(\kappa +\beta )(\kappa +\beta +\kappa a) - \beta (\kappa +\beta )w_i - \beta \kappa (w_i-\bar{w})a\). Simplifications yield
which together with (A.34) and (A.35) proves that (A.33) holds and therefore \(\mathcal {V}'_{\alpha } (a) - V'_{\alpha }(a) < 0\).
Recall that \(a_{\alpha }\) solves \(V'_{\alpha }(a)=0\). Therefore \(\mathcal {V}'_{\alpha } (a_{\alpha })<0\). Thus, the social planner wants to choose a monetary growth level at a lower level than \(a_{\alpha }\). We have shown that the optimal money growth level \(a^*<a_{\alpha }\).
Step 3. Let us show \(a^*>\beta -1\). It suffices to prove that \(\mathcal {V}'_{\alpha } (\beta -1) >0\) so that the social planner would want to move the money growth rate up from the eficient level \(\beta -1\). Differentiating (A.29) and using (A.23) yields after some simplification
Then
where \(\bar{\bar{w}}=\alpha _h w_l + \alpha _l w_h\). Further simplification results in
Note that clearly \((\kappa +1)w_h + (\beta -1)\bar{w}> 0\), and \((\kappa +1)w_l + (\beta -1)\bar{w}> 0\) due to the parameter restriction \(\frac{w_h}{w_l} < \frac{\kappa +\beta +\alpha _h(1-\beta )}{(1-\beta )\alpha _h}\) (see Appendix A.10). Therefore
and \(\mathcal {V}'_{\alpha }(\beta -1)>0\) if and only if \(-w_h w_l+\bar{\bar{w}}\bar{w}>0\). One can easily show that
Therefore \(\mathcal {V}'_{\alpha }(\beta -1)>0\). From here we conclude that \(a^* > \beta -1\).
Step 4. From Steps 2 and 3 we conclude that \(\beta -1<a^*<a_{\alpha }\). Since \(a=\beta -1\) and \(a=a_{\alpha }\) are delivered by CBs with preferences \(\gamma _h=\bar{\gamma }_h\) and \(\gamma _h=\alpha _h\) respectively, we conclude that the optimal money growth rate \(a^*\) is delivered by a CB with the weights \(\hat{\gamma }\) such that \(\alpha _h< \hat{\gamma }_h < \bar{\gamma }_h\). Putting all this together, we have:
1.8 On the sign of \(\psi '(a_0)\)
Let \(W_h(a)\) be defined as the left-hand side of (27), i.e.
Since the right-hand side of (27) is constant, \(W_h'(a)=0\). In other words,
Then
Recall that \(U_i(a)\) in (18) is defined as \(U_i(a)=u(c_i(a),n_i(a))\) and thus
Since \(\psi (a_0)=0\), from (A.40) and (A.41) we have
Since \(U_h'(a_0)<0\) (Claim 2) and \(u_c>0\), we have \(\psi '(a_0)<0\).
1.9 Proof of Claim 6
It is sufficient to show that \(W_l'(a_0)<0\).
Step 1. Similarly to derivation of (A.39) and by using (A.41) evaluated at \(a_0\), we obtain
From (A.43) and (A.42) we obtain
or
Thus \(W_l'(a_0)<0\) if and only if \(\sum _i \alpha _l c_i(a_0)U_i'(a_0) <0\).
Step 2. Let us determine the sign of \(\sum _i \alpha _i c_i(a_0)U_i'(a_0) <0\). From (A.41) and (16), using (9) we have
Thus
From (A.41), (A.44) and (A.45) it follows that
Differentiating (A.20) yields
Then combining (A.47), (A.23), and (A.20) results in
Then from (A.46) and (A.48), after some simplification, we obtain
Since \(a_0>\beta -1\) by assumption, we have \(\sum _i \alpha _i c_i U_i'(a_0)<0\). Therefore, it follows from the conclusion of Step 1 that \(W_l'(a_0)<0\).
1.10 Conditions on parameters
We impose some conditions on model parameters to ensure that the first-order-condition approach works. More precisely, we will make sure that \(n_i \in (0,1)\) in both competitive equilibrium and social optimum. It is shown below that the following conditions are sufficient:
From (15) it follows that in competitive equilibrium, \(n_i>0\) if and only if
This clearly holds for \(i=h\) since \(w_h > {\scriptstyle \sum }_i \alpha _i w_i\). For case \(i=l\) the inequality above is equivalent to
where, as before, \(\bar{w}={\scriptstyle \sum }_i \alpha _i w_i\) [see (A.22)].
We also require \(n_i<1\). This, using (15), can be shown to be equivalent to
Again, the above inequality holds for \(i=h\) as \(w_h>\bar{w}\). For case \(i=l\) the inequality above is equivalent to this one:
Let us turn to the social optimum. From (19) it is clear that \(n_i^s<1\). We also require that \(n_i^s>0\). Since \(\bar{w}<w_h\), from (19) it follows that \(n^s_h>0\). By requiring \(n_l^s>0\) we derive the following:
Combining (A.53) and (A.54) we obtain
Since \(\bar{w}={\scriptstyle \sum }_i \alpha _i w_i\) and \(\bar{w}/w_l-1 = \alpha _h(w_h/w_l-1)\), we obtain from (A.55) that
From this and (A.52) we conclude that the following is a sufficient condition for the competitive allocation to have \(n_i>0\): \( \beta -1 \le a < \max \left( \kappa +\beta , \frac{1-\beta }{\kappa } \right) \,. \)
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Turdaliev, N. Heterogeneity and monetary policy. J Econ 128, 119–145 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-018-0649-6
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-018-0649-6