Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                
Skip to main content

Advertisement

Sharing the cost of the polluted river: a class of bilateral compensation methods

  • Original Article
  • Published:
OR Spectrum Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Water pollution is harmful to people’s health and causes great damage to ecology. Cleaning up pollutants in cross-boundary river requires joint action of agents along the river. In this paper, we deal with the polluted river cost sharing problem in a cooperative situation. We first introduce a class of bilateral compensation methods (shortly the BC method), which are generalizations of the famous cost allocations, such as Upstream Equal Sharing method and Downstream Equal Sharing method. Then, we investigate the relationship between the BC method and the Shapley value of a special responsibility cost game. Also, we illustrate the stability of the BC method by studying the concavity of the corresponding cost game. Moreover, we provide two axiomatic characterizations of the BC method.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Both the ATS theory and the UTI theory are also inspired by Moulin (1990)’s group externalities depending on how we define responsibilities over water.

  2. In the case that there is only one basin (say k) which is polluted, i.e., \(c_k\not =0\) and \(c_j=0\) for all \(j\not =k\), then agent k is called a necessary agent.

  3. For every game (NV), agents i and \(i'\) are symmetry agents if \(V(S\cup \{i\} )= V(S\cup \{i'\} )\) for all \(S\subset N{\setminus } \{i,i'\}\). For the definition of Symmetry agents, please refer to Shapley (1953).

  4. For the Symmetry property of Shapley value, also refer to Shapley (1953).

References

  • Ambec S, Sprumont Y (2002) Sharing a river. J Econ Theory 107:453–462

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett S (1994) Confict and cooperation in managing international water resources. Working paper 1303. World Bank, Washington

  • Chakrabarty D, Goel G, Vazirani VV, Wang L, Yu C (2014) Submodularity helps in Nash and nonsymmetric bargaining games. SIAM J Discrete Math 28(1):99–115

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dong B, Ni D, Wang Y (2012) Sharing a polluted river network. Environ Resour Econ 53:367–387

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gengenbach MF, Weikard HP, Ansink E (2010) Cleaning a river: an analysis of voluntary joint action. Nat Resour Model 23(4):565–590

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gillies D (1953) Some theorems on n-person games. Ph.D. thesis, Princeton University Press

  • Godana B (1985) Africa’s shared water resources. France Printer, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Gómez-Rúa M (2013) Sharing a polluted river through environmental taxes. SERIEs 4:137–153

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hou D, Kong Q, Sun P, Sun H (2021) Adjacent downstream compensation method of sharing polluted rivers. Group Decis Negot 30:251–265

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hou D, Sun P, Yang G (2020) Sharing the costs of cleanup polluted river: upstream compensation method. Econ Lett 195:109473

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hung MF, Shaw D (2005) A trading-ratio system for trading water pollution discharge permits. J Environ Econ Manag 49(1):83–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kilgour DM, Dinar A (1995) Are stable agreements for sharing international river waters now possible? Policy research working paper 1474. World Bank, Washington

  • Li W, Xu G, van den Brink R (2023) Two new classes of methods to share the cost of cleaning up a polluted river. Soc Choice Welf 61(1):35–59

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moulin H (1990) Uniform externalities: two axioms for fair allocation. J Public Econ 43(3):305–326

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ni D, Wang Y (2007) Sharing a polluted river. Games Econ Behav 60:176–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapley LS (1953) A value for n-person games. In: Kuhn HW, Tucker AW (eds) Contributions to the theory of games II. Princeton University Press, pp 307–31

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapley LS (1971) Cores of convex games. Int J Game Theory 1:11–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steinmann S, Winkler R (2019) Sharing a river with downstream externalities. Games 10(2):23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sun P, Hou D, Sun H (2019) Responsibility and sharing the cost of cleaning a polluted river. Math Methods Oper Res 89:143–156

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van den Brink R, Gilles RP (1996) Axiomatizations of the conjunctive permission value for games with permission structures. Games Econ Behav 12(1):113–126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van den Brink R, He S, Huang J (2018) Polluted river problems and games with a permission structure. Games Econ Behav 108:182–205

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang Y (2011) Trading water along a river. Math Soc Sci 61:124–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors gratefully acknowledges the financial support by National Natural Science Foundation of China (No. 72,271,199; 72,071,158; 72,001,172), International Science and Technology Cooperation Program of Shaanxi Province (2022KW-27).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yifan Feng.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

We declare that there is no known competing financial interests or personal relationships that could have appeared to influence the work reported in this paper.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Lemma 3.2

The proof proceeds by checking the validity of Eq. (6). Firstly, we will prove that the Shapley value of the ordinary game \((N,V^{C^k},\alpha )\) has three forms.

For notation convenience, given any agent \(k\in N\), we denote \({\underline{U}}(k)=\{i|i<k\}\) and \({\underline{D}}(k)=\{i|i>k\}\) as the set of k’s strict upstream agents and the set of k’s strict downstream agents, respectively. Notice that for every \(k\in N\), it holds that

$$\begin{aligned}{} & {} \{S|S\subset N\} =\{S|S\ni k\}\cup \{S|S\not \ni k\} \\{} & {} =\{S|S\ni k\}\cup \{S|S\subset {\underline{U}}(k)\} \cup \{S|S\subset {\underline{D}}(k)\} \\{} & {} \cup \{S |S\not \ni k,S\cap {\underline{U}}(k)\ne \emptyset , S\cap {\underline{D}}(k)\ne \emptyset \}. \end{aligned}$$

Then, by Eq. (4), the ordinary game \((N,V^{C^k},\alpha )\) can be simplified as

$$\begin{aligned} V^{C^{k}} (S) =\left\{ \begin{aligned}&c_k,{} & {} S \ni k; \\&\alpha _kc_k,{} & {} S \subset {\underline{U}}(k); \\&(1-\alpha _k)c_k,{} & {} S \subset {\underline{D}}(k);\\&c_k,{} & {} S\not \ni k, S\cap {\underline{U}}(k)\ne \emptyset , S\cap {\underline{D}}(k)\ne \emptyset . \end{aligned} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(24)

Therefore, for all agents \(i,i'<k\) and all \(S\subset N{\setminus } \{i,i'\}\),

$$\begin{aligned} V^{C^{k}} (S\cup \{i\} ) =V^{C^{k}} (S\cup \{i'\} ) =\left\{ \begin{aligned}&c_k,{} & {} S \ni k; \\&\alpha _kc_k,{} & {} S \subset ({\underline{U}}(k)\setminus \{i,i'\}); \\&c_k,{} & {} S \subset {\underline{D}}(k);\\&c_k,{} & {} S\not \ni k, S\cap ({\underline{U}}(k)\setminus \{i,i'\})\ne \emptyset , S\cap {\underline{D}}(k)\ne \emptyset . \end{aligned} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(25)

This yields that for the game \((N,V^{C^{k}},\alpha )\), all the agents in \({\underline{U}}(k)\) are symmetry agentsFootnote 3. Hence, by Symmetry of Shapley value,Footnote 4 it holds that \(Sh_i(N,V^{C^k},\alpha )=Sh_{i'}(N,V^{C^k},\alpha )\) for all \(i,i'<k\). Similarly, we can prove that all agents in \({\underline{D}}(k)\) are symmetric, and \(Sh_j(N,V^{C^k},\alpha )=Sh_{j'}(N,V^{C^k},\alpha )\) for all \(j,j'>k\), where for any \(j,j'>k\) and \(S\subset N{\setminus } \{j,j'\}\), it holds

$$\begin{aligned} V^{C^{k}} (S\cup \{j\} )=V^{C^{k}} (S\cup \{j'\} ) =\left\{ \begin{aligned}&c_k,{} & {} S \ni k; \\&c_k,{} & {} S \subset {\underline{U}}(k); \\&(1-\alpha _k)c_k,{} & {} S \subset ({\underline{D}}(k)\setminus \{j,j'\});\\&c_k,{} & {} S\not \ni k, S\cap {\underline{U}}(k)\ne \emptyset ,\\{} & {} {}&and\ S\cap ({\underline{D}}(k)\setminus \{j,j'\})\ne \emptyset . \end{aligned} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(26)

Given this, we calculate the Shapley value of \((N,V^{C^k},\alpha )\) by distinguishing if (1) \(i<k\), (2) \(i>k\) or (3) \(i=k\) for any \(i\in N\).

Case (1) When \(i<k\), we show that \(Sh_i(N, V^{C^{k}},\alpha )=\frac{\alpha _kc_k}{k}\).

For the ordinary game \((N,V^{C^k},\alpha )\) with \(i<k\) and \(S\subset N{\setminus } \{i\}\), by Eqs (24) and (25), we have

$$\begin{aligned} V^{C^k} (S\cup \{i\} )-V^{C^k} (S) =\left\{ \begin{aligned}&\alpha _kc_k,{} & {} S \subset {\underline{D}}(k);\\&0,{} & {} otherwise. \end{aligned} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(27)

Therefore, by Eqs (5) and (27), for every \(i<k\),

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned}&Sh_i(N,V^{C^{k}},\alpha )\\&=\sum _{S\subset N\setminus \{i\}} \frac{(n-|S|-1)!|S|!}{n!} \Big (V^{C^k} (S\cup \{i\} )-V^{C^k} (S)\Big ) \\&=\sum _{S\subset N\setminus \{i\}, S\subset {\underline{D}}(k)} \frac{(n-|S|-1)!|S|!}{n!} \Big (V^{C^k} (S\cup \{i\} )-V^{C^k} (S)\Big )\\& \quad +\sum _{S\subset N\setminus \{i\}, S\not \subset {\underline{D}}(k)} \frac{(n-|S|-1)!|S|!}{n!} \Big (V^{C^k} (S\cup \{i\} )-V^{C^k} (S)\Big ) \\&=\sum _{S\subset {\underline{D}}(k)} \frac{(n-|S|-1)!|S|!}{n!}\cdot \alpha _kc_k+0 \\&=\sum _{0\le |S|\le n-k}\left( {\begin{array}{c}n-k\\ |S|\end{array}}\right) \frac{(n-|S|-1)!|S|!}{n!}\cdot \alpha _kc_k\\&=\frac{\alpha _kc_k}{k}, \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(28)

where the last equality holds by using induction on k with \(k\in \{1,\cdots ,n\}\).

Case (2) When \(i>k\), we show that \(Sh_i(N, V^{C^{k}},\alpha )=\frac{(1-\alpha _k)c_k}{n-k+1}\).

Analogously, for the ordinary game \((N,V^{C^k},\alpha )\) with \(i>k\) and \(S\subset N\setminus \{i\}\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} V^{C^k} (S\cup \{i\} )-V^{C^k} (S) =\left\{ \begin{aligned}&(1-\alpha _k)c_k,{} & {} S \subset {\underline{U}}(k);\\&0,{} & {} otherwise. \end{aligned} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(29)

Hence, by Eqs (5) and (29), it holds that for every \(i>k\),

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned}&Sh_{i}(N,V^{C^{k}},\alpha )\\&=\sum _{S\subset N\setminus \{i\}} \frac{(n-|S|-1)!|S|!}{n!} \Big (V^{C^k} (S\cup \{i\} )-V^{C^k} (S)\Big ) \\&=\sum _{S\subset N\setminus \{i\}, S\subset {\underline{U}}(k)} \frac{(n-|S|-1)!|S|!}{n!} \Big (V^{C^k} (S\cup \{i\} )-V^{C^k} (S)\Big ) \\& \quad +\sum _{S\subset N\setminus \{i\}, S\not \subset {\underline{U}}(k)} \frac{(n-|S|-1)!|S|!}{n!} \Big (V^{C^k} (S\cup \{i\} )-V^{C^k} (S)\Big )\\&=\sum _{S\subset {\underline{U}}(k)} \frac{(n-|S|-1)!|S|!}{n!}\cdot (1-\alpha _k)c_k+0 \\&=\sum _{0\le |S|\le k-1}\left( {\begin{array}{c}k-1\\ |S|\end{array}}\right) \frac{(n-|S|-1)!|S|!}{n!}\cdot (1-\alpha _k) c_k\\&=\frac{(1-\alpha _k)c_k}{n-k+1}. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(30)

Here, the last equality can be proved by using induction on k with \(k\in \{1,\cdots ,n\}\) and we omit it.

Case (3) When \(i=k\), we show that \(Sh_i(N,V^{C^{k}},\alpha )=c_k-\frac{(k-1)\alpha _kc_k}{k}-\frac{(n-k)(1-\alpha _k)c_k}{n-k+1}\). By Efficiency, we have

\(Sh_k(N,V^{C^{k}},\alpha )+\sum \limits _{i<k} Sh_i(N,V^{C^{k}},\alpha ) +\sum \limits _{i>k}Sh_i(N,V^{C^{k}},\alpha )=c_{k}.\)

This together with Eqs (28) and (30) implies

$$\begin{aligned} Sh_k(N,V^{C^{k}},\alpha )=c_k-\frac{(k-1)\alpha _kc_k}{k}-\frac{(n-k)(1-\alpha _k)c_k}{n-k+1}. \end{aligned}$$

This completes the proof. \(\square\)

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hou, D., Feng, Y., Sun, P. et al. Sharing the cost of the polluted river: a class of bilateral compensation methods. OR Spectrum 46, 1241–1264 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00291-023-00738-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00291-023-00738-8

Keywords

Mathematics Subject Classification