Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                
Skip to main content

Coordination of fuzzy closed-loop supply chain with price dependent demand under symmetric and asymmetric information conditions

  • S.I.: Innovative Supply Chain Optimization
  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates the coordination issue of a two-echelon fuzzy closed-loop supply chain. Two coordinating models with symmetric and asymmetric information about retailer’s collecting scale parameter are established by using game theory, and the corresponding analytical solutions are obtained. Theoretical analysis and numerical example show that the maximal expected profits of the fuzzy closed-loop supply chain in two coordination situations are equal to that in the centralized decision case and greater than that in the decentralized decision scenario. Furthermore, under asymmetric information contract, the maximal expected profit obtained by the low-collecting-scale-level retailer is higher than that under symmetric information contract.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Anupindi, R., & Bassok, Y. (1999). Centralization of stocks: Retailers vs. manufacturer. Management Science, 45, 78–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atasu, A., Toktay, B., & Van Wassenhove, L. (2013). How collection cost structure drives a manufacturers reverse channel choice. Production and Operations Management, 22, 1089–1102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cachon, G. (2003). Supply chain coordination with contracts. In A. G. de Kok & S. C. Graves (Eds.), Handbooks in operations research and management science: Supply chain management: design coordination and operation. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cachon, P., & Lariviere, A. M. (2005). Supply chain coordination with revenue-sharing contracts: Strengths and limitations. Management Science, 51, 30–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, T., Li, Y., & Xu, L. (2013). Channel leadership, performance and coordination in closed loop supply chains. International Journal of Production Economics, 146, 371–380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corbett, C. J., Zhou, D., & Tang, C. S. (2004). Designing supply contracts: Contract type and information asymmetry. Management Science, 50, 550–559.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guide, V., Teunter, R., & VanWassenhove, L. (2003). Matching demand and supply to maximize profits from remanufacturing. Manufacturing and Service Operations Management, 5, 303–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ha, A. (2001). Suppliercbuyer contracting: Asymmetric cost information and cutoff level policy for buyer participation. Naval Research Logistics, 48, 41–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsieh, C., Wu, C., & Huang, Y. (2008). Ordering and pricing decisions in a two-echelon supply chain with asymmetric demand information. European Journal of Operational Research, 190, 509–525.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krishnan, H., Kapuscinski, R., & Butz, D. (2004). Coordination contracts for decentralized supply chain with retailer promotional effort. Management Science, 50, 48–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lau, A., & Lau, H.-S. (2005). Some two-echelon supply-chain games: improving from deterministic-symmetric-information to stochastic-asymmetric-information models. European Journal of Operational Research, 161, 203–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lau, A., Lau, H., & Zhou, Y. (2006). Considering asymmetrical manufacturing cost information in a two-echelon system that uses price-only contracts. IIE Transactions, 38, 253–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lau, A., Lau, H.-S., & Zhou, Y.-W. (2007). A stochastic and asymmetric-information framework for a dominant-manufacturer supply chain. European Journal of Operational Research, 176, 295–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, B. (2002). Theory and practice of uncertain programming. Heidelberg: Physica-Verlag.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, B. (2004). Uncertainty theory: An introduction to its axiomatic foundations. Berlin: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, B., & Liu, Y. (2002). Excepted value of fuzzy variable and fuzzy expected value models. IEEE Transactions on Fuzzy Systems, 10, 445–450.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, Y., & Liu, B. (2003). Expected value operator of random fuzzy variable and random fuzzy expected value models. International Journal of Uncertainty, Fuzziness and Knowledge-Based Systems, 11, 195–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Majumder, P., & Groenevelt, H. (2001). Competition in remanufacturing. Production and Operations Management, 10, 125–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nahmias, S. (1978). Fuzzy variables. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 1, 97–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pasternack, B. A. (2005). Optimal pricing and return policies for perishable commodities. Management Science, 4, 166–176.

    Google Scholar 

  • Petrovic, D., Roy, R., & Petrovic, R. (1999). Supply chain modelling using fuzzy sets. International Journal of Production Economics, 59, 443–453.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Savaskan, R., & Van Wassenhove, L. (2006). Reverse channel design: The case of competing retailers. Management Science, 52, 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Savaskan, R., Bhattacharya, S., & Van Wassenhove, L. (2004). Closed-loop supply chain models with product remanufacturing. Management Science, 50, 239–252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spengler, J. (1950). Vertical restraints and antitrust policy. The Journal Political Economy, 58, 347–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, T. A. (2002). Supply chain coordination under channel rebates with sales effort effects. Management Science, 48, 992–1007.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, C., Tang, W., & Zhao, R. (2007). On the continuity and convexity analysis of the expected value function of a fuzzy mapping. Journal of Uncertain Systems, 1, 148–160.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wei, J., & Zhao, J. (2013). Pricing decisions for substitutable products with horizontal and vertical competition in fuzzy environments. Annals of Operations Research,. doi:10.1007/s10479-014-1541-6.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wei, J., Zhao, J., & Li, Y. (2012). Pricing decisions for a closed-loop supply chain in a fuzzy environment. Asia-Pacific Journal of Operational Research, 29, 1–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wong, B., & Lai, V. (2011). A survey of the application of fuzzy set theory in production and operations management: 1998–2009. International Journal of Production Economics, 129, 157–168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xie, Y., Petrovic, D., & Burnham, K. (2006). A heuristic procedure for the two-level control of serial supply chains under fuzzy customer demand. International Journal Production Economics, 102, 37–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yao, J., Chen, M., & Lu, H. (2006). A fuzzy stochastic single-period model for cash management. European Journal of Operational Research, 170, 72–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zadeh, L. (1965). Fuzzy sets. Information and Control, 8, 338–353.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zadeh, L. (1978). Fuzzy sets as a basis for a theory of possibility. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 1, 3–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhao, J., Tang, W., & Wei, J. (2012a). Pricing decision for substitutable products with retail competition in a fuzzy environment. International Journalof Production Economics, 135, 144–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhao, J., Tang, W., Zhao, R., & Wei, J. (2012b). Pricing decisions for substitutable products with a common retailer in fuzzy environments. European Journal of Operational Research, 216, 409–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhou, C., Zhao, R., & Tang, W. (2008). Two-echelon supply chain games in a fuzzy environment. Computers and Industrial Engineering, 55, 390–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zimmermann, H. (2000). An application-oriented view of modelling uncertainty. European Journal of Operational Research, 122, 190–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors wish to express their sincerest thanks to the editors and anonymous referees for their constructive comments and suggestions on the paper. We gratefully acknowledge the support of (i) National Natural Science Foundation of China (NSFC), Research Fund Nos. 71371186, 61403213 for J. Wei; (ii) National Natural Science Foundation of China, Nos. 71301116, 71302005 for J. Zhao.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jie Wei.

Appendix: Preliminaries

Appendix: Preliminaries

A possibility space is defined as a triplet \((\Theta ,\mathcal {P}(\Theta ), \mathrm{Pos})\), where \(\Theta \) is a nonempty set, \(\mathcal {P}(\Theta )\) the power set of \(\Theta \), and Pos a possibility measure. Each element in \(\mathcal {P}(\Theta )\) is called a fuzzy event. For each event A, Pos(A) indicates the possibility that A will occur. Nahmias (1978) and Liu (2002) gave the following four axioms

Axiom 1.:

\(\mathrm{Pos}(\Theta )=1.\)

Axiom 2.:

\(\mathrm{Pos}(\phi )=0, \text{ where }~\phi ~\text{ denotes } \text{ the } \text{ empty } \text{ set. }\)

Axiom 3.:

\(\mathrm{Pos}\bigg (\displaystyle \bigcup ^m_{i=1}A_i\bigg )=\displaystyle \sup _{1\le i\le m}\mathrm{Pos}(A_i)~\text{ for } \text{ any } \text{ collection }~A_i~\text{ in }~\mathcal {P}(\Theta ).\)

Axiom 4.:

\(\text{ Let }~\Theta _i~\text{ be } \text{ nonempty } \text{ sets, } \text{ on } \text{ which }~\mathrm{Pos}_i~\text{ is } \text{ possibility } \text{ measure } \text{ satisfying } \text{ the }~~~ \) first three axioms,\( ~i=1,2,\ldots ,n,~\text{ and }~\Theta =\prod ^n_{i=1}\Theta _i.\) Then

$$\begin{aligned} \mathrm{Pos}(A)=\mathop {\hbox {sup}}_{(\theta _1,\theta _2,\ldots ,\theta _n)\in A}\mathrm{Pos}_1(\theta _1)\wedge \mathrm{Pos}_2(\theta _2)\wedge \cdots \wedge \mathrm{Pos}_n(\theta _n), \end{aligned}$$

\(\text{ for } \text{ each }~A\in \mathcal {P}(\Theta ).~\text{ In } \text{ that } \text{ case } \text{ we } \text{ write }~\mathrm{Pos}=\wedge _{i=1}^n\mathrm{Pos}_i. \)

Lemma 1

(Liu 2002) Suppose that \((\Theta _i, \mathcal {P}(\Theta _i), \mathrm{Pos}_i)\) is a possibility space, \(i=1,2,\ldots , n\). By Axiom 4, \((\prod ^n_{i=1}\Theta _i, \mathcal {P}(\prod ^n_{i=1}\Theta _i), \wedge ^n_{i=1}\mathrm{Pos}_i)\) is also a possibility space, which is called the product possibility space.

Definition 1

(Nahmias 1978) A fuzzy variable is defined as a function from the possibility space \((\Theta , \mathcal {P}(\Theta ), \mathrm{Pos})\) to the set of real numbers and its membership function is derived from the possibility by

$$\begin{aligned} \mu _\xi (x)=\mathrm{Pos}\left( \{\theta \in \Theta \mid \xi (\theta )=x\}\right) , \quad \forall x\in R . \end{aligned}$$

Definition 2

(Liu 2002) A fuzzy variable \(\xi \) is said to be nonnegative (or positive) if  \(\mathrm{Pos}(\{\xi <0\})=0\) (or \(\mathrm{Pos}(\{\xi \le 0\})=0)\).

Definition 3

(Liu 2002) Let \(f: R^n\rightarrow R\) be a function, and \(\xi _i\) a fuzzy variable defined on the possibility space \((\Theta _i, \mathcal {P}(\Theta _i), \mathrm{Pos}_i), i=1,2,\ldots , n\), respectively. Then \(\xi =f(\xi _1,\xi _2,\ldots ,\xi _n)\) is a fuzzy variable defined on the product possibility space \((\prod ^n_{i=1}\Theta _i, \mathcal {P}(\prod ^n_{i=1}\Theta _i), \wedge ^n_{i=1}\mathrm{Pos}_i)\).

The independence of fuzzy variables was discussed by several researchers, such as Liu (2002), Nahmias (1978) and Zadeh (1978).

Definition 4

(Liu 2002) The fuzzy variables \(\xi _1,\xi _2,\ldots ,\xi _n\) are independent if for any sets \(\mathcal {B}_1,\mathcal {B}_2,\ldots ,\mathcal {B}_n\) of R,

$$\begin{aligned} \mathrm{Pos}(\{\xi _i\in \mathcal {B}_i,i=1,2,\ldots ,n\})=\mathop {\min }_{1\le i\le n}\mathrm{Pos}(\{\xi _i\in \mathcal {B}_i\}). \end{aligned}$$

Lemma 2

(Liu 2004) Let \(\xi _i\) be independent fuzzy variable, and \(f_i: R\rightarrow R\) function, \(i=1,2,\ldots ,m\). Then \(f_1(\xi _1),f_2(\xi _2),\ldots ,f_m(\xi _m)\) are independent fuzzy variables.

Definition 5

(Liu 2002) Let \(\xi \) be a fuzzy variable on the possibility space \((\Theta , \mathcal {P}(\Theta ), \mathrm{Pos})\), and \(\alpha \in (0,1]\). Then

$$\begin{aligned} \xi ^L_\alpha =\inf \{r|\mathrm{Pos}(\{\xi \le r\})\ge \alpha \}~~\text{ and }~~\xi ^U_\alpha =\sup \{r|\mathrm{Pos}(\{\xi \ge r\})\ge \alpha \} \end{aligned}$$

are called the \(\alpha \)-pessimistic value and the \(\alpha \)-optimistic value of \(~\xi \), respectively.

Example 1

The triangular fuzzy variable \(\xi =(a_1,a_2,a_3)\) has its \(\alpha \)-pessimistic value and \(\alpha \)-optimistic value

$$\begin{aligned} \xi ^L_\alpha =a_2\alpha +a_1(1-\alpha ) ~~\text{ and }~~ \xi ^U_\alpha =a_2\alpha +a_3(1-\alpha ). \end{aligned}$$

Lemma 3

(Wang et al. 2007) Let \(\xi _i\) be independent fuzzy variables defined on the possibility spaces \((\Theta _i, \mathcal {P}(\Theta _i), \mathrm{Pos}_i)\) with continuous membership function, \(i=1,2,\ldots ,n\), and \(f: X\subset \mathcal {R}^n\rightarrow \mathcal {R}\) a measurable function. If \(f(x_1,x_2,\ldots ,x_n)\) is monotonic with respect to \(x_i\), respectively, then

(a):

\(f^U_{\alpha }(\xi )=f(\xi _{1\alpha }^V,\xi _{2\alpha }^V,\ldots ,\xi _{n\alpha }^V),\) where \(~\xi _{i\alpha }^V=\xi _{i\alpha }^U\), if \(f(x_1,x_2,\ldots ,x_n)\) is nondecreasing with respect to \(x_i\); \(\xi _{i\alpha }^V=\xi _{i\alpha }^L\), otherwise,

(b):

\(f^L_\alpha (\mathbf {\xi })=f(\xi _{1\alpha }^{\overline{V}},\xi _{2\alpha }^{\overline{V}},\ldots ,\xi _{n\alpha }^{\overline{V}}),\) where \(~\xi _{i\alpha }^{\overline{V}}=\xi _{i\alpha }^L\), if \(f(x_1,x_2,\ldots ,x_n)\) is nondecreasing with respect to \(x_i\); \(\xi _{i\alpha }^{\overline{V}}=\xi _{i\alpha }^U\), otherwise,

where \(f^U_\alpha (\mathbf {\xi })\) and \(f^L_\alpha (\mathbf {\xi })\) denote the \(\alpha \)-optimistic value and the \(\alpha \)-pessimistic value of the fuzzy variable \(f(\xi )\), respectively.

Definition 6

(Liu and Liu 2002) Let \((\Theta , \mathcal {P}(\Theta ), \mathrm{Pos})\) be a possibility space and A a set in \(\mathcal {P}(\Theta )\). The credibility measure of A is defined as

$$\begin{aligned} \mathrm{Cr}(A)=\frac{1}{2}\left( 1+\mathrm{Pos}(A)-\mathrm{Pos}(A^c)\right) , \end{aligned}$$

where \(A^c\) denotes the complement of A.

Definition 7

(Liu and Liu 2002) Let \(\xi \) be a fuzzy variable. The expected value of \(\xi \) is defined as

$$\begin{aligned} E[\xi ]=\int _0^{+\infty }\mathrm{Cr}(\{\xi \ge x\}){\mathrm{d}}x-\int ^0_{-\infty }\mathrm{Cr}(\{\xi \le x\}){\mathrm{d}} x \end{aligned}$$

provided that at least one of the two integrals is finite.

Example 2

The triangular fuzzy variable \(\xi =(a_1,a_2,a_3)\) has an expected value

$$\begin{aligned} E[\xi ]=\frac{a_1+2a_2+a_3}{4}. \end{aligned}$$

Definition 8

(Liu and Liu 2002) Let f be a function on \(R\rightarrow R\) and \(\xi \) be a fuzzy variable. Then the expected value \(E[f(\xi )]\) is defined as

$$\begin{aligned} E[f(\xi )]=\int _0^{+\infty }\mathrm{Cr}(\{f(\xi )\ge x\}) {\mathrm{d}}x-\int ^0_{-\infty }\mathrm{Cr}(\{f(\xi )\le x\}){\mathrm{d}}x \end{aligned}$$

provided that at least one of the two integrals is finite.

Lemma 4

rm (Liu and Liu 2003) Let \(\xi \) be a fuzzy variable with finite expected value. Then

$$\begin{aligned} E[\xi ]=\frac{1}{2}\int ^1_0\left( \xi ^L_\alpha +\xi ^U_\alpha \right) {\mathrm{d}}\alpha . \end{aligned}$$

Lemma 5

(Liu and Liu 2003) Let \(\xi \) and \(\eta \) be independent fuzzy variables with finite expected values. Then for any numbers a and b,

$$\begin{aligned} E[a\xi +b\eta ]=aE[\xi ]+bE[\eta ]. \end{aligned}$$

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Zhao, J., Wei, J. & Sun, X. Coordination of fuzzy closed-loop supply chain with price dependent demand under symmetric and asymmetric information conditions. Ann Oper Res 257, 469–489 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-016-2123-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-016-2123-6

Keywords