Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                
Skip to main content

Inventory sharing of professional optics product supply chain with equal power agents

  • S.I.: RealCaseOR
  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study investigates the inventory sharing policy of a professional optics product supply chain based on a real case study. The supply chain sells a product via two sales agents with equal power. The manufacturer receives a single order from each agent at the beginning of the selling season. Stock is kept in the manufacturer’s central warehouse. Thus, the agents hold virtual inventory only. To obtain greater flexibility and earn more profit, the agents implement an inventory sharing policy between themselves, under which they can trade the excess product by negotiation. This study seeks to answer three questions regarding the implementation of inventory sharing: (1) Does inventory sharing always benefit all members of the supply chain? (2) Should the manufacturer charge agents service fees and if so, how much? (3) What is the mechanism for achieving an all-win situation? By formulating the problem as a mixed Stackelberg and Nash-bargaining game, this study observes that the current negotiation mechanism does not always benefit the supply chain and the manufacturer, because it gives too much flexibility to agents. An all-win leading inventory sharing mechanism is then proposed, and managerial insights are generated.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Based on the real case study, no sales agent dominates another. Therefore, this study considers a situation with two agents with equal power.

  2. Agents have separate clients networks and the needs of different clients could vary.

  3. We have \(\delta _r=\delta _p=0\) in the current private inventory sharing implemented by agents.

References

  • Bai, C., & Sarkis, J. (2016). Supplier development investment strategies: A game theoretic evaluation. Annals of Operations Research, 240, 583–615.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baron, O., Berman, O., & Wu, D. (2009). Bargaining within the supply chain and its implication in an industry. Decision Sciences, 47(2), 193–218.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhaskaran, S. R., & Krishnan, V. (2009). Effort, revenue, and cost sharing mechanisms for collaborative new product development. Management Science, 55(7), 1152–1169.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brandao, L., & Dyer, J. S. (2005). Decision analysis and real options: A discrete time approach to real option valuation. Annals of Operations Research, 135, 21–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, J.-Y., Dada, M., & Hu, Q. (2016). Flexible procurement contracts for competing retailers. European Journal of Operational Research, 259(1), 30–132.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chintapalli, P., Disney, S. M., & Tang, C. S. (2017). Coordinating supply chains via advance-order discounts, minimum order quantities, and delegations. Production and Operations Management, 26(12), 2175–2186.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiu, C.-H., & Choi, T.-M. (2016). Supply chain risk analysis with mean-variance models: A technical reiew. Annals of Operations Research, 240, 489–507.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiu, C.-H., Choi, T.-M., Dai, X., Shen, B., & Zheng, J. (2018). Optimal advertising budget allocation in luxury fashion markets with social influences: A mean-variance analysis. Production and Operations Management, 27(8), 1611–1629.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiu, C.-H., Choi, T.-M., Li, X., & Yiu, C. K. F. (2016). Coordinating supply chains with a general price-dependent demand function: Impacts of channel leadership and information asymmetry. IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management, 63(4), 390–403.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiu, C.-H., Choi, T.-M., Li, Y., & Xu, L. (2014). Service competition and service war: A game-theoretic analysis. Service Science, 6(1), 63–76.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiu, C.-H., Hou, S.-H., Li, X., & Liu, W. (2017). Real options approach for fashionable and perishable products using stock loan with regime switching. Annals of Operations Research, 257, 357–377.

    Google Scholar 

  • Choi, T. M., Li, Y., & Xu, L. (2013). Channel leadership, performance and coordination in closed loop supply chains. International Journal of Production Economics, 146(1), 371–380.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chow, P.-S., Choi, T.-M., & Cheng, T. C. E. (2012). Impacts of minimum order quantity on a quick response supply chain. IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man & Cybernetics: Part A, 42(4), 868–879.

    Google Scholar 

  • China International Optoelectronic Expo 2017. (2017). Press release. https://www.sohu.com/a/141458231-613224. August 1, 2018 (in Chinese).

  • Corbett, C. J., Zhou, D., & Tang, C. S. (2004). Designing supply contracts: Contract type and information asymmetry. Management Science, 50(4), 550–559.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dan, B., He, Q., Zheng, K., & Liu, R. (2016). Ordering and pricing model of retailers’ preventive transshipment dominated by manufacturer with conditional return. Computers and Industrial Engineering, 100, 24–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dong, L., & Rudi, N. (2004). Who benefits from transshipment? Exogenous vs. endogenous wholesale prices. Management Science, 50(5), 645–657.

    Google Scholar 

  • Du, S., Ma, F., Zhu, L., & Zhang, J. (2015). Game-theoretic analysis for an emission-dependent supply chain in a ‘cap-and-trade’ system. Annals of Operations Research, 228, 135–149.

    Google Scholar 

  • Etgar, M. (1977). Channel environment and channel leadership. Journal of Marketing Research, 14(1), 69–76.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gallagher, E. (2002). One stop co-op, discover how Johnstone Supply, a lead wholesale distribution company, uses a cooperative business model and succeeds. US Business Review, December, 1–6.

  • Han, X., Sun, X., & Zhou, Y. (2014). The equilibrium decisions in a two-echelon supply chain under price and service competition. Sustainability, 6(7), 4339–4354.

    Google Scholar 

  • He, Y., Zhang, P., & Yao, Y. (2014). Unidirectional transshipment policies in a dual-channel supply chain. Economic Modelling, 40, 259–268.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang, X. (2010). Repeated newsvendor game with transshipments under dual allocations. European Journal of Operational Research, 204(2), 274–284.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang, X., & Sosic, G. (2010). Transshipment of inventories: Dual allocations vs. transshipment prices. Manufacturing and Service Operations Management, 12(2), 299–318.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iyoob, I. Mohamed, & Kutanoglu, E. (2013). Inventory sharing in integrated network design and inventory optimization with low-demand parts. European Journal of Operational Research, 224(3), 497–506.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jat, M. N., & Rafique, R. A. (2017). Impact of inventory sharing on service availability and transportation levels in time-differentiated distribution. International Journal of Inventory Research, 4(1), 23–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ji, X., Sun, J., & Wang, Z. (2017). Turn bad into good: Using transshipment-before-buyback for disruptions of stochastic demand. International Journal of Profuction Economics, 185, 150–161.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kutanoglu, E. (2008). Insights into inventory sharing in service parts logistics systems with time-based service levels. Computer and Industrial Engineering, 54, 341–358.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, C., & Park, K. S. (2016). Inventory and transshipment decisions in the rationing game under capacity uncertainty. Omega, 65, 82–97.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, H. L. (1987). A multi-echelon inventory model for repairable items with emergency lateral transshipments. Management Science, 33(10), 1302–1316.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, L. (2018). Cooperative purchasing and preactive inventory sharing–channel balancing and performance improvement. European Journal of Operational Research. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2018.11.063.

  • Li, M., & Li, T. (2018). Consumer search, transshipment, and bargaining power in a supply chain. International Journal of Production Research, 56(10), 3423–3438.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liang, C., Sethi, S. P., Shi, R., & Zhang, J. (2014). Inventory sharing with transshipment: Impacts of demand distribution shapes and setup costs. Production and Operations Management, 23(10), 1779–1794.

    Google Scholar 

  • Minner, S., & Silver, E. (2005). A evaluation of two simple extreme transshipment strategies. International Journal of Production Economics, 93(1), 1–11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Narus, J. A., & Anderson, J. C. (1996). Rethinking distribution: Adaptive channels. Harvard Business Review, 74, 112–120.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nash, J, Jr. (1950). The bargaining problem. Econometrica, 18(2), 155–162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olsson, F. (2015). Emergency lateral transshipments in a two-location inventory system with positive transshipment leadtimes. European Journal of Operational Research, 242, 424–433.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ozkan, E., van Houtum, G., & Serin, Y. (2015). A new approximate evaluation method for two-echelon inventory systems with emergency shipments. Annals of Operations Research, 224, 147–169.

    Google Scholar 

  • Park, S. J., Lai, G., & Seshadri, S. (2016). Inventory sharing in the presence of commodity markets. Production and Operations Management, 25(7), 1245–1260.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paterson, C., Kiesmuller, G., Teunter, R., & Glazebrook, K. (2011). Inventory models with lateral transshipments: A review. European Journal of Operational Research, 210, 125–136.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramakrishna, K. S., Sharafali, M., & Lim, Y. F. (2015). A two-item two-warehouse periodic review inventory model with transshipment. Annals of Operations Research, 233, 365–381.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rong, Y., Snyder, L. V., & Sun, Y. (2010). Inventory sharing under decentralized preventive transshipments. Naval Research Logistics, 57(6), 540–562.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rudi, N., Kapur, S., & Pyke, D. F. (2001). A two-location inventory model with transshipment and local decision making. Management Science, 47(12), 1668–1680.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seidscher, A., & Minner, S. (2013). A Semi-Markov decision problem for proactive and reactive transshipments between multiple warehouses. European Journal of Operational Research, 230(1), 42–52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shao, J., Krishnan, H., & McCormick, S. T. (2011). Incentives for transshipment in a supply chain with decentralized retailers. Manufacturing and Service Operations Management, 13(3), 361–372.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sheu, J. B. (2016). Buyer behavior in quality-dominated multi-sourcing recyclable-material procurement of green supply chains. Production and Operations Management, 25(3), 477–497.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smirnov, D., & Gerchak, Y. (2014). Inventory sharing via circular unidirectional chaining. European Journal of Operational Research, 237, 474–486.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sodhi, M. S., Son, B. G., & Tang, C. S. (2012). Researchers’ perspectives on supply chain risk management. Production and Operations Management, 21, 1–13.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spiliotopoulou, E., Donohue, K., Gurbuz, M. C., & Heese, H. S. (2018). Managing and reallocating inventory across two markets with local information. European Journal of Operations Research, 266, 531–542.

    Google Scholar 

  • Srivathsan, S., & Kamath, M. (2017). Performance modeling of a two-echelon supply chain under different levels of upstream inventory information sharing. Computers and Operations Research, 77, 210–225.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang, L., & Ying, J. (2018). Industry in international trade: From the perspective of domestic technology value. Nanjing Journal of Social Sciences, 2, 12–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wu, D. (2013). Bargaining in supply chain with price and promotional effort dependent demand. Mathematical and Computer Modelling, 58(9–10), 1659–1669.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yan, X., & Zhao, H. (2011). Decentralized inventory sharing with asymmetric information. Operations Research, 59(6), 1528–1528.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yan, X., & Zhao, H. (2015). Inventory sharing and coordination among \(n\) independent retailers. European Journal of Operational Research, 243, 576–587.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhao, F., Wu, D., Liang, L., & Dolgui, A. (2016). Lateral inventory transshipment problem in online-to-offline supply chain. International Journal of Production Research, 54(7), 1951–1963.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhao, H., Deshpande, V., & Ryan, J. K. (2008). Inventory sharing and rationing in decentralized dealer networks. Management Science, 51(4), 531–547.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhao, H., Ryan, J. K., & Deshpande, V. (2008). Optimal dynamic production and inventory transshipment policies for a two-location make-to-stock system. Operations Research, 56(2), 400–410.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Funding

Funding was provided by The National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant Nos. 71371197, 71721001) and The Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities of China (Grant No. 1809160).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Chun-Hung Chiu.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

A Proofs

A Proofs

Proof of Proposition 1

If \(\delta > r-v\), then \(v+\delta _p\le t \le r-\delta _r\) (\(\Rightarrow \delta \le r-v\)) does not hold, namely, at least one of \(A_1\) and \(A_2\) do not agree to trade the excess order if \(\delta \ge r-v\). As \(v+\delta _p<t <r-\delta _r\), \(G_{\text {II}}(k,t)\) is strictly increasing in k. Therefore \(k^*_{\text {II}}=\min (E_2,S_1)\). Then by considering \(\partial G_{\text {II}}(k,t)/ \partial t = k^2 (r+v-\delta _r+ \delta _p-2t)\), and \(\partial ^2 G_{\text {II}}(k,t)/ \partial t^2 = -2k^2t\), \(t^*_{\text {II}}=t^*_{\text {III}}= \frac{1}{2}(r+v-\delta _r+\delta _p)\) and \(t^*_{\text {II}}=t^*_{\text {III}}\) is unique. If \(\delta \le r-v\), then \(t^*_{\text {II}} \in (v+\delta _p, r-\delta _r)\) then by putting \(t^*_{\text {II}}\) and \(k^*_{\text {II}}\) in to \(I_{A_i,AN,\text {II}}\), \(i=1,2\), we obtain (3). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 2

The proof of Proposition 2 is similar to the proof of Proposition 1. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 3

By taking the first and second order partial derivatives of \(\pi _{A_i,AN}(q_1,q_2)\) with respect to \(q_i\), \(i=1,2\), we obtain \(\partial \pi _{A_i,AN}(q_1,q_2) / \partial q_i = (r-w)- \frac{1}{2}[(r-v+\delta )F_i(q_i) + (r-v-\delta )W(Q)]\) and \(\partial \pi _{A_i,AN}(q_1,q_2)^2/ \partial ^2 dq_i = -\frac{1}{2}\{(r-v+\delta )f_i(q_i) + (r-v-\delta ) \int _0^Q f_i(Q-x_i)dF_i(x_i)\}<0\). Therefore, for any fixed \(q_2\ge 0\), \(\pi _{A_1,AN}(q_1,q_2)\) is strictly concave in \(q_1\), and for any fixed \(q_1\ge 0\), \(\pi _{A_2,AN}(q_1,q_2)\) is strictly concave in \(q_2\). Therefore, \(q_{A_i,AN}^*\), \(\forall i=1,2\) satisfy (7). By solving the simultaneous equations (7), we obtain \(F_1(q_1^*)=F_2(q_2^*)\). By putting \(F_1(q_1^*)=F_2(q_2^*)\) into (7), (7) becomes \(2(r-w)= G(q_1^*)\), where \(G(q_1^*) =(r-v+\delta )F_i(q_1^*) + (r-v-\delta )W(q_1^*+F^{-1}_2(F_1(q_1^*)))\). As W(Q) and \(F_i(q_i)\), \(i=1,2\), are strictly increasing in Q and \(q_i\), respectively, \(G(q_1^*)\) is strictly increasing in \(q_1^*\). Moreover, as \(Q(0)=F_i(0)=0\), for all \(i=1,2\), \(G(0)=0\). Therefore, there is a unique pair of (\(q_1^*,q_2^*\)) which satisfy \(F_1(q_1^*)=F_2(q_2^*)\) and the simultaneous equations (7). Finally, by (7), \(W(Q^*_A) \lesseqgtr F_i(q^*_{A_i}) \Leftrightarrow W(Q^*_A) \lesseqgtr (r-w)/(r-v) \lesseqgtr F_i(q^*_{A_i})\), \(\forall i=1,2\). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 4

By (8), we have \(d q^*_1 / dq^*_2 = f_2(q^*_2) / f_1(q^*_1)>0\) as \(f_1(q_2^*) >0\) and \(f_2(q_2^*) >0\). Therefore, we obtain part (a). Then by (7), for other parameters being fixed, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} dq_1^* / dv= & {} \frac{1}{\Lambda _1} \left\{ f_2(q^*_2)\left[ F_1(q^*_1) + \int _0^{Q^*_A}F_2(Q^*_A-x_1)dF_1(x_1)\right] \right\} ,\\ dq_1^*/dr= & {} -dq_1^*/dw = 2f_2(q^*_2)/\Lambda _1,\\ dq_1^* / d \delta= & {} \frac{1}{\Lambda _1} f_2(q^*_2)\left[ F_1(q^*_1) - \int _0^{Q^*_A}F_2(Q^*_A-x_1)dF_1(x_1)\right] , \end{aligned}$$

where

As \(r-v > \delta \) , \(\Lambda _1>0\), \(dq_1^*/dr >0\), \(dq_1^*/dv >0\), \(dq_1^*/dw <0\), \(dq_1^*/d \delta >0\) if and only if \(W(Q^*_A) > F_1(q^*_1)\), \(dq_1^*/d \delta =0\) if and only if \(W(Q^*_A) = F_1(q^*_1)\) and \(dq_1^*/d\delta <0\) if and only if \(W(Q^*_A) < F_1(q^*_1)\). Similar results are obtain for \(q_2^*\). Then, by Proposition 3(b), we obtain the results of part(d).\(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 5

For all \(i=1,2\), \(W(Q_A^*) \lesseqgtr (r-w)/(r-v)\lesseqgtr F_i(q_i^*) \Leftrightarrow \)\(F_i(q_i^o)= (r-w)/(r-v)\lesseqgtr F_i(q_i^*) \Leftrightarrow \)\(q_i^o \lesseqgtr q_i^* \) (because \(F_i(q)\) is a strictly increasing function of q) \(\Leftrightarrow \)\(Q_A^* \lesseqgtr Q_A^o\) (because \(Q_A^* = q_1^*+q_2^*\) and \(Q_A^o = q_1^o+q_2^o\)). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 6

Let \(\Pi _{A_i,AN}(q_1,q_2,x_1,x_2)\) and \(\Pi _{A_i,B}(q_1,q_2,x_1,x_2)\) be the profit of \(A_i\) for Model AN and Model B, respectively, for any given \(q_i\ge 0\), and \(x_i\ge 0\), for \(i=1,2\). For any fixed \(q_i > 0\), \(i=1,2\), \(\Pi _{A_i,AN}(q_1,q_2,x_1,x_2) \ge \Pi _{A_i,B}(q_1,q_2,x_1,x_2)\), \(\forall x_1\ge 0\) and \(\forall x_2\ge 0\). Moreover, \(\Pi _{A_i,AN}(q_1,q_2,x_1,x_2) > \Pi _{A_i,B}(q_1,q_2,x_1,x_2)\) for \(q_1 < x_2\) and \(q_2 > x_1\). Therefore, \(\pi _{A_i,AN}(q_1,q_2) > \pi _{A_i,B}(q_1,q_2)\) for all \(\forall q_i > 0\) and \(i=1,2\). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 7

Part (a): By Proposition 5, \(q_i^* \ge q_i^o\), for all \(i=1,2\), if \(W(Q^*_A)\ge (r-w)/(r-v)\). Therefore, \(\pi _{M,B}(q_1^o,q_2^o) = (w-c) (q^o_1 + q^o_2) \le (w-c) Q^*_R\). In addition, as \(\sum _{i=1}^2 \int _0^{q_i} F_i(x_i) dx_i > \int _0^Q F_1(x_1)F_2(Q-x_1)dx_1\), \(\forall q_1>0\) and \(\forall q_2>0\), \(\pi _{M,B}(q_1^o,q_2^o) \le (w-c) Q^*_A + \delta [\sum _{i=1}^2 \int _0^{q_i^*} F_i(x_i) dx_i - \int _0^{Q_A^*} F_1(x_1)F_2(Q-x_1)dx_1] = \pi _{M,AN}(q_1^*,q_2^*)\). As \(q_i^* > q_i^o\), for all \(i=1,2\), if \(W(Q^*_A) > (r-w)/(r-v)\), inequality (11) becomes strict. Finally, by (11) and Proposition 6, we obtain (12).

Part (b): According to Proposition 5, \(q^o_1 + q^O_2 > Q^*_A\) if \(W(Q^*_A) < (r-w)/(r-v)\). Then by considering \(\pi _{M,AN}(q^*_1,q^*_2)>\pi _{M,B}(q^o_1,q^o_2)\) and \(\pi _{SC,AN}(q^*_1,q^*_2)>\pi _{SC,B}(q^o_1,q^o_2)\), we obtain (13) and (14), respectively. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 8

If \(t < v\), then the provider suffers loss in the trading of product. If \(T = t +\delta > v\), then the purchaser suffers loss in the trading. Therefore, \(k^e=0\) if \(t < v\) or \(t +\delta > r\). If \(v \le t \le r-\delta \), then both the provider and the purchaser are profitable by trading any unit of product. Therefore, the provider wish to provide all the excess inventory, and the purchaser wish to receive as much as possible to fulfill the demand. For \(q_1 >x_1\), \(A_1\) has \(E_1\) excess stock, and \(A_2\) has \(S_2\) amount of shortage. Similarly, for \(q_2 >x_2\), \(A_2\) has \(E_2\) excess stock, and \(A_1\) has \(S_1\) amount of shortage. For \(q_1< x_1\) and \(q_2< x_2\), both \(A_1\) and \(A_2\) have shortage. Therefore, \(k^e=0\) and no trading occur. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 9

By considering the first order optimality condition of \(\pi _{A_i,MC}(q_1,q_2)\) with respect to \(q_i\), for \(i=1,2\), we obtain (15). By considering the second order optimality condition \(\pi _{A_1,MC}(q_1,q_2)\) with respect to \(q_1\), we obtain \(\partial ^2 \pi _{A_1,MC}(q_1,q_2)/ \partial q_1^2 = -(r-t-\delta ) \{ f_1(q_1) \bar{F}_2(q_2) + \int _{q_1}^Q f_2(Q-x_1)dF_1(x_1)\}-(t-v)\{f_1(q_1)F_2(q_2) + \int _0^{q_1} f_2(Q-x_1)dF_1(x_1)\}-\delta f_1(x_1) <0\). Similarly, we obtain \(\partial ^2 \pi _{A_2,MC}(q_1,q_2) \partial q_2^2 <0\). Therefore, for any fixed \(q_i \ge 0\), (15) is the necessary and sufficient optimality condition of \(A_i\), for \(i=1,2\).

Next, we prove that there exists a unique solution of the simultaneous equations (15). Equation (15) contains two equations. We use (15-1) to represent (15) for \(i=1\) and (15-2) to represent (15) for \(i=2\). Let \((\hat{q}_1,\hat{q}_2)\) be the pair of \((q_1, q_2)\) that satisfies (15-1), and \((\tilde{q}_1,\tilde{q}_2)\) be the pair of \((q_1, q_2)\) that satisfies (15-2). The simultaneous equations (15) has a unique solution if and only if there are unique \((\hat{q}_1,\hat{q}_2)\) and unique \((\tilde{q}_1,\tilde{q}_2)\) such that \((\hat{q}_1,\hat{q}_2)=(\tilde{q}_1,\tilde{q}_2)\).

Consider \(\hat{q}_1^0\) and \(\hat{q}_2^0\) which satisfy \(r-w=(t-v)\int _0^{\hat{q}_1^0} F_2(\hat{q}_1^0-x_1)dF_1(x_1) + (r-t) F_1(\hat{q}_1^0)\) and \(r-w=(r-t-\delta )\int _0^{\hat{q}_2^0} F_2(\hat{q}_2^0-x_1)dF_1(x_1)\), respectively. Moreover, consider \(\tilde{q}_1^0\) and \(\tilde{q}_2^0\) which satisfy \(r-w=(r-t-\delta )\int _0^{\tilde{q}_1^0} F_1(\tilde{q}_1^0-x_2)dF_2(x_2)\) and \(r-w=(t-v)\int _0^{\tilde{q}_2^0} F_1(\tilde{q}_2^0-x_2)dF_2(x_2) + (r-t) F_2(\tilde{q}_2^0)\), respectively. Notice that \((\hat{q}_1^0,0)\) and \((0,\hat{q}_2^0)\) are solutions of (15-1) and \((\tilde{q}_1^0,0)\) and \((0,\tilde{q}_2^0)\) are solutions of (15-2). Next, we explore the relationships between \(\hat{q}_1^0\), \(\hat{q}_2^0\), \(\tilde{q}_1^0\), and \(\tilde{q}_2^0\).

As \(\int _0^{q} F_1(q^0-x_2)dF_2(x_2) = \int _0^{q} F_2(q-x_1)dF_1(x_1)\) , \(\forall q\ge 0\), \(\hat{q}_1^0 = \tilde{q}_2^0\). By considering \(\hat{q}_1^0\) and \(\tilde{q}_2^0\), we have

$$\begin{aligned}&(t-v)\left[ \int _0^{\tilde{q}_2^0}F_1(\tilde{q}_2^0-x_2)dF_2(x_2) - \int _0^{\hat{q}_1^0}F_2(\hat{q}_1^0-x_1)dF_1(x_1)\right] \nonumber \\&\qquad \qquad \quad = (r-t)[F_1(\hat{q}_1^0)-F_2(\tilde{q}_2^0)]. \end{aligned}$$
(22)

For \(\hat{q}_1^0>F_2\tilde{q}_2^0\), L.H.S. of (22) is greater than 0 but R.H.S. of (22) is smaller than 0. For \(\hat{q}_1^0<F_2\tilde{q}_2^0\), L.H.S. of (22) is smaller than 0 but R.H.S. of (22) is bigger than 0. Therefore, \(\hat{q}_1^0=\tilde{q}_2^0\). Next, if \(\hat{q}_2^0 = \tilde{q}_1^0\), then

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{r-t}{r-2t+v-\delta } = \frac{\int _0^{\tilde{q}_1^0} F_1(\tilde{q}_1^0-x_2)dF_2(x_2)}{F_1(\hat{q}_2^0)}. \end{aligned}$$
(23)

As \(\int _0^{\tilde{q}_1^0} F_1(\tilde{q}_1^0-x_2)dF_2(x_2)<F_1(\hat{q}_2^0)\) and \(t> v-\delta \). The L.H.S of (23) is bigger than 1 but the R.H.S. of (23) is smaller than 1, and it is a contradiction. Hence, \(\hat{q}_2^0 \ne \tilde{q}_1^0\). In summary the above analysis implies that either (1) \(\hat{q}_1^0 > \tilde{q}_1^0\) and \(\hat{q}_2^0 < \tilde{q}_2^0\) hold, or (2) \(\hat{q}_1^0 < \tilde{q}_1^0\) and \(\hat{q}_2^0 > \tilde{q}_2^0\) hold.

For any fixed rwvt and \(\delta \), let \(D_1(\hat{q}_1,\hat{q}_2)=d\hat{q}_1/d\hat{q}_2\) and \(D_2(\tilde{q}_1,\tilde{q}_2)=d\tilde{q}_1/d\tilde{q}_2\). Furthermore, for any given \(q_i \ge 0\), \(i=1,2\), let \(B_1(q_1,q_2) = (r-t-\delta ) \int _{q_1}^{Q} f_2(Q -x_1) dF_1(x_1) + (t-v) \int _0^{q_1} f_2(Q -x_1) dF_1(x_1)\), \(C_1(q_1,q_2) = B(q_1,q_2) + f_1(q_1)[(t-v+\delta ) F_2(q_2) + (r-t) \bar{F}_2(q_2)]\), \(B_2(q_1,q_2) = (r-t-\delta ) \int _{q_2}^{Q} f_1(Q -x_2) dF_2(x_2) + (t-v) \int _0^{q_2} f_1(Q -x_2) dF_2(x_2)\), and \(C_2(q_1,q_2) = E(q_1,q_2) + f_2(q_2)[(t-v+\delta ) F_1(q_1) + (r-t) \bar{F}_1(q_1)]\). Notice that \(C_1(q_1,q_2)>B_1(q_1,q_2)>0\) and \(C_2(q_1,q_2)>B_2(q_1,q_2)>0\), and hence \(B_1(q_1,q_2)/C_1(q_1,q_2)<C_2(q_1,q_2)/B_2(q_1,q_2)\), \(\forall q_1,q_2>0\).

By taking the first order derivative on both sides of (15-1), we obtain \(D_1(\hat{q}_1,\hat{q}_2) = - B_1(\hat{q}_1,\hat{q}_2)/C_1(\hat{q}_1,\hat{q}_2)<0\). Similarly, for (15-2), we obtain \(D_2(\tilde{q}_1,\tilde{q}_2) = - B_2(\tilde{q}_1,\tilde{q}_2)/C_2(\tilde{q}_1,\tilde{q}_2)<0\). As \(B_1(q_1,q_2)/C_1(q_1,q_2)<C_2q_1,q_2)/B_2(q_1,q_2)\), \(\forall q_1,q_2>0\), \(D_1(\hat{q}_1,\hat{q}_2) < D_2(\tilde{q}_1,\tilde{q}_2)\), \(\forall \)\(\hat{q}_1=\tilde{q}_1\) and \(\hat{q}_2=\tilde{q}_2\).

Fig. 2
figure 2

Unique equilibrium of Model MC

As (1) \(\hat{q}_1^0 = \tilde{q}_2^0\) and \(\hat{q}_2^0=\tilde{q}_1^0\) and (2) \(D_1(\hat{q}_1,\hat{q}_2) < D_2(\tilde{q}_1,\tilde{q}_2)\), \(\forall \)\(\hat{q}_1=\tilde{q}_1\) and \(\hat{q}_2=\tilde{q}_2\), \(\hat{q}_1^0 < \tilde{q}_1^0\) and \(\hat{q}_2^0 > \tilde{q}_2^0\). Therefore, there exist a unique set of \((\hat{q}_1,\hat{q}_2)\) and \((\tilde{q}_1,\tilde{q}_2)\), such that \((\hat{q}_1,\hat{q}_2)=(\tilde{q}_1,\tilde{q}_2)\) (see Fig. 2). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 10

Remind that we consider the case for \(v<t<r-\delta \) only. For any given \(q_1\ge 0\) and \(q_2 \ge 0\), let \(E_1(q_1,q_2)=\int _0^Q F_2(Q-x_1)dF_1(x_1) - 2 \int _0^{q_1} F_2(Q-x_1)dF_1(x_1) dF_1(q_1) >0\) and \(E_2(q_1,q_2)=\int _0^Q F_1(Q-x_2)dF_2(x_2) - 2 \int _0^{q_2} F_1(Q-x_2)dF_2(x_2) dF_2(q_2) >0\). For fixed \(w>c\) and \(\delta \ge 0\), by considering the first order derivative of (15-1) and (15-2), we obtain the systems of ordinary differential equations

$$\begin{aligned} \left\{ \begin{array}{l} dt = \hat{h}_{11} dQ^e_A + \hat{h}_{12} dq^e_1, \\ dt = \hat{h}_{21} dQ^e_A - \hat{h}_{22} dq^e_1, \\ \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(24)

where \(\hat{h}_{11} = B_1(q^e_1,q^e_2)/E_1(q^e_1,q^e_2)>0\), \(\hat{h}_{12} = [C_1(q^e_1,q^e_2)-B_1(q^e_1,q^e_2)]/E_1(q^e_1,q^e_2)>0\), \(\hat{h}_{21} = C_1(q^e_1,q^e_2)/E_2(q^e_1,q^e_2)>0\) and \(\hat{h}_{22} = [C_2(q^e_1,q^e_2)-B_2(q^e_1,q^e_2)]/E_2(q^e_1,q^e_2)>0\). By solving the simultaneous equation (24) for \(dQ^e_A/dt\) and \(dq^e_1/dt\), we obtain \(dQ^e_A/dt = (\hat{h}_{12}+\hat{h}_{22})/(\hat{h}_{11}\hat{h}_{22}+\hat{h}_{12}\hat{h}_{21})>0\). Therefore, \(Q^e_A\) in strictly increasing in t, for \(v< t < r-\delta \). By solving the simultaneous equation (24) for \(dq^e_1/dt\), we obtain \(dq^e_1/dt= (\hat{h}_{21}-\hat{h}_{11})/(\hat{h}_{11}\hat{h}_{22}+\hat{h}_{12}\hat{h}_{21})\). \(dq^e_1/dt \lesseqgtr 0\) if and only if \(\hat{h}_{21} \lesseqgtr \hat{h}_{11}\). Therefore, \(q^e_1\) is non-monotonic with t. By following a similar approach, we obtain \(dq^e_2/dt= (\hat{h}_{12}-\hat{h}_{22})/(\hat{h}_{11}\hat{h}_{22}+\hat{h}_{12}\hat{h}_{21})\). \(dq^e_1/dt \lesseqgtr 0\) if and only if \(\hat{h}_{12} \lesseqgtr \hat{h}_{22}\). Therefore, \(q^e_2\) is non-monotonic with t too.

For fixed \(w>c\) and \(v<t<r\), by considering the first order derivative of (15-1) and (15-2), we obtain the systems of ordinary differential equations

$$\begin{aligned} \left\{ \begin{array}{l} d \delta = \tilde{h}_{11} dQ^e_R + \tilde{h}_{12} dq^e_1, \\ d \delta = \tilde{h}_{21} dQ^e_R - \tilde{h}_{22} dq^e_1, \\ \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(25)

where \(\tilde{h}_{11} = B_1(q^e_1,q^e_2)/[W(Q^e_A)-W(q^e_1)]>0\), \(\tilde{h}_{12} = [C_1(q^e_1,q^e_2)-B_1(q^e_1,q^e_2)]/[W(Q^e_A)-W(q^e_1)]>0\), \(\tilde{h}_{21} = C_1(q^e_1,q^e_2)/[W(Q^e_A)-W(q^e_2)]>0\) and \(\tilde{h}_{22} = [C_2(q^e_1,q^e_2)-B_2(q^e_1,q^e_2)]/[W(Q^e_A)-W(q^e_2)]>0\). By solving the simultaneous equation (25) for \(dQ^e_A/d \delta \), we obtain \(dQ^e_A/d \delta = (\tilde{h}_{12}+\tilde{h}_{22})/(\tilde{h}_{11}\tilde{h}_{22}+\tilde{h}_{12}\tilde{h}_{21})>0\). Therefore, \(Q^e_A\) in strictly increasing in \(\delta \), for \(0< \delta < r-t\). By solving the simultaneous equation (25) for \(dq^e_1/d \delta \), we obtain \(dq^e_1/d \delta = (\tilde{h}_{21}-\tilde{h}_{11})/(\tilde{h}_{11}\tilde{h}_{22}+\tilde{h}_{12}\tilde{h}_{21})\). \(dq^e_1/d \delta \lesseqgtr 0\) if and only if \(\tilde{h}_{21} \lesseqgtr \tilde{h}_{11}\). Therefore, \(q^e_1\) is non-monotonic with \(\delta \). By following a similar approach, we obtain \(dq^e_2/d \delta = (\tilde{h}_{12}-\tilde{h}_{22})/(\tilde{h}_{11}\tilde{h}_{22}+\tilde{h}_{12}\tilde{h}_{21})\). \(dq^e_1/d \delta \lesseqgtr 0\) if and only if \(\tilde{h}_{12} \lesseqgtr \tilde{h}_{22}\). Therefore, \(q^e_2\) is non-monotonic with \(\delta \) too. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 11

Part (a): For \(t=r\) and \(\delta =0\), (15) becomes

$$\begin{aligned} \left\{ \begin{array}{l} (r-w)/(r-v) = \int _0^{q^e_1} F_2(Q^e_R-x_1)dF_1(x_1), \\ (r-w)/(r-v) = \int _0^{q^e_2} F_1(Q^e_R-x_2)dF_2(x_2). \\ \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$

As \(F_1(q_1^o)=F_2(q_2^o)=(r-w)/(r-v)\), \(F_1(q^e_1)>\int _0^{q^e_1} F_2(Q^e_A-x_1)dF_1(x_1)\) and \(F_2(q^e_1)>\int _0^{q^e_2} F_1(Q^e_R-x_2)dF_2(x_2)\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} F_1(q_1^o)< F_1(q^e_1) \; \mathrm{and} \; F_2(q_2^o) < F_1(q^e_2). \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, \(q_1^o<q^e_1\), \(q_2^o<q^e_2\) and \(Q_A^o<Q^e_A\).

Part (b) For \(t=v\) and \(\delta =0\), (15) becomes

$$\begin{aligned} \left\{ \begin{array}{l} (r-w)/(r-v) = \int _{q^e_1}^{Q^e_A} F_2(Q^e_A-x_1)dF_1(x_1)+ F_1(q^e_1), \\ (r-w)/(r-v) = \int _{q^e_2}^{Q^e_A} F_1(Q^e_A-x_2)dF_2(x_2)+ F_2(q^e_2). \\ \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$

As \(F_1(q_1^o)=F_2(q_2^o)=(r-w)/(r-v)\), \(\int _{q^e_1}^{Q^e_A} F_2(Q^e_A-x_1)dF_1(x_1) >0\) and \(\int _{q^e_2}^{Q^e_A} F_2(Q^e_A-x_2)dF_2(x_2) >0\), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} F_1(q_1^o)> F_1(q^e_1), \; \mathrm{and} F_2(q_2^o) > F_1(q^e_2). \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, \(q_1^o>q^e_1\), \(q_2^o>q^e_2\) and \(Q_A^o>Q^e_A\).

Part (c): For \(t= (r+v-\delta )/2\), (15) is equivalently to (7). Therefore, \(q_1^*=q^e_1\), \(q_2^*=q^e_2\) and \(Q_R^*=Q^e_R\). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 12

Similar to the proof of Proposition 6. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 13

Part (a): For \((\delta ,t)\in \mathcal {Q}^+\), \(Q^e_A > Q^o_A\). Therefore, \(\pi _{M,B}(q_1^o,q_2^o) = (w-c) Q^o_A < (w-c) Q^e_A\). In addition, as \(\sum _{i=1}^2 \int _0^{q_i} F_i(x_i) dx_i > \int _0^Q F_1(x_1)F_2(Q-x_1)dx_1\), \(\forall q_1>0\) and \(\forall q_1>0\), \(\pi _{M,B}(q_1^o,q_2^o) < \pi _{M,MC}(q_1^e,q_2^e)\). By (16) and Proposition 12, we obtain (17). The proof of part (b) is similar to the proof of part (a), and we omit it here. Part (c): By considering \(\pi _{M,MC}(q^e_1,q^e_2)>\pi _{M,B}(q^o_1,q^o_2)\) and \(\pi _{SC,MC}(q^e_1,q^e_2)>\pi _{SC,B}(q^o_1,q^o_{A_2})\), we obtain (20) and (21), respectively. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Chiu, CH., Hao, G., Dai, X. et al. Inventory sharing of professional optics product supply chain with equal power agents. Ann Oper Res 291, 169–194 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-019-03177-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-019-03177-3

Keywords