Abstract
This paper concerns the dual risk model, dual to the risk model for insurance applications, where premiums are surplus-dependent. In such a model, premiums are regarded as costs and claims refer to profits. We calculate the mean of the cumulative discounted dividends paid until the time of ruin, if the barrier strategy is applied. We formulate the associated Hamilton–Jacobi–Bellman equation and identify sufficient conditions for a barrier strategy to be optimal. Numerical examples are provided.
Similar content being viewed by others
References
De Finetti, B.: Su un’impostazione alternativa della teoria collettiva del rischio [On an alternative setting of collective theory of risk]. Trans. XV Intern. Congr. Act 2, 433–443 (1957)
Gerber, H.U., Shiu, E.S.W.: Optimal dividends: analysis with Brownian motion. N. Am. Actuar. J. 8(1), 1–20 (2004)
Asmussen, S., Taksar, M.: Controlled diffusion models for optimal dividend pay-out. Insur. Math. Econ. 20(1), 1–15 (1997)
Jeanblanc, M., Shiryaev, A.: Optimization of the flow of dividends. Russ. Math. Surv. 50(2), 257–277 (1995)
Pablo, A., Nora, N.: Optimal reinsurance and dividend distribution policies in the Cramér-Lundberg model. Math. Financ. 15(2), 261–308 (2005)
Schmidli, H.: Optimisation in non-life insurance. Stoch. Models 22(4), 689–722 (2006)
Avram, F., Palmowski, Z., Pistorius, M.: On the optimal dividend problem for a spectrally negative Lévy process. Ann. Appl. Probab. 17(1), 156–180 (2007)
Avram, F., Palmowski, Z., Pistorius, M.R.: On Gerber-Shiu functions and optimal dividend distribution for a Lévy risk process in the presence of a penalty function. Ann. Appl. Probab. 25(4), 1868–1935 (2015)
Kyprianou, A., Palmowski, Z.: Distributional study of de Finetti’s dividend problem for a general Lévy insurance risk process. J. Appl. Probab. 44(2), 428–443 (2007)
Loeffen, R.: On optimality of the barrier strategy in de Finetti’s dividend problem for spectrally negative Lévy processes. J. Appl. Probab. 18(5), 1669–1680 (2008)
Loeffen, R.: An optimal dividends problem with transaction costs for spectrally negative Lévy processes. Insur. Math. Econ. 45(1), 41–48 (2009)
Loeffen, R., Renaud, J.F.: De Finetti’s optimal dividends problem with an affine penalty function at ruin. Insur. Math. Econ. 46(1), 98–108 (2010)
Czarna, I., Palmowski, Z.: Dividend problem with parisian delay for a spectrally negative Lévy risk process. J. Optim. Theory Appl. 161(1), 239–256 (2010)
Avanzi, B., Gerber, H.U., Shiu, E.S.W.: Optimal dividends in the dual model. Insur. Math. Econ. 41, 111–123 (2007)
Avanzi, B., Gerber, H.U.: Optimal dividends in the dual model with diffusion. ASTIN Bull. 38(2), 653–667 (2008)
Bayraktar, E., Kyprianou, A.E., Yamazaki, K.: On optimal dividends in the dual model. Astin Bull. 43(3), 359–372 (2014)
Ng, A.C.Y.: On a dual model with a dividend threshold. Insur. Math. Econ. 44, 315–324 (2009)
Afonso, L.B., Cardoso, R.M.R., dos Reis, E.: Dividend problems in the dual risk model. Insur. Math. Econ. 53, 906–918 (2013)
Albrecher, H., Badescu, A.L., Landriault, D.: On the dual risk model with tax payments. Insur. Math. Econ. 42(3), 1086–1094 (2008)
Marciniak, E., Palmowski, Z.: On the optimal dividend problem for insurance risk models with surplus-dependent premiums. J. Optim. Theory Appl. 168, 723–742 (2016)
Albrecher, H., Constantinescu, C., Palmowski, Z., Regensburger, G., Rosenkranz, M.: Exact and asymptotic results for insurance risk models with surplus-dependent premiums. SIAM J. Appl. Math. 73(1), 47–66 (2013)
Davis, M.H.A.: Markov Models and Optimization, Monographs on Statistics and Applied Probability. Chapman & Hall, London (1993)
Rolski, T., Schmidli, H., Schmidt, V., Teugels, J.: Stochastic Processes for Insurance and Finance. Wiley, Chichester (1999)
Acknowledgements
The first author would like to express her gratitude to Prof. Szymon Peszat for his motivation and encouragement. Our sincere thanks to Luis Lopez-Oliveros for useful suggestions and comments. We are also grateful to the anonymous reviewer whose suggestions helped to improve and clarify this paper. This work is partially supported by the National Science Centre under the grant 2015/17/B/ST1/01102. The second author kindly acknowledges partial support by the project RARE -318984, a Marie Curie IRSES Fellowship within the 7th European Community Framework Programme.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Appendices
Appendix A: Proof of the Verification Theorem 4.1
Fix an arbitrary \(x\in ]0,\infty [\) and \(\pi \in \Pi \). Let \(\{t_n\}_{n=1}^{\infty }\) denote all jumping times for \(L^{\pi }\). Since m is \(C^1\) on \(]0,\infty [\) and \(X^{\pi }_{t\wedge \sigma ^\pi }\in [0,\infty [\), we are allowed to apply Itô’s formula to the process
which gives:
where \(L^{\pi ,c}\) denotes the continuous part of \(L^{\pi }\) and \(M_t\) is a local martingale with \(M_0=0\). Since m satisfies (12), we have
Let \(\{s_n\}_{n=1}^{\infty }\) be a localizing sequence of M. Taking expectations and using the fact that \(m\ge 0\), we obtain
Letting first \(n\rightarrow \infty \), and then \(t\rightarrow \infty \) and applying the Monotone Convergence Theorem yields:
Therefore, since both \(\pi \in \Pi \) and x are arbitrary, we proved the desired inequality \(m(x)\ge v(x)\) for all \(x\in [0,\infty [\). \(\square \)
Appendix B: Additional Facts
Before we prove the main results of this paper, we demonstrate a few auxiliary facts used in these proofs.
Lemma B.1
Let \(\beta \ge 0\). Assume that we have a function \(h_\beta :{\mathbb {R}}\rightarrow [0,\infty [\), such that \(h_\beta (x)=x-\beta +h_\beta (\beta )\) for all \(x>\beta \) and \(h_\beta (x)=0\) for all \(x\le 0\). If the function \(h_\beta (x)\) solves the equation
with the boundary conditions \(h_\beta '(\beta )=1\), then
Proof
Let \(X^\beta :=X^{\pi _\beta }\). Take an arbitrary \(x\in [0,\beta ]\). Applying Itô’s formula to \(e^{-qt\wedge s_n}h_\beta (X^\beta _{t\wedge s_n})\), where \(\{s_n\}_{n=1}^{\infty }\) is a localizing sequence of M, we obtain
Note that the process \(X^{\beta }\) is decreasing between the positive jumps, hence \(L^{\beta ,c}\equiv 0\). Moreover, \(X_{s-}^\beta >\beta \) on \(\{\varDelta L^\beta _s>0\}\) and \(h_\beta (X_{s-}^\beta -\varDelta L_s^\beta )=h_\beta (\beta )\). Thus, after rearranging and letting first \(n\rightarrow \infty \) and then \(t\rightarrow \infty \), using the dominated convergence theorem yields:
This completes the proof. \(\square \)
Lemma B.2
Assume that p is \(C^1\) on \(]0,\infty [\) and that \(-p'(x) -q<0\) for all \(x\in ]0,\beta ]\). If \(v_\beta '(\beta -)\ge 1\), then \(v_{\beta }(x)\) is in \(C^2\) on \(]0,\beta [\) and it is increasing and concave on \(]0,\infty [\).
Proof
We begin by proving that \(v_{\beta }\) is increasing on \(]0,\beta [\). Let
By the Strong Markov property of the PDMP, \(R_t\) for all \(0<y<x<\beta \)
which completes the proof of this statement. Furthermore, since p is \(C^1\) by (15), we have that \(v_{\beta }\) is \(C^2\) on \(]0,\beta [\) and \(v_{\beta }\) is left-continuous at \(\beta \). Moreover, if we differentiate (15) with respect to x, then we get:
Consequently, since \(v_{\beta }'(\beta -)\ge 1\), we obtain
We prove the final part by contradiction. Assume that \(v_{\beta }\) is not concave. Then, by continuity of \(v_{\beta }''\), there exists \({\hat{x}}\in ]0,\beta [\), such that \(v_{\beta }''({\hat{x}})=0\) and \(v_{\beta }''(x)<0\) for all \(x\in ]{\hat{x}},\beta [\). Hence, from the assumption that \(v_\beta '(\beta -)\ge 1\), it follows
This leads to the contradiction. Therefore, \(v_{\beta }''(x)<0\) for all \(x\in ]0,\beta [\). \(\square \)
Now, we are ready to prove the main results.
Appendix C: Proof of the Theorem 4.4
From (13) and (15), we can conclude that \(v_\beta \) on \(]0,\beta [\) satisfies the equation:
with the initial condition \(v_\beta (0)=0\). We recall that we are looking for \(\beta ^*\) satisfying \(v_{\beta ^*}'(\beta ^*)=1\). Let
Transforming equation (20), we obtain the following Fredholm Equation for \(u_\beta \):
where
Taking \(x=\beta \) in (21) leads to the equation:
Let:
We want to prove the existence of \(\beta ^*\) with the constraint:
By our assumption:
We will show that
By contradiction, assume that \(\gamma ({\hat{x}})>1\). Then, by Lemma B.2, we have that \(u_{{\hat{x}}}\) is increasing and consequently \(u_{{\hat{x}}}(y)>1\) for all \(y\in ]0,{\hat{x}}[\). Thus,
In this way, we derived a contradiction. To get (23) by (24) and (25), it suffices to prove that \(\gamma \) is a continuous function. The latter follows from the following observation.
We denote \(\varDelta _\beta b_\beta (x)=b_{\beta }(x)-b_{\beta -}(x)\) for a general function \(b_\beta \). From (21), it follows that
and hence, function \(\beta \rightarrow \varDelta _\beta u_\beta (\beta )\) is continuous. Note that from the last conclusion, it follows that
and function \(\beta \rightarrow u_\beta (\beta )=\gamma (\beta )\) is also continuous. This completes the proof. \(\square \)
Appendix D: Proof of the Theorem 4.5
By Lemma B.2, we have \(v_{\beta ^*}'(x)\ge v_{\beta ^*}'(\beta ^*)=1\) for all \(x\in ]0,\beta ^*[\). Moreover, \(({\mathcal {A}}-q{\mathbf {I}})v_{\beta ^*}(x)=0\) for \(x\in ]0,\beta ^*[\). It remains to prove that \(({\mathcal {A}}-q{\mathbf {I}})v_{\beta ^*}(x)\le 0\) for \(x>\beta ^*\).
Note that \(v_{\beta ^*}\) is \(C^1\), and therefore, by assumption that \(p\in C^1\), the function \(({\mathcal {A}}-q{\mathbf {I}})v_{\beta ^*}(x)\) is continuous at \(x=\beta ^*\). Thus, we have \(({\mathcal {A}}-q{\mathbf {I}})v_{\beta ^*}(\beta ^*)=0\). Furthermore, since
and \(({\mathcal {A}}-q{\mathbf {I}})v_{\beta ^*}(x)=-p(x)+\lambda \int _0^\infty zdF(z)-q(x-\beta ^*+v_{\beta ^*}(\beta ^*))\), we have:
Hence, by Theorem 4.1, \(v_{\beta ^*}(x)\ge v(x)\) for all \(x\ge 0\). At the same time, by the definition of the value function, we have that \(v_{\beta ^*}(x)\le v(x)\) for all \(x\ge 0\). Consequently, \(v_{\beta ^*}(x)=v(x)\) and by Lemma B.1 v must uniquely solve the equation (15) with the boundary condition \(v^\prime (\beta ^*)=1\). This completes the proof. \(\square \)
Appendix E: Proof of the Lemma 4.1
Assume first that Condition (i) holds. In this case, we will follow the same arguments as in the proof of Theorem 4.5 to get the opposite to (26) inequality \(({\mathcal {A}}-q{\mathbf {I}})v_{\beta ^*}({\check{x}})>0\). Indeed, by the continuity of the function \(x\mapsto ({\mathcal {A}}-q)v_{\beta ^*}(x)\), there exists an open and bounded interval \(\mathrm {J}\subset ]\beta ^*,\infty [\) such that \({\check{x}}\in \mathrm {J}\) and \(({\mathcal {A}}-q)v_{\beta ^*}(x)> 0\) for all \(x\in \mathrm {J}\). Define a strategy \({\tilde{\pi }}\) as follows: whenever the process \(X^{{\tilde{\pi }}}\) takes values in the interval \(\mathrm {J}\), do not pay any dividends, otherwise operate according to \(\pi _\beta ^*\). If we extend \(v_{\beta ^*}\) to the negative half-axis by \(v_{\beta ^*}(x)=0\) for \(x<0\), then we have
where \(T_\mathrm {J}:=\inf \left\{ t\ge 0:R_t\notin \mathrm {J}\right\} \). Note that by Davis [22] and Rolski et al. [23], the process \(R_t\) is a piecewise deterministic Markov process, and the function \(v_{\beta ^*}(x)\) is in a domain of extended generator \({\mathcal {A}}-q{\mathbf {I}}\) of exponentially killed dual process R. Thus, the stopped process
is a Dynkin mean-zero martingale for \(R_0=x\in \mathrm {J}\). In fact, it is uniformly integrable since using (26) we have
and \({\mathbb {E}}T_{\mathrm {J}}<\infty \) because of the positive drift assumption and \({\mathbb {E}}R_{T_{\mathrm {J}}}\le \sup _{x\in \mathrm {J}}x +{\mathbb {E}}C_{N(T_{\mathrm {J}})}<\infty \). Now, we apply the Optional Stopping Theorem to \(K_{t}\) to get, for all \(x\in \mathrm {J}\),
Therefore, \(\pi _\beta ^*\) is not optimal among all admissible strategies.
Assuming Condition (ii), we can follow the proof of Lemma B.2. Taking \(\beta =\beta ^*\) and \(x=\beta ^*\) in (19), we have
By the continuity of \(v_{\beta }''\) and the fact that \(v_{\beta }'(\beta ^*)=1\), we can conclude that there exists an interval \(]{\dot{x}},\beta ^*[\) for which \(v_{\beta }'(x)<1\). We now consider a strategy \({\tilde{\pi }}\), which pays immediately anything above the level \({\dot{x}}\) if the reserve process takes values in \(]{\dot{x}},\beta ^*[\), and then follows the strategy \(\pi _\beta ^*\). Then, for \(x\in ]{\dot{x}},\beta ^*[\) , we have
Since \(v_{\beta }'(x)<1\) for all \(x\in ]{\dot{x}},\beta ^*[\), hence \(v_\pi (x)>v_\beta ^*(x)\). Thus, \(\pi _\beta ^*\) is not optimal. \(\square \)
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Marciniak, E., Palmowski, Z. On the Optimal Dividend Problem in the Dual Model with Surplus-Dependent Premiums. J Optim Theory Appl 179, 533–552 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10957-016-1050-7
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10957-016-1050-7
Keywords
- Dividends
- PDMP
- Optimal strategy
- Barrier strategy
- Integro-differential HJB equation
- Dual model
- Stochastic control
- Exit problems