Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

Concentration of land ownership

(Redirected from Land monopoly)

Concentration of land ownership refers to the ownership of land in a particular area by a small number of people or organizations.[1] It is sometimes defined as additional concentration beyond that which produces optimally efficient land use.[2]

Distribution

edit

Land concentration exists in many countries. In Brazil, one of the countries with the highest amount of land concentration, the situation has resulted in large tracts lying idle while 95% of farmers work just 11% of the arable land. In 2010, the Czech Republic had the highest concentration, according to World Bank figures.[3] In Scotland, just 400 people own more than 50% of privately owned land.[4] Other countries with high land concentration include the United States, Venezuela, Paraguay, South Africa, and Namibia.[5] Land concentration is currently increasing in the European Union[6] and the United States,[7] but decreasing in North Africa.[8]

Development

edit

In theory, a free market should allocate land in the most productive way, but in practice landowning groups have disproportionate power in many countries. Landlords seek to control land so they can extract rent, in the form of payments from tenant farmers, or more recently agricultural subsidies and other subsidies from the state.[9][10] State policies which favor large landowners, such as differential taxation that hits free peasants harder than large landlords and serfs,[11] are an important cause of land concentration.[8] One way that land is accumulated is through unitary inheritance, in contrast to life estates or partible inheritance which tend to redistribute land over time.[12][13] Conquest can lead to land concentration if the conquerors confiscate land from the original owners.[14][15] High interest rates or lack of access to credit can block poorer farmers from buying land, while debt can force them to sell to larger landholders.[16][17] Historically, when land owning becomes less profitable, landowners sell and rural peasants have an opportunity to acquire land.[18] Along with land reform, inheritance taxes and capital gains taxes have also led to the breakup of some estates.[17] Land reform in some countries, including Ireland, South Korea, Japan,[5] and Mexico, have significantly reduced land concentration.[19]

Effects

edit

Critics argue that concentrated land ownership gives the landowner too much power over local communities, reduces opportunities, and impedes economic growth.[20] One study of nineteenth-century Prussia found an inverse correlation between large estates and educational enrollment.[21] In Central America, an economic boom in coffee production led to vastly different results in different countries: Costa Rica and Colombia were dominated by smallholdings and experienced democratization and surging literacy rates, while in El Salvador and Guatemala, rural laborers earned bare subsistence.[22] Studies in 48 developing countries found a correlation between land concentration and deforestation.[23] Another study found an inverse correlation between inequality of land ownership and economic growth.[24] According to a Scottish landlord group, however, land use is more important than land ownership, and there is not enough evidence for a negative effect.[25]

Scholars have linked land inequality with unstable democracies and dictatorships, whereas greater land equality tends to be linked to stable democratic forms of government.[26][27][28]

According to some economists, concentrated land ownership in non-Western countries explains the Great Divergence in outcomes between wealthy, Western countries and the rest of the world. Israeli economist Oded Galor writes the mediating factor for this effect was that large landholdings gave the landowning elites political power to stop reforms aimed at improving education rates and therefore human capital, which in turn facilitated the divergence.[29] According to Gary Libecap, differences in land ownership patterns explain much of the different development trajectories between the United States and Latin America. He attributes the greater success and entrepreneurial spirit of the United States to its Homestead Acts giving land to prospective smallholders.[30]

Although there has been some debate as to the optimal size of landholdings for agricultural productivity, research has indicated that unlike industry, which benefits from economy of scale, the most productive farms are small- to medium- sized family farms cultivated with a minimum of hired labor. This may be because family labor is cheaper and more productive than hired labor, or because crops benefit from close attention. (The phenomenon of small farms being more efficient is known as the inverse relationship).[31] On the other hand, land fragmentation is known to reduce productivity of land.[32]

See also

edit
  • Absentee landlord – Person who rents a property, but does not live in the property's local economic region
  • Equal-field system – Ancient Chinese system of land ownership
  • Latifundia – Very extensive parcel of privately owned land both in antique Rome and in modern days
  • Land tenure – Legal regime in which area owned by an individual is held by another person
  • Land value tax – Levy on the unimproved value of land

References

edit
  1. ^ Glass, McMorran & Thomson 2019, p. 4.
  2. ^ United States Bureau of Corporations 1914, p. 156.
  3. ^ Paulino 2014, pp. 135–136.
  4. ^ Glass, McMorran & Thomson 2019, p. 9.
  5. ^ a b Moyo 2014, p. 19.
  6. ^ Kay 2016, p. 14.
  7. ^ O'Donoghue et al. 2010.
  8. ^ a b Moyo 2008, p. 42.
  9. ^ Binswanger-Mkhize & Deininger 2007, p. 1.
  10. ^ Deininger 2003, p. 14.
  11. ^ Wasserstrom 2013, p. 48.
  12. ^ Babie 2019, pp. 213–214.
  13. ^ Snay 2010, p. 104.
  14. ^ Tilly 2004, p. 136.
  15. ^ Carte et al. 2019, p. 8.
  16. ^ a b Glass, McMorran & Thomson 2019, p. 39.
  17. ^ Glass, McMorran & Thomson 2019, p. 10.
  18. ^ OECD 2006, p. 140.
  19. ^ Glass, McMorran & Thomson 2019, pp. 25, 28.
  20. ^ Cinnirella & Hornung 2016, p. abstract.
  21. ^ Glass, McMorran & Thomson 2019, p. 29.
  22. ^ Ceddia 2019, p. 2527.
  23. ^ Glass, McMorran & Thomson 2019, p. 28.
  24. ^ Carrell 2019.
  25. ^ Russett, Bruce M. (1964). "Inequality and Instability: The Relation of Land Tenure to Politics". World Politics. 16 (3): 442–454. doi:10.2307/2009581. ISSN 1086-3338. JSTOR 2009581. S2CID 154937085.
  26. ^ Ansell, Ben; Samuels, David (2010). "Inequality and Democratization: A Contractarian Approach". Comparative Political Studies. 43 (12): 1543–1574. doi:10.1177/0010414010376915. ISSN 0010-4140. S2CID 41858911.
  27. ^ Acemoglu, Daron; Naidu, Suresh; Restrepo, Pascual; Robinson, James A. (2015), Atkinson, Anthony B.; Bourguignon, François (eds.), Chapter 21 - Democracy, Redistribution, and Inequality, Handbook of Income Distribution, vol. 2, Elsevier, pp. 1885–1966, doi:10.1016/B978-0-444-59429-7.00022-4, hdl:1721.1/84473, ISBN 9780444594303
  28. ^ Galor, Moav & Vollrath 2009, 7. Concluding remarks.
  29. ^ Libecap 2018.
  30. ^ Jacobs 2010, p. 6.
  31. ^ Manjunatha et al. 2013, p. 397.

Sources

edit

Further reading

edit