Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                
Jump to content

Consumption function: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Made information more concise, eliminated unreferenced biased statements, and added Keynes' thoughts on the tendency for the MPC to decrease as income increases.
m no sentence
 
(44 intermediate revisions by 27 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Short description|Economic model relating consumption and disposable income}}
{{Distinguish|demand function}}
{{Distinguish|demand function}}
[[File:Consumption Function.png|thumb|Graphical representation of the consumption function, where a is autonomous consumption (affected by interest rates, consumer expectations, etc.), b is the marginal propensity to consume and Yd is disposable income]]
[[File:Consumption Function.jpg|thumb|Consumption function graph]]
In [[economics]], the '''consumption function''' describes a relationship between [[Consumption (economics)|consumption]] and [[Disposable and discretionary income|disposable income]].<ref>Algebraically, this means <math>C = f(Y_{d})</math> where <math>f \colon \mathbb{R}^{+} \to \mathbb{R}^{+}</math> is a [[Function (mathematics)|function]] that [[Map (mathematics)|maps]] levels of disposable income <math>Y_{d}</math>—income after government intervention, such as taxes or transfer payments—into levels of consumption <math>C</math>.</ref><ref>{{cite book |first=John |last=Lindauer |author-link=John Lindauer |title=Macroeconomics |location=New York |publisher=John Wiley & Sons |edition=Third |year=1976 |isbn=0-471-53572-9 |pages=40–43 }}</ref> The concept is believed to have been introduced into [[macroeconomics]] by [[John Maynard Keynes]] in 1936, who used it to develop the notion of a [[Fiscal multiplier|government spending multiplier]].<ref>{{cite book |last1=Hall |first1=Robert E. |author-link=Robert Hall (economist) |last2=Taylor |first2=John B. |author2-link=John B. Taylor |chapter=Consumption and Income |pages=63–67 |title=Macroeconomics: Theory, Performance, and Policy |location=New York |publisher=W. W. Norton |year=1986 |isbn=0-393-95398-X }}</ref>
__NOTOC__
In [[economics]], the '''consumption function''' describes a relationship between [[Consumption (economics)|consumption]] and [[Disposable and discretionary income|disposable income]].<ref>{{cite book |first=John |last=Lindauer |authorlink=John Lindauer |title=Macroeconomics |location=New York |publisher=John Wiley & Sons |edition=Third |year=1976 |isbn=0-471-53572-9 |pages=40–43 |url= }}</ref> Algebraically, this means <math>C = f(Y_{d})</math> where <math>f \colon \mathbb{R} \to \mathbb{R}</math> is a [[Function (mathematics)|function]] that [[Map (mathematics)|maps]] levels of disposable income <math>Y_{d}</math>—income after government intervention, such as taxes or transfer payments—into levels of consumption <math>C</math>. The concept is believed to have been introduced into [[macroeconomics]] by [[John Maynard Keynes]] in 1936, who used it to develop the notion of a [[Fiscal multiplier|government spending multiplier]].<ref>{{cite book |last=Hall |first=Robert E. |authorlink=Robert Hall (economist) |last2=Taylor |first2=John B. |author2link=John B. Taylor |chapter=Consumption and Income |pages=63–67 |title=Macroeconomics: Theory, Performance, and Policy |location=New York |publisher=W. W. Norton |year=1986 |edition= |isbn=0-393-95398-X }}</ref> Its simplest form is the ''linear consumption function'' used frequently in simple Keynesian models:<ref>{{cite book |first=David |last=Colander |authorlink=David Colander |title=Macroeconomics: Theory and Policy |location=Glenview |publisher=Scott, Foresman and Co. |year=1986 |isbn=0-673-16648-1 |pages=94–97 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=I1pQAQAAIAAJ&pg=PA94 }}</ref>


==Details==
<math>C = a + b \times Y_{d}</math>
Its simplest form is the ''linear consumption function'' used frequently in simple [[Keynesian economics|Keynesian models]]:<ref>{{cite book |first=David |last=Colander |author-link=David Colander |title=Macroeconomics: Theory and Policy |location=Glenview |publisher=Scott, Foresman and Co. |year=1986 |isbn=0-673-16648-1 |pages=[https://archive.org/details/macroeconomicsth0000cola/page/94 94]–97 |url=https://archive.org/details/macroeconomicsth0000cola |url-access=registration }}</ref>


:<math>C = a + b \cdot Y_{d}</math>
where <math>a</math> is the [[autonomous consumption]] that is independent of disposable income; in other words, consumption when income is zero. The term <math>b \times Y_{d}</math> is the [[induced consumption]] that is influenced by the economy's income level. The parameter <math>b</math> is known as the [[marginal propensity to consume]], i.e. the increase in consumption due to an incremental increase in disposable income, since <math> \partial C / \partial Y_{d} = b</math>. Geometrically, <math>b</math> is the [[slope]] of the consumption function. One of the key assumptions of [[Keynesian economics]] is that this parameter is positive but smaller than one, i.e. <math>b \in (0,1)</math>.<ref>{{cite book|title=[[The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money]]|last=Keynes|first=John M.|publisher=Harcourt Brace Jovanovich|year=1936|isbn=|location=New York|page=96|pages=|quote=The fundamental psychological law ... is that men [and women] are disposed, as a rule and on average, to increase their consumption as their income increases, but not as much as the increase in their income.}}</ref>


where <math>a</math> is the [[autonomous consumption]] that is independent of disposable income; in other words, consumption when disposable income is zero. The term <math>b \cdot Y_{d}</math> is the [[induced consumption]] that is influenced by the economy's income level <math>Y_{d}</math>. The parameter <math>b</math> is known as the [[marginal propensity to consume]], i.e. the increase in consumption due to an incremental increase in disposable income, since <math> \partial C / \partial Y_{d} = b</math>. Geometrically, <math>b</math> is the [[slope]] of the consumption function.
Keynes also took note of the tendency for the marginal propensity to consume to decrease as income increases, i.e. <math>b'<1</math>.<ref>{{Cite book|title=[[The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money]]|last=Keynes|first=John M.|publisher=Harcourt Brace Jovanovich|year=1936|isbn=|location=New York|pages=|quote=The marginal propensity to consume is not constant for all levels of employment, and it is probable that there will be, as a rule, a tendency for it to diminish as employment increases; when real income increases, that is to say, the community will wish to consume a gradually diminishing proportion of it.}}</ref> If this assumption is to be used, it would result in a nonlinear consumption function with a diminishing slope. Further theories on the shape of the consumption function include [[James Duesenberry]]'s (1949) relative consumption expenditure,<ref>{{cite book |last=Duesenberry |first=J. S. |year=1949 |title=Income, Saving and the Theory of Consumer Behavior |location= |publisher= |edition= }}</ref> [[Franco Modigliani]] and Richard Brumberg's (1954) [[life-cycle hypothesis]], and [[Milton Friedman]]'s (1957) [[permanent income hypothesis]].<ref>{{cite book |last=Friedman |first=M. |year=1957 |title=A Theory of the Consumption Function |location= |publisher= |edition= }}</ref>


Keynes proposed this model to fit three [[Stylized fact|stylized facts]]:<ref>{{Cite book |last=Mankiw |first=N. Gregory |url=https://www.worldcat.org/oclc/1289514240 |title=Macroeconomics |date=2022 |isbn=978-1-319-26390-4 |edition=11 |location=New York |at=20-1 What Determines Consumer Spending? |oclc=1289514240}}</ref>
Some new theoretical works are based, following Duesenberry's one, on behavioral economics and suggest that a number of behavioural principles can be taken as microeconomic foundations for a behaviorally-based aggregate consumption function.<ref>{{Cite journal | doi = 10.1016/j.joep.2010.09.004| title = Behavioral foundations for the Keynesian consumption function| journal = Journal of Economic Psychology| volume = 31| issue = 6| pages = 1035| year = 2010| last1 = d’Orlando | first1 = F. | last2 = Sanfilippo | first2 = E. }}</ref>

* People typically spend a part, but not all of their income on consumption, and they save the rest. They typically do not borrow money to spend, or borrow money to save.<ref name=":0">{{cite book |last=Keynes |first=John M. |title=[[The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money]] |publisher=Harcourt Brace Jovanovich |year=1936 |location=New York |at=Section 3.8.2 |quote=There are not many people who will alter their way of living because the rate of interest has fallen from 5 to 4 per cent, if their aggregate income is the same as before... the short-period influence of the rate of interest on individual spending out of a given income is secondary and relatively unimportant, except, perhaps, where unusually large changes are in question.}}</ref> This fact is modelled by requiring <math>b \in (0,1)</math>.
* People with higher income save a higher proportion of the income. This is modelled by <math>\frac{C}{Y_d}</math> decreasing with <math>Y_d</math>.
* People, when deciding how much to save, are insensitive to the interest rate.<ref name=":0" />
By basing his model in how typical households decide how much to save and spend, Keynes was informally using a [[Microfoundations|microfoundation]] approach to the macroeconomics of saving.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Solow |first=Robert M. |date=2004 |title=Introduction: The Tobin Approach to Monetary Economics |url=http://dx.doi.org/10.1353/mcb.2004.0067 |journal=Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking |volume=36 |issue=4 |pages=657–663 |doi=10.1353/mcb.2004.0067 |s2cid=154008365 |issn=1538-4616 |quote=... recall Keynes’s argument that the marginal propensity to consume should be between zero and one, or his discussion about whether the marginal efficiency of investment should be sensitive to current output or should depend primarily on “the state of long-term expectations.” Those are microfoundations.}}</ref>

Keynes also took note of the tendency for the marginal propensity to consume to decrease as income increases, i.e. <math> \partial^{2} C / \partial Y_{d}^{2} < 0</math>.<ref>{{Cite book|title=[[The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money]]|last=Keynes|first=John M.|publisher=Harcourt Brace Jovanovich|year=1936|location=New York|quote=The marginal propensity to consume is not constant for all levels of employment, and it is probable that there will be, as a rule, a tendency for it to diminish as employment increases; when real income increases, that is to say, the community will wish to consume a gradually diminishing proportion of it.}}</ref> If this assumption is to be used, it would result in a nonlinear consumption function with a diminishing slope. Further theories on the shape of the consumption function include [[James Duesenberry]]'s (1949) relative consumption expenditure,<ref>{{cite book |last=Duesenberry |first=J. S. |year=1949 |title=Income, Saving and the Theory of Consumer Behavior |url=https://archive.org/details/in.ernet.dli.2015.84155 }}</ref> [[Franco Modigliani]] and Richard Brumberg's (1954) [[life-cycle hypothesis]], and [[Milton Friedman]]'s (1957) [[permanent income hypothesis]].<ref>{{cite book |last=Friedman |first=M. |year=1957 |title=A Theory of the Consumption Function }}</ref>

Some new theoretical works following Duesenberry's and based in behavioral economics suggest that a number of behavioural principles can be taken as microeconomic foundations for a behaviorally-based aggregate consumption function.<ref>{{Cite journal | doi = 10.1016/j.joep.2010.09.004| title = Behavioral foundations for the Keynesian consumption function| journal = Journal of Economic Psychology| volume = 31| issue = 6| pages = 1035| year = 2010| last1 = d’Orlando | first1 = F. | last2 = Sanfilippo | first2 = E. | url = http://dipeg-wpe.unicas.it/dipse/files/wp200805.pdf}}</ref>


==See also==
==See also==
* [[Aggregate demand]]
* [[Aggregate demand]]
*[[Absolute income hypothesis]]
* [[Consumption (economics)]]
* [[Life cycle hypothesis]]
* [[Life cycle hypothesis]]
* [[Measures of national income and output]]
* [[Measures of national income and output]]
Line 23: Line 33:


==Further reading==
==Further reading==
* {{cite book |first=J. Carl |last=Poindexter |chapter=The Consumption Function |title=Macroeconomics |location=Hinsdale |publisher=Dryden Press |year=1976 |isbn=0-03-089419-0 |pages=113–141 |chapterurl=https://books.google.com/books?id=TLS7AAAAIAAJ&pg=PA113 }} ''(Undergraduate level discussion of the subject.)''
* {{cite book |first=J. Carl |last=Poindexter |chapter=The Consumption Function |title=Macroeconomics |location=Hinsdale |publisher=Dryden Press |year=1976 |isbn=0-03-089419-0 |pages=113–141 |chapter-url=https://books.google.com/books?id=TLS7AAAAIAAJ&pg=PA113 }} ''(Undergraduate level discussion of the subject.)''
* {{cite book |first=Thomas J. |last=Sargent |authorlink=Thomas J. Sargent |chapter=The Consumption Function |title=Macroeconomic Theory |location=New York |publisher=Academic Press |year=1979 |isbn=0-12-619750-4 |pages=298–323 |chapterurl=https://books.google.com/books?id=X6u7AAAAIAAJ&pg=PA298 }} ''(Graduate level discussion of the subject.)''
* {{cite book |first=Thomas J. |last=Sargent |author-link=Thomas J. Sargent |chapter=The Consumption Function |title=Macroeconomic Theory |location=New York |publisher=Academic Press |year=1979 |isbn=0-12-619750-4 |pages=298–323 |chapter-url=https://books.google.com/books?id=X6u7AAAAIAAJ&pg=PA298 }} ''(Graduate level discussion of the subject.)''


==External links==
==External links==
Line 31: Line 41:
{{Consumption}}
{{Consumption}}
{{Consumer behaviour}}
{{Consumer behaviour}}
{{Authority control}}


[[Category:Consumption]]
[[Category:Consumption (macroeconomics)]]

Latest revision as of 20:18, 7 December 2023

Graphical representation of the consumption function, where a is autonomous consumption (affected by interest rates, consumer expectations, etc.), b is the marginal propensity to consume and Yd is disposable income

In economics, the consumption function describes a relationship between consumption and disposable income.[1][2] The concept is believed to have been introduced into macroeconomics by John Maynard Keynes in 1936, who used it to develop the notion of a government spending multiplier.[3]

Details

[edit]

Its simplest form is the linear consumption function used frequently in simple Keynesian models:[4]

where is the autonomous consumption that is independent of disposable income; in other words, consumption when disposable income is zero. The term is the induced consumption that is influenced by the economy's income level . The parameter is known as the marginal propensity to consume, i.e. the increase in consumption due to an incremental increase in disposable income, since . Geometrically, is the slope of the consumption function.

Keynes proposed this model to fit three stylized facts:[5]

  • People typically spend a part, but not all of their income on consumption, and they save the rest. They typically do not borrow money to spend, or borrow money to save.[6] This fact is modelled by requiring .
  • People with higher income save a higher proportion of the income. This is modelled by decreasing with .
  • People, when deciding how much to save, are insensitive to the interest rate.[6]

By basing his model in how typical households decide how much to save and spend, Keynes was informally using a microfoundation approach to the macroeconomics of saving.[7]

Keynes also took note of the tendency for the marginal propensity to consume to decrease as income increases, i.e. .[8] If this assumption is to be used, it would result in a nonlinear consumption function with a diminishing slope. Further theories on the shape of the consumption function include James Duesenberry's (1949) relative consumption expenditure,[9] Franco Modigliani and Richard Brumberg's (1954) life-cycle hypothesis, and Milton Friedman's (1957) permanent income hypothesis.[10]

Some new theoretical works following Duesenberry's and based in behavioral economics suggest that a number of behavioural principles can be taken as microeconomic foundations for a behaviorally-based aggregate consumption function.[11]

See also

[edit]

Notes

[edit]
  1. ^ Algebraically, this means where is a function that maps levels of disposable income —income after government intervention, such as taxes or transfer payments—into levels of consumption .
  2. ^ Lindauer, John (1976). Macroeconomics (Third ed.). New York: John Wiley & Sons. pp. 40–43. ISBN 0-471-53572-9.
  3. ^ Hall, Robert E.; Taylor, John B. (1986). "Consumption and Income". Macroeconomics: Theory, Performance, and Policy. New York: W. W. Norton. pp. 63–67. ISBN 0-393-95398-X.
  4. ^ Colander, David (1986). Macroeconomics: Theory and Policy. Glenview: Scott, Foresman and Co. pp. 94–97. ISBN 0-673-16648-1.
  5. ^ Mankiw, N. Gregory (2022). Macroeconomics (11 ed.). New York. 20-1 What Determines Consumer Spending?. ISBN 978-1-319-26390-4. OCLC 1289514240.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link)
  6. ^ a b Keynes, John M. (1936). The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich. Section 3.8.2. There are not many people who will alter their way of living because the rate of interest has fallen from 5 to 4 per cent, if their aggregate income is the same as before... the short-period influence of the rate of interest on individual spending out of a given income is secondary and relatively unimportant, except, perhaps, where unusually large changes are in question.
  7. ^ Solow, Robert M. (2004). "Introduction: The Tobin Approach to Monetary Economics". Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking. 36 (4): 657–663. doi:10.1353/mcb.2004.0067. ISSN 1538-4616. S2CID 154008365. ... recall Keynes's argument that the marginal propensity to consume should be between zero and one, or his discussion about whether the marginal efficiency of investment should be sensitive to current output or should depend primarily on "the state of long-term expectations." Those are microfoundations.
  8. ^ Keynes, John M. (1936). The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich. The marginal propensity to consume is not constant for all levels of employment, and it is probable that there will be, as a rule, a tendency for it to diminish as employment increases; when real income increases, that is to say, the community will wish to consume a gradually diminishing proportion of it.
  9. ^ Duesenberry, J. S. (1949). Income, Saving and the Theory of Consumer Behavior.
  10. ^ Friedman, M. (1957). A Theory of the Consumption Function.
  11. ^ d’Orlando, F.; Sanfilippo, E. (2010). "Behavioral foundations for the Keynesian consumption function" (PDF). Journal of Economic Psychology. 31 (6): 1035. doi:10.1016/j.joep.2010.09.004.

Further reading

[edit]
[edit]