Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                
Skip to main content

The Art and Beauty of Voting Power

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Power and Responsibility

Abstract

We exhibit the hidden beauty of weighted voting and voting power by applying a generalization of the Penrose-Banzhaf index to social choice rules. Three players who have multiple votes in a committee decide between three options by plurality rule, Borda’s rule, and antiplurality rule, or one of the many scoring rules in between. A priori influence on outcomes is quantified in terms of how players’ probabilities are pivotal for the committee decision compared to a dictator. The resulting numbers are represented in triangles that map out structurally equivalent voting weights. Their geometry and color variation reflect fundamental differences between voting rules, such as their inclusiveness and transparency.

We thank an anonymous referee for his or her thoughtful reading and several helpful suggestions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 169.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    We recommend the contributions in Holler and Nurmi (2013) for a good overview of typical applications of power indices. Somewhat atypical applications are discussed by Kovacic and Zoli (2021) and Napel and Welter (2021). Napel (2019) provides a short introduction to power measurement with many further references.

  2. 2.

    See Kurz et al. (2020) for details and related literature: the article defines weighted committee games, characterizes and counts equivalence classes for selected voting rules, and provides lists of structurally distinct committees. Mayer and Napel (2021) does similarly for the special case of scoring rules. Kurz et al. (2021) generalizes the Penrose-Banzhaf and Shapely-Shubik indices to committee games. For a practical application of the framework, see Mayer and Napel (2020).

  3. 3.

    See Fig. 5 in Mayer and Napel (2021). It provides a map of the 51 Borda equivalence classes for \(n=m=3\) and \(w_1\ge w_2\ge w_3\) with a reference distribution of weights for each class. Maps could be constructed for more than three alternatives, too, but the higher number of preference profiles and perturbations has considerable computational costs. Equivalence classes for scores \(0<s<1\) change fast: the number of Borda classes rises from 51 to 505 and \(\ge \! 2251\) for \(m=3\), 4, and 5 (Kurz et al. 2020). Corresponding analogues of Fig. 3 exhibit smoother transitions with even more shades of color.

  4. 4.

    The Shapley-Shubik index (1954) belongs to the same family of indices but supposes a positive correlation of yes-or-no preferences across voters. In technical terms, it assumes an impartial anonymous culture (IAC), while the Penrose-Banzhaf index reflects an impartial culture (IC). The Holler-Packel index (1983) does not consider all coalitions of yes-supporters but only minimal winning coalitions \(S\subseteq N\) in which every yes-vote is pivotal for the outcome.

  5. 5.

    Replacing the IC assumption that underlies Eq. (1) by the IAC assumption (cf. fn. 4) naturally generalizes the Shapley-Shubik index (see Kurz et al. 2021). By contrast, generalization of the Holler-Packel index would first require the definition of a suitable analogue of minimal winning coalitions in weighted committee games. One possibility would be to study each winning alternative \(a\in A\) separately and to consider a-minimal preference profiles \(\textbf{P}\) where \(\rho (\textbf{P})=a\) such that \(\rho (\textbf{P}')\ne a\) for any profile \(\textbf{P}'\) in which a is ranked lower by some voter with constant preferences on subset \(A\smallsetminus a\).

References

  • Banzhaf, J. F. (1965). Weighted voting doesn’t work: A mathematical analysis. Rutgers Law Review, 19(2), 317–343.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holler, M. J., & Nurmi, H. (Eds.). (2013). Power, Voting, and Voting Power: 30 Years After. Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holler, M. J., & Packel, E. W. (1983). Power, luck and the right index. Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie (Journal of Economics), 43(1), 21–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kovacic, M., & Zoli, C. (2021). Ethnic distribution, effective power and conflict. Social Choice and Welfare, 57, 257–299.

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Kurz, S. (2012). On the inverse power index problem. Optimization, 61(8), 989–1011.

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Kurz, S., Mayer, A., & Napel, S. (2020). Weighted committee games. European Journal of Operational Research, 282(3), 972–979.

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Kurz, S., Mayer, A., & Napel, S. (2021). Influence in weighted committees. European Economic Review, 132, 103634.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maskin, E., & Sen, A. (2016). How majority rule might have stopped Donald Trump. New York Times, April 28, 2016.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayer, A., & Napel, S. (2020). Weighted voting on the IMF Managing Director. Economics of Governance, 21(3), 237–244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayer, A., & Napel, S. (2021). Weighted scoring committees. Games, 12(4), 94.

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Napel, S. (2019). Voting power. In R. Congleton, B. Grofman, & S. Voigt (Eds.) Oxford Handbook of Public Choice (Vol. 1, Chap. 6, pp. 103–126). Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Napel, S., & Welter, D. (2021). Simple voting games and cartel damage proportioning. Games, 12(4), 74.

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Peitgen, H.-O., & Richter, P. H. (1986). The Beauty of Fractals. Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Penrose, L. S. (1946). The elementary statistics of majority voting. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 109(1), 53–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapley, L. S., & Shubik, M. (1954). A method for evaluating the distribution of power in a committee system. American Political Science Review, 48(3), 787–792.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, A. D., & Zwicker, W. S. (1999). Simple Games. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Von Neumann, J., & Morgenstern, O. (1953). Theory of Games and Economic Behavior (3rd ed.). Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Stefan Napel .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2023 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Kurz, S., Mayer, A., Napel, S. (2023). The Art and Beauty of Voting Power. In: Leroch, M.A., Rupp, F. (eds) Power and Responsibility. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-23015-8_7

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics