Economics and Research Department
NBH WORKING PAPER
2000/4
Zoltán M. Jakab – Mihály András Kovács – Szabolcs Lorincz1 :
FORECASTING HUNGARIAN EXPORT VOLUME
September, 2000.
1
The views expressed are those of the authors, which do not necessarily reflect the official view of the
National Bank of Hungary. We would like to thank Zsolt Darvas, Barnabás Ferenczi and Judit
Neményi for useful comments. All remaining errors are entirely our own.
Online ISSN: 1585 5600
ISSN 1419 5178
ISBN 963 9057 79 7
Zoltán M. Jakab: Deputy Manager, Economics and Research Department,
E-mail: jakabz@mnb.hu
Mihály András Kovács: Economist, Economics and Research Department
E-mail: kovacsm@mnb.hu
Szabolcs Lorincz: Economist, Economics and Research Department
E-mail: lorinczsz@mnb.hu
The purpose of publishing the Working Paper series is to stimulate comments and
suggestions to the work prepared within the National Bank of Hungary. Citations
should refer to a National Bank of Hungary Working paper.
The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the official
view of the Bank.
National Bank of Hungary
H-1850 Budapest
Szabadság tér 8-9.
http://www.mnb.hu
2
ABSTRACT
The paper summarizes the research on forecasting the Hungarian export
volume. We elaborated a two-step procedure. In the first step we forecasted foreign
demand, then in the second step we forecasted Hungarian export using the best
outcome of the first step together with real exchange rate and import series. We used
several econometric techniques and tested our results statistically by two criteria. We
compared the precision and stability of the different forecasts. The ARIMA forecasts
were employed as a benchmark. We found that in terms of both criteria foreign
demand forecasts were significantly better than those obtained with ARIMA.
However, in the case of the Hungarian export volume our results were only better in
terms of the stability properties. Therefore the choice between the different
forecasting methods was not obvious, so a ’Consensus’ index was also computed as a
weighted average of different forecasts, where the weights were negative functions of
imprecision and instability.
3
4
CONTENTS
I. INTRODUCTION .....................................................................................................6
II. TWO STEPS OF THE FORECASTING PROCEDURE...................................7
II.1. Some Theoretical and Methodological Considerations .......................................................................7
II.2. Forecasting Foreign Demand......................................................................................................................8
II.3. Forecasting Exports ................................................................................................................................... 12
III. COMPARING PREDICTIVE ACCURACY OF THE MODELS................... 15
III.1. Comparing Forecasts of Foreign Demand.......................................................................................... 16
III.2. Comparing Export Forecasts................................................................................................................. 17
IV. SUMMARY.......................................................................................................... 18
REFERENCES ......................................................................................................... 20
APPENDICES .......................................................................................................... 22
Appendix A.: On Detrending Methods .......................................................................................................... 22
A.1. First Order Differencing (FOD) filter.....................................................................................................22
A.2. Hodrick-Prescott (HP) filter.....................................................................................................................22
A.3. Band pass (BP) filter.................................................................................................................................23
A.4. Single Variable Beveridge-Nelson (BN) filter......................................................................................23
A.5. Multivariate Beveridge-Nelson filter......................................................................................................24
Appendix B.: Tests of Forecasts ...................................................................................................................... 25
B.1. S2 and S2b tests ............................................................................................................................................25
B.2 MR-test.........................................................................................................................................................25
Appendix C.: Preliminary Data Analysis, Statistics of the Models and that of their Forecasts .... 27
C.1. Unit root test statistics...............................................................................................................................27
C.2. Model statistics ..........................................................................................................................................28
C.3. Forecast statistics .......................................................................................................................................33
5
I. INTRODUCTION
Export dynamics has a crucial role in determining the short and long run
development of Hungarian economy, which had a 120% openness in 1999 (measured
as the ratio of the sum of exports and imports to GDP). Hence forecasting exports is
crucial to both forecasting growth or underpinning policy decisions. This paper
summarizes the results of our econometric experiments in forecasting the volume of
the Hungarian exports of goods.
The problem was approached in two steps: first, we forecasted foreign
demand using GDP, import, real exchange rate and OECD leading indicator data of
Hungary’s main trading partners. Second, using the results from the first step and
Hungarian import and real exchange rate data we forecasted the export volume.
Methodologically, we used two different approaches depending on how the
long run (trend) and short run (cyclical) information was extracted from the original
series: (i) The first group of methods handle trend and cyclical components together.
The main methods are VAR and VEC models in this group. (ii) Applying the other
approach first the series was detrended to extract the cyclical components. Then
regression was made between these components, supposed to reflect the short run
dynamics of the economy. The extrapolation of long run tendencies is made
separately from forecasting short term movements. These methods can be
distinguished according to the type of the detrending procedure and the estimation
technique used to evaluate the relationship between cyclical components.
Several variants of these methods have been tested in both steps, such as
foreign demand and export forecasts. The predictive accuracy of the different
forecasts has been evaluated by two criteria. The first is precision, which shows the
extent to which a forecast deviates from facts. This deviation can be measured with
root mean squared error. Considering the second criterion, which is stability, we
examined to what extent a forecast of a given time period changes as the information
is extended with a new set of actual observations. For example, one can also forecast
the volume of exports for 2000 Q1 in the third and fourth quarters of 1999. The
smaller the difference between these two predictions (that is the smaller the revision)
the easier it will be to plan and forecast economic policy. However, there can be a
trade-off between the two criteria, in other words, there may not exist an optimal
forecast in both respects. The choice or weighting between them should reflect the
preferences of the user.
Hungarian quarterly export data were available from 1992 Q1 to 1999 Q3,
while foreign demand data from 1980 Q1 to 1999 Q2 (for some countries the data
series were available from earlier). As a final result we calculated a composite
forecast of export which was the weighted average of different forecasts. Weights
were inverse functions of root mean squared and revision errors. The same
importance was attributed to the two criteria, in other words, neither was chosen to be
more important.
6
Part II. offers a brief presentation of the two steps of the forecasting
procedure, Part III. gives an evaluation of the forecasts in respect of their predictive
accuracy, and Part IV. includes our conclusions.
II. TWO S TEPS OF THE F ORECASTING P ROCEDURE
We forecasted the export volume in a two-step procedure. The first step was
the prediction of foreign demand, while the second was forecasting exports using the
results of the first step. The separation of the forecasting process can be mainly
justified by the different size of samples (foreign series are much longer than
Hungarian ones). In addition, predicting the stance of the foreign business cycle has
its own importance as well.
II.1. SOME THEORETICAL AND METHODOLOGICAL CONSIDERATIONS
The majority of structural models on exports are based on export demand
equations. The most important variables in these equations are some measures of
foreign demand and relative prices, the latter often being regarded as the real
exchange rate. This technique of export demand modeling dates back to the MarshallLearner type partial export demand and supply equations. In the 1990’s, these partial
equations were derived in a general equilibrium framework (see Ceglowsky (1991),
Clarida (1994), Senhadji and Montenegro (1998)). These models describe the
behavior of a representative consumer. Two effects work in this set-up: a static and an
intertemporal one. (In a small open economy the second effect is only significant in
respect of imports, since the change in relative prices has only minimal effect on the
real interest rate in export markets, and therefore on the behavior of foreign
consumers and thus foreign demand.) Ceglowsky (1991), Senhadji and Montenegro
(1998), Reinhart (1995), Senhadji (1998), Rose (1991), Hooper, Johnson and
Marquez (1998) estimated these types of structural export demand equations.
However, these models describe a barter (endowment) economy and do not
consider supply effects and the effects of development in production possibilities. The
role of supply or technological shocks cannot be excluded from the analysis. Simon
(1991) emphasizes the weaknesses of demand equations and the importance of supply
conditions in the case of catching up countries. In particular, this is of special
importance for countries like Hungary where technological transfers from abroad and
trade integration into the world economy is an important phenomenon. This process is
modeled by Jakab, Kovács and Oszlay (2000) for three East-Central European
countries: the Czech Republic, Hungary and Poland. Murata, Turner, Rae and Le
Fouler (2000) apply a special non-linear trend fitting technique to these supply effects
. Darvas (2000) estimates the integration factor for Hungary with an unobserved,
latent variable model. Since one of the most important source of international
technological transfer is foreign direct investment, some papers (Pain and Holland
(1998), Murata, Turner, Rae and Le Fouler (2000)) also take into account the effect of
FDI on exports. Hooper, Johnson and Marquez (1998) implicitly quantify the effect of
7
supply shocks by using a Kalman-filter technique of variable parameters (although
this technique also captures the effects of changing export demand elasticity’s).
We treated seasonality as exogenous to forecasting. Therefore we started with
the seasonal adjustment of all the series with SEATS/TRAMO for the full sample
size. This is an accepted method in the empirical literature although some information
may be lost if seasonality is connected to cyclical movements in the variables.
Two main groups of forecasting techniques have been distinguished. In the
first group the trend and cyclical components are not separated explicitly. The vector
auto regression (VAR) and vector error correction (VEC) methods are the main
elements of this group.
Using the methods of the second group, we detrended the data series and then
modeled the relationship between the remaining cyclical components. Thus, in this
case, long run and short run forecasts were modeled separately. As we have
mentioned above, detrending may be justified by the existence of supply side effects.
Forecasts may differ according to the method of detrending or the method of
econometric estimation of cyclical relationships. We applied standard estimation
techniques (OLS, TSLS, 3SLS and SUR), combined with several detrending methods
(first order differencing, Hodrick-Prescott-, band-pass-, single- and multivariate
Beveridge-Nelson filtering2 ). We compared these different combinations of
detrending and estimation from different aspects. Finally, for forecasting, we used
neither the band-pass filter, because of its similarity to the results of the HP filter, nor
the BN filters because of the perfect correlations between the innovations driving the
trend and the cyclical component. Appendix A. contains a brief overview of the
different methods of detrending.
In evaluating the predictive accuracy of the different models we have chosen
the best ARIMA forecast of the time series as a benchmark. In practice, this method
proves to be quite successful in short term predictions. Therefore, a necessary
condition for any economic model based forecast to be acceptable is to be better than
the result of the ARIMA model, which does not explicitly handle the economic
relationship between variables. Part III. gives a more thorough evaluation of
forecasting results.
II.2. FORECASTING FOREIGN DEMAND
Foreign demand defined as the weighted imports of Hungary’s main trading
partners – calculated with weights from the Hungarian export structure – can be
explained by two variables. The first one is an income variable which can be
represented by the given countries’ GDP indices, the second is a relative price
variable which is the country’s real effective exchange rate. Additionally we also used
some OECD leading indicators of our trading partners, which are a valuable source of
2
First order differencing may be categorized in both groups, but we treat it as a detrending method
(second group).
8
additional information about future short term movements in their GDP. The
examined countries were the following: Austria, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, The
Netherlands, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, UK and USA. We did not analyze CEFTA
and former Soviet Union countries because of the lack of sufficiently long and
reliable data. All series were taken in logs and with the exception of real exchange
rates were seasonally adjusted. All of them were found to be integrated of order 1 at a
5% significance level. The results of unit root tests can be found in Appendix C.
A two-equation system was formulated between our variables, where the first
one explained GDP with the leading indicators and lagged GDP, while the second one
explained imports with GDP, real exchange rates and lagged import values. These
equations can be written in aggregated form (with weighted variables) as well as for
the individual countries. We have tested 32 versions of the above mentioned models.
The equations estimated had the following form (all variables were taken into logs
before any transformation).
For detrended variables:
GDPCYC t , j = θ ( L) LICYC t , j + η( L)GDPCYC t , j + ϕ ( L)ξ t1, j
IMPCYC t , j = ϑ ( L) REERCYC t , j + γ ( L )GDPCYC t , j + φ ( L)ξ t2,j ,
where GDPCYC t,j, LICYC t,j, IMPCYC t,j and REERCYC t,j are the cyclical components
of the jth country’s GDP, leading indicator, import and real effective exchange rate in
period t, respectively; ξ tk, j is the independent residual of the jth country’s kth equation
(k=1, 2); while θ ( L), η ( L), ϕ ( L ), ϑ ( L ),γ ( L) and φ ( L) are lag-polinomials.
The VAR model had the following specification:
∆GDPt , j υ
∆GDPt , j υ
∆LI t , j υ
ε t1, j υ
ε ∆IMP = Φ ( L ) ε ∆IMP + Ψ( L) ε∆REER + Ξ ( L ) ε 2 ,
t, j υ
t, j υ
t ,j υ
εε t , j υ
where ∆GDP t,j, ∆LIt,j, ∆IMP t,j és ∆REERt,j are first differences (growth rates) of the jth
country’s GDP, leading indicator, import and real effective exchange rate in period t,
respectively; ε t,k j is the independent residual of the jth country’s kth equation (k=1, 2);
while Φ(L), Ψ(L) and Ξ(L) are lag-polinomials.
The VEC model was the following:
∆GDPt , j υ
GDPt −1, j υ
∆GDPt , j υ
∆LI t , j υ
υ 1t , j υ
ε ∆IMP = Π ε IMP
+ Ω( L ) ε ∆IMP + Θ( L ) ε∆REER + Λ( L) ε 2 ,
t, j υ
t −1, j υ
t, j υ
t,j υ
ευ t , j υ
where Π=αβ, α is the vector of short term adjustment parameters, β is the
cointegrating vector; υt,k j is the independent residual of the jth country’s kth equation
(k=1, 2); while Ω(L), Θ(L) and Λ(L) are lag-polinomials.
9
For instrumental variable estimations we used predetermined variables and
their lags as instruments. Among the exogenous variables we also had to forecast the
path of leading indicators (real exchange rates entered the equations on 5th or bigger
lag, so it was not necessary to forecast them). We forecasted cyclical components of
leading indicators with ARMA equations and their trend by exponential smoothing.
For aggregate equations we created a composite indicator by shifting forward the
country level leading indicators and weighting them together. The size of the shift was
the number of lag on which the leading indicator’s cyclical component had the largest
correlation with that of GDP. Therefore the composite index is simultaneous. Finally,
the (Hodrick-Prescott) trend components of endogenous variables were forecasted
again by exponential smoothing.
As a test of our forecasts we made ex post out of sample forecasts for the
period between1989 Q4 and 1999 Q2. The procedure was the following. First, we
took a subsample – from the beginning of the whole sample to 1989 Q3 – and made
forecasts upon it up to 5 periods ahead. Then we extended the subsample by one
period, that is, the last period became now 1989 Q4 and repeated the 5 period
forecasting. We extended the sample gradually, period by period until 1999 Q1,
giving forecasts from each subsamples. These ex post out of sample forecasts were
supposed to reveal what predictions would have been given by the model at a certain
point in the past, had we made the forecast based on the information set of this period.
As a result of this procedure we obtained five series. The first contains one
period ahead forecasts, that is its first element is a forecast of 1989 Q4, based on the
information available in 1989 Q3, its second element is a forecast of 1990 Q1, based
on the information available in 1989 Q4 and so on. The second series contains the two
period ahead forecasts and so on, till the fifth series with the five horizon forecasts.
We found (see part III.) that the forecast with the smallest mean squared error
was the one using country level systems of equations of HP cyclical components
estimated by 3SLS technique. The statistics of these models can be found in Appendix
C. Figure 1. and 2. compare the five above mentioned forecast series with facts in the
case of this model. Log levels are plotted in Figure 1. while year-on-year indices are
plotted in Figure 2. Not surprisingly, the smaller is the forecast horizon, the greater is
its precision.
Note that forecasts are systematically biased downward. This could be a
consequence of an error in trend extrapolation. The trend of import demand became
steeper in the 1990’s.
10
Figure 1.: Foreign demand and its forecasts on five horizons
(log levels; seasonally adjusted data)
4.944
foreign demand
one period ahead forecasts
two period ahead forecasts
4.844
three period ahead forecasts
four period ahead forecasts
five period ahead forecasts
4.744
4.644
4.544
4.444
89
/III
.n
é.
90
/II.
né
.
90
/IV
.n
é.
91
/II.
né
.
91
/IV
.n
é.
92
/II.
né
.
92
/IV
.n
é.
93
/II.
né
.
93
/IV
.n
é.
94
/II.
né
.
94
/IV
.n
é.
95
/II.
né
.
95
/IV
.n
é.
96
/II.
né
.
96
/IV
.n
é.
97
/II.
né
.
97
/IV
.n
é.
98
/II.
né
.
98
/IV
.n
é.
99
/II.
né
.
99
/IV
.n
é.
00
/II.
né
.
Note: weighted average of main trade partners’ imports calculated from OECD Main Economic
Indicators data.
Figure 2.: Foreign demand and its forecasts on five horizons
(year-on-year indices; seasonally adjusted data)
10
8
6
4
2
0
foreign demand
one period ahead forecasts
-2
two period ahead forecasts
three period ahead forecasts
four period ahead forecasts
-4
five period ahead forecasts
-6
89
/III
.n
é.
90
/II.
né
.
90
/IV
.n
é.
91
/II.
né
.
91
/IV
.n
é.
92
/II.
né
.
92
/IV
.n
é.
93
/II.
né
.
93
/IV
.n
é.
94
/II.
né
.
94
/IV
.n
é.
95
/II.
né
.
95
/IV
.n
é.
96
/II.
né
.
96
/IV
.n
é.
97
/II.
né
.
97
/IV
.n
é.
98
/II.
né
.
98
/IV
.n
é.
99
/II.
né
.
99
/IV
.n
é.
00
/II.
né
.
Note: weighted average of main trade partners’ imports calculated from OECD Main Economic
Indicators data.
11
II.3. FORECASTING EXPORTS
For forecasting the export volume we used variables mentioned in the
theoretical part. In addition to export lags, foreign demand and the real exchange rate
were the explanatory variables, all of them in logs. We considered foreign demand as
exogenous to exports, which assumption makes sense in terms of economic theory
since Hungary’s exports are very small compared to the world market. We used our
best foreign demand forecast from the previous stage. We have chosen the unit labor
cost based-real exchange rate as the relative price variable, because it had the largest
explanatory power with respect to exports. In some regressions we also used the
import volumes as explanatory variables to deal with the integration of the Hungarian
economy and export capacity into the world market, since as mentioned above,
Hungarian exports have been growing at a much faster pace than GDP, which cannot
be purely explained by factors of demand and price- or cost-competitiveness.
We specified six competitive models to forecast exports. Their statistics are
contained in Appendix C.
(1) The ARIMA model’s specification was (1,1,0), which means that
growth of the export volume is explained with its own lag.
the
(2) HP procedure. We regressed the HP detrended cyclical component of
exports on its lags and the cyclical components of foreign demand and real
exchange rate and their lags.
(3) FOD procedure. We regressed export growth rate on its lags and growth
rates of foreign demand and real exchange rate and their lags.
In the case of the procedures (2) and (3), which are the filtering methods,
the following regressions were run:
EXPCYC t = ϑ ( L) REERCYC t + γ ( L) FIMPCYC t + φ ( L)ξ t ,
where EXPCYC t, REERCYC t, and FIMPCYC t are cyclical components of
export, real exchange rate and foreign demand in period t, respectively;
ϑ ( L ),γ ( L) and φ ( L) are lag polinomials; ξ t is a sequence of i.i.d. shocks.
(4) VAR2 model. We estimated the following VAR:
ε 1t υ
∆EXPt υ
∆EXPt υ
ε∆IMP = Φ ( L ) ε∆IMP + Ξ ( L ) ε 2 ,
tυ
t υ
ε t υ
where ∆EXPt, ∆IMP t are log differences of exports and imports in period t,
respectively; Φ(L) and Ξ(L) are lag polinomials; ε tk is the kth equations’
disturbance term (k=1,2).
12
(5) VAR4 model. We extended the list of endogenous variables in the VAR2
model and incorporated exogenous variables estimating the model in the
following form:
∆EXPt υ
∆EXPt υ
1
ε∆IMPt = Φ ( L) ε∆IMP + Ψ ( L)[∆FIMP ] + Ξ ( L ) ε t υ,
t
ε 2
t
ε
ε
ε t υ
ε∆REERt υ
ε ∆REERt υ
where ∆EXPt, ∆IMP t, ∆REERt, ∆FIMP t are log differences of export,
import, real exchange rate and foreign demand in period t, respectively;
Φ(L), Ψ(L) and Ξ(L) are lag polinomials; ε tk is the kth equations’
disturbance term (k=1,2).
(6) VEC2 model. We estimated export and import volumes by an error
correction model taking account of the possible long run relationship
between the two variables. A justification of this specification could be the
fact that due to the integration process of the Hungarian economy the
greatest part of import volume growth appeared in export volume growth.
Formally:
∆EXPt , j υ
EXPt −1 υ
υ t1 υ
∆EXPt υ
ε
= Π εIMP + Ω( L ) ε∆IMP + Λ ( L) ε 2 ,
∆
IMP
t,j υ
t
t −1 υ
υ
υ t υ
where ∆EXPt, ∆IMP t are log differences of exports and imports in period
t, respectively; Π=αβ; α is the vector of short term adjustment parameters,
β is the cointegrating vector; Ω(L) and Λ(L) are lag polinomials; υ tk is the
kth equation’s disturbance term (k=1,2).
As one can see in the tables of Appendix C., the parameters of our export
equations have the right signs and magnitudes. Note that elasticities between cyclical
components do not coincide with that of levels, but they reflect the relationships
between cyclical components. Therefore, if long run elasticity between cyclical
components of export and foreign demand is significantly bigger than one, it does not
implicate that the two original variables do not comove on the long run with elasticity
of one, after controlling for supply side effects. In the equation of first order
differences long run income elasticity of exports is 1.18, which is not significantly
different from one. Price elasticity in this equation is 0.21, while in the case of HP
cyclical components it is 0.11, which are both significantly different from zero 3 .
To evaluate the predictive accuracy of our models, similarly to the method
employed in analyzing the forecasts of foreign demand, we made ex post out of
sample forecasts, this time from 1996 Q1 on five horizons. We could not rank the
different methods unambiguously according to their compliance with the different
criteria. Therefore we created a ’consensus’ forecast which is a weighted average of
3
Note that the real exchange rate is the price of a foreign currency in terms of the home currency. That
is, real exchange rate is depreciating while its value is increasing. Therefore we expected positive
coefficients.
13
the different methods. The weights were based on the precision and stability features
of the methods (see part III.). Figure 3. and 4. plot export series and their consensus
forecasts on five horizons. As one can see the smaller is the forecasting horizon the
greater is its precision. However, we find that our forecasts are systematically biased
downwards. This is a result of the unpredictability (with respect to the methods used)
of extreme growth rates in 1997. This turning point in the trend was due to the activity
of multinational firms, which first moved into the country in 1997. After this shock,
alongside the expansion of the sample, the stability of the series as well as the
precision of our forecasts are also increasing.
Figure 3.: Volume of exports and related forecasts on five horizons
(levels; seasonally adjusted data)
260
240
Original
220
1 period ahead forecasts
2 period ahead forecasts
3 period ahead forecasts
200
4 period ahead forecasts
160
140
14
3q-99
2q-99
1q-99
4q-98
3q-98
2q-98
1q-98
4q-97
3q-97
2q-97
1q-97
4q-96
3q-96
2q-96
1q-96
4q-95
3q-95
100
2q-95
120
1q-95
%
5 period ahead forecasts
180
Figure 4.: Volume of exports and related forecasts on five horizons
(year-on-year indices; seasonally adjusted data)
45
40
35
30
Original
1 period ahead forecasts
25
%
2 period ahead forecasts
3 period ahead forecasts
20
4 period ahead forecasts
5 period ahead forecasts
15
10
99/III.né
99/II.né
99/I.né
98/IV.né
98/III.né
98/II.né
98/I.né
97/IV.né
97/III.né
97/II.né
0
97/I.né
5
III. COMPARING P REDICTIVE ACCURACY OF THE MODELS
As noted in the previous section, we have made ex post out of sample
forecasts with the different methods in an attempt to pick out the best one. One
question naturally arises: by which criteria can one consider a given forecast as being
better than another one. The question is not as easy to answer as one may think at first
glance, since the acceptability of a forecast depends on its intended use. We have
chosen two criteria that could be important. The first one is precision, that is, the
requirement that a forecast should differ from facts to the least possible extent. This
property is measured by the root mean squared error (rmse). The second criterion is
stability, which arises from the requirement that a forecast for a certain time period
should be stable as different sets of information are introduced into forecasting. The
reason for the use of this second criterion is that in many cases substantial variability
of the forecasts of a given period (entailing excessive revision) could be harmful. An
important example is the planning of policy decisions. Therefore holding revisions at
a low level could be a reasonable criterion. We measured revision also in a root mean
squared form.
However, the selection of forecasts by means of these two criteria is not
always obvious, there could be a trade-off: it is not sure that there exists a forecasting
method which is optimal in both respects. As an extreme example, it is trivial that if
our forecast were the same number for all horizons in all periods, then the revision
would be zero, while forecast errors would be certainly much larger than that of a
method which used more information. It is important to note that the existence of
revision error in itself does not reflect the weakness of the method, since even
predicting with a ’good’ model one must revise the forecast of a given period if an
15
unexpected shock arrives. Using stochastic models we assume that our series are
’noisy’, that is, they contain a random-shock component which is not predictable.
Therefore it would be a mistake not to change forecasts as the information set widens.
Thus there is a trade-off between the two criteria, and their weights depend on the
preferences of the forecast-user.
To compare forecasts quantitatively in terms of our criteria we computed three
statistics based on the work of Diebold and Mariano (1995) and Meese and Rogoff
(1988). The precision criterion was tested by two different statistics, S2 and MR,
while the stability (revision) criterion was tested by the S2b statistics. Appendix B.
describes the computation of these tests. All of them is based on a loss-differential
series, which is the difference of two models’ forecasting error series. These lossdifferential series cannot be autocorrelated by the assumption of S2 and S2b tests.
However, Diebold and Mariano’s (1995) simulations show that empirically they
perform quite well in the case of autocorrelation, too. This assumption is not
necessary for the MR test, yet this procedure is asymptotic and normality is
recommended. Therefore in small samples and with non-normal errors its power is
very low and the S2 test is superior even if the loss differential is autocorrelated
(again, by the simulations of Diebold and Mariano (1995)).
Computing these test statistics we always compared forecasts of a given
method to that of the ARIMA model, which often has better predicting ability than
models building more heavily on economic theory. Appendix C. contains test results.
III.1. COMPARING F ORECASTS OF FOREIGN DEMAND
We compared predictive accuracy of 32 foreign demand forecasting modelversions. The method mentioned in part II. (which used an HP filter, country level
equation system estimated by 3SLS) had smaller (by, on average, 30%) forecasting
(mean squared) error on all horizons than the ARIMA model, and this difference was
statistically significant by the S2 test. Concerning stability, this method had a
significantly lower (by 50%) revision error compared to the ARIMA model. From this
one can conclude, that the method can obviously beat the ARIMA, but comparing it to
the other models, the difference is not so obvious. The above mentioned trade-off
between precision and stability clearly exists in our case. If we use differentiating
(FOD filtering) instead of HP filtering, leaving other technical details unchanged, the
resulting forecasts have significantly the lowest revision error among all methods.
However its precision is even worse than that of the ARIMA model. Thus, there is no
obvious choice. At last we used the forecasts of the HP-method for predictions on
exports. This method has the best performance in terms of precision and the second
best in terms of stability.
Figure 5. illustrates the trade-off between precision and stability. On the
vertical axis we have the precision measure, while the two horizontal axes show
horizon and stability. We have plotted the data of the three previously mentioned
methods, namely the ARIMA; the one with the highest precision (HP); and the one
with best stability features (FOD). We can see that the larger the horizon, the larger
the forecasting errors. The points of the HP method are always on a lower level then
16
the other two points of the appropriate horizon, that is, this method has the lowest
forecasting error, and as we have already mentioned, this difference is statistically
significant. Concerning revisions, the FOD method has the lowest errors and this is
also a statistically significant result. However, the forecasting error of this method is
worse compared to ARIMA’s.
Figure 5.: Forecasting and revision errors of foreign demand forecasts on five
horizons
FOD
HP
ARIMA
Note: ARIMA – the simplest statistical model; HP – the model using Hodrick-Prescott filter, 3SLS
estimation on a country level system of equations; FOD – the same model as the previous one, using
differentiating instead of HP filtering.
III.2. COMPARING EXPORT FORECASTS
We had also ambiguous results in the case of export forecasts. We did not find
any methods with higher precision than the ARIMA model neither in the case of the
S2 test nor in the case of the MR test. However, HP and FOD methods showed
significantly better stability features. Figure 6. plots these informations in a similar
way to Figure 5. One can conclude that models treating trend and cycle together have
higher precision, while models using detrending methods have better stability
properties. We constructed a ’Consensus’ index which is a weighted average of
different forecast series. The weights depend negatively on forecasting and revision
errors, 4 and we attributed the same importance to the two types of errors that is, we
did not decide on the user’s preferences.
4
Forecasts of the VEC2 model did not take part in the ’consesus’ index since it had worse results than
the others in all dimensions and the cointegrating relationship was not stable over time.
17
Figure 6.: Forecasting and revision errors of export forecasts on five horizons
Note: ARIMA – model (1); HP – model (2); FOD – model (3); VAR2 – model (4); VAR4 – model (5);
VEC2 – model (6). The parameters of ARIMA and VAR2 models are so close to each other that plots
are virtually the same.
To sum it up, we have not been able to find a superior method for forecasting
the Hungarian export volume, that is why we computed a ’consensus’ index based on
the weighted average of the different forecasts.
IV. SUMMARY
This paper summarizes the results of our research in the field of forecasting
Hungarian export volume. We followed a two-step procedure. In the first step we
forecasted foreign demand using Hungary’s main trading partners’ GDP, import, real
exchange rate and OECD leading indicator series. In the second step we forecasted
the Hungarian export volume using the outcome of the first step and Hungarian real
exchange rate and import series.
We used several econometric techniques to map and extrapolate the dynamics
of the series (i) by treating trend and cycle together and (ii) by using different
methods of detrending.
The different methods were tested statistically by two criteria. The first
criterion shows how precise a forecast is, measured in terms of its root mean squared
error. The second criterion is stability, which measures how volatile a forecast is over
a given period of time. The benchmark forecast was based on the ARIMA, the
simplest statistical model. In respect of foreign demand the method using the HP filter
and country level system of equations estimated by 3SLS proved to be the best.
18
However, choosing between different forecasts of export was not obvious, and we
could not find an optimal method in both respects.
Therefore we computed a ’Consensus’ index for exports, which is a weighted
average of the different forecasts. Weights are negative functions of the forecasting
and revision errors, that is, the greater is the precision and/or stability of a given
method the greater is its weight.
19
R EFERENCES
Baxter, M - King, R. G. (1995), „Measuring Business Cycles: Approximate BandPass Filters for Economic Time Series” NBER Working Paper N. 5022, February
Beveridge, S. – Nelson, C. (1981), „A New Approach to the Decomposition of
Economic Time Series into Permanent and Transitory Component with Particular
Attention to the Measurement of the Business Cycle, Journal of Monetary Economics,
7.
Canova, F. (1998), „Detrending and Business Cycle Facts” Journal of Monetary
Economics, 41.
Ceglowsky, J. (1991), „Intertemporal Substitution in Import Demand” Journal of
International Money and Finance, 10.
Clarida, R. (1994), „Cointegration, Aggregate Consumption, and the Demand for
Imports: A Structural econometric Investigation” The American economic Review,
vol. 84, March.
Cagily, T – Nosan, J. M. (1995), „Effects of the Hodrick-Prescott Filter on Trend
and Difference Stationary Time Series: Implications for Business Cycle Research”
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 19.
Darvas, Zs. (2000), „Potential Output Estimates for Hungary” Mimeo, January.
Diebold , F. X. – Mariano, R. S: (1995), „Comparing Predictive Accuracy” Journal
of Business and Economic Statistics, Vol. 13., No. 3., July.
Evans, G. – Reichlin, L. (1994), „ Information, Forecasts, and Measurement of the
Business Cycle” Journal of Monetary Economics, 33.
Harvey, A. C. – Jaeger, A. (1993), „Detrending, Stylized Facts and the Business
Cycle” Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol. 8.
Harvey, A. C. (1985), „ Trends and Cycles in Macroeconomic Time Series” Journal
of Business and Economic Statistics, Vol. 3. No.3,July
Hodrick, R - Prescott, E. C. (1980), „Post-war US Business Cycles: An empirical
Investigation” Journal of Money Credit and Banking, Vol. 29.
Hooper, P. - Johnson, K.- Marquez, J. (1998), „Trade Elasticities for G-7
Countries” International Finance Discussion Papers n. 609, April.
Jakab, M. Z. – Kovács, M.A. – Oszlay, A. (2000), „How Far Has Trade Integration
Advanced? An Analysis of Potential Trade of Three Central and Eastern European
Countries” National Bank of Hungary, Working Papers 2000/1
King, R. G. – Rebelo S. T. (1993), „Low Frequency Filtering and Real Business
Cycles” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 17.
Montenegro, C. - Senhadji, A. (1998), „ Time Series Analysis of Export Demand
Equations: A Cross Country Analysis” IMF Working Paper/98/149, October
Murata, K. - Turner, D. – Rae, D. – Le Fouler, L. (2000), „ Modeling
Manufacturing Export Volumes Equations. A System Estimation Approach” OECD
Economics Department Working Papers no. 235.
Nelson, C. R. – Plosser C. I. (1982), „Trends and Random Walks in Macroeconomic
Time Series: Some Evidence and Implications” Journal of Monetary Economics, 10.
Pain, N. – Holland, D. (1998), „International trade in Services: Putting UK Export
Performance in Perspective” NIESR mimeo.
Prescott, E. (1986), „Theory Ahead of Business Cycle Measurement” CarniegeRochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 25.
Reinhart, C. (1995), „Devaluation, Relative Prices, and International Trade.
Evidence from Developing Countries” IMF Staff Papers, vol. 42, June.
20
Rose, A. (1989), „The Role of Exchange Rates in a Popular Model of International
Trade. Does the ‘Marshall-Lernel Condition Hold?’” Journal of International
Economics, 30.
Senhadji, A. (1998), „Time Series Estimation of Structural Import Demand
Equations: A Cross-Country Analysis” IMF Staff Papers, vol. 45, June.
Simon, A . (1991), „A Model of East-Asian Trade: Supply as a Driving Force”
Working Paper, ICSEAD, Kitakyushu, Japan
Stock, J. H. - Watson, W, M. (1998), „Business Cycle Fluctuations in U.S.
Macroeconomic Time Series” NBER Working Paper 6528, April.
21
APPENDICES
APPENDIX A.: ON DETRENDING METHODS
In this Appendix we briefly overview the main detrending methods. Beside the
literature quoted we relied heavily on the work of Canova (1998).
A.1. First Order Differencing (FOD) filter
We can consider first order differencing as cyclical filtering too (Nelson and
Plosser (1982)). The filter is optimal if original series can be written in the following
form:
y t = yt −1 + φ (l )ε t ,
where ε t is white noise and φ (l )ε t is the (stationary) business cycle phenomenon.
The weakness of the method from the point of view of business cycle research
compared to other filters is that it gives higher weights for waves with frequencies
higher than that of business cycles. However, the FOD filtering has the advantage that
one does not make additional errors with extrapolating trend when making forecasts.
A.2. Hodrick-Prescott (HP) filter
The trend suggested by Hodrick and Prescott (1980) is a solution of an optimization
exercise. The trend of a series yt is a series st, which minimizes the following
expression:
T
λ ( yt
t= 0
T
− st ) + λ λ
2
t= 0
((s t+1 − st ) − (s t − st −1 ))2
where λ is a parameter which penalizes changes in the slope of the trend; as it
becomes larger, the trend will be smoother. In the extreme case (λ=Α, and λ=0) the
trend is a linear trend or the original series, respectively. The ‘optimal’ value of the
parameter is the ratio of the standard deviations of the trend and cycle innovations. In
practice, however, researchers most often use the value 1600 (for quarterly data). In
this case one can show that the resulting filter is equivalent to a band-pass filter,
which ‘defines’ business cycle as frequencies with wavelength shorter than 8 years
(Prescott (1986)). A further result is that an HP filter makes all processes stationary
with up to integration of 4 (King és Rebelo (1993)).
The method has considerable disadvantages. (i) Beyond the business cycles
frequencies (from two periods to eight years) higher frequencies remain in the cyclical
components. While this is a problem in studying business cycles, in case of
forecasting it could be an advantage (see the next part dealing with the band-pass
filter). (ii) Cogley and Nason (1995) showed that the HP filter works as a high-pass
filter when it is applied for trend stationary processes. In this case HP filtering is
22
equivalent to a two step procedure: in the first step it filters out a linear trend then
filters the residuals by HP filter. However, the application of the filter for difference
stationary series is not equivalent to high-pass filtering. Difference stationarity can be
a quite frequent phenomenon among economic time series. The HP filter now can be
represented as a two step procedure, that first differentiate the series then smooth it by
an asymmetric moving average. This smoothing amplifies business cycles frequencies
and dampens the others. Thus the filter can generate spurious business cycle-like
movements which was not present in the original series (Harvey and Jager (1993)).
(iii) The HP trend is sensitive at the ends of the sample thus there is a considerable
uncertainty in the forecasts.
A.3. Band pass (BP) filter
Band-pass filters separate trend and cyclical components on a spectral base
(see for example Baxter and King (1994), Stock and Watson (1998), Canova (1998)).
That is, they produce cyclical component series which contain only the required
frequencies (or they approximate them). Therefore, if we define business cycle as a
certain frequency band, this filter is per definition the best. The solution, however, can
be spurious since – similarly to an HP-filter – the method generates business cyclelike movements even from a random walk. This is a consequence of the finiteness of
samples. From a forecasting point of view the picture is even more complicated. The
BP-filter – as most detrending methods – is sensitive at the end of the data. In
practice, trend components in these intervals are computed as an ARIMA
extrapolation of the ‘real’, mid-sample BP-trend. Therefore decomposition is unstable
at the ends.
One can construct different types of BP-filters according to the properties of
the required frequency band. A certain one-sided filter which filters frequencies with
wavelength less than or equal to 8 years is equivalent to the standard (λ = 1600) HPfilter for quarterly data (Prescott (1986)). Therefore, the same problems arise as in the
HP case. If we use two-side BP methods we can filter out very high frequency
movements, which can be helpful for studying business cycles, but it could be a
problem when we want to run regressions on cyclical components. This is because
variables in such regressions (that is, cyclical components) do not contain very high
frequencies. Consequently, residuals cannot be white noise; we have not been able to
give any stable or meaningful specification.
A.4. Single Variable Beveridge-Nelson (BN) filter
The method suggested by Beveridge and Nelson (1981) is a so-called forecast
based technique which decomposes a difference-stationary series to stationary
(cyclical) and non-stationary (trend) components. The trend component in period t is a
long run forecast based on the information set of this period. The foundation of this
forecast is an ARIMA representation selected by the researcher. The decomposition of
a series to trend and cyclical components is the following:
yt = st + CT,
where st and CT are trend and cyclical components, respectively. Their form described
in Beveridge and Nelson (1981) and Canova (1998) is the following:
23
st σ y t + wˆ t (1) + ... + wˆ t (k ) − kµ , and from this
c t = −(wˆ t (1) + ... + wˆ t (k ) − kµ ) = χ (L )ε t ,
where wt = (1 − L) y t is a stationary ARMA process which has the following moving
average
representation:
wt = µ + γ (L )ε t
and
its
forecast
is:
(
)
(λ
+ µ + (λ
wˆ t (i ) = E t wt +i ε?yt , y t−1 ,... = λ
equation becomes: st = s t−1
k −1
j+ k
j =0
i = j +1
Α
i =1
)
γ i ε t − j . If k → Α , then the first (trend)
)
γ i ε t . It is easy to see that the two components
are moved by the same innovation (ε t ) , therefore – in contrast with other methods of
detrending – they are perfectly correlated. A possible critique of this method can be
the fact that since two ARIMA models which have similar short run forecasting
properties can differ substantially in long run forecasting. This makes decomposition
unstable. Furthermore, BN trend is often more variable then the cyclical component.
A.5. Multivariate Beveridge-Nelson filter
A natural extension of BN-filtering is the case when instead of an ARIMA
representation we apply a broader model to compute long run forecasts. Evans and
Reichlin (1994) show that the wider is the information set used to calculate forecasts,
the bigger is the ratio of the cyclical component’s variance to that of the trend. This
justifies the multivariate method, although from the point of view of business cycle
research it is not of first priority to find a filter which leaves the biggest variance in
the cyclical components (for example, the cyclical component computed by a linear
trend filter contains the greatest part of the frequencies). However, the authors argue
that their method yields a cyclical component of US GDP which is broadly consistent
with NBER business cycle chronology.
The method of unobserved components based on Kalman-filter techniques can
be a further way of detrending series (see, for example, Harvey (1985)). The use of
this methodology for detrending could be a further research project. We did not use
BN-filters either because of the perfect correlation of the trend and cycle innovations.
In the paper we did not mention the results obtained by the BP-filters because they
were so close to those obtained by the HP-filter. 5
5
The results are available from the authors upon request.
24
APPENDIX B.: TESTS OF FORECASTS
Three tests have been used to evaluate the predictive accuracy of our methods.
The brief principles of these tests, which can be found in Diebold and Mariano
(1995), are as follows.
B.1. S2 and S2b tests
S2 and S2b tests are based on the binomial test for independence. The Th
model’s loss from departure from facts is formally signed as:
eti = g ( y t , yˆ ti ) ,
where
- eti is the Th model’s loss in period t,
- y t , yˆ ti are original (fact) and forecasted values of the Th model in period t,
-g(.) is a transformation measuring loss. Most often – as in the case of rmse – it is
quadratic: g ( yti , yˆ it ) = ( y ti − yˆ ti ) 2 .
The difference of the two models’ loss series is the loss differential series:
d ti, j = (e it − e tj )
The S2 test analyses the independence of the loss differential with the binomial
test. That is, positive values are coded as 1 and negative ones as 0. This series has
χT
binomial distribution: 0.5 k 0.5 T − k if the loss differential is not autocorrelated (T is
χk ρ
the number of observations, k is the number of 1’s).
Diebold and Mariano (1995) note that this test can be applied independently of
the definition of loss, g(.).
Our S2b test has the same principles and it has been developed for testing the
difference in variability (revision) between two forecasting methods. Now, the loss of
the Th method becomes:
eti = λ k = 2 ( yˆ ti,t − (k −1) − yˆ it, t− k ) 2
5
where yˆ ti, t− k is a forecast value based on the information set available in period t.
B.2 MR-test
-
The MR-test is based on Meese and Rogoff (1988). Its assumptions are:
quadratic loss function,
forecasting errors have zero mean and normal distribution.
25
The statistics is the following:
T γˆ xz → N ( 0, λ ) ,
where
- γˆ xz = cov( x, z )
[λ
Α
-
λ =
-
γˆ xz (τ ) = cov( xt , z t −τ )
γˆ zx (τ ) = cov( z t , x t−τ )
γˆ xx (τ ) = cov( x t , xt −τ )
γˆ xx (τ ) = cov( x t , xt −τ )
-
x t = eti + etj
-
z t = e it − e tj
τ = −Α
γ xx (τ ) ∗ γ zz (τ ) +γ xz (τ ) ∗ γ zx (τ )
]
This is an asymptotic test and it is quite sensible for non-normality.
26
APPENDIX C.: PRELIMINARY D ATA ANALYSIS, STATISTICS OF THE MODELS
AND THAT OF THEIR FORECASTS
C.1. Unit root test statistics
Unit root tests of foreign demand’s variables
AUS
FRA
GER
ITA
JAP
GDP
ADF
PP
-2.834*
-2.743*
-0.011
-0.298
-2.383
-3.481
-2.254
-2.077
-3.619*
-7.624*
ADF
PP
-8.265*** -4.434***
-13.282*** -7.036***
-5.16***
-5.450***
-11.398*** -6.225***
ADF
PP
-1.431
-1.372
-0.213
0.165
-0.309
-0.586
-10.101*** -4.189***
-15.672*** -4.716***
-5.097***
-8.203***
-6.586*** -5.820***
-11.619*** -9.171***
-2.267
-2.040
-1.904
-1.766
-2.386
-2.001
-6.640*** -7.662***
-10.027*** -8.686***
-4.808***
-8.599***
-5.304***
-7.895***
-4.682***
-8.440***
-1.179
-1.455
-1.826
-2.367
-1.249
-1.764
-1.976
-1.315
-2.897*
-5.852*
-6.110***
-5.090***
-5.783***
-6.032***
-5.252***
-5.754***
-7.288***
-5.929***
-3.749***
-3.917***
-3.107**
-7.961***
Import
ADF
PP
Real ex. rates
ADF
PP
ADF
PP
Leading Indicators
ADF
PP
ADF
PP
0.068
0.130
-7.662*
-8.686*
-2.076
-2.607
-1.854
-1.627
NL
levels
1.410
1.410
difference
-10.498***
-10.498***
levels
1.277
1.277
difference
-9.562***
-9.562***
levels
-1.542
-1.542
difference
-8.895***
-8.895***
levels
-3.142*
-3.142*
difference
-5.664***
-5.664***
SPA
-1.306
-1.657
-2.829**
-2.976**
-0.262
1.217
-5.350***
-4.159***
-2.628*
-2.350*
-6.569***
-8.828***
-2.615*
-4.357*
-4.977***
-4.868***
SWE
0.689
0.689
SWI
-0.554
-0.666
-10.920*** -3.134**
-10.920*** -2.821**
1.209
1.209
-8.223***
-8.223***
-1.017
-1.017
-9.161***
-9.161***
-1.901
-1.901
-5.187***
-5.187***
UK
-0.637
-0.637
USA
-2.667
-2.112
-12.703*** -6.465***
-12.703*** -9.124***
-0.905
0.411
0.491
0.491
-1.706
-1.718
-2.890*
-3.305**
-13.272*** -8.790***
-13.272*** -12.521***
-2.876*
-2.611*
-1.719
-1.719
-1.894
-1.630
-4.334***
-7.845***
-8.630***
-8.630***
-7.494***
-8.452***
-1.279
-1.619
-0.684
-0.684
-3.250*
-2.525*
-4.514***
-4.661***
-7.660***
-7.660***
-7.231***
-7.691***
Source: OECD Main Economic Indicators. AUS – Austria, FRA – France, GER – Germany, ITA –
Italy, JAP – Japan, NL – The Netherlands, SPA – Spain, SWE – Sweden, SWI – Switzerland, UK –
United Kingdom, USA – United States of America. Quarterly data: GPS and imports:1960 Q1 1999
Q2; real exchange rates and leading indicators: 1960 Q1 1999 Q4 (dates of first periods are different,
the shortest series – that of France – begin in 1980 Q1). Seasonally adjusted series (except real
exchange rates) in logs. ADF: Augmented Dickey-Fuller-, PP: Phillips-Perron- tests.
*significant at 10%
** significant at 5%
*** significant at 1%If the unit root statistics are significant, then the test rejects the null of unit root
(against stationarity) at the given level of significance.
Unit root tests of export equation variables
Sample
1992:1 1999:3
Level
ADF
PP
First difference
ADF
PP
Unit Root Test of the Variables of the Export Equations
Variable
Export
Foreign demand
Import
Unit root
Trend
Unit root
Trend
Unit root
Trend
-0.175*
-0.175*
-0.477**
-0.477**
0.008***
0.008***
-
-0.170
-0.170
0.003**
0.003**
-0.781***
-0.781***
-
Real exchange rate
Unit root
Trend
0.020
0.002
-
-0.036
-0.036
-
-1.472***
-1.472***
-
-0.762***
-0.762***
-
*significant at 10%
** significant at 5%
*** significant at 1%
If the unit root statistics are significant then the test rejects the null of unit root (against stationarity) at
the given level of significance.
27
C.2. Model statistics
C.2.1. Foreign demand
GDP-import systems of equations of foreign countries
AUS
FRA
GER
ITA
JAP
NL
SPA
SWE
SWI
UK
USA
Constant
GDP(-1)
LI
AR1
AR2
AR3
AR4
AR5
AR6
AR8
AR9
0.000
0.683***
0.098***
0.000
0.953***
0.068***
0.00
0.780***
0.129***
-0.340***
0.000
0.860***
0.146***
0.185**
0.000
0.878***
-0.131*
0.000
0.724***
0.210***
0.000
0.845***
0.079***
0.512***
0.000
0.584***
0.168***
0.000
0.874***
0.103***
1.128***
-0.616***
0.000
0.872***
0.130***
-0.310***
-0.246***
0.000
0.614***
0.206***
R squar.
Adj. R squar.
St. Error
DW
0.516
0.506
0.008
2.345
0.818
0.808
0.004
1.865
0.818
0.815
0.006
2.036
0.865
0.858
0.005
2.009
0.742
0.735
0.008
2.254
0.689
0.677
0.006
2.087
0.958
0.957
0.002
1.891
0.636
0.625
0.011
1.903
0.969
0.968
0.002
1.636
0.738
0.731
0.008
2.022
0.870
0.867
0.006
1.991
AUSIMP
FRAIMP
GERIMP
ITAIMP
JAPIMP
NLIMP
SPAIMP
SWEIMP
SWIIMP
UKIMP
USAIMP
0.000
1.958***
0.337***
0.626***
0.001
1.745***
0.240**
0.242***
0.000
0.335
0.729***
0.316**
0.000
1.428***
0.443***
-0.147*
0.000
1.107***
0.481***
0.149**
0.000
-0.099
1.081***
0.018
-0.195***
0.476***
0.000
1.467***
0.371***
0.120**
0.000
1.619***
0.419***
0.201***
0.380***
0.000
0.117
1.604***
0.001
-0.753***
0.201*
-0.002
2.042***
0.118*
0.073
1.045***
-0.313***
0.000
0.264**
1.606***
0.042**
-0.783***
-0.720***
0.223***
-0.414***
-0.243**
Constant
GDP
IMP(-1)
REER
GDP(-1)
AR1
AR3
AR4
AR7
AR8
-0.268***
-0.182**
-0.273***
-0.229**
-0.213***
-0.233**
0.069**
-0.243*
0.726***
0.183**
-0.174*
-0.286***
lag of
real ex. rate
5
8
7
9
6
6
8
6
5
5
5
R squar
Adj. R squar.
St. Error
DW
0.678
0.666
0.023
1.968
0.909
0.903
0.008
1.963
0.812
0.805
0.023
1.993
0.634
0.624
0.028
2.075
0.866
0.859
0.023
1.994
0.656
0.643
0.016
1.705
0.937
0.933
0.011
1.820
0.882
0.875
0.015
1.871
0.959
0.955
0.006
1.994
0.647
0.632
0.024
1.754
0.799
0.792
0.025
1.761
Obs.
138
80
154
113
147
81
114
74
74
151
153
Note: Base Source: OECD Main Economic Indicators. AUS – Austria, FRA – France, GER –
Germany, ITA – Italy, JAP – Japan, NL – The Netherlands, SPA – Spain, SWE – Sweden, SWI –
Switzerland, UK – United Kingdom, USA – United States of America. HP cyclical components of
seasonally adjusted logarithmized GDP series. –IMP, -LI, -REER variables are similarly defined
cyclical components of import volume, leading indicators, real exchange rate series, respectively.
The sample’s last observation is in every case 1999 Q2. We estimated equations in pairs (a country’s
GDP and import equation) with the 3SLS technique. The instruments were the lags of predetermined
variables.
(*), (**), (***) show the variable’s deviation from zero at 10, 5, 1% significance levels, respectively.
28
C.2.2. Exports
Sample: 1992 Q1 - 1999 Q2
Statistics of ARIMA model (1)
Equation:
DLOG(EXPORT)=C(1)+C(2)*DLOG(EXPORT(-1))
C(1)
C(2)
R^2
Adj. R^2
F-stat.
DW-stat.
*significant at 10%
** significant at 5%
*** significant at 1%
Coefficient
St. error
T-stat.
p-value
0.014
0.523
0.008
0.159
1.792
3.299
0.0844
0.0027
0.287
0.261
10.881***
2.012
LM autocor. test
White-heterosc. test
ARCH-test (LM)
Ramsey-Reset test
3.851
5.764
1.628
0.068
Statistics of HP model (2)
Equation:
LOGCYCHP(EXPORT)=C(1)+C(2)*LOGCYCHP(EXPORT(-1))
+C(3)*LOGCYCHP(FOR DEM)+C(4)*LOGCYCHP(REAL EX. R.(-5))
C(1)
C(2)
C(3)
C(4)
R^2
Adj. R^2
F-stat.
DW-stat.
*significant at 10%
** significant at 5%
*** significant at 1%
Coefficient
St. error
T-stat.
p-value
-0.003
0.627
0.713
0.108
0.005
0.081
0.286
0.065
-0.488
7.780
2.496
1.671
0.629
0.000
0.019
0.107
0.822
0.801
39.929***
1.764
LM Autocorr. test
White-heterosc. test
ARCH-test (LM)
Ramsey-Reset test
29
3.271
5.471
0.000
1.081
Statistics of FOD model (3)
Equation:
DLOG(EXPORT)=C(1)+C(2)*DLOG(FOR. DEM.)
+C(3)*DLOG(REAL EX. R.(-6))
C(1)
C(2)
C(3)
R^2
Adj. R^2
F-stat.
DW-stat.
*significant at 10%
** significant at5%
*** significant at 1%
Coefficient
St. error
T-stat.
p-value
0.008
1.184
0.214
0.009
0.483
0.114
0.927
2.453
1.868
0.362
0.021
0.073
0.319
0.268
6.310***
1.605
LM autocorr. test
White-heterosc.. test
ARCH-test (LM)
Ramsey-Reset test
2.096
15.676
0.171
0.054
Statistics of VAR2 model (4)
DLOG(EXPORT)
DLOG(IMPORT)
DLOG(EXPORT(-1))
St. error
DLOG(IMPORT(-1))
St. error
constant
St. error
0.560
-0.153
-0.289
-0.262
0.024
-0.012
0.118
-0.055
0.760
-0.093
0.004
-0.004
R^2
Adj. R^2
F-stat.
Log likelihood
Akaike AIC
Schwarz SC
0.348
0.299
7.198
58.551
-3.703
-3.563
0.728
0.708
36.120
89.519
-5.768
-5.628
Log Likelihood
Akaike Information Criterion
Schwarz Criterion
150.636
-9.642
-9.362
30
Statistics of VAR4 model (5)
DLOG(EXPORT)
DLOG(IMPORT)
DLOG(REAL EX. R.)
DLOG(EXPORT(-1))
St. error
DLOG(IMPORT(-1))
St. error
DLOG(REAL EX. R.(-1))
St. error
constant
St. error
DLOG(FOREIGN DEM.)
St. error
0.531
-0.187
-0.589
-0.294
-0.551
-0.265
0.045
-0.017
0.107
-0.570
0.122
-0.070
0.680
-0.110
-0.141
-0.099
0.010
-0.006
-0.028
-0.213
-0.116
-0.147
-0.196
-0.231
0.344
-0.208
0.020
-0.013
0.178
-0.448
R^2
Adj.R^2
F-stat.
Log likelihood
Akaike AIC
Schwarz SC
0.453
0.365
5.176
61.190
-3.746
-3.512
0.749
0.709
18.627
90.714
-5.714
-5.481
0.230
0.106
1.863
68.420
-4.228
-3.994
Log Likelihood
Akaike Information Criteria
Schwarz Criteria
227.314
-14.154
-13.454
31
Statistics of VEC2 model (6)
Cointegrating vector
1
-1.154
-0.063
1.047
LR
5% significance level
LOG(EXPSA(-1))
LOG(IMPSA(-1))
St. error
Constant
Eigenvalue
0.526
0.039
Error correction
22.029
15.410
1.126
3.760
D(LOG(EXPORT))
D(LOG(IMPORT))
Coint. equation
St. error
D(LOG(EXPORT(-1)))
St. error
D(LOG(EXPORT(-2)))
St. error
D(LOG(IMPORT(-1)))
St. error
D(LOG(IMPORT(-2)))
St. error
Constant
St. error
-0.223
-0.098
0.439
-0.210
0.045
-0.186
0.231
-0.607
-0.373
-0.544
0.022
-0.013
0.062
-0.035
0.113
-0.074
-0.060
-0.066
0.885
-0.214
-0.129
-0.192
0.006
-0.004
R^2
Adj. R^2
F-stat.
Log likelihood
Akaike AIC
Schwarz SC
0.439
0.311
3.440
57.034
-3.645
-3.360
0.778
0.727
15.382
86.163
-5.726
-5.440
Log Likelihood
Akaike Information Criterion
Schwarz Criterion
151.136
-9.795
-9.129
32
C.3. Forecast statistics
C.3.1 Foreign demand
The following tables show the p-values of a test aimed at determining whether
the mean squared and revision error of a given forecast differs significantly from that
of the bench-mark model (which is the ARIMA or HP-3SLS). The null is the equality
of the two errors, that is, a low p value shows significant difference. We indicated
with italics the cases when the error of the given forecast is lower then that of the
bench-mark.
ls, tsls, sur, 3sls denote the estimation techniques; in the tables showing the
mean squared errors, the numbers of the rows indicate the horizons of the forecasts.
Comparing forecast error of HP-filter models with that of ARIMA (S2 test)
gdp
ls
imp
tsls
1
2
3
4
5
0.500
0.209
0.094
0.066
0.003
sur
0.168
0.209
0.049
0.014
0.003
3sls
0.500
0.209
0.094
0.066
0.003
ls
0.168
0.128
0.024
0.014
0.008
tsls
1
2
3
4
5
0.054
0.128
0.162
0.121
0.045
sur
0.054
0.128
0.094
0.121
0.020
3sls
0.054
0.128
0.162
0.121
0.088
0.027
0.209
0.162
0.066
0.020
Comparing forecast error of HP-filter models with that of HP-3SLS (S2 test)
ls
1
2
3
4
5
tsls
0.375
0.314
0.162
0.121
0.750
gdp
sur
0.054
0.007
0.371
0.934
0.912
3sls
0.100
0.314
0.162
0.121
0.632
ls
1.000
1.000
1.000
1.000
1.000
tsls
0.100
0.128
0.162
0.566
0.155
imp
sur
0.261
0.209
0.256
0.566
0.250
3sls
0.100
0.072
0.906
0.121
0.155
1.000
1.000
1.000
1.000
1.000
Comparing revision error of FOD-filter models with that of ARIMA (S2b test)
ls
gdp
imp
tsls
sur
0
0
0
0
3sls
0
0
0
0
Comparing revision error of HP-filter models with that of HP-3SLS (S2b test)
ls
hp
fod
tsls
0.000
0.000
gdp
sur
3sls
ls
0.155
0.000
1.000
0.000
0.000
0.000
33
tsls
0.155
0.003
imp
sur
3sls
0.155
0.368
1.000
0.250
0.003
0.008
C.3.2 Exports
2
Does the given method have smaller rmse than ARIMA (significance levels)?
est. from 1995:1
Method
HP
FOD
VAR2
VAR4
Period
MR teszt
S2 teszt MR teszt S2 teszt MR teszt S2 teszt MR teszt
S teszt
C
1
0.3238
0.4653
0.3238
0.3970
0.0384
0.1896
0.5000
0.1703
2
0.1189'
0.0492
0.1189
0.4161
0.1189
0.2761
0.2403'
0.1227
3
0.0245
0.0394
0.0717'
0.2397
0.0064
0.2379
0.1662'
0.1914
4
0.0021
0.0466
0.1051'
0.0959
0.9616
0.3189
0.4018'
0.2282
5
0.0005
0.0410
0.3036'
0.0004
0.0037
0.4983
0.3036'
0.1838
Est. from 1996:1
1
0.3036
0.0830
0.3036
0.4192
0.1938
0.0669
0.3036
0.2989
2
0.2120'
0.0945
0.0898
0.4853
0.2120
0.1895
0.2120'
0.3875
3
0.0461
0.0979
0.1334
0.3550
0.0461'
0.0906
0.2905'
0.3840
4
0.0193
0.0589
0.1939'
0.0001
0.8062'
0.1180
0.1938'
0.3726
5
0.0059
0.0622
0.2744'
0.0010
0.0327'
0.2836
0.2744
0.2999
' Significant autocorrelation in the loss-differential at 5%
VEC
S2 teszt MR teszt
na
na
na
na
na
na
na
na
na
na
0.3036
0.6964
0.2905'
0.1938'
0.1133'
0.0642
0.1096
0.1354
0.1298
0.1006
Revisions compared to those of ARIMA (test S2b, significance levels)
HP
FOD
Estimation from 1995 Q1
Probability
0.0154'
0.0007
Estimation from 1996 Q1
Probability
0.0899'
0.0065
' Significant autocorrelation in the loss differential at 5% level
*Italic: ARIMA is worse, Normal: ARIMA is better.
34
VAR2
VAR4
VEC
0.2403'
0.0038
na
0.3953'
0.0287
0.0898'
MNB Füzetek / NBH Working Papers:
1995/1
(november)
Simon
András:
Aggregált
kereslet
és
kínálat,
külkereskedelem a magyar gazdaságban 1990-1994
termelés
és
1995/2
(november)
Neményi Judit: A Magyar Nemzeti Bank devizaadósságán felhalmozódó árfolyamveszteség kérdései
1995/3
(február)
Dr. Kun János: Seignorage és az államadóság terhei
1996/1
(március)
Simon András: Az infláció tényezõi 1990-1995-ben
1996/2
(június)
Neményi Judit: A tõkebeáramlás, a makrogazdasági egyensúly és az
eladósodási folyamat összefüggései a Magyar Nemzeti Bank eredményének
alakulásával.
1996/3
(június)
Simon András: Sterilizáció,
fizetési mérleg
kamatpolitika
az
államháztartás
és
a
1996/4
(július)
Darvas Zsolt: Kamatkülönbség és árfolyam-várakozások
1996/5
(augusztus)
Vincze János - Zsoldos István: A fogyasztói árak struktúrája, szintje
és alakulása Magyarországon 1991-1996-ban
Ökonometriai vizsgálat a részletes fogyasztói árindex alapján
1996/6
(augusztus)
Csermely Ágnes: A vállalkozások banki finanszírozása Magyarországon
1991-1994
1996/7
(szeptember)
Dr. Balassa Ákos: A vállalkozói szektor hosszú távú finanszírozásának
helyzete és fejlõdési irányai
1997/1
(január)
Csermely Ágnes: Az inflációs célkitûzés rendszere
1997/2
(március)
Vincze János: A stabilizáció hatása az árakra,
termelés (értékesítés) közötti összefüggésekre
1997/3
(április)
Barabás Gyula - Hamecz
pénzmennyiség
István:
1997/4
(május)
Zsoldos István: A lakosság
Magyarországon 1980-1996.
és
Tõkebeáramlás,
megtakarítási
és
az
árak
és
sterilizáció
portfolió
a
és
döntései
1997/5
(június)
Árvai Zsófia: A sterilizáció és tõkebeáramlás ökonometriai elemzése
1997/6
(augusztus)
Zsoldos
István:
A
Magyarországon
lakosság
Divisia-pénz
35
tartási
viselkedése
1998/1
(január)
Árvai Zsófia - Vincze János: Valuták sebezhetõsége: Pénzügyi válságok
a ‘90-es években
1998/2
(március)
Csajbók Attila: Zéró-kupon hozamgörbe becslés jegybanki szemszögbõl
ZERO -COUPON YIELD CURVE ESTIMATION FROM A CENTRAL BANK PERSPECTIVE
1998/ 3
(március)
Kovács Mihály András - Simon András: A reálárfolyam összetevõi
THE COMPONENTS OF THE REAL EXCHAGE RATE IN HUNGARY
1998/4
(március)
P.Kiss Gábor: Az államháztartás szerepe Magyarországon
THE ROLE OF GENERAL GOVERNMENT IN HUNGARY
1998/5
(április)
Barabás Gyula - Hamecz István - Neményi Judit: A költségvetés finanszírozási rendszerének
átalakítása és az eladósodás megfékezése
Magyarország tapasztalatai a piacgazdaság átmeneti idõszakában
FISCAL CONSOLIDATION , PUBLIC DEBT CONTAINMENT AND DISINFLATION
Hungary’s Experience in Transition
1998/6
(augusztus)
Jakab M. Zoltán-Szapáry György: A csúszó leértékelés tapasztalatai
Magyarországon
1998/7
(október)
Tóth István János
gyakorlata
-
Vincze
János:
Magyar
vállalatok
árképzési
1998/8
(október)
Kovács Mihály András: Mit mutatnak?
Különféle reálárfolyam-mutatók áttekintése és a magyar gazdaság árés költség-versenyképességének értékelése
1998/9
(október)
Darvas Zsolt: Moderált inflációk csökkentése
Összehasonlító vizsgálat a nyolcvanas-kilencvenes évek dezinflációit
kísérõ folyamatokról
1998/10
(november)
Árvai Zsófia: A piaci és kereskedelmi banki kamatok közötti
transzmisszió 1992 és 1998 között
THE INTEREST RATE TRANSMISSION MECHANISM BETWEEN MARKET AND COMMERCIAL BANK RATES
1998/11
(november)
P. Kiss Gábor: A költségvetés tervezése és a fiskális átláthatóság
aktuális problémái
1998/12
(november)
Jakab
M.
Zoltán:
Magyarországon
A
valutakosár
megválasztásának
1999/1
(January)
ÁGNES CSERMELY-JÁNOS VINCZE : LEVERAGE AND FOREIGN OWNERSHIP IN HUNGARY
1999/2
(március)
36
szempontjai
Tóth Áron: Kísérlet
bankrendszerben
a
hatékonyság
empírikus
elemzésére
a
magyar
1999/3
(március)
Darvas Zsolt-Simon András: A növekedés makrogazdasági feltételei
Gazdaságpolitikai alternatívák
CAPITAL STOCK AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT IN HUNGARY (May 1999)
1999/4
(április)
Lieli Róbert: Idõsormodelleken alapuló inflációs elõrejelzések
Egyváltozós módszerek
1999/5 (április)
Ferenczi Barnabás: A hazai munkaerõpiaci folyamatok Jegybanki
szemszögbõl
Stilizált tények
LABOUR MARKET DEVELOPMENTS IN HUNGARY FROM A CENTRAL BANK PERSPECTIVE –
Stylized Facts
1999/6
(május)
Jakab M. Zoltán – Kovács Mihály András: A reálárfolyam-ingadozások
fõbb meghatározói Magyarországon
DETERMINANTS OF REAL-EXCHANGE RATE FLUCTUATIONS IN HUNGARY
1999/7 (July)
ATTILA CSAJBÓK: INFORMATION IN T-BILL AUCTION BID DISTRIBUTIONS
1999/8 (július)
Benczúr
Péter:
A
magyar
nyugdíjrendszerben
rejlõ
implicit
államadósság-állomány változásának becslése
CHANGES IN THE IMPLICIT DEBT BURDEN OF THE HUNGARIAN SOCIAL SECURITY SYSTEM
1999/9 (augusztus)
Vígh-Mikle
Szabolcs–Zsámboki
Balázs:
A
denominációs összetétele 1991-1998 között
bankrendszer
1999/10 (szeptember)
Darvas Zsolt–Szapáry György: A nemzetközi pénzügyi
terjedése különbözõ árfolyamrendszerekben
FINANCIAL CONTAGION UNDER DIFFERENT EXCHANGE RATE REGIMES
1999/11 (szeptember)
Oszlay
András:
Elméletek
befektetésekrõl
és
tények
a
külföldi
mérlegének
válságok
tova
mûködõtõke-
2000/1 (január)
Jakab M. Zoltán – Kovács Mihály András – Oszlay András: Hová tart a
külkereskedelmi integráció?
Becslések
három
kelet.közép-európai
ország
egyensúlyi
külkereskedelmére
2000/2 (February)
SÁNDOR VALKOVSZKY – JÁNOS VINCZE: ESTIMATES OF AND PROBLEMS WITH CORE INFLATION IN
HUNGARY
2000/3 (március)
Valkovszky Sándor: A magyar lakáspiac helyzete
2000/4 (május)
Jakab M. Zoltán – Kovács Mihály András – Lorincz Szabolcs: Az export elorejelzése ökonometriai
módszerekkel
37
FORECASTING HUNGARIAN EXPORT VOLUME
2000/5 (augusztus)
Ferenczi Barnabás – Valkovszky Sándor – Vincze János: Mire jó a fogyasztói-ár statisztika?
2000/6 (August)
ZSÓFIA ÁRVAI – JÁNOS VINCZE: FINANCIAL CRIESES IN TRANSITION COUNTRIES : MODELS AND
FACTS
38