International Conference On Emerging Economic Issues In A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in a
Globalizing World
INTERNATIONAL CONFERENCE ON
EMERGING ECONOMIC ISSUES IN A
GLOBALIZING WORLD
IZMIR UNIVERSITY OF ECONOMICS AND SUNY CORTLAND
PROCEEDINGS
Đzmir, 2008
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Scientific Committee
Mark J. Prus (SUNY Cortland)
Oğuz Esen (Đzmir University of Economics)
Timothy P. Phillips (SUNY Cortland)
Lisi Krall (SUNY Cortland)
German Zarete-Hoyos (SUNY Cortland)
Ayla Oğu (Đzmir University of Economics)
Đ. Hakan Yetkiner (Đzmir University of Economics)
M. Efe Postalcı (Đzmir University of Economics)
Alper Duman (Đzmir University of Economics)
Gül Ertan (Đzmir University of Economics)
Organizing Committee
Mark J. Prus (SUNY Cortland)
Oğuz Esen (Đzmir University of Economics)
Özgül Bilici (Đzmir University of Economics)
Emre Can (Đzmir University of Economics)
Burcu Türkcan (Đzmir University of Economics)
Hakan Güngör (Đzmir University of Economics)
Đstemi Berk (Đzmir University of Economics)
Đsmail Doğa Karatepe (Đzmir University of Economics)
Izmir University of Economics
Publishing Date: August 2008
ISBN:
2
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
CONTENT
Tools of Financial Analysis ...................................................................................................... 5
Achim Monica, Babe -Bolyai University Cluj-Napoca & Achim Sorin, Babe -Bolyai
University Cluj-Napoca & Borlea Sorin, Babe -Bolyai University Cluj-Napoca
Regional Development in anlı Urfa Province, The Center of South Eastern
Anatolian Project (GAP): Key Sector Analyis..................................................................... 41
Menevi Uzbay Pirili, Ege University, Turkey & R.Funda Barbaros, Ege University,
Turkey
The Importance of ICT For The Knowledge Economy: A Total Factor Productivity
Analysis For Selected OECD Countries ............................................................................... 72
Đsmail SEKĐ, Ege University, Turkey
The Comparison of Technical Efficiency And Productivity Growth in Transition
Countries and The Soviet Union Countries ......................................................................... 92
Ertuğrul Delikta , Ege University, Turkey
Capital Flows and The Non-Tradables in The Turkish Economy after Capital
Account Liberalization......................................................................................................... 109
F. Kemal Kızılca, Ankara University, Turkey
The Analysis of The Romanian Business Environment in The Context of The
Adherence to The European Union .................................................................................... 120
Pop Fanuta, Babes-Bolyai University Cluj-Napoca, Romania &Achim Monica, BabesBolyai University Cluj-Napoca, Romania
Inflows and Outflows of Services in The EU and Turkey ................................................ 144
Beyza Sümer, Dokuz Eylül University, Turkey
Short Term Overreaction Effect: Evidence on The Turkish Stock Market ................... 156
Gülin Vardar, Izmir University of Economics, Turkey & Berna Okan, Izmir University of
Economics, Turkey
Statistic Study of Banking Efficiency Ratios...................................................................... 167
Ioan Batrancea, Babes-Bolyai University, Romania & Larissa Batrancea, Babes-Bolyai
University, Romania & Sorin Borlea, Babes-Bolyai University, Romania & Grigore Bace,
Romanian National Bank, Romania
The Determinants of Exchange Rate Regimes in Emerging Market Economies ........... 179
Mehmet Güçlü, Ege University, Turkey
3
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Relative Price Variability and the Philips Curve: Evidence from Turkey ..................... 194
A Nazif Çatik, Ege University, Turkey-Brunel University, UK & Christopher Martin, Brunel
University, UK & A. Özlem Önder, Ege University, Turkey
Competitive Industrial Performance Index and It’s Drivers: Case of Turkey and
Selected Countries ................................................................................................................ 210
Ne e Kumral, Ege University, Turkey & Çağaçan Değer, Ege University, Turkey & Burcu
Türkcan, Izmir University of Economics
Use of e-commerce in Small and Medium Size Enterprises: An Application in Ankara232
A. Ramazan Altınok, Prime Ministry, Turkey & Fuat Erdal, Adnan Menderes University,
Turkey
Similarities and Differences of The 1994 and 2001 Turkish Currency Crises: A Signal
Approach ............................................................................................................................... 248
akir Görmü , Adnan Menderes University, Turkey & Recep Tekeli, Adnan Menderes
University, Turkey & Osman Peker, Adnan Menderes University, Turkey
Economic Development and Religiosity: An Investigation of Turkish Cities................. 263
Sacit Hadi Akdede, Adnan Menderes University, Turkey & Hakan Hotunluoğlu, Adnan
Menderes University, Turkey
Multilateralism or Bilateralism: Trade Policy of the EU in the Age of Free Trade
Agreements............................................................................................................................ 274
Sevil Acar, Istanbul Technical University, Turkey & Mahmut Tekçe, Marmara University,
Turkey
The Relationship Between FDI And Growth Under Economic Integration: Is There
One? ....................................................................................................................................... 287
Antonio Marasco, Lahore University, Pakistan
4
International Conference On Emerging Economic Issues In A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Tools of Financial Analysis
Achim Monica
Babe -Bolyai University Cluj-Napoca
Achim Sorin
Babe -Bolyai University Cluj-Napoca
Borlea Sorin
Babe -Bolyai University Cluj-Napoca
Abstract
To evaluate the financial condition and performance of a company the financial analyst
needs certain yardsticks. The yardstick frequently used is a ratio, or index relating two
pieces of financial data to each other.
When comparing changes in the business's ratios from period to period, you can pinpoint
improvements in performance or developing problem areas. By comparing the ratios to
those in other businesses, you can see possibilities for improvement in key areas.
This paper focus on the main financial ratio calculated for the activity’s entities referring to
average levels registered for Romanian’ entities in comparison with average level
registered in Europe and generally, in the world.
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Introduction
The primary goal of financial management is to maximize the stock price’s entities but
accounting data do influences stock prices and to understand why a company is
performing, first of all is necessary to evaluate the information reported by financial
statements.
In order to assess how business is doing, one needs more than single numbers extracted
from the financial statements. Each number has to be viewed in the context of the whole
picture. For example, the income statement may show a net profit of 10,000 Euros. But is
this good? If this profit is earned on sales of 50,000 Euros, it may be very good; but if sales
of 200,000 Euros are required to produce the net profit of 10,000 Euros, things don’t look
so great anymore. A 200,000 Euros sales figure may seem impressive, but not if it takes
$2,000,000 in assets to produce those sales.
The true meaning of figures from the financial statements emerges only when they are
compared to other figures. Such comparisons are the essence of why business and
financial ratios have been developed.
The analysis of financial ratios involves two types of comparison.
First, the analyst can compare a present ratio with past and expected future ratios for
the same company. The current ratio for the present year-end could be compared with the
current ratio for the preceding year-end. When financial ratios are arrayed on a spreadsheet
over a period of years, the analyst can study the composition of change and determine
whether there has been an improvement or deterioration in the financial condition and
performance over time. Financial ratios also can be computed for projected, or pro forma
statements and compared with present and past ratios. In the comparisons over time, it is
best to compare not only financial ratios, but also the raw figures.
The second method of comparison involves comparing the ratios of one firm with those
of similar or with industry averages at the same point in time. Such comparison gives
insight into the relative financial condition and performance of the firm. Sometimes a
company will not fit neatly into an industry category. In such situations, one should try to
develop a set, albeit usually small, of peer firms for comparison purposes.
A number of sources, including many trade or business associations and organizations,
provide data for comparison purposes. Industry average is published by many companies,
trade associations, and governmental agencies. For example, a variety of ratios can be
found in the publications of Dun & Bradstreet’s, Moody’s Manual of Investments and
Standard & Poor’s Corporation Record.
The analysis must be in relation to the type of business in which the firm is engaged and to
the firm itself.
For our purposes, financial ratios can be grouped into five types: liquidity, debt,
profitability, coverage and market value ratios. No one ratio gives us sufficient
information by which to judge the financial condition and performance of the firm. Only
when we analyze a group of ratios are we able to make reasonable judgments. We must be
sure to take into account any seasonal character of a business.
6
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Liquidity Ratios
Liquidity ratios are used to judge a firm’s ability to meet short-term obligations.
From them, much insight can be obtained into the present cash solvency of a company and
its ability to remain solvent in the event of adversities. Essentially, we wish to compare
short-term obligations with the short-term resources available to meet these obligations.
Current ratio
The ratio most commonly used to appraise the debt exposure represented on the balance
sheet is the current ratio. This relationship of current assets to current liabilities is an
attempt to show the safety of current debt holders’ claims in case of default.
Current ratio = Current assets /Current liabilities
Presumably, the larger this ratio, the better the position of the debt holders. From the
lenders’ point of view, a higher ratio would certainly appear to provide a cushion against
drastic losses of value in case of business failure. A large excess of current assets over
current liabilities seems to help protect claims, should inventories have to be liquidated at a
forced sale and should accounts receivable involve sizable collection problems.
Seen from another angle, however, an excessively high current ratio might signal slack
management practices. It could indicate idle cash balances, inventory levels that have
become excessive when compared to current needs and poor credit management that
results in overextended accounts receivable. At the same time, the business might not be
making full use of its current borrowing power.
The Rumanians current accounting rules recommends an acceptable level, around 2 (The
Romanian accounting rules harmonization at EU norms, 2008).
The possible causes of a low current ratio are:
•
•
Current liabilities too high
Using short-term funds to fund long-term assets
If the firm feel it business's current ratio is too low, it may be able to raise it by:
• Paying some debts.
• Increasing your current assets from loans or other borrowings with a maturity of
more than one year.
• Converting non-current assets into current assets.
• Increasing your current assets from new equity contributions.
• Putting profits back into the business
Quick ratio (acid test ratio)
This ratio is an indicator of a company's short-term liquidity. The quick ratio measures a
company's ability to meet its short-term obligations with its most liquid assets, calculated
as follow:
7
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
The quick ratio = Current assets- Inventories /Current liabilities
The higher the quick ratio, the better the position of the company. Also known as the
"acid-test ratio".
This ratio is the same as the current ratio, except that it excludes inventories- presumably
the least liquid portion of current assets – from the numerator. The ratio concentrates on
cash, marketable securities and receivables in relation to current obligations and thus
provide a more penetrating measure of liquidity than does the current ratio. The key
concept here is to test collectibles of current liabilities in the case of a real crisis, on the
assumption that inventories would have no value at all.
Companies with ratios less than 1 cannot pay their current liabilities and should be looked
at with extreme caution. Furthermore, if the acid-test ratio is much lower than the working
capital ratio, it means current assets are highly dependent on inventory.
Retail stores are examples of this type of business.
The possible causes of a low quick ratio are:
•
•
•
Current liabilities too high
Using short-term funds to fund long-term assets
Stock too high
Solutions could be:
•
•
•
Move some short-term liabilities to long-term
Sale’ leaseback of some fixed assets
Reduce stock
Liquidity of receivables
When there are suspected imbalances or problems in various components of the current
assets, the financial analyst will want to examine these components separately in assessing
liquidity. Receivables, for example, may be far from current. To regard all receivables as
liquid when in fact a sizable portion may be past due, overstates the liquidity of the firm
being analyzed. Receivables are liquid assets only insofar as they can be collected in a
reasonable amount of time. For our analysis receivables, we have two basic ratios:
The first of which is the average collection period:
The average collection period = (Receivables/Annual credit sales)* Days in year(365)
The second ratio is the receivable turnover ratio:
The receivable turnover ratio = Annual credit sales/ Receivables
These two ratios are reciprocals of each other. The number of days in the year, 365,
divided by the average collection period, 62 days, gives the receivable turnover ratio, 5.89.
8
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
The number of days in the year divided by the turnover ratio gives the average collection
period. Thus, either of these two ratios can be employed.
Liquidity of Inventories
We may compute the inventory turnover ratio as an indicator of the liquidity of inventory
as follow:
The liquidity of inventory = Cost of goods sold/Average inventory
The average inventory figure used in the denominator typically is an average of beginning
and ending inventories for the period.
Generally, the higher the inventory turnover, the more efficient the inventory management
of the firm. Sometimes a relatively high inventory turnover ratio may be the result of a too
low a level of inventory and frequent stock outs. It might also be the result of too many
small orders for inventory replacement. Either of these situations may be more costly to the
firm than caring a larger investment in inventory and having a lower turnover ratio. When
the inventory turnover ratio is relatively low, it indicates slow-moving inventory or
obsolescence of some of the stock.
Debt Ratios
Most companies finance a portion of their assets with liabilities and the remaining portion
with equity. A company that finances a relatively large portion of its assets with liabilities
is at a greater risk. This is because the liabilities must be repaid and often require regular
interest payments. The risk is that a company may not be able to meet required payments.
One way to assess the risk associated with a company’s use of liabilities is to compute and
analyze debt ratio.
Debt proportion analysis is in essence static, and does not take into account the operating
dynamics and economic values of the business. The analysis is totally derived from the
balance sheet, which in itself is a static snapshot of the financial condition of the business
at a single point in time.
Nonetheless, the relative ease with which these ratios are calculated probably accounts for
their popularity. Such ratios are useful as indicators of trends, when they are applied over a
series of time periods. However, they still don’t get at the heart of an analysis of
creditworthiness, which involves a company’s ability to pay both interest and principal on
schedule as contractually agreed upon, what is, to service its debt over time.
In this category, we have three ratios as follows:
Debt-to-equity ratio
The debt-to-equity ratio which is computed by simply dividing the total debt of the firm
(including current liabilities) by its shareholders’ equity as follow:
Debt-to-equity ratio = Total debt/ Shareholder’s equity
9
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
When intangible assets are significant, they frequently are deducted from shareholders’
equity.
•
A ratio greater than one means assets are mainly financed with debt, less than one
means equity provides a majority of the financing.
•
If the ratio is high (financed more with debt) then the company is in a risky position
- especially if interest rates are on the rise.
The ratio of debt to equity varies according to the nature of the business and the volatility
of cash flow. An electric utility, with very stable cash flows, usually will have a higher
debt ratio than will a machine tool company, whose cash flows are far less stable.
A comparison of the debt ratio for a given company with those of similar firms gives us a
general indication of the creditworthiness and financial risk of the firm.
Long-term capitalization ratio
In addition to the ratio of total debt to equity, we may want to compute the following ratio,
which deals with only the long-term capitalization of the firm:
The
long-term
capitalization
=
Long-term
debt/Total
capitalization
where,
•
Total capitalization represents all long-term debt, preferred stock, and
shareholders’ equity.
This measure tells us the relative importance of long-term debt in capital structure.
The debt- to- total assets ratio
This ratio expresses what proportion of total farm assets is owed to creditors and it is
obtained by compares total farm liabilities to the value of total farm assets, after formula
below:
The Debt/Asset Ratio = The debt/Total assets
The ratio is one measure of the risk exposure of the farm business; thus, is important in
evaluating the financial trend of the business.
The goal of many farm business operators is to approach a debt free operation. A continual
lowering of this ratio is a trend in that direction. The higher the ratio, the greater the risk
exposure of the farm business.
So, it is favorably appreciated a descendent evolution of this indicator and the interval of
the financial safety is [0%, 30 % ] .
In USA, the industry average of this ratio is 40 % (Brigham E. F, 1999).
10
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
High Debt to total assets ratio:
High debt to total assets ratio means more of the firm's assets are financed by debt
relative to owners' funds.
A high ratio requires the commitment of more funds to pay interest and repay
principal amount. The failure to meet these requirements may force a company to
bankruptcy.
A company with a very high debt ratio may also find it difficult to attract additional
financing.
Positive aspects of high debt ratio are that existing shareholders can maintain
control because using debt avoids the sale of new shares.
Low Debt to assets ratio:
Generally, lower is better
Low debt ratio means that the firm is using more of owner’s capital and retained
earnings to finance its assets.
It means less risk to creditors.
Company can borrow additional funds with relative ease.
Coverage Ratios
Borrowing money is one of the most effective things a company can do to build its
business. But, of course, borrowing comes with a cost: the interest that is payable month
after month, year after year. These interest payments directly affect the company’s
profitability. For this reason, a company’s ability to meet its interest obligations, an aspect
of its solvency, is arguably one of the most important factors in the return to shareholders.
There are two types of coverage ratio:
•
•
Time Interests Earned (TIE) ratio
The Fixed Charge Coverage ratio
Time interests earned (TIE) ratio
Interest coverage is a financial ratio that provides a quick picture of a company’s ability to
pay the interest charges on its debt. The 'coverage' aspect of the ratio indicates how many
times the interest could be paid from available earnings, thereby providing a sense of the
safety margin a company has for paying its interest for any period. A company that
sustains earnings well above its interest requirements is in an excellent position to weather
possible financial storms. By contrast, a company that barely manages to cover its interest
costs may easily fall into bankruptcy if its earnings suffer for even a single month.
The Time Interests Earned (TIE) ratio = EBIT/ Interest charges
Because interest coverage is a highly variable measure, not only between companies within
an industry but between different industries, it is worthwhile to establish some guidelines
for setting acceptable levels of interest coverage in particular industries. Obviously, an
interest-coverage ratio below 1 is an immediate indication that the company, regardless of
its industry, is not generating sufficient cash to cover its interest payments. That said, an
11
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
interest-coverage ratio of 1.5 is generally considered the bare minimum level of comfort
for any company in any industry.
Beyond these absolute minimums, determining acceptable interest coverage for an industry
depends on its nature - or more specifically, the stability or consistency of its earnings.
The Fixed Charge Coverage ratio
This ratio is similar to the times-interest-earned-ratio but it’s more inclusive because it’s
recognizes that many firms lease assets and also must make sinking fund payment.
Leasing is widespread in certain industries, making this ratio preferable to the timeinterests-earned-ratio for many purposes.
Fixed charge include interest, annual long-term lease obligations and sinking fund
payments, and the fixed charge coverage ratio is defined as follow:
The Fixed Charge Coverage ratio = (EBIT + Lease payments)/(Interest
charges+Lease payment+Sinking fund payment (1-Tax rate))
Profitability Ratios
We turn now at the viewpoint of the owners of a business. These are the investors to whom
management is responsible and accountable. So far, we have not mentioned owners
directly, even though it should be quite clear that the management of a business must be
fully cognizant of, and responsive to, the owners’ viewpoint and expectations in the timing,
execution, and appraisal of the results of operations. This is the basis for shareholder value
creation, as we’ve said before. Similarly, management must be alert to the lenders’
viewpoint and criteria.
The key interest of the owners of a business, the shareholders in the case of a corporation,
is profitability. In this context, profitability means the returns achieved, through the efforts
of management, on the funds invested by the owners. The owners are also interested in the
disposition of earnings which belong to them, that is, how much is reinvested in the
business versus how much is paid out to them as dividends, or, in some cases, through
repurchase of outstanding shares. Finally, they are concerned about the effect of business
results achieved-and future expectations about results-and the market value of their
investment, especially in the case of publicly traded stocks.
Profitability ratios are of two types:
those showing profitability in relation to sales
those showing profitability in relation to investment.
Together these ratios indicate the firm’s efficiency of operation.
12
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Profitability in Relation to Sales
There are three key profit-margin ratios: gross profit margins, operating profit margins and
net profit margins.
Gross profit margin
This ratio tells us the profit of the firm relative to sales after we deduct the cost of
producing the goods sold. Your gross profit ratio tells you how much of each sales dollar
you can expect to use to cover your operating expenses and profit. In other words, it
measures the difference between what it costs to produce a product and what you're selling
it for.
The formula for this ratio is:
Gross profit margin = Sales less cost of goods sold/ Sales
There are two key ways to improve your gross profit margin:
First, it will be increase the prices.
Second, it will be decrease the costs to produce your goods.
Of course, both are easier said than done. An increase in prices can cause sales to drop. If
sales drop too far, you may not generate enough gross profit dollars to cover operating
expenses. Price increases require a careful reading of inflation rates, competitive factors
and basic supply and demand for the product you are producing.
The second method of increasing gross profit margin is to lower the variable costs to
produce your product. This can be accomplished by decreasing material costs or making
the product more efficiently. Volume discounts are a good way to reduce material costs.
The more material you buy from a supplier, the more likely they are to offer you discounts.
Another way to reduce material costs is to find a less costly supplier. However, you might
sacrifice quality if the goods purchased are not made as well.
Whether you are starting a manufacturing, wholesaling, retailing or service business, you
should always be on the lookout for ways to deliver your product or service more
efficiently. However, you also must balance efficiency and quality issues to ensure that
they do not get out of balance.
Companies with high gross margins will have a lot of money left over to spend on other
business operations, such as research and development or marketing. So be on the lookout
for downward trends in the gross margin rate over time. This is a telltale sign of future
problems facing the bottom line. When labor and material costs increase rapidly, they are
likely to lower gross profit margins - unless, of course, the company can pass these costs
onto customers in the form of higher prices.
It's important to remember that gross profit margins can vary drastically from business to
business and from industry to industry. For instance, the airline industry has a gross margin
of about 5%, while the software industry has a gross margin of about 90%
13
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Operating Profit Margin
By comparing earnings before interest and taxes (EBIT) to sales, operating profit margins
show how successful a company's management has been in generating income from the
operation of the business:
Operating Profit Margin = EBIT/Sales
This ratio is a rough measure of the operating leverage a company can achieve in the
conduct of the operational part of its business. It indicates how much EBIT is generated per
dollar of sales. High operating profits can mean the company has effective control of costs,
or that sales are increasing faster than operating costs.
Operating profit also gives investors an opportunity to do profit-margin comparisons
between companies that do not issue a separate disclosure of their cost of goods sold
figures (which are needed to do gross margin analysis). Operating profit measures how
much cash the business throws off, and some consider it a more reliable measure of
profitability since it is harder to manipulate with accounting tricks than net earnings.
Naturally, because the operating profit-margin accounts for not only costs of materials and
labor, but also administration and selling costs, it should be a much smaller figure than the
gross margin.
Net profit margin
The net profit margin tells us the relative efficiency of the firm after taking into account all
expenses and income taxes, but not extraordinary charges.
The formula for this ratio is:
Net profit margin= Net profit after taxes/ Sales
Margin analysis is a great way to understand the profitability of companies. It tells us how
effectively management can wring profits from sales, and how much room a company has
to withstand a downturn, fend off competition and make mistakes. But, like all ratios,
margin ratios never offer perfect information. They are only as good as the timeliness and
accuracy of the financial data that gets fed into them, and analyzing them also depends on
a consideration of the company's industry and its position in the business cycle.
Margin ratios highlight companies that are worth further examination. Knowing that a
company has a gross margin of 25% or a net profit margin of 5% tells us very little without
further information. As with any ratio used on its own, margins tell us a lot, but not the
whole story, about a company's prospects.
Profitability in Relation to Investment
With all the ratios that investors toss around, it's easy to get confused. Consider return on
equity (ROE) and return on assets (ROA). Because they both measure a kind of return, at
first glance, these two metrics seem pretty similar. Both gauge a company's ability to
generate earnings from its investments. But they don't exactly represent the same thing. A
closer look at these two ratios reveals some key differences. Together, however,
14
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
they provide a clearer representation of a company's performance. Here we look at each
ratio and what separates them.
Return on assets, which is of major importance for judging management
performance, and
Return on equity, which serves as the key measure from the owners’ viewpoint.
Return on Assets
This number tells you how effective your business has been at putting its assets to work.
The ROA is a test of capital utilization - how much profit (before interest and income tax)
a business earned on the total capital used to make that profit. The basic formula for return
on assets (ROA) is:
ROA= Net profit/Assets
This is an important ratio for companies deciding whether or not to initiate a new project.
The basis of this ratio is that if a company is going to start a project they expect to earn a
return on it, ROA is the return they would receive. Simply put, if ROA is above the rate
that the company borrows at then the project should be accepted, if not then it is rejected.
To get the most insight out of Return on assets we should look at the number in two
different ways:
Look at the trend in return on assets over time. A falling return on assets could
indicate that the company’s customers find new products much less valuable than an
existing product line or much less valuable than competitor’s offerings and aren’t willing
to pay as much for them. Older products with lower margins could be making up a bigger
and bigger part of sales. An older factory simply can’t produce the company’s products
very efficiently anymore. Management can simply be clueless about how to control
expenses. A falling return on assets inevitably leads to a declining stock price as investors
realize that management is earning less and less profit on the things the business owns.
Compare a company’s return on assets with the ratio at other companies in its
industry. Companies with a high return on assets relative to their peers own a very
powerful weapon. They are getting more profit out of each dollar of machinery or
inventory, for example. That means they have more money to devote to marketing or
research and such companies certainly have an easier time attracting investment capital for
new factories and new products. Companies with a low return on assets are probably losing
ground to competitors. A steadily falling return on assets may be a sign that this company
is headed onto history’s trash heap.
Return on equity or the ROE
Essentially, ROE reveals how much profit a company generates with the money
shareholders have invested in it and it is calculated as follow:
ROE= Net income/ Shareholders’ equity
The ROE is useful for comparing the profitability of a company to that of other firms in the
same industry.
15
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
This index may vary substantially from company to company or from period to period
because of the financial structure differences.
The ROE of an enterprise with a rapid growth will constantly decrease even if sales and net
gains look very good. This is happening because of the initial sub capitalization of the
enterprise.
Obtaining big profit with a company initially low on equity may give the ROE a staggering
evolution. A decreasing evolution of the ratio must not be seen as negative - the condition
is not to fall below a certain minimum limit that is admitted in the industry. An average
ratio on industry for this indicator is 9,2% (Halpern P., 1998)
Also, return on equity ratio, can have a different importance from a shareholder to another,
specking about the different interest of a majortar shareholder comparison with minortar
shareholder.
Therefore, the majortar shareholder does a long term placement for which he doesn’t need
an immediately remuneration, so he won’t be interested in obtain of dividend, right away.
He will want to realize an acceptable level of return on equity ratio, based on the reinvest
the profit and also generating a raise of entity value.
Contrarily, the minortar shareholder will be interested in a short-term ratability consist in
the value of dividends received for their investment. This level of ratability is evaluated
with another group of ratios we will focus later, in this paper. So, the minortar shareholder
won’t have a special interest for this ratio.
The Difference between ROA and ROE is All about Liabilities. The big factor that
separates ROE and ROA is financial leverage, or debt. The balance sheet's fundamental
equation shows how this is true: assets = liabilities + shareholders' equity. This equation
tells us that if a company carried no debt, its shareholders' equity and its total assets would
be the same. It follows then that their ROE and ROA would also be the same.
Market-Value Ratios
There are relating the current market price of share of stock to an indicator of the return
that might accrue to the investor. This ratios focus on the current market price of stock
because that is the amount the buyer would invest. Four market ratios can be used by the
analysts and investors as follow:
1.
Earning per share Power (EPS)
It shows how much of the company's profits, after tax, each shareholder owns.
EPS = Net income/Number of Shares Outstanding
This ratio evaluates profitability strictly from the common stockholders’ point of view.
This key ratio is used in share valuations.
16
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
2. Price to Earnings ratio (P/E)
This ratio measures the relationship between the current market price of the stock and its
earnings per share.
P/E = Market Value Per Share/Earnings Per Share
The P/E ratio is used as an indicator of the future performance of the stocks. Analysts use
the P/E ratio to predict how the stock price may react to a change in the level of the
company’s earnings.
In general, a high P/E suggests that investors are expecting higher earnings growth in the
future compared to companies with a lower P/E. An average industry rate, for these
indicators is 7 (Halpern P., 1998).
3. Market-to-book Ratio (MTBR)
Simply put, the market value of a firm divided by capital invested.
MTBR = Market Value per Share/Book Equity Value
Market to Book Ratio seeks to show the value of a company, by comparing the book value
and market value. Book value is calculated from the companies historical cost, or
accounting value, and market value is calculated from its market capitalization. An average
industry rate, for this indicators is 0,9 (Halpern P., 1998).
4. Dividend Yield Ratio (DYR)
The indicator measures the earnings of shareholders resulting from investment in
enterprise stocks.
Dividend Yield Ratio = Dividend per share/Market Price per Share
Like the P/E ratio, this ratio is a volatile measure because the price of stock may change
materially over short period of time, and each change in market price or dividend payment
changes the ratios.
For comparison, in the table below, we present the average performance ratios registered
for Romania, Europe and world average economy:
17
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 1: The main average performance ratios: Comparison between Romania,
Europe and world average.
For Romania, referring to liquidity ratio, we can observe there is a good liquidity at the
global economy level. The solvability ratios are bigger than even the average world level,
especially by reason of a good level registered for gross or net profit There is one except,
namely Return on assets, that has small level compare with average world ratio but higher
than average Europe ratio. The explanation consists in a higher level of assets compare
with the profit that generates it. We can also observe a very small turnover ratio for total
assets, with a big level above even the average ratio. The problem is caused by the big
level of fix assets and their very small turnover.
As for the solvability ratios, there is a very small debt ratios cause of mistrust for financial
organization and also of the small level of their development.
In conclusion, there are no “magic” ratios which somehow encapsulate all that is important
to understand about the position of particular company (Walton P, Haller A., Raffournier
B, p.494) for minimum two reasons:
First, the ratios can only be interpreted on a comparative, basis. Financial analysis often
use four type of standards against which ratio are compared (Short G. Daniel, 1993,
Boston, p. 760):
Comparison of the ratios for the current year with the historical ratios for the
same company. Particular attention is given to the trend of each ratio over time.
18
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Comparison of the ratios for the current year with ratios of other companies
for the same year. These comparisons include the use of ratios from other similar
companies and from industry average.
Experience of the analyst who has a subjective feel for the right relationship in
a given situation. These subjective judgments of an experienced and competent observer
can be more reliable than purely mechanical comparison.
Comparison of the ratios for the current year with goals and objectives
expressed as ratios. Many companies prepare comprehensive profit plans (the budgets)
that incorporate realistic plans for the future. These plan usually incorporated goals for
significant ratios, such as profit margin, return on investment, earning per share.
Second, the ratios doesn’t represent the final point of analyze and doesn’t reflect
strengths and weaknesses point of a business, only through themselves. A unilateral
analyze of an individual ratio could generate wrong conclusions about the activity
evaluation. It’s impose that financial ratios of a specific business to be best interpreted as
a group, rather than making judgments on individual ratios. The interpretation of one ratio
may be altered by other ratios of the same business.
Also, supplementary, a compute analyze of ratio with another dates about the entity’s
management or another entity’s economic conditions, it would be reflect, certainly, the
fair value about the entity’s activity.
19
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
References
Brigham E. F., Gapenski, L.C. Ehrhardt M.C. (1999) Financial management, Theory and
practice, Ninth edition, The Dryden Press, USA ( p.79)
Halpern P., Weston J. F., Brigham E.F., Managerial finance, Canadian model, Ed.
Economica, Bucuresti, 1998, pg.118
Parker Philip M. (2006) Financial return profitability ratio, after ww.ebsco.com
Short G. D. (1993), Fundamentals of Financial Accounting, seventh edition, Boston, USA,
1993 (pp. 760)
Walton P, Haller A., Raffournier B. (2003) International accounting, second edition, Ed.
Thomson, London (pp.494)
*** The Order of Financial Minister no. 1752/2005 that approve The accountant’s rules
conforms to European Directives, published in M. Of. nr. 1090 din 30.11.2005, Romania
modified and completed by OMFP 2374/2007 published in M. O. no.25/14,01.2008.
20
International Conference On Emerging Economic Issues In A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
How Does FDI and Economic Growth Affect Each Other?
The OECD Case
Burcu Türkcan
Izmir University of Economics, Turkey
Alper Duman
Izmir University of Economics, Turkey
I. Hakan Yetkiner
Izmir University of Economics, Turkey
Abstract
This paper tests the endogenous relationship between FDI and economic growth using a
panel dataset for 23 OECD countries for the period 1975-2004. Following the literature,
we treat economic growth and FDI as endogenous variables, and estimate a two-equation
simultaneous equation system with the generalized methods of moments (GMM) for the
OECD case. We find that FDI and growth are important determinants of for each other.
We also find that export growth rate is statistically significant determinant of FDI and
economic growth. Our results indicate that there is an endogenous relationship between
FDI and economic growth.
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Introduction
What kind of relationship does exist between FDI and GDP growth? This is one of the
interesting questions in modern times as capital movement is almost completely free to
move between countries. World Bank statistics show that FDI worldwide grew 23.4
percent per annum on average between 1970-2006 and reached 1.4 trillion dollars in 2006.
The huge growth of capital movement liberalization next to free trade movement indicates
that there is some positive relationship between FDI and economic growth. The following
graph indicates this positive relationship in one dimension: FDI growth versus GDP
growth.
Figure 1: Average GDP Growth versus Average FDI Growth in OECD
The figure scatter plots average growth rate of GDP against average growth rate of FDI of
OECD countries in the period 1975-2004. The figure exhibits that there is a positive
relationship between average GDP growth and average FDI growth, though the latter has
large variations across countries.
On possible question that one may ask on the relation between FDI and economic growth
is how FDI affects economic growth? There is contradicting evidence on this issue, though
most of them support the idea that FDI has a positive impact on economic growth. On the
theoretical grounds, FDI may affect growth positively because FDI, which moves in
general from capital-rich countries to capital-scarce economies, lower rental rate of capital
and increase production via enhancing labor productivity and introducing new technology
embedded in the capital. On the other hand, FDI may affect growth negatively, as it may
deteriorate competition and may corrupt the development path of the country in its own
interests. Most empirical works nonetheless seem to have found a positive impact of FDI
on economic growth. For example, Papanek (1973), Balasubramanyam et al. (1996),
Borensztein et al. (1998), Balasubramanyam et al. (1999), Berthelemy and Demurger
22
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
(2000), Obwona (2001), Reisen and Soto(2001), Zhang and Ram(2002), Massoud (2003),
Bengoa and Sanchez–Robles (2003), Basu et al. (2003), Saha (2005), Li and Liu (2005),
Hansen and Rand (2006), Hyun (2006), Johnson (2006), Güner and Yılmaz (2007), Basu
and Guariglia (2007) found empirically that FDI enhances economic growth. On the
contrary, Fry (1993) and Bornschier et al. (1978) found that FDI may deteriorate growth as
it may distort the development part of FDI receiving economy. Interestingly, some other
studies like Alfaro et al. (2002), Carkovic and Levine (2002), Durham (2004), and Herzer
et al. (2008) found that there is no direct relationship between FDI and economic growth.
In Annex A, we provide a more detailed review of the literature and their main findings.
The alternative question that one may ask due to figure 1 is whether economic growth has
any impact on determining FDI or not? On theoretical grounds, it also has contradicting
explanations. On the one hand, the higher the growth rates in a country, the higher the
growth in demand, which implies greater profitability opportunities for inflowing capital.
Hence, capital must prefer higher growing countries. On the other hand, lower growing
economies may imply more profitability opportunities for capital, given that these
economies are capital-scarce and labor abundant (if they are capital abundant and have low
growth rates, it does not have any incentive for capital to move in such economies).
Empirical research on the issue has mixed results. On the one hand, works by Chowdhury
and Mavrotas (2006), Saha (2005) and Choe (2003) found that higher growth rates attract
more FDI (=countries having higher growth rates attract more FDI). On the other hand,
studies like Hansen and Rand (2006), Hsiao and Hsiao (2004) and Mencinger (2003) argue
that high-growing countries do attract much FDI.
This study works out the above-discussed two fundamental questions in a simultaneous
equation system for the case of OECD. The simultaneous equation setup allows us to treat
FDI and economic growth variables endogenously. Heuristically speaking, our approach is
rare in the literature; most empirical studies use either single equation estimation
techniques or (Granger-) causality tests to determine the direction of causality. Our
simultaneous equation model allows us to estimate the determinants of FDI and economic
growth for OECD countries by using panel data. Moreover, following Saha (2005) and Li
and Liu (2005), we use Generalized Methods of Moments (GMM) estimation technique in
a panel dataset.
The organization of paper is as follows. Section 2 portrays an illustrative framework. We
show that FDI determines economic growth and that economic growth is a determinant of
FDI. Section 3 first describes the data and its limitations and next discusses the
simultaneous equation system. Section 4 presents the findings of the model and its
implications. The last section provides some concluding remarks.
An Illustrative Framework1
Let us assume an open economy that capital may freely move between borders. Let us
further assume that domestic and foreign capital are perfect substitutes for factor of
production; hence each pay the same rate of return, r , the world interest rate. Suppose that
capital per person k * that exists in a domestic country at a particular time has two possible
ownerships: domestic residents and foreigners. Suppose also that k is capital per person
that belongs to domestic residents. Hence, k * − k represents total foreign investments in
1
This section is based on chapter 3 of Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2005).
23
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
the domestic country. For matter of illustration, we assume that k * − k > 0 , without loss of
generality. In another interpretation, k * − k represents net claims by foreigners on the
domestic economy. We assume that the model is single-good economy. The only function
of openness in this model is the free movement of capital. We continue to assume that
labor is immobile. The budget constraint for the representative household is
k = w + ( r − n) ⋅ k − c
(1)
Where k is capital per person owned by domestic residents, w is the real wage rate, r is
the world’s real rate of interest, n is the population growth rate, c is the consumption, and
a dot on top of a variable indicates a time derivative of the variable.
Suppose that utility function of the representative consumer is defined as
∞
U (c) = ∫ e − ρt u (c) Ldt
(2)
0
Where U (c) is the overall utility, ρ is the subjective rate of discount, u (c) is the
momentary felicity function, L is the labor which grows at rate n . We assume that
c1-θ − 1
, where θ is the elasticity of marginal utility.
momentary utility is defined as u (c) =
1−θ
The representative household’s optimization problem implies constructing an optimal
control problem, which yields:
c 1
= (r − ρ )
c θ
(3)
Suppose that the production technology is represented by
(
Y = F K *, N
)
(4)
Where Y output, K * is total physical stock available in the domestic economy, and N is
labor stock. The optimization conditions for the representative firm entail equality between
the marginal products and the factor prices:
f ′(k * ) = r
(5a)
f (k * ) − k * f ′(k * ) = w
(5b)
If we substitute for w from equation (5b) into equation (1) and use equation (5a), the
change in assets per capita can be determined as
( )
k = f k * − r (k * − k ) − nk − c
(6)
24
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Note from equation (6) that it would become the standard equation of motion of Ramsey if
the economy were closed, k * − k = 0 . The difference between equation (6) and the
macroeconomic budget constraint of Ramsey model is that the domestic economy is
incurring rental cost for the total foreign capital that came in until time t . By definition, it
t
must be true that k * − k = ∫ FDIdt , where FDI is the physical capital inflow from abroad
0
at time t . If we take time derivative of this identity, we obtain that k * − k = FDI . Hence,
we may alternatively express equation (6) as follows:
( )
k * = f k * − r (k * − k ) − nk − c + FDI
(7)
y f ′(k * )k * k *
=
. Hence, the
y
f (k * ) k *
growth rate of domestic economy is positively supported by FDI, that is,
Given that y = f (k * ) , the growth rate of output g is g y =
gy =
( )
(k * − k )
k
c FDI
f ′(k * )k * f k *
r−n * − * + *
r
−
*
*
*
k
k
k
k
f (k ) k
(8)
Hence, g y = h( FDI , Z ) , with hFDI (⋅) > 0 and Z represents vector of all variables that
determine growth rate.
Since we have not modeled the foreign (lending) economy next to the domestic
(borrowing) economy, we may directly exploit the literature on FDI on the determinants of
FDI. As we know from our literature survey above, ex ante differences between domestic
and world interest rates, the size of the economy, the growth rate of economy, export
growth rate of economy all contribute to determination of FDI. Hence, we may argue that
the following FDI function is capable of capturing FDI behavior:
FDI = f ( g y , M )
(8)
where M represents vector of variables next to the growth rate of domestic economy that
contributes to the determination of FDI.
Data, Method and its limitations
Data
FDI inflows data have been retrieved from World Development Indicators Online
Database. Raw FDI data were in current US$. Per capita FDI data were formed by using
populations of countries, which were collected from Penn World Table Database. Lastly,
FDI per capita growth rates were calculated from these per capita FDI data. A similar
procedure was applied for determining export growth rates. Firstly, exports of goods and
services data were collected from WDI Online Database. Next, per capita exports values
calculated by using population data from Penn World Table and finally growth rates of
export per capita were found. Growth rates of per capita GDP values were directly
retrieved from WDI Online Database.
25
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Our data set consists of 23 OECD countries and covers time period of 1975–2004. We
included Australia, Austria, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Iceland,
Ireland, Italy, Japan, Mexico, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Spain,
Sweden, Switzerland, Turkey, United Kingdom, and USA in our data set. We dropped
Belgium and Luxembourg from the data set as their FDI data are not trustable.
Consequently our sample size consists of 690 observations and also it is a balanced panel
data set.
Simultaneous Equation System
The empirical method that is used to predict more than one equation systems is called
simultaneous equation system approach. A simultaneous equation system consists of a
number of structural equations involving several endogenous variables whose values are
determined within the specified system. Their values also depend on several exogenous
variables whose values are specified outside the system, and also on lagged values of
variables, known as predetermined variables. To avoid confusion, exogenous variables are
also considered predetermined. Structural equations can be behavioral, technical, identities
or equilibrium conditions. If each of the endogenous variables is solved in terms of the
exogenous and predetermined variables, we obtain a system of reduced form equations.
These equations will not contain any endogenous variables but will depend on the
stochastic terms of all the equations. A good example to simultaneous equation system is
demand and supply equations; price and quantity are jointly determined in this system.
Although the implications of simultaneity for econometric estimation were recognized long
time ago, e.g., Working (1926), the first major contribution to the area of estimating
simultaneous equation system has been made by Trygve Haavelmo (1943). According to
Haavelmo (1943), if one assumes that the economic variables considered satisfy,
simultaneously, several stochastic relations; it is usually not a satisfactory method to try to
determine each of the equations separately from the data, without regard to the restrictions
which the other equations might impose upon the same variables. That this is so is almost
self-evident, for in order to prescribe a meaningful method of fitting an equation to the
data, it is necessary to define the stochastic properties of all the variables involved.
Otherwise, we shall not know the meaning of the statistical results obtained. Furthermore,
the stochastic properties ascribed to the variables in one of the equations should, naturally,
not contradict those that are implied by the other equations.
If the simultaneity is ignored and ordinary least squares applied, the estimates will be
biased and inconsistent. Consequently, forecasts will be biased and inconsistent. In
addition, tests of hypotheses will no longer be valid (Ramanathan, 1998).
Our illustrative framework suggests that FDI contributes positively to the growth rate of
FDI receiving economy, and that positive growth rate stimulates positively FDI inflows.
That means there is bi-directional causality relationship between variables. Hence, we need
to consider the determination of FDI and growth rate together as it is not possible to
construct one-equation regression models.
26
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Econometric Analysis
In this part of the paper, we present our results out of simultaneous equation systems
analysis. In this work, our simultaneous equation system is composed of two equations:
gFDI,it = β0 + β1gY ,it + β2 gX ,it + β3 gFDI,it (−1) + uit
(9a)
gY ,it = α0 + α1 g FDI,it + α 2 g X ,it + α3 gY ,it (−1) + vit
(9b)
gFDI,it is the growth rate of foreign direct investment of the i'th country at time t,
is the growth rate of GDP, gX ,it is the growth rate of exports and gFDI,it (−1) is one
In (9a),
gY,it
year lagged value of FDI growth rate. In (9b), gY ,it is one year lagged value of GDP
growth rate.
Growth rate of exports is the annual percentage change of goods and services exports.
GDP growth rate is stated as annual percentage change in GDP. Lastly, FDI growth rate is
the growth rate of foreign direct investment inflows to countries.
Before starting to an econometric analysis, unit root tests of related series must be made in
order to beware of “artificial regression” problem. Because if there is a unit root problem
in any series, which is used in the model, there will be no stationary in this series.
Consequently, estimation results will not be economically meaningful.
There are different approaches to unit root tests. Our results with these different
approaches are shown in Annex B. Unit root test results prove that our series are stationary
series and they do not involve unit root problems. Hence, we can estimate our model by
using these series. The following table shows the estimation results of our simultaneous
equation system which was estimated by the different econometric methods.
27
International Conference On Emerging Economic Issues In A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 1: Estimation Results of the Simultaneous Equation System
Dependent Variables
1
gFDI
2
3
4
5
6
1
2
3
4
5
6
gY
Independent Variables
Constant
gy
gFDI
gx
gFDI(-1) gFDI(-2)
gy(-1)
gy(-2)
-137.668*
15.917
4.367
(-1.92)
(0.75)
(0.55)
-323.153
17.202
27.849
(-1.58)
(0.27)
(0.82)
-404.177**
88.391
16.463
(-1.99)
(1.43)
(0.48)
-244.410*** 18.773***
18.944***
(-6.21)
(2.61)
(4.14)
-245.333*** 21.626***
19.044*** -0.008
(-5.99)
(3.10)
(4.16)
(-1.60)
-220.755*** 15.520**
17.295*** -0.007
0.008*
(-5.03)
(2.00)
(3.62)
(-1.37)
(1.95)
1.260***
5.230
0.121***
(10.46)
(0.75)
(8.97)
1.226***
0.0001
0.142***
(4.62)
(0.52)
(3.59)
1.239***
0.0002
0.142***
(4.69)
(0.76)
(3.59)
1.167***
0.0002*
0.155***
(5.90)
(1.80)
(5.02)
0.523***
0.0006*** 0.127***
0.417***
(2.86)
(3.38)
(4.36)
(11.46)
0.247
0.0008*** 0.157***
0.360*** 0.114***
(1.23)
(4.39)
(4.98)
(10.26)
(4.06)
t values in parenthesis: *** %1 level, ** %5 level, * %10 level
International Conference On Emerging Economic Issues In A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
For matter of clarity, let us suppose that “the first equation” refers to the equation that tries
to identify the determinants of FDI and that “the second equation” refers to the equation
that tries to identify the determinants of GDP growth. The first model uses Ordinary Least
Squares (OLS) estimation method, to identify the first and second equations. t-statistics of
gY,it and gX ,it in the first equation are insignificant for 1%, 5%, and 10% levels of
significance.
In the second equation, t-statistic of gFDI,it is insignificant at all levels, while gX ,it is
significant at 1% level. Our test results indicate us that OLS regressions do not produce
statistically reliable/significant results.
In the second model, Two Stage Least Squares Method (TSLS) was used to estimate the
system. The results indicate that t-statistics of
insignificant. Moreover, t-statistics of
gY,it and gX ,it in the first equation are
gFDI,it in the second equation is insignificant. Again,
gX ,it is statistically significant for the 1% level of significance.
In the third model, Three Stage Least Squares (3SLS) estimation technique was used in
gY,it and gX ,it in the first equation, are statistically
insignificant. Also, in the second equation, gFDI,it is statistically insignificant, too.
However, t-statistics of gX ,it is statistically significant for the 1% level of significance.
order to estimate the system.
In the fourth model, which was estimated by GMM technique, although coefficients of all
the variables are statistically significant at the 1% level of significance and signs are
gX ,it is statistically significant for 1%
level of significance in the second equation; t-statistics of gFDI,it is only significant for the
positive as expected for the first equation, and also
level of 10%.
Fifth model is the model which consists of one year lags of gFDI,it and gY ,it . It is estimated
by GMM method, because model includes one year lagged values of dependent variables
and this means that our model behaves as an autoregressive model. As it can be seen from
the table, in the first equation only coefficient of one year lagged
gFDI,it is insignificant.
gY,it and gX ,it are significant for the 1% level of significance. However in the second
equation, all the coefficients are statistically significant at the level of 1% and also signs of
coefficients are as expected.
gFDI,it and gY,it ,
respectively. According to the estimation results of this model, only gX ,it shows
significance at the 1% level for the first equation. gY ,it is statistically significant for 5%
Sixth model consists both one-year and two-year lagged values of
level and two-year lagged value of
gFDI,it is significant at the 10% level. However, in this
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
equation, one-year lagged value of gFDI,it is statistically insignificant. In the second
equation, all the independent variables are statistically significant at the level of 1%.
As a result, from the table above, it can easily be seen that, best model for our system is
certainly Model 5.
In model 5, coefficients of the variables show that FDI and economic growth are important
determinants of each other. Also, it is obvious from the results that export growth rate is
statistically significant determinant of FDI and economic growth. On the other hand,
although both FDI and economic growth affect each other in a positive way, the effect of
economic growth on FDI is larger than the effect of FDI on economic growth in OECD
countries.
Our findings are mainly consistent with the literature, though there are some counter
findings. Our finding that FDI inflows affect economic growth positively is also found by
Güner and Yılmaz (2007), Hyun (2006), Li and Liu (2005), Saha (2005), Hsiao and Hsiao
(2004), Bengoa and Sanchez-Robles (2003), Mencinger (2003), Massoud (2003), Zhang
and Ram (2002), Reisen and Soto (2001), Obwona (2001), Berthelemy and Demurger
(2000), Balasubramanyam, Salisu and Sapsfort (1999), Borensztein, Gregerio and Lee
(1998), Balasubramanyam, Salisu and Sapsford (1996) and Papanek (1973). Contradicting
evidence is given by Bornschier, Chase-Dunn and Rubinson (1978) and Durham (2004).
The former study argues that FDI has especially negative impact on the growth rate of
developing countries. The latter study asserts that current value of FDI does not have any
positive impact on the growth rate. Johnson (2006) on the other hand argues that FDI has
positive impact on developing countries but not on developed countries. As our study
focuses on OECD countries, which are developed by and large, our results contradicts with
this result.
Concluding Remarks
It is well known from the wide literature of economic growth that FDI is a major engine of
economic growth. However, what is less understood is the two-way relationship between
FDI and growth. In other words, there is an endogeneity between FDI and growth, and if
this endogeneity is ignored econometric estimations will produce wrong and misleading
results.
In this paper, the endogenous relationship between foreign direct investment and economic
growth was examined for 23 OECD countries and 1975 – 2004 period of time. For this
purpose a simultaneous equation system was established and an econometric estimation
procedure was applied. Our empirical results suggest that FDI positively affects economic
growth rate and also economic growth rate positively affects FDI inflows. Our results
indicate that economic growth stimulates growth rate of FDI inflows more than that the
growth rate of FDI stimulates economic growth.
30
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
References
Alfaro, L., Chanda, A., Kalemli-Ozcan, S. and Sayek, S. (2002). “FDI and Economic
Growth:
The
Role
of
Local
Financial
Markets”.
http://www.people.hbs.edu/lalfaro/JIEfinal1.pdf
Anderson, James E. “A Theoretical Foundation for the Gravity Equation”, The American
Economic Review, Vol. 69, No. 1 (Mar., 1979), pp. 106-116.
Balasubramanyam, V.N., Salisu, M. ve Sapsfort, D. (1996). “Foreign Direct Investment
and Growth in EP and is Countries”. The Economic Journal. Vol. 106. No. 434. pp: 92 –
105.
Balasubramanyam, V.N., Salisu, M. and Sapsford, D. (1999). “Foreign Direct Investment
as an Engine of Growth”. The Journal of International Trade and Economic Development.
8:1. pp: 27 – 40.
Basu, P. and Guariglia, A. (2007). “Foreign Direct Investment, Inequality and Growth”.
Journal of Macroeconomics 29. pp: 824 – 839.
Basu, P., Chakraborty, C. and Reagle, D. (2003). “Liberalization, FDI, and Growth in
Developing Countries: A Panel Cointegration Approach”. Economic Inquiry. Vol. 41. No.
3. pp: 510 – 516.
Bengoa, M. and Sanchez – Robles, B. (2003). “Foreign Direct Investment, Economic
Freedom and Growth: New Evidence From Latin America”. European Journal of Political
Economy. Vol. 19. pp: 529 – 545.
Berthélemy, J-C. and Démurger, S. (2000). “Foreign Direct Investment and Economic
Growth: Theory and Application to China”. Review of Development Economics. 4(2). pp:
140 – 155.
Borensztein, E.; Gregorio, J-De. and Lee, J.W. (1998). “How does Foreign Direct
Investment Affect Economic Growth?”. Journal of International Economics. Vol. 45. pp:
115 – 135.
Bornschier, V. (1984). “The Role of MNCs in Economic Growth – Reply to Szymanski”.
Journal of Conflict Resolution. Vol. 28. No.1. pp 157 – 164.
Bornschier, V., Chase-Dunn, C. and Rubinson, R. (1978). “Cross-national Evidence of the
Effects of Foreign Investment and Aid on Economic Growth and Inequality: A Survey of
Findings and a Reanalysis”. The American Journal of Sociology. Vol.84. No:3. pp:651 –
683.
Carkovic, M. and Levine, R. (2002). “Does Foreign Direct Investment Accelerate
Economic Growth?”.
Choe, J. I. (2003). “Do Foreign Direct Investment and Gross Domestic Investment
Promote Economic Growth?”. Review of Development Economics. Vol. 7(1). pp: 44 – 57.
31
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Chowdhury, A. and Mavrotas, G. (2006). “FDI and Growth: What Causes What?”. United
Nations University.
De Mello, L. R. (1999). “Foreign Direct Investment-Led Growth: Evidence From Time
Series and Panel Data”. Oxford Economic Papers. Vol. 51. pp: 133 – 151.
Durham, J.B. (2004). “Absorptive Capacity and the Effects of Foreign Direct Investment
and Equity Foreign Portfolio Investment on Economic Growth”. European Economic
Review 48. pp: 285 – 306.
Duttaray, M. (2001). “Essays on Foreign Direct Investment and Growth: Causality and
Mechanism”.
Firebaugh, G. (1992). The American Journal of Sociology. Vol. 98. No.1. pp. 105 – 130.
Fry, M. J. (1993). “Foreign Direct Investment in a Macroeconomic Framework – Finance,
Efficiency, Incentives, and Distortions”. The World Bank International Economics
Department. Working Papers. WPS 1141.
Güner, Ü. and Yılmaz, M. (2007). “The Effect of FDI on Economic Growth: A Panel Data
Evidence For Developing Countries (1993 – 2004)”. Akademik Ara tırmalar Dergisi. Sayı
34. pp: 1 – 13.
Haavelmo, T. (1943). “The Statistical Implications of a System of Simultaneous
Equations”. Econometrica. Vol. 11. No:1. pp: 1-12.
Hansen, H. and Rand, J. (2006). “On the Causal Links Between FDI and Growth in
Developing Countries”. University of Copenhagen and Development Economics Research
Group. Copenhagen.
Helpman, E. and P. Krugman, 1985, Market Structure and Foreign Trade; Increasing
Returns, Imperfect Competition, and the International Economy. Cambridge MA/ London:
MIT Press.
Hermes, N. and Lensink, R. (2003). “Foreign Direct Investment, Financial Development
and Economic Growth”. Journal of Development Studies. 40:1. pp: 142 – 163.
Hsiao, F.S.T. and Hsiao, M-C.W. (2006). “FDI, Exports and GDP in East and Southeast
Asia – Panel Data Versus Time-Series Causality Analysis”. Journal of Asian Economics
17. pp: 1082 – 1106.
Hyun, H-J. (2006). “Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Developing
Countries”. Indiana University.
Johnson, A. (2006). “The Effects of FDI Inflows on Host Country Economic Growth”.
CESIS Electronic Working Paper Series. Paper No. 58.
Li, X. and Liu, X. (2005). “Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth: An
Increasingly Endogenous Relationship”. World Development. Vol. 33. No:3. pp: 393 –
407.
32
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Mencinger, J. (2003). “Does Foreign Direct Investment Always Enhance Economic
Growth?”. KYKLOS. Vol. 56. pp: 491 – 508.
Nair – Reichert, U. and Weinhold, D. (1999). “Causality Tests for Cross – Country Panels:
New Look at FDI and Economic Growth in Developing Countries”.
Obwona, M. B. (2001). “Determinants of FDI and their Impact on Economic Growth in
Uganda”. African Development Bank Economic Policy Research Centre.
Papanek, G. V. (1973). “Aid, Foreign Private Investment, Savings and Growth in Less
Developed Countries”. The Journal of Political Economy. Vol. 81. No.1. pp:120 – 130.
Ram, R. and Zhang, K. H. (2002). “Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth:
Evidence From Cross – Country Data for the 1990s”. Economic Development and Cultural
Change. Vol. 51. pp. 205.
Ramanathan, R. (1998). “Introductory Econometrics with Applications”. Fourth Edition.
The Dreyden Press. Fort Worth – USA.
Saha, N. (2005). “Three Essays on Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in
Developing Countries”. Utah State University. Logan, Utah.
WORLD
BANK.
“World
http://devdata.worldbank.org/dataonline .
Development
Indicators
Online”.
Working, E.J. (1927). “What Do Statistical Demand Curves Show?”. The Quarterly
Journal of Economics. Vol.41. No.2. pp: 212 -235.
Zhang, K.H. (2001). “Does Foreign Direct Investment Promote Economic Growth?
Evidence From East Asia and Latin America”. Contemporary Economic Policy. Vol. 19.
No.2. pp. 175 – 185.
33
International Conference On Emerging Economic Issues In A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Annex A
Table 1: Literature Review
Author
Sample Size and
Time Period
Econometric Method
and Tests
Empirical Evidences
Basu & Guariglia
(2007)
119 developing
countries
1970 – 1999
Generalized Methods
of Moments (GMM)
FDI enhances both educational inequalities and economic growth in
developing countries. However, it reduces the share of agriculture
sector in GDP.
Güner & Yılmaz
(2007)
104 countries
1993 – 2004
Ordinary Least
Squares (OLS)
FDI affects economic growth in a positive way and it provides some
advantages on capital accumulation.
Johnson
(2006)
90 developed and
developing
countries
1980 – 2002
OLS
FDI inflows accelerate economic growth in developing countries. But
it is not valid for developed countries.
Chowdhury
&Mavrotas
(2006)
3 countries
1969 – 2000
Toda – Yamamoto
Causality Test
In Chile, GDP growth is the Granger Cause of FDI but reverse is not
true. In Malaysia and Thailand FDI and economic growth are
Granger causes of each other.
Hyun
(2006)
59 developing
countries
1984 – 1995
OLS
FDI has positive effect on economic growth but lagged FDI values
have no positive effects on current economic growth.
Hansen & Rand
(2006)
31 developing
countries
1970 – 2000
Unit Root Tests, Panel
Cointegration Test and
VAR Analysis
There is a strong causality from FDI through GDP growth.
Li & Liu
(2005)
21 developed
countries and 63
developing
Unit Root Tests,
Durbin – Wu –
Hausman Test, OLS
Endogenous relationship between FDI and economic growth has
accelerated since the middle of 1980s. Also, relationships between
FDI, human capital and technological differences effect economic
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
countries
1970 – 1999
growth in developing countries indirectly.
Saha
(2005)
20 Latin America
countries and
Caribbean
countries
1990 – 2001
3 Stage of Least
Squares
FDI and economic growth are important determinants of each other
in Latin America and Caribbean. There is an endogenous relationship
between FDI and economic growth.
Durham
(2004)
80 countries
1979 – 1998
Extreme Bound
Analysis (Sensitivity
Analysis)
There is no direct positive effect of current and lagged values of FDI
and portfolio investment on economic growth.
Hsiao & Hsiao
(2004)
8 countries
1986 – 2004
Granger Causality
Test and VAR
Analysis, Unit Root
Tests
GMM method
Hermes & Lensink
(2003)
67 less developed
countries
1970 – 1995
OLS
Financial development level of a FDI attracting country is an
important pre-condition in order to provide positive affect of FDI on
economic growth.
Basu, Chakraborty &
Reagle
(2003)
23 developing
countries
1978 – 1996
Unit Root Tests and
Panel Cointegration
Test
There is a steady state relationship between FDI and GDP growth in
the long – run.
Bengoa & Sanchez –
Robles
(2003)
18 Latin America
countries
1970 – 1999
Hausman Test
OLS
Economic freedom is an important determinant of FDI inflows. Also
FDI affects economic growth positively.
Mencinger
(2003)
8 EU countries
1994 – 2001
Granger Causality
Test
FDI affects economic growth but economic growth doesn’t affect
FDI.
Massoud
51 developing
OLS
FDI accelerates economic growth in both time periods (1989 – 1996
There is one – way causality from FDI through GDP growth and
exports. FDI and exports make positive contribution to economic
growth.
35
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
(2003)
countries
1989 – 1996
1989 - 2000
and 1989 – 2000)
Choe
(2003)
80 countries
1971 – 1995
Granger Causality
Test
FDI is Granger cause of economic growth and economic growth is
Granger cause of FDI. However economic growth affects FDI growth
more.
Zhang & Ram
(2002)
85 countries
1990 – 1997
OLS
There is a positive relationship between FDI and economic growth in
1990s.
Carkovic & Levine
(2002)
72 developed and
developing
countries
1960 – 1995
OLS and GMM
FDI alone has no statistically significant affect on economic growth.
Alfaro, Chanda,
Kalemli-Ozcan &
Sayek
(2002)
1. sample:
20 OECD
countries and 51
non-OECD
countries
1975 – 1995
OLS
FDI alone has an ambiguous affect on economic growth. However,
the countries which have developed financial markets can benefit
from FDI.
Granger Causality
Test
It’s more possible FDI to affect economic growth in export
promoting countries than import substituting countries.
2. sample:
20 OECD
countries and 29
non-OECD
countries
1980 – 1995
Zhang
(2001)
11 East Asia and
Latin America
countries
36
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
1957 – 1997
(different time
periods among
these years)
Duttaray
(2001)
66 developing
countries
1970 – 1996
Granger Causality
Test, Non-Stationarity
Test
In less than %50 of selected countries, FDI affects economic growth.
Reisen & Soto
(2001)
44 countries
1986 – 1997
GMM
FDI and portfolio investments affect economic growth positively.
Obwona
(2001)
Uganda
1975 – 1991
2 Stage Least Squares
FDI has a positive effect on economic growth in Uganda.
Berthelemy &
Demurger
(2000)
24 Chinese
provinces
1985 – 1996
GMM
FDI plays an important role in the economic growth of Chinese
provinces.
De Mello
(1999)
32 OECD and nonOECD countries
1970 – 1990
Augmented DickeyFuller Test, Panel
Cointegration Test,
OLS
There is an inverse relationship between the difference of
technologically leader countries and their followers, and effect of
FDI on economic growth.
Nair – Reichert &
Weinhold
(1999)
24 developing
countries
1971 – 1995
MFR model (mixed
fixed and random
model) Causality Test
Although there is heterogeneity between countries, the affect of FDI
on future economic growth rates is more in more open countries.
Balasubramanyam,
Salisu & Sapsford
(1999)
46 countries
1970 – 1985
OLS
FDI – labor force relations play an important role in the growth
process.
Borensztein, Gregorio
& Lee
69 developing
countries
SUR Method
FDI is an important tool for technology transfer. Also, it makes more
contributions to economic growth than domestic investment.
37
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
(1998)
1979 – 1989
Balasubramanyam,
Salisu & Sapsfort
(1996)
46 developing
countries
1970 – 1985
OLS
In export promoting countries affect of FDI on economic growth is
more than import – substituting countries.
Fry
(1993)
16 developing
countries
OLS
In 11 developing countries, FDI affects economic growth negatively.
But in Pacific Basin countries FDI affects economic growth
positively. The reason of these different evidences is that, in Pacific
Basin countries economic distortions are less.
1975 – 1991
(different time
periods according
to different
countries)
Bornschier, ChaseDunn & Rubinson
(1978)
76 less developed
countries
1960 – 1975
OLS
FDI has negative impact on economic growth in developing
countries. Also, this impact increases as income level increases.
Papanek
(1973)
1. Sample:
34 countries
1950s
OLS
Savings and FDI flows affect one third of economic growth; foreign
aids have more impact than other determinants on economic growth.
There is no obvious relationship between FDI and foreign aids. Also,
economic growth is not correlated with export, education, per capita
income and country size.
2. Sample:
51 countries
1960s
Source: Constructed by authors
38
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Annex B
Table 2: Unit Root Test Results for FDIg
Method
Levin, Lin&Chu
Statistics Probability
-5.64182
0.0000
(Null Hypothesis: Unit Root)
Im, Pesaran and Shin W-stat
-9.05500
0.0000
(Null Hypothesis: Unit Root)
ADF - Fisher Chi-square
179.043
0.0000
(Null Hypothesis: Unit Root)
PP - Fisher Chi-square
366.293
0.0000
(Null Hypothesis: Unit Root)
Hadri Z-stat
-0.18945
0.5751
(Null Hypothesis: No Unit Root)
Table 3: Unit Root Test Results for Yg
Method
Levin, Lin&Chu
Statistics Probability
-4.83151
0.0000
(Null Hypothesis: Unit Root)
Im, Pesaran and Shin W-stat
-9.57166
0.0000
(Null Hypothesis: Unit Root)
ADF - Fisher Chi-square
179.632
0.0000
(Null Hypothesis: Unit Root)
PP - Fisher Chi-square
262.024
0.0000
(Null Hypothesis: Unit Root)
Hadri Z-stat
0.43079
0.3333
(Null Hypothesis: No Unit Root)
39
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 4: Unit Root Test Results for Xg
Method
Levin, Lin&Chu
Statistics Probability
-7.34907
0.0000
(Null Hypothesis: Unit Root)
Im, Pesaran and Shin W-stat
-11.8374
0.0000
(Null Hypothesis: Unit Root)
ADF - Fisher Chi-square
226.190
0.0000
(Null Hypothesis: Unit Root)
PP - Fisher Chi-square
349.215
0.0000
(Null Hypothesis: Unit Root)
Hadri Z-stat
-0.18645
0.5740
(Null Hypothesis: No Unit Root)
40
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Regional Development in anlıurfa Province, the Center of South
Eastern Anatolian Project (GAP): Key Sector Analysis
Menevi Uzbay Pirili
Ege University, Turkey
R.Funda Barbaros
Ege University, Turkey
Abstract
The challenges facing
anlıurfa are not unique, they are the same challenges found in
rural areas all around the world. Agriculture is still the most important sector in anlıurfa,
but it is generating fewer and fewer jobs. New approaches used in regional development
shift from a focus on individual sectors (such as agriculture policy) to one based on a
comprehensive multisectoral approach in which agriculture is conceived as one
component sector of a comprehensive regional development policy.
Within this framework, there are two major aims of this study. The first aim is to identify
the high point sectors (key industries) by using LQ analysis in anlıurfa province and
11 districts. The analysis encompasses all sectors of industry and services thus excluding
agriculture. On the other hand the economy of anlıurfa, endowed with very rich arable
land resources and irrigation facilities, thanks to GAP-(South Eastern Anatolian Project), is
mainly based on agriculture. Accordingly the second aim of this paper is to analyze the
development potentials of “clusters of agro-industries based on organic agriculture
products” in the region.
The findings of the analysis reveal that the key sectors identified in industry and services
(food and textiles industries and retail and wholesale of food stuff) provide inputs from the
main agricultural products in the region. On the other hand considering the availability of
land and other facilities for organic agricultural products the findings of the study strongly
supports development of “clusters of organic - agro industries” in anlıurfa Region.
41
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Socio-Economic Profile of anlıurfa Province
Among the 26 NUTS 2 regions defined by State Planning Organization in the framework
of regional development policies, anlıurfa is grouped together with Diyarbakır under the
code TRC2. At NUTS 3 level its code is defined as TRC21. Map 1 shows 9 Provinces of
the south eastern Anatolia.
Map 1: anlı Urfa in South East Anatolia Region
The surface area of anlıurfa located in Southeastern Anatolia Region of Turkey is 19.020
km2 and this constitutes 3% of the total surface area of Turkey (Bulu and Eraslan, 2004).
anlıurfa is the Center City of GAP project. anlıurfa is surrounded by Gaziantep in the
west, Adıyaman in the northwest, Diyarbakır in the northeast, Mardin in the east, and Syria
in the south. There are 11 districts including the central district. These are Akçakale,
Birecik, Bozova, Ceylanpınar, Halfeti, Harran, Hilvan, Suruç, Siverek and Viran ehir.
Demographic Structure
As it may be seen in Table 1, total population including the central province and districts
is 1,443,42 according to 2000 census. Population growth rate is 30.9 (‰), far above the
average of Turkey (14.9 ‰). On the other hand the average size of a household in the
province is higher than 4.5, the average of Turkey. It is 6.87. Namely, approximately 7
persons live in a house. When the distribution according to age is considered, the province
has a quiet young population. 0-4 age group has the biggest share within population. It is
estimated that the population of anlıurfa will reach 1.9 million in 2010 through this
rapidly growing population.
42
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 1: Demographic Indicators - 2000
Codes
Total
Populatio
n
67,803,9
6,608,619
Urban
populatio
n growth
rate %
64,9
62,69
Türkiye-TR
South
East
Anatolia-TRC
anlıurfa,Diya
rbakır-TRC2
anlıurfaTRC21
DiyarbakırTRC22
ZonguldakTR811
ĐstanbulTR100
Population
Populatio
growth rate n density
(‰) 2004
86
86
Total
Fertility
Rate
(‰)
2,53
4,57
14.9
21.23
2,806,130
59,15
1,443,42
Househol
d avaregeperson
4,5
6,48
24.6
80
4,68
6,76
58,34
30.9
75
4,83
6,87
1,627,08
60
18.4
87
4,51
6,64
615,599
40,66
-10,08
186
1,93
4,23
10,018,73
90,69
30,73
1,885
1,97
3,93
Source: TUĐK, DPT, Annual Statistical Reports.
The economy of anlıurfa is based on agriculture. As it may be seen in Table 1 and 2
nearly 42% of the population live in rural area. Urbanization rate decreases down to 30%
in the districts except the central district. However, with 58% urbanization rate, the
province is below the average of Turkey which is %65.
Table 2: Population Breakdown of the Provinces of anlıurfa
Name
of Total
District
Population
Merkez
534706
Akçakale
77261
Birecik
74671
Bozova
65842
Ceylanpınar
67817
Halfeti
34402
Harran
56258
Hilvan
38411
Siverek
224102
Suruç
82247
Viran ehir
187705
Urban population
385588
32114
40054
19848
44258
2766
8784
16094
126820
44421
121382
Share of urban population
in total %
72,11
41,57
53,64
30,14
65,26
8,04
15,61
41,9
56,59
54,01
64,67
Source: TUĐK, DPT, Annual Statistical Reports.
Regarding literacy rate it is very low particularly among women (52%) which is far below
the average of Turkey (%80). Another striking issue is the extent of net outmigration in
anliurfa (-39 (‰). Namely, 39 out of 1000 persons migrate from anliurfa. As it may be
seen in Table 3, the province with the highest net outmigration is Zonguldak- 74 (‰), and
43
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Antalya ranks first in term of net immigration. One needs to analyze the structure of the
labor market of anliurfa to understand the reasons of outmigration in anlıurfa.
Table 3: Migration Data
Codes
Inmigration
Outmigration
Net
Migration
Growth of
Net
Migration
Türkiye-TR
permanent
Settlement
population
2000
60,752,995
40,983,56
40,983,56
0
0
South Eastern-TRC
5,687,740
212,425
4,223,15
-209,890
-36.23
anlıurfa,Diyarbakır- 2,419,448
TRC2
anlıurfa-TRC21
1,243,058
96,864
194,240
-97,376
-39.45
38,320
87,632
-49,312
-38.9
Diyarbakır-TRC22
1,176,390
62,996
111,060
-48,064
-40.04
Antalya-TR611
1,451,771
171,982
81,525
90,457
64.31
Zonguldak-TR811
574,182
27,839
71,848
-44,009
-73.82
Source: TUĐK, DPT, Annual Statistical Reports.
Economic structure and Labour Market
Economic structure of anliurfa is mainly based on the agriculture sector. According to
2000 data, the sectoral breakdown of regions GDP is agriculture (43%), services (40%),
industry (11%) and construction (6%). GDP in 2000 is 1 billion 850 Million Dollars, and
income per capita is 1.300 Dollars. (Table 4). However referring to the labour market data,
we see that employment generating capacity of agriculture sector has been declining. As it
may be seen in (Table 6), in terms of TRC2 -Urfa-Diyarbakir data, employment share of
agricultural has declined from 47.4% in 2004 to 26.9% in 2006. On the other hand the
share of industry in employment is increasing gradually as it increased from 12.1% in 2004
to 16.2% in 2006.
44
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 4: Distribution of GNP by Sector
Codes
Per capita GNP
1995-$
Per capita GNP
2001-$
Türkiye-TR
2727
2146
Güneydoğu Anadolu-TRC
1498
1186
1471
1238
1156
1300
Diyarbakır-TRC22
1696
1313
Ağrı,Kars, Iğdır,Ardahan-TRA2
877
730
Kocaeli,Sakarya,Düzce,Bolu,YalovaTR42
4873
4109
anlıurfa,Diyarbakır-TRC2
anlıurfa-TRC21
Source: TUĐK, DPT, Annual Statistical Reports.
Table 5: Employment and Labour Force in TRC2 Region
1000 person
2004
Population
2005
2006
3.155
3.199
TRC
(2006)
7347
1.731
1.782
4214
615
575
1452
64
69
204
551
505
1248
10.4
12
14
35.5
32.3
34
3.05
Civilian Population 15 + ages
1.657
Labour Force
649
Unemployed
70
Employment
579
Unemployment
10.8
Labour Force participation rate
%
39.2
45
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 6: Distribution of Employment by Sector
Codes
Türkiye-TR
Güneydoğu-TRC
anlıurfaDiyarbakır TRC2
Ağrı,Kars,Iğdır
,Ardahan TRA2
Đstanbul TR100
2004
2005
2006
Agriculture Industry Service Agriculture Industry Service Agriculture Industry Service
Person
Thousand
%
Person
Thousand
%
Person
Thousand
%
Person
Thousand
%
Person
Thousand
%
7,400
5,017
9,375
6,493
5,456
10,097
6,088
5,674
10,568
34,0
572
23,0
249
43,0
635
29,5
408
24,7
292
45,8
673
27,3
299
25,4
294
47,3
654
39,3
275
17,1
70
43,6
234
29,7
210
21,3
76
49,0
264
24,0
136
23,6
82
287
47,4
209
12,1
14
40,1
94
38,1
201
13,8
18
47.9
107
26.9
172
16.2
18
56,8
116
65,9
26
4,4
1,412
29,7
1,880
61,7
23
5,5
1,527
32,8
2,005
56,0
19
5,9
1,538
37,8
2,119
0,8
42,6
56,7
0,6
42,9
56,4
0,5
41,8
57,6
Source: TUĐK, DPT, Annual Statistical Reports.
TUĐK Genel Sanayi ve Đ yerleri Sayımı, Geçici Sonuçlarına Göre Đl Đ yeri Sayısı ve Đstihdam, 2005.
46
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Another striking point is that labour force participation rate has been declining in the recent
years. The participation rate which was 39% in 2004 decreased to 32% as of 2006 (Table
5) Findings of a recent research carried out by State Planning Institute reveals that the
number of people who have no hope in finding a job is highest in anlıurfa (105,000
people) among all the provinces of Turkey. On the other hand the highest number of
people that leave the region for seasonal works is also very high. Declining employment
opportunities in agriculture, inadequate access to education and leisure facilities and
declining job opportunities in the public sector employment due to recent climate of fiscal
restraint are among the main reasons of high rates of outmigration from anlıurfa.
Agriculture
Table 7 shows that Sanliurfa owns rich and plentiful land resources for farming activity.
1.200.572,5 hectares of its 1.858.400-hectare-area constitute the agricultural area of the
region. 836.000 hectares of this area is suitable for irrigation. Currently 313.025 hectares
of agricultural area can be irrigated. 167.325 hectares of this irrigation is provided by state
and 145.700 hectares is provided by the public. Agricultural area of Urfa consists 13% of
Turkey’s agricultural area and it also constitutes 35% of agricultural area of southeastern
region.
Table 7: Total Agriculture Arable Land
Regions
Land Area –
Ha
TRC- South Eastern Anatolia
Percentage share %
13 (in Turkey)
3.453.464
TRC 2 anlı Urfa-Diyarbakır
58 (in TRC)
1.995.235
TRC 21- anlı Urfa
35 (in TRC)
1.200.572
TRC 22- Diyarbakır
23 (in TRC)
798428
Source: anlı Urfa Tarım Đl Müdürlüğü, anlı Urfa Sanayi ve Ticaret Odası, TUĐK
anliurfa is one of the major producers of cotton, wheat and barley in Turkey. Other
farming products produce are red lentil, pistachio, grape, sesame and various vegetables.
After 1995 with the initiation of GAP, there has been a great increase in cotton production;
cotton production which was 277.000 tons in 1995 increased to 708,602 tons/year in 2004.
(Table 8)
47
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 8: Agriculture Products Before/After GAP
Products
Products
Wheat
Barley
Lentil
Sesame
Cotton
Corn
Pistachio
Before GAP
Wheat, Lentil, Pistachio, Sesame,
Barley
After GAP
Ton/year
1442884
762767
209314
5368
867790
18300
42097
Tomato
81507
Aubergine
53352
Source: anlıurfa Tarım Đl Müdürlüğü
In Turkey, 30% of total cotton production; 11% of total dry legumes production; 6.4% of
total barley production; 4% of total wheat production is provided by anliurfa.
Farming of Animals
Sheep and goat farming is at the forefront in terms of husbandry. In spite of the fact that
bovine breeding is not at expected levels, it is improving gradually. In 2006, the amount of
farmed animals are as follows; sheep and goat 1.584.495 unit/per year,; cattle breeding
144. 848 unit/per year; poultry 1.010.097 unit/per year; bee hive 8.491 unit/per year.
As it may be seen in Table 9, almost 2000 tons of meat was produced in the region in
2002.
Table 9: Manufacture of Meat Products (2002)
Products
Meat (Ton)
Leather (Unit)
Milk (Ton)
Honey (Kg)
Amount
8.688
168.573
166.495
90.143
Source: anlıurfa Tarım Đl Müdürlüğü
Atatürk Dam and Euphrates River offer valuable potentials in terms of fisheries and fish
breeding. Total 38,835-hectare of water surface comprises 1430 hectares of ponds and
nearly 37,405 hectares of dam area. The potential of this area in terms of fishery products
is of great importance. Implantation works carried out to protect and increase available
fishery products potential in lakes, pounds and dams, and to make use of the new resources
efficiently have an important impact on the development of fishery in the province. Total
48
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
production of fishery products is 405 tons as of 2001 in the region, and 30 tons of this
figures was provided by aquaculture. As a result of the studies to be carried out in the
region it is expected that the production will reach 3700 tons through hunting and 2000
tons through aquaculture. The available production which is 405 tons/year will reach
5700tons/year.
According to a study entitled “Regional Development Policies in Turkey” carried out by
TUSIAD, Urfa-Diyarbakır Region, among the 26 NUTS 2 Regions;
•
•
•
(1.77)
•
Ranks first in field crops (1.6)
Ranks last in fruit and vegetable (0.3)
Ranks second in sheep and goat farming after TRB2 (Bitlis, Hakkari, Van, Mu )
Also ranks among the top provinces in meat production (1.78)
A crucial problem in the region is the salting of land due to over irrigation which is also
called high ground water. 1.512 hectares of the total land area has already been suffering
from this problem. Drainage works and reconstruction works are underway in order to
tackle this issue.
To sum up, inspire of the many problems, agriculture still plays an important role in
shaping the rural landscape and the regions economy therefore it remains a wellspring of
regional support for development. However, this would make sense if agriculture were
conceived more as a part of a regional restructuring process towards multisectoral
approaches, than as a traditional sector producing commodities.
Industry
While the share of employment in agriculture has been declining, the employment share of
industry has been increasing and reached 16.2 % in 2006. The number of the firms
employing 2 or more workers in manufacturing sector increased rapidly in recent years and
this number is 2.933 as of 2002. With regards the industry sector as a whole
(manufacturing, electricity, gas and water and construction) the number of companies and
the number of workers are 3138 and 16392 consecutively.
In 1992, contractions works for First Organized Industrial Zone was launched and it was
completed in 2000 except waste treatment facilities. 295 industry parcels were allocated to
148 entrepreneurs. As of today, 135 factories are operating, 23 factories are under
construction, and 11 factories are in the phase of project. When all of these facilities are
completed in 1. Organized Industrial Zone where 4.500 people are employed, in total 8.000
people will be employed.
Since the First Organized Industrial Zone could not meet the demands of high number of
entrepreneurs, construction works for the Second Organized Industrial Zone was launched.
The total area of 2. Organized Industrial Zone which was included in 1997 investment
Programme is 1186 hectares.
49
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Industry and Services Sectors in anlıurfa: Key Sector Analysis
Clusters and Key Sector Analysis
The idea that national economic success depends, in part at least, on the development of
localised concentrations of industrial specialisation can be traced back more than one
hundred years to Alfred Marshall (Marshal, 1949). He argued that Britain’s economic
growth and leadership during the 19th century was founded on the development of several
examples of localised industries. Examples include cotton textiles in Lancashire, the
potteries district around Stoke, furniture around High Wycombe, and so on.
A century later, economists have rediscovered Marshall’s work on industrial localisation.
Their argument is that regional economic agglomeration and specialisation can maximise
the potential offered by technological, market and other externalities that underpin
increasing returns hence the more geographically localised is an industry within a
given nation, the more internationally competitive that particular industry is likely to be
(Porter, 1990, 1998; Krugman, 1991, 1993; Antonelli 2003).
Porter’s identification of these contemporary local economic agglomerations has been
especially influential, and his term ‘industrial cluster’ has become the standard concept in
this field. Porter’s concept of ‘clusters’(Porter, 1990), originated in his work on
international competitiveness argues that the leading exporting firms in a range of different
countries are not isolated success stories but belong to successful groups of rivals within
related industries. These groups are termed clusters, which refers to industries related by
horizontal and vertical links of various kinds.
The definition of Clusters according to M. Porter is as follows:
Clusters are Geographic concentrations of interconnected companies, specialized
suppliers, service providers, firms in related industries, and associated institutions (for
example, universities, standards agencies, and trade associations) in particular fields that
compete but also co-operate” (Porter,1998.op. cit. page 197)
Accordingly clusters lead to higher growth in three main ways.
-First, they raise productivity by allowing access to specialized inputs and employees, by
enhancing access to information, institutions and public goods and by facilitating
complementarities.
-Second, they increase firms’ capacity for innovation by diffusing technological knowledge
and innovations more rapidly.
-Third, clusters stimulate higher rates of new business formation, as employees become
entrepreneurs in spin-off ventures. Over the past few years, the cluster approach has found
an audience amongst policy-makers at al levels. The idea is that governments and local
authorities can help to provide the business and institutional environment necessary to
cluster success. Identifying high point sectors and industries at the regional level is a
prerequisite for cluster study.
50
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Over the past few years the cluster approach has found an audience amongst policy-makers
at al levels. The idea is that governments and local authorities can help to provide the
business and institutional environment necessary to cluster success. In Turkey in the
framework of the nations accession to EU, there has been a number of case studies realized
which aim at identifying high point industries at NUTS 1 and NUTS 2 levels Some of
those studies have been analyzed by Akgüngör, Kumral and Lenger (2003), Kumral and
Deger (2003), Akgüngör (2003), Kumral and Değer (2004), TUSIAD and DPT (2005).
These studies have had significant contributions to Turkey’s regional development issues
both at theoretical and political levels. However the scope of the majority of such studies is
limited to the manufacturing sectors.
High Point Industries (Key Sectors) Analysis in anlıurfa
The scope of our study covers the entire industry and services sectors in the Province of
anlıurfa. It aims at investigating each and every regional sector to determine whether and
to what extent they may form high points in the province. Hence the findings of this
study is expected to contribute to the previously realized studies
Method
In this study by making use of 4 digit NACE 1.1 codes, employment data belonging to the
years of 2002. The specialization and concentration levels for anlıurfa Province in the
industry sector and services sector have been calculated by using Location Quotient Index.
The fundamental quantitative measure of firm activity we use in anlıurfa province is that
of employment. We will use a relative measure of employment density known as the
location quotient (LQ) as the main technique to determine the degree of localization of a
given sector. We used a methodology similar to DTI’s application on UK to identify high
point industries and clusters (DTI, 2001; 14).
The questions of scale and significance are central to the analysis hence our study attempts
to identify the high point sectors in terms of comparative scale; the size of the sector in
relation to the relevant sector nationally. Hence all the LQ values of each sector within the
industry and services sectors will be calculated. LQ is defined as follows:
LQ = (Eij/Ej)/(Ein/En) or LQ = (Eij/Ein)/(Ej/En)
Eij employment in industry in region j,
Ej is total employment in region j,
Ein is national employment in industry i, and En is total national employment relative to
the region’s share of a given industry’s national employment.
Firstly, LQ values have been calculated that high point industries of individual region.
The LQ values will measures the share of a given industry’s employment in anlıurfa
relative to the region’s share of total national employment.
51
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
An LQ greater than1.5 indicates that there is an above average proportion of employment
in a given industry in a given region. Conversely for an LQ of less than 1.5. Those sectors
with an LQ value greater than 1.5 will be identified as key sectors (high point sectors) in
anlıurfa.
Sectors Besides the Agriculture Sector include Industry sector and Services Sector. Sub
sectors are as follows:
Industry Sectors: Manufacturing Industry (D);
Construction (F)
Electricity, Gas and Water (E);
and
Service Sectors : Wholesale and Retail trade (G) ; Hotels and restaurants (H),
Transportation, Storage and Communication (I), Activities of Financial Intermediary
Institutions (J), activities of Real estate, Renting and Business (K), Education (M), Healthy
Affairs and Social Services (N), Other Social and Private Activities (I)
The sector level data that used is from two sources: Firstly from the “Manufacturing
Industry Surveys” and 1992 and 2002 “General Census Of Industry And Business
Establishments” provided by the State Statistics Institute of Turkey. The second data
source will be Chambers of Industry and Trade of anlıurfa. The data is based on four
digits Nomenclature of Economic Activities (NACE).
Empirical Results
- High Point Sectors In Industry
As seen in Table 10, 19 High Point Industries have been identified in anlı Urfa Region’s
Manufacturing Industry. The main high point sectors identified are basically in food
products and in the textile sector.
Food Industry, the high point sector with the highest LQ value is Manufacture of Diary
Products (code. 1551; LQ = 21.26). Other high point sectors with high LQ values are
Manufacture of Bakery Products (1581) and Manufacture of Vegetable and animal oil and
fats (1541).
Textile Industry, Only one high point sector, preparation and spinning of cotton type
fibers (1711) has been identified. As indicated above Urfa is the major cotton producer in
Turkey. 1711 sector constitutes the first stage in textile production and most of the
companies among the 57 sited in the table are mainly cotton fibers spinning factories. The
share of identified high point food industries and textile industry within the total
manufacturing employment is (54 .1 %). The share of these within the total number of
establishments in manufacturing industry accounts to (35.2 %).
Other high points industries identified are those sectors that provide input to the fast
developing construction sector which accounts for 11% of the GDP in anlıurfa. These
high point sectors are manufacture of builder’s carpentry (2640), manufacture of bricks
and tiles and construction products in clay (2661) and manufacture of plaster products for
construction (2662).
52
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Treatment and coating of metals (2851) is another key industry with a high LQ (4.2)
value identified in Urfa. Urfa with its very rich cultural and religious heritage and
historical places is an important tourist site in the South Eastern Anatolia. The high LQ
values of 2851 sector is due to the very lively souvenir products trade in the city. A
majority of the souvenirs are made form various metals and especially form copper.
Manufacture of pumps and compressors (2912) and manufacture of other agricultural
machinery are two other key sectors identified. The agriculture based structure of the
province gives rise to development of these industries in the city.
In general the share of the 19 high point manufacturing industries in the total
manufacturing sector’s employment of anlıurfa is as high as (74%). On the other hand
share of establishments of these sectors in the total number of establishments in the
manufacturing industry is (67.2%).
In the industry sector apart from the manufacturing industry four sub sectors are identified
as key industries (high point sectors) in the region. Among these;
Construction of water projects (4524) is identified as having a very high LQ value
(16.22). The significance of this industry is due to the South Anatolian Project - GAP and
the Atatürk dam constructed in the region.
General Construction of Building and Civil Engineering Works (4521) is also another
high point sector identified. This is due to the fact that anlıurfa has been receiving inward
migration from the various provinces in the South Anatolian Region which gives rise to
the flourishing of the constructions sector especially in the central province.
53
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 10: Key Sectors in anliurfa Industry Sector
MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY (D)
Manufacture of food products, beverages and tobacco
- Manufacture of crude oils and fats
- Operation of dairies and cheese making
- Manufacture of ice cream
- Manufacture of grain mill products
- Manufacture of bread; manufacture of fresh pastry goods and cakes
Manufacture of textiles and textile products
- Preparation and spinning of cotton-type fibres
Manufacture of wood and wood products
- Manufacture of builders' carpentry and joinery
Manufacture of other non-metallic mineral products
- Manufacture of bricks, tiles and construction products, in baked clay
- Manufacture of concrete products for construction purposes
- Manufacture of plaster products for construction purposes
- Manufacture of ready-mixed concrete
Manufacture of fabricated metal products, except machinery and equipment
- Manufacture of builders' carpentry and joinery of metal
- Forging, pressing, stamping and roll forming of metal; powder metallurgy
- Treatment and coating of metals
Manufacture of machinery and equipment n.e.c.
- Manufacture of pumps and compressors
- Manufacture of agricultural tractors
- Manufacture of non-electric domestic appliances
Manufacture of electrical machinery and apparatus n.e.c.
Codes
1541
1551
1552
1561
1581
LQ
Value
2,615745
21,26409
2,448733
2,556871
6,210733
Number of Firms
Number of
(unit)
Employees
9
6
9
142
803
86
1727
19
324
3315
1711
2,005054 57
966
2030
2,540999 366
766
2640
2661
2662
2663
1,957132
2,268367
2,436588
1,857636
189
121
22
105
2812
2840
2851
2,452018 106
1,113881 47
4,265273 183
270
105
317
2912
2931
2972
2,556782 19
1,19153 11
1,900737 42
92
34
106
54
57
8
5
6
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
- Manufacture of electric motors, generators and transformers
3110
1,946323 10
73
- Manufacture of jewellery and related articles n.e.c.
(D) - KEY MANUFACTURING SECTORS (D) TOTAL
ELECTRICITY, GAS, WATER (E) and CONSTRUCTION (F)
- Collection, purification and distribution of water
- Test drilling and boring
- General construction of buildings and civil engineering Works
- Construction of water projects
- Other building installation
Key sectors in
E and F Total
Key Sectors in D, E and F Total
3622
1,315522 82
1,968
103
8,740
4100
4512
4521
4524
4534
1.12955
1.595
2.03
16,2211
1.45
55
8
7
67
3
32
117
2,085
224
14
1993
794
47
3,072
11,812
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
- High Point Sectors in Services
We identified two main services sectors that have LQ values greater than 1.5. These are
Code
G
I
SECTORS
Wholesale and Retail Trade
Communication and Transportation
LQ value
1.87
1.85
Most of the sub sectors within these two sectors have LQ values greater than one. Those
subsectors that have LQ values greater than two are as follows (see Annex for LQ values
of the sectors)
Services Sectors Having Lq Value Greater Than Two:
Sale, maintenance and repair of motorcycles and related parts and accessories 5040
Agents involved in the sale of furniture, household goods, hardware and
ironmongery 5115
Agents involved in the sale of food, beverages and tobacco 5117
Wholesale of grain, seeds and animal feeds 5121
Wholesale of dairy produce, eggs and edible oils and fats 5133
Non-specialized wholesale of food, beverages and tobacco 5139
Retail sale of meat and meat products 5222
Retail sale of textiles 5242
Freight transport by road 6024
Wholesale and Retail Trade, is a sector that has been growing in the recent years both in
terms of its share in GDP of the region and also in employment. Its share has increased
from 40% in 2004 52% in 2006. On the other hand the key sectors identified in our
analysis are those services sectors that have a close input-out relationship with the
agriculture sector such as wholesale of seeds, dairy products, retail sale of meat and meat
products and textiles.
Freight Transport by Road has been found to have a very high LQ value (4.08). The
main reason of this high share is due to the fact that anlıurfa is situated on the main road
between Mersin Port and Habur Customs Gate to Iraq. In the recent years military
equipment and food stuff arriving at Mersin Port are transported by road to Iraq through
the Habur gate. On the other hand after the competition of reconstruction Works at
Akçakale Customs Gate which is on the border between anlıurfa and Syria, freight
Transport by road sector is expected to flourish even further.
Organic Agriculture and Sanliurfa
It is estimated that organic agriculture is carried out in more than 24 million hectares all
over the world. The biggest parts of this area is in Australia (nearly 10 million hectares),
Argentina (nearly 3 million hectares) and Italy (nearly 1.2 million hectares). While
Australia has 42% of the organic agriculture area in the world, North America follows it
although Latin America and Western Europe ranked first in the world for a long time in
terms of organic food and beverage market. The sale of organic products reached 10.5
billion Dollars by increasing 8% in 2002. In 2002, Germany, the biggest market in Europe,
spent 3.06 billion Dollars for organic agriculture; England, the third biggest market in the
56
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
world spent 1.5 billion Dollars; and the markets of Italy and France spent 1.3 billion
Dollar. North America organic product market is the fastest growing one in the world.
The sale of organic food and beverages reached 11.75 billion Dollars with an increase of
12% in 2002. Although the second largest organic agriculture area is in Latin America, it
has a very small market in terms of marketing of these products (Turkishtime, 2004).
According to the estimations, the world’s trade volume regarding organic products will
increase from 11 billion Dollars to 100 billion Dollars within the next 10 years. Actors
both public and private all around the world and especially in European countries, have
realized the huge potentials this sector may offer and hence organic agriculture promises
huge development prospects in the future
Ecologic Agriculture Organization Association (ETO) was established in 1992 in order to
materialize a sound ecologic (organic) agriculture movement in Turkey. “II. Conference on
Ecologic Agriculture in Mediterranean Countries” was held in Izmir by ETO within the
same year. With the initiation of a new perspective on ecological agriculture in Turkey,
Izmir city has become the leading center of this movement. Currently 12.275 organic
producers produce 168.306 tons of 92 different types of ecologic products cultivating on a
46.523 hectare land area. Although there is lack of accurate data regarding net
contribution of ecologic agriculture sector to the economy via exports which is due to
various problems in customs legislation, it is estimated that this figure is nearly 150 million
dollars.
Map 2: Ecological Zones in Turkey by FAO
57
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Organic Agriculture in anlıiurfa2
After 1995 with the introduction of GAP irrigated farming (as contrary to dry farming)
became widespread in anlıurfa. Majority of the farmers started to plant cotton, which had
a ready market outside hence spectacular increases in cotton production. However as a
result of excessive irrigation, serious problems emerged such as salinity, drought and
pollution of the soil through pesticides
The eligible areas for organic agriculture in anlıurfa province are in Siverek, Karacadağ,
Bozova, Birecik, Akziyaret, Viran ehir, Hilvan geographic borders. On the other hand after
the removal of land mines, a very large area suitable for organic agriculture will be
obtained.
Map 3: Organic Agriculture Zone in anlıurfa
Organic Agriculture Products in anliurfa
Medical and Aromatic Plants
Anasone, Fenugreek, Cummin, Coriander, Mint (Mentha Piperita L. or the plant named as
English mint has pharmacologic peculiarities and Turkey exports this product.), Thyme,
Crocus (The market value of per kilo is almost 2000 USA Dollars. Its added value is quite
high and it is in line with genetic material of anliurfa. It can only grow around Safranbolu
in Turkey. The pilot production of this plant was carried out by GAP- (Agricultural
Development Önder Çiftçi Consultancy Association.)
Nuts
Pistage, Almond, Industrial Plants, Cotton, Corn, Soy bean.
2
GAP-GĐDEM Entrepreneur Support Centers have been carrying out cluster analysis in the South-eastern
Anatolia Region within the framework of EU-GAP Regional Development Programme 2002-2007 and in
collaboration with UNDP. The below information is based on the findings of the Report on Organic
Agriculture Clusters in anlıurfa (Bulu and Eraslan 2004)
58
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Fruit trees
Fig, Grapes, Plum, Olive.
Vegetables
All kinds of vegetables can grow. The vehicles having “interfolding” feature is necessary
in order to transport the vegetables.
Cereals and Grain
Barley, Wheat, Lentil, Chickpea.
Natural Flora
Reverse/Crying Tulip (The liquid that comes out from the plant represents the tears of
Virgin Mary.)
Organic Husbandry
As it may be known, crop shift is necessary for organic agriculture. Within this context,
fodder crops are advised as alternative products. “Fodder cost” in husbandry constitutes
70% of the total cost. Hence the product obtained from fodder crops during organic
agriculture application will be used in organic fodder production, and in line with this
practice, organic husbandry will improve in the region.
On the other hand the sub sectors of poultry and apiculture could not improve since the
climate and geographic conditions of the region impede those. Only in Karacadağ area,
there is an environment known as suitable for apiculture, and small scale apiculture is
carried out there.
State of the Art
In Sanlıurfa Province, there are a limited number of producers producing via utilizing
organic agriculture method. The products are as follows: medical and aromatic plants such
as mulberry, pomegranate, tomato, grapes, wheat, soy bean, nigella, and pistachio and
spices. Ceylanpınar is pretty suitable for organic milk.
Actors in anliurfa Organic Agriculture Group
A)
Producers
Companies of Roza Ecologic Agricultural Nutrition Products Corp. and Selim Uludağ
Organic Agriculture Corp., and farmers; Đbrahim Ethem Polat and Mehmet Emin Yıldırım
carry out organic agriculture. General Directorate of Ceylanpınar Agriculture Enterprise
produces organic cotton and peanut as a trial. Moreover Koç-Ata-Sancak Nutrition and
Agricultural Products Corp. operating as one of the most modern agriculture enterprises in
the region has the potential yet it has no organic agriculture activity.
59
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
B) Non Governmental Organizations:
•
•
•
GAP Agricultural Development Önder Çiftçi Consultancy Association
GAP Sustainable Agricultural Development Association
AGRO-GAP Önder Çiftçi Consultancy Association
C) DATA generating Institutions
•
•
Harran University, Faculty of Agriculture
Siverek Vocational School of Higher Education
D) State and Public Institutions
•
•
•
•
GAP - GĐDEM
Provincial Directorate of Agriculture
Social Security Authority (SSK)
Social Security Organization for Artisans and Self Employed (Bagkur)
E) Other Institutions
•
•
anlıurfa Trade and Industry Chamber ( UTSO)
anlıurfa Young Businessman Association ( UGĐAD)
F) Customers
60
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Map 3: anliurfa Cluster Map
Source: Bulu and Eraslan, 2004.
•
Major players, namely producers are limited
•
The relations with certification organizations are weak
•
Financing demand: Banking sector is advanced in the region yet new financing
opportunities may be provided
•
There is no adequate network with NGOs but there are relations between them
•
There are few customers and most of them are domestic. This field should be
certainly improved.
•
The relations with data generating institutions are very weak
•
There is adequate infrastructure that will meet energy demand
•
The relation with GĐDEM is developed
•
There is quite limited relation with TÜBĐTAK
According to the level analysis in grouping, the density of the other players; particularly
public institutions and data generating institutions is relatively limited. It is of great
importance that these players have active roles in terms of sound development of grouping
in long run. For instance, there is only one network with TÜBĐTAK.
Moreover, the density figure is 0.0376. The value of density is very close to zero. This
demonstrates us that there is a limited relation between players. However, in spite of the
fact that this situation indicates a weak grouping, it is seen that there is a serious potential
to be acquired by enhancing the relations between players.
Findings and Conclusion
61
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
The challenges facing anlıurfa regarding its economic development is not unique, they
are the same challenges found in rural areas all around the world. Although agriculture is
still the most important economic sector in anlıurfa (with 42% of the population living in
rural areas and the agriculture’s share in regions GDP amounts to 43%), it is producing
fewer and fewer jobs. This is evident from the fact that the employment share of
agriculture has fallen from nearly 48% in 2004 to 26% in 2006 in TRC2 region. The
region suffers from the highest outmigration rates all over Turkey. Declining employment
opportunities in agriculture, inadequate access to education and leisure facilities and
declining job opportunities in the public sector employment due to recent climate of fiscal
restraint are among the main reasons of high rates of outmigration.
New regional development approaches and policies are responding these challenges in
many different ways; and successful policies appear to have some common traits. First,
regional policy in rural areas shifts from a focus on individual sectors (such as farm policy)
to one based on territories or regions which involves coordination of policies at the
regional level. Second the coordination of policies at the regional level often means
forming partnership among various public departments and agencies, knowledge producing
institutes as well as private and non profit sectors. (M.Pezzini, 2001). Third, regarding the
identification of the sectors that have high growth potentials in the region and also the
relevant policies to be implemented, “cluster” approaches have proved to be successful.
One important feature of anlıurfa is that due to its agricultural basis, rich land
endowment, suitable climate and clean and arable land the region has high potentials for
the improvement of organic agriculture sector. As a matter of fact local public departments
and agencies consider the improvement and hence support of organic agriculture to
enhance the region’s economy. (M. Sayın, 2000). The organic cluster map study carrried
out by GAP- GĐDEM- Eastern Anatolian Project Entrepreneur Support Centers, reveals
that there is a strong potential for the improvement of organic agriculture, however the
network relations between the possible actors of an organic cluster are still weak.
Based on this background, this paper tried to find out the development potentials of an
agro-industry cluster based on organic agricultural commodities in anlıurfa. The
findings of the study based on LQ analysis and regarding the identification of high point
industries (key sectors) in the industry and services sectors of anlıurfa, reveal that there is
a strong potential for the improvement of an industrial structure based on organic
agricultural products.
Our findings reveal that the majority of the key sectors of industry in anlıurfa are
concentrated in either manufacturing of food products or preparation of textile fibres,
industries that have their basic inputs obtained from the agriculture. The following list
shows the key industries in anlıurfa revealing high LQ values
62
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Key Industries
LQ
values
Manufacture of crude oils and fats
2.6
Manufacture of diary products
21.1
Manufacture of Grain Mill products
2.5
Manufacture of bread, Pastery and bread
6.2
Preparation and Spinning of Cotton type 2.0
fibres
Basic
Inputs
from
Agriculture
Sesame, corn and cotton
Milk
Wheat
Wheat
Cotton
On the other hand the findings also support the fact that the majority of the key sectors
identified in the services sector are involved in wholesale and retail trade of food and
textile industry products. Services sectors with LQ values greater than 2 are:
Agents involved in the sale of food, beverages and tobacco ( code: 5117)
Wholesale of grain, seeds and animal feeds (code:5121)
Wholesale of dairy produce, eggs and edible oils and fats (code: 5133)
Non-specialized wholesale of food, beverages and tobacco (code: 5139)
Retail sale of meat and meat products (code: 5222)
Retail sale of textiles (code:5242)
Clusters include spillovers of knowledge and enhance collective learning hence they play a
crucial role in promoting innovation and entrepreneurial dynamics. Clusters are important
because they allow companies to be more productive and innovative than they could be in
isolation. The major actors of clusters are buyers and sellers interconnected to each other in
a value added chain with forward and backward linkages. The key sectors identified in
the industry and services sectors of anlıurfa demonstrate that such a value added chain of
buyer - seller relations exists between these key industries and the conventional
agricultural product sectors.
Past development policies tended to focus on rural areas as one uniform block treating
them as homogenous with similar problem and opportunities and the policy design and
implementation were basically based on subsidizing one sector such as the farming sector.
Such an approach no longer reflects the present development opportunities for rural
regions. Because each rural region have certain characteristics and resources – as
geographic location, topography and climate, natural resource endowments, industrial
heritage and endowments of human, physical and social capital - that shape their
development trajectory and potential (M. Pezzini, 2001). Together with the new impetus in
regional development policy there is a shift from an approach based on subsidizing sectors
to one based on strategic investments and hence identification of possible development
strategies per type of region.
In the light of the analysis carried out in this study and also of the new approaches in
regional development policy, this paper lends support to the following three issues for
anlıurfa Region:
First, agriculture still plays an important role in shaping the economy of anlıurfa and it
remains as a wellspring of support for development. However, this would make sense if
agriculture were conceived more as part of a restructuring process towards a multisectoral
approach than as a traditional sector being subsidized.
63
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Second, bearing in mind that the local public departments and agencies in anlıurfa give
priority to the development of organic agriculture sector and cluster formation in shaping
regions’ development, organic agriculture cluster will constitute one component of such a
multisectoral development strategy.
Third, the findings of this paper’s reveal that there is great scope for the development of
agro-industry sectors based on organic agriculture commodities, hence investments and
support policies for the formation of an agro-industry cluster may constitute another
component of such a multisectoral development strategy for anlıurfa.
.
64
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
References
Antonelli, Christiano (2003) “Knowledge Complementary and Fungebility: Implications
for
Regional Dtrategy”, Regional Studies, Vol.37. 6&7, August/October, pp.595-606.
Akgüngör, Sedef, N.Kumral and A.Lenger (2003) “National Industry Clusters and
Regional
Specialization in Turkey”, European Planning Studies Vol.11, No 6, September, pp.647668.
Akgüngör, Sedef (2003) “Exploring Regional Specialization in Turkey’s Manufacturing
Industry”, Reinventing Regions in the Global Economy, Paper Prepared for Presentation at
the
Regional Studies Association International Conference, 12th-15th April, Pisa, Italy.
Bulu ve Eraslan (2004)
GIDEM, anlı Urfa
anlı Urfa Organik Tarım Kümelenme Analizi Raporu, GAP-
DTI- Department of Trade and Industry (2001) Bussiness Clusters in the UK, Volume 3
DTI- Department of Trade and Industry (2001) UK Clusters: Performances, Policies,
Emergent Issues, No.3
GAP Đdaresi (2003) anlıurfa Đli Ekosistemine Uygun Tarımsal Ürünler Raporu, Ankara.
GAP Türkiye: http://www.gapturkiye.gen.tr/il/sanliurfa.html
Gap’ta Organik Tarım, (2003) anlıurfa, Gap Gidem Yayınları.http://www.ankaratarim.gov.tr/diger/organik/organik.htm
Krugman, P. (1991), Increasing Returns and Economic Geography. Journal of Political
Economy, Vol: 99, pp. 484-99.
Krugman, P. (1998), What is new about The New economic Geography?. Oxford Rewiev,
14,2
Kumral, Ne e and Ç. Değer (2003) “An Industrial Cluster Study: As a Basis for the
Aegean
Region’s Development Policy”, A Paper for “Reinventing Regions in the Global Economy”
Regional Studies Association, 12th-15th April , Pisa Congress Center, Pisa, Italy.
65
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Pezzini, M. (2001), “Rural Policy Lessons from OECD Countries” International regional
Science Review, Vol.24, No. 1, pp. 134-145.
Porter, M.E. (1990), The Competitive Advantage of Nations, London: Macmillan.
Porter, Michael E. (1998) “On Competition”, A Harvard Business Review Book.
Sayın, M. (2006) “Yerel Ekonomik Kalkınma Đçin Model Önerisi”, Bölgesel Klakınma ve
Yöneti im Sempozyumu, ODTU.
engül ve Ersoy (2004) anlı Urfa Kentinde Yoksulluk, ODTU
anlıurfa Genç Đ adamları Derneği ( UGĐAD), http://www.sugiad.org.tr
anlıurfa Tarım Đl Müdürlüğü Yayınları.
anlıurfa Ticaret ve Sanayi Odası ( UTSO) Yayınları, T OF Plaka Matbaacılık A. .,
Ankara. http://www.sutso.org.tr
anlıurfa Valiliği: http://www.sanliurfa.gov.tr/ilceler/ceylanpinar/
TUSIAD and DPT (2005) “Türkiye’de Bölgesel Geli me Politikaları Sektör-Bölge
Yığınla ma Politikaları”, TÜSĐAD Büyüme Stratejileri Dizisi, No:4 Eylül, Yayın No.
TUSIAD-T/ 2005-09/408.
Turkishtime, Orada bir Pazar var Uzakta, Türkiye Đhracatçılar Meclisi Yayın Organı, 15
Nisan 2004. http://www.turkishtime.org/27/98_tr.asp
Türkiye’de Organik Tarımın Geli tirilmesi ve Yasal Düzenlemelerin Güncelle tirilmesi
Çalı tayı, 21-22 Ocak 2004, Ankara
66
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Appendix:
Codes of All Sector (Agriculture excluded)
C
D
E
F
G
H
I
J
K
M
N
O
C – Mining
D – Manufacturing
E – Electricity, Gas and Water
F – Construction
G – Wholesale and Retail Trade
H – Hotels, Restaurants
I – Transportation, Communication and Storage
J – Activities of Financial Intermediaries
K – Activities of Real Estate, Renting and Business
M – Education
N – Health Services and Social Services
O - Other Social and Personal Service Activities.
67
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
LQ Values of South Eastern Anatolia Provinces
Adıyaman
Diyarbakır
ANLIURFA
Gaziantep
Kilis
Batman
Mardin
Siirt
ırnak
C
D
E
F
G
0,960040202
0,833825159
1,349423199
0,276626199
1,334440244
0,75383
0,49877
2,06979
0,86853
1,29268
0,021158505
0,686588001
1,383
1,8720
1,3006
0,02887601
1,461964956
1,111297091
0,432922184
0,957868919
0
0,77053548
1,2793593
1,17203513
1,325022797
14,92483931
0,316379861
3,972229745
0,67438393
1,156697609
0,54036106
0,389170675
2,06142072
0,57921049
1,330260476
0
0,401559492
2,995452166
1,808098846
1,409736051
6,661757613
0,203610065
2,217218032
0,122809447
1,58847692
H
I
J
K
M
N
O
0,806300068
1,453751
0,493820
0,382346
0,742014
0,674317
1,284323
1,3909
1,5665
0,74149
0,77489
1,3071
1,0305
1,1490
0,664818571
1,8557
0,5578150
0,3541285
0,391332472
0,900675915
0,882878919
0,609161988
0,650152845
0,405080079
0,478592266
0,613351522
1,109713346
0,97187459
0,794090056
1,40554435
0,606171107
0,323739544
1,289786203
0,476573617
1,550645723
1,062446102
1,444889584
0,336514153
0,374641406
1,032441749
0,497933697
0,932073002
0,80231181
2,893630688
0,865843366
0,406899758
0,761802938
0,684346226
0,806667383
1,163784149
1,633837933
0,846290161
0,229543853
0,867100663
0,853826986
1,347324101
0,890586833
2,19511661
0,885174187
0,335874443
0,472849506
0,554624953
0,655912774
68
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Key sectors and LQ Values in Services Sector in anlıurfa
Sector
Code
Sub-Sector
Code
Explanation
Employment
LQ Value
G
5010
Sale of motor vehicles
411
1,432949561
G
5020
Maintenance and repair of motor vehicles
1720
1,543789768
G
5040
Sale, maintenance and repair of motorcycles and related parts and accessories
121
2,998508614
G
5050
Retail sale of automotive fuel
776
1,444599375
G
5111
26
1,303299613
G
5112
Agents involved in the sale of agricultural raw materials, live animals, textile raw
materials and semi-finished goods
Agents involved in the sale of fuels, ores, metals and industrial chemicals
14
1,186709644
G
5115
17
5,026523007
G
5116
Agents involved in the sale of furniture, household goods, hardware and
ironmongery
Agents involved in the sale of textiles, clothing, footwear and leather goods
3
1,424629515
G
5117
Agents involved in the sale of food, beverages and tobacco
459
4,019813858
G
5121
Wholesale of grain, seeds and animal feeds
345
2,682279199
G
5122
Wholesale of flowers and plants
26
1,158745941
G
5133
Wholesale of dairy produce, eggs and edible oils and fats
260
3,839284253
G
5139
Non-specialized wholesale of food, beverages and tobacco
400
4,044435756
G
5143
Wholesale of electrical household appliances and radio and television goods
151
1,139086407
G
5144
Wholesale of china and glassware, wallpaper and cleaning materials
124
1,488467759
G
5151
Wholesale of solid, liquid and gaseous fuels and related products
132
1,040916873
G
5152
Wholesale of metals and metal ores
55
1,011472327
69
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
G
5154
Wholesale of hardware, plumbing and heating equipment and supplies
90
1,0272274
G
5155
Wholesale of chemical products
61
1,109285065
G
5156
Wholesale of other intermediate products
23
1,233825477
G
5211
3859
1,461874619
G
5221
Retail sale in non-specialized stores with food, beverages or tobacco
predominating
Retail sale of fruit and vegetables
162
1,476733685
G
5222
Retail sale of meat and meat products
793
3,190614143
G
5224
Retail sale of bread, cakes, flour confectionery and sugar confectionery
95
1,237778294
G
5231
Dispensing chemists
650
1,859456195
G
5233
Retail sale of cosmetic and toilet articles
65
1,028509507
G
5241
Retail sale of textiles
904
2,176826675
G
5242
Retail sale of clothing
873
1,006980944
G
5243
Retail sale of footwear and leather goods
408
1,644321153
G
5244
Retail sale of furniture, lighting equipment and household articles n.e.c.
678
1,274234633
G
5245
Retail sale of electrical household appliances and radio and television goods
409
1,137251658
G
5246
Retail sale of hardware, paints and glass
1038
1,113051974
G
5247
Retail sale of books, newspapers and stationery
249
1,031608788
G
5248
Other retail sale in specialized stores
1834
1,207741598
G
5250
Retail sale of second-hand goods in stores
58
2,081680231
G
5261
Retail sale via mail order houses
9
4,257760665
G
5271
Repair of boots, shoes and other articles of leather
123
1,856735686
70
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
G
5272
Repair of electrical household goods
618
1,762765097
G
5273
Repair of watches, clocks and jewellery
55
1,763931147
G
5274
Ba ka yerde sınıflandırılmamı tamirler
170
1,531617503
I
6021
Other scheduled passenger land transport
657
1,232531463
I
6023
Other land passenger transport
1277
1,839655341
I
6024
Freight transport by road
5217
4,048866278
I
6321
Other supporting land transport activities
246
1,656481886
71
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
The Importance of ICT for the Knowledge Economy: A Total Factor
Productivity Analysis for Selected OECD Countries
Đsmail SEKĐ
Ege University, Turkey
Abstract
Science, technology and innovation have become key factors contributing to economic
growth in both advanced and developing economies. In the knowledge economy,
information circulates at the international level through trade in goods and services, direct
investment and technology flows, and the movement of people. Information and
communication technologies (ICT) have been at the heart of economic changes for more
than a decade. ICT sector plays an important role, notably by contributing to rapid
technological progress and productivity growth. Firms use ICTs to organize transnational
networks in response to international competition and the increasing need for strategic
interaction. As a result, multinational firms are a primary vehicle of the everspreading
process of globalization. New technologies and their implementation in productive
activities are changing the economic structure and contributing to productivity increases in
OECD economies.
Economic competitiveness depends on productivity level and in the knowledge economy,
ICT sectors determine the productivity level. As a result , we can say that the power of
economic competitiveness of a country depends on the productivity of its ICT sector.
There are two ways to improve the TFP of ICT and to improve the power of
competitiveness. First of all, if the selected countries solve their inefficiency problem by
reallocation of resources, they can improve their TFP of the ICT sector and as a result they
can be more competitive. Secondly, the technological improvement in these countries
creates an expectation about increasing TFP of ICT sector for future. If there will be a
sustainable technological improvement by innovation, it will cause a sustainable increase
in the TFP of ICT sector and as a result it will cause a sustainable increase in
competitiveness.
72
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Introduction
Advance economies are becoming knowledge based economies in an increasing scope in
the context of generation, using and dissemination of knowledge because of the fast
improvements in science and technology. As a result of this progress, the importance of
knowledge as a production factor is increasing. The engine of economic growth and
development is knowledge, not physical goods or natural resources in such an economics
based on knowledge networks. Knowledge economics is a term that is used to define an
economic system in which the knowledge is generated, disseminated and used by firms,
institutions, individuals and society to reach an advance social and economic development.
There are two kinds of knowledge called tacit knowledge and codified knowledge. While
these two knowledge are complementary, the generation processes and the roles on
learning process of these knowledge are very different from each other.
Tacit knowledge is not included by machineries. It is a kind of knowledge that emerges as
a result of interaction between the environment, structure of social institutions, attitudes
and norms. This knowledge contains the expertise and knowledge that is obtained by the
experience of the production, marketing and distribution process. Additionally, it contains
attitude forms that is settled and developed through time. Tacit knowledge can not be
transformed into universal codes easily because it is the product of the specific and
complex environment. Because of that feature, tacit knowledge is not universally
accessible like codified knowledge. Tacit knowledge is also divided into two sub-groups
called internal and external tacit knowledge. Internal tacit knowledge is formed by the
rules and skills (know-how) that arise as a result of learning by doing process. However the
source of the external tacit knowledge is social life. Entrepreneurs systematically see each
other by means of various clubs and associations, local cooperatives, councils of regional
management means.
Codified knowledge is a kind of knowledge which is included in machineries or in general,
included in production devices. Because of that character, codified knowledge has the
facility that everyone can reach by using universal codes. This relation is defined as
hardware/software relation. Software is the knowledge or language that explains the
universal usage of the machinery while hardware is the knowledge which is included in
machinery. We can divide the codified knowledge into two sub-group called internal and
external codified knowledge. Internal codified knowledge is the result of research and
development (R&D) activities. External codified knowledge emerges as a result of
recombination of different information bits in different contents during the collective
works (projects) of universities, R&D departments of firms and different research centers.
Because of the pressure of global competition, firms are both increasing the scope of using
the technology, especially information and communication technologies (ICT), and try to
adopt their organizational structures to the process of knowledge economics (Kelleci,
2003:4).
In the knowledge economy, the most important issue is to generation, using and
dissemination of knowledge. That issue gives ICT sector a vital importance because ICT
sector is the fastest way of using and disseminating knowledge. As a result, we can say that
the power of economic competitiveness of a country depends on the productivity of its ICT
sector.
73
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
There is literature review in the second part of the study. In the third part, methodology
that is used is explained. In the forth part, the data and the source of data is examined. In
the fifth part, there is the empirical analysis of selected OECD countries. In the sixth and
the last part, there is conclusion about the empirical analysis.
Literature Review
There are several studies about Total Factor Productivity (TFP) in the literature. When we
look at the literature, we can see that most of the studies in literature try to explain the
relationship between TFP and economic growth. Here we mention the some selected
empirical studies in the literature.
Hulten (2000) argues that economists have long recognized that total factor productivity is
an important factor in the process of economic growth. However, just how important it is
has been a matter of ongoing controversy. Part of this controversy is about methods and
assumptions. Total factor productivity growth is estimated as a residual, using index
number techniques. It is thus a measure of our ignorance,' with ample scope for
measurement error. Another source of controversy arises from sins of omission, rather than
commission. A New Economy critique of productivity points to unmeasured gains in
product quality, while an environmental critique points to the unmeasured costs of growth.
This essay is offered as an attempt to address these issues. Its first objective is to explain
the origins of the growth accounting and productivity methods now under scrutiny. It is a
biography of an idea, is intended to show what results can be expected from the
productivity framework and what cannot. The ultimate objective is to demonstrate the
considerable utility of the idea, as a counter-weight to the criticism, often erroneous, to
which it has been subjected. Despite its flaws, the residual has provided a simple and
internally consistent intellectual framework for organizing data on economic growth, and
has provided the theory to guide a considerable body of economic measurement.
Miller and Upadhyay (2002) try to find the answer of that question; “Do openness and
human capital accumulation promote economic growth?” While intuition argues yes, the
existing empirical evidence provides mixed support for such assertions. They examine
Cobb-Douglas production function specifications for a 30-year panel of 83 countries
representing all regions of the world and all income groups. They estimate and compare
labor and capital elasticities of output per worker across each of several income and
geographic groups, finding significant differences in production technology. Then they
estimate the total factor productivity series for each classification.
Using determinants of total factor productivity that include, among many others, human
capital, openness, and distortion of domestic prices relative to world prices, they find
significant differences in results between the overall sample and sub-samples of countries.
In particular, a policy of outward orientation may or may not promote growth in specific
country groups even if geared to reducing price distortion and increasing openness. Human
capital plays a smaller role in enhancing growth through total factor productivity.
Scarpetta and Tressel (2004) present empirical evidence on the determinants of industrylevel multifactor productivity growth. They focus on 'traditional factors,' including the
process of technological catch up, human capital, and research and development (R&D), as
well as institutional factors affecting labor adjustment costs. Their analysis is based on
harmonized data for 17 manufacturing industries in 18 industrial economies over the past
74
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
two decades. The disaggregated analysis reveals that the process of technological
convergence takes place mainly in low-tech industries, while in high-tech industries,
country leaders tend to pull ahead of the others. The link between R&D activity and
productivity also depends on technological characteristics of the industries: while there is
no evidence of R&D boosting productivity in low-tech industries, the effect is strong in
high-tech industries, but the technology leaders tend to enjoy higher returns on R&D
expenditure compared with followers. There is also evidence in the data that high labor
adjustment costs (proxied by the strictness of employment protection legislation) can have
a strong negative impact on productivity. In particular, when institutional settings do not
allow wages or internal training to offset high hiring and firing costs, the latter reduce
incentives for innovation and adoption of new technologies, and lead to lower productivity
performance. Albeit drawn from the experience of industrial countries, this result may have
relevant implications for many developing economies characterized by low relative wage
flexibility and high labor adjustment costs. This paper--a joint product of the Social
Protection Team, Human Development Network, World Bank, and the International
Monetary Fund is part of a larger effort to understand what drives productivity growth.
Hallward-Driemeier et. al. (2002) use new firm level data from five East Asian countries to
explore the patterns of manufacturing productivity across the region. One of the striking
patterns that emerges is how the extent of openness and the competitiveness of markets
affects the relative productivity of firms across the region. Firms with foreign ownership
and firms that export are significantly more productive, and the productivity gap is larger
the less developed is the local market. They exploit the rich set of firm characteristics
available in the database to explore the sources of export firms' greater productivity. They
argue that it is in aiming for export markets that firms make decisions that raise
productivity. It is not simply that more-productive firms self-select into exporting; rather,
firms that explicitly target export markets consistently make different decisions regarding
investment, training, technology and the selection of inputs, and thus raise their
productivity.
Han et. al. (2003) compare the sources of growth in East Asia with the rest of the world,
using a methodology that allows one to decompose total factor productivity (TFP) growth
into technical efficiency changes (catching up) and technological progress. It applies a
varying coefficients frontier production function model to aggregate data for the period
1970-1990, for a sample of 45 developed and developing countries. Their results are
consistent with the view that East Asian economies were not outliers in terms of TFP
growth. Of the high-performing East Asian economies, their methodology identifies South
Korea as having the highest TFP growth, followed by Singapore, Taiwan and Japan. Their
methodology also allows us to separately estimate technical efficiency change, which is a
component of TFP growth, and they find that, in general, the estimated technical efficiency
of the high-performing East Asian economies was not out of line with the rest of the world.
Felipe (1997) surveys the empirical literature on total factor productivity (TFP) and the
sources of growth in the East Asian countries. It raises the question whether the literature
has helped us understand better the factors that have propelled growth in the region. The
paper discusses the main theoretical aspects in the estimation of TFP growth, as well as the
empirical results, and provides a survey of estimates of TFP growth for nine East and
Southeast Asian countries. It is concluded that:
75
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
(i) The main merit of the literature is that it has helped focus the attention of scholars on
the growth process of East Asia, and has made countries in the region aware of the
importance of productivity;
(ii) The theoretical problems underlying the notion of TFP are so significant that the whole
concept should be discarded;
(iii) The TFP growth estimates are contentious: they vary significantly, even for the same
country and time period, depending on assumptions and data sources;
(iv) Research on growth in East Asia based on the estimation of TFP growth is an activity
subject to decreasing returns. If we are to advance in our understanding of how East Asia
grew during the last 30 years we need new avenues of research.
OECD Growth Project edited by Dirk Pilat (2003) is an important project about
productivity and growth. Growth and productivity are on the policy agenda in many OECD
countries, and therefore also affect work of the OECD. The organization was asked in 1999
by its member countries to examine the variation in growth performance in the OECD
area, analyze its causes and provide guidance for policy making. The strong performance
of the United States at the time and related claims about a “new economy” were among the
reasons for this demand, as was the poor performance of several other OECD countries at
the time.
Ark (2002) try to examine productivity and income differentials among OECD countries.
Using a conceptual framework, which is rooted in a traditional growth accounting
framework — but with several extensions — he focused on two sources of growth
differentials. First he looked at the role of the “new economy,” in the sense that ICT has
been a source of faster productivity growth in the United States. Then he looked at the
impact of the creation of intangible capital, which has been identified as a necessary
condition for exploiting the productivity advantages of ICT investment. The analysis
suggests that differential realization of the potential to generate productivity accelerations
from ICT has contributed to the differential economic growth performance among OECD
countries. At the same time, it is difficult to precisely measure the contribution of the
various factors at the macroeconomic level. One may even argue that the traditional
methods for analyzing and measuring the relation between inputs and output at the
macroeconomic level are, increasingly, failing to describe the processes that drive changes
and differences in growth performance between firms.
Guerrieri et. al. (2005) argue that in the last half of the 1990s, labor productivity growth
rose in the U.S. and fell almost everywhere in Europe. They document changes in both
capital deepening and multifactor productivity (MFP) growth in both the information and
communication technology (ICT) and non-ICT sectors. They view MFP growth in the ICT
sector as investment-specific productivity (ISP) growth. They perform simulations
suggested by the data using a two-country DGE model with traded and nontraded goods.
For ISP, they consider level increases and persistent growth rate increases that are
symmetric across countries and allow for costs of adjusting capital-labor ratios that are
higher in one country because of structural differences. ISP increases generate investment
booms unless adjustment costs are too high. For MFP, they consider persistent growth rate
shocks that are asymmetric. When such MFP shocks affect only traded goods (as often
assumed), movements in 'international' variables are qualitatively similar to those in the
76
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
data. However, when they also affect nontraded goods (as suggested by the data),
movements in some of the variables are not. To obtain plausible results for the growth rate
shocks, it is necessary to assume slow recognition.
Nicoletti and Scarpetta (2003) look at differences in the scope and depth of procompetitive regulatory reforms and privatization policies as a possible source of crosscountry dispersion in growth outcomes. They suggest that, despite extensive liberalization
and privatization in the OECD area, the cross-country variation of regulatory settings has
increased in recent years, lining up with the increasing dispersion in growth. The authors
then investigate empirically the regulation-growth link using data that cover a large set of
manufacturing and service industries in OECD countries over the past two decades and
focusing on multifactor productivity (MFP), which plays a crucial role in GDP growth and
accounts for a significant share of its cross-country variance. Regressing MFP on both
economywide indicators of regulation and privatization and industry-level indicators of
entry liberalization, the authors find evidence that reforms promoting private governance
and competition (where these are viable) tend to boost productivity. In manufacturing, the
gains to be expected from lower entry barriers are greater the further a given country is
from the technology leader. So, regulation limiting entry may hinder the adoption of
existing technologies, possibly by reducing competitive pressures, technology spillovers,
or the entry of new high-technology firms. At the same time, both privatization and entry
liberalization are estimated to have a positive impact on productivity in all sectors. These
results offer an interpretation to the observed recent differences in growth patterns across
OECD countries, in particular between large continental European economies and the
United States. Strict product market regulations--and lack of regulatory reforms are likely
to underlie the relatively poorer productivity performance of some European countries,
especially in those industries where Europe has accumulated a technology gap (such as
information and communication technology-related industries). These results also offer
useful insights for non-OECD countries. In particular, they point to the potential benefits
of regulatory reforms and privatization, especially in those countries with large technology
gaps and strict regulatory settings that curb incentives to adopt new technologies. This
paper--a product of the Social Protection Team, Human Development Network is part of a
larger effort in the network to understand what drives productivity growth.
Bernard and Jones (1996) examine the role of sectors in aggregate convergence for
fourteen OECD countries during 1970-87. The major finding is that manufacturing shows
little evidence of either labor productivity or multifactor productivity convergence, while
other sectors, especially services, are driving the aggregate convergence result. To
determine the robustness of the convergence results, the paper introduces a new measure of
multifactor productivity which avoids many problems inherent to traditional measures of
total factor productivity when comparing productivity levels. The lack of convergence in
manufacturing is robust to the method of calculating multifactor productivity.
Kask and Sieber (2002) argue that among manufacturing industries employing a
substantial proportion of research and development and technology-oriented workers, the
information technology industries exhibited particularly strong productivity growth over
the 1987-99 period. This article examines productivity developments in a set of detailed
industries representing the high-tech manufacturing sector and uses aggregate measures
that were developed to permit comparison with the manufacturing industry as a whole. In
addition to labor productivity and related measures, the analysis includes multifactor
77
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
productivity. This analysis is based on data produced by the BLS Office of Productivity
and Technology, and the industries used are classified at the three-digit SIC level.
When we look at the power of competitiveness in literature, we see that economists
directly relate competitiveness power to TFP. According to Bryan (1994), the industry
which has the highest productivity level relative to its competitors is the successful
industry. According to Khemani (1997), competitive power is has the same meaning with
productivity. Competitive power is the power of increasing TFP of
firms/industries/countries.
Data
In this study we use Telecommunications data as a proxy of ICT sector because of the data
restrictions about ICT sector. The reason of selected telecommunications data as a proxy is
that telecommunication is an important part of the ICT sector and it has a vital role in
dissemination of knowledge. Our data source is OECD Telecommunications Database
2005
which
can
be
reached
at
that
web
address
[http://oecdstats.ingenta.com/OECD/TableViewer/dimView.aspx]. We use panel data between the
period 1980-2003 for selected 26 OECD countries. Our dependent variable is GDP (in
USD) and independent variables are Total Staff in Mobile Telecommunication and Gross
Fixed Capital Formation. We had to omit the data related with Czech Republic, Hungary,
Poland and Slovak Republic. Because there are no sustainable data for the period 19802003 for these countries.
Methodology
The Malmquist Productivity Index
The Malmquist productivity index (MPI), as proposed by Caves, Christensen and Diewert
(1982), is defined using distance functions, which allow one to describe multi-input,
multioutput production without involving explicit price data and behavioural assumptions.
Distance functions can be classified into input distance functions and output distance
functions. Input distance functions look for a minimal proportional contraction of an input
vector, given an output vector, while output distance functions look for maximal
proportional expansion of an output vector, given an input vector. In this study, we use
output distance functions.
Before we define the distance function we must first define the technology. Let xt RN+
and yt
RM+ denote, respectively, an (Nx1) input vector and an (Mx1) output vector for
period t (t=1,2,…,). Then the graph of the production technology in period t is the set of all
feasible input-output vectors, or
GRt = {(xt,yt): xt can produce yt},
(1)
where the technology is assumed to have the standard properties, such as convexity and
strong
disposability, described in Fare et al (1994).
The output sets are defined in terms of GRt as:
78
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Pt(xt) = {yt: (xt,yt)
GRt}.
(2)
The output distance function for period t technology, as described in Shephard (1970), is
defined on the output set Pt(xt) as:
dot(xt,yt) = inf{δt: (yt/δt)
Pt(xt)}
(3)
where the subscript “o” stands for “output oriented”. This distance function represents the
smallest factor, δt, by which an output vector (yt) is deflated so that it can be produced with
a given input vector (xt) under period t technology.
The productivity change, measured by the MPI, between periods s and t, can be defined
using the period t technology as:
(4)
Similarly, the MPI using period s technology may be defined as:
(5)
In order to avoid choosing the MPI of an arbitrary period Fare et al (1994) specified the
Malmquist productivity change index as the geometric mean of equations 4 and 5:
(6)
The MPI formula in equation 6 can be equivalently rewritten as:
(7)
79
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
The first component of equation 7 measures the output-oriented technical change between
period s and t whilst the second component measures shift in technology between the two
periods. For further discussion of the MPI, refer to Coelli, Rao and Battese (1998).
Calculation of the Malmquist Productivity Index
The MPI has been calculated in various ways. These may be classified in two groups: those
which require both price and quantity data, and those which only require quantity (panel)
data. The price-based method was proposed by Caves, Christensen and Diewert (1982),
who showed that if the distance functions are of translog form with identical second order
terms and there is no technical and allocative inefficiency, then the Malmquist index can
be computed as the ratio of Törnqvist output index and Törnqvist input index.
Fare et al (1994) subsequently showed that the MPI could be calculated without price data,
if one had access to panel data. Furthermore, in this instance, the MPI can be decomposed
into technical change and catch-up components, as shown in equation (7). Fare et al (1994)
used Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) methods to estimate and decompose the MPI. We
now briefly outline their approach.
The Standard Malmquist DEA Method
Given suitable panel data are available, four distance functions must be calculated (hence
four linear programs (LPs) must be solved) for each firm, in order to measure Malmquist
TFP changes between any two periods, as defined in equation (7). First we define some
notation. Let K, N, M and T represent, respectively, the total number of firms, inputs,
outputs and time periods in the sample. Let φ denote a scalar, which represents the
proportional expansion of output vector, given the input vector. Let λ=[λ1, λ2, …, λK]’
denote the (Kx1) vector of constants, which represent peer weights of a firm. Let yit and
xit represent the (Mx1) output vector and the (N×1) input vector, respectively, of the i-th
firm in the t-th period (t=1,2,…T). Let Yt and Xt represent, respectively, the (MxK) output
matrix and (NxK) input matrix in period t, containing the data for all firms in the t-th
period. The notation for period s are defined similarly.
The four required LPs are:
Subject to (s.t.)
(8)
80
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
s.t.
(9)
s.t.
(10)
s.t.
(11)
The above four LPs are very similar to standard DEA LPs. In fact, equations (8) and (9)
are standard DEA LPs, which measure the technical efficiency of the i-th firm in the t-th
and s-th year, respectively. In equations (10) and (11) the i-th observation from the t-th
period is compared to the technology constructed using the period s data, and vice versa.
Thus, in these LPs the φ need not to be greater than or equal to one, if technical regress or
progress has occurred. The above four LPs are required for each firm (or region in our
study) in each pair of adjacent years. Thus, if one has data on K firms over T time periods,
one must solve Kx(3T-2) LPs to construct the required firm-level chained indices (Coelli et
al., 1998).
81
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Empirical Analysis
Technical Efficiency (TE), change in TE, Technological change and change in Total Factor
Productivity (TFP) is calculated by using Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) and
Malmquist TFP Index for selected OECD countries under the assumption of Constant
Returns to Scale. The DEAP- XP software programme which is the advanced version of
DEAP 2.1 written by Coelli (1996) is used for the calculation of these indexes.
Technical Efficiency
In the calculation of TE indexes, efficient reference borders are determined by using linear
programming methods and the selected countries are compared with these efficient
borders. If TE of a country is equal to one (TE = 1), it means that the country has perfect
TE or it is on the perfect production border. If TE of a country is lower than one (TE < 1),
it means that there is an inefficiency. In other words the inefficiency level is 1 – TE.
Inefficiency level shows the inefficient using of production factors. If the TE is lower than
1 (if the inefficiency level (1-TE) is bigger than zero), it means that optimal production can
not be reached with given inputs under the current technology level or current production
level can be reached by using inputs lower than current level so the production factors are
unproductive. The lower TE means the lower producing performance for a country.
In table 1, Technical Efficiency Index under the Assumption of Constant Returns to Scale
is given. Luxembourg is the only country that has perfect TE (TE=1) in the period of 1980
– 2003. It is the one which determines the best production border for all years. It is called
“reference country.” There are other countries which has TE = 1 in different years. These
countries had the effect on determining the best production border for different years.
However, Luxembourg has the best performance for all years.
United Kingdom (UK) has an impact to determine the best production level in 1980, 1982
and between the period 1999-2002. Italy has an impact to determine the best production
level in 1990, 1991 and between the period 1993-2002. Sweden has an impact to determine
the best production level between the period 1993-2003. United States (US) has impact to
determine the best production level between the period 1988-1992. Denmark has an impact
to determine the best production level in 1992, 1994 and between the period 1980-1982.
When we look at Turkey, we see that it has an impact to determine the best production
border just only in years 1980 and 2003.
If we order the countries from the most technical efficient to the less technical efficient
according to the mean of TE for selected period, we can have ordering like that:
Luxembourg, UK, Italy, Sweden, US, Denmark, Belgium, Mexico, Netherlands, France,
Switzerland, Germany, Austria, Iceland, Ireland, Canada, Norway, Japan, Finland, New
Zealand, Spain, Turkey, Greece, Australia, Portugal and Korea (Republic of). The average
of the sample data is 0.837 and the Mean of TE for Turkey is below that average (TE =
0.767).
82
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 1: Technical Efficiency Index under the Assumption of Constant Returns to Scale
Country/Year
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
Australia
Austria
Belgium
Canada
Denmark
Finland
France
Germany
Greece
Iceland
Ireland
Italy
Japan
0.715
0.850
0.884
0.829
1.000
0.737
0.871
0.899
0.694
0.767
0.649
0.843
0.651
0.603
0.787
0.866
0.699
1.000
0.643
0.822
0.846
0.639
0.748
0.589
0.795
0.661
0.690
0.833
0.911
0.784
1.000
0.658
0.818
0.857
0.750
0.731
0.670
0.809
0.653
0.687
0.775
0.961
0.814
0.946
0.627
0.795
0.777
0.679
0.756
0.757
0.764
0.650
0.673
0.785
0.983
0.858
0.900
0.669
0.834
0.800
0.834
0.764
0.825
0.765
0.671
0.607
0.714
0.901
0.780
0.770
0.621
0.786
0.765
0.733
0.735
0.870
0.735
0.726
0.675
0.870
1.000
0.840
0.836
0.718
0.902
0.896
0.759
0.903
1.000
0.916
0.764
0.669
0.914
1.000
0.809
0.886
0.729
0.911
0.937
0.782
0.913
1.000
0.980
0.796
0.679
0.911
0.981
0.836
0.955
0.747
0.919
0.955
0.793
0.958
1.000
0.986
0.918
0.677
0.869
0.905
0.811
0.914
0.689
0.866
0.885
0.770
0.920
0.999
0.951
0.854
0.769
0.909
0.897
0.836
0.982
0.727
0.900
0.877
0.755
0.937
0.932
1.000
0.727
Korea (Republic of)
0.546
0.553
0.568
0.530
0.541
0.515
0.571
0.560
0.585
0.563
0.506
Luxembourg
Mexico
Netherlands
New Zealand
Norway
Portugal
Spain
Sweden
Switzerland
Turkey
1.000
0.898
1.000
0.779
0.759
0.613
0.870
0.943
0.875
1.000
1.000
1.000
1.000
0.697
0.722
0.516
0.738
0.853
0.835
0.869
1.000
1.000
1.000
0.685
0.707
0.527
0.786
0.888
0.964
0.892
1.000
1.000
0.922
0.666
0.636
0.542
0.784
0.854
0.929
0.894
1.000
1.000
0.860
0.648
0.645
0.679
0.871
0.851
0.901
0.899
1.000
0.881
0.779
0.583
0.644
0.688
0.778
0.766
0.885
0.732
1.000
0.930
0.917
0.746
0.693
0.743
0.847
0.869
0.864
0.696
1.000
0.974
0.972
0.727
0.721
0.651
0.835
0.842
0.858
0.664
1.000
0.960
0.978
0.816
0.756
0.635
0.830
0.836
0.848
0.640
1.000
1.000
0.905
0.821
0.784
0.647
0.770
0.755
0.747
0.757
1.000
0.976
0.936
0.885
0.882
0.665
0.778
0.868
0.771
0.763
United Kingdom
1.000
0.985
1.000
0.993
0.940
0.881
0.967
0.912
0.866
0.794
0.851
United States
0.955
0.846
0.917
0.900
0.865
0.808
0.954
0.955
1.000
1.000
1.000
mean
0.832
0.781
0.811
0.794
0.810
0.757
0.841
0.846
0.861
0.833
0.851
83
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 1: Technical Efficiency Index under the Assumption of Constant Returns to
Scale (continue)
Australia
Degree
of
inefficiency
0.778 0.757 0.708 0.700 0.718 0.726 0.688 0.698 0.711 0.786 0.740 0.679 0.642 0.699
0.301
Austria
0.867 0.856 0.879 0.867 0.900 0.875 0.857 0.859 0.844 0.834 0.821 0.824 0.826 0.847
0.153
Belgium
0.915 0.909 0.884 0.913 0.924 0.907 0.883 0.890 0.924 0.914 0.895 0.907 0.927 0.920
0.080
Canada
0.853 0.853 0.853 0.824 0.892 0.889 0.804 0.815 0.854 0.905 0.873 0.831 0.794 0.831
0.169
Denmark
0.964 1.000 0.971 1.000 0.972 0.967 0.904 0.881 0.919 0.899 0.867 0.805 0.789 0.922
0.078
Finland
0.781 0.871 0.935 0.990 0.977 0.944 0.868 0.855 0.875 0.857 0.813 0.871 0.856 0.794
0.206
France
0.888 0.900 0.896 0.920 0.930 0.939 0.936 0.953 0.941 0.923 0.898 0.860 0.822 0.885
0.115
Germany
0.839 0.812 0.794 0.802 0.849 0.853 0.840 0.851 0.866 0.856 0.877 0.893 0.882 0.855
0.146
Greece
0.723 0.762 0.768 0.831 0.859 0.830 0.794 0.779 0.756 0.719 0.703 0.693 0.613 0.751
0.249
Iceland
0.898 0.920 0.930 0.956 0.990 0.864 0.839 0.708 0.761 0.746 0.779 0.880 0.738 0.839
0.161
Ireland
0.951 0.963 1.000 0.937 0.908 0.835 0.796 0.777 0.720 0.701 0.749 0.736 0.668 0.835
0.165
Italy
1.000 0.979 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 0.997 0.938
0.062
Japan
0.833 0.864 0.976 0.965 0.755 0.713 0.740 0.758 0.906 1.000 0.981 0.910 0.802 0.803
0.197
Korea
(Republic of)
0.486 0.485 0.515 0.530 0.526 0.517 0.530 0.542 0.585 0.633 0.635 0.573 0.532 0.547
0.453
Luxembourg
1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000
0.000
Mexico
0.927 0.905 0.915 0.900 0.989 0.905 0.805 0.787 0.808 0.823 0.868 0.857 0.812 0.913
0.087
Netherlands
0.942 0.922 0.889 0.912 0.944 0.916 0.887 0.908 0.814 0.845 0.824 0.800 0.804 0.903
0.097
New Zealand
0.993 0.972 0.845 0.789 0.754 0.778 0.814 0.855 0.881 0.901 0.865 0.808 0.719 0.793
0.207
Norway
0.905 0.916 0.806 0.855 0.859 0.848 0.776 0.704 0.796 1.000 1.000 1.000 0.954 0.807
0.193
Portugal
0.653 0.684 0.701 0.696 0.700 0.695 0.638 0.625 0.645 0.655 0.657 0.670 0.697 0.651
0.349
Spain
0.782 0.810 0.787 0.806 0.807 0.806 0.789 0.779 0.778 0.765 0.745 0.740 0.723 0.792
0.208
Sweden
0.914 0.993 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 0.926
0.074
Switzerland
0.831 0.819 0.900 0.890 0.887 0.894 0.878 0.867 0.895 0.878 0.873 0.876 0.849 0.867
0.133
Turkey
0.684 0.687 0.584 0.629 0.670 0.644 0.595 0.669 0.783 0.759 0.916 0.991 1.000 0.767
0.233
UK
0.908 0.986 0.990 0.975 0.979 0.982 0.985 0.965 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 0.962 0.955
0.045
United States
1.000 1.000 0.938 0.958 0.926 0.913 0.894 0.886 0.880 0.902 0.927 0.927 0.872 0.926
0.074
Mean
0.858 0.870 0.864 0.871 0.874 0.855 0.829 0.824 0.844 0.858 0.858 0.851 0.818 0.837
0.163
Country/Year 1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
Mean
There are exciting results that we cannot expected before for example Korea and Japan
which are developed in high levels in last decades has a lower TE in selected period. Korea
is the last country according to mean of TE which is equal to 0.547. When we look at the
figure 1, we will see that there are 12 countries below the average TE (= 0.837) and 14
over the average. The countries below the average are Australia, Canada, Finland, Greece,
Ireland, Japan, Korea, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Spain and Turkey. However, the
countries over the average are Austria, Belgium, Denmark, France, Germany, Iceland,
Italy, Luxembourg, Mexico, Netherlands, Sweden, Switzerland, UK and US.
84
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Figure 1: Means of TE
Australia
Austria
Mean of TE
1.200
1.000
Belgium
Canada
Denmark
0.800
Finland
France
Germany
Greece
0.600
Iceland
Ireland
Italy
Japan
Korea (Republic of)
Luxembourg
Mexico
0.400
Netherlands
New Zealand
Norway
Portugal
0.200
Spain
Sweden
Switzerland
Turkey
0.000
country
United Kingdom
United States
In figure 2, we can see that TE of countries was at its lowest level in 1985 (TE = 0.757)
and at its highest level in 1995 (TE = 0.874). Also we can say that there is a relatively
sustainable increase in the period between 1985-1995.
85
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Figure 2: Annual Means of TE between 1980-2003
0.9
0.88
0.86
Means of TE
0.84
0.82
0.8
means of TE
0.78
0.76
0.74
0.72
0.7
20
02
20
00
19
98
19
96
19
94
19
92
19
90
19
88
19
86
19
84
19
82
19
80
0.68
years
We can conclude that most of the European Union Members are has a TE level over the
sample average while Japan and Korea are below the average. However the average level
of TE index for the period 1980-2003 is lower than 1 (=0.837). It means that, in selected
OECD countries, optimal production can not be reached with given inputs under the
current technology level or current production level can be reached by using inputs lower
than current level so the production factors are unproductive.
Changes in Total Factor Productivity
If the changes in total factor productivity (TFPCH) index is greater than one (TFPCH > 1)
shows that there is an increase in TFP. If the TFPCH is lower than one (TFPCH < 1), it
means that there is a decrease in TFP. There are two components of TFP, these are changes
in technical efficiency (EFFCH) and changes in technology (TECHCH). If these two
indexes are higher than one, it means that there are improvements in both technical
efficiency and technology. If they are lower than one, it means that there are decline in
both technical efficiency and technology. In another word, if EFFCH index is higher than
one (EFFCH > 1), there is a bigger catching – up effect for the country. If TECHCH index
is higher than one (TECHCH > 1), it means that production border shifts up.
We can divide EFFCH index into two sub-index called changes in pure efficiency (PECH)
and changes in scale efficiency (SECH). SECH index shows the achievement of producing
in an appropriate scale.
Decomposition of Malmquist TFP index is useful to determine the sources of the changes
in TFP (Delikta , 2002:263).
We can see in the table 2 that the annual average value of EFFCH index is 0.999. It means
that there is a decreasing in technical efficiency in general. However, there is no decrease
86
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
in the components of EFFCH. Both the average of PECH and SECH are equal to 1.
Although TECHCH index is increased by %1.8, EFFCH index is decreased by %0.1 and
also TFPCH index is increased by %1.7 in the period of 1980-2003 for all countries. The
increase in TECHCH causes the increase in TFP. In another words, the reason of the
improvement in TFP is technological improvement, not the changes in technical efficiency.
The value of EFFCH indexes which belong to Belgium, Finland, Ireland, Italy, Japan,
Norway, Portugal and Sweden are higher than one. It means that these countries have
higher catching-up effect to reach the optimal production border/frontier. In other words,
these countries are successful to catch up the best production border that is determined by
the reference country (Luxembourg). The most successful country for catch up is Norway.
However Australia, Austria, Canada, Denmark, France, Germany, Greece, Iceland, Korea,
Mexico, Netherlands, New Zealand, Spain, Switzerland, UK and USA have EFFCH levels
lower than 1. It means that there is no catching – up effect in these countries. In addition,
Luxembourg and Turkey have the EFFCH indexes equal to 1. Luxembourg is the reference
country and Turkey is stable so Turkey has no success or failure to catch up the best
production border. In other words, annual average technical efficiency level of Turkey is
not changed.
According to the technological change index (TECHCH), Japan obtains the highest
technological improvement in the period of 1980-2003. Switzerland, Norway,
Luxembourg, Italy, Netherlands, Spain, Austria, Belgium, Korea, France, Germany,
Denmark, US, Sweden, Finland, Portugal, Australia, Canada, Ireland, Iceland, UK, Greece,
New Zealand, Mexico and Turkey follow Japan respectively. In that period all countries
have the technological improvement and annual average TECHCH index is measured
1.018 and TFPCH index is measured 1.017 for all countries. TECH index is higher than 1,
it means that the annual average of best production border is shifted up by technological
improvement.
87
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 2: Malmquist Index Summary of Country Means
EFFCH: Changes in technical efficiency, TECHCH : Changes in technology, PECH:
Changes in pure efficiency, SECH: Changes in scale efficiency, TFPCH: Changes in total
factor productivity.
When we look at the TFP of countries, we can see that Japan has the highest increase in
annual average TFP. Norway, Switzerland, Italy, Luxembourg, Belgium, Austria, Finland,
Portugal, Sweden, Korea, Germany, France, Spain, Ireland, Netherlands, US, Canada,
Iceland, UK, Australia, Denmark, Greece, New Zealand, Turkey follow the Japan
respectively. Only Mexico has a decrease in its annual average TFP. The source of that
decrease is the decreasing in technical efficiency.
88
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Conclusion
The performance of ICT sectors of selected OECD countries are considered by using Data
Envelopment Analysis (DEA) for the period of 1980-2003. The levels of technical
efficiency, changes in technical efficiency, technological change and the changes in TFP
are calculated in this study for all selected OECD countries. Here are the main evidences
that we reach as a result of the study.
First of all, according to the results of the technical efficiency index Luxembourg is the
reference country (TE = 1) and Korea has the worst performance. Secondly, there are
technological improvements in all countries (TECHCH > 1), however there are declines in
technical efficiencies (EFFCH < 1). Thirdly, the effect of technological improvement is
higher than the effect of declining in technical efficiency, as a result of this, there are
positive changes in TFP in all countries except Mexico. According to EFFCH and TFPCH
indexes, Turkey is under the average level of selected OECD countries. According to the
technological change index (TECHCH), Japan obtains the highest technological
improvement and according to EFFCH index, the most successful country for catch up is
Norway in the period of 1980-2003.
Most of the European Union Members are has a TE level over the sample average while
Japan and Korea are below the average. However the average level of TE index for the
period 1980-2003 is lower than 1 (=0.837). It means that, in selected OECD countries,
optimal production can not be reached with given inputs under the current technology level
or current production level can be reached by using inputs lower than current level so the
production factors are unproductive.
There are two ways to improve the TFP of ICT and to improve the power of
competitiveness. First of all, if the selected countries solve that inefficiency problem by
reallocation of resources, they can improve their TFP of the ICT sector and as a result they
can be more competitive. Secondly, the technological improvement in these countries
creates an expectation about increasing TFP of ICT sector for future. If there will be a
sustainable technological improvement by innovation, it will cause a sustainable increase
in the TFP of ICT sector and as a result it will cause a sustainable increase in
competitiveness.
89
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
References
Antonelli, C. (2005), “Models of Knowledge and Systems of Governance”, Journal of
Institutional Economics 1, 51-73.
Antonelli, C. (2006), “The Governance of Localized Knowledge. An Information
Economics Approach to the Economics of Knowledge”, Industry and Innovation 13
forthcoming.
Ark, B.V. (2002), “Understanding Productivity and Income Differentials Among OECD
Countries: A Survey”, [http://www.irpp.org/miscpubs/archive/repsp1202/vanark.pdf].
Arrow, K. J. (1962), “Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention”,
in Nelson, R. R. (ed.) The Rate And Direction Of Inventive Activity: Economic And Social
Factors, Princeton University Press for NBER, Princeton, pp. 609-625.
Bernard, A.B. and Jones, C. (1996), “Comparing Apples to Oranges: Productivity
Convergence and Measurement across Industries and Countries”, American Economic
Review, vol. 86, no. 5, pp. 1216-38
Bryan, I. A. (1994), “Canada in the New Global Economy: Problems and Process”,
Toronto: John Wiley and Sons.
Caves, D.W., L.R. Christensen and W. E. Diewert (1982), “The Economic Theory of Index
Numbers and the Measurement of Input, Output and Productivity”, Econometrica, 50, 6,
1393-1414.
Coelli, T.J., D.S.P. Rao and G.E. Battese (1998), “An Introduction to Efficiency and
Productivity Analysis”, Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston.
Cooke, P. (2002), “Knowledge economies”, London, Routledge.
Dasgupta, P. and David, P.A. (1994), “Towards a New Economics of Science”, Research
Policy 23: 487-521.
Delikta , E. (2002), “Türkiye Özel Sektör Đmalat Sanayiinde Etkinlik ve Toplam Faktör
Verimliliği Analizi.” ODTU Geli me Dergisi, 29: 247 – 284.
Färe, R., S. Grosskopf, M. Norris and Z. Zhang (1994), “Productivity Growth, Technical
Progress, and Efficiency Change in Industrialized Countries”, American Economic Review,
84, 66-83.
Felipe, J. (1997), “Total Factor Productivity Growth in East Asia: A Critical Survey”,
EDRC Report Series No. 65. [http://www.adb.org/Documents/EDRC/Reports/ER065.pdf].
Foss, N.J. (2006), “The Emerging Knowledge Governance Approach: Challenges and
Characteristics”, DRUID Working Paper, No. 06-10.
90
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Guerrieri, L., Henderson, D.W. and Jinill, K. (2005), “Investment-Specific and Multifactor
Productivity in Multi-Sector Open Economies: Data and Analysis”, Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System (U.S.), International Finance Discussion Papers: 828.
Hallward-Driemeier, M., Iarossi, G. and Sokoloff, K.L. (2002), “Exports and
Manufacturing Productivity in East Asia: A Comparative Analysis with Firm-Level Data”,
NBER
Working
Paper
Series,
Working
Paper
8894.
[http://www.nber.org/papers/w8894.pdf].
Han, G., Kalirajan, K. and Singh, N. (2003), “Productivity, Efficiency and Economic
Growth: East Asia and the Rest of the World”, Santa Cruz Centre for International
Economics, Working Paper 03-02. [http://repositories.cdlib.org/sccie/03-02]
Hulten, C.R. (2000), “Total Factor Productivity: A Short Biography”, NBER Working
Paper Series, Working Paper 7471. [http://www.nber.org/papers/w7471.pdf].
Kask, C. and Sieber, E. (2002), “Productivity Growth in ‘High-Tech’ Manufacturing
Industries”, Bureau of Labor Statistics Monthly Labor Review, vol. 125, no. 3, pp. 16-31
Kelleci, M.A (2003), “Knowledge Economics, Basic Actors of Labor Market and
Inequity”, Turkish State Planning Organization, No.2674.
Khemani, R. S. (1997), “Fostering Competitiveness”. [http:/www.cipe.org/mdf1997/foster.
htm.]
Miller, S.M. and Upadhyay, M.P. (2002), “Total Factor Productivity, Human Capital and
Outward Orientation: Differences by Stage of Development and Geographic Regions”,
University of Connecticut Department of Economics Working Paper Series, Working
Paper 2002-33. [http://www.econ.uconn.edu/working/2002-33.pdf].
Nicoletti, G. and Scarpetta, S. (2003), “Regulation, Productivity and Growth: OECD
Evidence”, The World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper Series: 2944.
Scarpetta, S. and Tressel, T. (2004), “Boosting Productivity via Innovation and Adoption
of New Technologies: Any Role for Labor Market Institutions?”, The World Bank, Policy
Research Working Paper Series: 3273.
91
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
The Comparison of Technical Efficiency and Productivity Growth in
Transition Countries and the Soviet Union Countries
Ertugrul Delikta
Ege University, Turkey
Abstract
This study compares economic performance of the 15 transition economies for two
periods: The Soviet Union Countries and transition countries. These periods include data
of countries for 1970-1989 and 1991-2003. It is known that centrally planned economies
are criticized for widespread economic inefficiency and low total factor productivity. Thus,
in order to see how the efficiency levels and productivity growth of the former Soviet
Union countries have changed during the transition or market-based period, we compare
two periods using Data Envelopment Analysis.
The results of analysis indicate that, on average, technical efficiency has slightly increased,
however, total factor productivity decreased due to technical regress over the transition
period when compared to the era of Soviet Union for 15 countries.
92
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Introduction
The Soviet Union grew rapidly through the mid of 1970s due to rapid and successful
planned capital accumulation1. Therefore, a powerful rivalry occurred between the Soviet
Union and the United States until 1980s. However, in the mid of 1980s, the political and
economic structures of the Soviet Union and the Eastern European planned countries
started to crumble (Case and Fair, 2004).
By the end of 1991, the Soviet Union collapsed and the fifteen Soviet Union countries
declared their independences. The 12 of these countries formed the commonwealth of
Independent States, CIS, in December 1991 except for Baltic countries (Estonia, Latvia
and Lithuania). After collapse of the Soviet Union, these 15 countries have also decided to
transform from planned economy to market-based economy. Then they are called the
transition economies. It is argued that the underlying economic reason of the transition was
the ever-worsening economic inefficiency in the pre-transition period due to economic
production occurred overwhelmingly in the public sector and the use of resources was
determined by political decisions made within the planning office. Therefore, it is expected
that economic efficiency would increase after transition to the market economy. However,
at the beginning of the transition the production efficiency; therefore, the per capita GDP
decreased. Most transition economies recovered pre-transition GDP levels only after 2000
(Deliktas and Balcilar 2005).
For most analysts (see e.g. Lipton and Sachs (1990), Hinds (1990), establishing the market
economy in transitional economies mainly depends on four inter-related policies on the
micro-economic side: price liberalization, integration to the world economy, reducing
barriers to entry by new firms and privatization. These policies also suggested by the
International Monetary Fund and the World Bank (Delikta and Emsen, 2002). They are
the main ingredients of a successful transition from socialist economy to a market based
economy. The establishment of market supporting institutions, social safety to deal with
unemployment and poverty, and external assistance have also a vital importance in
transition process. The transition process to a market economy is not complete until these
ingredients can be reached. It was hoped that these policies taken together would motivate
a supply response at the industry level which would alter the structure of national
production, the pattern of sales, both domestically and internationally, the quality and
variety of output and enterprise productivity (Estrin, 1996).
However, transition process to market economy is not easy and may take a longer time.
Advocates of shock therapy believe that the economies in transition should proceed
immediately on all fronts. On the other hand, advocates of a gradualist approach suggest
building up market institutions first, gradually decontrol prices, and privatize only the most
efficient government enterprises first. Of course, these two approaches may have different
effect on performances of economies. Delikta ve Balcilar (2005) indicated that the annual
mean technical efficiency level of advanced reformers is higher than that of the slow
reformers in 1991-2000. However, the advanced reformers had a larger total factor
productivity decline than the slow reformers due to technical regress in the same period.
1
The Soviet Union’s economy was growing much faster than that of the United states during the late 1950s
(Case and Fair, 2004).
93
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Generally, it is expected that transition to market economy would increase economic
performance and then the transition economies have a higher of production frontiers in the
transition period than in the pre- transition period. Because, the transition to market
economy may cause production efficiency to increase due to private-owned enterprises,
independent financial institutions. Accordingly, the transition economies can be thought of
as operating either on or within best-practice frontier; and the distance from the frontier as
reflecting inefficiency. Over time, a country can become less or more efficient and
“catch-up” to the frontier or the frontier itself can shift, indicating technical progress. In
addition, a country can move along the frontier by changing proportion of inputs used in
production. Hence, output growth can be thought in terms of three different components:
efficiency change, technical change, and input change. Economists often refer to the first
two components collectively as “total factor productivity change” (Osiewalski et al. 1998)
In the literature, there are some studies about growth and performance measurement of
nations. These studies use different approaches (Rao et al. 1998b). The first approach
focuses on growth in real per capita income or real GDP per capita. This indicator can be
considered as a proxy for the standard of living achieved in a country. The second
approach is to examine the extent of convergence achieved by the poor countries and
measure disparities in the global distribution of income. The third and most widely used
recent approach is to consider productivity performance of economic decision units. This
approach bases on a partial measure, such as output per person employed or per hour
worked, and multi factor productivity measures based on the concept of total factor
productivity and its components, such as technical efficiency change and technical change.
Total factor productivity is considered as an important indicator of economic performance
of nations. Technical efficiency change is also an indicator of the level of catch-up and
convergence among the countries (Delikta and Balcılar 2005).
In this paper I employ the Malmqüist total factor productivity change index developed by
Caves et al., 1982. In our study, following Fare et al., 1994, Malmqüist TFP change index
is considered as a joint effect of the shift in the production frontier (technological progress)
and a movement towards the frontier (efficiency change). The Malmqüist TFP change
index is computed by the data envelopment analysis (DEA).The DEA used here is
deterministic. There some advantageous of this approach: It does not require a specific
underlying functional form. It enables a decomposition of TFP growth into changes in
technical efficiency and changes in technology. The DEA has been widely used in various
areas (Coelli and Rao, 1998).
The main objective of this paper is to examine how much progress has the Former Soviet
Union (FSU) countries made in terms of technical efficiency and total factor productivity
growth by considering two periods: pre-transition period (1970-1989) and transition period
(1991-2005).
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. The second section briefly outlines the
major sources of data and describes all the variables used in the study. The third section
defines the methodology used in the analysis. The fourth section presents empirical results
and the fifth section concludes the paper.
94
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Data
Measurement of total factor productivity usually requires either data on input and output
prices or the measures of inputs and output. As known, it is difficult to collect data on the
prices of inputs and output. However, Malmqüist indices require information about
quantities or values of inputs and outputs not prices. The inputs and outputs of decisionmaking units are used to determine distance functions by the DEA. In this paper, the input
and output data of the FSU countries for transition period were obtained from the World
Development Indicators 2006 (WDI) published by the World Bank. On the other hand,
data for the pre-transition period were obtained from the Center of Economic Analysis and
Forecasting in Moscow. All data for the pre-transition period is annual for 1970-1990. For
the pre-transition period output was measured by real net material product (in 1973
constant rubbles)2 and capital input was measured by capital stock in 1973 constant rubbles
and labor was measured by the number of employment. In transition period, output was
measured by real GDP (constant 1995 US dollars) for each country. Inputs used in our
model are labor and capital. Labor input was measured as the total labor force. The capital
stock for each country was cumulatively calculated from gross fixed capital formation
(constant 1995 US dollars) by taking 1989 as the base year for the transition countries.
Methodology
In this study the measure we use to analyze productivity performance of the FSU countries
is the DEA based on Malmqüist TFP indices. These indices were introduced by Caves et
al., 1982. Malmqüist indices allow for technical efficiency change and technological
change indices by means of distance functions. The distance functions can be either in
input-oriented form or output-oriented form. The output-oriented form is used in this study.
Because it is more appropriate to investigate the achievable maximal output increase with
respect to the allocation of inputs rather than to calculate the maximum proportional
contraction of the input vector (Angeriz et.al. 2006).
As stated by Fare et al., 1994. By following Coelli et al., 1998, p.158 and Fare et al., 1994,
we define a production technology at time t=1, …T, which represents the outputs,
x t = ( x t1 , , x k )
y t = ( y 1t , , y tM )
t , as:
, which can be produced using the inputs
R t = {( x t , y t ) : xt can produce y t }.
(1)
The equation (1) represents the feasible output set that can be produced by the given input
vector. Following Shephard 1970, the output distance function relative to technology of
R t can be defined as:
{
}
D0t ( x t , y t ) = min ϕ : ( x t , y t / ϕ ) ∈ R t .
(2)
2
NMP = Net Material Product. The Soviet concept of Net Material Product omitted from GNP services not directly
related to production, such as passenger transportation, housing, and output of government employees not producing
material output.
95
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
The distance function is the inverse of Farrel’s, 1957, measure of technical efficiency,
which calculates how far an observation is from the frontier of technology. Distance
D0t ( xt , y t ) = 1 if and only if ( xt , yt ) is on the frontier of the technology, D0t ( xt , y t ) ≤ 1 if
and only if ( x t , y t ) ∈ R t (Karadağ et al. 2005).
Similarly, the output-oriented distance function can be defined with respect to
period t benchmark technology as
{
D0t ( x t +1 , y t +1 ) = min ϕ : ( x t +1, y t +1 / ϕ ) ∈ R t
}
(3)
where ϕ corresponds to the minimum value required to deflate the period t output vector of
the unit onto the production surface of a benchmark fixed in the same period.
Following Fare et al., 1994, Malmquist index of productivity change between period t and
t+1 is defined as
MTFP
t ,t +1
0
D0t +1 ( x t +1 , y t +1 ) D0t ( x t +1 , y t +1 )
t +1
( x t , y t , x t +1 , y t +1 ) =
t
D ( x , y )
(
,
)
D
x
y
t
t
t
t
0
0
1/ 2
,
(4)
where D0t +1 ( xt , y t ) denotes the distance from the period t observation to the period t+1
technology.
Efficiency and technical changes are the two components of TFP change (see Nishimizu
and Page 1982; and Fare et al., 1994, for pioneering studies) as defined below:
t ,t +1
0
MTFP
D t +1 ( x , y ) D t ( x , y ) D t ( x , y )
( x t , y t , x t +1, y t +1 ) = 0 t t +1 t +1 x t 0+1 t +1 t +1 t 0+1 t t
D0 ( x t , y t )
D0 ( x t +1 , y t +1 ) D0 ( x t , y t )
1/ 2
, (5)
The first term on the right-hand side of equation (5) represents the technical efficiency
change (EC) and measures the convergence or catch-up performance of the country to the
best-practice frontier by comparing the technical efficiency measure in period t+1 with
respect to period t. The second squared bricked term on the right-hand side of equation (5)
indicates technological change (TC) over time.
Hence Malmqüist total factor productivity change defined in equation (5) becomes
MTFP 0t ,t +1 = EC ⋅ TC .
(6)
96
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
When there is an increase in the level of productivity from period t to t+1 then the
MTFP0t ,t +1 > 1
MTFP0t ,t +1 < 1
, otherwise there is a decrease in the TFP if
and no change if
t ,t +1
MTFP0 = 1
from period t to t+1. On the other hand, the index (EC) is bigger than one, it
indicates that the country is catching up the best-practice frontier from period t+1 to period
t. If the index is smaller than one, the country is falling behind of the best-practice frontier,
and the index is one, the country has not improved its position with respect to the bestpractice frontier between two periods. The TC index can also be explained in the same
manner, but it provides a measure of the rate of change of the best-practice frontier
between periods t+1 and t. If the index is bigger than one, it indicates technical progress
and if it is smaller than it implies technical regress.
Malmqüist distance functions and therefore, total factor productivity indices mentioned
above can be obtained by the DEA linear programming programs. The DEA method was
developed by Charnes et al., 1978. Since then, there has been a large literature about the
application of DEA methodology specifically in the area of calculations of TFP changes.
Charnes et al., 1995, and Seiford, 1996, give the comprehensive review of this method.
Also, panel data applications of DEA method are widely used in the literature (see for
example, Milan and Aldaz, 2001; and Singh et al., 2000, Delikta 2002, Delikta and
Balcilar, 2005, Karadag et.al, 2005, Delikta et al. 2005, Angeriz et al. 2006).
The output-oriented DEA model for a single output used in this study is closely related to
Coelli et al., 1998. The model can be formalized as follows. Consider the situation for the
N industries, each producing a single output by using K inputs. For the i-th industry xit is a
column vector of inputs, while yit is a scalar representing the output. X denotes the K × NT
matrix of inputs and Y denotes 1× NT matrix of output. The CRS output-oriented DEA
model is given by;
max φ ,
(7)
φ ,λ
subject to
− φ y it + Yλ ≥ 0 ,
xit − Xλ ≥ 0 ,
λ ≥0,
where 1≤ φ <∞, λ is a NT×1 vector of weights. 1/φ defines technical efficiency score,
which varies between zero and one, with a value of one indicating any point on the
frontier. The linear programming problem must be solved NT times in order to provide a
value of φ for each industry in the sample.
97
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Empirical results
Technical efficiency levels for transition economies
Table 1 presents estimates of annual means of efficiency levels for the transition
economies over the 1991-2005 period. Efficiency index lies between zero and one. One
indicates full efficiency and zero indicates full inefficiency for a country. The efficiency
levels of countries are calculated by Equation (7) based on the DEA.
According to annual averages of efficiency levels for all countries, which are given in the
second column of Table 1, Lithuania appears to be the most efficient countries, followed
by Azerbaijan, Estonia, and Latvia. On the other hand, Tajikistan appears to be the least
efficient countries, followed Ukraine and Belarus. Average efficiency level for the
transition economies is 0.634 over the 1991-2005 period.
Table 1: Technical efficiency levels for transition countries (1991-2005)
Country
Armenia
Azerbaijan
Belarus
Estonia
Georgia
Kazakhstan
Kyrgyzstan R.
Latvia
Lithuania
Moldova
Russian F.
Tajikistan
Turkmenistan
Ukraine
Uzbekistan
Annual mean
Annual mean
for each country
of 15 countries
(1991-2005)
0.502
0.979
0.473
0.978
0.532
0.511
0.567
0.944
0.999
0.536
0.614
0.422
0.511
0.430
0.506
year
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
0.463
0.502
0.565
0.559
0.548
0.561
0.574
0.598
0.633
0.657
0.689
0.717
0.790
0.821
0.832
The third column of Table 1 gives the annual means of technical efficiency scores of 15
countries for each year. This column indicates that the annual means of technical
efficiency scores increased from 0.463 to 0.832 over the 1991-2005 period except for 1994
and 1995.
Figure 1 also shows annual means of technical efficiency scores of the transition countries
over the 1991-2005 period.
98
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Figure 1: Mean technical efficiency levels of transition economies
Technical efficiency :1991-2005
0.9
0.8
0.7
TE
0.6
0.5
Seri 1
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
year
Technical efficiency change, technological change and total factor productivity change
for transition economies
Table 2 presents the means for he technical efficiency change, technological change and
total factor productivity change indices of the transition economies. Over the period of
1991-2005, the mean technical efficiency change is 1.054 and technological change is
0.854 and the TFP change is 0.902. As the table shows, the average rate of growth in the
mean technical efficiency is 5.4 percent over the 1991-2005 period. The increasing
efficiency over the entire sample period is an indicator of a country’s performance in
adapting the global technology, and therefore represents the catch-up factor (Rao and
Coelli 1998b). The rate of growth in efficiency also indicates a more efficient use of the
existing technology over time. Table 3 also presents information on the year-to-year
evaluation of the TFP change and changes its components. The negative efficiency change
occurred in1994 and 1995.
99
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 2: Annual means of technical efficiency change, technological change and total
factor productivity change in Transition economies, 1991-2005
year
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
Mean
Mean
technical
efficiency
change
1.097
1.164
0.991
0.986
1.033
1.034
1.065
1.076
1.050
1.061
1.049
1.111
1.043
1.015
1.054
Mean
total factor
Productivity
change
0.663
0.813
0.816
0.880
0.917
0.942
0.940
0.951
0.979
0.998
0.966
0.987
0.989
0.857
0.902
Mean
technological
change
0.604
0.699
0.823
0.893
0.888
0.911
0.883
0.884
0.932
0.940
0.921
0.888
0.949
0.844
0.856
Note: For each year, the change given is that over the previous year (e.g. 1992 gives the
change over 1991-1992).
Figure 2: Mean technical efficiency change for transition economies
Technical efficiency change:1991-2005
1.4
1.2
TECH
1
0.8
Seri 1
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
year
The third column in Table 3 shows that average technological change in transition
economies is negative, with an average technical change about -14.4 percent, over the
1991-2005 period. That is, there is a technological regress over the whole period. The
transition countries have suffered from substantial capital losses during the first half of
100
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
1990s. Therefore, a negative technical change is not unexpected for these countries
(Delikta and Balcilar, 2005). Taskin and Zaim (1997) estimated a -1.38 percent technical
change for low-income countries. Delikta and Balcilar (2005) estimated a -4.3 percent
technological regress for 25 transition economies over the 1991-2000 period. Angeriz et al.
(2006) calculated -2.7 percent technological regress for European Union regional
manufacturing region over the 1986-2002 period.
Figure 3: Mean technological change for transition economies
TECH
Technological change:1991-2005
1
0.9
0.8
0.7
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
1990
mean
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
year
The column four in Table 3 presents the TFP change indices for transition economies. The
TFP growth is important because it determines the real standard of living that a country
can achieve for its citizens. There is a simple link between productivity growth and the
standard of living (Delikta and Balcilar 2005). The TFP change index can be decomposed
into technical efficiency change and technological change as given equation (5). The
decomposition of total factor productivity change makes it possible to understand whether
the countries have improved their productivity levels simply through a more efficient use
of existing technology or through technical progress. Furthermore, these two components
make up for the overall productivity growth. The average annual TFP change index for the
transition countries is 0.902 over the 1991-2005 period. The negative TFP growth rate is
due to significant technical regress and slight increase in the efficiency. Overall, we
observe that the average annual growth in technical efficiency is 5.4 percent, but the
average annual technical change is -14.4 percent. The sum of these two changes is -9.8
percent. That is, the average annual TFP in the transition countries has declined by 9.8
percent over the 1991-2005 period due to a technical regress over the entire period.
101
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Figure 4: Mean total factor productivity change for transition economies
Total factor productivity change:1991-2005
1.2
1
TFPCH
0.8
0.6
mean
0.4
0.2
0
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
year
Technical efficiency levels for the pre-transition economies
Table 3 presents estimates of annual means of efficiency levels for the pre- transition
economies (or the FSU countries) over the 1970-1989 period. Over the entire period,
average efficiency level for the FSU countries was calculated as 0.806. It is higher than
that of transition period. According to annual averages of efficiency levels for all countries,
Belarus and Latvia were the most efficient countries while Turkmenistan was the least
efficient country in the same period. It is also seen that annual mean of technical efficiency
score of 15 countries was the highest in 1970. The level of changes in technical efficiency
is given in Table 4.
102
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 3: Technical efficiency levels for the Soviet Union economies (1970-1989)
Annual mean
for each country
(1970-1989)
Country
Armenia
0.933
Azerbaijan
0.744
Belarus
1.000
Estonia
0.950
Georgia
0.757
Kazakhstan
0.607
Kyrgyzstan R
0.747
Latvia
1.000
Lithuania
0.851
Moldova
0.894
Russian F.
0.862
Tajikistan
0.730
Turkmenistan
0.488
Ukraine
0.826
Uzbekistan
0.711
Annual mean
of 15 countries
year
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
0.868
0.848
0.836
0.829
0.836
0.812
0.810
0.809
0.804
0.812
0.818
0.795
0.803
0.795
0.793
0.788
0.777
0.743
0.796
0.769
Figure 5 shows annual means of technical efficiency scores of the pre-transition countries
over the 1970-1989 period.
Figure 5: Mean Technical Efficiency Levels in Soviet Union Economies
Technical efficiency:1970-1989
0.88
0.86
0.84
TE
0.82
Seri 1
0.8
0.78
0.76
0.74
0.72
1965
1970
1975 year 1980
1985
1990
103
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Technical efficiency change, technological change and total factor productivity change
for the Former Soviet economies
The second column of Table 4 gives the mean technical efficiency changes in the pretransition period with respect to countries. Over the whole period mean technical
efficiency change score is 0.992 indicating that the economies fell further behind the bestpractice frontier. However, the positive efficiency change occurred for some years, such as
1974, 1979, 1980, and 1988.
Table 4: Annual means of technical efficiency change, technological change and total
factor productivity change in the Soviet Union economies, 1970-1989
Year
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
mean
Mean
Mean technical
Mean
efficiency
technological
total factor
change
change
productivity change
0.976
1.031
1.006
0.984
0.999
0.983
0.991
1.014
1.005
1.010
0.995
1.005
0.970
1,027
0.995
0.996
1.008
1.004
0.998
0.989
0.986
0.994
1.006
1.000
1.009
0.986
0.996
1.006
0.990
0.996
0.967
1.031
0.997
1.008
0.990
0.997
0.989
1.014
1.003
0.993
0.997
0.990
0.993
0.981
0.974
0.985
1.001
0.986
0.952
0.998
0.941
1.080
0.997
1.077
0.959
1.050
1.008
0.992
1.005
0.997
Note: For each year, the change given is that over the previous year (e.g. 1971 gives the
change over 1970-1971).
Figure 6 presents mean technical efficiency change of the FSU countries over the 19701989 period. In this period, technical efficiency change fluctuated and decreased on
average.
104
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Figure 6: Mean technical efficiency change for the Soviet Union economies
Technical efficiency change:1970-1098
1.1
1.08
TEFCH
1.06
1.04
Seri 1
1.02
1
0.98
0.96
0.94
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
year
The third column of Table 4 presents mean technological change indices of the FSU
economies in the study period. The average annual technological change was 1.005. That
is, this period had a technical progress, on average. However, some years negative
technological changes were recorded. The mean of technological change is presented by
Figure 7.
Figure 7: Mean technical change for the Soviet Union economies
Technological change:1970-1989
1.06
1.05
TECH
1.04
1.03
1.02
1.01
mean
1
0.99
0.98
0.97
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
year
Table 4 also presents the mean of total factor productivity change over the 1970-1989
period. The mean of TFP change was 0.997, which can be decomposed into technical
efficiency change of 0.992 and technological change of 1.005. The mean TFP change
index indicates that the Soviet Union economies experienced a negative factor productivity
growth due to the declining technical efficiency level over the entire sample period. In this
105
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
period, the technological progress was offset by a declining technical efficiency, so that the
TFP growth of -0.03 percent per annum was measured.
Figure 8 presents the TFP growth scores of the FSU economies over the period 1970-1989.
It is seen that the TFP growth almost smoothly moved from 1970s until the mid of 1985s,
but then it dropped in 1987 and sharply increased due to technical efficiency increase in
1988 and technological progress in 1989.
Figure 8: Mean total factor productivity growth for the Soviet Union economies
Total factor productivity change:1970-1989
1.1
1.08
TFPCH
1.06
1.04
1.02
1
Seri 1
0.98
0.96
0.94
0.92
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
year
Conclusion
I calculated Malmqüist total factor productivity indices for the 15 transition economies
over the 1991-2005 period and the Soviet Union economies (after 1991 they are called
transition economies) over the 1970-1989 period using the DEA methods.
According to findings of the study, the transition to the market economy reduced
inefficiency in the formerly planned economies. These economies have an increasing
efficiency level over the transition period, on average. On the other hand these countries
have suffered from technical regress and the overall result has been an average total factor
productivity decline.
In the Soviet Union, while the countries had a technological progress, on average, they
had a declining efficiency level in the 1970-1989 period. In both periods, the TFP growth
is negative. The negative TFP growth in transition period can be explained by technical
regress while the negative TFP growth in the pre-transition period can be explained by a
declining technical efficiency level.
106
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
References
Angeriz A., J.McCombie and M.Roberts. 2006. “Productivity, Efficiency and
Technological Change in European Union Regional Manufacturing: A Data Envelopment
Analysis Approach”, The Manchester School Vol 74, No.4, Special Issue 1463-6785 500525.
Case K.E. and R.C. Fair. 2004. Principles of Economics, Seventh Edition, USA.
Caves, D.; L. Christensen; and W. E. Diewert. 1982. “The Economic Theory of Index
Numbers and the Measurement of Input, Output and Productivity.” Econometrica 50, no.
6: 1393- 1414.
Charnes, A.; W.W. Cooper, A.Y. Lewin; and L.M. Seiford. 1995. Data Envelopment
Analsis: Theory, Methodology and Applications. Boston: Kluwer.
Coelli, T.J.; D.S.P. Rao; and G.E. Battase. 1998. An Introduction to Efficiency and
Productivity Analysis. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Coelli T.J. (1996) A guide to DEAP version 2.1: A data envelopment analysis (computer)
program, CEPA Working Papers 96/08, Australia.
Delikta E. 2002. “Türkiye Özel Sektör Đmalat Sanayinde Etkinlik ve Toplam Faktör
Verimliliği Analizi” METU Development Studies, Vol 29, No.3-4, pp.247-284.
Delikta E. and M. Balcilar. 2005. “ A Comparative analysis of Productivity Growth,
Catch-up and Convergence in Transition Economies”, Emerging Markets Finance and
Trade, Vol 41, No.1, pp. 6-28, January-February.
Delikta E. and S.Emsen, 2002. “The Evaluation of Privatization Process in
Kyrgyzstan:1991-2001”, International Science conference in Modern Societies, Osh State
University, 17-18 July, Osh, Kyrgyzstan.
Delikta E. .M.Ersungur and M.Candemir. 2005. “The Comparison of Agricultural
Efficiecy and Productivity Growth in the EU and Turkey:1980-2002”, International
Journal of Business Management and Economics, Vol 1. No.1, pp.109-124, Ya ar
University, Đzmir.
Estrin, Soul (1996), “Privatization in Central and Eastern Europe”, CERT (Central for
Economic Reform and Transformation), March, pp: 1-36.
Färe, R.S.G.; M. Norris; and Z. Zhang. 1994. “Productivity Growth, Technical Progress
and Efficiency Changes in Industrial Countries.” American Economic Review, no. 84:
66-83.
Farrel, M. J. (1957) The measurement of productive efficiency, Journal of Royal Statistical
Society, Series A 120 (3), 253-82.
107
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Kim S. and Han G. (2001) A decomposition of total factor productivity growth in Korean
manufacturing industries: A Stochastic Frontier Approach, Journal of Productivity
Analysis 16, 269-81.
Lipton, D., and Sachs, J., “Creating a Market Economy in Eastern Europe: The Case of
Poland”, Brookings Papers on Economics Activity, 1990.
Milan J.A. and Aldaz N. (2001) Efficiency and technical change in a panel DEA
framework, VII European workshop on efficiency and productivity analysis.
Nishimuzi, M., and J.M. Page. 1982. “Total Factor Productivity Growth, Technical
Progress and Technical Efficiency Change: Dimensions on Productivity Change in
Yugoslavia 1965-72.” Economic Journal 92, no.368: 920-936.
Osiewalski, J.; G. Koop; and M.F.J. Steel. 1998. “A Stochastic Frontier Analysis of Output
Level and Growth in Poland and Western Economies.” Center for Economic Research
Working Paper No. 9785, Tilburg University, Tilburg.
Rao, D.; S. Prasada; and T.J. Coelli. 1998a. “Catch-Up and Convergence in Global
Agricultural Productivity 1980-1995.” Centre for Efficiency and Productivity Analysis
Working Paper No. 4/98, University of New England, Armidale.
Seiford L.M. (1996) Data envelopment analysis: The evolution of the state of the art (1978
1995), Journal of Productivity Analysis 7, 99-138
Singh S., Coelli T., and Fleming E. (2000) Performance of dairy plants in the cooperative
and private sectors in India, CEPA Working Papers 2/2000, Australia.
Taskin, F. and O. Zaim. 1997. “Catching-up Innovation in High and Low IncomeCountries.” Economic Letters 54, no. 1, 93-100.
World Development Indicators, 2006.
108
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Capital Flows and the Non-Tradables in the Turkish Economy after
Capital Account Liberalization
F. Kemal Kızılca
Ankara University, Turkey
Abstract
This paper investigates the relationship between capital flows and the share of the nontradables sector in the Turkish economy after capital account liberalization. Findings
support a lagged, yet positive effect of capital flows on the share of non-tradables, which
brings the economy more vulnerable to the risk of reversal of capital inflows. This
underline the importance of a regulation controlling foreign currency denominated
borrowings of private sector firms with limited export earnings and elimination of
excessive official reserve accumulation which acts as an implicit bailout guarantee.
109
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Introduction
Most of the developing countries liberalized their capital accounts in the 1990s.
Liberalization has led to an increase both in the volume and the volatility of international
capital flows1. Capital surplus of developing countries fluctuated between US$200.1
billion and US$12.9 billion from 1996 to 2002; and increased up to US$82.9 billion in
2003 (UNCTAD, 2004: 58). Net capital flows to Turkey have also increased significantly
since the capital account liberalization in 1989. In 2005, the capital surplus of Turkey
reached US$ 44 billion approximately, while it was only US$ 780 million in 1989.
According to the official statistics, as of the third quarter of 2007, the total foreign debt
stock of Turkey is $247 billion (approx. 50% of the annual GDP), 18% of which is shortterm2.
Since the outbreak of the East Asian financial crisis in 1997, the destabilizing effects of
volatility of capital flows on developing countries gained central interest in
macroeconomics literature. In their seminal paper, Prasad et al. (2003:41) argue that “…,
the increase in the 1990s of the volatility of consumption relative to that of income for the
MFI [more financially integrated] economies suggests that financial integration has not
provided better consumption smoothing opportunities for these economies.” In the same
vein, Radelet et al. (1998:71) state “…that international financial markets are inherently
unstable, at least for developing countries borrowing heavily from abroad at short
maturities and in foreign currency”. They also stress that there is no evidence suggesting
increased financial integration stimulates higher growth in developing countries.
After the Asian crisis, various studies examined the relations among the pro-cyclical
behavior of bank credits, price bubbles in the real estate markets and banking crises.
Herring and Watchter (1999) and Hilbers et al. (2001) show that in economies where
banks own a bigger portion of total assets, an increase in real estate prices may start creditasset price bubble spirals. Similarly, a fall in real estate prices may cause a financial sector
distress through reducing the value of bank capital. Collyns and Senhadji (2002) analyze
how this spiral ended in with a crisis in Asian countries. Tornell et al. (2003), on the other
hand, suggest that growth in the relative share of the non-tradables as a whole during
capital inflows is one of the important factors causing financial crises in developing
economies; while they still favor capital account liberalization on the grounds that despite
the crises, long-term average growth rates in these countries are still higher than the preliberalization period.
Without dwelling on the issue of long-term growth effects of international capital flows,
this paper investigates the real locative effects of foreign credit between tradable and nontradable sectors (T - and N - sectors henceforth, respectively) in the Turkish economy after
the capital account liberalization. Three other studies touched upon the same issue:
Yenturk (1999), Çimenoğlu and Yenturk (2005) and Çiftçioğlu (2005) suggest that there is
a rising trend of the share of the N-sector investments since the capital account
liberalization in Turkey. However, because of the limitations of the dataset used, no
statistical analysis was carried in those studies. This paper seeks to contribute to the
literature by measuring the scope of the effect of capital flows on the size of the N-sector
1
For detailed statistics on capital account liberalization by IMF-member countries, see IMF (2006). For a
further discussion on instability and volatility of capital flows see Gabriele et al. (2000).
2
All the data used in this paper is available at the website of Central Bank Republic of Turkey
(www.tcmb.gov.tr) and International Financial Statistics of IMF.
110
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
production in the Turkish case. It is shown that, in the post-liberalization period, capital
inflows stimulated higher growth rate of the N-sector relative to the GDP.
The next section identifies the channels through which capital flows affect T- and Nsectors asymmetrically. The third section depicts how capital flows affected growth and
the share of the N-sector in GDP after liberalization in the Turkish economy. Section (iv)
provides estimation results. The last section concludes.
Asymmetric Effects of Foreign Capital Flows on Output in Developing Economies
Capital inflows and outflows to a small and open economy affect output asymmetrically.
FitzGerald (2000) shows that depressing effects of capital outflows on output dominate the
growth effect of inflows in developing countries. Fixed capital formation stimulated by a
foreign credit is irreversible; therefore, any adjustment in course of an outflow should be
carried through the working capital of firms, which causes output to shrink.
There is also another asymmetry arising from different financing opportunities of T- and
N-sector firms. Pledging export earnings as collateral, the T-sector firms can access to
external finance while N-sector firms are constrained by the volume of domestic credit. An
increase in capital account surplus, therefore, mostly benefits N-sector firms by removing
limits on the volume of credit in the banking sector (Tornell and Westermann, 2003).
Using a dataset from 35 countries for 1980-1999 period, Tornell et al. (2003) show that
foreign credit growth causes N-sector output to grow relatively faster than T-sector in
developing countries, an effect which puts them more prone to self-fulfilling crises.
The asymmetry between the financing opportunities of N- and T-sectors is not the only
mechanism for N-sector to grow faster during capital inflows. Sachs and Larraín (1993)
show that because output is limited by domestic production in N-sector by definition, an
increase in aggregate demand caused by a foreign credit expansion shifts production away
from T-sector, for which demand can be met by imports. On the other hand, using the data
from the Bangladesh economy Hossain (1999) asserts that, because N-sector mostly
consists of services for which income elasticity of demand is high, growth stimulated by a
credit expansion causes the share of N-sector in GDP to increase.
Real exchange rate appreciation caused by the increased demand for N-sector produces a
deterioration in the balance of payments, which is considered to be a key factor in making
of financial crises. The irreversibility of investments during a capital outflow intensifies
the effect of such a crisis on N-sector. This exacerbates the social cost of crises considering
the labor-intensive nature of N-sector, which consists mostly of services.
Capital Flows and the Share of the N-Sector in the Turkish Economy
Like many other developing countries, there has been a strong correlation between the
capital flows and growth in the Turkish economy, historically. This correlation has even
become stronger with the growing integration with the world economy and increasing size
of the capital flows since the 1990’s. Boratav and Yeldan (2001:9) state that prior to the
capital account liberalization, foreign capital was used to finance the current account
deficit, which was mainly determined by the growth rate of the GDP. However, after the
capital account liberalization this linkage has been reversed with capital inflows
determining the size of the domestic demand, hence, current account deficits. Two
111
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
important consequences of this reversal are the broken link between current and capital
accounts, resulting with excessive reserve accumulation, and the increase in the volatility
of the growth rate. In the post-liberalization period, three major crises hit the Turkish
economy; each being preceded by net capital outflows (fig. 1).
Figure 1: Foreign capital flows and growth
0.15
25000
20000
0.1
15000
0.05
10000
1
1
1
20
07
Q
20
06
Q
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
20
05
Q
20
04
Q
20
03
Q
20
02
Q
20
01
Q
20
00
Q
19
99
Q
19
98
Q
19
97
Q
19
96
Q
19
95
Q
19
94
Q
19
93
Q
19
92
Q
19
91
Q
19
90
Q
1
5000
19
89
Q
19
88
Q
1
0
0
-0.05
-5000
-0.1
-10000
-0.15
-15000
GDP Growth (left scale)
Capital Account Balance (million $ US, right scale)
As pointed in the previous section, capital flows affect real exchange rates mainly through
two channels: On the real side, inflows may increase the demand for goods and services
produced in the N- sector as Sachs and Larraín (1993) point out. The increased demand
raises the N-sector good prices, where the T-sector prices are determined in the world
markets. On the financial side, inflows may lead to an appreciation through increasing the
supply of foreign currency. This appreciation affects the size of the N-sector depending on
the price elasticity. With the income effect being constant, the N-sector is expected to grow
with appreciation provided that the elasticity is less than unity. In the opposite case, the net
effect will depend on the relative importance of demand and price effects of capital flows.
Figure 2 plots the capital flows and real exchange rates in the Turkish economy since the
first quarter of 1988. Agénor et al. (1997) and Çimenoğlu and Yentürk (2005) suggest that
there is a causality relation between the two, where the former affects the latter3. On the
other hand, Agénor et al. (1997) emphasize the importance of a third factor, namely the
fiscal policy changes, determining both the size of the capital flows and private domestic
absorption, which affects the relative price of non-traded goods.
3
See also Ulengin and Yentürk (2001) and Celasun et al. (1999) for a concise evaluation of the effects of
capital flows on the Turkish economy.
112
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Figure 2: Foreign capital inflows and real exchange rates
200
25000
180
20000
160
15000
140
10000
120
100
5000
80
0
60
-5000
40
-10000
20
Real Exchange Rates (Left Scale, 1995=100)
1
1
20
07
Q
Q
1
06
20
05
20
04
Q
Q
20
03
Q
1
1
1
Q
20
02
20
20
01
Q
Q
1
1
1
00
20
99
19
98
Q
Q
1
1
Q
19
97
19
19
96
Q
Q
1
1
1
19
95
Q
1
94
19
93
19
92
Q
Q
1
1
Q
19
19
91
Q
1
Q
90
19
Q
89
19
88
19
1
-15000
1
0
Net Capital Inflows (million $ US, right scale)
There are few previous studies, which provide some descriptive data on the positive effect
of capital flows on the share of the N-sector in GDP in the Turkish economy. Using the
annual investment data published by the State Planning Organization (SPO), Yenturk
(1999) and Çimenoğlu and Yenturk (2005) explain the growth in the share of N-sector
investments as an outcome of increased profitability of this sector following exchange rate
appreciation after the capital account liberalization. Çiftçioğlu (2005), on the other hand,
emphasize the demand-increasing effects of capital inflows for the N-sector, which causes
exchange rate appreciation. Tornell et al. (2003) provide some econometric evidence in
their multi-country panel regressions; however, they do not provide cross sectional results.
The definition of the N-sector in their analysis includes the construction industry only,
which is quite restrictive.
Data and Results
In this section, the extent of the effect of the capital flows on the relative size of the Nsector in Turkey is investigated. The N-sector is defined as the sum of production in
construction, wholesale and retail, ownership of dwellings, and professions and services
activities. The share of these activities in GDP fluctuated between 25% and 35% in
1987Q1 – 2007Q3 period. Because the data shows high level of seasonality, it is used in
the forth-differenced form. The changes in capital flows and the share of the N-sector in
GDP from the previous year values are plotted in Figure 3. The figure implies a lagged
effect of capital flows on the N-sector: the peak values of the change in the N-sector share
follow the changes in capital flows after 3 to 6 quarters.
113
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Figure 3: Foreign credit growth and the share of the N-Sector in GDP
0.06
20000
0.04
15000
0.02
10000
19
88
Q
1
19
89
Q
1
19
90
Q
1
19
91
Q
1
19
92
Q
1
19
93
Q
1
19
94
Q
1
19
95
Q
1
19
96
Q
1
19
97
Q
1
19
98
Q
1
19
99
Q
1
20
00
Q
1
20
01
Q
1
20
02
Q
1
20
03
Q
1
20
04
Q
1
20
05
Q
1
20
06
Q
1
20
07
Q
1
0
5000
-0.02
0
-0.04
-5000
-0.06
-10000
-0.08
-0.1
-15000
Change in the share of the N-sector (left scale)
Change in net capital inflows (million $ US, right scale)
Following the literature on the well-known “St. Louis equation” I investigate the real effect
of monetary aggregates (capital flows) on real variables (the change in the relative size of
the N-sector) in an Almon-lag framework. Before performing the regression analysis two
separate unit root tests were performed. Table 1 shows that both the change in net capital
inflows (DIFINANCE) and the change in the size of the N-sector (DIFNT) from the
previous year values are stationary.
Table 1: Unit root tests
ADF
Phillips-Perron
Variable
Lag
length
Test
statistic
Prob.
value
Bandwidth
Test
statistic
Prob.
value
DIFINANCE
DIFNT
3
4
-5.9965
-2.9029
0.0000
0.0498
4
5
-6.5473
-6.2809
0.0000
0.0000
Table 2 reports the Almon-lag estimation results4. The appropriate lag of DIFINANCE
(11) was decided using Akaike Information Criteria values (AICs) based on ad hoc
estimations5. It was necessary to include autoregressive (AR(.)) and moving average terms
(MA(.)) to overcome the serial correlation problem. Thus, the model estimated here is an
ARMAX with X values being the polynomial distributed lags of DIFNT. Results with third
and second order polynomials are reported in the table. Both estimations produce similar
4
Eviews 5.0 is used in estimations.
The diagnostic values reported in Table 1 were obtained from the transformed coefficients of Almon-lag
estimations.
5
114
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
results but the adjusted-R2 and AIC values favor the third order one. The LM tests for serial
correlation up to 12 lags (Table 3) indicate that there is no problem of autocorrelation in
the residuals.
Table 2: The Effects Capital Flows on the Size of the N-Sector
ALMON-LAG ESTIMATIONS
Estimations with a
second order polynomial
Estimations with a
third order polynomial
Variable
Coefficient
t-statistic
Coefficient
t-statistic
C
-0.00140
-8.907
-0.00126
-7.272
AR(1)
0.24722
2.457
0.22645
2.59889
MA(4)
-1.38689
-66.559
-1.36088
-69.023
MA(12)
0.41412
21.917
0.39307
23.374
0
-0.00041
-1.196
-0.00081
-1.627
1
-0.00017
-0.902
-0.00019
-1.146
2
0.00003
0.420
0.00021
1.715
3
0.00020
2.870
0.00044
2.167
4
0.00033
2.815
0.00054
2.475
5
0.00043
2.919
0.00053
3.060
6
0.00049
3.303
0.00047
4.314
7
0.00051
4.149
0.00040
4.432
8
0.00050
5.517
0.00034
2.480
9
0.00045
3.859
0.00035
1.920
10
0.00036
1.617
0.00046
2.248
11
0.00024
0.633
0.00071
2.724
Sum of lagged
effects
0.00295
5.018
0.00346
6.315
Lags:
R^2
0.7121
0.7303
Adj. R^2
0.6833
0.6983
AIC
-6.6901
-6.7255
F-Stat
24.7309
22.8204
Prob (F-stat)
0.0000
0.0000
115
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 3: Diagnostic tests
LM Tests for serial correlation
1st estimation
Lag 1
Lag 2
Lag 3
Lag 4
Lag 5
Lag 6
Lag 7
Lag 8
Lag 9
Lag 10
Lag 11
Lag 12
2nd estimation
F-Statistic
Probability
F-Statistic
Probability
0.0113
0.1390
0.6757
0.5173
0.8503
0.9650
1.0790
0.9422
0.8361
0.9066
0.8179
0.7545
0.9157
0.8705
0.5705
0.7233
0.5203
0.4577
0.3898
0.4906
0.5866
0.5344
0.6226
0.6920
0.0691
0.1149
0.3967
0.3338
0.7754
0.6524
0.7371
0.6493
0.6028
0.7559
0.7244
0.6519
0.7936
0.8917
0.7559
0.8540
0.5717
0.6880
0.6416
0.7326
0.7886
0.6692
0.7097
0.7868
The DIFNT data used in estimations are in billion US dollars. Thus, findings imply that a
USD 10 billion increase in the capital account balance has a cumulative growth effect on
the share of N-sector in GDP from 3 to 3.5 %.
Conclusions
This paper examined the effects of foreign capital inflows on the share of the non-tradables
production in the Turkish economy since the capital account liberalization. I employed
Almon-lag estimation procedures to account for the lagged nature of the effects of the
credit increases on the real side of the economy. The findings indicate that there is a
significant impact of capital flows on the size of the N-sector: a billion dollar change in the
capital flows has a distributed affect on the size of the N-sector around 0.35 percent in 11
quarters. This brings us to the conclusion that the continuous growth in the relative size of
the N-sector prior to the 2001 crisis and since the fourth quarter of 2003 (see figure 3) can
largely be explained by the excessive capital inflows.
If the T-sector firms need the N-sector inputs for production, as suggested by many
authors, what are the risks brought by this N-sector-led growth? The legal regulations
following the currency crisis of 2001 limited the short-positions to be maintained by the
banks to 20 percent of the balance sheet total. However, there is no regulation limiting the
international borrowings of commercial firms without foreign dominated assets. Findings
in this study indicate that, since the capital account liberalization foreign capital flows to
the Turkish economy have been mostly directed to the N-sector firms whose assets are
domestic currency denominated. As also suggested by Özmen and Yalçın (2007), the
liability dollarization in Turkish corporate sector remains as an important source of
fragility against financial shocks. This underlines the importance of legal regulations on
and monitoring of foreign borrowings of the corporate sector.
116
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
An important factor encouraging foreign creditors to take the risk of lending to the Nsector is excessive official reserve accumulation of the central bank, which acts as an
implicit bailout guarantee. As of July 2007 the volume of the official reserves of the central
bank reached up to $ 69 billion, which corresponds approximately 18 percent of the GDP.
In addition to the cost of holding excessive reserves, this policy stimulates foreign credit to
be directed to the firms without foreign exchange revenues, which puts a limit to the
exports potential of the economy in the long run.
117
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
References
Agénor, P., J. McDermott and E. M. Ucer (1997): “Fiscal Imbalances, Capital Inflows and
the Real Exchange Rate: The Case of Turkey”, IMF Working Paper, 97/1.
Boratav, K. and E. Yeldan (2001): “Turkey, 1980-2000: Financial Liberalization,
mimeo,
Macroeconomic
(In)-Stability,
and
Patterns
of
Distribution”,
http://bilkent.edu.tr/~yeldane
Celasun, O., C. Denizer and Dong He (1999): “Capital Flows, Macroeconomic
Management, and the Financial System”, World Bank Policy Research Paper, no: 2141.
Collyns, C. and A. Senhadji (2002): “Lending Booms, Real Estate Bubbles and the Asian
Crisis”, IMF Working Paper, WP/02/20.
Çiftçioğlu, S. (2005): “Growth, Traded Goods and External Debt Before and after Capital
Account Liberalization: Case of Turkey”, Economicky Casopis, 53 (8), 834-848.
Çimenoğlu, A. and N. Yentürk (2005): “Effects of International Capital Inflows on the
Turkish Economy”, Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, 41(1), 90-109.
FitzGerald E.V.K. (2000): “Short-Term Capital Flows, The Real Economy And Income
Distribution In Developing Countries”, in Short Term Capital Flows and Economic Crises,
Stephany Griffith-Jones, Manuel F. Montes and Anwar Nasution (Eds.), Oxford University
Press.
Gabriele, A., K. Boratav and A. Parikh (2000): “Instability and Volatility of Capital Flows
to Developing Countries”, The World Economy, 23(8), 1031 – 56.
Herring, R. and S. Wachter (1999): “Real Estate Booms and Banking Busts: An
International Perspective”, Wharton School Working Papers, 99-27.
Hilbers, P. , Q. Lei and L. Zacho (2001): “Real Estate Developments and Financial Sector
Soundness”, IMF Working Paper, WP/01/129.
Hossain, A. (2000), Exchange Rates, capital flows and International trade: the Case of
Bangladesh, Dhaka, University press Limited.
Özmen, E. and C. Yalçın (2007): “Küresel ve Finansal Riskler Kar ısında Türkiye’de Reel
Sektör Finansal Yapısı ve Borç Dolarizasyonu”, CBRT Working Papers, 07/06.
Prasad, E., K. Rogoff, W. Shang-Jin and M.A. Kose (2003): “Effects of Financial
Globalization on Developing Countries: Some Empirical Evidence”, IMF.
Sachs, J. and Larraín (1993), Macroeconomics in the Global Economy, Prentice Hall,
Englewood Cliffs, NJ.
Tornell, A. and F. Westermann (2003): “Credit market imperfections in middle income
countries”, NBER Working Paper Series, May 2003.
118
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
________ and L. Martinez (2003): “Liberalization, Growth and Financial Crisis: Lessons
From Mexico and the Developing World”, Brooking Papers on Economic Activity, 2, s. 1112.
Ulengin, B. and N. Yentürk (2001): “Impacts of Capital Inflows on Aggregate Spending
Categories: The Case of Turkey”, Applied Economics, 33, 1321-1328.
UNCTAD (2004): Trade and Development Report, Geneva.
Yentürk, N. (1999): “Short Term Capital Inflows and Their Impact on Macroeconomic
Structure: Turkey in the 1990s”, The Developing Economies, XXXVII (1), 89-113.
119
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
The Analysis of the Romanian Business Environment in the Context of
the Adherence to the European Union
Pop Fanuta
Babes-Bolyai University Cluj-Napoca, Romania
Achim Monica
Babes-Bolyai University Cluj-Napoca, Romania
Abstract
Performance is a state of competitivity that ensures the maintenance and the development
on the market, where everybody attempts to reach the first place. Each enterprise will take
advantage from the business environment, and in order to get one step ahead the others it
will „invent” new methods of winning the competition, since nowadays performance has
got larger valencies (global performance or lasting development). This paper tries to assess
the Romanian business environment on sectors of activity, especially in the year 2007,
when Romania has become a member of the European Union and to make comparisons
between the Romanian business environment and that of other countries. We believe that a
valid analysis of the business environment is very important as it helps the enterprises to be
aware of the direction they are heading and contributes to pointing out the favourable
factors it should develop, the ones that give them a competitional advantage, but also the
factors that have a bad influence. Moreover, we try to present the strengths and the
weaknesses, the opportunities and the drawbacks of the Romanian business environment.
120
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Introduction
In a world of competition, that has become increasingly dynamic, as a result of changes
within the financial environment and of the increase of risk once with the economicalfinancial disturbances and the globalization of money and capital exchange, the
achievement of „excellence” in business represents the only way of survival and
development of enterprises in a competitive economy. One of the ways to achieve
excellence is performance, thus more people speak today of global performance. This new
approach upon performance is currently known as lasting development, which has three
objectives: the increase of economic-financial performance of the company, the
development of the efficiency of the surrounding environment and the stimulation of social
development. Therefore, we can say that global performance represents the sum of
economic-financial, ecology and social performances.
In the present conditions of the globalization of world economy, an enterprise is
performant if „it creates added value for its shareholders, satisfies the clients demand, takes
into account the opinion of employees and protects the surrounding environment. Thus,
shareholders are satisfied because the enterprise has reached the target of rentability,
clients trust in the future of the enterprise or the quality of its products and services,
employees are proud of the company they work in, and the society benefits, through the
policy adopted by the enterprise, of the protection of the surrounding environment.”1
To meet these objectives, we consider that the analysis of the business environment in
which the enterprise develops its activity has a great importance, especially in the present
conditions when performance has much exceeded the borders of traditional approach
which used to take into account only the economic-financial objectives, because the factors
that influence the business environment, the advantages or restrictions it presents, can
facilitate or stop the achievement of global performance. On the other hand, it is not at all
surprising the fact that the environment in which the enterprise develops its activity is not
organized to respond to its vision and interests but, on the contrary, many components of
the environment can be opposite so that the enterprise is the one that has to permanently
adapt to environment changes, and adaptation implies firstly knowledge and information.
The business environment is a sum of factors that affect the capacity if the enterprise to
develop and maintain successful transactions with its partners. Romania’s adherence and
integration in the European structures has had, still has and will further have a major
impact upon the local business environment. In these conditions, we are going to speak not
only about the Romanian business environment, but also about the European business
environment in which, once with the elimination of borders, many changes will take place
regarding the national enterprises and the national economy, in general.
In what concerns the history of the economic and social-political of Romania along the last
decade, the most important step made by our country has been the adherence to the
European Union, a reality which offers both possibilities of development and some
aspects that could stop this process.
1
Jianu Iulia, „The performance – a notion which looking for define . Ambiguity and clarity”, Accounting,
Expertise and Business Audit Review, no. 5/2006, Bucharest, pag. 18.
121
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
The history of Romania’s integration in the European economic block began in1995, when
the European Council required the Commission to present its point of view regarding
Romania’s adherence to the European Union, after that on the 22nd of July it had handed
the official request of adherence. In accordance to this desideratum, on the 15th of July
1997 was born the so-called community “aquis2”, that made rough critics to Romania’s
request of adherence. The final decision was based on the criteria from Copenhagen, by
which it was admitted the fact that Romania had passed through an important development
regarding the achievement of political conditions, but also remarked that on mean time
period (not even speaking of the short term situation) the country faces great problems with
economic competitivity and reaching the European competitive level. The biggest concern
to that moment was the fact that judicial homogenization was not even a priority to our
country, while on the structural plan, not even the most elementary legislation was
adopted.
Starting with 1998 the Commission has yearly elaborated a “monitoring” report. The first
such report admitted the fact that the first criterion from Copenhagen, namely political
stability, was achieved, but Romania was still steady with national economy and its
competitivity worsened. In 1999 social problems regarding the protection of the underaged were discussed, together with the issue of discrimination against gypsies. However,
the general economic situation still recorded no improvements, but there was considerable
progress in taking the community aquis.
In spite of major economic problems, the European Union has proposed the Commission to
start negotiations and talks regarding Romania’s adherence. The focus point of the official
discussions on this purpose was chosen on the15th February 2000, this fact being
mentioned in an addendum to the report of the Helsinki Meeting from December 1999.
Also, on the same date, there began talks with Slovakia, Latvia, Lithuania and Malta,
countries that managed to meet the requirements of the European Union 3 years earlier
than Romania.
Parallel to preparations for the start of negotiations, our country has developed a sustained
effort to shape an economic strategy in the mean term. This strategy, sustained by a
political statement of support made by the entire political, social and economic spectrum in
Romania, was presented to the European Commission on the 20th of March 2000. On May
30, 2000 it was approved and transmitted to the European Commission the plan of action
so that the strategy objectives be put into practice. The strategy regards the rigorous
assessment of the social costs of transition and promotion of reform, as well as of the
adherence to the European Union, ensuring the necessary financial and legal support.
Moreover, one of the objectives of the strategy was to create a favourable business
environment, based on a coherent and stable legislation framework able to ensure the
development of market economy, the reduction of transition costs and of fiscal burden; to
promote specific measures to stimulate the small and mean enterprises; to define clearly
property laws, ensure adequate management and judicial structures, able to ensure the
application of law and the respecting of contract obligations.
From 2000 the country reports elaborated by the European Commission already describe
an economic and social-political situation about to improve, pointing out the progress in
the social plan regarding the situation of minorities and harmonization of legislation, and
2
The official opinion of the European Union, represented by the European Comission.
122
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
in 2004 Romania was given the status of functional market economy – the last criterion
that had to be met. Therefore, talks with the purpose of adherence were closed on
December 14, 2004. Criteria from Copenhagen were achieved with some exceptions; in the
case of eight domains Romania required and received departing from the achievement of
the expectancies of the Union. These domains were the free circulation of services and
capital, legislation regarding economic competition, agriculture, transports, the problem of
taxes, the energy policy, the protection of environment. The chapter with the most difficult
issues was that concerning the competitional policy and those from the domain of internal
and judicial policy.
In 2002 was set the date of adherence, on January 1, 2007. Although 2007 was already
fixed as the time of the adherence, there also arouse the certainty of great sacrifices from
Romania in the time left. With this purpose, in the treaty of adherence, as final disposition,
it was mentioned the fact that if the country would not meet until the moment of the
adherence all the objectives it had agreed with, the date could still be changed to the 1st of
January 2008.
25 aprilie 2005 was the date when Romania together with Bulgaria signed the treaty of
adherence to the European Union. In the context of this treaty the two countries could
achieve the status of member with full rights starting with the 1st of January 2007.
Romania had waited for 12 for the de jure adherence to take place. We say de jure because
in what concerns the commerce and the partnership between Romania and the European
block the de facto integration had taken place previously. The failure of the CAER brought
a rapid – but not sudden – reorientation of the Romanian commerce towards the European
Union, a phenomenon specific to all the other countries from Central and Eastern Europe.
By the end of 1999, more than 65% of Romania’s exports headed to the European Union,
while imports coming from the European Union reached a percentage of 60%. The
European Union-15 represented in 2001 59,6% of the commercial fluxes of Romania. The
figures can be compared with the amount of inter-European commerce of many of the
states of the European Union. We can say that at least from the commercial point of view –
with the exception of certain tax barriers for agriculture and of some industrial sectors
protected by the European Union – Romania integrated de facto within the community
commerce right before 2007.
The year 2007 marks the passage from the phase of acquiring of acquis to the phase of
generation of acquis and construction of the political Union. The fact that Romania has
adhered to the UE in 2007 left few time to companies to prepare, in case they have not yet
done that. The business environment becomes more competitive, and Romanian companies
have to compete with firms renown in Europe.
After 2007, the activity of firms from Romania has to be licensed on the market according
to the European standards of competitivity. The activity of companies has to be assessed
by informatised systems (in present there are SAP and SIVECO, but there will also be
introduced another American system). There is some danger – not very imminent however
– that the Romanian economy not be able to meet the European technological standards.
Romania is now in the centre of attention for the European Union from two main reasons.
Firstly, it is one of the countries that recently adhered and even if it was supposed from the
previous time to prove stability and economic growth, bow it is even more supposed to do
that, and it must compare its strengths and achievements “with the members of a select
123
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
club”.3 Secondly, Romania is part of a courageous project4 of the European Union in what
regards the development in the Black Sea area. This project has a great importance among
the objectives of the development policy of our country. One of these objectives is the
strengthening of collaboration within the Organization of Economic Cooperation of the
Black Sea for the development and effective application of projects already agreed upon
(energy, financial and bank system, transport, tourism), with the view to update its
activities to the priorities of national economy and the interests of groups of Romanian
businessmen.
From these reasons, the development of economic competition and of services in Romania
is both the goal of our country and of the European Union, while in the opposite case their
plans could be slowed down or even stopped.
One year after the integration in the European Union, due to reforms from the sector of
credits and tax payment, Romania holds the 48th place from 176, in the classification of
states with the most favourable business environment, according to the annual report
„Doing Business 2008”5 realized by the World Bank. This classification eas made in
accordance with a certain methodology, based on data from 10 domains regarding the
period April 2006-June 2007.
The classification made by the World Bank and the International Finance Corporation is
based on time and cost indicators meant to respect the requirements of public
administration about the setting of a business, the functioning, commercial activity,
fiscality and closing of the business. This classification does not concern variables such as
the macroeconomic policy or quality of infrastructure, the fluidity of currency, the
perception of investors or the rate of criminality.
According to this classification regarding the attractivity of the business environment,
Romania steps 7 positions compared to the previous year (from the 55th place), recording
significant progress only in two of 10 domains, after which the classification was realized,
namely: the easiness to contract credits (from 32 in 2006, to 13 in 2007) and the easiness
to close (liquidate) a business (from 109 to 81). It stepped one position from the previous
year in what concerns the domain of tax payment (from 135 to 134) and the domain of
transborder transactions (from 39 to 38). In exchange, regresses were recorded with the
results obtained in five of the most significant domains (less than 12 places from 2006) as
follows: the setting of a business (from 14 to 26), the staff employment (from 133 to 145),
the property recording (less than 11 places from 2006, from 112 to 123). At chapters
obtaining of licenses and protection of investors, there was also some regress, less
significant however (from 87 to 90, respectively from 32 to 33). In a single domain – the
contract application – Romania occupied the same position in both years (position 37).
3
Dragos Pîslaru, founding member of the Group of Applied Economy.
The initiative to institutionalize the interest for the Black Sea area manifested itself in 1992, when 11
surrounding states founded the Organization of Economic Cooperation at the Black Sea (BSEC), which set
as its objective the gradual integration of the region in the world economy, especially the European one. It
was firstly taken into consideration the potential of the market and the resources of the region. The European
Union did not define clearly a policy for the Black Sea area, but the example of the Euro-Mediterranian
partnership, or Finland’s attempts to cooperate in the Northern area suggest that there won’t be long until
such a policy is shaped.
5
http://www.doingbusiness.org/economyrankings/
4
124
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
If we take into account the classification for the area of Eastern Europe-Central Asia,
Romania stands, according to the same report, on the 9th place of the 28 countries, after
Estonia, Georgia, Latvia, Lithuania, Slovakia, Armenia, Hungary and Bulgaria, being
followed by Slovenia, Czech Republic, Turkey, Kazakhstan, Poland.
Within the region, Romania stands out by the attractivity of the business environment,
occupying the first 5 places at the following chapters: the easiness to contract a credit (2nd
place in the region), protection of investitors (3rd place), the easiness to start a business
(4th place), transborder transactions (5th place). Among the 28 economies of the region,
Romania stands in the middle of the classification at the following chapters: obtaining of
licenses (the11 th place), application of contracts (the 13th place) and closing (liquidation)
of a business (the 15th place). It is situated on the last places at 3 of the 10 chapters
according to which the classification was made, namely: tax payment (the 20th place), staff
employment and property record (the 26th place). The leader of the group that realized
this report, Simeon Djankov, pointed out the fact that states from Eastern Europe and the
former Soviet block surpassed the states of Eastern Asia in what concerns the attractivity
of the business environment, some of them even compared to states from Western Europe
(for example Estonia, Georgia, Latvia, Lithuania which are nowadays classified in front of
countries like Belgium, Germany, Austria or France).
A classification made by the Economist Intelligence Unit (EIU)6 forecasts that in 2008
Romania would stand on the 45th place with 5,46 points on a scale from 1 to 10. Thus,
Romania maintains the place obtained in 2007 when it got 5,32 points.
The classification was made on basis of data obtained at the level of economies from 70
states all over the world. To make the top there were taken into consideration 100
quantitative and qualitative variables organized into six distinct categories, feed into the
e-readiness rankings. The six categories (and their weight in the model) are7:
•
connectivity and technology infrastructure (20%);
•
business environment (15%); As in previous years, scoring model in 2008 makes use
of our existing Business Environment Rankings, which evaluates over 70 separate
indicators grouped in ten categories of criteria, such as political stability, macroeconomic
health and the country’s overall policy towards free enterprise. Utilizing these allows us to
assess each country’s ability to maintain a stable, secure and unfettered place to conduct
commerce in the manner in which it attracts and fosters (or repels and hinders) digital
commerce. The rankings for this category reflect our view of each country’s expected
performance in the five-year period of 2008-20128.
•
social and cultural environment (15%);
•
legal and policy environment (10%);
•
government policy and vision (15%);
consumer and business adoption (25%).
•
The data used in the rankings are sourced from the Economist Intelligence Unit, Pyramid
Research, the World Bank, the World Intellectual Property Organization and others.
6
http://www.eiuresources.com/mediadir/
www.eiu.com/sponsor/ibm/e-readinessrankings2008
8
„E-readiness rankings 2008. Maintaining momentum A white paper from the Economist Intelligence Unit”,
The Economist Written in co-operation with The IBM Institute for Business Value
7
125
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Qualitative criteria are assessed by the Economist Intelligence Unit’s extensive network of
country experts, and their assessments are reviewed by top economists.
In the classification on regions, most points (the first three places), for the region of
Central and Eastern Europe (see table no.1) were obtained by countries like: Estonia,
Slovenia, Czech Republic (these being the countries with most „nominations” for the first
three places), then Slovakia, Lithuania and Hungary, each with one „nominalization” for
the first three places in the categories the classification was made. In the following table
we present the situation of the top of countries from Central and Eastern Europe, on
categories of criteria and points.
Table 1: The situation of the classification of countries from the region of Central and
Eastern Europe in top 70
Connectivity
and
technology
infrastructure
(20%)
Business
environment
(15%)
Social and
cultural
environment
(15%)
Legal
environment
(10%)
Government
and
vision
(15%)
Consumer
and
business
adoption
(25%)
Overall
score
Place
2008/
2007
Estonia
Slovenia
Czech
Republic
Hungary
6,50 (*)
6.40 (**)
5.95 (***)
7,81 (*)
7.32
7.42 (**)
6,73
7.00 (*)
6.87 (**)
7,80 (*)
6.60
6.90 (***)
6,25 (*)
6.10 (**)
5.70 (***)
7,10
6.93
6.68
28/28
29/29
31/31
5.30
7.08
6.47
6.90
5.55
7,60 (**)
7.70 (*)
7.20
(***)
6.75
6.30
33/34
Slovakia
5.40
7.42 (***)
6.40 (***)
6.90
4.70
6.05
6.05
36/39
Latvia
Lithuania
Romania
5.60
5.00
4.70
7.10
7.09
6.57
6.20
6.33
5.47
6.90
7.20 (**)
6.30
4.70
4.70
5.25
6.10
6.35
5.20
6,03
6,03
5,46
37/37
38/41
45/45
Categories
of
criteria
Country
Bulgaria
4.40
6.79
5.33
6.30
4.55
4.70
48/48
5,19
Note: The symbols (*), (**), (***) attached to the points allotted to criteria according to which the classification is
made, signify the position (I, II, III) the respective country occupies by the amount of points obtained to one of the 6
criteria, for the Central and Eastern European region
Source: “E-readiness rankings 2008. Maintaining momentum A white paper from the Economist Intelligence
Unit”, The Economist written in co-operation with The IBM Institute for Business Value
The process of adherence to the European Union triggered off the improvement of the
business environment in many of the states from Central and Eastern Europe, however
these states’ motivation to implement reforms decreases once with the acquiring of the
quality of member of the European community, according to the report realized by the
European Intelligence Unit (EIU). At the international level, the same report assesses that
the business environment will maintain favourable for the next five years (2008-20012), in
spite of obstacles like: the intensification of protectionism, the risks of the security system
and macroeconomic disturbances, which might transform in big global threats. With all
these, the process of globalization is still yet to go on. The international trend of
liberalization and regulation will be further sustained by important factors, such as the
increasing concurential pressures upon multinational companies and the competition
between different countries for foreign investments.
126
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
In order to resist to the strong competition in the current context of globalization, the
Romanian business environment, as part of the European business environment, has to
offer attractive conditions both for local and foreign enterprises, with the view to
increasing the country competitivity.
A country competitivity represents its capacity to create and maintain the institutional,
economic and infrastructure conditions that would favour the setting/attraction and
development of companies producing goods and services at a higher quality and/or at
lower prices than in case of external competitors. The capacity of competition manifests
itself both on international and on national markets, as related to the goods and services
from import.
In present the country competitivity is mainly ensured by the small costs of work and of
certain local raw materials and manifests itself in sectors characterized by a relatively
small added value. This model of competitivity is specific to many countries situated to a
lower level of economic development. At the same time, taking into consideration the
increase of internal prices, the external opening of the country, the abundance of cheap
manpower in other countries, the intense emigration of citizens, our comparative
advantages determined by small costs will erode more and more, while the technological
lagging behind developed countries could get worse. This is why it is necessary to ensure
a gradual transition from competitivity determined by the cost factor to the competitivity
determined by the efficiency factor and the quality factor together with the orientation of
the economy towards branches with a relatively higher added value. Competitivity based
on efficiency and quality will be the basic source of lasting economic growth and
development and improvement of living standards for people.
The increase of competitivity on internal and external markets by ensuring the transition
from competitivity based on costs to competitivity based on efficiency and quality. The
most important progress indicators are:
•
Rate of growth of work productivity on sectors and branches of activity;
The relative work productivity in Romania (compared to similar indicators in the
•
main competing countries in the region – Bulgaria, Latvia, Lithuania, Ukraine etc.);
•
Structure of raw added value on sectors and branches of activity;
Rate of finite products within the total of exports;
•
•
Growth of the amount of GNP;
Amount of intensive products in technology within the total volume of production;
•
Rate of growth of exports on the main sale markets, related to the total growth;
•
•
Rate of main local products on the segments of external market
A first step in this direction was made in Romania by elaborating the project of the
National Export Strategy (NES).9 This process is the result of collaboration between
state institutions with attributions in the economic domain and private environment. The
identification of sectors with potential for export has determined the realization of a plan of
measures annexed to the document which states the intention to increase substantially the
exports for the following years.
9
National Export Strategy 2005-2009, Commission of Strategy, Competitivity, Marketing and Branding,
Council of Export, August, 2004
127
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
The initiatives and measures from the NES are focused on: technological development,
identification of resources and products required on external markets, improvement of the
process of production of services, reduction of production costs, programs of training for
the staff, support for research and design, promoting of the Romanian scientific research
abroad, development of services of quality certification, development of business alliances
between companies and associations which act especially at the level of the region,
diversification of services, growth of manager skills and preparation of firms for the
competition from the European market after the 1st of January 2007.
The domains with potential for export were identified by work groups built on the principle
of public-private partnership. The 23 sector groups identified the opportunities of
development of the offer for export in the following domains: clothing, furniture, wine,
glass and pottery, chemical products, technology of information and communications,
machine constructions, machine equipment and components, rural tourism, ecology
agriculture, spa services, crafts, electronics and electrotechnics, culture and other emerging
services representing the protection of environment, research, development, quality
certification, transport etc. In exchange, the 7 intersector groups have focused upon the
identification of common parameters to all sectors with potential for export which have to
be respected in order to reach the target of the strategy (competivity for export of
Romanian enterprises, commerce information, commerce financing, quality management,
skills development, facilitation of commerce, promotion and branding, research and
innovation).
According to the Strategy, Romania, in its quality of exporting country, has to focus on
products with great value, on attracting local and foreign investments, introducing in the
system of production components that are now imported (for example in the sector of
clothing, the raw materials produced in the country), the branding of exporting sectors,
identification of market niches etc..
The first projects of sector branding regard the domains of IT, vineyard-wine, furniture
and clothing. To their achievement contribute, besides the Ministry of Economy and
Commerce through the Department of External Commerce, other ministries, syndicates,
professional associations.
The elaboration of the National Export Strategy took nine months and it was launched
under public debate at the beginning of September 2005. The technical assistance was
provided by the International Centre of Commerce from Geneva OMC/UNCTAD.
In order to achieve successfully the SNE objectives, it is necessary to evaluate the
Romanian economic environment to know its strengths and weaknesses, so that the
initiatives and measures proposed have a real base of realization. Specialists assigned from
the organizations that collaborated with the government to elaborate the strategy had no
easy task SWOT analysis of the entire Romanian economy is rather difficult to make
because there are significant differences between its sectors and sub-sectors, and the
climate in which the economic activity develops is the result of national and international
wide interaction of several factors.
The sum of these factors constitute the external macroenvironment which exerts an indirect
influence upon it, while the reverse influence is less significant or does not exist. Just by
taking a look at the dimension of the enterprise we may notice that this can do little or
128
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
almost nothing to have an impact upon its macroenvironment. It just has to monitor its
evolution and prepare for unavoidable changes. In exchange, the business environment can
produce many effects upon the microeconomic activity by the measures taken by
organizations in charge.
The macroenvironment includes a complex set of variables that form together a framework
led by the following factors: economic factors, technical and technological factors, the
demographic factor and the structure of population, social-cultural factors, politicaljudicial factors and natural factors.
The SWOT10 analysis realized on groups of factors was based on an aggregation of several
SWOT analyses prepared by every of the teams specialized in strategy (see Table no.2)
Table 2: The SWOT analysis of the Romanian business environment
STRENGHTS
WEAKNESSES
Human
resources,
social
capital, Human resources, social capital,
infrastructure of education and research
infrastructure of education and
research
►Great amount of manpower, at low costs
and an acceptable level of initial education ;
►Lack
of
synchronization,
communication and cooperation between
►The existence of infrastructure of research companies, research institutions and the
and training (schools and institutes) public sector; between banks and
specialized on important domains of activity companies; between the suppliers of
such as: wood processing, machine utilities and natural resources and
construction, machine components, industrial processors;
equipment, textiles, chemicals etc.
►Insufficient
connections
and
►The
educational
system
has
the cooperation between the needs of the
infrastructure, the institution and human business sector and the educational
resources well—prepared and distributed in system in the curriculum area (IT,
territory in strategic domains (IT&C, textiles, furniture, textiles);
furniture, chemicals and oil-chemicals,
engineering) ;
►Low capacity of association in a
business or between firms in order to
►The good concentration of foreign create marketing, branding centres etc.
languages speakers in the big cities;
►Low level of knowledge about foreign
►Very well-prepared specialists with key markets and the effects of the UE
integration,
globalization
and
positions in transnational companies;
liberalization;
►Cultural heritage specific to the European
►Lack of understanding the need of
context.
quality control and certification, of
creating and protecting brands and
10
http://www.cpisc.ro/files/13_septembrie/SNE_document_final;
www.mie.ro/euroimm/%3Fid2%3D0301+analiza+swot+a+comertului+exterior+romanesc
129
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
industrial
property
or
of
the
requirements, advantages and priorities
for a lasting development, rural
Natural resources and the environment
development
and
protection
of
►Natural resources available for wood environment;
processing (90% of the main types of
►Focus on sectors with low added
regenerative wood), quality of soil;
value/strategies based on reduced costs;
►Increased biodiversity, climatic conditions
good for the health and unique ecology ►Insufficient capacity of industries (IT,
ecology agriculture, food processing) to
systems as the Danube Delta;
absorb funds due to low demand and lack
►Natural conditions good for the agriculture. of entrepreneur skills;
Other significant
competitivity
factors
►Lack of management skills and brand
building and networks of distribution on
regarding foreign markets which determine a low
degree of market sophistication
►Friendly business environment and a
national infrastructure in course of
modernization
with
UE
funds.
Macroeconomic stability.
►Insufficient
marketing
resources,
market development and promotion at
the level of company, association,
macroeconomic and public level;
►The existence of industries able to provide
and adapt the offer within the national value
chain for the integration on vertical of the
products of strategic sectors such as:
furniture, car industry, chemicals, electric
objects, metal processing and IT&C;
►Lack of experience of farmers in
creating business plans and getting
financing from available sources like the
UE SAPARD program;
►Low adaptability of manpower and
low level of learning all along the time of
►Complementarities and capacity of vertical life;
specialization in European industries like car
►An important segment of population
construction, car components etc.;
affected by poverty and social exclusion
►Long tradition in manufacturing sectors
like: textiles, wood processing, chemistry and
oil chemistry, metal processing;
Natural
resources
and
the
►Governmental support for strategic sectors environment
in certain key areas such as: development of
►High level of wood cutting and use of
the infrastructure IT&C;
wood resources in primary industries
►Increased interest and pro-active attitude of with small added value, such as export of
business associations for ecologic farms and unprocessed wood and timber;
the special priority of this sector in the
programs of adherence and integration ►Low protection and promotion of
Romania-UE combined with the introduction biodiversity;
of legislation accordingly;
►Inefficient agriculture (exceedingly
130
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
►The measure of the internal market;
intensive in labour), the excessively
fragmented agriculture surface;
►Favourable geographic conditions such as:
fast connections with foreign markets with ►Poorly
developed
touristic
good possibilities of car, railway, sea and infrastructure and inadequate marketing;
Danubian transport.
► High energy intensity
Other
factors
competitivity
significant
for
►Technological disparity and low level
of modernization of technologies
(viticulture,
furniture
and
other
processing sectors), low productivity,
high costs (excepting the labour);
►Disparity from advanced standards of
quality and environment;
►Digital disparity in the electronic
commerce, e-business and the use of IT
services and of computer-assisted
technologies; high costs for the Internet
and phone infrastructure;
►Lack of information about markets and
marketing skills;
►The inexistence of a coherent image of
sectors;
►The business environment is still
altered
by
monopol
agreements,
corruption cases and the lack of
collaboration,
communication,
transparency;
►Connections with producers of textiles,
ornaments, accesories etc. of companies
from the final sectors (clothing and
textiles) were broken;
►Weak links on the value chain between
final processors of oil-chemical goods
such as tyres, plastic materials etc. and
suppliers of raw materials and increased
costs of production in primary
131
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
industries ;
►Financial blockings at the level of
productive companies;
►Lack of cooperation between foreign
investments in sectors considered as an
important source of managerial knowhow, transfer of technology and access to
foreign markets and other production
factories within the respective sectors,
even if they have different production
profiles;
►Insufficient efforts of restructuring and
recapitalization for the infusion of new
technologies capable of helping the
sector and create and increase the added
value of the product;
►Dependence on raw materials and
imported accessories such as: lack of
offers of local raw materials and
insufficient technical endowment of
primary sectors;
►Flawed local legislation regarding the
commerce of goods, exports and
transport;
►
Degraded
infrastructure/
and
insufficient
low accessibility inside and outside the
country.
OPPORTUNITIES
THREATS
Human
resources,
social
capital, Human resources, social capital,
infrastructure of education and research
infrastructure of education and
research
►Romania’s adherence to the UE. Romania
will benefit from the UE of research and ►External brain drain, especially in the
education
infrastructures,
legislation case of IT specialists, engineers,
framework and support schemes;
mathematicians, inventors;
►Education and research will be more tied to ►Lack of a well-developed school of
production;
industrial design with connections with
the business environment in important
►Good general knowledge of foreign production sectors such as: textiles,
languages allowing the development of
132
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
delocalizaed services;
clothing, furniture etc.
►Dimension (the second country as ►Focusing of human resources upon
population from the new member states -10+2 unspecialized activities with small gains;
and the seventh of all UE countries);
►Lack of interest of enterprises
►New sources of investment, including the
regarding the use of the results of the
activities of research-development and
innovation for the improvement of
Structural and Cohesion Funds;
competitivity of products and services;
►Development of business infrastructure;
►Low interest for innovation and
original brands.
►Bigger direct foreign investments;
►Modernization of the capital and of other
city centres where most of the learned
Natural
resources
and
the
population lives;
environment
► The necessity/acceptation of the need to
►Loss of biodiversity and rural cultural
change;
heritage because of chaotic economic
activities;
Natural resources and the environment
►Increased interest for the protection of ►Concentration of activities in cities and
environment and biodiversity in the world and an unbalanced development between
cities and rural areas;
in Europe;
►A new type of consumer, interested in ►Climatic changes/degradation of the
ecology,
protection
of
environment, natural environment.
biodiversity;
► Romania as touristic destination – niche
tourism -potential knot in the region for Other
factors
natural gases and electric energy transport
competitivity
►Modernization of agriculture
Other factors significant for competitivity
significant
for
►Integration but not convergence within
the EU;
►Greater exposure to competition on
globalized markets;
►Romanian enterprises will benefit of the ►Value chains of the strategic sectors
scale economy of the great community are inefficient and weak, having reduced
profits and being much too dependent on
market;
international value chains;
►Liberalization and
globalization
of
of
Romania’s
commerce and the modernization of business ►Strenghtening
position/image as an economy focused
models;
on sectors with low added value;
►Delocalization and growth of competition
133
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
between CTNs and IMMs to set or enter ►Poor e-business infrastructure;
world value chains;
►Lack of significant information about
►The great importance given by the UE to the market in highly specialized domains
the “new economy” and the high-tech sectors, (IT
externalization,
industrial
development of infrastructure, energy subcontracting, organic farms);
efficiency, protection of environment;
►Inconsistent country branding;
►The existence of IT&C, electric, electronic
and hardware industries relatively developed ►Low productivity and efficiency in the
and a great number of specialists in this consume of utilities and raw materials as
domain who can face the requirements of compared to competition;
informatisation; The application of ecommerce/e-governing techniques
►Aggressive
foreign
competition
borrowing segments from the local
►Complete
liberalization
of
public market in sectors such as: textiles,
acquisitions
furniture, metal and wood processing etc.
due to liberalization and integration.
►migration of certain industrial sectors
towards external locations with lower
costs
►long periods of stagnation/economic
decline at European or world level
Considering this SWOT analysis we can say that the Romanian economy has a relatively
small level of competitivity in the European context, and Romania attracted smaller
investments per capital, as compared to other countries from the region, because of the
absence of a transparent legislation frame and an increased competition in the region. The
competitive disparity compared to the rest of the EU member states cannot be ignored in
the conditions of the importance the European market has for Romania. It is very likely for
this disparity to grow within the perspective of an even greater liberalization and
integration of the world commerce, leaving the Romanian exporters in a critical situation.
In spite of the continuous opening of the external commerce and in spite of significant
performances of exports, Romanian exports are still not enough diversified. This is mainly
due to the fact that only few enterprises run innovative or research activities in the
development of their products and activities. A short look upon the principal Romanian
exports proves the fact that the majority of them are traditional sectors. There hasn’t been
much innovation and, for this reason, there are still few industries intensively using new
technology.
In consequence, Romania’s strategic priority should now be the competitive advantages,
the development of capacity and competence of exporting sectors, attraction of local and
foreign investments and creation of an economy able to develop in conditions of free
commerce in a more globalized market. Direct foreign investments (ISD) represent a
source of capital, of know-how, of technology and management skills and stimulate
economic growth. Romania has to become a better candidate for the absorption of direct
foreign investments, especially those oriented towards export.
134
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Romania can no longer be defensive or protectionist, but focus on problems of access or
regularization of supply of products and services for domestic market. The introduction of
the common custom tax once with Romania’s adherence to European structures from
January 2007, imposes a fast adaptation to the conditions of the international market. It is
essential that productive sectors take into account this aspect.
Competitive advantages do not appear out of protectionism, rates or preferential access to
market. In fact, these measures can have a negative effect upon economic performances
because they lower the motivation of enterprises for efficiency, quality and innovation.
From this point of view, we consider useful the analysis of the situation of Romanian
economy through the basic economic-financial and money indicators for the period 20002007 (table no.3). This period is extremely important for the economic situation of our
country because it coincides with the beginning of negotiations and talks concerning
Romania’s adherence to the EU (the 15th of February 2000), with the obtaining by
Romania of the status of functional economy (the year 2004) and the integration in
European structures (January 1, 2007).
Table 3: Situation of the principal macroeconomic indicators at the level of the
Romanian economy for the period 2000-2007
UM
2000
2001
2002
ECONOMIC GROWTH AND ASSOCIATED FACTORS
Value of
Gross
Mil. lei
National
80377,3 116768,7 151475,1
Product
(RON)
(current
prices)
Rhythm of
growth of
%
2.1
5.7
5
GNP
Rhythm of
growth of the
%
7.1
8.4
6
industrial
production
Rhythm of
%
1.4
6.3
2.4
growth of the
final consume
Raw
formation of
%
5.5
10.1
8.2
fix capital
COMMERCE AND INVESTMENTS
FOB exports
Mil. Euro
11273
12722
14675
FOB imports
Mil. Euro
13140
16045
17427
Commercial
-1867
-3323
-2752
Mil Euro
balance
Direct foreign
Mil Euro
1147
1294
1212
investments
Deficit of
current
Mil Euro
-1494
-2488
-1623
account
INFLATION
IPC(end of the
%
40.7
30.3
17.8
year)
IPC(mean)
%
45.7
34.5
22.5
LABOUR
Population in
Thousands
4623
4619
4568
charge
of people
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
197564,8
246468,8
288047,8
342418
404708,8
4.9
8.3
4.1
7.7
6
3.1
4.3
2.5
6.9
5.1
6.9
10.2
8.5
12.6
10.2
9.2
10.1
13
16.1
28,.9
15614
19569
18935
24258
22255
30061
29380,3
50882,6
-3995
-5323
-7806
25850,5
40745,8
14895,3
1946
5183
5213
9082
7069
-3060
-5098
-6883
-9973
-16872
14.1
9.3
8.6
4.9
6.57
15.3
11.9
9.0
6.03
5
4591
4420
4704
4575
4717,2
-21502,3
135
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Unemployed
Thousands
of people
Rate of
unemployment
(end of the
year)
EXCHANGE RATE
RON/USD
(end of the
year)
RON/USD
(mean)
RON/EUR
(end of the
year)
RON/EUR
(mean)
1007
827
761
659
558
523
460,5
367,8
%
10.5
8.8
8.4
7.4
6.2
5.9
5.2
4.1
-
2.5926
3.1597
3.3500
3.2595
2.9067
3.1078
2.5676
2.4564
-
2.1693
2.9061
3.3055
3.3200
3.2637
2.9137
2.8090
2.4383
-
2.4118
2.7881
3.4919
4.1117
3.9663
3.6771
3.3817
3.6102
-
1.9956
2.6027
3.1255
3.7556
4.0532
3.6234
3.5245
3.3373
Source: The reports of the National Bank of Romania (http://www.bnr.ro/) and the Statistic Yearbooks of
Romania during 2000-2007 edited by the National Institute of Statistics (http://www.insse.ro/)
The analysis of data from the table and other data we hold shows us some important
aspects during the respective period, especially in 2007, regarding the situation of
Romania:
The increase of the GNP in the last two years is an actual fact. We can say that the
Romanian people started to work better and harder. In the first semester of 2006 it was
recorded the biggest rhythm of growth of the Gross National Product (GNP) from 2001
until now: 7,4%, compared to the same period of the year 2005, according to the National
Institute of Statistics. A special support to this performance was brought by the growth of
productivity of work. The high level of productivity of work reflects the result of correct
restructuring measures. Re-allotment of sources (for example migration of labour from the
industrial sector to agriculture; subventions allotted to heavy industry, most from the state)
have partially altered the real economic growth. If in 2007, after Romania’s adherence to
the European Union the Romanian state no longer allotted subventions to the mining
sector. Unprofitable mines were closed or will be closed. We are speaking of about 370
localities from 22 counties that are affected from a social and economic point of view.
Romania has a strategy of restructuring of mining societies, but besides these mining areas
need social and economic regeneration. The main purpose of the project is increasing the
capacity of local communities to administrate the economic and socială situation in the
area. The project has created business centers and offered support for new entrepreneurs.
There was also a component of microcredits (there were offered approximately 2.500
microcredits with a total value of 5.589.140 dollars) and one for financial stimulants for
employers and for reforming of manpower (at the end of the project for 2006 there were
reported 6.736 newly created workplaces).
Although Romania’s exports depend to a considerable extent on the process of
transformation of raw materials in final products, there was not possible to balance the
export and the import. One example in this sense is Romania’s commercial deficit in the
agriculture and food sector. The degree of coverage of imports by exports maintains at
about 80% by year.
One potential winner of the market liberalization could be the sector of services
because of the fact that it is relatively intensive in latest technologies (thus losing its
competitivity) and especially because it includes in a percentage of 60% work force. It is
estimated a constant decrease of the competitive disadvantage from the European Union,
136
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
due to the unitary cost of the Romanian manpower which is much under the European one
and due to gain in efficiency through imports of technology. Therefore, services contribute
to the sold of the general balance sheet and to the macroeconomic development of the
country.
The domain from which Romania could take much profit is that where exported
„products” are „intensive in manpower” while from imports it could win only if the
products are „intensive in technology”, but not the goods of final use, that have no impact
or significance for Romania’s production or exports, but machines and equipment used as
inputs for the sectors less intensive in technology.
In 2004 from the total of manpower employed 30 % were working in services,
compared to 31,5% hired in agriculture domains, 25,9% in industry, 10,3 % in the
commerce and 2,3% in other domains. Even if at the end of 2007, Romania records the
lower rate of unemployment from the entire period analyzed, the truth is that we deal with
an under-use of existing manpower and in the context of the future deficit of manpower
from the European Union, Romania has great chances to become a source for the attraction
of human resources by European industries11 (either directly, through migration of labour,
or indirectly, by subcontracting). As a matter of fact, this thing is in progress now and is
starting to become a threat to the Romanian manpower market. From the second half of
2007 Romania has also started to face the lack of specialized labour especially in the
domain of services. This situation would not be such a great matter in the hypothesis of
repatriation the income. The problem lies however elsewhere. More than half of the money
sent in the country by the Romanian people go to rural areas. In the stage of the
development of Romanian rural from 2007 this repatriation exclusively means consume, so
the sums brought back in the country are not invested, decreasing the chances for a real
contribution to the formation of GNP.
Romania succeeded to attract more direct foreign investments than we would have
expected according to the relative part it holds from the world gross national product. This
means that it makes visible efforts to attract investments and is going through continuous
liberalization. In this context Romania offers good perspectives of economic growth, a
high level of qualification of manpower, considerable natural resources, capacities in the
domain of scientific research, advanced infrastructure and an efficient financial support
especially due to massive privatizations from these domains in the past 7 years.
The summer drought has strongly affected the economic growth, this being placed
at the level of 6% and has determined the increase of inflation not only for 2007 but also
for 2008
The first year in the European Union brought some important news for Romanian
economy. The most important of these is the great fluctuation of money exchange, after
long periods in which the rate of exchange was heading in a single direction. Now during
the same year we have witnessed a record-appreciation (at the middle of August 2007, the
rate of exchange leu/Euro being of 3,15 lei/Euro) and a record devaluation (at the end of
2007, the rate of exchange leu/Euro being of 3,61 lei/Euro) with a disparity of almost 20%.
This was due, on the one hand, to the increase of prices at food because of the drought that
affected the agriculture, and on the other hand, to the world economic crisis generated by
the fall of real estate markets from the SUA and Great Britain, and to the inflation from the
EU.
The rhythm of growth of imports up the rhythm of growth of exports situated
Romania on the 5th place among the EU states in what concerns the extent of the
commercial deficit. Moreover, the deficit of current account and the worsening of the
11
We include here in the name of industry the domain of services.
137
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
perspective of country rating are other factors that reduced the interest of investors for
Romania. At the end of January 2008, the rating agency Fitch had to change from „stable”
to „negative” Romania’s perspective, as result of the deepening of the deficit of current
account, one of the biggest in the world, it is shown in the press communicate quoted by
Standard Business.
The lowering of the interest of investors because of the decline of macroeconomic
indicators, in what regards the transactions from the Stock Exchange Bucure ti, has
reduced the mean volume transactioned, in November, to 14,2 million Euro compared to
22,8 million Euro in July (according to statements made by chief-economist from East
Capital).
A major problem that Romania faces is corruption. One year after the integration in
EU the efforts made by governors to diminish its level seem inefficient. The study
presented by the company Transparency International12 (TI) regarding world corruption,
shows that Romania is placed on the first positions, together with countries like Cambodia,
Pakistan or region Kosovo. Just like in 2006, in 2007 also the most corrupt institutions in
the country are the political parties and the Parliament. The citizens’ perceptions upon
corruption in certain sectors are also worrying, a fact which might influence the business
environment. Opposite to the neighbouring country, Bulgaria, where corruption manifests
at the level of criminality, in Romania acts of corruption are restricted to thefts, frauds,
traffic of influence, bribery.
With all these, in 2007 there were recorded unprecedented growths in almost all
domains of activity, only agriculture passed through the worst year after the Revolution,
because of the drought, causing unfavourable effects in the food industry.
The incomes grew in 2007 in a rhythm that places Romania on the second place in
the EU and on the fourth place in the world, while sales of cars and goods surpassed any
previous expectations and constructions went from record to record, even if it is recorded a
deficit of manpower in this sector (of approximately 150.000 workers).
Romania’s integration in the EU has also brought some elements of novelty or in absolute
premiere for the Romanian economy, in certain domains such as:
The first year with mandatory private pensions;
In the exchange market the most waited event was the initial public offer Transgaz,
other events being represented by the finalization of the privatization of the company
Electroputere, the cancellation of the capital increase from Oltchim, the announcement
from AVAS of auction sale of Antibiotics Ia i. Moreover, the Stock Exchange from
Warsaw became shareholder of the Financial and Goods Stock Exchange from Sibiu;
The bank domain was marked by the apparition of new players (Bank of Cyprus,
Millennium Bank), the fluctuations of the interest rates policy, the loosening of norms of
crediting made by the NBR, the starting of the staff crisis from the bank domain and the
fast extension of bank infrastructure;
The explosion from the domain of constructions, in spite of the deficit of
manpower;
The record car registrations, 2007 being the year with the most registrations for
new cars;
There were achieved 57 km of highway of the 784 km in execution;
12
http://www.transparency.org/news_room/latest_news/press_releases_nc/2007
138
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
The agriculture production more than twice smaller than that from 2006 (from
15,63 million tones of cereals, to 7,11 million tones of cereals because of the drought has
had a negative impact upon economy);
The fiscal system went through some changes: the exemption from the payment of
the imposit on dividends received from its branches if they are in another member state and
fulfill certain conditions, the return to custom payment of the AVT corresponding to
imports from extracommunity countries; decrease of custom taxes at electronic and
electrocasnic products imported from the countries outside the EU; the introduction of
green tax for electronic and electrocasnic products; impositing by 16% of the partake and
real estate transactions;
In the energy domain it was finalized the process of liberalization of natural gases
and electricity, consumers, including the home ones being able to choose their supplier,
according to the advantages of offers; it was put back in function reactor 2 from
Cernavodă; the acquisition Shell Gas Romania by Petrom which undertook the business
with liquiefid gas; the sale of 75% of shares of The Rompetrol Group to the state company
Kaz MunaiGas from Kazakhstan; transaction Petrom-Petromservice in which Petrom
undertook the division of oil services from Petromservice.
2007 was a much better year from the economic point of view than it seemed, even if
previous periods required great sacrifices in order to integrate our country in the European
structures. From now on Romanian economy cannot be separated from the European and
the world economy, on the contrary its influences will be stronger. The effects of the
American real estate crisis are just at the beginning and 2008 is the year when they will be
more visible.
In conclusion, we can say that Romania’s adherence to the European Union has led and
will further lead to the improvement /attractivity of the Romanian business environment by
filtering the economies active on the market.
With all sacrifices made, Romania still has the potential to win from its adherence to the
European Union. The competitivity of services is increasing, this fact being attractive both
for internal but especially for external investors, who have another important reason to
enter the Romanian market of services: the opening of markets, especially for the members
of the European Union, then for the entire world economy due to the many conventions
and agreements signed by the EU within the OMC for market liberalization and for the
reduction of the level of tariff and nontariff protection.
One of the best directions to follow for Romania in the present moment would be a budget
policy that could redirect public expenses to domains that would strengthen the human
capital of the country, the infrastructure and administration capacity, while the competition
policy should redirect the state support towards the domain of research-development.
There should also be encouraged the risk capital for innovative firms, and the government
should provide co-financing for a fund of risk capital in order to support these firms. The
best way to support research in the private sector would be indirect financial measures,
which are allowed by EU regulations.
However, to achieve these objectives, Romania needs a strategic effort at the national level
based on the development of competitive advantages, to create a performant economy.
Romania must further open its economy to stimulate the competitivity based on efficiency,
quality and innovation. It is essential that our country be able to generate and maintain
139
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
more added value on the production chain. This process has to be related to substantial
increases in productivity and diversification of the capacities of production, and exports are
the most efficient way to sustain social-economic growth.
The European Union has accepted us and is now giving us a helping hand through the
infusion, in 2008, of structural funds with favourable effects upon the evolution of
economy, including of the money exchange, in spite of the fact that the rate of absorption
will probably be low, judging by the experience of the states from the region.
By measure that Romania will be able to recognize the domains benefiting from the
adherence and the time to reorient towards these domains is shorter, costs and
disadvantages will balance with gains and advantages brought by this process, but it further
depends on the Government of Romania, through its organizations in charge, how would it
further promote and develop economic, political, legislation reforms with great impact
upon the Romanian economic environment.
140
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
References
Barney, J.& Hesterly, W. (2006). Strategic Management and Competitive Advantage:
Concepts and Cases. 1st ed., New York: Prentice Hall (pp.20-140).
Campean, V. (2005). Identification of the branches of Romanian industry, which are
competitive on the internal and external market. In Romanian Academy, (Ed.). Romanian
Economic development. Competitivity and integration in the EU. Volume II, Bucure ti..
Carstea, G. (2002). Strategic analysis of competitive environment, Bucuresti: Economica,
(pp. 25-120).
Cazan, L. (2003). Strategy regarding the development and increase of Romania’s
competitivity, with the purpose of integration in the European Union. In Romanian
Academy, (Ed.). Economic development of Romania. Competitivity and integration in the
EU. Volume I, Bucure ti..
Cazan, L. (2005). Regeneration on competitive bases of the industry – possible directions
of action. In Romanian Academy, (Ed.). Economic development of Romania.
Competitivity and integration in the EU. Volume II, Bucure ti..
Ciumara, M. (2003). Corruption versus competitivity. In the volume of the International
Scientific Symposion. The competitive potential of the national economies of Romania and
Republic of Moldavia. Possibilities of valorification on the internal, European and world
market, Pitesti.: University “Constantin Brâncoveanu”, Romanian Academy (Institute of
Economic Research) and the Academy of Economic Studies from Chi inău.
Daianu, D. (2005). Institutional diversity, economic policies and economic development.
In Romanian Academy, (Ed.). Economic development of Romania. Competitivity and
integration in the EU. Volume II, Bucure ti..
David, F. (2007). Stategic Management, Concepts and Cases. 11th ed., New York: Prentice
Hall (pp. 50-180).
Ionescu, M. (2003). Romanian firms on the unique European market, in present and in
perspective. The role of the Government and Patronates in supporting the increase of
competitivity of the offer of export. In Romanian Academy, (Ed.). Economic development
of Romania. Competitivity and integration in the EU. Volume I, Bucure ti..
Iordan, M. & Chilian, M. N. (2005). The Evolution of Competitivity of Industrial Branches
from România. In Romanian Academy, (Ed.). Economic development of Romania.
Competitivity and integration in the EU. Volume II, Bucure ti..
Jula, D.& Jula, N. et al . (2003). Competititivity and regional disequilibriums. In Romanian
Academy, (Ed.). Economic development of Romania. Competitivity and integration in the
EU. Volume I, Bucure ti..
Porter, M. (2004). Building the Microeconomic Foundations of Prosperity: Finding from
the Business Competitiveness Index. In M.E. Porter, K. Schwab, H.S. Martin and A.
141
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Lopez-Claros. (Ed.). The Global Competitiveness Report, Palgrave-MacMillan, New
York.: Harvard Business School - Institute for Strategy and Competitiveness.
Russu, C. (2005). Raw added value and Industrial Competitiveness in Romania –
evolutions, correlations and perspectives. In Romanian Academy, (Ed.). Economic
development of Romania. Competitivity and integration in the EU. Volume II, Bucure ti.
Wheelen, T. & Hunger, D. (2006). Strategic Management and Business Policy. 10th ed.,
New York: Prentice Hall (pp. 30-216).
*** Statistic year-book of Romania for the period 2000-2007.
*** Reports of the National Bank of Romania for the period 2000-2007.
*** Decision of the Romanian Government no. 1828/ 22.12.2005 for the approval of the
National Export Strategy for the period 2005-2009, published in the Official Gazette of
Romania no.65 from 24.01.2006.
*** World Investment Report 2006. FDI from Developing and Transition Economies:
Implications for development, United Nations, New York and Geneva, 2006.
*** World Economic and Financial Surveys, World Economic Outlook Database, April
2008, International Monetary Fund
(http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2000/01/data/index.htm)
www.doingbusiness.org
www.insse.ro – National Institute of Statistics
www.bnr.ro – National Bank of Romania
www.mie.ro – Ministry of European Integration
http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/ - statistics of the European Commission
http://www.infoeuropa.ro/ Romania
Centre of Information of the European Commission in
www.eiu.com/sponsor/ibm - Economist Intelligence Unit Written in co-operation with The
IBM Institute for Business Value
142
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Insolvency
It can be seen that the highest bankruptcy rate in 2006 was in Hungary (1% in 2006
rapidly decreasing as compared to 2005).Second place goes to Romania, and in 2005 it
was Croatia. In Romania’s case, an increase was registered in the number of companies
being under bankruptcy with 45,9% in 2006 as compared to 2005, and this was primarily
due to the issuing of the new law for insolvency published in July 2006, law that protects
the lenders. The large amount of insolvencies at the end of 2006 was also caused by the
long period of time allocated to law suits, actually less than half of the total of insolvencies
were lawsuits opened in 2006. In 2007 it was expected to have the same type of evolution,
by rapidly increasing with 50% for the companies that would go bankrupt, mainly because
of the new legislation combined with the EU one, which would destroy the small
companies which have an unstable financial situation. In Poland, the rate of registered
insolvents is extremely low, almost, but the number of bankruptcy reported does not reflect
on the real situation, because all cases of lack of actives are rejected by the court and there
are no official records on the number of rejected cases.
There is a small percentage of bankruptcy in Bulgaria, fact which is primarily due to the
complicated procedure and the duration of bankruptcy in this country.
Except for Romania, the number of bankruptcy for the countries that have joined the EU in
2006 can be observed, fact which underlines the capacity of the new EU economies to
overcome the competition on the unique market, invalidating the provisions regarding the
number of bankruptcies, especially for the small and intermediate businesses.
143
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Inflows and Outflows of Services in the EU and Turkey
Beyza Sümer
Dokuz Eylül University, Turkey
Abstract
Services have increasingly becoming a predominant field in the economies globally, yet it
is difficult to categorize services as a tertiary sector due to the fact that it constitutes a
dynamic component of other sectors in the knowledge era. It encompasses traditional
economic activities such as tourism, transportation, construction, financial and business
services; and also other activities such as counseling, data processing, and technical
analysis. Services have a high share in the total output and maintain a high percentage in
value added and employment in the western world. Services are subject to foreign trade
and foreign direct investment substantially due to the globalization process and
technological changes. The same trend for services is witnessed in Turkey, like in the EU.
The objective of this paper is to show insufficient intra-trade in the EU and opportunities
for Turkey in the trade of services. The method of analysis is comparative based on
empirical data.
144
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Introduction
Services are increasingly seen as an engine of economic growth and employment in the
EU, as well as in Turkey and other countries. Services account for seventy percent of
economic activity in the European Union, and a similar proportion of overall employment.
Growth in the economy is essentially driven by services. The same trend is witnessed in
Turkey, with services having a share of 64 percent in GDP and and 51 percent in total
employment (State Planning Institute, 2006). Services occur at every stage of the business
process. This underlines the economic importance of services in the European Union.
The rapid growth of services is an indication of fundamental changes in the production and
consumption structures of our societies. Particularly the use of new information and
telecommunication technologies causes forms of value adding, which are characterized by
a more intensive division of work and a higher degree of specialization. In the course of
changed patterns of value adding, complex interaction processes between the production of
goods and services, and between customers and service providers take place. Therefore it
is widely accepted that the growth of services can not be comprehended, nor be explained,
by a mere sectoral view (Granz, 2005).
There is an ever-growing number of different services, ranging from more traditional
service sectors such as transport, retail distribution, telecommunications, tourism and the
regulated professions, to more recently developed services such as waste management,
energy conservation, management consulting, data processing and technical analysis and
testing.
Services include four broad categories: Distributive trade (sale, maintenance/repair of
motor vehicles; wholesale/commission trade; retail trade and repair of personal goods),
Hotels and Restaurants, Transport and Communications (land transport, transport via
pipelines; water transport; air transport; supporting transport activities, travel agencies;
post and telecommunications), Real Estate, Renting and Business Activities (real estate
activities; renting of machinery, and of personal and household goods; computer and
related activities; resarch and development; other business activities).
Services were the main activity of 13.1 million enterprises in the EU-25 in 2003, which
generated a turnover of 10 363 billion euro. Producing a value added of 2 650 billion euro,
and employing 69 million persons, services accounted for 55 % and 59 % respectively of
the total non-financial business economy. In terms of employment, it was the largest
sector, well ahead of industry and construction, with shares of 30 % and 11 % respectively.
In 2003, 99.9 % of the business population in services were small and medium-sized
enterprises. These enterprises accounted for 68.5 % of employment and 63 % of value
added (Urbanski, 2007).
When looking more closely at employment in services, the sector clearly employs a high
share of women, part-time workers and self-employed. Of those working part-time, 75 %
were women, which was only two percentage points more than the average for the nonfinancial business economy. The share of self-employed (19%) in the services workforce
was also higher than the nonfinancial business economy average. The importance of
services in Member States’ economies was greater in terms of employment than for value
added which indicates relatively low apparent labour productivity (value added per person
employed). The gross operating rate – which is one indicator of profitability, was 11 % in
145
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
2003. The most profitable services activities were renting of machinery, real estate
activities, and post and telecommunications. It was also these same activities that were the
most productive (Urbanski, 2007).
Employing around 55 million persons in 2001, or nearly 55 % of total employment in the
European Union (EU) market economy, business-related services have been by far the
main source of job creation in the EU. Business services cover knowledge-intensive
business services, such as information technology (IT) consulting, management consulting,
advertising and professional training services, as well as operational services consisting of
services such as industrial cleaning, security services and secretarial services. The business
services sector is not just the largest creator of employment, it also adds more value to the
economy than any other macro-economic sector. It has the highest growth potential, more
new enterprises are created than in any other sector, and business-related services provide
the foundation for the knowledge-based economy. The main challenges in a knowledgebased economy relate to the ability to remain competitive, and that depends to a great
extent on the capacity to invest in IT and R&D. Unfortunately, in this respect the EU is
trailing far behind the United States: overall IT expenditures in the EU amounted to 4.2 %
of GDP in 2001 compared to 5.3% in the US, whilst EU average R&D expenditures were
13 % - with large differences across Member States - against the US figure of 34 %.
Business services lag behind the growth in productivity recorded in the United States. It is
frequently stated that this will constitute a threat to future employment in Europe. There is
a genuine danger that services jobs may be transferred to the US and Asia unless the
political authorities respond quickly to the challenges facing business-related services in
the EU.1
It should also be noted that the services sector is the main provider of jobs attracting new
groups to the labour market as part-time employment or in low-skilled jobs (Nielsen,
2005). In this paper, inflows and outflows of services will be analyzed from the perspective
of international trade and FDI, in the EU and Turkey. The following section will depict the
justifications and measures for liberalizing services in the EU for completing the internal
market. The third section will display the present situation of inflows and outflows of
services in the EU and Turkey in comparison with their world trade and intratrade in the
EU. The conclusion part will sum up the arguments discussed in the paper and will
highlight the disadvantageous position of the EU in intratrade of services and the
advantageous position of Turkey in the international trade of services.
Liberalization of Services in the EU
Barriers in services for the internal market
Since the 1988 Cecchini report, much progress has been made towards creating a single
European market for goods. The single market for services is, however, still in its infancy.
In most service sectors, less than 5 per cent of production is exported to other EU member
states. Research done by the European Commission established that this is at least partly
caused by trade costs resulting from a multitude of regulatory barriers in the member states
(Kox et al., 2004).
1
http://europa.eu/scadplus/leg/en/s70002.htm
146
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
While the single market has largely been achieved for the EU market for goods, the
services sector has lagged behind. This has resulted in sluggish activity, low productivity
growth, high prices, that show a wide dispersion and relatively high inflation in this sector.
Both the OECD product market regulation study and the European Commission study on
internal market barriers conclude that there are large barriers to trade between the EU
countries.2
The Lisbon European Council adopted an economic reform program with the aim of
making the EU the most competitive and dynamic knowledge-based economy in the world
by 2010. A key part of this program is to make the Internal Market work for services. With
this aim the Commission adopted its two-stage Internal Market Strategy for Services. The
Commission’s Report, which completed the first stage, attempted to draw up a
comprehensive inventory of the Internal Market barriers that continued to inhibit services.3
As the reasons why services are not frequently traded between Member States, the
Commission spent some time on the legal and economic analysis of the issues including a
consultation with Member States, other European institutions and stakeholders. This
resulted in the publication of a ‘Report on the State of the Internal Market for Services’ in
July 2002. This report set out, in detail, the legal, administrative and practical obstacles to
the free movement of services across borders in the EU. The large-scale consultation which
formed the basis of the report involved the European Parliament, the Economic and Social
Committee, the Committee of Regions, Member States and interested parties, and was
carried out throughout 2001 and early 2002. This report provided a basis for actions that
would be launched as a second stage in 2003. It concluded that there was still a huge gap
between the vision of an integrated EU economy and the reality as experienced by
European citizens and European service providers.4
Because of the complex and intangible nature of services and the importance of the knowhow and the qualifications of the service provider, the provision of services is often subject
to much more complex rules covering the entire service activity than is the case for goods.
Furthermore, while some services can be provided at a distance, many still require the
permanent or temporary presence of the service provider in the Member State where the
service is delivered. Whereas with goods only the goods themselves are exported; in the
case of service provision, it is often the provider himself, his staff, his equipment and
material that cross national borders. As a result, some or all of the stages of the business
process may take place in the Member State where the service is provided and be subject to
requirements differing from those in the Member State of origin.
Lack of information, transparency, and confidence, divergent rules between various
Member States, cultural and language barriers prevent consumers from enjoying the full
benefits of the Internal Market. Barriers to trade in services penalize in particular small and
medium sized enterprises. Given the predominance of SMEs in service operations, this has
clearly acted as a considerable hindrance the development of the Internal Market for
services. Services are intricately intertwined. They are often provided and used in
combination and feature as inputs at each stage of the service provider's business process.
Barriers to one service will trigger knock-on effects for other services and also for the
2
http://www.olis.oecd.org/olis/2005doc.nsf/linkto/ECO-WKP(2005)36
http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/services/services-dir/background_en.htm
4
ibid
3
147
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
wider industrial economy, given the integration of services into manufacturing. Many
barriers are horizontal and affect a range of service activities.5
Although barriers are widespread, they have a number of common traits in both their
origins and effects. It is apparent that while the previous Internal Market programs were
effective in removing physical and technical barriers, these have been replaced by legal
barriers arising from national, regional and local regulation. In addition, new barriers arise
from the behaviour of administrations, including the use of discretionary powers or heavy
and non-transparent procedures, which favour domestic operators. A number of difficulties
result from unsatisfactory application of certain EU instruments. It seems obvious that
Member States lack the necessary confidence in the quality of each other's legal regimes
and are reluctant to adapt their own regimes where necessary to facilitate cross-border
activities.6
Services Directive
The Lisbon European Council adopted an economic reform program with the aim of
making the EU the most competitive and dynamic knowledge-based economy in the world
by 2010. A key part of this program is to make the Internal Market work for services. The
freedom of establishment, set out in Article 43 of the Treaty and the freedom to provide
cross border services, set out in Article 49, are two of the fundamental freedoms which are
central to the effective functioning of the EU Internal Market. The principle of freedom of
establishment enables an economic operator to carry on an economic activity in a stable
and continuous way in one or more Member States. The principle of the freedom to
provide services enables an economic operator providing services in one Member State to
offer services on a temporary basis in another Member State, without having to be
established.
These provisions constitute the basis for the modification of national laws of the member
states. While some important developments and progress in the field of services have been
brought about through specific legislation in certain sectors (telecommunications,
broadcasting, and financial services), for the bulk of services the principles of freedom of
establishment and free movement of services have been clarified and developed over the
years through the case law of the European Court of Justice.7
Following the report, in January 2004, the Commission made a proposal for a directive on
services in the Internal Market. The Services Directive was finally adopted by the
European Parliament and the Council in December 2006 and will have to be transposed by
the Member States by the end of 2009. This directive is aimed at eliminating obstacles to
trade in services, thus allowing the development of cross-border operations. It is intended
to improve the competitiveness not just of service enterprises, but also of European
industry as a whole. It will remove discriminatory barriers, cut red tape, modernize and
simplify the legal and administrative framework - also by use of information technology –
and make Member State administrations co-operate much more systematically. It will also
strengthen the rights of users of services. The abolition of legal and administrative
5
http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/services/
Report from the Commission to the Council and the European Parliament on the state of the internal market
for services presented under the first stage of the Internal Market Strategy for Services, COM/2002/0441
final, http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=CELEX:52002DC0441:EN:HTML
7
http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/services/principles_en.htm
148
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
obstacles to cross-border trade and investment in the EU has been stepped up following the
Directive on Services in the Internal Market together with the liberalization of international
trade in business-related services.8 It has been asserted by OECD and Copenhagen
Economics that liberalizing services will generate employment, and will increase growth,
productivity and wages.9
The Services Directive falls under the framework of the Lisbon Strategy and proposes four
main objectives for creating an internal services market:
•
to ease freedom of establishment for providers and the freedom of provision of
services in the EU;
•
to strengthen rights of recipients of services as users of the latter;
•
to promote the quality of services;
•
to establish effective administrative cooperation among the Member States.
The Directive establishes a general legal framework for any service provided for economic
return (with the exception of excluded sectors) while taking the specific nature of certain
activities or professions into account. The following services are excluded: non-economic
services of general interest; financial services (including those such as banking, credit,
insurance and re-insurance, occupational or personal pensions, securities, investment funds
and payments); electronic communications services with respect to matters covered by
Directives; transport services, including port services; services of temporary work
agencies; healthcare services; audiovisual services; gambling; activities which are
connected with the exercise of official authority; certain social services (relating to social
housing, childcare and aid for persons in need); private security services; services provided
by notaries and bailiffs, who are appointed by an official act of government.10
It has been stated by the European Commission that there are essentially three reasons for
the regulation of professional services:11 (1) asymmetry of information: the difference in
the information available to consumers and service providers; (2) externalities: the
provision of a service may have an impact on third parties. Rules are therefore needed to
ensure that both service providers and purchasers take proper account of these external
effects. (3) the concept of "public goods": certain professional services are deemed to be in
the public good since they are of value for society in general, for example, the correct
administration of justice or the development of high-quality urban environments.
There are various oppositions against the services directive. ETUC (European workers
confederation) claims that the services directive will facilitate the firms to posite in the
countries with low social standards and regulations, and thus it will lead to social dumping
in the EU. Socialists oppose the directive from the view that it will bring the wages and the
social regulations down.12 Some of the new members are in favour of the services directive
and they assert that services directive will support completing the internal market.13 A
8
http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/top_layer/index_19_en.htm
European Commission, Extended impact assessment of proposal for a directive on services in the internal
market, http://europa.eu.int/comm/internal_market/services/docs/services-dir/impact/2004-impactassessment_en.pdf
10
http://europa.eu/scadplus/leg/en/s70002.htm
11
http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market
12
http://www.spectrezine.org/Editorial/servicesdirective.htm
13
http://news.bbc.co.uk
9
149
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
study shows that services enhance growth in the new member countries. The study claims
that there is a positive connection between tertiarization (dominance of services sector in
the economy) and per capita income. It has been asserted that the process of tertiarization
is compatible with growth in both employment and productivity (Breitenfellner &
Hildebrandt, 2006).
Inflows and Outflows of Services in the EU and Turkey
International trade and foreign investment in services have always been important for the
world economy since the mid of 19th century. Banking, transportation, distribution of gas
and electricity, business services are among to mention of a variety of services.
After 1990s, due to the structural change in the economies, firms have increasingly
relocated their industrial activities to countries with lower cost bases, and have outsourced
their non-industrial activities to the external service providers either for non-core activities,
such as transport or marketing services, or for part of the core activities in order to increase
flexibility, through the use of labour recruitment services (Nielsen, 2005). As a
consequence, business-related services have become more specialized and has enhanced
the competitiveness of the users of these services. The borderline between manufacturing
and services has become increasingly blurred and sometimes outdated, as an expanding
share of manufacturing companies become service providers due to the growing
importance of services in the value added creation of all sectors of the economy.
Services account for over 70% of European GDP and employment but represents only 28%
of European external trade.14 It also constitutes a lower share in Turkey’s foreign trade.
The world trade in services is 2.8 trillion dollars for exports and 2.7 trillion dollars for
imports (2006).15 EU25’s share in world total exports of services is 27% and in total
imports is 24%, in 2006.16
EU25’s international trade volume in services is about 2 trillion Euros, of this 1.17 trillion
is credits and 1.08 trillion is debits. EU25 is in net position in services with 90.7 billion
Euros.17 UK, Germany, France, Italy, Spain, Netherlands and Ireland are the countries with
the highest export and import values in the services trade. The share of the new members
in the international trade of services is very low when compared with the EU15 countries.
Table 1 shows the values of export and imports of services of the EU countries.
14
European Services Forum, www.esf.be
http://www.wto.org/english/res_e/statis_e/its2007_e/section3_e/iii01.xls
16
http://stat.wto.org/CountryProfile/WSDBCountryPFView.aspx?Language=E&Country=E25,TR
17
http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/extraction
15
150
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 1: International Trade of Services by the EU countries
billion dollars, 2006
EU15
Austria
Belgium
Denmark
Finland
France
Germany
Greece
Ireland
Italy
Luxemburg
Netherlands
Portugal
Spain
Sweden
UK
EU15 Total
EU10
Cyprus
Czech Rep.
Estonia
Hungary
Latvia
Lithuania
Malta
Poland
Slovakia
Slovania
EU10 Total
exports
imports
45.2
59.9
51.8
16.9
118.5
174.5
35.8
69.2
98.6
51.4
84.5
17.8
106.3
50.4
229.7
1 210.5
32.4
54.9
44.9
14.8
107.9
195.3
14.0
65.4
100.4
30.6
78.9
11.6
78.3
39.8
164.6
1 033.8
7.3
13.3
3.5
13.5
2.7
3.6
1.9
20.6
5.4
4.5
76.3
2.9
11.8
2.5
10.6
1.9
2.5
1.5
18.4
4.7
3.3
60.1
Source: UNCTAD Handbook of Statistics, www.unctad.org
In 2006, China remained the EU’s second largest trading partner and displaced the United
States as the largest source of EU imports. Chinese imports to the EU totaled
approximately €191 billion during that period, representing a year-on-year increase of
almost 21%. Likewise, EU exports to China increased by 22.5% to approximately €63
billion, accounting for overall bilateral trade of upwards of €254 billion. Whereas the EU
enjoyed a trade surplus with China at the beginning of the 1980s, trade relations are now
characterized by a sizeable and widening EU deficit with China (approximately €128
billion in 2006). This represents the EU's largest bilateral trade deficit. EU25’s exports in
services (2006) to China is 11 billion Euros, and imports from China is 8.8 billion Euros.
EU25’s trade in services (exports and imports) with China accounts for 3.2%. The share of
other countries in EU25’s trade in services is as follows: USA 34.8%, Switzerland 12.6%,
151
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Japan 4.7 %, Russia 3.1%, Canada 2.6%, Turkey 2.4%, Australia 2.2%, India 1.6%, South
Korea 1.5%, Mexico 1.0%, Taiwan 0.8%, and Israel 0.8%.18
One of the challenges facing the European Union is that EU25’s international trade in
services is more than the trade within the EU. Half of the total trade in services is realized
with the non-EU countries. Intratrade of services in the EU is insufficient from the view of
importance of services for the EU economy as a whole.
Another important issue is that a substantial amount of total intratrade is carried by the
EU15. Though the new members benefit from the intratrade of services, the contribution of
EU12 to the value of credits in intratrade of services is 179.6 billion Euros. When this
figure is compared with EU15’s credits, 420.3 billion Euros, it only constitutes 30% of the
credits for intratrade of services.
Table 2: Intratrade of Services, EU countries
EU27,
2006
EU25,
2006
EU15,
2003
EU27
credits
599
931.6
594
403.6
debits
566
573.9
561
218.9
net
33
357.6
33
184.6
EU25
credits
debits
net
587
884
440
946
554
949.5
433
494
32
934.9
7452
EU15
credits
debits
net
420
292
416
923
3369
Source: http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/extraction
Direct investment in services in the European Union realized by the EU27 countries
amount to 224.5 billion Euros (2006). EU15 countries made 201.5 billion Euros of
investment in the EU. Only 23 billion Euros of direct investment is realized by the EU12.
The share of the new members in the direct investment of services within the EU is only
10%.
Over the last decade, the share of intra-trade of services has increased somewhat, namely
from 3.3% of GDP in 1995 to 4.5% of GDP in 2004. One might argue that this is an
increase of over one third. However, the key point is rather that services trade amounts to
less than 5% of GDP whereas the sector contributes to over 60% of GDP. Less than 8% of
services output is actually traded within the EU-15 (the number would be very similar for
the EU25). Services are to a very large extent still a sheltered sector. Moreover, it seems
that in services the ratio of intra-EU exports to extra-EU exports has not increased at all
over the last decade, it remains at around 1.2. This implies that the expansion of services
trade was thus part of a global phenomenon, not a consequence of EU integration (Gros,
2007).
18
http://ec.europa.eu/trade/issues/bilateral/countries/
152
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 3: Direct Investment in Services, EU countries
million Euros
EU27, 2006
EU25, 2006
EU15, 2005
EU27
EU25
224 452
221 002
201 498
EU15
224 236
220 789
201 278
223 444
220 235
201 219
Source: http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/extraction.
Turkey’s total credits were 26.5 billion dollars and debits were 11.4 billion dollars in 2005.
Turkey’s net position in the trade of services was positive 14.2 billion dollars.19 In 2007,
Turkey’s total exports were 107.2 billion dollars and total imports were 170.1 billion
dollars. Credits in services trade amounted to 28.7 billion dollars and debits were 14.6
billion dollars.20 In two years, from 2005 to 2007, credits increased by 2.2 billion dollars
and debits increased by 3.2 billion dollars. This clearly shows that debits are increasing
more than credits. Tourism is the dominant subcategory in the trade of services.
Transportation, other services, and other business services follow tourism.
Table 4: International Trade in Services, Turkey
million
Exports
Imports
dollars, 2006
Transportation
4 052
Tourism
16 853
Financial
277
services
Construction
879
services
Other
289
business
services
Government
314
services
Other services
1 643
Total
24 307
3 989
2 743
524
0
724
1 034
1 754
10 768
Source: Turkish Central Bank, Balance of Payments,
www.tcmb.gov.tr/ucaylik/ua10/a92.pdf
It has been asserted that Turkey has advantages in tourism, transportation, logistics,
construction, consultancy, and engineering services. It has further been stated that the
barrier to the competitiveness of Turkey does not depend on Turkey’s incapability but is
due to the barrier of free establishment in the EU (Dervi et al., 2004).
In 2005, EU25’s imports from Turkey in services was 13.1 billion dollars.21 In 2006,
EU25’s imports from Turkey in services amounted to 10.5 billion Euros and EU25’s
exports to Turkey in services were 4.4 billion Euros.22 Due to the difficulty in obtaining
19
http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/extraction
www.dtm.gov.tr
21
http://www.wto.org/english/res_e/statis_e/its2007_e/its07_world_trade_dev_e.htm
22
http://ec.europa.eu/trade/issues/bilateral/countries/turkey
20
153
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
data for the subcategories of trade in services between Turkey and the EU, it can broadly
be stated that Turkey has an advantage over the EU in the trade of services. A through
assessment of services trade by composition is one of the shortcomings of this paper.
Conclusion
The insufficient share of intra-trade of services in the total trade of the EU should
constitute a solid basis for further liberalization of services in the EU. Some researchers
assert that this figure is due to the regulatory and other barriers among the member
countries. Yet some other claim that it is due to the low productivity of labour in services.
It is evident that some European member countries benefit from the trade in services far
more than the other member countries. New members, such as Hungary, Poland and
Republic of Czech also favour further liberalization of services.
The data clearly depicts that the issue of trade in services is beyond the domain of the
internal market due to the globalization process and the technological changes. Therefore,
it would be pervasive to treat the trade of services within the scope of single market. Single
market was for the goods and it served well for the economies of scale. Now, economies
of scope, where the services constitute the main part of it, bypass the geographies and
locations. It can be suggested that it would be much more realistic and non-blurring if the
European Union institutions treat the trade and liberalization of services within a global
perspective.
Turkey has advantages in the trade in services, namely, tourism, transportation, logistics,
consulting services and other business services. More promotion and awareness in the
importance of services are needed. A unique statistical database for the services would help
the scholars and researchers to make further analysis in this respect.
154
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
References
Breitenfellner, A. and Hildebrandt, A. (2006). High Employment with Low Productivity?
The Service Sector as a Determinant of Economic Development. Monetary Policy & the
Economy, 1/06, 110.
Dervi , K. Emerson, M., Gros, D., and Ülgen, S. (2004). The European Transformation of
Modern Turkey. Centre for European Studies, (pp. 75-76).
Granz W. (2005). Research in the Services Sector, (Final report). Fraunhofer Institut für
Arbeitswirtschaft und Organization, Stuttgart, July 14th, 2005, 1-3.
Gros, D. (2007). EU Services Trade: Where is the single market in services?. Centre for
European Policies, www.ceps.be
Kox, H., Lejour, A., Montizaan, R. (2004). The free movement of services within the EU.
CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis, 17-25, retrieved from
http://www.cpb.nl/eng/pub/cpbreeksen/document/69/doc69.pdf (April 2008).
Nielsen, P. (2005). Development of Services Sector Statistics at a cross road?, 20th
Voorburg Group meeting on Services Statistics, Helsinki, Finland.
State Planning Institute (2006). 9th Development Plan, Ankara: (p. 33).
Urbanski, T. (2007). Main features of the services sector in the EU. Eurostat, Statistics in
focus, 19, 1-6.
155
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Short Term Overreaction Effect: Evidence on the Turkish Stock Market
Gülin Vardar
Izmir University of Economics, Turkey
Berna Okan
Izmir University of Economics, Turkey
Abstract
In this paper, we empirically examine the short term overreaction effect in the Istanbul
Stock Exchange using daily stock data from January 1999 to December 2003. The study
period covers the pre- and post- Turkish financial crisis period. Consistent with other prior
studies on other markets, we find evidence of short term overreaction effect in the Istanbul
Stock Exchange prior and post financial crisis. Our analysis highlights that stocks that
display a large price increase (winners) show an evidence of overreaction in the short run,
however, stocks that display a large price decline (losers) indicate no significant evidence.
We also find the price reversal for winners in pre-crisis period is more pronounced than in
post-crisis period. These results indicate a diminished degree of overreaction after the
crisis period which may be attributable to the behaviors of traders.
156
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Introduction
The Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH) states that all relevant information is completely
reflected in the price of financial assets and that change in the prices of financial assets can
not be predicted, therefore, failing to provide abnormal profit opportunities. However, in
recent studies, EMH has been challenged by the documentation of “Overreaction
Hypothesis” which shows that past prices can forecast future movements in prices and
those profitable investment strategies can be created to take advantage of overreaction
effect. Therefore, further studies of the overreaction phenomena have significant
implications not only for financial academics and practitioners but also for the investors.
While the efficiency of stock markets has been studied mostly for developed markets, the
analysis of the efficiency on emerging stock markets has begun in recent years.
Empirically, the studies have found important differences among markets whether they are
classified as either emerging or developed markets which reveal that abnormal returns
following the shocks are significantly larger for emerging markets. Some of the reasons
behind the significant abnormal returns in those markets are the globalization effects, the
removal of trade barriers and the advance in the communication technology. Therefore,
domestic and international investors can gain enormous benefits by diversifying their
portfolios in these markets.
Istanbul Stock Exchange (ISE), being established in 1986, has become one of the rapidly
growing emerging markets. As a leading emerging market, ISE, which is smaller, less
liquid and more volatile than developed markets has begun to suggest attractive investment
alternatives to investors all around the world. The participation of foreign investors in the
ISE has increased from 1.8 % in 1990 to 53.7 % in 1999 and reached to nearly above 75%
in 2008.
The main purpose of this paper is to contribute to the short term overreaction literature by
using daily return stock data of Istanbul Stock Exchange over the period of 1999-2003.
The reason of selecting this time period is to investigate the impact of the February 2001
Turkish financial crisis. As our data extends to the period of Turkish financial crisis, this
will provide a better understanding of the trading behaviors of investors before and after
the crisis. This paper contributes to the existing literature in some respects. First, this study
examines the overreaction hypothesis in an emerging market, ISE, while previous studies
generally have focused on developed markets. Second, we investigate individual company
stock price performance rather than the portfolio performance regarding pre- and postcrisis reaction.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section II gives brief review in this literature.
Then, the data and methodology are discussed in section III. Empirical results are
presented in the section IV and final section concludes.
Literature Review
All available information is fully reflected into prices of financial assets in
“informationally efficient” markets. Theoretically, abnormal returns cannot be earned by
using investment strategies based on available information. One of the potential challenge
for the “Efficient Market Hypothesis” is referred to as the ‘overreaction phenomena”
comes from DeBondt and Thaler (1985). They suggested, using U.S. data, which prior
157
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
losers over a long term period outperform prior winner over a subsequent holding period of
the same length of time, following the physiological study of Kahneman and Tversky
(1982), who argue that investors tend to overweight recent information and underweight
prior information.
More specifically, the strategy of buying the losers and short selling the winners will
produce abnormal profits in the long run. These profits, called as contrarian profits, are due
to the investors’ excessive optimist and pessimist reactions to information. Several studies
have examined the overreaction hypothesis in financial markets in both short term and
long-term horizons. Although the most recent studies have been based on the long-term
horizons, the evidence on the cause of long run returns reversals are conflicting. However,
there are a number of studies that attempt to reveal the evidence of the short-term return
reversals, which are more consistent in favor of overreaction. Moreover, investigating
short-term overreaction has advantages over the long-term overreaction tests. Lin (1988),
who examined the daily, weekly and monthly returns for Taiwan Stock Market found the
existence of overreaction. Brown and Harlow (1988) examined the overreaction issue by
using monthly data of CRSP-listed NYSE firms in the period of 1946 and 1983. While the
winners do not show any decline after the first month, the losers indicated large price
reversals. Zarowin (1989) presented the existence of stock market overreaction in the short
run by ranking the common stocks with respect to their performance during a given month
and concluded that the market was weak form inefficient in the short run. Atkins and Dyl
(1990) investigated the behavior of common stock prices in NYSE after a large price
change during a single trading day and provided evidence of overreaction, especially in the
case of price declines. Ferri and Chung-ki (1996) illustrated the evidence of overreaction
hypothesis in the S&P 500 index from 1962 to 1991 using daily data.
In one of the more recent studies, Larson and Madura (2003) studied NYSE stocks that
experienced a one-day price change over the period 1988 to 1998 and found overreaction
effect in response to uninformed events for gainers and under-reaction in both informed
and uninformed events for losers. Ma et. al. (2005) examined the overreaction hypothesis
by studying the price reversal behavior of NYSE and Nasdaq securities between 1996 and
1997. While they provide evidence of overreaction effects for both Nasdaq gainers and
losers, no such evidence is found for NYSE gainers and losers.
Overreaction hypothesis is also investigated in some of the international markets, which
are Spain (Alonso and Rubio (1990)), Canada (Kryzanowsky and Zhang (1992)), Australia
(Brailsford (1992)), UK (Clare and Thomas (1995)), Japan (Chang et al. (1995)), Hong
Kong (Akhigbe et al. 1998)), Brazil (DaCosta and Newton (1994), Richards (1997)), New
Zealand (Bowman and Iverson (1998)), China (Wang et al. (2004)), Greece (Anthoniou et.
al., 2005) and London (Spyrou et.al., 2007).
Data and Methodology
For the empirical analysis, daily closing prices of 190 stocks traded in one of the major
Turkish equity indices (ISE) are examined for the 4-year period between January 1999 and
December 2003. These sample data were obtained from the IBS. We divide the sample
period into two sub-periods. The whole sample period consists of 1216 trading days in
which the first consists of 500 trading days from January 5, 1999 through January 31, 2001
and the second period is composed of 716 trading days from February 1, 2001 through
158
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
December 31, 2003. We exclude some days in the sample period which have missing price
data.
To investigate the short-term overreaction effect, we firstly compute the raw return of
stocks on each day t (ri, t) as the difference between today’s and previous day’s closing
price (P) as follows:
=
−
−
(1)
−
Abnormal return for each stock on the two sub-periods is computed using a marketadjusted model1:
=
−
(2)
where ARi,t is the abnormal return on each stock i for day t; ri,t is the return of each stock i
on day t and E(ri,t ) is the expected return on each stock i for day t. The expected return is
assumed to be the return on the market index.
Based on the abnormal returns, winners and losers are selected for the two sub-periods. On
each sample day, the stock with the lowest return is called as the “loser” of that day and the
stock with the highest return is called as the “winner” of that day. Pre-crisis period sample
includes 485 winners and losers and post-crisis period sample includes 701 winners and
losers.
Finally, the abnormal returns for each loser and winner on each trading day from t= -7 and
t= +7 are computed and then the average abnormal returns for each loser and winner on
each trading day from t= -7 and t= +7 are cumulated over different days to calculate the
cumulative abnormal return:
=
+
∑
(3)
=−
Empirical Results
The average daily abnormal returns from t = -7 and t = +7 for the winners and losers in
pre- and post-crisis period are reported in Table 1 and 2 respectively. In those tables, day 0
indicates the day where a significant price change of the stocks occurs.
1
Strong (1992) discussed the strengths of the market-adjusted model.
159
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 1: Average Daily Abnormal Returns for ISE-100 Stocks that indicates a large
one day price increase or decrease within the period of January 5, 1999 through
January 31, 2001
1999-2001
Day(t) Abnormal Return
t-statistics
Abnormal Return
t-statistics
The Winner Sample (N=485)
The Loser Sample (N=485)
-7
0.581797
2.294814**
0.766884
2.784166***
-6
0.341884
1.330598
1.076951
3.781300***
-5
0.182781
0.703928
0.582405
2.126821**
-4
-0.062553
-0.252161
0.532439
1.981085**
-3
0.846486
3.410896***
1.477918
4.722299***
-2
0.717411
2.543642**
1.429111
4.001720***
-1
2.436467
6.466963***
1.052307
2.877353***
0
16.025264
21.803987***
-11.277304
-19.230200***
1
1.727013
4.459111***
-0.708542
-2.174070**
2
-0.136683
-0.415161
-0.382208
-1.393640
3
-0.715141
-2.309653**
-0.194723
-0.803960
4
0.089952
0.301570
-0.112319
-0.456530
5
0.186887
0.651885
-0.601330
-2.515440**
6
-0.158658
-0.558179
-0.244671
-0.976040
7
0.004440
0.016307
-0.360022
-1.543370
***Denotes significance at the 1% level (two-tailed test)
**Denotes significance at the 5% level (two-tailed test)
*Denotes significance at the 10% level (two-tailed test)
The average daily abnormal returns for the winners and losers in period 1999-2001 are
shown in Table1. In this table, the average daily abnormal returns obtained by the winners
are negative for three of the seven days following the large one day price increase.
However, the daily abnormal return on day t = 3 is statistically significant at the 5% level
even though on day t = 2 and t =6 not statistically significant. After the large price increase
which denotes day 0, the price reversal does not occur on the first day. However, the
reversals take place on day 3 as the market is not able to correct its previous information in
a timely manner. Moreover, significant positive abnormal returns obtained on days t = -3, t
= -2 and t =-1 are due to the information leakage.
The large negative return that occurs on day t = 0 is the result of the large decline in price.
As opposed to the winners, price reversals for losers can not be obtained in the pre-crisis
period which can be interpreted as no evidence of overreaction.
160
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 2: Average Daily Abnormal Returns for ISE-100 Stocks that indicates a large
one day price increase or decrease within the period of February 1, 2001 through
December 31, 2003
2001-2003
Abnormal Return
t-statistics
Abnormal Return
t-statistics
The Winner Sample (N=701)
The Loser Sample (N=701)
0.618897
3.400242***
1.041148
5.228637***
0.437705
2.376956**
1.027202
5.013088***
0.592522
3.346280***
1.183094
5.374692***
0.598463
3.160672***
1.424188
6.336834***
0.673227
3.369772***
1.895305
7.339178***
1.055852
4.978101***
1.714117
6.311741***
2.451450
9.040694***
1.443817
4.760019***
14.660618
26.308445***
-10.326258
-20.474300***
1.510407
4.823650***
-0.783581
-3.047420***
-0.256768
-0.982589
-0.548478
-2.523280**
-0.354136
-1.464886
-0.408084
-2.015040**
-0.538773
-1.658767*
-0.232604
-1.283380
-0.157455
-0.750889
-0.538020
-2.821920***
-0.265152
-1.313957
-0.435337
-2.366300**
-0.246704
-1.255414
-0.227266
-1.373060
***Denotes significance at the 1% level (two-tailed test)
**Denotes significance at the 5% level (two-tailed test)
*Denotes significance at the 10% level (two-tailed test)
Day(t)
-7
-6
-5
-4
-3
-2
-1
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
The average daily abnormal returns for the winners and losers in period 2001-2003 are
shown in Table 2. Consistent with the results in the pre-crisis period, we document the
evidence of overreaction for the winners but not for the losers in the post-crisis period.
After a large price increase for winners, a significant price reversals occur on day t = 4 at
10% level while the average daily abnormal returns are negative but not statistically
significant for six of the seven days following the day t = 0.
In both tables, we observed that positive daily abnormal returns during seven days
preceding the day of the large price decline are statistically significant at the % 1 and % 5
levels. This indicates that there is no information leakage in pre-event period for losers.
It is also interesting to note, from Figure 1 and 3, that cumulative abnormal returns earned
by stocks indicated a large increase in price during a single trading day for the period
surrounding the day of the price increase both in pre- and post-crisis period.
161
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Cumulative Abnormal Returns
Figure 1: Cumulative Abnormal Returns for 190 stocks that exhibited a large price
increase on day t = 0 within the period of January 5, 1999 through January 31, 2001
25
20
15
10
5
0
-7 -6 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
Event Days
Cumulative Abnormal Returns
Figure 2: Cumulative Abnormal Returns for 190 stocks that exhibited a large price
decrease on day t = 0 within the period of January 5, 1999 through January 31, 2001
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-7 -6 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
-4
-6
-8
Event Days
Figure 2 and 4 exhibits cumulative abnormal returns earned by stocks indicated a large
price decline during a single trading day for the period surrounding the day of the price
decline both in pre- and post-crisis period.
162
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Cumulative Abnormal Returns
Figure 3: Cumulative Abnormal Returns for 190 stocks that exhibited a large price
increase on day t = 0 within the period of February 1, 2001 through December 31,
2003
25
20
15
10
5
0
-7
-6
-5
-4
-3
-2
-1
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
Event Days
Figure 4: Cumulative Abnormal Returns for 190 stocks that exhibited a large price
decrease on day t = 0 within the period of February 1, 2001 through December 31,
2003
Cumulative Abnormal Returns
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-7
-6
-5
-4
-3
-2
-1
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
-4
-6
Event Days
The results obtained for the winners in pre- and post-crisis period indicates a significant
evidence of overreaction. (See Figure 1 and 3) However, as seen from the results in
Figures 2 and 4, the overreaction is not induced for losers both in pre- and post-crisis
period.
163
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
The analysis of the pre- and post-crisis period results reveals the impact of the Turkish
financial crisis, which caused a more volatile market. In this crisis period, the market is
expected to be less efficient and heavily overreact to bad news. Yet, the findings of this
study are rather surprising since the overreaction of the winners is more obvious in precrisis period than the post-crisis period. Moreover, the losers do not overreact significantly
to information before and after the crisis. These results indicate that the stock market is
more efficient than expected after the crisis, meaning that exhibiting less overreaction. To
avoid the risk during the crisis period, investors become more conservative toward bad
news and information. With the decrease of noise traders in the crisis, the importance of
overreaction also decreases. However, when investors receive good news and information,
the initial price increases in stocks encourage the noise traders to invest which leads to an
increase the magnitude of overreaction.
Conclusion
This paper highlights the empirical evidence of short term overreaction in the Turkish
stock market. It differs from the previous studies in that this study considers the impact of
the Turkish financial crisis by decomposing the whole sample into two sub periods, preand post-crisis period. We find that stocks that display a large price increase (winners)
show an evidence of overreaction in the shot run, however, stocks that display a large price
decline (losers) indicate no significant evidence. We also find the price reversal for
winners in pre-crisis period is more pronounced than in post-crisis period. These results
indicate a diminished degree of overreaction after the crisis period which may be
attributable to the behaviors of traders.
164
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
References
Akhigbe, A., Gosnell, T. and Harikumar, T. (1998). Winners and losers on NYSE: A reexamination using daily closing bid-ask spreads. Journal of Financial Research, 21, 53-64.
Alonso, A. & Rubio, G. (1990). Overreaction in the Spanish equity market. Journal of
Banking and Finance,14, 469–481.
Antoniou, A., Galariotis, E. C. and Spyrou, S.I. (2005). Contrarian profits and the
overreaction hypothesis: The case of the Athens Stock Exchange. European Financial
Management, 11, 71-98.
Atkins, A.B. & Dyl, E. (1990). Price reversals, bid–ask spreads, and market efficiency.
Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 25, 535–547.
Bowman, R.G. & Iverson, D. (1998). Short-run over-reaction in the New Zealand stock
market. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 6, 475–491.
Brailsford, T.(1992). A test for the winner–loser anomaly in the Australian equity market:
1958–1987. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 19, 225–241.
Brown, K.C. & Harlow, W.V. (1988). Market overreaction: Magnitude and intensity.
Journal of Portfolio Management, 14, 6–13.
Chang, R., McLeavey, D. and Rhee, S. (1995). Short-term abnormal returns of the
contrarian strategy in the Japanese stock market. Journal of Business Finance and
Accounting, 22, 1035–1048.
Clare, A. & Thomas, S. (1995). The overreaction hypothesis and the UK stock market.
Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 22, 961–973.
daCosta Jr., N.C.A., (1994). Overreaction in the Brazilian stock market. Journal of
Banking and Finance, 18, 633–642.
DeBondt, W. F M. and Thaler, R. (1985). Does the stock market overreact?. Journal of
Finance 40, 793-805.
Ferri, M.G. & Chung-ki, M. (1996). Evidence that the stock market overreacts and adjusts.
Journal of Portfolio Management, 22, 71-76.
Kahneman, D., and Tversky, A. (1982). Intuitive prediction: Biases and corrective
procedures. In D. Kahneman, P. Slovic and A. Tversky (Eds.). Judgment under
uncertainly: heuristics and biases, New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
Kryzanowski, L. & Zhang, H. (1992). The contrarian strategy does not work in Canadian
markets. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 27, 383–395.
165
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Larson, S.J. & Madura J. (2003). What drives stock price behavior following extreme oneday returns. Journal of Financial Research, 26, 113-128.
Lin , Y. T. (1988). The study of investors’ overreaction in Taiwan stock market. Security
Management, 6, 2-10.
Ma, Y., Tang, A.P., and Hasan, T., (2005). The stock price overreaction effect: evidence
on Nasdaq stocks. Quarterly Journal of Business and Economics, 44.
Richards, A. (1997). Winner–loser reversals in national stock market indices: Can they be
explained?. Journal of Finance, 52, 2129–2144.
Spyros, S., Kassimatis, K. and Galariotis, E.(2007). Short term overreaction, underreaction
and efficient reaction: Evidence from the London Stock Exchange. Applied Financial
Economics, 17, 221-235.
166
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Statistic Study of Banking Efficiency Ratios
Ioan Batrancea
Babes-Bolyai University, Romania
Larissa Batrancea
Babes-Bolyai University, Romania
Sorin Borlea
Babes-Bolyai University, Romania
Grigore Bace
Romanian National Bank, Romania
Objectives
In order for a more relevant financial-economic analysis, we realized a statistic processing
of data resulted from financial statements for the period 2001-2006. Essentially, the
statistic study has concentrated around “RETURN ON EQUITY” (ROE) indicator, which
in our opinion, is the main financial efficiency criterion. The number of values registered
for each statistic variable is relevant, taking into consideration that the data from the six
annual balance sheets are highlighted at quarterly level.
Data and methods
Due to presentation reasons, which correspond to statistic links, we shall use the following
symbols for the financial-economic indicators from the annual financial statements:
ROE - Financial Profitability Ratio;
RACADEPA - Assets Covering with Attracted Deposits Ratio;
DOBACTIV - Active Interest;
DOBPASIV - Passive Interest;
GAP - Gap between Active and Passive Interest;
FDCLNEBA - Funds attracted from non-banking customers;
DATORII – Total Attracted Funds;
FLUXNUM - Total Cash-Flow;
PROVR_CH - Provisions;
167
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
CREANTE - Receivables;
DATORII - Debts;
RACTLICH - Current Assets Ratio;
LUXFIN - Financing Cash-Flow;
GESTRLIC - Liquidity Risk Financial Administration;
FLUXINV - Investment Cash-Flow;
INDSOLV1 - Solvency 1Indicator;
CAPNIV1 - Level 1 Equity;
CAPNIV2 - Level 2 Equity;
CAPNIV3 - Level 3 Equity.
In the following, we shall analyze some of the most significant statistic links which have
been identified at many Romanian banks level, based on the data from the annual financial
statements, during the period 2001-2006.
Results
Another factor which influences ROE variance by almost 50% is the ratio of assets
covering with attracted deposits (RACADEPA). The following information is significant
in this issue:
The regression result for the dependent variable: ROE
R = 0.7228; R2 = 0.5224; R2adjusted = 0.4985;
F(1.20) = 21.883; p < 0.00014; standard estimation error: 1.5493
coef. ai
a0
RACADEPA
37.03123
-0.42407
St. ERR
For ai
7.499546
0.090655
t(20)
4.93720
-4.67790
p-level
0.000079
0.000145
CORRELATIONS
RACADEPA
ROE
RACADEPA
1.00
-0.72
ROE
-0.72
1.00
168
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
COVARIANCE
RACADEPA
13.9
-5.9
RACADEPA
ROE
ROE
-5.9
4.8
The econometric model between ROE and RACADEPA is:
ROEt = 37.03 – 0.42 . RACADEPAt + εt
Which means that for an increase by one percent of RACADEPA, ROE decreases by 0.42
%.
Figure1: ROE and RACADEPA Correlation
Scatterplot (DATE.STA 27v*24c)
y=37,031-0,424*x+eps
7
6
5
ROE
4
3
2
1
0
-1
74
76
78
80
82
84
86
88
90
92
RACADEPA
The statistic links between the ROE variance and the following elements are interesting:
active interest, passive interest, and the difference between them (GAP). In the following,
we present information which resulted from data processing, in order to analyze their
significance.
The regression result for the dependent variable: ROE
R = 0.9108; R2 = 0.8296; R2adjusted = 0.8211;
F (1.20) = 97.419; p < 0.0000; standard estimation error: 0.9853
169
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
coef. ai
a0
DOBACTIV
-2.63217
0.14873
St. ERR
For ai
0.507519
0.015069
t(20)
-5.18635
9.87013
p-level
0.000045
0.000000
CORRELATIONS:
DOBACTIV
1.00
0.91
DOBACTIV
ROE
ROE
0.91
1.00
There is a direct link between ROE and DOBACTIV, meaning that with an increase by one
percent of active interest, ROE will increase by an average 0.14 %. DOBACTIV influences
ROE variance by 82%. Moreover, there is a high level of correlation between the two
indicators.
In order to analyze the link between ROE and passive interest we use the information
below.
The regression result for the dependent variable: ROE
R = 0.9066; R2 = 0.8219; R2adjusted = 0.8180
F(1.20) = 92.349; p < 0.0000; standard estimation error: 0.94596
coef. ai
a0
DOBPASIV
-2.19204
0.18426
St. ERR
For ai
0.479001
0.019174
t(20)
-4.57628
9.60985
p-level
0.000183
0.000000
The link between ROE and DOBPASIV is almost equivalent to that previously studied,
between ROE and DOBACTIV. In the last case, the model is the following:
ROEt = -2.19 + 0.18. DOBPASIVt + εt
This means that ROE variance is slightly sensitive to DOBPASIV variance (a1 = 0.18 %).
Beside this, both the correlation level and the percent through which the factor explains
ROE variance are almost the same.
170
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Figure2: ROE and DOBPASIV Correlation
Scatterplot (DATE.STA 27v*24c)
y=-2,192+0,184*x+eps
7
6
5
ROE
4
3
2
1
0
-1
4
10
16
22
28
34
40
DOBPASIV
ROE variance in correspondence with GAP can be analyzed as following:
The regression result for the dependent variable: ROE
R = 0.7313; R2 = 0.5349; R2adjusted = 0.5116;
F(1.20) = 23.002; p < 0.00011; standard estimation error: 1.5290
coef. ai
a0
GAP
-2.02471
0.47868
St. ERR
For ai
0.897001
0.099808
t(20)
-2.25720
4.79603
p-level
0.035337
0.000110
CORRELATIONS
GAP
ROE
GAP
1.00
0.73
ROE
0.73
1.00
171
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
COVARIANCES
GAP
11.2
5.5
GAP
ROE
ROE
5.85
4.79
The difference between active and passive interest explains by 51% ROE variance.
Although there is a strong correlation between the two indicators, the link between them is
the following:
ROEt = -2.02 + 0.47 . GAPt + εt
With an increase by one percent of the gap between the two interests, the financial
profitability ratio increases by 0.47 %.
Figure 3: ROE and GAP Correlation
Scatterplot (DATE.STA 27v*24c)
y=-2,025+0,479*x+eps
7
6
5
ROE
4
3
2
1
0
-1
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
GAP
Another factor which influences ROE variance is represented by the funds attracted from
non-banking customers. The effect analysis is conducted based upon the following
information:
The regression result for the dependent variable: ROE
R = 0.7167; R2 = 0.5137; R2adjusted = 0.4849;
F(1.20) = 21.233; p < 0.00017; standard estimation error: 1.5634
172
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
coef. ai
a0
FDCLNEBA
6.481126
-0.000405
St. ERR
For ai
1.033644
0.000088
t(20)
6.27017
-4.59711
p-level
0.000004
0.000175
CORRELATIONS
FDCLNEBA
1.00
-0.72
FDCLNEBA
ROE
ROE
-0.72
1.00
The model which relates the two variables has the following structure:
ROEt = 6.48 – 0.000405. FDCLNEBAt + εt
It is observed that for an increase by a million lei of the funds attracted from non-banking
customers, the financial profitability ratio decreases by an average 0.00405 %. There is a
high enough correlation between the two indicators (ρ = -0.72). Based upon the data above,
it is observed that FDCLNEBA factor influences ROE variance by 49%. Obviously, there
are also many other factors which influence ROE variance.
Figure 4: ROE and FDCLNEBA Correlation
Scatterplot (DATE.STA 27v*24c)
y=6,481-0*x+eps
7
6
5
ROE
4
3
2
1
0
-1
2000
6000
10000
14000
18000
22000
FDCLNEBA
The total funds attracted by the bank (DATORII) represent another factor which influences
ROE variance. For the analysis we take into consideration the following information:
The regression result for the dependent variable: ROE
R = 0.6363; R2 = 0.4049; R2adjusted = 0.3751;
173
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
F(1.20) = 13.609; p < 0.00145; standard estimation error: 1.7295
coef. ai
a0
DATORII
St. ERR
For ai
1.364906
0.000092
6.831070
-0.000338
t(20)
5.00479
-3.68898
p-level
0.000068
0.001454
CORRELATIONS
DATORII
1.00
-0.64
DATORII
ROE
ROE
-0.64
1.00
The link between the two variables is:
ROEt = 6. 83 – 0.000338. DATORIIt + εt
It is observed that the DATORII influence effect upon ROE is almost the same as in the
case of the FDCLNEBA factor. For an increase by one million lei of DATORII factor,
profitability ratio decreases by 0.000338 %. The accounting effect can be converted to a
more convenient form, if DATORII factor is transformed in billion lei. Only 37% of ROE
variance is explained through DATORII. Between the two indicators, the correlation level
is above average, ρ = -0.64.
Figure 5: ROE and DATORII Correlation
Scatterplot (DATE.STA 27v*24c)
y=6,831-0*x+eps
7
6
5
ROE
4
3
2
1
0
-1
6000
10000
14000
18000
22000
26000
DATORII
174
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Possible influences of factors which can influence ROE variance are also important for
study. In this way, we analyzed the following correlations which allow us to quantify one
factor variance effect upon others. In order to study the correlation between DATORII and
FDCLNEBA we use the following information:
The regression result for the dependent variable: DATORII
R = 0.9688; R2 = 0.9385; R2adjusted = 0.9358;
F(1.22) = 336.27; p < 0.0000; standard estimation error: 1047.8
coef. ai
a0
FDCLNEBA
2834.793
1.036
St. ERR
For ai
680.9076
0.0565
t(20)
4.16326
18.33759
p-level
0.000405
0.000000
CORRELATIONS
FDCLNEBA
1.00
0.97
FDCLNEBA
DATORII
DATORII
0.97
1.00
The interaction between the two variables can be studied with the help of the model:
DATORIIt = 2834.793 + 1.036 . FDCLNEBAt + εt
This means that if funds which are attracted from non-banking customers increase
by one million, then debts increase by 1.036 millions. FDCLNEBA explain DATORII
variance by 53%. It is observed that there is a high correlation level between the two
indicators, ρ = 0.97.
Figure 6: DATORII and FDCLNEBA Correlation
Scatterplot (DATE.STA 27v*24c)
y=2834,793+1,036*x+eps
26000
22000
DATORII
18000
14000
10000
6000
2000
6000
10000
14000
18000
22000
FDCLNEBA
175
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
The analysis of the link between active (passive) interest and funds which are attracted
from non-banking customers makes the object of an interesting study. The dependence
between DOBACTIV and FDCLNEBA is based on the following:
The regression result for the dependent variable: FDCLNEBA
R = 0.6524; R2 = 0.4257; R2adjusted = 0.3996;
F(1.22) = 16.310; p < 0.00055; standard estimation error: 2997.6
coef. ai
a0
DOBACTIV
St. ERR
For ai
1580.083
47.960
17330.79
-193.69
t(20)
10.96828
-4.03855
p-level
0.000000
0.000549
CORRELATIONS
DOBACTIV
1.00
-0.65
DOBACTIV
FDCLNEBA
FDCLNEBA
-0.065
1.00
DOBACTIV influence upon FDCLNEBA can be summarized in the following model:
FDCLNEBAt = 17330.79 – 193.69 . DOBACTIVt + εt
If the active interest increases by 1%, then the funds attracted from the non-banking
customers decrease by 193.69 million lei. FDCLNEBA variance is explained through the
DOBACTIV variance by 40%. The correlation level between the two indicators is: ρ = 0.65.
Figure 7: FDCLNEBA and DOBACTIV Correlation
Scatterplot (DATE.STA 27v*24c)
y=17330,79-193,69*x+eps
22000
FDCLNEBA
18000
14000
10000
6000
2000
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
50
DOBACTIV
176
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
The correlation between FDCLNEBA and DOBPASIV is studied based on the information
below.
The regression result for the dependent variable: FDCLNEBA
R = 0.6389; R2 = 0.4082; R2adjusted = 0.3813;
F(1.22) = 15.178; p < 0.00078; standard estimation error: 3042.9
coef. ai
a0
DOBPASIV
St. ERR
For ai
1460.525
60.017
16597.,30
-233.82
t(20)
11.36392
-3.89590
p-level
0.000000
0.000777
CORRELATIONS
DOBPASIV
1.00
-0.64
DOBPASIV
FDCLNEBA
FDCLNEBA
-0.64
1.00
The econometric model which links the two variables is the following:
FDCLNEBAt = 16597.30 – 233.82 . DOBPASIVt + εt
which means that, for an increase by one percent of the passive interest, an average
decrease by 233.82 million lei of funds which are attracted from non-banking customers is
registered. Passive interest explains the variance of these funds by 38%. Correlation level
between the two indicators is of -0.64.
Figure 8: FDCLNEBA and DOBPASIV Correlation
Scatterplot (DATE.STA 27v*24c)
y=16597,3-233,818*x+eps
22000
FDCLNEBA
18000
14000
10000
6000
2000
4
10
16
22
28
34
40
DOBPASIV
177
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Conclusions
Although ROE is influenced by many factors, a study concerning ROE variance regarding
various factors, in the same time, cannot be conducted. This is also observed from the
independent analysis of influence factors which emphasize a strong co linearity
phenomenon.
References
Cade E. – Banking Risks, Fitzroy Dearborn Publishers, Chicago, 1999
Crouhy M., Galai D., Mark R. – Risk Management, McGraw-Hill, New York, 2001
Fabrozzi F.J, Petersen P.P. – Financial Management & Analysis, John Wiley &Sons, Inc.,
USA, 2003
Johnston J., Dinardo J., Econometric Methods, Fourth Edition, the McGraw – Hill
Companies, Inc., New York, 1997
Needles B.E. Jr., Anderson H.R., Caldwell J.C., Principles of Accounting, Houghton
Mifflin Company, Boston, 1987.
178
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
The Determinants of Exchange Rate Regimes in Emerging Market
Economies
Mehmet Güçlü
Ege University, Turkey
Abstract
The choice of exchange rate regime has become one of the most important issues one more
time in many economies after the financial crises in recent years. In the wake of the
financial crises, many countries, especially emerging market economies, opted for floating
exchange rate regimes by forsaking the pegged regimes. Consequently, an old debate on
the choice and determinants of exchange rate regimes has been triggered. Economists have
started to debate what appropriate exchange rate regime for an economy is. When the
tendency in recent years is taken into consideration, the choice of exchange rate regime of
countries, especially emerging economies, needs to be analyzed. To do this, in this paper,
we attempt to uncover how emerging market economies choose their exchange rate
regimes. In other words, we try to find the economic and political factors underlying the
choice of exchange rate regimes. The study includes 25 emerging market economies over
the period 1970-2006. We use random effect ordered probit model in order to find the long
run economic and political determinants of exchange rate regimes for emerging economies.
The determinants of both the de jure and de facto exchange regimes are empirically
analyzed in the paper.
179
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Introduction
Following the financial crises in recent decade, many countries switched from one
exchange rate regime to another (mostly rigid one to more flexible one). It has fueled the
old debate on the choices and determinants of exchange rate regimes. Economists have
started to argue what appropriate exchange regime for an economy is once more. Over the
past 40 years, economists have developed various answers to this question. The first
contribution to the debate came from optimum currency area (OCA) theory. It explains that
how some macroeconomic aggregates of a country affect flexibility of an exchange rate
regime to be adopted by that country. In the meanwhile, regime choices have also been
discussed in terms of optimal stabilization policy, monetary policy credibility and currency
crises. Since the second half of 1990s, the empirical literature (Edwards, 1996; Breger et
al., 2000) has tended to explain the role of political and institutional variables in regime
choices. The empirical studies using political variables generally say that there is a
negative correlation between political instability and exchange rate flexibility. The last
contribution to the debate was made by Calvo and Reinhart with fear of floating in 2000. It
has brought about to realize that there is a serious difference between de jure and de facto
exchange rate regimes. The economists say that owing to fear of floating, some
macroeconomic variables affect choices of regimes in an opposite direction to what the
previous theories say. Besides, fear of floating creates a difference between what countries
say and what countries do. Because of the difference between the de jure and de facto
exchange regimes, the de facto regimes are also taken into account in this paper.
In order to explain the determinants of exchange rate regimes, empirical researchers have
applied theoretical guidelines to the observed choices of exchange rate regimes. In doing
this, most studies have employed the de jure regimes that the governments announce,
while few studies have used the de facto regimes that they actually pursue. Until recently,
the distinction between de jure and de facto regimes has mostly been ignored in the
literature. The studies by Gosh et al. (1997), and Levy-Yeyati and Sturzenegger (1999,
2005), and Clavo and Reinhart (2000) developed some classification methods to determine
type of exchange rate regime of a country in a specific year or period. They have reached
that there was a serious difference between the de jure and de facto exchange rate regimes.
Although why countries put into effect exchange rate regimes different from their official
announcements remains a puzzle in the literature, it appears that the de facto classifications
are more reliable than the de jure classifications.
Although there are many studies on the determinants of exchange rate regimes, there are
no studies analyzing especially emerging market economies at least as far as we know.
With this motivation, we analyze emerging market economies in this paper. Since most of
the papers haven’t used panel estimation method and / or disregarded the panel
characteristics of data, their results may be misleading. In order to overcome this problem,
we use random effect panel probit model in analyzing emerging market economies. The
rest of paper is organized as fallows. Section 2 presents the literature review. In section 3
and 4, the data and estimation method are explained respectively. The empirical results are
presented in the next section. The paper results in conclusion in section 6.
Literature Review
The empirical findings on the determinants of exchange rate regimes are numerous and
controversial. The reason for the differences among the findings mostly depends on the
180
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
country samples taken into consideration, time periods, regime classifications used in the
analyses, estimation methods and assumptions of econometric models.
As stated before, the econometric methods and regime classifications used in the papers are
different from each other. Thus, it creates different results. For instance, some of the
studies (Edwards, 1998; Berger et. al; 2000; and Meon and Rizzo, 2002) used a simple
binary structure to classify exchange rate regimes into either fixed or flexible ones while
the others (Poirson, 2001; Zhou, 2003; and Von Hagen and Zhou, 2007) used an orderedchoice or multinomial-choice structure in order to classify the regimes. Besides, the studies
also differs form each other in terms of estimation methods. A commonly used estimation
method in the papers (Heller, 1978; Holden et el., 1979; Melvin, 1985; Edwards, 1998;
Rizzo, 1998; Poirson, 2001; and Juhn and Mauro, 2002) is cross section analysis. Due to
technical difficulties in the estimation of panel data models, especially due to the heavy
computational burden of numerical integrations, panel data models are rarely implemented
in the literature. Few of the studies in the literature (Zhou, 2003; Kato and Uctum, 2005,
Von Hagen and Zhou 2007) employed panel data models in order to empirically analyze
the determinants of exchange rate regimes.
The studies on the determinants of exchange rate regimes largely consist of the papers
including the developing countries ( Rizzo, 1998; Breger et. al, 2000; Poirson, 2001; Zhou
2003; Von Hagen and Zhou, 2005, Bleaney and Francisco, 2005); or both the developing
and developed countries (Meon and Rizzo, 2002; Juhn and Mauro 2002; Kato and Uctum,
2005, Levy-Yeyati and Sturzenegger, 2007). A few of the paper (Collins, 1996;
Papaioannou, 2003; Markiewic, 2006) considered specific country groups such as Latin
American countries, Central American countries, transition economies and etc. In the
existing literature, as far as we know, there are no studies focused on emerging market
economies. This motivates us to analyze emerging economies.
Most studies considered some of the optimum currency area variables, such as trade
openness, size of economy, degree of economic development and geographical
concentration of trade. In addition, some studies also included such macroeconomic
variables as inflation, foreign exchange reserves, domestic credit, real exchange rate, and
terms of trade. Also, a few studies contained political or institutional variables.
When the results of previous studies are considered, no results appear to be reasonably
robust to changes in country coverage, sample period, estimation method, and exchange
rate regime classification. For instance, trade openness is positively associated with the
probability of adopting a flexible regime in the papers by Dreyer, 1978; Bernard and
Leblang, 1999; Poirson, 2001; Juhn and Mauro, 2002; Von Hagen and Zhou, 2005),
whereas it is negatively associated with the probability of adopting a flexible regime in the
papers by Melvin, 1985; Rizzo, 1998; Berger et. al., 2000; and Meon, and Rizzo, 2002).
Likewise, size of economy (Gross Domestic Product) is found to be positively associated
with floating regimes in almost all studies, but not always significantly. Economic
development (GDP per capita) is found to be significantly associated with floating regimes
by four studies (Holden et. al.,1979; Savvides, 1990; Edwards, 1996, and Von Hagen and
Zhou, 2005) significantly associated with fixed regimes by three studies ( Honkapojha and
Pikkarainen, 1994; Edwards, 1999; Rizzo, 1998) and not significantly associated with any
particular regime by another two studies (Collins, 1996, and Poirson, 2001). Inflation is
always positively and significantly associated with floating except for one study (Von
Hagen and Zhou, 2005). The similar results are valid for the other variables (the other
181
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
macroeconomic, political and institutional variables). This suggests that the
macroeconomic, political and institutional variables are not robust predictors of exchange
rate regime choice. On the other hand, it doesn’t mean this denies the potential importance
certain variables for specific groups of countries, in certain time periods, or across some of
the regime categories.
Data Description
All series are annual and cover the years 1970 to 2006. Our analysis takes into
consideration 25 emerging market economies1. The World Development indicators and
International Financial Statistic are main sources for most of the independent variables. All
the political variables come from Database of Political Institution-2006. The variable
representing capital account restriction (CAR) is taken the paper by Prasad, et. al. (2003).
Based on theoretical suggestions and empirical findings, we take into consideration three
groups of potential exchange rate regime determinants: OCA fundamentals,
macroeconomic aggregates, and political and institutional features. The exact construction
of data and data sources are reported in the Appendix I. The descriptive statistics of data
and correlation matrix of explanatory variables are presented in the Appendix II and III
respectively. The explanatory variables, their symbols and definitions are as follows:
For OCA fundamentals, we include trade openness (OPENNESS, measured as imports
plus exports as a share of GDP), geographical trade concentration (GEOGTRADE,
measured by the share of the largest trade partner in total trade), inflation differential
(INFLATION, measured as USA inflation minus domestic inflation), size of economy
(GPD, measured by gross domestic product in logarithm), and level of economic
development (GDPpercapita, measured by log of GDP per capita). The OCA theory says
that more open economies want to adopt less flexible regimes while larger economies and
economies with higher level of GDP per capita want to adopt more flexible regimes.
For macroeconomic aggregates, we employ current account deficit or surplus (CA,
measured as current account deficit/surplus as a share of GDP), de facto capital account
openness (CAOPENNESS; measured as sum of the absolute value of inward and outward
gross capital as a ratio of GDP) , reserves (RESERVES, measured as total reserves as a
ratio of Imports) , rate of growth of M2 (M2GROWTH, measured as annual growth rate of
money plus quasi money), and terms of trade (TOT, measured as standard deviation of
annual percentage change of terms of trade). The economic theory suggests that high
reserves are associated with a fixed regime.
In an attempt to reflect the political and institutional features, we consider capital account
restriction (CAR), period of duration of chief executive in office (YRSOFFC), a variable
showing that executive parties have an absolute majority in assembly (MAJORITY), and a
variable representing whether executive party is nationalist (NATINALIST) or not. All the
OCA and macroeconomic variables are lagged one period to avoid potential endogeneity
problems. Most of the previous studies imply that there is a negative relationship between
political stability and flexibility of an exchange rate regime.
1
While determining emerging market economies, we use Morgan Stanley Emerging Index. This index
includes 26 emerging economies. Owing to lack of data on Thailand, we exclude this country. The countries
considered in this paper are Argentina, Brazil, Chile, China, Colombia, Czech Republic, Egypt, Hungary,
India, Indonesia, Israel, Jordan, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Morocco, Pakistan, Peru, Philippines, Poland,
Russia, South Africa, Sri Lanka, Thailand, and Turkey.
182
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
As a dependent variable, the de facto classification called natural classification by Reinhart
and Rogoff (2003) and the de jure classification based on the IMF’s classification are used.
Natural classification is coded as follows2: 1 for pegged regimes, 2 for limited flexibility
arrangements, 3 for managed floating, 4 for freely floating, and 5 freely falling. Freely
falling is a new category introduced by the authors that indicates high inflation period in
which annual inflation rate is higher than 40 %. We also use the more detailed version of
natural classification including the fifteen different regimes. Since natural classification
classifies the regimes until the year 2001, the de facto classification is used in the estimated
for the period 1970-2001. As a dependent variable, the new IMF exchange rate
classification (the de jure classification) that has been in use since 1999 is employed in the
analysis for the years 1999-2006, too. The de jure exchange rate regimes of countries are
taken from the various IMF Annual Reports. In this classification the least flexible regime
takes the lowest value while the most flexible regime takes the highest value: 1 for no
separate legal tender, 2 for currency board, 3 other conventional fixed peg, 4 for pegged
exchange rates within horizontal bands, 5 crawling bands, 6 for exchange rates within
crawling bands, 7 for managed floating, and 8 for independently floating. In addition, we
combine the IMF classifications before and after 1999 and construct a new dependent
variable over the period 1996 to 20063.
Estimation Strategy
In this section, we present the econometric model which is applied to test the determinants
of exchange rate regimes in emerging economies for the period 1970-2006. We use a
random effect ordered probit model for an unbalanced panel of 25 emerging market
economies. We describe the choices of exchange rate regimes in our sample using a
discrete variable yit, which takes a value of yit = 1 if the least flexible regime selected by
country i in year t, and yit = J for the most flexible regime. This choice based on the latent
variable y*it, which is a function of the variables discussed above. A larger value of the
latent variable indicates that a more flexible regime is desirable for the country and period
under consideration. Given the discrete nature of regime choices, we assume that a country
chooses the least flexible regime, yit = 1, if latent variable is below a certain threshold, y*it
≤ m0. Similarly, the most flexible regime is chosen, yit = J, if the latent variable is above
another threshold, mj-1 < y*it, with m0 < mj-1.
2
Reinhart and Rogoff (2003) classify exchange rate regimes into 15 and 6 subcategories. The last categories
both in 15-way and 6-way classifications don’t represent a exchange rate regime, and denote missing data
category. So we exclude these categories from the classifications and regard them as 14-way and 5-way
classifications in this paper.
3
The old IMF exchange rate classification before 1999 divides the exchange rate regimes into four
categories: (1) pegged to single currency or currency basket, (2) limited flexibility, (3) managed floating, and
(4) independent float. When we combine the old and new IMF classifications, categories 1 and 2 in the old
classification are regarded as other conventional fixed pegs and exchange rates within crawling bands in the
new classification respectively. Similarly, category 3 and 4 are received as managed floating, and
independently floating in the new classification respectively.
183
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
yit =
if y*it ≤ m0
1
2 if m0 < y*it ≤ m1
3 if m1 < y*it ≤ m2
.
.
.
.
if m j −1 < y*it
j
where the ms is unknown cut point parameters (thresholds).
The estimated equation for the model is equation below.
y*it = β ' X it + ε it
for i = 1, 2, 3, …….N, and t = 0, 1, …..Ti
where Xit, β, t and i represent are a vector of explanatory variables, a vector of coefficients,
country and time respectively4. The estimates of the coefficients of the vector Xit and of the
thresholds, i.e, m1 < m2 < m3….<mj-1 are obtained by maximizing the likelihood function
by using the quadratic hill climbing algorithm.
Empirical Results
In this section, we present the results of random effect ordered probit analyses, conducted
by using the unbalanced panel data sets. We estimate several specifications both for the de
jure and de facto classifications. The results of estimations are presented in Table 1. We
estimate the four regressions varying across regime classifications and time periods. The
results of the first and the second regression are obtained for the period 1970-2001 by
using the 5-way classification (RR 5), and the 14-way classification (RR 14) developed by
Reinhart and Rogoff (2003) as a dependent variable. The third and fourth regressions are
estimated by using the new IMF classification and the combined IMF classification
constructed by us respectively.
4
Note that the panel is unbalanced as Ti varies across i.
184
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 1: Random Effect Ordered Regression Results For Emerging Economies
1970–2001
Variable
GDP
GDPpercapita
OPENNESS
INFLATION
GEOGTRADE
CAGDP
CAOPENNESS
RESERVES
M2GROWTH
TOT
CAR
YRSOFFC
NATIONALIST
MAJORITY
Observations
Log-likelihood
LR χ 2 (14) c
RR 5
0.0555
(0.0838)
0.9409 ***
(0.1154)
0.0094 ***
(0.0032)
-0.0014 ***
(0.0005)
-0.0104 *
(0.0059)
0.0128
(0.0163)
0.0016
(0.0129)
-0.2864 ***
(0.0394)
0.0044 ***
(0.0011)
0.1629 ***
(0.0287)
0.7105 ***
(0.1967)
.-0.044516 ***
(0.0082)
-2.4600 ***
(0.6286)
0.0298
(0.1812)
1970–2001
RR 14
0.2176 ***
(0.0797)
0.5272 ***
(0.1066)
0.0011
(0.0027)
-0.0013 ***
(0.0005)
-0.0082
(0.0055)
0.0061
(0.0152)
0.0017
(0.0119)
-0.1922 ***
(0.0352)
0.0042 ***
(0.0010)
0.0514 *
(0.0294)
0.4632 ***
(0.1784)
-0.0307 ***
(0.0070)
-2.8011 ***
(0.5783)
0.0044
(0.1896)
1999–2006
a
IMF1
0.1810
(0.3624)
0.9347 ***
(0.3514)
0.0054
(0.0076)
0.0338
(0.0223)
0.0898 ***
(0.0272)
0.0503
(0.0537)
0.1045 *
(0.0554)
-0.0474
(0.1218)
-0.0343 *
(0.0196)
0.2489 ***
(0.0721)
-0.3131
(0.4675)
0.0038
(0.0421)
-0.3529
(1.1684)
-0.7600
(0.4642)
1996–2006
IMF2b
0.6285 ***
(0.2021)
-0.7449 ***
(0.2040)
0.0002
(0.0045)
0.0171
(0.0142)
0.0612 ***
(0.0177)
-0.0174
(0.0299)
0.1044 ***
(0.0299)
-0.0376
(0.0781)
-0.0202
(0.0129)
0.1397 ***
(0.0417)
0.0775
(0.3056)
-0.0084
(0.0185)
-0.5481
(0.7083)
0.3492
(0.3594)
448
-632.0558
448
-361.4228
112
-84.1975
154
-152.9535
18.125
23.304
43.0722
39.7188
Notes: The figures in parentheses are standard deviations.
* z statistics are significant at the 10 % level; ** significant at the 5 % level; *** significant at the 1 % level.
a
: The IMF1 represents the IMF classification since 1999.
b
: The IMF2 is constructed by combining the IMF classifications before and after 1999.
: The χ value is defined as 2 (L1-L0), where the L0 is the value of log-likelihood function with only the
constant term, and L1 is the value of the log-likelihood function when all the explanatory variables are
included.
c
2
A positive sign of a coefficient means that an increase in the associated variable raises the
probability of adopting a flexible exchange rate regime. Most of the signs of optimum
currency variables in the first and the second regressions are found as expected. For
example, the size of economy, level of development (geographical concentration of trade)
are expected to have a positive (negative) sign and their signs are found to be positive
(negative). Although the sign of openness is expected to be negative, it is found to be
185
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
positive. In contrast to the variables mentioned above, inflation affects negatively the
probability of selecting a flexible exchange rate regime. Although most of the signs are as
expected, the size of economy in the regression I and, OPENNESS and GEOGTRADE in
the regression II are statistically insignificant. MAJORITY is positive, but insignificant in
both the two regressions.
RESERVES, YRSOFFC and NATIONALIST are negatively and significantly associated
with a flexible regime while M2GROWTH, TOT, CAR are positively and significantly
associated with a flexible regime. The result related to YRSOFFC says that political
stability is in favor of adopting a fixed regime. Like YRSOFFC, the sign of
NATIONALIST implies that nationalist governments want to adopt more fixed regimes. In
the three regressions, the current account deficit /surplus and de facto capital account
openness are statistically insignificant.
Most of the variables in the regressions III and IV used the de jure classification are
statistically insignificant. In contrast to the expected sign, it is found that the level of
development decreases the probability of adopting a flexible regime in both the
regressions. Similarly, contrary to the expected sign, the geographic concentration of trade
is significantly and positively associated with a flexible regime.
When the four regressions are taken into consideration, the only two variables ( level of
development and TOT) are statistically significant. Nevertheless, the level of economy has
a positive sign in the regressions I and II, whereas it has a negative in the regressions III
and IV. When the de facto and de jure classifications are compared to each other, it
appears that the relationship between the de facto classifications and the determinants of
exchange rate regimes are stronger than the relationship between the de jure classifications
and the determinants of regimes.
Conclusion
In this paper, we apply a random effect ordered probit model to estimate the determinants
of exchange rate regimes in 25 emerging market economies. We consider a wide range of
potential regime determinants including the OCA fundamentals, macroeconomic
aggregates, and political and institutional features. To avoid potentially misleading
classification, we use two different measures of the dependent variable, namely de jure
(official) and de facto (actual) choice of exchange rate regimes. The estimations of the de
jure and de facto specifications generate different results for the variables. The de facto
models produce a better fit. This is consistent with the notion that official regime changes
carry a cost that exceeds the cost of changing the de facto regime, and that country use this
as a policy instrument to adjust their exchange rate policy to macroeconomic developments
earlier and faster than they respond with their official regime. Therefore, it can be said that
the de facto classifications should be preferred in order to classify the exchange rate
regimes in emerging economies. It is found that the de jure regimes are not enough to
explain the relationship between the exchange rate policies and the variables. Almost all
the macroeconomic and political variables in the de jure models are found to be
statistically insignificant.
186
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Based on the findings obtained from the de facto regressions, we may conclude that the
choice of exchange rate regime adopted by 25 emerging economies for the periods under
discussion have been influenced by the level of economic development, inflation
differential and political factors, and not influenced by the current account deficit/surplus,
(de facto) capital account openness.
187
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
References
Berger, H., Sturm, J.-E., and De Haan, J., (2000), “An Empirical Investigation into
Exchange Rate Regime Choice and Exchange Rate Volatility”, CESifo Working Paper;
No. 263.
Bernhard, W., and Leblang, D. (1999), “Democratic Institutions and Exchange-rate
Commitments”, International Organization, 53 (1 (Winter), pp. 71-97.
Bleaney, M., and Francisco, M. (2005), “The Choice of Exchange Rate Regime: How
Valid is the Binary Model?”, CREDIT research paper, No: 05/02.
Calvo, G. A., and C. M. Reinhart (2000), “Fear of Floating”, NBER Working Paper, No:
7993.
Collins, Susan M., (1996), “On Becoming More Flexible: Exchange Rate Regimes in Latin
America and the Caribbean,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 51, pp. 117–38.
Dreyer, Jacob S., (1978), “Determinants of Exchange Rate Regimes for Currencies of
Developing Countries: Some Preliminary Results,” World Development, Vol. 6, pp. 437–
45.
Edwards, S. (1996). "The Determinants of the Choice Between Fixed and Flexible
Exchange Rate Regimes", NBER Working Paper, No: 5756.
Edwards, S. (1998), “Exchange Rate Anchors and Inflation: A Political Economy
Approach”, In: Eijffinger, S., Huizinga, H. (Eds.), Positive Political Economy: Theory and
Evidence, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Ghosh, A.R., Gulde, A.-M., and Ostry, J., Wolf, H. (1997), “Does the Nominal Exchange
Rate Matter?”, NBER Working Paper, No: 5874.
Heller, H.R. (1978), Determinants of Exchange Rate Practices, Journal of Money, Credit,
and Banking 10 (August), 308-321.
Holden P., M. Holden, and E. Suss, (1979), “The Determinants of Exchange Rate
Flexibility: An Empirical Investigation," Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 61, pp.
327-33.
Honkapohja, S., and Pikkarainen, P. (1994), “Country Characteristics and the Choice of the
Exchange Rate Regime: Are Mini-Skirts Followed by Maxis?” in Exchange Rate Policies
in the Nordic Countries, ed. by Johnny Åkerholm and Alberto Giovannini (London: Centre
for Economic Policy Research).
IMF, various issues, (1996-2006), Annual Reports (International Monetary Fund:
Washington DC)
Juhn, G., and Mauro, P., (2002), “Long-run Determinants of Exchange Rate Regimes: A
Simple Sensitivity Analysis”, IMF Working Paper, No: 02/104.
188
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Kato, I., and Uctum, M. (2005), Choice of Exchange Rate Regime and Currency Zones,
http://userhome.brooklyn.cuny.edu/economics/muctum/WP.htm
Levy-Yeyati, E., Sturzenegger, F. (1999) Classifying Exchange Rate Regimes: Deeds vs.
Words, http://ideas.repec.org/a/eee/eecrev/v49y2005i6p1603-1635.html
Levy-Yeyati, E., and Sturzenegger, F. (2005), “Classifying Exchange Rate Regimes:
Deeds vs. Words”, European Economic Review, 49 (6), 1603-1635.
Levy-Yeyati, E., and Sturzenegger, F., and Iliana, R. (2007), “On the Endogeneity of
Exchange Rate Regimes”, http://ideas.repec.org/p/udt/wpbsdt/veintiuno.html
Markiewicz, A. (2006), “Choice of Exchange Rate Regime in Central and Eastern
European Countries: An Empirical Analysis”, Center for Economic Studies Working
Paper.
Melvin, M., (1985), “The Choice of An Exchange Rate System and Macroeconomic
Stability”, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking ,17 (4) (November, Part 1), pp. 467-478.
Meon, P.-G., and Rizzo, J.-M. (2002), “The Viability of Fixed Exchange Rate
Commitments: Does Politics Matter? A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation.”, Open
Economies Review, 13 (No. 2), pp. 111-132.
Papaioannou, M. C. (2003), “Determinants of the Choice of Exchange Rate Regimes in Six
Central American Countries: An Empirical Analysis”, IMF Working Paper, No: 03/59.
Poirson, H. (2001), “How Do Countries Choose Their Exchange Rate Regime?”, IMF
Working Paper, No: 01/46.
Prasad, E. S., Rogoff, K., Wei, S. and Kose, M. A. (2003), “Effects of Financial
Globalization on Developing Countries: Some Empirical Evidence”, IMF,
http://www.nber.org/~wei/data.html
Reinhart, C., and Rogoff, K. S., (2003), “The Modern History of Exchange Rate
Arrangements: A Reinterpretation”, http://www.wam.umd.edu/~creinhar/Papers.html
Rizzo, J.-M., (1998), “The Economic Determinants of the Choice of an Exchange Rate
regime: a Probit Analysis”, Economics Letters, 59, pp. 283-287.
Savvides, A. (1990), “Real Exchange Rate Variability and the Choice of Exchange Rate
Regime by Developing Countries,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 9,
pp. 440–54.
Von Hagen, J., and Zhou, J. (2007), “The Choice of Exchange Rate Regimes in
Developing Countries: A multinomial Panel Analysis”, Journal of International Money
and Finance, 26, pp. 1071-1094.
Von Hagen, J., Zhou, J., (2005), “The Choice of Exchange Rate Regimes: An Empirical
Analysis for Transition Economies”, Economics of Transition, 13 (4), 679-703.
189
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Zhou, J. (2003), “The Choice of Exchange Rate Regimes in Developing Countries: A
Multinomial Panel Probit Analysis”.
190
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Appendix I
Table 2: Definition of Variables and Sources
Variable
Explanation
Database
GDP
Log of GDP (constant 2000 US$), lagged one period
WDI online
GDPpercapita
Log of GDP per capita (constant 2000 US$), lagged one period
WDI Online
(Exports + Imports) / 2, lagged one period
IFS Online
inflation differential: domestic inflation minus USA inflation, lagged one
IFS Online
INFLATION period
Share of Export to the largest Trade Partner in total Exports, lagged one
DOT Online
GEOGTRADE period
Sum of the absolute value of inward and outward gross capital as a ratio of
IFS Online
CAOPENNESS GDP, lagged one period
OPENNES
CA
Current account deficit or surplus as a share of GDP, lagged one period
WDI online
RESERVES
Total reserves in months of imports, lagged one period
WDI online
M2GROWTH
Annual Growth Rate of Money plus Quasi money, lagged one period
IFS Online
TOT
Standard deviation of annual percentage change of terms of trade
CAR
Existence of Capital Account Restrictions, lagged one period
WDI online
Prasad, et. al.
(2003).
YRSOFFC
How many years has the chief executive been in office?
DPI 2006
NATIONALIST Nationalist (1 if yes)
Does the party of the executive have an absolute majority in the houses
that have lawmaking powers?
MAJORITY
DPI 2006
DPI 2006
191
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Appendix II
Table 3: Summary Statistics of Variables Used in the Analysis (the period 1970-2006)
Variable
CA
OPENNESS
GDP
GDPpercapita
RESERVES
M2GROWTH
INFLATION
CAOPENNESS
TOT
CAR
GEOGTRADE
YRSOFFC
NATIONALIST
MAJORITY
Obs
715
858
857
857
731
836
839
714
564
730
607
701
697
626
Mean
-1.95
45.18
25.02
7.48
4.36
62.94
53.99
7.68
8.18
0.84
27.06
7.39
0.08
0.60
Std. Dev.
4.55
29.64
1.19
1.05
2.50
307.45
353.34
5.80
3.84
0.37
14.38
8.84
0.27
0.49
Min
-18.18
4.98
21.43
4.66
0.31
-43.74
-13.37
0.06
1.67
0
6
1
0
0
Max
18.04
199.50
28.27
9.82
13.76
6384.95
7476.26
51.24
17.15
1
89
46
1
1
192
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Appendix III
Table 4: Correlation Matrix
Variable
CA
OPENNESS
GDP
GDPpercapita
RESERVES
M2GROWTH
INFLATION
CAOPENNES
S
TOT
CAR
GEOGTRAD
E
YRSOFFC
NATIONALI
ST
MAJORITY
CA
OPENN
ESS GDP
GDP
percapit RESER M2GRO INFLA CAOPE
a
VES
WTH TION NNESS
TOT
GEOGT YRSOF NATIO
RADE
FC NALIST
CAR
1
0.058
0.229
0.043
0.230
0.027
0.027
1
-0.408
0.150
-0.188
-0.149
-0.145
1
0.241
0.150
0.123
0.095
1
0.069
0.095
0.082
1
0.065
0.052
1
0.897
1
-0.109
0.040
0.025
0.415
-0.365
-0.138
-0.253
0.271
-0.061
0.262
-0.442
-0.012
0.042
0.104
-0.163
-0.042
0.146
0.087
-0.028
0.110
0.086
1
-0.325
-0.041
1
-0.217
1
-0.034
-0.008
0.020
0.234
0.233
-0.437
0.296
-0.134
-0.283
-0.104
-0.055
-0.107
-0.057
-0.104
-0.111
0.030
0.091
0.071
-0.153
-0.129
1
-0.053
1
0.024
-0.065
-0.170
0.146
0.175
-0.319
0.253
-0.209
0.109
-0.162
0.084
-0.035
0.130
0.005
0.107
-0.009
-0.189
0.075
-0.126
-0.221
-0.055
0.105
-0.061
0.470
1
0.095
193
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Relative Price Variability and the Philips Curve: Evidence from Turkey
A Nazif Çatik
Ege University, Turkey
Brunel University, UK
Christopher Martin
Brunel University, UK
A. Özlem Önder
Ege University, Turkey
Abstract
We argue that relative price changes are a key component of the Phillips curve relationship
between inflation and output. Building on work by Ball and Mankiw, we propose
including measures of the variances and skewness of relative price adjustment in an
otherwise standard model of the Phillips curve. We examine the case of Turkey, where
distribution of price changes is especially skewed and where the existence of a Phillips
curve has been questioned. We have two main findings: (i) inclusion of measures of the
distribution of relative price changes improves our understanding of the Phillips curve
trade-off; (ii) there is no evidence of such a trade-off if these measures are not included.
194
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Introduction
Many studies have shown that consideration of the distribution of relative price
adjustments can improve our understanding of the inflation rate. Early studies found a
clear relationship between the level of inflation and the variance of relative prices (e.g.
Vining and Elwertowski, 1976, Fischer, 1981, and Domberger, 1987). Following work by
Ball and Mankiw (1994, 1995), more recent studies have also found a relationship between
inflation and the skewness of relative price changes (e.g. Debelle and Lamont, 1997,
Aucremanne et al., 2002 and Caraballo and Usabiaga, 2005). Although the relative size of
the variance and skewness effects is controversial (e.g. Hall and Yates, 1988), the fact that
the skewness effect appears quite strong for low inflation rates but much weaker when
inflation is higher is consistent with the menu cost foundations of Ball and Mankiw’s
analysis.
In this paper we use these insights to improve our understanding of a key macroeconomic
relationship, the Phillips Curve. We propose including measures of the distribution of
relative price adjustment in an otherwise standard model of the Phillips curve. In doing so,
we will combine two related but distinct literatures. The literature on the Phillips curve
relates inflation to output or unemployment gaps. The literature on relative price
variability relates inflation to the second and third moments of relative price changes. In
this paper, we relate inflation to both factors.
We present empirical evidence for the case of Turkey. We do this for two reasons. First,
the impact of the distribution of relative price changes on the Phillips curve may be more
apparent in Turkey, where the distribution of relative price changes is markedly skewed.
Second, there is some debate on whether the Phillips curve trade-off exists in Turkey (e.g.
Ku tepeli, 2005; Önder, 2004 and Önder 2008). We hypothesise that this debate may
reflect the difficulty in establishing a Phillips Curve if strong distributional effects from
relative price changes are omitted from the model.
Beginning with a standard model of the hybrid Phillips curve similar to that derived by
Gali and Gertler (1999), we first develop an empirical model in which inflation is
determined by lagged values of inflation and current and lagged values of the output gap.
We investigate the relationship between inflation, the output gap and the variance and
skewness of relative price changes in Turkey, using monthly data for 1996:01 and 2007:05,
for which we have information on prices of 75 sub-components of the consumer price
index. We calculate standard measures of the standard deviation and skewness of changes
in these disaggregated price indices, finding evidence of substantial skewness and variance
and of marked changes in these distributional measures over time.
Our econometric approach is also a novelty in this literature. Since tests of the order of
integration of our variables produced mixed results, we cannot be certain that all variables
share the same order of integration. We therefore used the estimation procedure of
Pesaran, Shin and Smith (1996, 2001) (hereafter, PSS). To do this, we estimated ARDL
models in first differences, augmented by the lagged level values of our variables, with the
differenced rate of inflation as the dependent variable. The bounds test procedure of PSS
on the significance of these lagged terms was then used to assess whether the relationship
is cointegrated. Estimates of any cointegrating relationships were then obtained by reestimating this model expressed in terms of levels, with short-run dynamics being obtained
by estimating the model in error-correction form.
195
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Using this procedure, we find that the estimated relationship between inflation and the
output gap is not cointegrated but that the relationship between inflation, the output gap
and the variance and skewness of relative price changes is cointegrated. From this we
conclude that there is a Phillips curve relationship in Turkey, but that omission of measures
of the distribution of relative price changes can create the misleading impression that it
does not.
The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 provides an overview of
past literature on relative price changes, inflation and the Turkish Phillips Curve and
derives our empirical model. Section 3 describes our data. Section 4 presents our
econometric estimates and discusses their implications. Section 5 concludes.
Methodology
The literature on the relationship between inflation and the distribution of relative price
changes typically estimates models of the form
(1)
π t = βπ ( L)π t −1 + β sd ( L) sdrpt + β sk ( L) skrpt + ε t
where π is the inflation rate, sdrp is the standard deviation of relative price changes, skrp
is the skewness of relative price changes, ε is an iid error term, βπ , β sd and β sk , are
polynomials of length nπ , nsd and nsk respectively in the lag operator L , where
βπ ( L) = β1π + β 2π L + .... + β nππ Lnπ −1 ,
β sk ( L) = β 0sk + β1sk L + .... + β sk Ln
sk
nsk −1
β sd ( L) = β 0sd + β1sd L + .... + β sd Ln
sd
nsd −1
−1
−1
and
.
Early studies (e.g. Vining and Elwertowski, 1976, Parks, 1978, Fischer, 1981, Domberger,
1987 and Hartman, 1991) examined the empirical relationships between inflation and
relative price variability. Theoretical support for these relationships was provided Fischer
(1981, 1982) and Cuckierman (1983). Following work by Ball and Mankiw (1994, 1995),
who argued that, in the context of a menu cost model, an asymmetric pattern of relative
price changes at the microeconomic level had implication for the behaviour of the
aggregate inflation rate, the third moment of relative price changes was also considered
(Balke and Wynne, 2000, argue that these effects can also arise in a model without price
rigidities). This more recent literature has continued to find a strong association between
inflation and the distribution relative price changes, although there is debate about the
relative strength of the effect of the second and third moments. Some studies find that the
effect of skewness is stronger (e.g. Ball and Mankiw, 1995, Debelle and Lamont, 1997, for
the US; Aucremanne et al., 2002, for Belgium; Caraballo and Usabiaga, 2005, for Spain),
while De Abreu et al. (1995) for Australia; Bonnet et al. (1999) for France; Dopke and
Pierdzioch (2003) for Germany and Assorson (2004) for Sweden, found the effects to be of
roughly equal size. However some studies have found more ambiguous effects (see, for
example, Hall and Yates (1998), for the UK; Ratfai (2004) for Hungary and Pou and
Dabus (2005) for Spain and Argentina). More skeptical commentators include Holly
(1997), who uses Japanese data to argue that causation runs from aggregate inflation to the
196
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
distribution of relative price changes, and not vice-versa and Bryan and Cecchetti (1999),
who argue that the relationships estimated in the literature reflect measurement error (but
see, the rejoinder by Ball and Mankiw, 1999). It has also been suggested that a
relationship based on menu-cost arguments will not be applicable in a context of a higher
inflation rate where menu costs are less relevant.
Studies on Turkish data include Alper and Ucer (1998), who used a measure of relative
price variability based on 21 subcomponents of the wholesale price index (WPI) for the
1985-97 period. The effect of relative price variability was not significant and there was
no evidence that relative price variability has a Granger-causal relationship with the
aggregate inflation rate. By contrast, Caglayan and Filiztekin (2001), using annual data
from 1948 to 1997 found a strong relationship between relative price variability and the
inflation rate, as did Kucuk and Tuger (2004) using monthly data for 1994-2002. To our
best knowledge there appears no study which has examined the relationship between
inflation and the third moment of relative price changes.
In this paper, we investigate whether the distribution of relative price changes affects the
Phillips curve. This is not entirely novel, as some papers have included measures of
unemployment or the output gap in equation similar to (1). However they are included as
additional control variables and to check on the robustness of the relationship between
inflation and the distribution of relative price changes (Dopke and Pierzdioch, 2001,
include the unemployment rate in a model similar to (1), while Assarsson, 2004, includes
unemployment relative to the natural rate of unemployment as one of eight control
variables). To our knowledge, ours is the first paper systematically to investigate this
issue.
We begin with the “hybrid” model of the Phillips curve, proposed by Gali and Gertler
(1999), given by
(2)
π t = (1 − θ )π t −1 + θδ Etπ t +1 + γ mct
where mc is the proportional deviation of marginal cost from it’s steady-state value, δ is
the discount rate and θ captures the relative weight on forward-looking price-setting. Gali
and Gertler (1999) derive (2) using the Calvo (1983) model of nominal price adjustment
but assuming that not all firms that are able to change price do so optimally, the other
following a simple rule-of-thumb. The parameter θ reflects both the probability of being
able to adjust price and the proportion of firms who reset prices optimally. Recent work
has attempted to derive Phillips curves similar to (2) in the context of menu cost models
(Gertler and Leahy, 2005) and information cost models (Mankiw and Reis, 2002), although
models based around the Calvo model remain dominant (Dennis, 2007).
Since this paper uses time series techniques, it is convenient to express this model
as
197
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
∆π t = −
(3)
θ (1 − δ )
θδ
γ
π t −1 +
Et ∆π t +1 +
mct
1 − θδ
1 − θδ
1 − θδ
We assume that expected future changes in the inflation rate can be expressed as a function
of
current
and
lagged
inflation
rates,
Et ∆π t +1 = λπ ( L)∆π t ,
where
λπ ( L) = λπ1 + λπ2 L + .... + λπnπ Lnπ −1 . We also assume that marginal cost can be expressed as a
function of the output gap, mct = λ y ( L) yt , where λ y ( L) = λ 1y L + λ y2 L2 + .... + λ y y L y .
Substituting these into (3) yields
n
(4)
∆π t = −λπ π t −1 + λ∆π ( L)∆π t −1 + λ y yt −1 + λ∆y ( L)∆yt −1 + ε t s
where λπ ( L) =
θ (1 − δ )
γ
n
, λ y ( L) =
(λ 1y + λ y2 + ... + λ y ) ,
π
π
1 − θδ (1 + λ1 )
1 − θδ (1 + λ1 )
n
y
θδ
(λ2π + λ3π L + .... + λnππ Lnπ −1 ) ,
π
1 − θδ (1 + λ1 )
n
n
n
γλ y1
n n −1
1
2
y
y
λ∆y ( L) = λ∆y + λ∆y L + .. + λ∆y L = −
(∑ λi + ∑ λi L + ∑ λiy L2 + .....)
π
1 − θδ (1 + λ1 ) i =1
i =2
i =3
λ∆π ( L) = λ∆1π + λ∆2π L + .. + λ∆nππ Lnπ −1 =
y
y
y
y
y
and ε s is an iid error term reflecting expectational errors. This model is the empirical
counterpart of the hybrid Phillips curve in (2).
We next add measures of the second and third moments of relative price changes1,
giving the augmented Phillips curve
(5)
∆π t = −λπ π t −1 + λ∆π ( L)∆π t −1 + λ y yt −1 + λ∆y ( L)∆yt −1 +
λsd sdrpt −1 + λ∆sdrpπ ( L)∆sdrpt −1 + λsk skrpt −1 + λ∆skrp ( L)∆skrpt −1 + ε t s
where β sd ( L) = λsd1 + λsd2 L + .... + λsdnsd Lnsd −1 and β sk ( L) = λsk1 + λsk2 L + .... + λsknsk Lnsk −1 .
Our
empirical strategy will be to estimate the ARDL models in (4) and (5) and test whether the
augmented model in (5) is superior. As with other models in the literature, there are no
formal micro-foundations for (4). This is beyond the scope of this paper, but we would
1
We did not include the cross product of
multicollinearity.
skrp and sdrp , as in Ball and Mankiw (1995), because of
198
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
speculate that these will emerge once the literature has produced menu cost models that
can generate Phillips curve models similar to (4). Drawing on the more heuristic
microfoundations provided by the work of Ball and Mankiw (1994, 1995), we expect
λπ > 0 , λy > 0 λsd > 0 and λsk > 0 .
Data
We use monthly Turkish data for the period 1996:01 and 2007:05. The inflation rate is the
proportional month-on-month change in the Index of Consumer Prices (HICP) (taken from
the Eurostat database). The output gap is the proportional difference of de-seasonalised real
GDP (made available by the Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey) from its’ underlying
Hodrick-Prescott (1992) trend.
Figure 1 depicts the inflation rate and output gap over the sample period. As can be seen
from the figure Turkey has experienced high inflation accompanied by volatile growth
until the end of 2002. In an attempt to end a long sequence of high inflation rates, an IMFdirected disinflation program, based on nominal exchange rate stability, was adopted in the
beginning of the 2000. Eleven months later, this program was abandoned in the face of an
economic crisis triggered by banking sector fragility and accumulating current account
deficits, in favour of floating exchange rate regime (see, Alper, 2001, and Akyurek, 2006
for details). A rapid and depreciation of the Lira followed (the currency lost 51 percent of
its value against major currencies), which led to a monthly inflation rate of 11.8 percent by
April 2001 and an annual inflation rate of 75.1 percent in 2001. Following these traumas,
the Central Bank of Turkey adopted a policy of monetary base targeting in early 2002, with
an explicit focus on lowering and then stabilizing the future inflation; this was in effect a
regime of implicit inflation targeting but where the main policy instrument was the
monetary base. This policy has proved successful. Inflation gradually decreased throughout
2002 and has remained largely low and stable since.
We use data on 75 sub-components of the price index2. The individual rate of inflation of
each of these sub-components is calculated as
(6)
π i ,t = pit − pit −1
where pit is the natural logarithm of the price of sub-component i at time t and where the
N
aggregate price is defined as π t = ∑ wiπ i ,t , where wi is the weight on sub-component i,
i =1
where i=1,…,753 . We use standard measures of the distribution of relative price changes.
The second moment is defined as
2
Some of the sub-components were not available for the whole sample period, therefore we used main
components for these items and hence reduced the data to 75 subcomponents.
3
The data related to 1996-2007 weights of the CPI was not fully available; therefore we
used 1996 weights in this study.
199
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
(7)
sdrpt =
N
∑ w (π
i
i =1
i ,t
−πt )
2
while the third moment is defined as
N
(8)
skrpt =
∑ w (π
i =1
i
i ,t
−πt )
3
sdrpt 3
Figure 2 and Figure 3 depicts second and third moments of relative price changes with
monthly inflation. Relative price changes are clearly highly volatile. Movements in the
second moment are move with changes in the inflation rate. This closely relationship has
been widely documented in previous studies (see, for example, Ball and Mankiw (1995),
Debelle and Lamont (1997), Aucremanne et al. (2002), Caraballo and Usabiaga (2005), De
Abreu et al. (1995), Bonnet et al. (1999), Dopke and Pierdzioch (2003) and Assorson
(2004), Hall and Yates (1998), Ratfai (2004), Pou and Dabus (2005)). However we note
that the reduced inflation rate in recent years has only partially been reflected in lower
volatility. The skewness of relative price changes is most marked in periods of
macroeconomic stress, when larger negative values are apparent. Overall, skewness has
reduced in recent years.
Econometric Estimates
We begin by examining the stationarity properties of our data. As Table 1 shows,
application of a variety of tests produces mixed results. We therefore use the bounds
testing procedure proposed by Pesaran, Shin and Smith (1996, 2001) which allows us to
test for the existence of a linear long run relationship with variable which may be of
differing orders of integration.
To do this, we first estimate the ARDL models in (4) and (5) using ordinary least squares.
We then test the restriction that all estimated coefficients of lagged variables equal zero by
means of an F-test. In the case of (4), the null hypothesis of no cointegration corresponds
to H 0 : λπ = λ y =0 . For (5) the null is H 0 : λπ = λ y = λsd =λsk =0 . This test has a nonstandard asymptotic distribution, for which PSS provide two sets of critical values,
corresponding to the cases where all variables are I(0) and where all variables are I(1).
These upper and lower bounds constitute a range that includes all possible combinations of
I(1), I(0) (or even fractionally integrated) variables. If the F-statistic lies above the upper
critical bound, the null of no cointegration is rejected, while the test is inconclusive if the
F-statistic lies between the upper and lower bounds. Any long run relationship that is
detected can then be estimated using an ARDL model similar to (4) and (5) above but
which includes lags of the levels rather than the first differences of the variables of interest.
200
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Short-run dynamics can then be obtained by estimating an error correction version of this
model, where the estimated long-run relationship forms the error-correction term.
We estimated the conditional ARDL models using up to 13 lags, (although we only
included one lag of sdrpt ; further lags were not significant and were omitted to prevent
over-parameterisation). We also included a dummy variable for April 2001, which was
interacted with the output gap to correct for a sharp and anomalous drop in output in that
month (at the height of the crisis of early-mid 2001). For each model, we calculated tests
of serial correlation, since, as PSS point out, the validity of these tests for cointegration
requires serially uncorrelated residuals.
Cointegration tests for the model in (4) are presented in Table 2. As column (v) of that
table shows, the test statistic exceeds the upper critical value in the case where 3 lags are
used. However, as column (iv) shows, that model suffers from serial correlation. The test
statistic is in the inconclusive zone when 1 or 2 lags are used, but these models also fail the
test for serial correlation. In all other cases, the test statistic for cointegration is less than
the lower critical value. Therefore the null hypothesis of no cointegration in estimates of
(4) is never rejected. In other words the Phillips curve relation is not valid for Turkey,
casting doubt on this fundamental macroeconomic relationship. There is some debate on
the existence of the Turkish Phillips Curve in the literature. While Kustepeli (2005) finds
no evidence of a Phillips curve in Turkey, Önder (2004) founds a linear relationship by
using output gap instead of unemployment gap. On the other hand, Önder (2008)
investigates instability of the Phillips curve and she finds weaker support for the curve by
taking nonlinearities into account
Tests for the model in (5) are presented in Table 3. The results in this case are very
different as there is strong evidence that the augmented Phillips curve model in (5) is
cointegrated. The null hypothesis of no cointegration is rejected in every model that does
not from serial correlation. Inclusion of the higher moments of the distribution of relative
price changes has allowed the Phillips curve relationship to be established.
Having established that (5) is cointegrated, we estimated a levels version of (5), as
discussed above4, to extract estimates of this relationship. They are
(8)
π t = −0.02 + 0.228 yt + 0.822sdrpt + 0.174skrpt
(0.007)
(0.079)
(0.149)
(0.037)
where standard errors are in parentheses. All estimated coefficients are significantly
different from zero and have expected signs. The coefficients above do not represent
elasticities and standard deviation and skewness differ in terms of magnitude (See Figure 1
and 2). Therefore we have calculated average elasticity of inflation with respect to
skewness and standard deviation and found as 3.45 and 1.30 respectively5. That means the
4
We included a full lag structure for skrp , as suggested by PSS. The specification of our ARDL was
determined by the AIC criteria, by which measure an ARDL(11,3,4,11) model performed best.
5
Elasticities are calculated by using the following formula ε y , x
=
∆y x
⋅ .
∆x y
201
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
effect of third moment of relative price variability is higher than that of standard deviation.
This result is also consistent with Ball and Mankiw’s result.
Finally, Table 4 presents estimates of the ARDL model expressed as an error-correction
model and using the estimated cointegrating relationship as the error-correction term. The
model passes diagnostic checks for normality, autocorrelation, misspecification and
heteroscedasticity. Furthermore, Cumulative Sum of Residuals (CUSUM) and Cumulative
Sum of Squared Residuals (CUSUMSQ) tests (these are not reported, but are available
upon request) find no evidence of instability in the estimated coefficients. The error
correction coefficient is large (-0.398) and highly significant. We estimate that 40% of the
deviation from the long-run equilibrium level of inflation is corrected within a month.
Although the dynamic structure is quite complex, it is apparent that almost all lags of
skewness are very significant and the skewness of the underlying distribution of prices is a
more persistent determiner of movements in variables at the macroeconomic level than is
relative price variability. This suggests that the relative importance of skewness, first
established by Ball and Mankiw (1995) in the context of (1), also applies in the case of the
Phillips curve.
Conclusions
This paper has argued that relative price changes are a key component of the Phillips curve
relationship between inflation and output. We have combined the literature on the
relationship between inflation and the distribution of relative price changes with the
literature on the Phillips curve by including the variance and skewness of relative price
adjustment in an otherwise standard model of the Phillips curve. We examine the case of
Turkey, where distribution of price changes is especially skewed and where the existence
of a Phillips curve has been questioned.
We find that measures of the distribution of relative price changes do indeed improve our
understanding of the Phillips curve trade-off. Using monthly data from 1996-2007, we
find no evidence of a trade-off between inflation and output in a conventional model of the
Phillips curve. By contrast, a well-determined trade-off is obtained when the variance and
skewness of relative price changes is included in the model.
202
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
References
Akyurek, C. (2006), The Turkish Crisis of 2001: A Classic?, Emerging Markets Finance
and Trade, 42,1,5-32.
Alper, E. (2001), “The Turkish Liquidity Crisis of 2000: What Went Wrong?”, Russian
and East European Finance and Trade, 37,6, 58-80.
Alper, E and M Ucer, M. (1998), “Some Observations on Turkish Inflation: A “Random
Walk” Down the Past Decade”, Bogazici Journal: Review of Social, Economic and
Administrative Studies, Vol. 12, No.1, pp. 7-38 .
Assarsson, B. (2004), “Inflation and Relative-Price Changes in the Swedish Economy”,
Sveriges Riksbank Economic Review, 3, pp. 43-62.
Aucremanne, L., Brys, G., Hubert, M., Rousseeuw, P.J. and Struyf, A. (2002), “Inflation,
Relative Prices and Nominal Rigidities”, National Bank of Belgium, Working Paper, no:
20.
Balke, N and C Wynne (2000), “An Equilibrium Analysis of Relative Price Changes and
Aggregate Inflation”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 45:2, pp 269-92
Ball, L. and NG Mankiw, (1994), "Asymmetric Price Adjustment and Economic
Fluctuations", Economic Journal, 104 (423), pp. 247-261.
Ball, L. and NG Mankiw, (1995), "Relative-Price Changes as Aggregate Supply Shocks",
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110 (1), pp. 161-93.
Ball, L. and NG Mankiw, (1999), "Interpreting the Correlation between Inflation and the
Skewness of Relative Prices: A Comment on Bryan and Cecchetti ", Review of Economics
and Statistics, 91, pp 1897-8
Bonnet, X, E Dubois and L Fauvet, (1999)”Asymmetrie de Inflations Relative et Menu
Costs”, Revue Economique, (5), pp 547-56
Bryan, M and S Cecchetti, 91999), “Inflation and the Distribution of Price Changes”,
Review of Economics and Statistics, 91, pp 188-96
Caglayan M., Filiztekin A. (2001), “Relative Price Variability and Inflation: New Evidence
from Turkey”, Sabanci University Discussion Paper series, no.2001-11.
Calvo, G. (1983) “Staggered prices in a utility-maximizing framework”, Journal of
Monetary Economics, 12, 383–98.
Caraballo, M.A., Dabús, C. and Usabiaga, C.( 2006), “Relative Prices and Inflation: New
Evidence from Different Inflationary Contexts”, Applied Economics; Vol. 38 (16), pp.
1931 -44.
203
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Cukierman, A (1983), “Relative Price Variability and Inflation: A Survey and Further
Results”, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 19, pp. 103-38.
De Abreu, L and D Gruen, (1995), “Price Stickiness and Inflation”, research discussion
paper no 9502, Reserve Bank of Australia
Debelle, Guy & Lamont, Owen (1997), "Relative Price Variability and Inflation: Evidence
from U.S. Cities", Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 105(1),
pp. 132-52.
Dennis, R, (2007), “Recent Research on Sticky Prices”, Federal Reserve Bank of San
Francisco Economic Letter, no 2007-35
Domberger, Simon (1987), “Relative price variability and inflation: A disaggregated
analysis”, Journal of Political Economy, 95, pp. 547-66.
Döpke, J. and Pierdzioch, C. (2003), “Inflation and Skewness of the Distribution of
Relative Price Changes: Empirical Evidence for Germany”, Jahrbücher für
Nationalökonomie und Statistik, 223 (2), pp. 136-159.
Fischer, Stanley (1981), “Relative Shocks, Relative-Price Variability, and Inflation”,
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 2, pp. 381 - 441.
Gali, J. and M. Gertler (1999), “Inflation dynamics: a structural econometric analysis”,
Journal of Monetary Economics, 44, 195-222.
Gertler M and J Leahy, (2005), “A Phillips Curve with an Ss Foundation”, FRB of
Philadelphia Working Paper Series No. 06-8
Hall, S and A Yates (1998), “Are there downward nominal rigidities in product markets?”,
Bank of England Working Paper Series, no 80.
Hartman, R., (1991), “Relative price variability and inflation”, Journal of Money, Credit
and Banking, 23, pp. 185–205.
Holly, S, (1997) “Relative Price Dispersion and the Rate of Inflation: The Evidence from
Japan”, Journal of Economic Integration, 12:2, pp 206 – 226.
Kucuk, H and T, Burc (2004), “Relative Price Variability: The Case Of Turkey 19942002”, Central Bank of Turkey Research Department Working Paper, No:04/02.
Ku tepeli, Y. (2005) “A comprehensive Short-run Analysis of a
Phillips Curve”, Applied Economics, 37: 581-591.
(Possible) Turkish
Mankiw, N. G., and R. Reis.( 2002), “Sticky Information Versus Sticky Prices: A Proposal
to Replace the New Keynesian Phillips Curve”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107:4 ,
pp 1295-1328.
204
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Önder, A. Ö. (2004), “Forecasting Inflation in Emerging Markets by Using the Phillips
Curve and Alternative Time Series Models” Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, 40:
71-82.
Önder, A. Ö. (2008), “The Stability of the Turkish Phillips Curve and Alternative Regime
Shifting Models” , Applied Economics, forthcoming.
Parks, R.W. (1978), "Inflation and Relative Price Variability", Journal of Political
Economy, 86 (1), pp. 79-95.
Pou, A.C. and C. Dabus (2005), “Nominal rigidities, relative prices and skewness” 2005.
Fundación Centro de Estudios Andaluces Working Paper, no 2005/17.
Pesaran, M.H., Shin, Y., Smith, R.J. (1996), “Testing for the Existence of a Long-Run
Relationship”, DAE Working Paper, No. 9622, Department of Applied Economics,
University of Cambridge.
Pesaran, M. H.., Shin, Y. and Smith, R. J. (2001), “Bounds Testing Approaches to the
Analysis of Level Relationships”, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 16, pp. 289-326.
Raftai, A.(2004), “Inflation and Relative Price Asymmetry”, European Central Bank,
Working Paper Series, no: 301.
Vining, D.R. and Elwertowski, T.C. (1976), "The Relationship between Relative Prices
and General Price Level", American Economic Review, 66 (4), pp. 699-708.
205
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Appendix
Figure 1: Consumer Price Inflation and Output Gap in Turkey: 1996:2-2007:5
Figure 2: Standard Deviation of Relative Price Changes and Inflation in Turkey:
1996:2-2007:5
! " #
206
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Figure 3: Skewness of Relative Price Changes and Inflation in Turkey: 1996:2-2007:5
$ %
&&
Table 1: Unit Root Tests
ADF
PP
KPSS
DFGLS
NGP(MZα)
-6.175***
-6.105***
1.252***
-2.356
-14.49*
y
sdrp
sdrp
skrp
-3.544***
-1.38
-5.47***
-2.963
-3.986***
-9.262***
-8.184***
0.220
0.115*
0.065
0.561
-13.648***
-3.389
-0.822*
-1.00*
-0.100 *
-20.336
-0.525*
-2.579*
0.235*
skrp
-9.728***
-
-
-
-
π
π
y
Note: *, ** and *** indicate significant at 10, 5 and 1% respectively. The lag length for ADF test is
chosen based on the AIC criterion. Contrary to other unit root tests null hypothesis of KPSS test is
stationary. Bandwiths in the PP and KPSS unit root tests are determined by the Newey-West statistic
using the Barlett-Kernel. The lag length of the DF-GLS and Ng-Perron tests are selected by the
Modified Akaike Information Criterion (MAIC).
207
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Lag
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
Table 2: Bounded F-tests for Phillips Curve for model (4)
χ sc2 (12)
AIC
SBC
F-statistics
397.623
402.094
398.269
398.843
393.697
388.885
384.689
382.468
378.866
374.798
376.043
373.018
371.121
388.908
391.952
385.262
382.987
375.008
367.378
360.381
355.373
349.002
342.181
340.689
334.944
330.344
39.4574(.000)
25.9915(.011)
29.6960(.003)
25.4362(.013)
29.2646(.004)
25.8388(.011)
29.4465(.003)
25.9342(.011)
27.7414(.006)
30.6840(.002)
27.2604(.007)
20.9068(.052)
21.1679(.048)
4.764 (i)
4.615 (i)
4.900 (r)
3.278
2.647
2.689
2.519
1.811
2.301
1.323
0.446
0.480
0.669
Note: Asymptotic critical values for bounded F-test are 3.79 and 4.85 for I(0) and I(1) respectively 5%
significance level.
χ sc (12) is LM test statistics for testing no serial correlation, p-values are in
2
parenthesis. In column (v), (i) indicates a test statistic in the inconclusive range, while (r) indicates
rejection of the null
Table 3: Bounded F-Tests For Phillips for model in (5)
Lag
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
AIC
388.558
392.511
391.396
390.665
390.870
389.252
387.110
385.870
389.814
390.936
389.178
388.812
390.785
SBC
371.685
370.013
367.493
362.543
358.530
352.6932
346.333
340.875
340.601
337.505
331.528
326.944
324.699
χ sc2 (12)
26.2965(.010)
19.5594(.076)
17.1983(.142)
21.3265(.046)
20.9821(.051)
22.1253(.036)
23.3544(.025)
23.0645(.027)
20.9203(.052)
16.094(.207)
17.9594(.117)
14.0916(.295)
20.3149(.061)
F-statistics
2.895 (i)
3.568 (i)
5.890 (r)
4.9011 (r)
5.738 (r)
4.250 (r)
4.369 (r)
4.745 (r)
6.333 (r)
5.792 (r)
4.396 (r)
4.724 (r)
4.922 (r)
Note: Asymptotic critical values for bounded F-test are 2.86 and 4.01 for I(0) and I(1) respectively
at 5% significance level. χ sc (12) is LM test statistics for testing no serial correlation, p-values are in
2
parenthesis. In column (v), (i) indicates a test statistic in the inconclusive range, while (r) indicates
rejection of the null hypothesis.
208
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 4: Error Correction Form of the ARDL(11,2,11,12) Phillips Curve
Model
Regressor
Coefficient
Standard Error
p-value
π(-1)
-0.212
0.101
0.039
π(-2)
-0.165
0.099
0.099
π(-3)
-0.023
0.093
0.807
π(-4)
0.031
0.088
0.723
π (-5)
0.175
0.086
0.044
π (-6)
0.213
0.086
0.015
π (-7)
0.181
0.080
0.027
π(-8)
0.144
0.079
0.071
π(-9)
0.312
0.072
0.000
π(-10)
0.173
0.070
0.015
y
0.005
0.045
0.916
y(-1)
-0.120
0.045
0.009
y(-2)
-0.183
0.043
0.000
sdrp
0.315
0.043
0.000
sdrp(-1)
0.072
0.074
0.335
sdrp(-2)
0.072
0.064
0.263
sdrp(-3)
0.105
0.048
0.032
skrp
0.002
0.000
0.000
skrp (-1)
-0.005
0.001
0.002
skrp(- 2)
-0.004
0.001
0.003
skrp (-3)
-0.004
0.001
0.001
skrp (-4)
-0.003
0.001
0.003
skrp (-5)
-0.003
0.001
0.006
skrp(-6)
-0.003
0.001
0.000
skrp(-7)
-0.003
0.001
0.000
skrp (-8)
-0.002
0.001
0.002
skrp (-9)
-0.003
0.001
0.000
skrp(-10)
-0.001
0.000
0.012
Constant
-0.009
0.003
0.004
Dummy
-0.633
0.098
0.000
Ecm(-1)
-0.398
0.082
0.000
R-Bar-Squared
0.765
F-stat.
F( 36, 88)
13.356(.000)
χ SC (12)
2
.10446(.747)
χ FF (1)
2
1.9868(.159)
χ H (12)
2
8.8177[.718]
χ (12)
2
N
Notes: χ SC (12) , χ (12) , χ FF (1) and χ N (12) denote chi-squared statistics for residuals, to
2
2
2
2
H
test the null hypothesis of no serial correlation, no functional form misspecification, normality
and homoscedasticity respectively. p values are in parenthesis.
209
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Competitive Industrial Performance Index and It’s Drivers: Case of
Turkey and Selected Countries
Ne e Kumral
Ege University, Turkey
Çağaçan Değer
Ege University, Turkey
Burcu Türkcan
Izmir University of Economics
Abstract
Competitiveness of manufacturing industry is regarded as one of the basic determinants of
long run sustainable growth of a country. Therefore it is important to have an
understanding of relative positions of countries in terms of competitiveness and
determinants of competitive ability. This study aims to reveal the standing of Turkey in a
group of countries and analyze determinants of competitive ability. The competitive
industrial performance (CIP) index, taken to be an indicator of relative competitive ability,
has been calculated for a sample of 33 countries for years 1985, 1990, 1998 and 2002.
Panel data methods then have been employed to reveal sources of competitive ability.
Conducted analysis reveals Turkish manufacturing industry to be lagging behind many of
the sample countries and presents a grim picture for sustainable development in medium
and long run.
210
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Introduction
Competitiveness is regarded as the main condition for existence in the new global market
and competitive environment which are shaped by knowledge economies. Success of a
country in the process of competition is closely related to the degree at which it can
simultaneously increase the real incomes of it's citizens and produce internationally
demanded goods and services in accordance with free and fair market conditions. In
addition, a country's or a region's competitiveness includes the provision of high living
standards and employment opportunities. Definition of competitiveness also includes
evasion of unsustainable foreign deficits and risking the welfare of future generations
(European Competitiveness Report, 2004). Within this framework, the components of
macro competitiveness are revealed as a successful economic performance, increasing
living standards, existence of goods and services that are capable of competing in open
economies and evasion of unsustainable deficits. Competitive success also includes
realization of certain social and environmental targets. These dimensions of the concept
present that the definition of competitiveness is through the output of competitiveness, like
life quality, rather than its inputs.
The question of where competitiveness of a country is actually embedded has little room
for debate. The common understanding is that competitive ability of a country originates in
the manufacturing industry for manufacturing industry is the real part of the economy and
is the prime creator of value added and jobs in many economies. And higher is the
technical complexity of processes and products in manufacturing industry, higher is the
value added created. At this point manufacturing industry becomes the focus of policy and
research for sustainable development.
Manufacturing industry is regarded as one of the most important economic activities that
enable sustainable competitiveness and economic growth (UNIDO 2002- 2003:11).
Therefore identification of relative standings of countries in terms of competitiveness
arises as an important research question. The aim of this paper is to analyze the relative
standings of a sample of countries by using the CIP (Competitive Industrial Performance)
index and examine drivers of competitiveness, as measured by CIP, making use of panel
data analysis methods.
The study progresses as follows: second part explains the calculation of CIP (Competitive
Industrial Performance) index and the drivers behind the index. A brief description of the
data used for calculation of CIP index is also provided. Section 3 presents the calculated
performance indicators fro the sample countries and CIP index results. Section 4 presents
an overview of the drivers data collected to create a panel data set and addresses the related
econometric concerns on estimation. Section 5 presents the econometric results.
Conclusions and comments on policy implications are presented in Section 6.
CIP Index and Drivers
The analysis conducted in this study actually consists of two layers. The first part is related
to the calculation of CIP index and the picture provided by the index rankings. Second part
consists of econometric analysis and makes use of available panel data. Forming the core
of sections 2 and 3, Competitive Industrial Performance Index (CIP) shows the
performances of the countries on producing and exporting manufactured goods in a
competitively. It is an amalgam of four basic indicators. The first two of these indicators
211
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
are about industrial capacity whereas the other two provide intuitions on technological
complexity of manufacturing industry (UNIDO, 2002).
CIP index is frequently used by international institutions and its applications focus on
international comparison of manufacturing industry. The index is derived by transforming
four data items in to performance indicators and then by taking their average. The four
indicators mentioned before are as follows:
•
Performance indicator 1: This indicator is composed of manufacturing industry
value added per capita statistics. This indicator helps to observe the contribution of the
manufacturing sector to the development, rather than growth, of a country by focusing on a
limited measure of individuals’ gains from manufacturing industry.
•
Performance indicator 2: This indicator consists of manufacturing industry
exports per capita statistics. This indicator is related to the competitiveness of the industry
in international markets.
Performance indicator 3: The ratio of medium and high technology industries’
•
value added to the aggregate manufacturing industry value added is the basis of this
indicator. The higher rates of medium and high - tech industries’ value added in whole
manufacturing value added mean that the country’s technological development level and
industrial competitiveness are high. Technological intensity of an industry is very
important in terms of creation and dissemination of innovations and future
competitiveness, for it carries the potential for feedbacks that may trigger further technical
improvements.
•
Performance indicator 4: The last indicator is based on the ratio of medium and
high – tech industries’ exports to the total manufacturing industry exports. This indicator
provides information about the competitive power of technologically complex goods
produced by a country’s manufacturing industry in international markets.
These four performance indicators are calculated by using the formula below:
I j ,i =
X
j ,i
Max ( X
− Min ( X
j ,i
j ,i
)
) − Min ( X
j ,i
)
(1)
Here, Xj,i represents the jth statistical value of ith country for the related index. The
values of calculated indicators range between 0 and 1 where 0 represents the worst case
and 1 stands for the case where the relevant data is highest. The logic of the indicator can
be viewed as forming a line segment with length equal to the distance between best and
worst case countries. Then, all the countries are placed along the line segment to reveal
their relative standings.
CIP index is then calculated as the average of the four performance indicators, presenting
an overall view of a country’s manufacturing industry’s relative standing. The CIP index is
capable of taking into account competitiveness not only in terms of technological content
of manufacturing industry but also is capable to account for how beneficial it is for the
country’s citizens, for it takes in to account per capita value added values as well. Given
212
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
that success in competitiveness is defined to include improvements in the well being of
citizens, the index is ideal for the study’s aim. It not only enables uncovering relative
standings of countries but also does a good job of embracing the concept of
competitiveness as defined above.
Moreover a number of drivers of CIP index are identified by UNIDO Industrial
Development reports for years 2005 and 2002/2003. These drivers are assumed to
contribute to competitiveness of a country and thus can be taken as determinants of the
index. Among those drivers are skills, foreign direct investment (FDI) and modern
infrastructure.
Skills have always been important for industrial performance. But they have become even
more crucial because of the explosive growth of the weightless economy and the high
information content of industrial activities. It is difficult to quantify a country’s stock of
industrial skills. Few countries publish data on people’s skills by discipline. And even if
such data existed, it would be impossible to estimate levels of relevant, up-to-date skills. A
common method in existing literature is to approximate existing human capital by
education data. The logical connection runs causality from education to skills; a better
educated population will be more capable of displaying advanced skills and would be more
capable of complex production methods. This would lead to ease of creation of high value
added goods.
However, it should be kept in mind that measures like current education enrollments at the
primary, secondary and tertiary levels have two main drawbacks. First, they ignore on-thejob learning—experience and training—which in many countries is a major source of skill
formation. Second, enrolment data do not take into account the significant differences
across countries in education quality, completion rates and relevance to industrial needs.
Given the lack of sources for appropriate data, education figures are used despite the stated
shortcomings. Such an approach will also be adopted here.
As a second driver, foreign direct investment (FDI) is an important way of transmitting
skills, knowledge and technology to developing countries. Transnational corporations,
generally the leading innovators in their industries, are engaging in more and more
technology transfer. This can be taken to be reflecting the rising cost and pace of technical
progress and the reluctance of innovators to sell valuable technologies to independent
firms. Transnational corporations also provide capital, skills, managerial know-how and
access to diverge markets.
Countries can accelerate their industrial development by plugging into integrated global
production systems— governed by transnational corporations—and becoming global or
regional supply centers, particularly in high-tech activities. Independent firms in
developing countries can participate in these systems, but few have the capabilities to meet
the extremely high technical standards. Most countries that have entered these systems in
recent years have done so through FDI.
The ideal FDI measure for assessing industrial performance would be inflows into
manufacturing (and within that, into domestic and export production). But this kind of
disaggregation is generally not possible: for most countries the only available measures are
inward FDI flows and stocks.
213
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
The final driver considered here is the modern infrastructure. Compared to traditional
infrastructure, which includes items like roads, railways, power lines etc, modern
infrastructure is defined to include a more knowledge and communication oriented
structure. Any item that enables creation and transfer of knowledge can be considered
within modern infrastructure. The point is choosing the data to represent such knowledge.
Some examples would include number of internet users, number of PCs or internet serves
and existing telecommunication lines.
The ease of communication presented by such an infrastructure enables transfer of
knowledge and raises possibility to spread information, know-how and innovations at a
faster rate. It would be easier to acquire information and the difficulty of creating new
knowledge would decrease significantly. This would enable not only production but also
design of goods with high technology. Hence, value added creation will increase and the
country will become capable of not only selling successfully at the international market but
also be able to maintain high living standards for citizens.
Data issues regarding drivers will be discussed in more detail under the econometric model
section. For the sole purpose of calculation of CIP index, necessary data have been
collected from UNIDO Industrial Development Report 2002/2003 (for the years of 1985
and 1998) and UNIDO Industrial Development Report 2005 (for the years of 1990 and
2002). The data have been used firstly to form the performance indicators and secondly to
calculate the CIP index. The sample includes 33 countries; namely, Argentina, Australia,
Austria, Belgium-Luxembourg, Brazil, Canada, Czechoslovakia, Denmark, Finland,
France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Korea, Mexico,
Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Singapore, Spain, Sweden,
Switzerland, Taiwan, Thailand, Turkey, UK and US. Due to lack of data, it has been
necessary to merge Belgium with Luxembourg and Czech Republic with Slovakia.
Performance Indicator Results
This section provides rankings of countries in terms of performance indicators. Presented
below as Table 1 are the country ranks according to the first performance indicator
calculated by using manufacturing value added of the selected countries. Japan and
Switzerland are consistently leading in terms the first indicator. The high places are
occupied by the rich OECD members. The notable exception is Ireland, a common
example for growth practices. It has risen to 5th place in 2002 from 19th place in 1985.
Similar dynamics are presented by Singapore and Taiwan, albeit with less success. Korea
arises as an other success story, rising from 24th place to 13th place in about 20 years.
Latin America countries occupy low ranks and share low ranks with East European
countries like Czechoslovakia, Hungary and Poland. Outlook is grim for Turkey for it has
not been possible to rise above rank 30 in the considered time period.
214
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 1: Performance Indicator 1 Rankings
Source: Authors’ calculations
Presented next on Table 2 are performance indicator ranks of indicator 2 which is based on
exports per capita for manufacturing industry. Ireland once more displays a striking
performance but Singapore consistently occupies the first place for all considered years.
Belgium-Luxembourg also consistently occupies the top ranks. These countries are
followed by other OECD countries that are known for their high income levels. Latin
America countries once more occupy the low ranks. One interesting point is that Mexico
has risen to rank 25 in 1998, a jump of 7 ranks from year 1990. This can be due to the
North America Free Trade Agreement, signed in 1992 by USA, Canada and Mexico. It is
possible that reallocation of production processes to Mexico has triggered an increase in
the country’s export capability.
215
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 2: Performance Indicator 2 Rankings
1985
1990
1998
28
30
29
Argentina
24
25
24
Australia
12
7
9
Austria
2
2
3
Bel-Lux
27
33
31
Brazil
9
12
11
Canada
NA
20
18
Czech-Slov.
8
9
8
Denmark
7
8
7
Finland
16
13
13
France
11
10
10
Germany
25
27
26
Greece
13
24
32
Hungary
NA
26
NA
Iceland
10
6
2
Ireland
17
15
15
Italy
6
17
23
Japan
19
21
17
Korea
30
32
25
Mexico
4
4
5
Netherlands
21
19
22
New Zealand
14
11
16
Norway
26
29
28
Poland
23
18
20
Portugal
1
1
1
Singapore
22
22
19
Spain
5
5
6
Sweden
3
3
4
Switzerland
15
14
12
Taiwan
31
28
27
Thailand
29
31
30
Turkey
18
16
14
United Kingdom
20
23
21
United States
2002
32
26
9
3
33
10
20
8
7
14
12
30
19
27
2
15
17
18
25
5
23
13
29
22
1
21
6
4
11
28
31
16
24
Source: Authors’ calculations.
South East Asian countries in the sample do not display increases in per capita exports but
on average do slightly better than East European Countries. Turkish case is once more
discouraging, occupying the 29th place in 1985 but falling to 31st place in 2002. Doing
worse than Turkey are Brazil and Argentina with ranks 33 and 32 respectively. Greece,
Poland and Thailand perform slightly better than Turkey in year 2002 and occupy ranks
30, 29 and 28. Faring unexpectedly poorly according to this indicator is the USA. It is
possible that the low ranks of USA are due to relatively large population, leading to a low
per capita export value, and domestic market oriented production.
216
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 3: Performance Indicator 3 Rankings
1985
1990
1998
27
27
29
Argentina
21
20
16
Australia
16
21
20
Austria
14
14
17
Bel-Lux
11
19
11
Brazil
17
18
18
Canada
18
11
23
Czech-Slov.
19
23
19
Denmark
22
25
13
Finland
15
15
14
France
2
2
4
Germany
31
30
31
Greece
5
16
24
Hungary
NA
32
NA
Iceland
12
9
3
Ireland
9
7
15
Italy
3
3
2
Japan
20
13
9
Korea
26
26
30
Mexico
10
8
10
Netherlands
28
29
26
New Zealand
13
12
21
Norway
23
24
25
Poland
29
31
32
Portugal
1
1
1
Singapore
24
22
22
Spain
7
10
8
Sweden
8
6
5
Switzerland
25
17
12
Taiwan
32
33
27
Thailand
30
28
28
Turkey
6
5
7
United Kingdom
4
4
6
United States
2002
25
23
19
16
18
13
14
17
15
21
8
31
20
33
2
24
3
6
27
9
26
12
30
32
1
22
4
10
11
28
29
5
7
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Presented on Table 3 are rankings of countries according to the third performance indicator
based on the ratio of medium and high technology sectors in total manufacturing value
added. The consistent success of Ireland and Singapore is once more observed. Japan is
also a winner in terms of the third indicator. The OECD countries once more occupy most
of the high ranks. However, some interesting dynamics can be observed. Italy displays a
considerable worsening in terms of technology content in production, falling to 24th
position in 2002 from 9th position in 1985. Korea, on the other hand, displays considerable
rank increase from 1985 to 2002, moving up to 6th position. Hungary is another country
that suffers serious rank losses and moves to 20th position in 2002 from 4th position in
1985. Argentina and Mexico perform blow average but Brazil displays above average
performance. Turkey once more occupies some of the lowest
217
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
The volatilities in Table 3 imply that in the last 20 years, the world has experienced
considerable shifts in allocation of medium and high technology across countries. It is
unfortunate that Turkey has not moved to higher ranks during this process. It is possible
that Turkey has not managed to benefit from shifts in global reallocation of production
processes and has not been able to attract or create the ability to produce medium and high
technology goods. The situation bodes ill for the country, implying that a gap between
sample countries and Turkey is now in existence and efforts are needed to close this gap.
Based on share of medium and high technology sectors in manufacturing industry exports,
the 4th performance indicator gives rise to the rankings presented in Table 4. It is
interesting to note that Ireland is not a success story in this case; actually, Ireland falls to
19th position in 2002 from 13th in 1985. One other interesting point is that some of the
relatively more developed countries display losses in ranks. Within the considered time
period, Austria falls from 9th position to 16th, Norway falls all the way to 30th position,
and Switzerland falls to 10th position after losing 6 ranks. Relatively milder falls are
observed for other well developed countries as well.
Table 4: Performance Indicator 4 Rankings
1985
1990
1998
28
29
28
Argentina
30
27
31
Australia
9
12
19
Austria
15
15
21
Bel-Lux
23
25
26
Brazil
11
9
20
Canada
NA
NA
14
Czech-Slov.
19
17
24
Denmark
20
23
18
Finland
7
8
11
France
2
3
5
Germany
27
31
30
Greece
31
24
10
Hungary
NA
21
NA
Iceland
13
14
15
Ireland
12
18
16
Italy
1
1
1
Japan
8
13
8
Korea
6
5
3
Mexico
21
20
17
Netherlands
29
32
32
New Zealand
24
22
29
Norway
16
19
25
Poland
22
28
23
Portugal
14
7
2
Singapore
17
11
13
Spain
5
10
12
Sweden
4
6
6
Switzerland
18
16
9
Taiwan
26
26
22
Thailand
2002
29
28
16
25
24
18
23
20
21
11
5
32
7
14
19
22
1
9
3
17
33
30
26
27
2
13
12
10
8
15
218
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Turkey
United Kingdom
United States
25
10
3
30
4
2
27
7
4
31
6
4
Source: Authors’ calculations.
On the other side of the coin are position gains by other countries. Hungary rises to 7th
place whereas Mexico displays a surprising rise to 3rd position. From the 14th position in
1985, Singapore rises to 2nd position in 2002. Taiwan also follows a similar path. It is
possible that as production of relatively high technology goods re-allocates to less
developed countries, probably due to lower labor costs, these countries become exporters
of such goods. This may appear to be a contradiction for these countries are not among the
countries that have very high shares of medium and high technology sectors in
manufacturing value added. Such a contradiction may be explained away as follows:
Consider a developing country that does not produce very complex goods and thus has low
shares of medium and high technologies in manufacturing value added and exports. Now
consider a reallocation of production processes to similar developing countries. These
countries will now be producing relatively more complex goods, but such production may
account for a small portion of total value added created in the economy. If the country is
initially exporting simple goods that have low value added, introduction of medium and
high technology goods which have more value added would distort the export structure in
favor of complex goods. This would be even truer if the country had previously been
producing for mostly the local market and had relatively low exports to begin with. Such a
dynamic would be even more logical if one assumes or believes that such reallocation of
production processes aims to use developing countries as production base for goods to be
sold in developed countries.
However, such analysis would not curtail Turkey’s lagging position; even though Turkey
occupies the 25th place in year 1985, the rank has fallen to 31 in year 2002. This can be
taken to mean that Turkey has not been able to benefit from a reallocation of production
processes and the opportunity to gain from the technology transfers provided by such
reallocations appear to have been missed.
Having obtained the performance indicator values, it is now possible to calculate the CIP
index values for the selected countries. The rankings implied by the calculated index
values are available on Table 5. It should be noted that the rows of this table are ordered
according to rank in year 2002.
Singapore, Switzerland and Japan share the top places in the CIP index rankings. Ireland
rises from 15th place to 2nd in the time period under focus. Finland, Korea and Taiwan are
other examples of improvement. Latin America countries display below average
performance whereas Southeast Asian countries display at least slight improvements in
rank, as in the case of Thailand, or are consistent leaders, as is Singapore. The rankings
also imply that France, Canada, Italy and Norway have become slightly less competitive
during the last 20 years. Hungary is one of the countries that slightly improve in rank, but
Poland and Czechoslovakia have recessed to lower ranks. Finally, Turkey has one of the
lowest ranks for all the four years and has slowly, but steadily fallen to the 32nd position in
2002.
219
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 5: CIP Rankings of Countries
CIP
1985
1990
3
1
Singapore
15
13
Ireland
2
3
Switzerland
1
2
Japan
6
6
Sweden
4
4
Germany
7
5
Bel-Lux
5
7
United States
14
14
Finland
19
19
Korea
10
8
United Kingdom
18
18
Taiwan
9
9
Netherlands
12
10
Austria
16
12
Denmark
11
11
France
8
15
Canada
21
22
Hungary
13
16
Italy
20
20
Spain
17
17
Norway
22
21
Mexico
NA
NA
Czech-Slov.
24
25
Brazil
25
23
Australia
31
32
Thailand
NA
26
Iceland
26
27
Portugal
28
29
Argentina
23
24
Poland
27
28
New Zealand
29
31
Turkey
30
30
Greece
1998
1
4
2
3
6
5
10
7
9
15
8
13
11
14
17
12
18
21
16
19
22
23
20
24
26
28
NA
25
30
27
29
31
32
2002
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Drivers’ Data and Econometric Model
Country coverage of the collected driver data is 32 countries; specifically Argentina,
Australia, Austria, Belgium-Luxembourg, Brazil, Canada, Czechoslovakia, Denmark,
Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Korea, Mexico,
Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Singapore, Spain, Sweden,
Switzerland, Thailand, Turkey, United Kingdom and United States. Due to lack of data,
Belgium and Luxembourg have been treated as a single entity. Same situation holds for
Czech Republic and Slovakia as well.
220
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
The econometric part of this study makes heavy use of data obtained from International
Measures of Schooling Years and Schooling Quality Dataset (Barro and Lee, 2000: 24–32
) and World Bank’s WDI (World Development Indicators) Database. Foreign direct
investment is taken to be one of the drivers of CIP and is generally regarded to be a vehicle
of technology transfer to manufacturing industry. To account for such transfers, net FDI
inflow as percentage of GDP and net current FDI inflow have been obtained from WDI.
The net current FDI inflow has been turned to real units by making use of United States
GDP deflator series that takes year 2000 as the base year. The deflator is from WDI as
well. The data related to FDI is generally available for all sample countries between years
1975 and 2005. The noticeable exceptions are Argentina for years 1975 and 1976,
Czechoslovakia for 1975 to 1989, Poland for 1975 to 1984 and Switzerland for 1975 to
1982.
One other item to be considered as a driver of CIP is the existing modern infrastructure.
Upon defining modern infrastructure to include technological components, it becomes
necessary to include items like number of internet users or availability of personal
computers. However, data on such items is not available for past decades, simply because
such items did not exist back then. In order to account for relatively technical infrastructure
differences across countries, two items of data have been chosen: fixed line and mobile
phone subscribers per 100 people and telephone mainlines per 100 people. These two items
are available through WDI dataset for all countries in the sample with 13 missing
observations for various in the case of fixed and mobile line subscribers’ data.
The last major item concerns education as a representative of capabilities of the labor
force. To account for skills of the labor force, a human capital line of thought has been
adopted. Thus education variables have been the focus as the last driver of CIP. Percentage
of primary school attained, percentage of primary school completed, percentage of
secondary school attained, percentage of secondary school completed, percentage of higher
school attained and percentage of higher school completed have been taken from BarroLee dataset. The mentioned percentages are of the total population, where total population
consists of people aged 25 and above. Average schooling years, average years of primary
schooling, average years of secondary schooling and average years of higher schooling in
total population are also taken from the same dataset. The data covers all countries except
Belgium-Luxembourg, forcing the country out of the econometric considerations. The
coverage of the data is also lacking in time dimension; it is available for years 1975, 1980,
1985 and 1990 only.
Finally, the dependent variable is the CIP with data available for years 1985, 1990, 1998,
and 2002. Thus the existing dataset of the study is actually a panel that focuses on 4 time
periods and 32 countries, if one includes Belgium-Luxembourg.
The existing panel dataset raises the need for appropriate estimation techniques. Consider a
panel dataset of N cross section units and T time dimensions, be it years or any other unit.
In most general terms, the estimation of a linear equation making use of a panel dataset can
be summarized by the following:
Y = β0 + Xβ + e
(2)
221
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
where Y is the NTx1 vector of independent variable and X is the NTxk matrix of k
independent variables. The β is the kx1 vector of slope coefficients to be estimated; β0 is
the intercept term that is assumed to be common for all cross section units and time
periods. Regarding the NTx1 error term, e, it is assumed that E(eit) = 0, E(eit2) = σ2 (i.e.
variance is constant) and E(eitejs) = 0 for all i,j and t ≠ s and E(eit | X) = 0 for all i,t. These
assumptions imply that the stated model can be estimated by ordinary least squares (OLS)
technique (Erlat, 2008).
One interesting possibility in panel data is to assume that each cross section unit has
unique properties that can be introduced into the model separately. This approach
introduces different intercepts for each cross section unit through use of dummy variables.
Such a model is called a one way model and can be summarized as
Y = β0 + Dδδ + βX + e
(3)
where Dδ is a NTxN matrix of stacked dummy variables. Above formulation assumes that
each cross section will have an intercept that varies from a common intercept, β0, by the
amount δi. These variations or effects can take two forms; they can be fixed or random.
In case of fixed effects, direct estimation of the model by OLS is not possible due to the
perfect collinearity introduced by the Dδ dummies. The estimation procedure in this case
includes a transformation that wipes out the individual effects to obtain an estimator of β
vector (Baltagi, 1995:10-11). One candidate transformation turns the data into deviation
from cross section means and thus leads to the within estimator of β (Johnston and
DiNardo, 1997: 398). Identification of the common intercept and the deviations is
relatively easy, given the between estimator (Erlat, 2008: 12), and a joint significance test
can be conducted to determine the significance of the fixed effects. If the fixed effects are
found to be insignificant, one can simply use pooled OLS approach.
Alternative specification assumes that the effects summarized by δ are random variables.
This formulation leads to the random effects model where δ effects are now part of the
error term. Therefore, assumptions on their distribution are in order. Firstly, E(δi) = 0 and
E(δi2) = σ2δ for all i; also, E(δi δj) = 0 for all i≠j whereas E(δi ejt) = 0 for all i, j and t
(Hsiao, 2003: 34). And last, but certainly not the least, E(δi |X) = 0 for all i (Erlat, 2008:
13).
We can think of the random effects model to have a composite error term, εit = δi + eit.
Given the distribution properties of e and δ, it can be shown that the composite error term
has the following properties: E(uit) = 0, E(uit2) = σ2δ + σ2 and E(uit|X) = 0 while E(uitujs) = 0
for all i=j and t ≠ s(Erlat, 2008:13; Greene, 2003:294). It should be noted that the δ term
introduces a correlation among error terms of the same cross section unit but error terms
are not correlated across cross section units (Hsiao, 2003: 35). Such correlations inspire
use of generalized least squares (GLS) approach to estimate the random effects model. The
construction of appropriate transformation is based on the estimation of variances σ2δ and
σ2; the method is due Swamy and Arora (1972).
Ignoring the differing intercepts of different cross section units would lead to biased OLS
estimation. As compared to pooled OLS, fixed effects estimator would be immune to such
bias. However, significant cross section specific effects may be correlated to the composite
error term and may lead to biased GLS estimates (Kennedy, 2003: 305-306). Thus it is
222
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
necessary to test if the assumption E(u |X) = 0 holds. A most common procedure to test
this is by Hausman (1978). The test is based on the idea that when the stated assumption
does not hold, within estimator of the fixed effect model is consistent whereas GLS
estimator of the random effect model becomes inconsistent. The proposed test makes use
of the difference between these two estimators (Baltagi, 1995: 68).
Econometric Results
Since current competitiveness should be determined by previous occurrences in the
economy, the considered model includes lagged values of independent variables. However,
it is necessary to reconcile the CIP data and education data available. The education data is
available for years 1975, 1980, 1985 and 1990. CIP is available for years 1985, 1990, 1998
and 2002. These dates imply two lags practically applicable; a 5-year lag or a 10-year lag
for education related data.
If a lag of 5 years is selected, CIP for 1985 will match education data for 1980 and CIP
data for 1990 will match the education data for year 1985. However, the education data for
1990 will have to be used for the 1998 CIP data, assuming that 1990 data is a good
indicator for education in 1993. Also, there will not be matching education data for the
year 2002. This would lead to a loss in time dimension of the panel data. In order to avoid
this loss, a lag of 10 years has been adopted. Therefore, 1985, 1990, 1998 and 2002 CIP
data are matched with 1975, 1980, 1985 and 1990 education data respectively. Implicit
here is the assumption that education data for 1985 and 1990 are good proxies for
corresponding education data for 1988 and 1992.
Basically, the model is planned to include three independent variables; one of them an
indicator of education and hence human capital, the second an indicator of modern
infrastructure and the last a representative of FDI flows. The data, as explained above,
exists. Actually, there is a surplus of variables to pick from. Therefore, two points are of
concern at this point: which independent variables will be used and which lags will be
chosen for these independent variables?
The last problem is actually partially solved by data restrictions: education related data
have to have a lag of 10 years. Trial and error by estimation of a considerable number of
models has led to the complete solution and the important result that all the trials point to
significant cross-section specific effects. The process also has eliminated the data on fixed
line and mobile phone subscribers per 100 people and real FDI flow as determinants of
CIP by identifying them as statistically insignificant at all lags. The fine tuning of the
adopted methodology will be presented here. The following table of data and related
abbreviations has been provided to make the discussion more comprehensible.
223
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 6: Variables and Abbreviated Names
Average schooling years in the total population
sch_aver
Average years of higher schooling in the total population.
sch_aver_hgh
Average years of primary schooling in the total population
sch_aver_pr
Average years of secondary schooling in the total population. sch_aver_sec
CIP
cip
Foreign direct investment, net inflows (% of GDP)
fdi_gdp
Percentage of "higher school attained" in the total pop
sch_hgh_a
Percentage of "higher school complete" in the total pop.
sch_hgh_c
Percentage of "no schooling" in the total population
sch_no
Percentage of "primary school attained" in the total pop.
sch_pr_a
Percentage of "primary school complete" in the total pop
sch_pr_c
Percentage of "secondary school attained" in the total pop
sch_scnd_a
Percentage of "secondary school complete" in the total pop
sch_scnd_c
Telephone mainlines (per 100 people)
telep_main_100
The most generic form of the model that is the basis of the analysis is as follows:
cipit = β0 + β1 fdi_gdpt-4 + telep_main_100t-3 + EDUCATIONt-10
(4)
Regarding sign expectations, foreign direct investment inflows are expected to enable
technological transfers and contribute to the competitiveness of manufacturing industry;
thus a positive sign is expected for the related coefficient. Telephone mainlines per 100
people is taken as an indicator of technical complexity of the relevant country. A higher
complexity is expected to contribute to higher competitiveness, leading to a positive sign
expectation. Higher education of the population would enable use of more complex
production techniques and enable production of goods with higher value added. Thus a
higher education level is expected to contribute to competitiveness and this should be
revealed by a positive sign.
Table 7: Models List with Relevant Education Variable
Model Name
Education Variable
Model 1
sch_aver(t-10)
Model 2
sch_aver_hgh(t-10)
Model 3
sch_aver_pr(t-10)
Model 4
sch_aver_sec(t-10)
Model 5
sch_hgh_a(t-10)
Model 6
sch_hgh_c(t-10)
Model 7
sch_pr_a(t-10)
Model 8
sch_pr_c(t-10)
Model 9
sch_scnd_a(t-10)
Model 10
sch_scnd_c(t-10)
Model 11
sch_no
224
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
By adopting various education related variables from the above table, it is possible to
introduce a number of models. These models are listed in Table 7 above. The pooled OLS,
fixed effects and random effects estimation results of these models are presented in Table 8
below.
Presented on the second column from the right on Table 8, the F-test rejects the null
hypothesis that fixed effects coefficients are jointly insignificant. The Hausman test, on the
other hand, leads to the rejection of the null hypothesis that GLS estimator of random
effects model is consistent. A fixed effects model is more preferable for it is not only
consistent but also takes into account the existence of cross section specific intercepts.
Note that this analysis holds for all the considered models.
Regarding significance of coefficients; FDI inflow coefficients are found to be positive and
statistically significant for all models and the three estimation methods. Telephone
mainlines per 100 people is statistically significant with positive sign for all models in case
of pooled OLS. However, once cross section specific effects are taken into account, this
variable turns insignificant for all but two of the models. The coefficient sign also turns
negative as well.
The situation is much more complicated in the case of education variables. The case of
model 11 should be considered separately for it uses percentage of no schooling in total
population. As more people receive no education, the competitiveness of the country
should decrease, creating a negative coefficient. The education coefficient expectation for
model 11 is negative.
Returning to the evaluation of models; in the case of pooled OLS, models 2, 5 and 6
display statistically significant results regarding education but with negative coefficients.
These models use average years of high schooling, percentage of high school attainment
and high school completion in total population, respectively. These results imply that
higher school education leads to a decrease in competitiveness, a situation contrary to
expectations. Leaving significance considerations aside, models 4, 7, 8, 9 and 10 display
expected signs on education variables. These models use secondary and primary education.
In the case of model 11, where education variable measures no education in total
population, the coefficient is negative.
These results imply dynamics contradictory with our expectations. As education level
decreases from higher levels to primary level, sign on education variable turns positive but
loses significance. This is emphasized by model 11 where the sign on education variable is
negative, implying that as the portion of population without education increases,
competitiveness falls.
Given such confusing results, it is fortunate that the F-test points to a fixed effects model.
In fixed effects estimation, FDI is statistically significant with the expected positive sign.
Telephone mainlines per 100 people has a negative effect in 10 of the considered models.
These negative coefficients are significant only in the case of models 3 and 11.
Regarding education, models 3, 7, 8 and 11 have statistically significant education
coefficients with expected signs. These models correspond to the cases of average primary
schooling years, primary school attainment ratio, primary school completion ratio and no
schooling ratio. This can be taken to indicate that lower education levels correspond to
225
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
higher competitiveness. Whenever the education coefficients are not significant, they are
negative contrary to sign expectations.
Consider the random effects estimations as the final case. Foreign direct investment has the
expected sign for all models. The coefficients for telephone mainlines are concentrated
around the value zero for all the models and are all insignificant except for model 11.
Education coefficients are no insignificant for all models other than model 7, 8 and 11.
First two of these models refer to primary school attainment and completion. The last
model refers to the case of no schooling and has a negative sign.
226
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 8: Estimation Results
OLS
Fixed Effects
Random Effects
Fixed Effects
Hausman
fdi_gdp(-4)
telep_main_100(-3)
EDUC
fdi_gdp(-4)
telep_main_100(-3)
EDUC
fdi_gdp(-4)
telep_main_100(-3)
EDUC
Test
Test
0.0142
0.0051
-0.0065
0.0073
-0.0013
0.0045
0.0061
-0.0006
0.0072
0.0000
0.0000
Model 1
2.4535
4.7355
-0.7869
2.4596
-1.5199
0.3568
2.1407
-0.7747
0.7871
(0.4401)
(0.4328)
(0.0157)
(0.0000)
(0.4330)
(0.0160)
(0.1323)
(0.7221)
(0.0344)
0.0137
0.0059
-0.1762
0.0077
-0.0007
-0.0681
0.0064
0.0002
-0.0746
0.0000
0.0000
Model 2
2.4183
6.0058
-2.3139
2.6189
-1.0104
-1.1053
2.2696
0.3646
-1.3219
(0.0172)
(0.0000)
(0.0225)
(0.0105)
(0.3152)
(0.2722)
(0.0251)
(0.7160)
(0.1888)
0.0144
0.0049
-0.0086
0.0070
-0.0018
0.0555
0.0060
-0.0006
0.0204
0.0000
0.0000
Model 3
2.5080
5.4891
-0.8931
2.4662
-2.6805
2.3761
2.2140
-0.9650
1.5457
(0.0136)
(0.0000)
(0.3737)
(0.0157)
(0.0089)
(0.0198)
(0.0288)
(0.3366)
(0.1250)
0.0149
0.0041
0.0108
0.0072
-0.0004
-0.0246
0.0061
-0.0002
-0.0010
0.0000
0.0000
Model 4
2.5615
3.4550
0.5277
2.4537
-0.4709
-1.1003
2.1446
0.7933
-0.0535
(0.9574)
(0.9574)
(0.0117)
(0.0008)
(0.5987)
(0.0162)
(0.6389)
(0.2744)
(0.0341)
0.0134
0.0060
-0.0054
0.0077
-0.0007
-0.0019
0.0062
0.0001
-0.0020
0.0000
0.0000
Model 5
2.3739
6.0801
-2.4355
2.60007
-1.1011
-1.1152
2.2233
0.2930
-1.2310
(0.0193)
(0.0000)
(0.0164)
(0.0110)
(0.2740)
(0.2680)
(0.0282)
(0.7700)
(0.2209)
0.0000
0.0001
-0.0046
0.0141
0.0055
-0.0080
0.0077
-0.0007
-0.0036
0.0066
0.0003
Model 6
-1.3683
2.4867
5.7969
-1.8349
2.6112
-0.9373
-0.9742
2.3201
0.4154
(0.1739)
(0.0221)
(0.6786)
(0.0144)
(0.0000)
(0.0692)
(0.0107)
(0.3513)
(0.3328)
0.0153
0.004946
0.0009
0.0088
5.16E-5
0.0032
0.0074
0.0006
0.0025
0.0000
0.0000
Model 7
2.6310
5.4516
0.8826
3.1389
0.0764
3.3813
2.7614
0.9469
3.0164
(0.0097)
(0.0000)
(0.3793)
(0.0023)
(0.9393)
(0.0011)
(0.0067)
(0.3457)
(0.0032)
0.0003
0.0032
0.0000
0.0000
0.0075
-0.0003
0.0037
0.0066
0.0001
0.0046
0.0145
Model 8
2.7019
-0.4687
3.3916
2.4741
0.4952
3.1670
0.0715
5.5451
2.4812
(0.0011)
(0.0148)
(0.6214)
(0.0020)
(0.9431)
(0.0084)
(0.6405)
(0.0000)
(0.0146)
-0.0001
0.0000
0.0000
-0.0002
0.0060
0.0144
0.0041
0.0008
0.0073
-0.0008
-0.0008
Model 9
-0.1222
-0.2866
2.1446
-0.7919
2.5019
3.8030
0.6157
2.4937
-1.1359
(0.7749)
(0.9029)
(0.0341)
(0.0146)
(0.2593)
(0.4307)
(0.0138)
(0.0002)
(0.5393)
0.0151
0.0039
0.0019
0.0073
-0.0011
0.0002
0.0063
-0.0005
0.0011
0.0000
0.0001
Model 10
2.6036
3.5595
0.8704
2.4731
-1.6394
0.1382
2.2073
-0.7226
0.7976
(0.0105)
(0.0005)
(0.3859)
(0.0154)
(0.1049)
(0.8904)
(0.0293)
(0.4714)
(0.4267)
0.0044
-0.0005
0.0151
0.0085
-0.0012
-0.0049
0.0076
-0.0011
-0.0043
0.0000
0.0001
Model 11
2.5231
4.2303
-0.3702
2.9922
-2.9390
-3.1162
2.7963
-1.9266
-3.2808
(0.0130)
(0.0000)
(0.7119)
(0.0036)
(0.0043)
(0.0025)
(0.0061)
(0.0565)
(0.0014)
Notes: Authors’ calculations. Presented below model coefficients are t-values, with p-values in parenthesis. Regarding significance; (*) denotes a significant coefficient at 10% level whereas (**) and
(***) denote 5% and 1% respectively. The three EDUC columns stand for the relevant education variables of models and report the coefficients and related statistics of relevanrt education data. Fixed
effects test is the F-test for the joint significance of cross-section specific intercepts. Last column is the Hausman test explained above. Both columns report only the p-values.
227
International Conference On Emerging Economic Issues In A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
It is possible to use fixed effects estimation results to obtain a relative standing of Turkey.
Since the dummy variable coefficient estimates in a fixed effect model point to how
different one country’s intercept is from the others, checking the dummy coefficients on
Turkey may be informative. Turkey’s dummy variable coefficient values for all 11 models
are presented in Table 9 below.
Table 9: Turkey’s Dummy Variable
Coefficient for Considered Models
Model 1
-0.2744
Model 2
-0.2981
Model 3
-0.138
Model 4
-0.3087
Model 5
-0.2982
Model 6
-0.2972
Model 7
-0.2279
Model 8
-0.2478
Model 9
-0.3011
Model 10
-0.2894
Model 11
-0.1084
It can be seen that the dummy has a negative coefficient for all considered models. This
can be taken to imply that Turkey’s intercept is lower than the average; specifically,
Turkey’s competitiveness is less than the group average.
The general impression obtained from econometric considerations is that FDI has a
positive and significant effect on international competitiveness as measured by CIP. Even
though pooled OLS results support the view that a technical infrastructure as measured by
telephone mainlines per 100 people has a positive and significant effect on competitiveness
of a country’s manufacturing industry, this view is questioned by fixed effects and random
effects estimation results.
It can be argued that a better measurement of modern infrastructure should be developed in
order to measure this effect better. Such a measure could include available data on number
of PCs per 100 people, number of internet users, secure internet server figures etc.
However, these data items are available for only recent years. A regression relating these
variables with competitiveness would raise a causality question. Does a country have a
modern infrastructure now because it is competitive or is it competitive because it has a
modern infrastructure? Such questions have already been eliminated by the current study
with the assumption that current competitiveness is determined by past values of variables.
An analysis that connects current competitiveness and current infrastructure (or any other
variable) should first be subject to causality tests. The moral of this discussion is that it is
not possible to have a better idea on whether technical / technological development as
indicated by a modern infrastructure is currently not possible to measure due to data
limitations. As more data becomes available on the technological development level of a
large group of countries, empirical research on the issue may flourish.
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
The conclusion is quite unclear in the case of education. The lack of a strong relationship
between education and competitiveness is against theoretical literature but apparently is
not an exception for a body of literature. Taking growth literature as the one closest to the
current study’s vision, it can be confirmed that the current study’s education relation
findings are not an exception but simply another drop in an ocean of debate.
Despite established theoretical relation between human capital and economic growth,
Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995: 537) find it difficult to empirically connect the two. One
other study admits that “… the channel from schooling to growth is too weak” and this
situation “remains true even when we take into consideration the effect of schooling on
technology adoption” (Bils and Klenov, 2000: 1177). Temple (2001) also concludes that
“the aggregate evidence on education and growth, for large samples of countries, continues
to be clouded with uncertainty”. A recent study, on the other hand, mentions that even if
education has the effect of accelerating growth, the lag may be many decades rather than
simply 10 years as is the case adopted above (Szirmai, 2008: 21-22).
As a result, what can be firmly concluded is that FDI inflows have a positive impact on
competitiveness. Modern infrastructure may contribute to competitiveness, but existing
measures are lacking in detail and the available data on a relatively lower technology like
existing telephone mainlines is simply inadequate to reflect the exact dynamics. Impact of
education is also questionable but this can be a reflection of an existing uncertainty in the
literature. Apparently, better measures of education or longer datasets are needed for more
detailed research. Dummy coefficients from fixed effects estimation show that Turkey’s
competitive standing is less than average and confirm the ranking lists of CIP.
Conclusions
It’s well known from the related literature that manufacturing industry is one of the major
components of countries’ competitiveness. It is the main source of innovations, a field for
application of technological development to production, creates positive externalities for
the rest of the economy and enables attainment of dynamic comparative advantage in
international trade.
From this viewpoint in this study, the competitive industrial performance (CIP) index,
taken to be an indicator of relative competitive ability, has been calculated for a sample of
33 countries for years 1985, 1990, 1998 and 2002. Panel data methods then have been
employed to reveal sources of competitive ability. The insights obtained from the
conducted analysis can be summarized as follows.
Indicator results imply a spatial shift of production of medium and high technology goods
from developed countries to some of the developing countries. This is confirmed by CIP
results where a small number of relatively less developed countries are catching up with
developed countries in terms competitive ability. Turkey does not appear to be part of this
process and displays poor competitive standing compared to other countries in the sample.
Econometric results confirm that Turkey is lagging behind other countries in terms of
competitive ability. The negative coefficient on Turkey’s dummy in fixed effects model
signifies the situation. It is also observed that FDI is a major determinant of competitive
ability; attempts to attract FDI would contribute to future well being of a country.
229
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Moreover education proves to be an elusive variable in determining competitive ability. It
is possible that education is not a good instrument to represent skills. Such elusive
behavior of education, however, is not an uncommon occurrence and has been encountered
many times in the empirical part of growth literature. One other interesting note is that
econometric results imply that too much schooling may be unnecessary for development of
competitive abilities. It is possible that on-the-job training or development of skills through
practice is a better determinant of competitiveness than formal education.
Telephone mainlines per 100 people, as a variable, either contributes negatively to
competitiveness of a country or has no effect at all. The statistical significance of negative
effect is also in doubt. Two conclusions are possible: either modern infrastructure is not
related to competitiveness or a better modern infrastructure measurement is necessary. A
better measure is currently not possible due to unavailability of datasets with long time
dimension.
Lastly, as a policy recommendation, Turkey should focus on attracting more FDI and focus
on technical training of the workforce rather than concentrate on providing higher and
higher levels of education.
230
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
References
Baltagi, Badi H. (1995) Econometric Analysis of Panel Data, John Wiley & Sons Ltd.
Sussex, England.
Barro, Robert J. and Xavier Sala-i-Martin (1995) Economic Growth, McGraw Hill: New
Y. york USA.
Bils, Mark and Peter J. Klenov (2000) “Does Schooling Cause Growth?” American
Economic Review, 90(5).
Erlat, Haluk (2008) Panel Data: A Selective Survey,Unpublished Lecture Notes.
Greene, William H. (2003) Econometric Analysis, Prentice Hall: New Jersey, USA.
Hausman, J. A. (1978) “Specification Tests in Econometrics” Econometrica, 46, 12511271.
Hsiao, Cheng (2003) Analysis of Panel Data, Cambridge University Press: Cambridge,
UK.
Johnston, Jack and John DiNardo (1997) Econometric Methods, McGraw-Hill Book Co.
Kennedy, Peter (2003) A Guide to Econometrics, Blackwell Publishing: Oxford: UK.
Swamy, P. A. V. B. and S. S. Arora (1972) “The Exact Finite Sample Properties of the
Estimators of Coefficients in the Error Components Regression Models” Econometrics, 40,
261-275.
Szirmai, Adam (2008) “Explaining Success and Failure in Development”, United Nations
University Working Paper Series No. 2008-13.
Temple, Jonathan R. W. (2001) Generalizations That Aren’t? Evidence on Education and
Growth”, European Economic Review 45(4-6).
UNIDO. (2002). “Industrial Development Report 2002/2003: Competing through
Innovation and Learning”. http://www.unido.org.
UNIDO. (2005). “Industrial Development Report 2005: Capacity Building for Catching
Up; Historical, Empirical and Policy Dimensions”. UNIDO Publication No. 454.
http://www.unido.org.
Barro, R.J. and Lee, J-W. (2000). “International Data on Educational Attainment: Updates
and Implications”. CID Working Paper No.42. Harvard University.
231
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Use of e-commerce in Small and Medium Size Enterprises: An
Application in Ankara
A. Ramazan Altınok
Prime Ministry, Turkey
Fuat Erdal
Adnan Menderes University, Turkey
Abstract
A great deal of efficiency and productivity increase has been achieved in the production
process through the use of information and communication technologies (ICTs) in recent
years. These developments have created remarkable opportunities for the small and
medium size enterprises (SMEs) whose advertising and marketing budgets are relatively
limited.
A comprehensive survey and interviews are carried out with a sample of SMEs in OSTIM
and Sincan Industrial Districts in Ankara in order to find out the present use of ecommerce in the SMEs, its perceived advantages, potential problems and the future
expectations.
The ordered logit models are estimated to investigate the factors affecting the use of ecommerce in the firms, potential advantages of e-commerce use and the main obstacles in
implementing the ICTs.
The results reveal that the firms are aware of the fact that e-commerce would increase the
speed of business, lower the cost of production, give competitive advantage, enable to
reach the customers easily and expand the markets and that B2B and B2C e-commerce and
the use of ICTs are more common in relatively bigger firms (in terms of capital, sales
revenue and employment).
The main reasons why the SMEs are not able to use ICTs are found as the lack of
information and specialized personnel, security and legal framework.
232
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Introduction
A great deal of efficiency and productivity increase has been achieved in the production
process through the use of information and communication technologies (ICTs) in recent
years. These developments have created remarkable opportunities for the small and
medium size enterprises (SMEs) whose advertising and marketing budgets are relatively
limited. Implementation of e-commerce by the SMEs, the most dynamic components of an
economy, is expected to have significant impacts on the future of the country.
Invention of Internet probably one of the most important developments in the history of
mankind. When the project called ARPANET which was designed as a defense system was
opened to the civil use after the end of cold war, many changes has happened in the
relations between citizen-to-citizen, citizen-to-government, citizen-to-business and
business-to-business.
Internet covers almost all communication tools such as fax, telephone and TV, it is
interactive, it removes the geographical barriers, it enables economic transactions as well
as cultural and social relations in only seconds. Such a rapidly developing technology will
make the world smaller in the information age. A remarkable increase has been achieved in
efficiency and productivity in many areas by means of the ICTs.
From 2000, fiber-optics with 160 channels were able to transmit 1.6 trillion byte
information. By this way, the whole American Library which contains 110 million
documents can be transferred to somewhere else within 14 seconds (Schiesel, 1999)
Business life has also benefited significantly from the Internet technologies. Almost all
commercial activities (except delivery) to sell or purchase a product can be done via
Internet: Orders, advertising, marketing, payment, follow up of delivery and so on. This
new type of trade is called as e-commerce.
ICTs has brought remarkable advantages particularly for the SMEs. It has become possible
for the SME’s to compete with the giant competitors at least in the cyber-world
Internet in Turkey
The use of Internet started in the universities in 1980s as a part of European Academic and
Research Network (EARN), however, Internet service providers started in 1992. There
were 600.000 pc with Internet connection in 1999, it has reached to 5.5 million pc in 2003.
Business-to-Business (B2B) and Business-to-Customer (B2C) commerce have started in
1997, but spread after 2001. The pioneers of B2C e-commerce are Migros and TEBA. The
supermarket chain Migros started cyber market in 1997, while TEBA has sold electronic
kitchen equipments (Arıcı, 2000:26). In 2002 9,2 % of the firms use B2B and 8.7% of the
firms use B2C commerce (Bili im, 2002:65). E-commerce activities are still low when
compared to the Europe. It is widely used in banking and financial sectors, travel and
tourism sectors and now in goods markets. Table 1 presents some figures about the use of
computers and Internet in Turkey.
The most comprehensive surveys on the use of Internet in business in Turkey are done by
Turkish Institute of Statistics in 2005 and KOSGEB in 2005. 68% of SMEs are connected
to Internet, 37 % have web site and 7% does e-commerce (TUIK, 2005, KOSGEB 2006).
233
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 1: Use of information technologies in Turkey
Telephone lines (unit per 100 people)
Mobile phones (unit per 1000 people)
Personal computer (unit per 1000 people)
Internet users (1000 people)
Expenditures of ICTs (million $)
Share in GDP (%)
1995
211
7
14,7
50
2777
1, 6
2001
295
302
40,7
2.500
9.333
3, 6
Source: OECD, 2004
Turkey has recorded a significant increase in the use of ICT’s and Internet, it is still low
when compared to the EU, USA, Japan and OECD. Table 2 shows a comparison of basic
figures.
Table 2: Information and communication technologies
Turkey
Internet access per 100 people (2001)
27,55
Internet channels per 100 people (2001) 27,5
Mobile subscribers per 100 people 26,8
(2001)
Broad band subscribers per 100 people 0,06
(2003)
Telecom investment per capita (US$ 42
2001)
Public telephone investment per access 152
channels (US$, 2001)
PC per 100 people (2001)
2,65
Internet users over fixed service 5
providers per 100 people (2001)
EU
44,33
58,9
74,3
USA
53,03
62,5
49,1
Japan
40,09
58,4
58,8
OECD
45,58
54,5
8,9
4,95
8,25
8,6
6,05
129,67
330
190,04 109,23
212,68
493,97 331,94 310,61
27,5
16,8
81,77
27,2
38,79
18,9
39,48
13,7
Source: OECD, 2004
Use of Information Technologies In Small And Medium Size Enterprises
The coverage of Internet use in businesses change from simply having a website to using
ICTs in all production process. In order to exploit the potential benefits of ICTs, the
companies should have good management organization, technical capacity and innovative
skills. The United Nations e-commerce report draws attention to particularly three issues in
using Internet in businesses:
1. Broad band Internet access should be expanded to cover rural areas.
2. Legal and regulatory framework should be settled to proceed to e-businesses.
234
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
3. If we want the SMEs to use Internet not only for mail and research but also for an
integrated e-business, additional investment should be done and e-business strategies
should be developed (UN, 2004:XXIV).
A statistical survey in the UK reveals that half of the big firms, 20% of the medium size
firms (50–249 employees) and 8% of small size firms use e-business systems (Goodridge
and Clayton, 2004). Another research on 2000 firms in Canada finds that e-business
increases remarkable productivity, increases revenues by 7%, decreases sales and
management costs by 7,5% and decreases general costs by 9,5 % (CeBI, 2002).
Data and Methodology
There are 4074 small and medium size enterprises in Ankara and total employment is
57414 in 2005. A comprehensive survey is carried out with a sample of SMEs in OSTIM
and Sincan Industrial Districts in Ankara in order to find out the present use of ecommerce in the SMEs, its perceived advantages, potential problems and the future
expectations. A questionnaire with 21 questions is designed for that purpose. 250 of them
are filled by face-to-face interviews and 50 questionnaires are filled by electronic survey
on the Internet.
Empirical Analyses
Initially, the data obtained are analyzed by correlations and cross tabulations. Then ordered
logit models are estimated to investigate the factors affecting the use of e-commerce in the
firms, potential advantages of e-commerce use and the main obstacles in implementing the
ICTs.
Descriptive statistics
Before testing the hypotheses, Table 3 present information about the respondents. About
90 % of the respondents are secondary and high school graduates. 36 % of the firms
employ between 50 to 100 people. Sectoral composition of the firms are varied thus 60 %
of the firms indicated as the other sectors than the listed.
235
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Annual sales
revenues (YTL)
Average age
of the
employees
Sectors
Number of
employees
Education levels
Table 3: Descriptive statistics about the respondents
Factors
Primary school
Secondary school
High school
University
Graduate
TOTAL
1-9
10-24
25-49
50-99
100 +
TOTAL
Textiles
Furnitures
Industrial products
Food
Others
TOTAL
18-25
26-35
36-40
41-50
Numbers
4
125
146
18
7
300
84
40
65
108
3
300
24
34
50
13
179
300
27
231
32
10
TOTAL 300
Less than 20.000
16
20.000-50.000
63
51.000-100.000
21
100.000-250.000
31
More than 250.000
169
TOTAL 300
%
1,3
41,7
48,7
6,0
2,3
100,0
28,0
13,3
21,7
36,0
1,0
100,0
8,0
11,3
16,7
4,3
59,7
100,0
9,0
77,0
10,7
3,3
100,0
5,3
21,0
7,0
10,3
56,3
100,0
77 % of the employees are the age of between 26-35 years. Finally annual sales revenues
are 250.000 YTL for 56 percent of the companies. One of the critical questions asked to
the firms is whether they use e-commerce in their businesses. More than half of the sample
use e-commerce as indicated in Table 4.
Table 4: Use of e-commerce
Yes
No
TOTAL
Frequency
156
144
300
%
52,0
48,0
100,0
236
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
In addition to the descriptive question about the respondents, 21 questions are asked in five
points scale of Lickert type as:
Fully agree : 1
Agree
:2
Non decided : 3
Disagree
:4
Fully disagree : 5
The answers and their averages are shown in Table 5. As can bee seen from the table,
many of the managers agree with the advantages of e-commerce such as speeding up the
commercial transactions, lowering costs, facilitating to reach to the customers, expanding
the markets. They are worried about the security and legal framework. Moreover, lack of
government support and skilled personnel are specified as the other barriers to do ecommerce.
Table 5: Dependent variables (answers) for e-commerce user companies
1
1-We have retail / wholesale sales over Internet
33
2-We use Internet in business with our agents
38
3-E-commerce is the trade model of the future
119
4-E-commerce speeds up the commercial 115
transactions
5-E-commerce enables to reach to customer with 99
lower cost
6-E-commerce facilitates to reach the potential 39
customers
7-E-commerce facilitates to reach world markets 37
by lowering costs
8-E-commerce expands the market and solves 41
marketing problem
9-E-commerce gives a competitive advantage to 114
my firm
10-Having a website in Internet makes the firms’ 122
image stronger in the market
11-Internet is necessary for R and D
126
12- My company will be more dependent on e- 29
commerce in the next 5 years
13-We can decide to invest on e-commerce after 39
seeing successful examples
14-E-commerce is not secure
10
15- Government’s support e-commerce is not 22
sufficient
16-There is no sufficient legal framework for e- 23
commerce
17-We have lack of information and personnel 26
for e-commerce
2
20
112
28
27
3
80
4
5
2
4
13
2
0
6
5
11
1
5
7
32
5
10
11
101
4
6
7
102
6
4
8
91
9
11
5
17
8
9
9
18
2
9
6
14
93
4
21
5
9
8
5
26
79
6
7
22
105
23
14
94
9
9
8
105
15
12
3
103
5
13
11
Average
2,6752
1,8280
1,3694
1,4904
1,7389
1,9873
2,0064
2,0318
1,6115
1,4650
1,4395
2,1592
2,4650
3,4430
2,2152
2,1582
2,2405
237
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Several questions are asked for those companies who do not use e-commerce about the
causes, as presented in Table 6. Financial difficulties and inappropriateness of the products
for the Internet sales are stated as main reasons why they do not have e-commerce.
However, they all agree that they will use it in the near future.
Table 6: Dependent variables (answers) for non-e-commerce users
1
2
18-We do not use e-commerce due to financial
34
problems
19-We do not use e-commerce because our products
60
are not appropriate for Internet sales
20- We want to have a web site in the future
98
21- We will connect to the Internet soon
111
3
4
5
Average
48 10 27 23 2,6972
18 29 18 17 2,3944
25 7
18 6
3
1
9
6
1,5915
1,4014
Test of hypotheses through correlations and cross-tabulations
Several hypotheses related to the use of e-commerce will be tested by cross-tabulations and
bilateral correlations. Some noticeable results are reported in Tables 7 to 12.
Hypothesis 1: Use of e-commerce becomes more common as the firm gets bigger (in
terms of no of employees)
Table 7: Use of e-commerce and company size (in terms of number of employees)
Use of e-commerce
No of employees in the firm
1-9
10-24
25-49
27
19
24
50-99
85
100+
2
Total
1-9
157
17,2
12,1
15,3
54,1
1,3
100,0
57
21
41
23
1
143
%
39,9
14,7
28,7
16,1
,7
100,0
Total
%
84
40
65
108
3
300
28,0
13,3
21,7
36,0
1,0
100,0
Yes
%
No
χ2=50.643
d.f.=4 χ2 (table) =9.49 P<0.05
Cross-tab test (χ2 being greater than the table value) indicates that there is a positive
relationship between the use of e-commerce and firm size. Both parametric and nonparametric correlation tests supports that conclusion:
Pearson Correlation:
Kendall's tau_b:
Spearman's rho:
-0,342**
-0,330**
-0,360**
Hypothesis 2: Use of e-commerce becomes more common as the firm gets bigger (in
terms of sales revenue)
238
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 8: Use of e-commerce and company size (in terms of sales revenues)
Annual sales revenue of the firm (YTL)
Use of
commerce
Yes
e- <20.000
20.00050.000
51.000100.000
100.000- >250.000
250.000
Total
5
16
7
8
121
157
3,2
10,2
4,5
5,1
77,1
100,0
11
47
14
23
48
143
%
7,7
32,9
9,8
16,1
33,6
100,0
Total
%
χ2=58.101
16
5,3
63
21
21,0
7,0
χ2 (table) =9.49
31
10,3
169
56,3
300
100,0
%
No
d.f.= 4
P<0.05
According to the result of the test, the possibility of using e-commerce is higher as the
sales revenue increases. Further support comes from the correlation tests below:
Pearson Correlation:
Kendall's tau_b:
Spearman's rho:
-0,380**
-0,384**
-0,412**
Hypothesis 3: Use of e-commerce (B2C) becomes more common as the firm gets bigger
(in terms of sales revenue)
Table 9: Use of B2C e-commerce and the firm size (annual sales)
Use of B2C
Fully agree
%
Agree
%
Non decided
%
Disagree
%
Fully disagree
%
Total
χ2=58.101
Annual sales (YTL)
Less than 20.00020.000
50.000
2
4
6,1
12,1
0
2
,0
10,0
51.000100.000
2
6,1
3
15,0
100.000250.000
4
12,1
3
15,0
Total
More than
250.000
21
63,6
12
60,0
33
100,0
20
100,0
0
,0
1
7,7
2
18,2
5
3,2%
0
,0
1
7,7
1
9,1
7
4,5%
0
,0
0
,0
1
9,1
8
5,1%
80
100,0
1
7,7
7
63,6
121
77,1%
80
100,0
13
100,0
11
100,0
157
100,0%
0
,0
10
76,9
0
,0
16
10,2%
d.f. = 16 χ2t =26.30
P<0.05
239
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
The hypothesis 3 cannot be rejected at 5% level as the χ2 value is greater than the critical
value. That is, bigger companies are more inclined to use B2C commerce. The correlation
tests provides additional support to that argument as stated below:
Pearson Correlation:
0,423**
Kendall's tau_b:
0,407**
Spearman's rho:
0,455**
Hypothesis 4: Use of B2B e-commerce becomes more common as the education level of
the employees gets higher
Table 10: Use of B2B e-commerce and the education level of employees
Use of B2B
Fully agree
%
Agree
%
Non decided
%
Disagree
%
Full disagree
%
Total
%
χ2=119.789
Total
Average education level of the employees
Secondary
3
7,9
56
50,0
1
25,0
0
,0
0
,0
60
38,2
High
school
26
68,4
51
45,5
0
,0
0
,0
1
100,0
78
49,7
d.f. =12 χ2t = 21.00
University
7
18,4
5
4,5
0
,0
0
,0
0
,0
12
7,6
Graduate
2
5,3
0
,0
3
75,0
2
100,0
0
,0
7
4,5
38
100,0
112
100,0
4
100,0
2
100,0
1
100,0
157
100,0
P<0.05
The test indicates that there is a positive relationship between the level of education
of the employees and the business-to-business e-commerce use by the firms.
Nonparametric tests supports that result.
Pearson Correlation :
Kendall's tau_b:
Spearman's rho:
-0,012
-0,230**
-0,234**
Hypothesis 5: Relatively bigger firms (in terms of sales revenue) agree that use of ecommerce speeds up the transactions
240
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 11: Use of e-commerce and the speed of commercial transactions
E-commerce
speeds
transactions
up
Annual sales (YTL)
Less than 20.00020.000
50.000
51.000100.000
100.000250.000
More than
250.000
4
3
3
4
101
115
%
Agree
3,5
2,6
2,6
3,5
87,8
100,0
1
10
0
2
14
27
%
3,7
37,0
,0
7,4
51,9
100,0
0
0
0
1
1
2
%
Disagree
,0
,0
,0
50,0
50,0
100,0
0
2
1
0
3
6
%
Fully disagree
,0
33,3
16,7
,0
50,0
100,0
0
1
3
1
2
7
%
,0
14,3
42,9
14,3
28,6
100,0
Total
%
5
3,2
16
10,2
7
4,5
8
5,1
121
77,1
157
100,0
χ2=74,021
d.f.=16
Fully agree
Not decided
Total
χ2t =26.30
P<0.05
The hypothesis cannot be rejected, supporting the argument that bigger firms agree that use
of e-commerce increases the speed of economic transactions. Bilateral correlation tests
supports that view as well.
Pearson v-correlation:
Kendall's tau_b:
Spearman's rho:
-0,314**
-0,385**
-0,482**
Hypothesis 6: Lack of legal framework makes the use of e-commerce difficult
241
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 12: Use of B2C e-commerce and sufficiency of legal framework
Legal
framework of
e-commerce is
not sufficient
Fully agree
Agree
Undecided
Disagree
Fully
disagree
Total
We use B2C e-commerce
Total
Fully
agree
13
13
2
4
Agree
3
11
3
3
Fully
Undecided Disagree disagree
0
1
5
76
2
3
0
10
0
2
0
3
22
105
15
12
1
0
2
0
0
3
33
20
80
13
11
χ2=140.153
d.f.=16
χ2t =26.30
157
P<0.05
The users of B2C e-commerce agree with the view that the legal framework of Internet use
is still not sufficient. Nonparametric tests gives further support for that view.
Kendall's tau_b:
Spearman's rho:
0,167*
0,173*
Econometric Analyses
In this section, the factors affecting the use of e-commerce by the SMEs, the potential
benefits of using e-commerce in business and the main barriers to use e-commerce will be
analyzed by econometric logit models. Logit and probit models are useful models for
discreet dependent variable and discreet data. Logit models are preferred if the
observations are skewed towards to the end or beginning (Emcee, 2002:14). As the data
obtained through the survey seem to show non-normal distribution, ordered logit model is
used in this study.
The first empirical analyses investigates whether the characteristics of the company have
an impact on the use of e-commerce. The following ad hoc model is estimated for that
purpose:
Use of e-commerce = f (No of employees, education level of employees, annual sales
revenue of the firm, average age of employees).
Table 13 presents the estimation results of the model. Likelihood Ratio (LR) statistics
indicates that the model is significant as a whole. While interpreting the results, the
codification of the survey data should be kept in mind: 1 indicates ‘fully agree’, while 5
indicates ‘fully disagree’.
242
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 13: The factors affecting the use of B2C e-commerce (Dependent variable: B2C
e-commerce)
Variables
Education
No of employees
Sales revenue
Age of employees
Limit Points
Limit_2
0.347
Limit_3
1.325
Limit_4
4.429
Limit_5
5.409
Diagnostic Statistics
LR statistics
63.542
LR prob value 0,000
Pseudo-R2
0,154
N
156
Model 1
Coefficient
-0.172
1.272**
-0.792**
1.036*
0.315
1.175
3.864
4.648
Z-statistics
-0.675
6.441
-4.578
2.466
0.612
1.585
4.679
5.665
Model 2
Coefficient
--1.309**
-0.817**
0.936*
Z-statistics
--6.924
-4.806
2.399
0.598
1.505
4.329
5.158
63.083
0.000
0.152
156
*p< 0.05, ** p<0.01.
The electronic commerce between the firm and the customer (B2C) is affected positively
by the sales revenue of the company and education level of the employees. The
implementation of e-commerce increases as the company size increases and education
level of the employees rises. On the other hand, smaller firms with respect to number of
employees seems to use more e-commerce probably in order to reach the markets easily.
Younger people are more familiar with the Internet using, thus the companies with
relatively younger employees are more inclined to use e-commerce in their businesses.
Excluding the education variable, which is found to be nonsignificant statistically, from the
model does not change the results as seen in Model 2.
The above model is re-estimated by changing the dependent variable as B2B e-commerce
and the results are given in Table 14.
243
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 14: The factors affecting the use of B2B e-commerce (Dependent variable: B2B
e-commerce)
Model 1
Coefficient
0.895**
-0.200
-0.171
1.190*
Variables
No of employees
Sales revenue
Education
Age of employees
Limit Points
Limit_2
2.570
Limit_3
7.348
Limit_4
8.265
Limit_5
9.396
Diagnostic Statistics
LR Statistics 35.319
LR
prob 0.000
value
Pseudo-R2
0.147
N
156
Model 2
Z-statistics Coefficient
4.474
0.935**
-1.092
-0.217
-0.543
--2.540
1.091*
2.012
5.201
5.457
5.414
2.883
7.674
8.609
9.744
Z-statistics
5.058
-1.208
--2.561
2.650
6.010
6.232
6.021
35.019
0.000
0.146
156
*p< 0.05, ** p<0.01.
Sales revenue of the firm does not seem to affect e-commerce with their agents. However,
the number of employees and average age have negative effects on the use of e-commerce.
Smaller firms with younger employees seem to prefer to use e-commerce.
Second group of econometric analyses relates the characteristics of the firm to the
perceived benefits of e-commerce. It investigates whether the perceived benefits of ecommerce vary with the characteristics of the company. The following model is estimated
accordingly:
Benefits of e-commerce = f (No of employees, education level of employees, annual
sales of the firm)
244
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 15: Perception of e-commerce
Benefits of
e-commerce
Commercial model of future
Lower cost
Easier reach to customers
Faster trade
Opening to world markets
Expanding markets
Competitive advantage
Powerful image
Research & development
No
of Sales revenue
employees
-0,803**
-0,455**
(-3,467)
(-0.455)
-0.614**
-0.557**
(-3.508)
(-3.258)
0.545**
0.182
(3.066)
(1.093)
-0.239
-0.655**
(-1.281)
(-3.699)
0.248
0.222
(1.367)
(1.311)
0.321
0.229
(1.789)
(1.283)
-0.457*
-0.479*
(-2.538)
(-2.811)
-0.412*
-0.357*
(-2.219)
(-1.945)
-0.150
-0.579**
(-0762)
(-3.023)
Education
-0.829*
(-2.176)
0.962**
(3.525)
0.452
(1.805)
0.671*
(2.234)
0.446
(1.762)
0.512*
(2.009)
0.926*
3.270
1.472**
(4.872)
1.423**
(4.702)
*p< 0.05, ** p<0.01. The figures in brackets are z-statistics
According to the results given in Table 15, as the firm size increases with respect to both
number of employees and annual sales revenue, e-commerce is perceived to be the trade
model of future. Education level of the employees influences that perception positively.
Relatively bigger companies think that use of e-commerce would lower the costs, speeds
up the commercial activities, gives competitive advantage and provides a powerful image
for the firm. On the other hand, the perception of the potential benefits such as expanding
the markets, opening up to the world markets, supporting R & D facilities do not seem to
be affected by the characteristics of the firms.
The last group of empirical analyses focuses on the barriers to use of e-commerce. The
literature as well the face-to-face interviews in the field expose several problems in using
e-commerce in businesses, including the lack of sufficient legal framework, specialized
personnel and information, government guidance and finding trade in cyber world
insecure. The following model is estimated in order to examine whether these specified
problems are valid for our sample of firms:
e-commerce = f (security, government support, legal framework , knowledge and
specialized personnel)
Again two models are estimated with two dependent variables: B2B commerce and B2C
commerce. The results are presented in Table 16 and 17.
245
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 17: Barriers to e-commerce (Dependent variable: B2B e-commerce)
Potential barriers
Security
Government support
Legal framework
Knowledge
and
personnel
LR statistics
LR prob value
Pseudo R2
n
Coefficient
1,004**
0.052
1.323**
specialized 0.500*
z-statistics
4,502
0.152
3.204
1.849
56.864
0.000
0.237
156
*p< 0.05, ** p<0.01.
Positive and significant coefficients indicate that lack of security, proper legal framework,
knowledge and skilled personnel are main impediments to use e-commerce for many
businesses. However, the lack of government support does not seem to be taken as a
barrier to use e-commerce. The analysis is repeated by changing the dependent variable to
B2C commerce to see if trade between the firm and the agents is influenced by these
barriers. The estimation results are presented in Table 18. The results are almost the same
with the previous estimations.
Table 18: Barriers to e-commerce (Dependent variable: B2C e-commerce)
Potential barriers
Security
Insufficient Government support
Legal framework
Knowledge and specials personnel
LR statistics
LR prob value
Pseudo R2
n
Coefficient
0,441*
-0.411
1.003**
0.591*
18.314
0.000
0.044
156
z-statistics
2,351
-1.693
3.074
2.547
*p< 0,05, ** p<0,01.
Conclusion
Firms are aware of the fact that e-commerce would increase the speed of business, lower
the cost of production, give competitive advantage, enable to reach the customers easily
and expand the markets. Particularly small and medium size enterprises have to adopt
changing information and communication technologies rapidly in order to exploit these
benefits and become competitive in globalizing world markets..
B2B and B2C e-commerce and the use of ICTs are more common in relatively bigger
firms in terms of capital, sales revenue and employment. The main reasons why the SMEs
are not able to use ICTs are found as the lack of information and specialized personnel,
security and legal framework.
246
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
References
Emeç, H. (2002) “Ege Bölgesi Tüketim Harcamaları Đçin Sıralı Logit Tahminleri ve
Senaryo Sonuçları”, Dokuz Eylül Üniversitesi, Sosyal Bilimler Dergisi, 4(2): 13-29.
CEBI, 2002, Canadian e-Business Initiative Net Impact Study Canada: The SME
Experience, CEBI. www.netimpactstudy.com [20.06.2006].
OECD (2004) Türkiye’deki Küçük ve Orta Ölçekli Đ letmeler, Mevcut Durum ve
Politikalar, OECD:Ankara.
KOSGEB (2006) “Bölgesel Kalkınma Ara tırma Raporu, TR 51 Ankara Alt Bölgesi”,
KOSGEB:Ankara.
Schiesel, S., “Nortel Plans New Product To Bolster Optical Networks”, The New York
Times, 4 May 1999. http://www.nytimes.com/library/tech/99/05/biztech/ articles/
04nortel.html [20.10.2007]
TUIK, (2005) Hane Halkı Bili im Anketi, Ankara. www.tuik.gov.tr [20.06.2008]
UN, (2004), Global E-Readiness Report, New York.
http://www2.unpan.org/egovkb/global_reports/04report.htm[20.06.2008]
247
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Similarities and Differences of The 1994 and 2001 Turkish Currency
Crises: A Signal Approach
akir Görmü
Adnan Menderes University, Turkey
Recep Tekeli
Adnan Menderes University, Turkey
Osman Peker
Adnan Menderes University, Turkey
Abstract
The paper will examine the 1994 and 2001 Turkish currency crises by using early warning
system which is based on the “signal” approach proposed by Kaminsky, Lizondo and
Reinhart (KLR) (1998). The “signal” approach is a non-parametric approach. In this
approach, the behavior of a number of individual variables is monitored and they are
evaluated against a certain threshold levels. If any of these indicator exceeds its threshold,
it is said that indicator issues a “signal” that a currency crisis may occur within a given
period.
The objectives of this paper are two folds: to investigate causes of currency crises under
consideration and to compare similarities and differences of the 1994 and 2001 currency
crises. The data consist of monthly data and range from January 1987 to November 2005
for the following variables: reserves, inflation rate, GDP growth, portfolio capital inflow to
reserves, short term external debt to reserves, domestic debt, money supply to reserves,
current account to GDP, real exchange rate overvaluation, regional stock market return,
regional market pressure index, stock market index, export and import.
Results showed that 2001 crisis is deeper and costlier than 1994 crisis, external factors play
more imported role in 2001 crisis than 1994 crisis and in both crises Weighted Composite
Index increases sharply previous the both crises.
248
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Introduction
Turkey experiences two major currency crises in the post stabilization and liberalization
period. After the April 1994 currency crisis, the Turkish economy once again found itself
more severe and persistent currency crises in February 2001. The effect of the 1994 and
2001 currency crises on the Turkish economy were extremely costly. In 1994 and 2001,
GDP (unemployment) decreased (increased) 4 % (7%) and 9 % (12%), respectively1.
Even though there are a great deal of studies related to the 1994 and 2001 Turkish currency
crises, most of them investigate each crises separately2. Therefore, those studies can not
reach a general conclusion about causes of the 1994 and 2001 currency crises and can not
compare the similarities and the differences of the 1994 and 2001 currency crises. To fill
up this gap, it is worth to study the causes of the 1994 and 2001 currency crises and try to
show similarities and differences of both currency crises.
The paper will examine the 1994 and 2001 currency crises by using early warning system
which is based on the “signal” approach proposed by Kaminsky, Lizondo and Reinhart
(1998). The “signal” approach is a non-parametric approach. In this approach, the
behavior of a number of individual variables is monitored and they are evaluated against a
certain threshold levels. If any of these indicator exceeds its threshold, it is said that
indicator issues a “signal” that a currency crisis may occur within a given period.
The paper is organized as follows. In section 2, we provide a brief literature review about
financial crises models. In section 3, we introduce “signal approach”, data and variables.
In section 4, we represent our results from “signal approach” model. Section 5 is
conclusion.
Financial Crises Models
There are mainly two approaches in the literature to explain the determinants of currency
crises. The first-generation model was developed by Krugman (1979) and extended by
Flood and Garber (1984) in response to currency crises in developing countries in the
1980s. According to the first-generation currency crises model, expansionary fiscal and
monetary policies are inconsistent with fixed exchange rate policies. When the fiscal
deficit is financed by expansion of domestic credit, reserves decrease to defend the fixed
exchange rate and significant loss of reserves forces the authorities either to devalue or
float the domestic currency.
Second-generation models are due to Obstfeld (1986) and later extended by him (1994,
1996) to respond to currency crises when the fundamentals of an economy were sound, as
in the 1990s. According to second-generation models, changes in the government’s
objective function change agents’ expectation and trigger currency crises. In Obstfeld’s
(1994, 1996) model, the government favors lower unemployment and higher output: hence
when the costs of defending the peg (such as higher interest rates, higher unemployment,
lower growth) are more than the benefit of defending the peg (such as gaining credibility
and lower inflation) the government devalues even if macroeconomic fundamentals such
as foreign debt, budget deficit, reserves etc are sound.
1
T.C.M.B.
2 Yeni Türkiye Dergisi (2001), Kriz özel sayısı 41 and Ekonomik Kriz Oncesi Erken Uyari Sistemleri
(2006).
249
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
There are mainly two alternative methods to predict to currency crises. First one is limited
dependent variables estimation which using logit or probit model to predict financial
crises. Due to the failure of the limited dependent variables estimation method to predict
the currency crisis, Kaminsky, Lizondo and Reinhart (KLR) came out a new approach in
1998, which is called “Signal Approach”. In signal approach, each variable are monitored
separately from each other and the deviation of the variable exceeds a certain “threshold”
value before crises give us an early warning signal about a possible currency crisis within a
specific period of time.
Signal approach has some advantages. First, if variables have sharp changes between crisis
and tranquility periods, signal approach may predict crises better. Second, indicators can
be ranked according to noise-to signal ratio, which ability of indicator to predict crises and
avoid false signals.
KLR (1998) surveyed a large number of empirical studies to identify the most important
indicators. Their survey covered 76 currency crises and included 15 developing and 5
developed countries during 1970-1995. Out of more than 100 indicators, they founded
following (real exchange rate, real interest rate, imports, M2 multiplier, output, bank
deposits, “excess” M1 balances, exports, terms of trade, international reserves, stock
prices, real interest rate differential, M2/international reserves, lending rate/deposit rate
and domestic credit/GDP) 15 indicators most important. In their empirical work for signal
approach, they found that the best indicators of currency crises based on noise-to signal
ratios are real exchange rate, export, stock prices and M2/ international reserves.
Ucer, Van Rijckeghem and Yolalan (1998) applied KLR’s signal approach in to the April
1994 Turkish currency crisis. In their empirical work, first, they duplicated KLR’s work
for Turkey during the fourth quarter of 1989 to fourth quarter of 1997, with exception of
the real interest rate differential, lending rate/deposit rate and bank deposits. Second, they
examined seven additional variables (export/import, short-term advances to the
treasury/GDP, short-term external debt/GNP, (reserves/M2Y), domestic government debt
stock, domestic government debt maturity, government deficit/GDP and short-term
advances to the treasury/GDP). In their finding, KLR variables performed very poor to
predict the 1994 Turkish crisis. Out of the 12 KLR variables only excess M1 variables
signaled two times, export, M2/reserves and stock prices variables signaled one time and
seven variables did not signal. Additional variables performed well compared to KLR
variables. Export/import, (reserves/M2Y),domestic government debt stock and short-term
advances to the treasury/GDP variables signaled two times, short-term advances to the
treasury/GDP variable signaled one time and short-term external debt/GNP signaled three
times.
Studies related to 1994 and 2001 Turkish currency crises showed that exchange rate
overvaluation, current account deficit, capital outflow, increase in external debt and money
supply were main indicators of currency crises3.
3
C. Gerni, Ö. S. Emsen, M. K. Değer (2006), M. Alagöz, N. I ık, G. Delice (2006), M. Doğanlar (2006), and
S. Değirmen, A. engönül, I. Tuncer (2006).
250
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Signal Approach
In this study, we uses the “signal” approach model proposed by KLR (1998) to compare
similarities and differences of the 1994 and 2001 currency crises.
Signaling Horizon and Threshold Level
To make the signal approach model operational we need to define a signaling horizon and
a threshold level. The signaling horizon or crises window can be defined as the period
within or time interval over which crises would be anticipated by indicators. We use 12
months crises window for currency crises. The threshold level is chosen to minimize the
“noise-to-signal” (bad signal to good signal) ratio. We will use following matrix to
measure the “noise to signal” ratios for each indicators.
Indicator issues a signal
Indicator does not issue a signal
Currency Crisis
No Currency Crisis
A
C
B
D
* 12 months window was selected.
Where A(t) is the number of instances in which a indicator issues a signal and a currency
crisis occurred in the next 12 months (i.e. A(t) is the number of the time the indicator
provides “good signal” about the occurrences of currency crisis). B(t) is the number of
instances in which a indicator issues a signal and a currency crisis did not occurred in the
next 12 months (i.e. B(t) is the number of the time the indicator provides “bad signal” or
“noise” about the occurrence of currency crises in the next 12 months ). C(t) is the number
of instances in which a indicator did not issues a signal in the next 12 months when there
was a currency crisis in the next 12 months (i.e. C(t) is the number of the time the indicator
did not provide a good signal about the occurrence of currency crises in the next 12 months
). D (t) is the number of instances in which a indicator did not issues a signal in the next
12 months when there was no currency crisis in the next 12 months (i.e. D(t) is the
number of the time in which neither indicator issue a signal and crises occurred in the next
12 months). It is obvious from above matrix that the perfect predictor will produce only
observations A and D.
Data Sample
The data consist of monthly data and range from January 1987 to November 2005. Most
of the data are from the International Financial Statistics CD-ROM database. International
Financial Corporation’s Emerging Market Dataset and Morgan Stanley Countries Index
provide stock market indexes. Table 1 shows selected variables and references for
expected signs.
251
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 1: Selected variables and expected signs
Expected Sign References
_
Kaminksy, Lizondo and Reinhart
(1998), Kaminksy and Reinhart (1999)
Return of regional stock market Bilson, Brailsford and Hooper (2001)
index (RSMI)
Inflation rate
+
Fama (1981), Geske and Roll (1983),
Stulz (1986)
GDP
Kaminksy, Lizondo and Reinhart
(1998), Kaminksy and Reinhart (1999)
Reserves
Kaminksy, Lizondo and Reinhart
(1998), Kaminksy and Reinhart (1999)
Portfolio capital inflow/Reserves Bond (1999)
Export
Kaminksy, Lizondo and Reinhart
(1998), Kaminksy and Reinhart (1999)
Import
+
Kaminksy, Lizondo and Reinhart
(1998), Kaminksy and Reinhart (1999)
Real exchange rate
+
Frankel and Rose (1996)
Explanatory Variables
Stock market index
Short term external debt / reserves +
Sachs and Radelet (1998)
Short term domestic debt / +
reserves
Ratio of money supply to reserves +
Ucer and Yeldan (1998)
Ratio of current account to real GDP
Regional market pressure index +
variable (RMPI)
Calvo and Mendoza (1996), Frankel and
Rose (1996)
Kaminksy and Reinhart (1999)
Eichengreen, Rose and Wyplosz (1996),
Fratzscher (2002)
Regional Stock Market Index provided by International Financial Corporation’s Emerging
Market Dataset and Morgan Stanley Countries Index. Regional Market Pressure Index
constructed individual countries market pressure index. The regional market pressure
index for Turkey is the average of Greece, Russia, Germany, England, France, Italy and
Spai’s market pressure index.
Results from Signal Approach
Results based on signal approach represented table 2 and 3. By using those two tables we
can see the similarities and the differences of the 1994 and 2001 currency crises.
Table 2 reports performances of selected crises indicators for 1994 and 2001 crises. The
first two columns show the number of times a signal was issued in the 12 months window
preceding the indicated crises. The last two columns give aggregate information about the
threshold level and noise-to-signal ratio. Based on the noise-to-signal ratio except inflation
all variables appear useful because their noise-to-signal ratio is less than one. Lower noiseto-signal ratio is preferred. From table 2, we can reach following conclusions. All of the
252
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
crises indicators (except inflation for 2001) issued at least one signal prior to 1994 and
2001 crises. Prior to 1994 (2001) crises selected variables issued 27 (30) signals. Out of
14 variables import variable signaled seven times, reserves variable signaled three times
and reel exchange rate, export, CA/GDP, inflation and GDP variables signaled two times
prior to 1994 currency crises. Out of 14 variables import and CA/GDP variables signaled
six times, RSMI variable signaled three times and portfolioInv./reserves, domestic debt,
external debt, RMPI and GDP variables signaled two times prior to 2001 currency crises.
Regional market pressure index, regional stock market index, CA / GDP,
PortfolioInv/Reserves and external debt variables issued six signals prior to 1994 currency
crisis and fifteen signals prior to 2001 currency crisis. Therefore, we can say that external
factors play more imported role in 2001 crisis than 1994 crisis.
Table 3 evaluates overall performance of crises indicators 12 months prior to crises. The
first two columns show the number of indicators and number of signal issued in monthly
base prior currency crises. The last column shows Weighted Composite Index (I)4.
Weighted Composite Index is total number of signal divided by noise-to signal ratio and
gives aggregate information about the likelihood of upcoming crises.
Table 2: Overall Performance of Selected Variables
Reserves
Real Exchange Rate
Stock Market Index
Export
Import
Portfolio
Inv./Reserves
Domestic Debt
External Debt
M2/Reserves
CA / GDP
RMPI
Inflation
RSMI
GDP
4
Number of Signals in Preceding
12 Months
Aggregate Information
February 1994
3
2
1
2
7
1
February 2001
1
1
1
1
6
2
Threshold
-10
+10
-18
-10
+40
-10
Noise-to-Signal
0.18
0.48
0.57
0.86
0.76
0.81
1
1
1
2
1
2
1
2
2
2
1
6
2
0
3
2
+12
+15
+9
-6
-0.45
+5
-7
-6
0.48
0.54
0.63
0.49
0.94
1.9
0.87
0.71
n
It = Σ Sjt / Wj
where Sjt is 1 if variables j issued a signal in period t, 0 otherwise and Wj is the
j=1
adjusted noise-to signal ratio of each variable j.
253
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 3: Selected Variables Performance Monthly Base
Summary of Prediction : 1994 Crisis
Dates
Feb1993
Mar1993
Apr1993
May1993
Jun1993
Jul-1993
Aug1993
Sep1993
Oct1993
Nov1993
Dec1993
Jan1994
Feb1994
Number
of
Indicator
14
14
14
14
14
14
14
Number
of
Signals
1
2
3
1
4
1
3
14
14
14
14
14
14
2
2
2
3
2
Summary of Prediction : 2001 Crisis
Weighted Dates
Composite
Index
Feb-2000
5.55
Mar-2000
3.67
Apr-2000
5.44
May1.31
2000
Jun-2000
8.13
1.31
Jul-2000
Aug4.56
2000
Sep-2000
0.01
Oct-2000
2.55
Nov2.46
2000
Dec-2000
1.84
Jan-2001
7.49
Feb-2001
3.60
Number
of
Indicator
14
Number
of
Signals
1
Weighted
Composite
Index
2.04
14
1
2.04
14
2
4.05
14
2
3.35
14
14
14
2
1
2
3.50
1.31
2.47
14
0.01
14
4
5.95
14
5
11.35
14
3
4.98
14
4
7.34
14
3
7.85
Weighted Composite Index increases prior to both crises. Specially, started from October
Weighted Composite Index higher prior to 2001 crisis than prior to 1994 crisis. Therefore,
we can say that 2001 crisis is more predictable than 1994 crisis.
Table 4 shows the cost of 1994 and 2001 crises. We used three crises indicator to evaluate
the cost of currency crises. For each indicator, we identified maximum level prior the
crisis, minimum level, and recovery period. In 1994 currency crisis, reserves reached
maximum level (17.8 Billion $) at October 1993 then reached minimum level (12.4
Billion) at May 1993 (9 months period). Finally, reserves recovery at January 1995.
Recovery of reserves took 27 months. In 2001 currency crisis, reserves reached maximum
level (36 Billion $) at July 2000 then reached minimum level (28 Billion) at November
2001 (11 months period). Finally, reserves recovery at October 2002. Recovery of
reserves took 28 months. Recovery of SMI in 1994 (2001) crisis took 7 months (44
months). Recovery of industrial production in 1994 (2001) crisis took 19 months (34
months).
254
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
We can concluded from table 4 that 2001 crisis is deeper and costlier than 1994 crisis.
Table 4: Cost of Currency Crises
Cost of 1994 Crisis
Indicators
Maximum
Reserves
Oct. 93=17.8
B.
SMI
Jan. 94=241
Industrial. Dec. 93=86
Production
Cost of 2001 Crisis
Indicators
Maximum
Reserves
July 2000=36
B.
SMI
Apr.
2000=17200
Industrial. July 2000=108
Production
Minimum
May 94= 12.4
B.
March
94=145
June 94= 68
Recovery
Jan. 95=18.2 9 months
B.
Aug 94=245
5 months
7 months
July 95=88
13 months
19 months
Minimum
Nov 01= 28.
Recovery
Oct. 02=36 B.
11 months
28 months
March
01=8432
Jan. 01= 91
Dec.03=17326
33 months
44 months
April 03=110
27 months
34 months
27 months
Conclusion
In this study, we used signal approach to identify which variables tent to indicate that a
country might be vulnerable to a financial crisis. Even if it is generally accepted that
currency crises are unpredictable the results from table 2 show that all of the crises
indicators (except inflation for 2001) issued at least one signal prior to 1994 and 2001
crises. Also, table 3 shows that in both crises Weighted Composite Index increases
sharply. Specially, started from October Weighted Composite Index higher prior to 2001
crisis than prior to 1994 crisis. Therefore, we can conclude that both crises are predictable
but 2001 crisis is more predictable than 1994 crisis.
External variables issued six signals prior to 1994 currency crisis and fifteen signals prior
to 2001 currency crisis. Therefore, we can conclude that external factors play more
imported role in 2001 crisis than 1994 crisis. Finally, the result from table 4 shows that
2001 crisis is deeper and costlier than 1994 crisis.
255
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
References
Alagöz, M., I ık, N. ve Delice, G. (2006). “Finansal Krizler Đçin Erken Uyarı Sinyali
Olarak Cari Hesap Göstergeleri”. In Seyitoğlu, H. and Yıldız, R. (Ed). Ekonomik Kriz
Öncesi Erken Uyarı Sistemleri.
Bilson, C. M., Brailsford, T. J., and Hooper, V. J. (2001), “Selecting Macroeconomic
Variables as Explanatory Factors of Emerging Stock Market Returns.” Pasific-Basin
Finance Journal, Vol.9, pp.401-426.
Bond, T. J. (1999). “Capital Inflows to Asia: The Role of Monetary Policy.” Transition
Economies in Comparative Countries, pp.61-70.
Calvo, Guillermo A. and Mendoza, Enrique G. (1996). “Mexico’s Balance of Payments
Crisis: A Chronicle of A Death Foretold.” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 41,
(November), pp. 235-264.
Değirmen, S., engönül, A., ve Tuncer, I. (2006). “Kriz Erken Uyarı Sinyalleri Olarak
Reel Ekonomik Göstergeler”. In Seyitoğlu, H. and Yıldız, R. (Ed). Ekonomik Kriz Öncesi
Erken Uyarı Sistemleri.
Doğanlar, M. (2006). “ Türkiye Ekonomisi’nde 1994 Krizi Đçin Öncü Göstergeler
Denemesi”. In Seyitoğlu, H. and Yıldız, R. (Ed). Ekonomik Kriz Öncesi Erken Uyarı
Sistemleri.
Eichengren, B., Rose, A. K. and Wyplosz, C. (1996). “Contagious Currency Crises.”
NBER Working Paper, No.5681.
Fama, Eugene F. (1981). “ Stock Returns, Real Activity, Inflation, and Money.” The
American Economic Review, Vol.71 (September), pp. 454-565.
Flood, Robert P. and Garber, Peter M. (1984). “Collapsing Exchange Rate Regime: Same
Linear Example.” Journal of International Economics, Vol.17, pp. 1-13.
Frankel, Jeffrey A. and Rose, Andrew K. (1996). “Currency Crashes in Emerging Markets:
An Empirical Treatment.” Journal of International Economics, Vol.41, pp.351-366.
Fratzscher, M. (2002). “On Currency Crises and Contagion.” European Central Bank
Working Paper, No.139.
Gerni, C., Emsen, Ö., S. ve Değer, M., K. (2006), “Ekonomik Krizlerde Erken Uyarı
Sinyalleri Olarak Dı Ticaret Göstergeleri: Türkiye Uygulaması. In Seyitoğlu, H. and
Yıldız, R. (Ed). Ekonomik Kriz Öncesi Erken Uyarı Sistemleri.
Geske, Robert, and Roll, Richard (1983). “The Fiscal and Monetary Linkage between
Stock Returns and Inflation.” The Journal of Finance, Vol.38 (March), pp. 1-33.
Kaminsky, Graciela L., and Reinhart, Carmen M. (1999). “The Twin Crises: The Cause of
Banking and Balance-of-Payment Problems.” American Economic Review, June, pp. 473500.
256
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Kaminsky, Graciela L., Lizondo, Saul and Reinhart, Carmen M. (1998) “Leading Indicator
Of Currency Crises.” Policy Research Working Paper, No. 1852, December.
Krugman, Paul R. (1979). “A Model of Balance-of –Payments Crises.” Journal of Money,
Credit, and Banking, Vol. 11, No. 25, pp. 311-325.
Obstfeld, Maurice (1986). “ Rational And Self-Fulfilling Balance of Payment Crises.”
American Economic Review, Vol. 76, No.1, March, pp. 72-81.
Obstfeld, Maurice (1994). “ The Logic of Currency Crises.” NBER Working Paper, No.
4640, February.
Obstfeld, Maurice (1996). “Models of Currency Crises With Self-Fulfilling Features”
European Economic Review, Vol. 40, pp. 1037-1047.
Sachs, Jeffrey and Radelet, Steven (1998).” The Onset of the East Asian Financial Crisis”,
NBER Working Paper, No. 6680.
Ucer, M., Van Rijckeghem. R. ve Yolalan R. (1998). “Leading Indicator of Currency
Crises: A Brief Literature Survey and an Application to Turkey” Yapı Kredi Economic
Review, Vol 9, December.
Stulz, R., M. (1986). “Asset Pricing and Expected Inflation.” The Journal of Finance,
Vol.41, March, pp. 209-223.
Thorbecke, Willem (1994). “ Trade Deficit News, Systematic Risk and the Crash of 1987.”
Eastern Economic Journal, Vol.20 (Winter), pp. 97-114.
257
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Appendices: Percentage change of selected variables 24 months prior crises.
% Re se r v e s
80.00
60.00
40.00
20.00
1994
12
24
t+
-40.00
t+
6
t+
t0
t6
t24
-20.00
t12
0.00
2001
Real Exchange Rate
60,00
40,00
20,00
t+
12
t+
24
t+
12
t+
24
t+
6
t-0
t-6
-20,00
t-1
2
t-2
4
0,00
-40,00
-60,00
1994
2001
Stock Prices
500
400
300
200
100
1994
t+
6
t-0
2
t-6
t-2
-100
t-1
4
0
2001
258
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Export
60
50
40
30
20
10
1994
t+
24
t+
12
t-0
t-1
t-6
2
4
t-2
-20
t+
6
0
-10
2001
Import
100
80
1994
t+24
t+12
t+6
t-0
t-6
t-12
-20
-40
-60
t-24
60
40
20
0
2001
CA/GDP
10
5
2001
t+
24
t+
6
1994
t+
12
t-0
t-6
-5
t -1
2
t -2
4
0
-10
-15
259
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
M2/Res
30
-20
-30
t+24
t+12
t+6
t-0
t-6
t-24
0
-10
t-12
20
10
-40
1994
2001
Inflation
200
150
100
50
1994
t+
24
t+
12
t+
6
t -0
t -6
2
t-1
t-2
4
0
2001
GDP
30
20
10
24
t+
12
t+
t+
6
t- 0
t- 6
-10
t-1
2
t-2
4
0
-20
1994
2001
260
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
External Debt
40
20
24
t+
t+
12
6
t+
t- 0
t- 6
t-2
4
-20
t-1
2
0
-40
-60
1994
2001
Internal Debt
1994
t+
24
t+
12
t+
6
t-0
t-6
2
t -1
t -2
4
300
250
200
150
100
50
0
2001
Portinvt/Res
10
5
t+24
t+12
t+6
t-0
t-6
t-12
-5
t-24
0
-10
-15
-20
1994
2001
261
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
24
t+
t+
24
6
12
t+
t+
12
1994
t+
t- 0
t- 6
t- 2
4
100
80
60
40
20
0
-20
-40
-60
t- 1
2
RSMI
2001
Regional MPI
2
1.5
1
0.5
-1
t+
6
t-0
t-6
t-1
t-2
4
-0.5
2
0
-1.5
1994
2001
262
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Economic Development and Religiosity: An Investigation of Turkish
Cities
Sacit Hadi Akdede
Adnan Menderes University, Turkey
Hakan Hotunluoğlu
Adnan Menderes University, Turkey
Abstract
The relationship between the degree of religiosity and economic development is
empirically investigated for a cross-section of all Turkish cities with municipal authorities.
It is found that economic development and the degree of religiosity have a non-linear
relationship.
Religiosity increases with industrialization first, however, as the
industrialization increases more, the degree of religiosity decreases. Coastal towns are less
religious. Mosques and schools are complements rather than substitutes as they affect each
other positively. This can be interpreted as the ideological competition between religious
communities and secularists.
263
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Introduction
This paper investigates population and development elasticity of religiosity of a crosssection of all Turkish cities with municipal authorities. Villages are excluded from the
sample since data are not available for them. Investigating the determinants of religiosity
at the aggregate city level is not a worthless endeavor since scholars from different
disciplines try to understand the sources of degree of religiosity, especially after the
September 11 attacks. Religiosity of a particular city in this paper is measured by the
number of mosques in total number of all buildings in that city. Only mosques are
included in the analysis here since there is very small number of religious buildings related
to other religions in only small number of cities in Turkey. Therefore, this is an aggregate
economic analysis of mosques in the city level. It can be argued that the number of
mosques themselves might not necessarily be a good measure of how religious a
community is if mosques are almost always empty. Even if it is so, since mosques are
built by donations of either individuals or non-governmental organizations and land is a
relatively expensive factor in Turkey, mosque financiers still have a perception that
society/community values the mosques more or they have the intention of making people
more religious (religious propaganda or ideological competition with secularists in Turkey)
if mosques are chosen among alternatives like schools, sport centers, cultural centers, etc.
Therefore, it would not be wrong to have the number of mosques as a measure of
religiosity. In fact, popular discussions among different political circles in Turkey often
cite the number of mosques as a measure of religiosity.
This paper investigates the two elasticities mentioned in the first sentence of introduction
section since there is a popular understanding in Turkey, and in many other circles in
different countries in this matter, that economic development reduces the need for religious
services or religiosity. The assumed link from economic development to reduced religious
services, as theory suggests, is the modernization. Modern societies/communities, as
opposed to traditional societies/communities, are assumed to be less religious or have more
secularization (Giddens,1993; Martin,1978) even though the USA does not confirm this
explanation, Verweij et al. (1997).
Modernization theory states that increasing
modernization leads to the process by which religion loses its social significance in human
behavior (Wilson, 1982). The modernization process is characterized as development
which marks the transition from agrarian or traditional economy into large scale industrial
or commercial economy, Verweij et al. (1997). It is claimed that industrialization and
commercialization make people more worldly (secular). Some scientist, however,
discussed that modernization theory should be abandoned completely since it is simple
wrong. They claim that modernization of USA does not reduce the degree of religiosity of
people in that country as the church attendance rate is all time high in the 1990s as the
issue is discussed in great detail in Stark and Iannaccone (1994).
This paper therefore explicitly tests this popular perception that modernization reduces the
degree of religiosity of a society as the issue is not exhaustively empirically investigated,
under the condition that economic development is assumed to transform the societies from
traditional ones into modern ones. This paper is organized as follows. The next section
reviews the related literature. Section III defines the data and gives some descriptive
statistic and section IV gives the estimation results. Section V concludes the paper.
264
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Literature Review
Studies of religion and economics are analyzed and summarized in Iannaccone (1998). It
is mainly mentioned three lines of inquiry: microeconomic determinants of religious
behavior, economic consequences of religion, and religious economics, which is primarily
about economic policies from a religious perspective like Islamic banking and taxation as
specific examples of the research. Recently, the literature about economics of religion
focuses more on the first two lines. Papers about the microeconomic determinants of
religious behavior use the degree of religiosity as the dependent variables and different
economic variables as the independent variables (Verweij et al., 1997; Smith et al. 1998;
Smith and Sawkins, 2003; McCleary and Barro, 2006; Arano and Blair, 2007; Lopez and
Santos, 2008). Papers about economic consequences of religion investigate different
religions and their effects on economic growth and development. This branch of the
literature uses the Weber (Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism) work as an
inspiring paper (Grier, 1997; Blum and Dudley, 2001, 208; Guiso et al. 2002; Barro and
McCleary, 2003; Montalvo and Reynol-Querol, 2003, 202; Noland, 2005; Cavalcanti et al.
2007,106). In addition to these ‘direction of causation’ studies, recently some papers are
investigating the political results of religious behaviors as MacCulloch and Pezzini (2007)
states that revolutionary rise in a country can be offset by belonging to a religion which
lowers the probability of revolution by between 1.8 and 2.7 percentage points. Another
paper by Lehrer (2004) investigates the role of religion in union formation.
The already existing studies have the following features.
-They are mostly using different kinds of survey data sets for religiosity and other social
attitudes like World Values Survey (WVS), General Social Surveys (GSS), International
Social Survey Programme (ISSP), and other surveys.
-Most of them are cross-country studies.
-Most of the studies are about developed countries since data are usually unavailable for
developing countries.
This paper, however, is contributing to existing literature from several dimensions: First of
all, this study uses a novel data set of all existing buildings in use for all the cities (both
small and large) with municipal authorities. The data set is prepared by the Turkish
Statistical Institution (TSI). Secondly, this paper is about a cross-section of cities in a
relatively homogeneous country, Turkey. Turkey is 99.8 % Muslim (Sunni), 0.2 %
Christians, Jews, and other religions1.
Cross-country studies about the relationships
between economic growth/development and religiosity might have some problems in
especially determining the effects of religion on growth since growth of different countries
might be affected by other several cultural variables than religion. In addition to that, data
about religiosity of different countries are including a vast array of subjectivity of surveys.
Thirdly, this study is about a developing country. In addition, this study is the first study of
its kind in Turkey. In fact, this data set, to the best of our knowledge, has not been used in
another paper.
1
CIA Factbooks.
265
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Investigating the relationship between religious and other economic and social variables by
the tools of economics is a relatively new topic in economics. The relationship between
cultural and religious factors and economic well being or economic development is
recently being paid more attention, especially after the September 11 2001 attack to Twin
Towers in New York City as mentioned before in the introduction section. The main
motivation of this paper is to contribute to this literature. This paper investigates the
population and development elasticity of religiosity. Therefore, the size of religious
services (the degree of religiosity) is assumed to be in a relation with the size of population
and the level of economic development.
Population can serve two purposes to test: first, in the cities with higher population, the
cost per capita of the services would be smaller if there is increasing returns to scale with
respect to religious services, which mostly show public good features. As is known, public
goods highly likely show the feature of increasing returns to scale as Alesina and Wacziarg
(1998) showed it in a different context of public expenditures. As an example, a mosque
except for Fridays, where some congestion effect reveals, is a public good since it is
nonexcludable and nonrival. If this is the case, the more populated the city, the smaller the
cost of religious services per capita, mainly cost of building the mosque since imams are
getting paid by government but mosques are being built by nongovernmental organizations
or individuals in Turkey. Second, cities with higher population are relatively culturally
more heteregenous cities than the cities with smaller population. In more heteregenous
cities, there would be two types of social behavior in terms of financing religious services
or participation to religious services.
The first, different groups of people try to free ride, in which case, supply of services of
public good per capita would be smaller if the income or wealth is distributed relatively
evenly. If the income distribution is relatively bad, then this outcome would not
necessarily have to be observed since some religious wealthy people alone can take the
financial burden of the religious services, mainly building the mosques. As a related
observation, it should be mentioned here that small towns have relatively better income
distribution than big cities have in Turkey even though big cities have a higher income per
capita. As a second observation, most mosques are built on land which is donated by
wealthy people in Turkey. Donations by the attendees of the mosques are mostly used for
maintenance of the mosques.
The second, cultural heterogeneity would make the citizens of the city more or less open
minded or less or more conservative respectively. If cultural heterogeneity makes the
citizens more open minded or less conservative, religious public services per capita would
be smaller in more populated cities. If, on the contrary, cultural heterogeneity makes the
citizens of the city less open minded or more conservative, religious public services per
capita would be higher in more populated cities.
What would be the final effect of population on religious services depends on the
dominating factors. Which effects would be eventually prevailing is an empirical question
since theoretically all possible three types of behavior are likely to be observable.
The level of development can also affect the religiosity of societies or individuals. As the
literature is reviewed briefly above, the relationship between economic and socio political
developments and degree of religiosity is investigated in the literature in some detail
(Mangeloja 2005, 2350; McCleary and Barro, 2006, 150; Arano and Blair, 2007; ). The
266
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
direction of causality is usually one of the main concerns in most of the research in this
field. One way of directions is from the development to religiosity and the other way is the
reverse. Development, it is claimed in the literature reviewed above, increases
industrialization and therefore secularization or decreased level of religiosity. However,
this may not be the only outcome of development. Development can cause a religious
market competition since different sects or denominations might have the resources to
compete. This market structure and government regulation of it can affect the degree of
religiosity. In short, development can also increase the degree of religiosity. This issue is
entirely an empirical one. The degree of religiosity can affect the development and growth
as well, the reverse causation. More religious communities, as is discussed in the literature,
can develop a social trust among themselves to do better business. In other words, higher
level of religiosity can increase the social capital and therefore economic growth and
development. This issue is also entirely empirical one since different countries or societies
can respond this relationship differently. Therefore, there is a huge need for more empirical
studies for different societies or countries.
Data and Descriptive Statistics
The domain of the empirical study is the cross section of the Turkish cities. Provinces (il),
towns (ilce), and small towns (belde) are used in the study. There are 81 provinces, 850
towns, and 2267 small towns in Turkey. Villages are excluded from the study due to non
availability of the data.
In terms of the variables in the empirical models here, first type of public good is the
number of mosques in total building. That is, mosques and mescits, smaller and easy-built
(sometimes an apartment can be used as a mescit) versions of mosques. There is some
small number of churches in some of the major cities. However, their statistical effects are
ignorable since almost all of the religious buildings are mosques or mescits. The second
type of public goods is the number of buildings for educational and cultural use in total
number of all buildings. These different buildings and their use are defined below.
Aggregate wealth per capita of the city is proxied by total number of all buildings per
person. The building classification in Table 1 below is using international classification of
buildings.
267
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 1: Descriptive Statistics
Provinces
Towns
Small
Towns
mean
std
max
min
mean
std
max
min
mean
Pop.
255954.26
453238.40
3168054.00
17274.00
28336.76
67691.67
663299.00
683.00
4191.17
Res.
25308.98
41058.45
246231.00
1487.00
2902.85
4627.83
43799.00
72.00
639.53
Com.
2133.18
3051.18
15924.00
94.00
273.64
523.71
9583.00
1.00
33.66
Ind.
868.16
1809.52
9484.00
2.00
61.88
141.43
1547.00
1.00
13.05
Educul.
112.03
177.56
1325.00
16.00
15.93
20.81
270.00
1.00
3.78
Health
70.58
122.20
914.00
6.00
9.03
14.88
183.00
1.00
2.78
Gov.
140.66
277.45
2221.00
10.00
17.14
25.62
496.00
1.00
3.87
Rel.
83.64
96.50
562.00
3.00
13.86
17.72
209.00
1.00
4.10
Agri.
92.01
147.93
930.00
1.00
73.66
156.51
1960.00
1.00
64.22
total
32223.94
52144.71
301642.00
2665.00
3930.31
6143.76
56484.00
115.00
888.35
std
max
min
5526.08
148981.00
858.00
808.50
15509.00
1.00
74.97
1380.00
1.00
54.68
1475.00
1.00
2.83
38.00
1.00
6.49
217.00
1.00
12.90
536.00
1.00
3.24
33.00
1.00
103.14
1298.00
1.00
918.02
18954.00
156.00
Pop.: Population, Res.: Residential Buildings, Com.: Building for commercial use, Ind.: Building for
industrial use, Educul.: Building for educational and cultural use like schools, private tutoring institutions, all
the schools related buildings like sports centers, school cafeteria, dormitories, etc. Health: building for health,
social and sportive use, Gov.: Government buildings, Rel.: Buildings for religious use (mosques, smaller
mescits), Agri.: Building for agricultural use, total: total buildings in a particular city.
The Model and Results of Regressions
The first model to estimate
Yi = Z i γ + ε i
(1)
Where the dependent variable is the number of mosques in total number of all buildings in
a given city, independent variables are population, industrialization, level of wealth, and
educational and cultural use buildings in the total number of all buildings along with
several dummy variables. Level of wealth is measured by total number of buildings per
capita. Eq. 1 is estimated by OLS and 2SLS to account for endogeneity with all variables
in the system as instrumental variables. The results of these regressions are reported in
Table 2.
268
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 2: Religiosity and Development
Dependent Variable: Number of
religious buildings in total number
of buildings
Regression 1: OLS
Coefficient
t-stat
-2.88***
-19.48
-0.16***
-11.73
0.02***
2.70
-0.004**
-2.10
-0.23***
-6.48
0.23***
10.12
Dependent Variable: Number of
religious buildings in total number
of buildings
Regression 2: 2SLS
Coefficient
t-stat
-2.99***
-19.83
-0.18***
-12.19
0.02**
2.37
-0.004*
-1.89
-0.35***
-7.28
0.20***
8.85
constant
Population
Industrialization
Industrialization2
Wealth
Building for educational and
cultural use in total buildings
Coastal towns
-0.24***
-5.98
-0.22***
-5.52
Aegean
-0.39***
-9.28
-0.37***
-8.65
Mediterranean
-0.26***
-5.81
-0.26***
-5.82
Marmara
-0.63***
-14.03
-0.62***
-13.59
East Anatolia
-0.38***
-7.40
-0.40***
-7.64
Central Anatolia
-0.27***
-7.19
-0.27***
-7.20
South East Anatolia
-0.38***
-6.47
-0.40***
-6.88
Adj-R2
0.31
0.31
Observations
2297
2297
*** p<0.01, ** p <0.05, *p<0.10,
Industrialization=((Buildings for industrial use+ buildings for commercial use)/ buildings for agricultural
use)
Wealth: Total buildings/population. Regional dummies: Aegean, Mediterranean, Marmara, East Anatolia,
Central Anatolia, South East Anatolia, Black Sea.
All the variables except for dummy variables are in their natural logarithms. According to
Table 2 there is a non linear relationship between industrialization and the degree of
religiosity in Turkish cities. At the beginning level of industrialization, the degree of
religiosity is increasing; however, as the industrialization increases eventually the degree
of religiosity is decreasing. There is also a negative relationship between wealth and the
degree of religiosity: as wealth increases, the degree of religiosity decreases.
These results here are confirming the secularization hypothesis of modernization theory.
As industrialization and wealth increase, the religiosity decreases. We can not test for
religious competition in this paper as it is tested for many other countries (Smith and
Sawkins, 2003; Lopez and Santos, 2008) since majority of the population is Muslim and
Sunni. Therefore, there is no competition between different religions and/or different
denominations or sects. There is however a highly likely ideological competition between
religious communities and secularists. The results of the regressions of eq.1 indicate that
educational and cultural buildings in total buildings are positively significantly affecting
the religiosity. That is, if a city relatively to other cities has a higher ratio of cultural and
educational buildings in total buildings, that city has also higher ratio of mosques to total
buildings. This can be interpreted as the existence of ideological competition between
secularists and religious communities in a city if mosques and educational and cultural
buildings are not being funded by the same people. As is known very well that mosques
are being built by individuals or non-governmental institutions, schools (educational
buildings) or cultural buildings are being built by government. The regression is controlled
for population and wealth. Coefficient of population is negative and significant, showing
that crowded cities are less religious. Different links of population variable as defined
above can not be disaggregated into different variables since data are not available. It is
269
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
very interesting to observe that coastal towns which are tourism towns are less religious or
the degree of religiosity for those towns is smaller compared to other towns. Tourism
promotes non-religious business opportunities and makes people more open minded and
secular.
In order to address the endogeneity problem, eq.1 is run by 2SLS. The results of 2SLS are
also reported in Table 2. The results of regression 2 are very similar to those of regression
1.
In order to be able to investigate the ideological competition between schools and
mosques, eq. 2 below is run by a system of equations. The system estimation is done by
3SLS and the results are reported in Table 3.
Y1i = Z i γ + α 1Y2i + vi
(2)
Y i 2 = X i β + α 2Y1i + ε i
Where y1i
is the natural logarithm of percentage of mosques in total number of all
buildings and y 2i is the natural logarithm of percentage of educational and cultural
buildings in total number of all buildings Zi and Xi re vectors of independent variables,
and are vectors of unknown parameters and and. vi are error terms.
Table 3: System Estimation
Dependent Variable: Number of Dependent Variable: Number of
religious buildings in total number cultural and educational buildings in
of buildings
total number of buildings
Estimation method: 3SLS
First equation in the system
Second equation in the system
Coefficient
t-stat
Coefficient
t-stat
-2.91***
-19.62
-3.64***
-28.21
-0.18***
-11.15
-0.13***
-9.84
0.02***
2.66
0.006
0.94
-0.004**
-2.21
-0.32***
-6.80
-0.42***
-13.56
0.22***
10.22
Constant
Population
Industrialization
Industrialization2
Wealth
Expenditures on education
and culture (% in total)
Coastal towns
-0.22***
-5.76
Number
of
religious
buildings in total number of
buildings
Aegean
-0.37***
-8.57
Mediterranean
-0.26***
-5.75
Marmara
-0.61***
-13.86
East Anatolia
-0.40***
-8.15
Central Anatolia
-0.26***
-6.99
South East Anatolia
-0.39***
-5.75
Adj-R2
0.31
Observations
2297
System Observations
4594 (Balanced System)
***p<0.01, **p<0.05, *p<0.10
-0.14***
0.22***
-3.71
10.95
-0.16***
-0.12***
-0.17***
0.14***
-0.13***
-0.07
0.27
2297
-3.89
-2.75
-3.94
2.98
-3.57
-1.08
270
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table 3 shows that the non-linear relationship between the degree of religiosity and
industrialization is kept in system estimation as well. All the variables are significant
except for the industrialization variable in the second equation in the system. Since
schools are built by the government and it is exogenous to industrialization, it is not
surprising that industrialization is not statistically significant. Schools are built if there is
enough population. Industrialization is not required to build schools since children of the
non-industrial cities also need to go to school and the government should provide
schooling for them. Table 3 indicates that schools and mosques are complement rather
than being substitutes since they affect each other positively and significantly. If schools
and mosques are not funded by the same resources, this complementarity can be
interpreted as ideological competition. This is an interesting result since popular press
discusses the ideological competition between secularist government structure and
religious communities in Turkey. This point, however, needs to be investigated with
different type of disaggregated data, which is a subject of another paper.
Conclusion
This paper investigates empirically the relationship between the degree of religiosity and
economic development for a cross section of Turkish cities. Degree of religiosity is
measured by the total number of mosques in total number of all buildings, whereas
industrialization is measured by the ratio of industrial and commercial buildings to
agricultural buildings. It is observed that there is a nonlinear relationship between the
degree of religiosity and industrialization. As industrialization is increased a little, the
degree of religiosity is also increased. Therefore, villagers are less religious than people
who live medium size commercial cities, ceteris paribus. As industrialization increases
more, the degree of religiosity is decreasing, conforming the hypothesis of modernization
and secularization.
Coastal towns are found to be less religious. This is not surprising the coastal towns in
Turkey are known culturally very liberal. Coastal towns are tourism towns and cultural
very diverse. Cultural diversity might reduce the neighborhood pressure to practice
religion.
Another interesting finding is that mosques and schools are complement and there might
be a ideological competition between secularists and religious communities.
As a further research, a different type of data set is needed to investigate whether there is
really ideological competition between secularists and religious communities.
271
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
References
Alesina, A. and Wacziarg, R. (1998) Openness, country size, and government, Journal of
Public Economics, 69, 305–21.
Arano, K. G. and Blair, B. F. (2007) Modeling religious behavior and economic outcome:
Is the relationship bicausal? Evidence from a survey of Mississippi households, The
Journal of Socio-Economics, (Forthcoming).
Barro, R. J. and McCleary R.M. (2003) Religion and Economic Growth, American
Sociological Review, 68, 760-781.
Blum, U. and Dudley, L. (2001) Religion and Economic Growth: was Weber Right?,
Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 11, 207-230.
Cavalcanti,T.V., Parente, S.L. and Zhao,R. (2007) Religion in macroeconomics: A
quantitative analysis of Weber’s thesis, Economic Theory, 32(1), 105-123.
Giddens, A. (1993) Sociology, Oxford: Polity Press.
Grier, R. (1997) The Effect of Religion on Economic Development: A Cross National
Study of 63 Former Colonies, Kyklos, Vol. 50, Fasc.1, 47-62.
Guiso, L., Sapienza, P. and Zingales, L.(2002) People’s Opium? Religion and Economic
Attitudes, Working Paper 9237, http://www.nber.org/papers/w9237.
Iannaccone, L.R. (1998) Introduction to the Economic of Religion, Journal of Economic
Literature, Vol. XXXVI, 1465-1496.
Lehrer, E.L. (2004) The role of religion in union formation: An economic Perspective,
Population Research and Policy Review, 23, 161-185.
Lopez J.A.P. and Santos, J.M.S. (2008) Effects of competition on religious markets: some
empirical evidence, Applied Economics Letters, 15, 371-374.
MacCulloch, R. and Pezzini, S. (2007) Money, Religion and Revolution, Economics of
Governance, 8, 1-16.
Mangeloja, E. (2005) Economic Growth and Religious Production Efficiency, Applied
Economics, 37, 2349-2359.
Martin, D. (1978) A General Theory of Secularization, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
McCleary R.M. and Barro R.J. (2006) Religion and Political Economy in an International
Panel, Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion, 45(2), 149-175.
Noland, M. (2005) Religion and Economic Performance, World Development, Vol. 33,
No.8, 1215-1232.
272
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Montalvo, J.G. and Reynal-Querol, M. (2003) Religious Polarization and economic
development, Economics Letters, 80, 201-210.
Smith, I., Sawkins, J.W. and Seaman, P.T. (1998) The Economics of Religious
Participation: A Cross-Country Study, Kyklos, Vol. 51, Fasc.1, 25-43.
Smith, I. and Sawkins, J.W. (2003) The economics of regional variation in religious
attendance, Applied Economics, 15, 1577-1588.
Stark, R. and IannacconeR.L.(1994) A Supply Side Reinterpretation of the Secularization
of Europe, Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion,33(3), 230-252.
Verweij, J., Ester, P. and Nauta, R. (1997) Secularization as an Economic and Cultural
Phenomenon: A Cross-National Analysis, Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion,
36(2),309-324.
Wilson, B. (1982) Religion in Sociological Perspective. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
273
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Multilateralism or Bilateralism: Trade Policy of the EU in the Age of
Free Trade Agreements
Sevil Acar
Istanbul Technical University, Turkey
Mahmut Tekçe
Marmara University, Turkey
Abstract
Until 2006, trade policy of the European Union (EU) had mainly been focused on
multilateralism embraced by the Doha Development Agenda (DDA). Meanwhile, the EU
maintained an effective suspension on the opening of bilateral or regional negotiations
where their increasing number was considered a ‘spaghetti bowl’ that creates problems for
the international trading system. However, the suspension of the DDA negotiations in July
2006 forced the EU to reveal a new trade policy with the motto of “rejection of
protectionism at home, accompanied by activism in creating open markets and fair
conditions for trade abroad” which focuses on the removal of tariff and non-tariff barriers
to trade of goods and services. Consequently, the EU gave pace to signing FTAs with its
significant trade partners. This new trade strategy based on increasing FTAs and thus on
bilateralism, which aims at the highest possible degree of trade, investment, and services
liberalization, targets regulatory convergence and the abolishment of non-tariff barriers
beside stronger provisions on intellectual property rights and competition. This paper
discusses whether the new trade strategy of the EU leads to a distraction of the EU’s trade
policy focus from multilateralism to bilateralism or it still remains committed to the WTO.
274
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Introduction
Following the temporary suspension of the Doha Development Agenda (DDA) of the
World Trade Organization (WTO), in October 2006, the European Commission (EC)
revealed a new trade policy strategy under which the EU will pursue bilateral free trade
agreements (FTAs) with targeted economies in order to secure new markets and protect or
enhance competitiveness for European businesses. This new strategy was a significant shift
from the EC’s de facto moratorium of any bilateral agreements and expressing loyalty to
multilateral trade policy focus of the WTO. This change in the trade policy strategy raised
concerns about the completion of the DDA and the future of the multilateral trading
system, as the biggest proponent of multilateralism shifted its attention to bilateralism.
This paper aims to analyze the evolution, motives and main characteristics of the European
Union (EU)’s external trade policy and the possible consequences of the adoption of the
new trade strategy on the further progress of the WTO-based multilateral trading system.
Section 2 explains the historical stance of the EU on bilateralism and multilateralism, and
its previous trade policy strategy. Section 3 analyzes the post-Doha international trade
environment and the new trade policy of the EU. Section 4 examines the trade relations of
the EU with the countries the European Commission is either negotiating an FTA or set a
target to pursue one. Concluding remarks discuss how this policy shift of the EU might
influence the fate of the multilateral trading system.
Evolution of the EU’s Trade Policies
Regionalism through Regional Trade Agreements (RTAs) or Free Trade Agreements
(FTAs) has been widely discussed among trade economists since the 1950s. In the
pioneering theoretical approach on the subject, Viner (1950) introduced the concepts ‘trade
creation’ and ‘trade diversion’ and stressed the discriminatory aspects of regional trade
liberalization. His claim was that, bilateral or regional economic integration can create
trade by lowering tariffs and thereby reducing prices, but it can also lead to trade diversion
for the countries outside the trade agreement. Thus, regional or bilateral trade agreements
increase the exports of the signatory countries at the expense of third countries.
The formation of the European Economic Community (EEC) in 1957 and European Free
Trade Association (EFTA) in 1960 became the first remarkable examples of regional trade
agreements. On the other side of the Atlantic, the US was keeping a multilateralist
approach to trade liberalization, based on the negotiated rules of the General Agreement on
Tariffs and Trade (GATT). While Europe was integrating in the 1960s and 70s, the US was
rejecting proposals for a North Atlantic Free Trade Area (Panagariya, 1999, p. 481). Thus,
since the 1980s, RTAs were mostly limited to Western Europe and regionalism was mainly
a ‘European’ concept. According to Bhagwati (1993), “the first wave of regionalism that
took place in the 1960s failed to spread because the US supported a multilateral
approach.” Following Bhagwati’s terminology, the ‘second wave of regionalism’ started
after the failure of the GATT multilateral trade negotiations in November 1982, whereas
this time the US changed its position and favored RTAs. This regionalism wave affected
both developed and developing countries and led to the formation of several regional
groupings including the EU, NAFTA and Mercosur. Hence the EU, itself an example of a
regional integration, has been an early promoter of regional trade agreements, and the
1970s and the 1990s witnessed several preferential trade agreements of the EU with
different countries.
275
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
However, in the mid 1990s, the EU turned its attention to multilateralism. The conclusion
of the Uruguay Round of multilateral trade negotiations in 1994, and the establishment of
the WTO in 1995 to provide the institutional support to the multilateral trade agreements,
flourished the expectations that a world trading system based on common rules and
multilateral liberalization can be formed. There was an expectation that “exceptions to
multilateralism, such as regional trade agreements (...) would either become less of an
alternative policy option for countries or will need to be adapted and conducted in such a
manner as to become outward-oriented, not inward-looking, and thus constitute building
blocks for the new multilateralism ushered in by the WTO.” (Mashayekhi et al., 2005, p. 3)
EU’s steer towards multilateralism was reinforced when Romano Prodi, the president of
the EC, appointed Pascal Lamy as the European Commissioner for Trade in 1999. Lamy
was a strict proponent of multilateralism and during his period as the Commissioner, the
EU maintained an effective suspension on the opening of bilateral or regional negotiations
to conclude FTAs, and championed the multilateral trading system. Lamy (2002) explained
this policy as one “pursu[ing] all existing mandates for regional negotiations with vigour
and fairness, but not to begin any new negotiations”. (p. 1412) This trade strategy was
based on two reasons: first, it favored the multilateral approach of the Doha Development
Agenda (DDA) and the EU did not want to take any initiative that might detract from its
completion; and second, the EU had a ‘deep integration’ approach in FTAs and these
agreements were complex and time-consuming to negotiate (Lamy, 2002, pp. 1412-1413).
Increasing the number of bilateral agreements has been labeled as ‘spaghetti bowl’ of
overlapping trade rules that erode the principle of non-discrimination and raise the
transaction costs of doing business, and was assumed to complicate the international
trading system as a whole.
The EU had announced its strict loyalty to the completion of a comprehensive multilateral
round of the WTO, but certain developments were creating some disturbances in this trade
policy stance. The first development was that, the US had started to pursue an activist FTA
policy based on ‘competitive liberalization’ after the Bush Administration had restored the
Fast Track Negotiating Authority (also known as the Trade Promotion Authority) in 2002,
which had expired and not been in effect since 1994. With the Authority, the US saw an
opportunity to catch up with the EU’s long record of pursuing preferential agreements
(CRS, 2006) and started FTA negotiations with several countries including Chile,
Singapore, Australia and Morocco. Second, the DDA, which was set to conclude in
December 2006, started to show significant slowdown in progress towards multilateral
liberalization. Especially after the Cancun talks collapsed in 2003, and three of the
‘Singapore issues’1 dropped down from the DDA in 2004, the wisdom of multilateralism
started to be questioned in the EU. Even Lamy argued, in the Trade Policy Assessment
document that summarizes his five-year term as the Trade Commissioner, that, “our
arguments in favour of a better regulated multilateral world have been less effective.
Indeed, arguably as a result, trade policy or the WTO has too often been the sole focus for
efforts to strengthen international governance, which risks weakening its legitimacy both
internally within the Union, and in the outside world. I don’t believe the WTO can or
should remain the sole island of governance in a sea of unregulated globalization.”
(European Commission, 2004, p. 5) Lamy had stuck to his initial policy of keeping the
moratorium on FTAs during his service in the Commission, but he also had given the first
signs of a probable change in the EU trade policy.
1
Singapore issues are; investment protection, competition policy, transparency in government procurement
and trade facilitation. On 1 August 2004, WTO members agreed to start negotiations on trade facilitation, but
not on the other three Singapore issues.
276
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
New Trade Policy of the EU: Focus on FTAs
In July 2006, negotiation talks in Geneva failed to reach an agreement and the DDA was
officially suspended. This development threw multilateralism into a bleak future.
Regarding the fact that the biggest competitor, the US, has been pursuing FTAs with many
countries, especially with developed and emerging markets in East Asia, the EU had to act
as soon as possible to avoid trade diversion and a shift in the EU’s trade strategy had
already become inevitable. With the suspension of the DDA, multilateralist position of the
EU has lost its ground and the Commission has been forced to change its trade policy
focus.
The European Commission revealed a new trade policy strategy in October 2006, under
which the EU would pursue bilateral FTAs with major economies in order to secure the
market access and competitiveness of European companies in important markets. The core
of the new trade strategy of the EU has been summarized by the Commission as; “rejection
of protectionism at home, accompanied by activism in creating open markets and fair
conditions for trade abroad” (European Commission, 2006).
The new trade policy strategy primarily focuses on the need to identify and remove tariff
and non-tariff barriers (NTBs) to market access for goods and services that are important
for the European exporters. With the FTAs, the Commission also aims to solve some
behind-the-border issues, especially the Singapore issues of investment protection,
competition policy, and transparency in government procurement, which cannot be tackled
by the DDA. The new trade policy strategy report also revealed an agenda aiming to
influence the forces driving change, to seize the opportunities of globalization and to
manage the risks and challenges posed by the emerging economies especially in Asia and
South America.
The FTA strategy constitutes a very important part of this trade policy. The EU already has
quite a large number of bilateral deals: the agreements with the EFTA countries, the
customs union with Turkey, the goods agreements with the Euromed countries and the
preferential arrangements offered to the sub-Saharan African, Caribbean and Pacific (ACP)
countries. The EU had also signed FTAs with Chile, Mexico and South Africa.
Furthermore, as the recent developments in the world trade system made it necessary for
the EU to enhance its access to new markets in order to protect and improve
competitiveness of European business, the Commission defined economic criteria, target
countries and coverage for future FTAs.
The European Commission defines the key economic criteria for new FTA partners as
market potential and the level of protection (tariffs and NTBs) against EU export interests.
In this sense, the Commission defines ASEAN, Korea and Mercosur as prior FTA partners,
and India, Russia and the Gulf Cooperation Council as countries of direct interest. China,
on the other hand, despite meeting many of the criteria, is not defined as a possible FTA
partner, but a country of special attention because of the opportunities and the risks it
presents (European Commission, 2006, pp. 10-11). The EU's new FTA strategy aims at the
highest possible degree of trade, investment, and services liberalization, in addition to a
ban on export taxes and quantitative import restrictions. The main targets are regulatory
convergence, non-tariff barriers and stronger provisions on intellectual property rights
(IPRs) and competition. These trade relations could also include incorporating new
cooperative provisions in areas relating to labor standards and environmental protection. In
277
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
this sense, the EU would also have to take the erosion of its existing trade preferences into
account when negotiating FTAs, which could translate into sheltering certain products
from tariff cuts (ICTSD, 2006).
The trade policy change in the EU raised the concerns that the EU was shifting its attention
from the WTO to bilateral agreements, and the revival of the DDA would become more
difficult. Although the strategy report clearly states that “there will be no European retreat
from multilateralism and the EU remains committed to the WTO” (European Commission,
2006, p. 10), the rising number of FTA negotiations and proposals in the years after the
policy shift keeps these concerns alive.
After the announcement of its new FTA strategy, the EU has instantly given pace to its
efforts for signing FTAs. Currently, the following can be listed as the key EU bilateral
agreements:
•
Economic Partnership Agreements in negotiation with ACP countries (Cotonou)
•
Free Trade Agreements with EFTA, EEA, Euromed, Mercosur (in negotiation),
Mexico, Chile and South Africa
•
Customs Unions with Turkey, Andorra and San Marino
•
Partnership and Cooperation Agreements with Russia and Ukraine
As stated in the strategy paper, primarily targeted FTA partners were ASEAN and Korea,
and negotiations with both of them started in May 2007. Following them, FTA talks with
another important economy in Asia, with India, started in June 2007. In addition, the EU
accelerated the FTA talks that had started before the policy change, but had been
suspended because of the EU’s multilateralist position (e.g. FTA negotiations with the Gulf
Cooperation Council (GCC) and Mercosur). The EU is also seeking to negotiate FTA
agreements with Russia and the Andean and Central American countries. There are also
FTA proposals to the EU from several countries including Japan and Pakistan. In the
appendix, we display summarized tables for the trade indicators (amounts and shares of
exports and imports) of the EU with its target FTA partners and those for the previous FTA
partners from 2000 to 2006. The numbers evidence an increasing trend for each country
and country group (such as ASEAN and MERCOSUR) in both export shares and import
shares of the EU.
Motives Behind the EU’s Free Trade Agreements
In this section we will explore the trade relations of the EU with the countries that it is
negotiating or seeking for an FTA. We begin with an examination of the broader picture
showing on which grounds and motives the EU has pursued bilateral trade agreements so
far. Then we exemplify the motives and the possible gains from potential bilateral
agreements with Korea, ASEAN and India with which the EU has already started
negotiations.
According to Woolcock (2007), the EU’s framework of bilateral and regional trade
agreements can be differentiated into two main motives; foreign policy and security, and
commercial interests. Political motivations were dominant in EU’s trade agreements
related to its neighborhood policy, including the Europe Agreements with the Central and
Eastern European countries, the Euro-Med Association Agreements with Mediterranean
countries, and the Stability Pact with the countries of the Western Balkans. The
278
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
commercial or economic motivations for economic partnership agreements or FTAs, on the
other hand, primarily focus on limiting or neutralizing potential trade diversionary effects
which result from FTAs concluded between important trading partners and a third country.
The prime example of neutralizing trade diversion through an FTA is the EU–Mexico
FTA, motivated by a desire to neutralize trade diversion after the conclusion of NAFTA.
Commercial motivations also include forging strategic links with countries or regions
experiencing rapid economic growth, and enforcement of international trade rules.
Regarding the current FTAs of the EU, we observe that commercial or economic interests
are the dominant motivations. Neutralizing trade diversion motive can be observed in all
FTA negotiations that started in the new trade policy environment. ASEAN, Korea and
India had already been approached by the US, and the EU needed to pursue FTAs with
these important markets as soon as possible in order to avoid diversion of the imports of
these countries from Europe to the US.
Some research has been done on the trade potential of these countries (such as Korea,
ASEAN and India) in the context of bilateral trade agreements. One of these studies
belongs to Kim and Lee (2004), who examine the trade potential capacity of the EU and
Korea using the gravity model approach. A simple gravity equation embodies the ‘normal’
patterns of bilateral trade by integrating the economic, geographical and cultural factors.
Frankel (1997) argues that if actual trade volume is higher than the normal level of trade
that is obtained from the gravity factors (economic, geographical and cultural), then intraregional trade bias occurs. Kim and Lee employ a gravity equation analysis which intends
to estimate the trade potential capability of Korea and the EU-15. Constructing two
models, one for estimating separately the gravity equations for 52 countries between 1980
and 2002, and another for estimating the normal pattern of bilateral relations in the world,
the authors first find that there is a noticeable degree of over-trade between the EU-15 and
Korea. Another point the paper reveals is that this over-trading is a result of the fact that
“Korea has enjoyed a higher ratio of openness in terms of the ratio of the trade volume
with respect to GDP” (Kim and Lee, 2004, p.147). Second, when Korea and its trade with
the world are considered, the EU-Korea trade is found to be under-traded, pointing to the
possible explanation that Korea’s trade volume with the EU is much less than its trade
performance with its other trading partners. Another paper of Kim (2005) emphasizes that
an FTA with Korea would be desirable for the EU because the structural EU trade deficit
since the 1990s is usually attributed to the problems EU companies and products encounter
while entering and operating in the Korean market. These problems create barriers to trade
as the Korean rules for both products and services differ from those of the EU. Hence, an
FTA between the EU and Korea is expected to be advantageous for the EU especially if it
succeeds in removing the trade barriers, adoption of the EU standards for goods and
services and strong cooperation. Besides, as Korea is one of the most dynamic emerging
markets in East Asia, the EU finds it much beneficial to build an economic basis in Korea,
where an FTA would effectuate the role (Kim, 2005, p. 10).
Regarding the relations between the EU and ASEAN which date back to 1980, we can start
with the first EU-ASEAN agreement that was concluded in the form of a cooperation
agreement. It was a declaration of good will and intentions and contained some basic
principles about trade. Although this initiation developed a political dialogue between the
EU and ASEAN, it was not able to prioritize closer and deeper relations. In the 1990s, the
two partners engaged in a significant effort to deepen the cooperation and encourage
greater contact. However, the 1997-1998 Asian Financial Crisis impeded the relations once
279
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
more. After the recovery from the effects of the crisis, in 2001 and 2003, the EU attempted
to vitalize its relations in Southeast Asia and classified ASEAN as a key economic and
political partner. The following priorities were designated for the relations with the
Southeast Asia (Moeller, 2007):
• Supporting regional stability and the fight against terrorism;
• Promote human rights, democratic principles and good governance in all aspects of EC
policy dialogue and development cooperation;
• Dialogue incorporating issues such as migration, trafficking in humans, money
laundering, piracy, organized crime and drugs;
• Invest dynamism by launching a trade action plan called Transregional EU-ASEAN
Trade Initiative (TREATI);
• Support the development of less prosperous countries;
• Intensify dialogue in specific policy areas.
These priorities constitute a well-established ground for the EU to stimulate a cooperative
environment in Southeast Asia. Moeller (2007) points to two long term and far-reaching
benefits for EU-ASEAN relations arising from an FTA: first, it will please them both in
Asian integration; and second, an FTA will enhance their ability to tackle nonconventional and common threats to stability and security (Moeller, 2007, p. 478).
Theoretically, these two benefits may be gained without an FTA, but the political
environment calls for one. Since ASEAN has already concluded or is negotiating FTAs
with so many other partners, it seems difficult to solidify EU-ASEAN relations without
such an agreement. According to Moeller (2007), for ASEAN, “an FTA with the EU may
provide a platform for adjusting the competitive position of member states, making them
more capable of carving out a platform for competing with Asia's two giants: China and
India” (Moeller, 2007, p. 479). Since most ASEAN countries can no longer compete on
costs, they are in need of gaining competitive characteristics in areas such as corporate
governance, legal system, protection of intellectual property rights, design, quality,
performance. As long as some of these issues are not covered by the international set of
trade rules under the WTO, a considerable number of countries seek a solution through
FTAs. What is more, an EU-ASEAN FTA will confirm the belief that the two partners
trust each other and their intention to deepen and spread cooperation into other areas. One
such area is supposed to be transnational security issues. Therefore, in case the EU and
ASEAN fail to achieve enhanced cooperation in trade and economics, “dealing with more
complex issues such as security issues will be impossible” (Moeller, 2007, p. 479).
Botezatu (2007) also handles the circumstances of an EU-ASEAN FTA as a question of
‘when’ rather than ‘whether’. She emphasizes that the EU and Southeast Asia share many
common interests and features in the sense that they both seek ground for deeper
integration between their own member states and they are both embedded in multilateral
trade relations in the multi-polar world. Here arises another common situation for them
which results from the shortcomings of the multilateral system. Politically, they reflect
their will on creating a more effective multilateralism through cooperation in a wider range
280
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
of issues besides trade such as development aid, economic assistance and non-military
security cooperation. Since there is a huge development gap between ASEAN’s rich and
poor members, financial aid from the EU and hence a bilateral agreement is considered an
opportunity that should not be missed. In terms of trade relations, the strong commercial
links between these two blocs confirm the necessity. The EU was ASEAN’s third largest
trading partner as of 2007. Similarly, ASEAN is of crucial economic importance for the
EU. Cooperation on environmental issues such as the Kyoto Protocol and dialogue on
migration are also common aspirations of the two trade partners. Taking these into
consideration, Botezatu concludes that the establishment of a free trade area between the
EU and ASEAN will certainly welcome important economic benefits that will support and
expand the European model of integration among ASEAN countries.
Finally, the EU started negotiations with India on a bilateral trade and investment
agreement on 28 June 2007. Before, the Council had adopted a negotiating Directive for an
FTA with India on 23 April 2007, together with negotiating Directives for an EU-ASEAN
and an EU-Korea FTA2. India is trying to adhere to a ‘grand leap forward’ liberalization
model3, which targets to improve its manufacturing exports and information technologies,
and aims to ease its access to foreign markets. Having already become an important
production base and outsourcing destination for EU companies, India is in the target of the
EU who aims to get access to the large Indian market, increase its investment and the
export of goods and services, and settle on favorable trade rules and regulations. The
bilateral FTA is supposed to prepare the ground for a ‘strategic partnership’ in trade and
investment. Polaski et al. (2008) employ a simulation analysis using the social accounting
matrices of India and the EU and find the possible effects of an FTA on the EU. According
to the analysis, all the macroeconomic indicators of the EU, such as private consumption,
government consumption, investment consumption, import demand, export supply and
total domestic production, display significant increases. For instance, export supply
appears to increase by 1.35 billion dollars corresponding to a 0.05 % change, whereas
import demand is found to increase by 3.21 billion dollars which corresponds to a 0.11%
rise. Similarly, total domestic production is expected to increase by 0.05% as a result of the
simulations.
To sum up, reasons for bilateral trade agreements other than commercial motivations have
started to come to the fore as multilateral trade has encountered some obstacles and as
solutions to these obstacles can only be sought through FTAs between individual partners.
The EU has adopted itself to evaluate the best strategy with its potential partners in order to
deepen integration, expand its share in world exports, incorporate dialogue on universal
issues such as migration and environment and promote good governance and development
cooperation.
Conclusion
The European Community (later the European Union) has been a landmark for
regionalism. By promoting its own model of regional integration throughout Europe and its
neighboring countries, the EC/EU aimed to enhance its reach to different markets.
Nevertheless, it also supported the multilateral trade liberalization of the GATT/WTO,
albeit not as loyal as the US. In the late 1990s, the EU shifted its attention entirely to the
2
http://ec.europa.eu/trade/issues/bilateral/countries/india/index_en.htm
This strategy is announced by the Department of Commerce, Ministry of Commerce and Industry, India at
http://commerce.nic.in/index.asp.
3
281
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
completion of multilateral WTO negotiations and put a moratorium to all bilateral
agreement talks. However, the collapse of the WTO negotiations in Cancun in 2003,
proliferation of FTA negotiations by the US, and finally the suspension of the DDA in July
2006 forced the EU to pursue bilateral FTAs in order to protect the competitiveness of
European businesses.
The shift of the trade policy focus of the EU from multilateralism to bilateralism raised
concerns about the future of the WTO. Although the strategy paper of the new trade policy
clearly expressed that there will be no European retreat from multilateralism and the EU is
still loyal to WTO principles, the question still remains: will it be feasible (or even
necessary) to revive the DDA after concluding several FTAs?
There is a significant difference between the ‘new generation’ FTAs of the EU and its
previous bilateral trade agreements and the European integration scheme. Former FTAs
were mainly concluded with neighboring states or former colonies and the essential
motives behind those FTAs were dominantly foreign policy and enlargement. The new
trade policy of the EU, on the other hand, puts a strong emphasis on economic arguments
by linking FTAs to purely economic criteria, such as the market potential of the partner
and the existing tariff and non-tariff barriers to EU exports. Having completed the
economic integration in almost entire Europe and its neighborhood, the EU now targets the
emerging economies in Asia and Latin America. Another noteworthy characteristic of the
new generation FTAs is that, in the absence of the WTO negotiations, the EU sees these
FTAs as an opportunity to negotiate regulatory and beyond-the-border issues that are not
included in the DDA, and also to deal with ‘tough’ issues like agriculture, which seems
almost impossible to solve in the multilateral talks. Relying upon these motivations,
surveyed research on the potential consequences of FTAs between the EU and selected
countries evidence the gains from increasing free trade and cooperation.
We argue that, although both the US and the EU express that they are still loyal to
multilateralism, the recent surge of FTAs makes the revival of the DDA more difficult. As
major trade partners achieve their goals in increasing bilateral trade by removing the trade
barriers, the marginal gains from the results of multilateral negotiations diminish.
Currently, it seems that multilateralism is losing its ground against bilateralism. The hopes
for agreeing on multilateral free trade based on common WTO rules seem to be fading
away, but this does not mean that ‘free trade’ is weakening; bilateralism and FTAs became
the new tools of globalization and free trade. As for the Doha Round, as the Trade Minister
of India, Kamal Nath said, “the round is not dead, but between intensive care and the
crematorium”, and two years after the suspension of the talks, we can say that each FTA
makes the DDA one step closer to the crematorium.
282
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
References
Botezatu, E. (2007). “EU-ASEAN FTA: Regional Cooperation for Global
Competitiveness”, MPRA Working Paper, available at http://mpra.ub.unimuenchen.de/4946/
CRS (2006). Regional Trade Agreements: An Analysis of Trade-Related Impacts,
Congressional Research Service Report no. RL31072, by G. J. Wells.
COMTRADE (2008). UN Commodity Trade Statistics Database http://comtrade.un.org/db/
European Commission (2004). Trade Policy in the Prodi Commission, 1999-2004: An
Assessment, DG External Trade, Brussels
European Commission (2006). Global Europe: Competing in the World, Commission Staff
Working Document, DG External Trade, Brussels
Frankel, J. A. (1997). Regional Trading Blocs in the World Economic System, Washington
D.C.: Institute for International Economics.
ICTSD (2006). New EU Trade Strategy: Pursue Bilateral FTAs, Reduce NTBs,
International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development Bridges Weekly News Digest,
Vol. 10, No. 33
Kim, H. C. (2005). “Korea-EU FTA: Prospects for the Future”, presented at the Second
Italian-Korean Economic Workshop “Economic Policies, Growth and Economic
Integration East Asia and Europe in Perspective" Turin, Fondazione “Luigi Einaudi”, 20
June 2005
Kim, H.C. and Lee, C. (2004). “Korea-EU Trade Relations: Over-traded or Under-traded?”
Asia-Pacific Journal of EU Studies, vol. 2, no. 2
Lamy, P. (2002). “Stepping Stones or Stumbling Blocks? The EU's Approach Towards the
Problem of Multilateralism vs Regionalism in Trade Policy”, The World Economy, Vol.
25, pp. 1399-1413
Mashayekhi, M, L. Puri and T. Ito (2005). “Multilateralism and Regionalism”, in M.
Mashayekhi and T. Ito, Multilateralism and Regionalism: The New Interface, UNCTAD:
New York
Moeller, J. O. (2007). “ASEAN's Relations with the European Union: Obstacles and
Opportunities”, Contemporary Southeast Asia, Vol. 29, No. 3, pp. 465-82.
Panagariya, A. (1999). “The Regionalism Debate: An Overview”, The World Economy,
vol. 22, no. 4, pp. 477-511
Polaski, S. (2008). India’s Trade Policy Choices, Washington D.C.: Carnegie Endowment
for International Peace.
283
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Viner, J. (1950). The Customs Union Issue, New York: Carnegie Endowment for
International Peace
Woolcock, S. (2007). “European Union policy towards Free Trade Agreements”, ECIPE
Working Paper No. 03/2007.
284
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Appendix
All sources: Authors’ calculations from COMTRADE (2008)
Table A.1. Exports of the EU with Target FTA Partners (millions $)
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
ASEAN
37.724
38.482
37.768
43.457
53.330
55.844
61.939
MERCOSUR
21.935
21.702
17.257
17.345
22.844
25.644
29.656
S. Korea
15.064
13.895
16.322
18.185
22.190
24.998
28.783
India
12.368
11.175
12.444
16.107
21.181
26.215
30.447
China
23.512
27.086
32.669
46.024
59.932
64.310
80.219
Russia
20.353
27.569
31.962
41.390
56.999
70.081
92.311
GCC
27.314
30.508
33.744
42.115
51.073
62.579
70.002
China
2,96
3,37
3,82
4,60
4,98
4,84
5,37
Russia
2,56
3,43
3,73
4,14
4,73
5,28
6,18
GCC
3,44
3,79
3,94
4,21
4,24
4,71
4,69
Table A.2. Share in EU's Total Exports (%)
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
ASEAN
4,75
4,79
4,41
4,34
4,43
4,20
4,15
MERCOSUR
2,76
2,70
2,02
1,73
1,90
1,93
1,99
S. Korea
1,90
1,73
1,91
1,82
1,84
1,88
1,93
India
1,56
1,39
1,45
1,61
1,76
1,97
2,04
Table A.3. Imports of the EU with Target FTA Partners (millions $)
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
ASEAN
64.034
59.043
63.896
74.283
85.913
87.907
103.951
MERCOSUR
22.638
23.021
23.715
29.173
35.269
37.928
44.402
S. Korea
24.591
20.566
22.830
29.074
37.650
41.292
58.323
India
11.804
11.977
12.802
15.788
20.185
23.480
29.034
China
68.316
72.739
84.576
119.048
158.488
196.335
284.954
Russia
48.922
48.141
50.648
66.394
100.384
132.631
149.713
GCC
20.914
17.794
17.379
22.832
31.759
46.405
46.418
China
7,42
8,25
9,49
11,18
12,35
13,43
16,29
Russia
5,32
5,46
5,68
6,24
7,82
9,07
8,56
GCC
2,27
2,02
1,95
2,14
2,47
3,17
2,65
Table A.4. Share in EU's Total Imports (%)
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
ASEAN
6,96
6,70
7,17
6,98
6,69
6,01
5,94
MERCOSUR
2,46
2,61
2,66
2,74
2,75
2,59
2,54
S. Korea
2,67
2,33
2,56
2,73
2,93
2,83
3,33
India
1,28
1,36
1,44
1,48
1,57
1,61
1,66
285
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Table A.5. Exports of the EU with Previous FTA Partners (millions $)
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
Chile
3.161
3.283
2.951
3.293
3.878
4.827
5.363
Mexico
12.991
13.565
14.306
16.078
18.289
20.816
23.952
S. Africa
10.725
11.034
11.475
15.032
19.953
22.448
25.529
Table A.6. Share in EU's Total Exports (%)
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
Chile
0,40
0,41
0,34
0,33
0,32
0,36
0,36
Mexico
1,64
1,69
1,67
1,61
1,52
1,57
1,60
S. Africa
1,35
1,37
1,34
1,50
1,66
1,69
1,71
Table A.7. Imports of the EU with Previous FTA Partners (millions $)
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
Chile
4.680
4.546
4.568
5.566
8.962
9.767
15.548
Mexico
6.707
6.825
6.151
7.333
8.545
11.163
13.768
S. Africa
13.328
14.218
14.224
16.745
19.614
20.779
23.180
Table A.8. Share in EU's Total Imports (%)
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
Chile
0,51
0,52
0,51
0,52
0,70
0,67
0,89
Mexico
0,73
0,77
0,69
0,69
0,67
0,76
0,79
S. Africa
1,45
1,61
1,60
1,57
1,53
1,42
1,32
286
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
The Relationship between FDI and Growth under Economic Integration:
Is There One?
Antonio Marasco
Lahore University, Pakistan
Abstract
This study is a contribution to the debate on the relationship between FDI and growth. The
idea that the alleged link between FDI and growth is rather the consequence of both FDI
and growth responding endogenously to economic integration is tested empirically. The
results confirm precisely this point: it is not FDI as such but economic integration, in any
form or shape that determines growth.
287
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Introduction
The relationship between FDI and growth is one of the most intensively researched issues
in international economics. There is a fair amount of evidence suggesting that there exists a
positive relationship between these two quantities, albeit with some qualifications (see,
among others, Borenzstein et al. 1998). More controversial has been the issue whether
underpinning such a positive relationship there is causality running from FDI to growth or
not. One recent twist on this debate has been provided recently by Ting Gao (2005).
According to Ting Gao’s paper, the often observed positive correlation between FDI and
growth might not imply any causal relationship, since both of them might respond
endogenously to economic integration. The situation he suggests is like the one illustrated
in flowchart 1 below:
Flowchart 1
FDI
Economic
Integration
Growth
By contrast, according to the bulk of the literature on FDI and growth, causation would run
from FDI to growth. Economic integration could then also be accommodated in either of
two ways, as shown in flowchart 2 below:
Flowchart 2a
FDI
Economic
Integration
Growth
288
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Flowchart 2b
Economic
Integration
FDI
Growth
The aim of this paper is to gather empirical evidence and evaluate flowchart 1 against
flowchart 2. This is novel in the sense that although the literature on FDI and growth is
abundant, to the best of my knowledge, there is no study that has tested the relationship
when economic integration is included. Such a study would be an important contribution in
the face of works like that of Ting Gao, which cast doubts on the causal relationship
between FDI and growth.
The Econometric Framework
This study aims at testing the existence of a causal relationship that runs from economic
integration through FDI to growth. With this objective in mind, the following econometric
specification is used:
FDI it = α 0 + α1 int egrit + α 2instrit + α 3controlsit
git = β 0 + β1 FDI it + β 2 int egrit + β 3controlsit
The econometric specification consists of a structural model made up of two equations.
The first has the ratio of FDI flow to GDP (FDI) as the dependent variable, which is
regressed on economic integration ( Integr ), on an instrument for FDI and on a set of three
control variables (controls)1. The second equation has the growth rate of output (g) as the
dependent variable, and this is regressed on FDI, economic integration and the same set of
control variables. Estimation is done via two-stage least squares (2SLS), the most common
method used for estimating simultaneous-equation models (see Greene, 2003). The quality
of this study hinges a great deal on the choice of a good instrument. The variable to be
instrumented is FDI, hence in this case an instrument is good if it is highly correlated with
FDI and weakly correlated, if at all, with growth. This is a hard call, particularly in growth
regressions, where most economic variables have some kind of relationship with growth.
In the specific case, the variable chosen as instrument is the lagged value of FDI2.
Another important issue relates to the computation of the variable Integr . The existing
literature on the subject has produced measures of integration which are based on FDI,
trade and private capital flows (as an example, see Ismihan et al., 1998). In our case,
reliance on such an index would create a serious endogeneity issue in the first equation,
since FDI would enter both sides of the equation. Ideally, our measure of integration
should not include FDI at all in its calculation. On the other hand, an accomplished
1
The three control variables chosen (in logs) are inflation (measured by GDP deflator), population, and
human capital, proxied with years of schooling.
2
In the regression with the full sample of all 51 countries (i.e. regressions 1.1, 2.1 and 3, see below), lagged
FDI correlation coefficient is 0.697 with current FDI, and 0.057 with g respectively.
289
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
measure of integration should take financial integration into account, an important part of
which is of course FDI. This study tries to strike a delicate balance between these two
opposite considerations. To this end, the variable Integr consists of an index computed as
the average of two items. The first item is a trade integration index which is computed as
follows:
TII it =
Opennessit − MinOpenness
MaxOpenness − MinOpenness
where TII it stands for trade integration index for country i at time t, Opennessit is the ratio
of exports plus imports to GDP (in constant prices) and MinOpenness and MaxOpenness are the
minimum and maximum openness values in the sample respectively (both over time and
across countries).
The second item is a financial integration index which is computed in a likewise fashion as
follows:
FII it =
FI it − MinFI
MaxFI − MinFI
where FII it stands for financial integration index for country i at time t, FI it is the ratio of
financial assets plus financial liabilities to GDP for country i at time t, and MinFI and
MaxFI are the minimum and maximum financial integration values in the sample
respectively. Finally, the variable Integrit is calculated simply as:
Integrit =
TII it + FII it
2
FDI still enters the calculation of the variable Integr because an important part of financial
assets and liabilities are FDI assets and liabilities. Notice however that endogeneity
concerns have been addressed in three ways. First, FDI assets and liabilities are two stock
concepts while the calculation of the variable FDI is based on FDI inflows. This difference
should work towards decoupling FDI from Integr . Furthermore, when compared with the
integration measure produced by Ismihan et al. the weight of FDI has been reduced.
Finally, the variable Integr is a measure of the relative position of each country within the
sample, whereas the variable FDI is an absolute measure of the ratio of FDI inflows to
GDP. It is perfectly conceivable to think of a situation in which a country witnesses an
increase in FDI and at the same time its relative position in the sample with respect to the
same quantity worsens.
For complete peace of mind, I also run regressions in which the measure of integration is
based on the openness measure only. This is done in two ways. First, I use a measure of
integration, denoted Integr 2 , which is simply the trade integration index calculated above,
as follows:
Integr 2it = TII it .
290
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
The third measure of integration employed is just the trade openness variable as such, with
no further manipulation. That is:
Integr 3it = Opennessit =
Exportsit − Importsit
GDPit
Underpinning such measures is the idea that economic integration equals trade integration.
Obviously, FDI does not enter the calculation of these measures in any way.
The three variables Integrit , Integr 2it and Integr 3it yield three different sets of regressions.
As far as Integrit and Integr 2it are concerned, in each case regressions are run not only with
respect to the full dataset of 51 countries, but also to the reduced dataset including
developing and developed countries. This gives six regressions, to which I refer as
regressions 1.1, 1.2, 1.3 and 2.1, 2.2, 2.3 in the Tables. This is not repeated in the case of
Integr 3it , since it would not add much information. Hence, the latter is referred to as
regression 3.
One further alternative measure of integration could also potentially be used to check for
robustness of the results. Such a measure would be based on an evaluation of the barriers
to integration. In principle, this measure should account both for tariffs as well non tariff
barriers (NTB). Because of severe lack of data on NTB in the time dimension, a measure
that account both for tariffs as well as NTB is not feasible. Even if the index were to be
based on tariffs’ data only, lack of data would still be severe enough to undermine any kind
of comparison that one would want to make with the other measures of integration. I
therefore leave this option as a possible addition to be included in future research, once
data coverage on tariffs and NTB improves.
Data and Sample Selection Issues
There is a choice of sources for the data regarding the main variables of this study. FDI
data were taken from the UNCTAD FDI online database, GDP data came from the U.N.
National Accounts database. Data on trade openness (used in calculating Integr ) are from
the Penn World Tables, Version 6.2. Data regarding financial assets and liabilities, used to
calculate the financial integration index, are from the External Wealth of Nations (EWN)
database (see Kose et al., 2006). As for the control variables, data on population and
inflation came from the World Development Indicators 2005 (World Bank) and, in a few
instances (mainly for 2004) from the World Development Indicators online. Finally, data
for average years of schooling (my proxy for human capital), came from Barro and Lee
dataset on educational attainment (2000).
With respect to sample selection, this was dictated by availability of data for the main
variables. Initially I had thought to have a panel of both developed and developing
countries covering as large a geographical area as possible for the time interval 1980-2004.
Included in the sample are countries from Latin America, East Asia and Pacific, South
Asia, Africa, Middle East, Eastern Europe, as well as the OECD countries. It soon became
clear, though, that in order to maintain the countries of Eastern Europe in the sample, the
time interval had to be shortened to the period 1990-2004. After running the regressions,
breath of geographical coverage seemed to be qualitatively more important than the length
of the time interval chosen, I opted for sticking to the period 1990-2004 and keeping the
291
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
countries of Eastern Europe in the sample. As a result of this strategy, the sample includes
51 countries (the full list is given in the Appendix) covering 15 years. In the year 2000,
these 51 countries accounted for approximately 65% of world GDP3, and for 78% of world
population. The regression with the full sample, both in terms of countries included and
years covered, features 680 observations, instead of the potential 765 (51*15=765),
because 51 values are lost when lagging FDI for the first year (1990), and inflation data
include 34 negative rates, which result into 34 lost values when taking logs (51*15=76551=714-34=680). Detailed descriptive statistics are shown in Tables 4, 5 and 6.
Results
The results of the 2SLS regressions are displayed in Table 1 (first stage) and Table 2
(second stage)4. As discussed earlier, results are given for three different types of
integration measures, and along three different levels of aggregation (all countries,
developing countries and developed countries). Regressions are identified by two digits,
the first referring to the integration measure used, and the second referring to the level of
aggregation. For example regression 2.1 refers to Integr 2it and to all countries, and so on.
Table 1 clearly shows that economic integration is a significant and positively signed
determinant of FDI. Such result holds no matter how one defines integration or which level
of aggregation is chosen. In the case of Table 2, two points emerge in almost as equally
clear-cut a manner as the message conveyed by Table 1. Firstly, integration is a positive
determinant of growth in all cases but regressions 1.2 and 1.3. This point is in full
accordance with Gao (2005). Secondly, an even more important point, FDI is never a
significant contributor to growth. This (non) result is very robust to all types of integration
measures and all levels of aggregation. It is also perfectly in line with the argument that the
alleged relationship between FDI and growth might just be a classical example of omitted
variable bias, where the omitted variable in the specific case would be economic
integration. To make the evidence more compelling, I run a fixed-effects regression of FDI
on growth without economic integration5, whose results are presented in Table 3. As
before, the exercise is repeated for all countries in the sample, the developing countries and
the developed countries respectively. The evidence that I get is mixed, since FDI is
significant at the 5% level if I restrict attention to developed countries, not significant
when attention is restricted to developing countries and significant at the 10% level if the
entire sample is included. This is precisely the kind of mixed evidence that would emerge
from past literature on FDI and growth. Such uncertainty is wiped out though once
economic integration enters the frame, as we have seen. Then, there is simply no role for
FDI, singularly considered, as a determinant of growth.
3
The figure for world GDP in 2000 is taken from world GDP estimates produced by DeLong and available
online at http://econ161.berkeley.edu/TCEH/1998_Draft/World_GDP/Estimating_World_GDP.html. The
figure for world population in 2000 is taken from the U.N. population database (online address:
http://esa.un.org/unpp/ ).
4
In all regressions concerned, the fitted model is the one with fixed-effects. The Hausman test, performed to
test for its suitability against the random-effects model, returned high values of the chi-square statistic in all
cases.
5
Once again the Hausman test was used to aid the decision whether to go for fixed or random effects. Once
again that test returned a high chi square statistic in all cases, confirming appropriateness of the fixed-model.
292
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Conclusion
This study has been yet one more attempt at shedding light on the relationship between
FDI and growth. The new twist here, after taking inspiration from recent theoretical work
by Gao (2005), consisted in adding the variable “economic integration” to the analysis.
Exactly as expected, and as claimed by Gao, the alleged positive link between FDI and
growth disappears once integration is added. This study suggests that the current frenzy of
countries from all income brackets to attract FDI as a way to improve their growth
prospects, might be misplaced. What countries that want to grow faster should do is to
become ever more integrated with the world economy. The actual mode of integration,
whether through trade, FDI or else, seems not to matter.
This study can be improved upon and extended in several ways. Firstly, the dataset of
reference should be extended as new data become available, particularly with respect to the
countries of Eastern Europe and the countries belonging to the lower income brackets.
Also, the concept of economic integration should be augmented to include labor market
integration. Labor of course, is a very important dimension of the economy, and I have left
it out both for problems of data availability and a lack of an effective proxy to measure
labor integration. In future work however, the latter should definitely be included if one is
to make a more convincing claim that, under economic integration, there is no link
between FDI as such and economic growth.
293
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
References
Barro, Robert J., Lee, Jong-Wha, 2000. “International Data on Educational Attainment:
Updates and Implications” CID Working Paper No. 42, April 2000
Borensztein, E., De Gregorio, J., Lee, J.-W., 1998. “How does foreign direct investment
affect economic growth?” Journal of International Economics 45 (1), 115–135.
Gao, Ting, 2005. “Foreign Direct Investment and Growth under Economic Integration.”
Journal of International Economics 67 (1), 157-174.
Ismihan, M., Olgun, H. and Utku, F. M. 1998. “A Proposed Index for Measuring
‘Globalization’ of National Economies.” METU Economic Research Center (erc) Working
Papers in Economics, No.98/5.
Kose, M. Ayhan, Prasad, E., Rogoff, K., Wei, Shang-Jin, 2006. “Financial Globalization: a
Reappraisal“ NBER Working Paper No.12484, August.
Lane, Philip R., Milesi-Ferretti, G.M., 2006. “The External Wealth of Nations Mark II:
Revised and Extended Estimates of Foreign Assets and Liabilities, 1970-2004” IMF
Working Paper No. 69 (WP/06/69), March.
Motta, Massimo, Norman, George, “Does Economic Integration Cause Foreign Direct
Investment?” International Economic Review, Department of Economics, University of
Pennsylvania and Osaka University Institute of Social and Economic Research
Association, 37(4), 757-83, 1996.
294
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
Appendix
a) Tables
First Stage Estimation Result of 2SLS Regression
Dependent Variable: FDI
Regression Number
1.1 (All
1.2
1.3
2.1 (All
Countries) (Developing) (Developed) Countries)
Coefficient
Independent Variable
(Standard Error)
0.1009***
0.0275*
0.1334*
0.063***
integr (integr2, integr3)
(0.02523)
(0.01548)
(0.0498)
(0.0202)
0.4504***
0.4550***
0.4247***
0.4814***
lagged FDI
(0.0379)
(0.047)
(0.0629)
(0.0361)
-0.0091
-0.0174
-0.0713
-0.0010
pop
(0.0337)
(0.0249)
(0.1335)
(0.0340)
-0.00094
-0.0023**
0.0026
0.0006
infl
(0.0015)
(0.0012)
(0.0045)
(0.0015)
-0.0091
0.0017
-0.0138
-0.0086
H
(0.0346)
(0.025)
(0.1035)
(0.0352)
TABLE 1
TABLE 2
Independent
Variable
FDI
integr (integr2, integr3)
pop
infl
H
Second Stage Estimation Result of 2SLS Regression
Dependent Variable: g
Regression Number
1.3
2.1 (All
1.1 (All
1.2
Countries)
(Developing) (Developed) Countries)
Coefficient
(Standard Error)
-0.1160
(0.1064)
0 .1215***
(0.0379)
-0.1168***
(0.0426)
-0.0066***
(0.0019)
0.0628
(0.0438)
-0.0098
(0.2415)
0.0385
(0.0376)
-0.1345**
(0.0584)
-0.0073**
(0.0029)
0.0892
(0.0599)
-0.0466
(0.0686)
0.0259
(0.0284)
-0.0145
(0.0622)
-0.0041*
(0.0021)
0.0860*
(0.0481)
295
-0.1140
(0.0930)
0.1449***
(0.0273)
-0.1003**
(0.0420)
-0.0055***
(0.0019)
0.0306
(0.0436)
2.2
(Developing)
2.3
(Developed)
3 (All
Countries)
0.0254*
(0.0147)
0.4546***
(0.0471)
-0.0105
(0.0249)
-0.0023**
(0.0012)
-0.0028
(0.0262)
0.2128***
(0.0626)
0.4069***
(0.0621)
-0.0957
(0.1303)
0.0028
(0.0045)
-0.1002
(0.1100)
0.0003***
(0.0001)
0.4814***
(0.0362)
-0.0009
(0.0339)
-0.0006
(0.0015)
-0.0086
(0.0352)
2.2
(Developing)
2.3
(Developed)
3 (All
Countries)
-0.1451
(0.2382)
0.1414***
(0.0356)
-0.1096*
(0.0574)
-0.0062**
(0.0029)
0.0378
(0.0602)
-0.1256
(0.0737)
0.1267***
(0.0397)
-0.0843
(0.0635)
-0.0036
(0.0022)
0.0052*
(0.054)
-0.114
(-0.9299)
0.0006***
(0.0001)
-0.1004**
(0.0421)
-0.0055***
(0.0019)
0.0306
(0.0437)
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
TABLE 3
Fixed-Effects Regression
Dependent
Variable: g
Regression Number
1.1 (All
1.2
Countries)
(Developing)
Independent Variable
Coefficient
(Standard
Error)
0.0958*
0.0921
FDI
(-0.0503)
(0.1224)
-0.0886*
-0.1150*
pop
(0.0459)
(0.0630)
-0.0120***
-0.014***
infl
(0.0019)
(0.0027)
-0.0302
-0.0216
H
(0.0438)
(0.0592)
TABLE 4
Descriptive Statistics
Obs
FDI
integr
integr2
FII
integr3
GDP(millions)
g
laggedFDI
pop (millions)
infl
H
logpop
loginfl
logH
765
765
765
765
765
765
765
714
765
765
765
764
731
765
1.3
(Developed)
0.0630**
(0.0248)
0.0295
(0.0488)
-0.0035**
(0.0019)
0.0503
(0.0402)
all
Mean
Standard
Error
Min
Max
0.0298
0.1811
0.2674
0.9486
32.9814
482267.4
0.0323
0.0297
90.706
39.6876
7.5422
17.2019
1.8242
1.9301
0.0406
0.1179
0.1689
0.1034
19.4799
1109062
0.0466
0.0408
212.664
323.1064
2.6319
1.4015
1.3792
0.4924
-0.0588
0
0
0
1.9823
4904
-0.3392
-0.0239
3.049
-5.5509
0.55
14.9303
-3.0909
-0.5978
0.4603
0.8839
1
1
115.3647
8734868
0.6854
0.4603
1294.846
7485.8
12.306
20.9816
8.9207
2.51
296
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
TABLE 5
Descriptive Statistics
Obs
FDI
integr
integr2
FII
integr3
GDP(millions)
g
laggedFDI
pop (millions)
infl
H
logpop
loginfl
logH
450
450
450
450
448
450
450
420
450
450
450
450
437
450
developing
Mean
0.0289
0.2887
0.2532
0.3243
30.98
153275.4
0.0373
0.0281
125.8228
65.4176
6.2771
17.555
2.4736
1.7312
TABLE 6
Descriptive Statistics
Obs
FDI
integr
integr2
FII
integr3
GDP(millions)
g
laggedFDI
pop (millions)
infl
H
logpop
loginfl
logH
315
315
315
315
315
315
315
294
315
315
315
315
294
315
Standard
Error
0.0321
0.1373
0.1759
0.1511
19.931
207277.2
0.0578
0.0313
265.6321
419.2691
2.3816
1.4077
1.3286
0.5327
Min
Max
-0.0239
0
0
0
1.982
4904
-0.3392
-0.0239
3.049
-5.5509
0.55
14.9303
-3.0909
-0.5978
0.2146
0.7992
1
1
115.364
1477367
0.6854
0.2146
1294.864
7485.8
10.756
20.9816
8.9207
2.3754
developed
Mean
Standard
Error
Min
Max
0.031
0.2173
0.31
0.1247
35.7891
950757.9
0.0252
0.0319
39.7873
2.812
9.35
16.692
0.8564
2.2141
0.0505
0.161
0.2042
0.1432
18.5092
1597697
0.0209
0.0515
60.864
2.7968
1.7867
1.2263
0.7341
0.2173
-0.0588
0.0061
0
0
8.0979
43043
-0.0638
-0.0053
3.448
-2.4899
4.33
15.0533
-2.3834
1.4655
0.4603
0.9689
1
1
101.0557
8734868
0.1168
0.4603
295.4069
20.6907
12306
19.5038
3.0296
2.51
297
International Conference on Emerging Economic Issues in A Globalizing World, Izmir, 2008
b) Countries Included in the Sample
Argentina
Brazil
Chile
Colombia
Costa Rica
Dominican Republic
Mexico
Paraguay
Peru
Uruguay
Venezuela
Bangladesh
China
India
Indonesia
Malaysia
Pakistan
Philippines
Rep. Korea
Sri Lanka
Thailand
Egypt
Nigeria
South Africa
Czech Republic
Hungary
Poland
Romania
Russian Federation
Turkey
Australia
Austria
Belgium and Luxemburg
Canada
Denmark
Finland
France
Germany
Greece
Ireland
Italy
Japan
Netherlands
New Zealand
Norway
Portugal
Spain
Sweden
Switzerland
United Kingdom
United States
298