Trade Patterns as a Source of Militarized Conflict*
Manuel Flores†
Abstract
The analysis of the effects of international trade on conflict has almost exclusively focused on the
volume of trade flows, mostly disregarding any consideration related to the content of trade flows.
This paper empirically explores the determinants of bilateral conflict taking into account several
measures describing relevant dimensions of trade flows at the product level, as the degree of
complementarity between the two countries, the extent of substitutability of the partner as a
destination market and an imports provider, and the level of rivalry between the members of each pair
as exporters and importers in third markets. Proposing an innovative instrument to address the
endogeneity of trade variables, I estimate a directed model which takes advantage of a continuous
event-based measure of interstate conflict. Results show that the three considered dimensions of the
patterns of trade are relevant to explain interstate conflict. Results also vary when explaining the
frequency or the hostility level of conflict events. According to the results, liberal and realist
approaches emerge as coexisting explanations of the consequences of trade on political relations
between countries.
Keywords: interstate conflict, international trade, trade patterns, rivalry, trade substitutability, trade
complementarity, trade network
JEL codes: F51, F14
This research is part of the project “Trade and Conflict: A network approach”, funded by the Swiss Network for
International Studies. I am grateful to Nicolas Berman, Simon Hug, Imaculada Martinez-Zarzoso, Alessandro Nicita,
Marcelo Olarreaga, Dominic Rohner, Federico Trionfetti, Marcel Vaillant, and participants in seminars in Degit XX, Ridge
Forum, Unige and Decon for comments and suggestions on earlier drafts. I am also grateful for financial support by the
Agencia Nacional de Investigación e Innovación (ANII, Uruguay). I am responsible for all errors.
*
†
Geneva School of Economics and Management, Université de Genève, Switzerland, and Universidad de la República,
Uruguay. email: Manuel.Flores@unige.ch
1 Introduction
A central hypothesis in the international relations’ literature states that trade reduces conflict between
countries. Assuming that conflict has a deterrent effect on trade, it is straightforward to see that
political disruptions lead to a loss of gains from trade, which can be seen as the opportunity cost of
conflict. Hence, in this liberal approach the higher the volume of bilateral trade, the higher the
opportunity cost of conflict, and the lower the incentives for political leaders to engage in international
disputes. An opposing view asserts that higher trade leads to an increase in the vulnerability of each
country to the interruption of trade, and so can in turn increase conflict.
The debate the effects of international trade on conflict has almost exclusively focused on the volume
of trade flows, mostly disregarding any consideration related to their content. This paper focuses on
the role that trade specialization patterns, i.e. the specific groups of products imported from and
exported to each partner, may have on the level of conflict between countries. More specifically, trade
patterns allow to consider not only observed trade flows but also the role of potential trade, they enrich
the operationalization of the opportunity costs of conflict, and they enable to weigh the role of actors
and targets in the international trade network.
If trade is already disrupted by some degree of conflict, exports and imports will no longer reflect the
strategic importance of a partner. However, the degree of complementarity between the products
imported and exported by the two partners gives an indication about the amount of potential trade,
which could still be relevant in explaining new variations in the level of conflict. Still, both positive
and negative effects are theoretically possible, since as for the volume of trade countries could react to
a high complementarity caring about opportunity costs of conflict or could also react aggressively
against strategic providers. Our results will show that countries tend to fight more with complementary
origin and destination markets, and conflict is particularly high in the second case.
Second, not every conflict embeds the same opportunity costs. The loss produced by the interruption
of trade relations is larger when the goods being traded are harder to substitute. For a given country,
some partners are hardly substitutable as providers of imported products or as destinations for specific
exports, while other partners can be easily replaced in both roles. Our results suggest that countries
react with more frequent and intense engagements against hard to substitute origins and destinations,
using conflict to secure sensitive markets.
Finally, countries’ conflict decisions towards a particular target might respond not only to bilateral
trade but to the role of the target country on the entire trade network. Hence, conflict could pursue a
utility gain in terms of strategic trade interests in third markets, and countries may have incentives to
send out higher conflict against their global competitors.1 We will show that the degree of rivalry in
terms of the product-specific destination markets significantly increases the expected level of conflict
in a country-pair, whereas coincidence in the sourcing markets is actually pacifying.
To understand the causal links behind international militarized conflict, in particular to weigh the role
of the pattern of traded products as a source of political disrupts, is important for many reasons.
Countries’ development is somehow related to their capacity to produce a very diverse set of goods,
We refer to countries’ utilities in a wide sense, it can represent the welfare level for all the economy, which would coincide
with the case of a political leader maximizing social utility, or it can also be thought as the result of lobbying groups, where
some would beneficiate from increased trade and then lobby for peace, while others would lobby for war as a means to obtain
private gains.
1
2
while least developed countries typically produce a narrow basket of some primary goods. So
development could be seen as a process in which among other things countries diversify their
production, acquiring new capacities to produce more complex goods. The political dimension of this
process, in terms of the reactions it will produce in trade partners who could be benefited or hindered,
have not been systematically explored. We contribute to the literature on the determinants of conflict,
which seeks to explain the reasons why countries fight with each other as a means to improve peace
promoting policies, and we alert about the relevance of the trade patterns mechanisms that could
trigger militarized disputes. It is politically relevant to know if some kinds of trade instead of
promoting peace promote conflict, and our findings suggest considering theories where some forms of
trade can promote conflict. Our approach also contributes to the debate over the liberal peace.
Showing that more conflict should be expected the more substitutable the partner we are giving
support to the liberal interpretation on the gains from trade as a component of the opportunity cost of
conflict. Nonetheless, the role of trade rivalries as a source of conflict could be evidence in favor of a
realist approach.
The main challenges for an empirical evaluation of the forces at play are related to the measurement of
the relevant dimensions for the patterns of trade and their inclusion in a directed model for conflict, as
well as the adequate treatment of endogeneity of trade values within a conflict model.
In order to measure complementarities, substitutabilities and rivalries at the country-pair level we turn
to the distances between countries in different bipartite networks. Links are defined as probabilities
and e.g. country j is more complementary for i’s exports the higher the probability of j importing a
product that i exports. Analogous measures are defined for substitutability and rivalry in trade.
The relevant dimensions of trade patterns are necessarily asymmetric; since the degrees of commercial
complementarity, substitutability, or rivalry, are not the same when country evaluates country than
when the reciprocal evaluation is observed. This means we need a directed dataset, in which
observations are directed dyads ( , and , are two separate observations) and each variable is defined
accordingly when possible. This is particularly infrequent when measuring bilateral conflict, since war
variables or the commonly used Militarized Interstate Disputes (MID) conceive conflict as undirected.
To overcome this limitation we turn to an event-based measure of material military actions taken by
official actors in each country towards official actors of every partner. An additional advantage comes
from the proposed variable being continuous, since this involves a possibility to capture the
importance of the actions countries engage in, and also appreciably increases the nonzero values in
comparison with the typical binary variables for war or MID.
The empirical assessment of the effects of trade patterns on conflict needs to control for the volume of
bilateral trade for each directed dyad, but reverse causality is a serious problem since many authors
have shown the deterrent effects of conflict on trade (even if this conclusion is subject of debate). We
address this endogeneity issue through an Instrumental Variable (IV) approach, proposing original
excluded instruments that measure exports to synthetic destinations and imports from synthetic
origins, being these synthetic partners built as an average of the most similar third countries in term of
economic size. Considering a large enough number of countries in the averages, neighbors are so
diverse that a synthetic directed trade flows should not be associated with the directed conflict in the
dyad.
Related literature has mainly developed around the liberal/realists debate over the existence of
pacifying effects of trade. Liberals argue that interdependence between two countries tend to reduce
the probability of conflict between them, operationalizing interdependence with trade values. The
3
argument is based on the dissuading role of the opportunity cost of conflict in terms of losing the
potential gains from trade during hostility times (Russett and Oneal, 2001)2. Realists show many
channels through which dependence from another country would encourage the use of force (Waltz,
1979). Marxist argue that trade promotes conflict because specialization and interdependence produce
insecurity and vulnerability to external events (Choucri and North, 1975). Empirical studies give
mixed results, with papers showing trade reduces conflict3, others obtaining that trade increases
conflict4, and some that reveal no statistical relation5.
Interdependence is a theoretically debated concept6, and it has been operationalized in different
manners, using volumes of total bilateral trade or relative measures of bilateral trade (in terms of total
trade of each country, or in terms of their GDPs). But the notion of interdependence is much richer if
we take the content of each flow into account. Intuitively, political leaders would care more about
relations with those countries exporting the very kind of products their country imports, and also when
trade flows include goods that are hard to buy or sell elsewhere. Some literature has addressed this
distinction through the notions of “sensitivity interdependence” and “vulnerability interdependence”
(Keohane and Nye, 1977). Blanchard and Ripsman (1996) proposed to evaluate vulnerability of a
country to trade disruptions looking at the potential for each country to mitigate the costs of a cut-off
by considering the availability of alternative suppliers, the prospects of increasing domestic
production, the prospects of conservation, and the potential for substitution. Our measure focus on
alternative suppliers and adding the alternative buyers we use disaggregated product information to
weigh how exclusive each partner is in terms of the particular products contained in their bilateral
trade flows.
Few studies have explored the effects of the content of trade on conflict, most of them based on a
decomposition of trade by sector. Literature on resource-conflict relationship, asking whether some
specific resources increase the probability of conflict, is mostly based on qualitative approaches and
case studies.7 In an early cross-country approach, Reuveny and Kang (1998) consider 10 different
sectors and find that while trade Granger-causes conflict in some cases, the reverse causality holds for
others, describing a pattern that leads to the strategic-goods literature. The main limitation in their
study comes from the limited scope of their sample, comprised by just 20 dyads.
More recently Goenner (2010) identified six groups of strategic goods (at the SITC 4-digits level)
showing that an increase in trade in energy, non-ferrous metals, and electronics increases conflict,
while more trade in chemicals and arms reduces conflict. Coinciding with Dorussen (2006), he shows
that homogeneous commodities (highly elastic import demand and export supply curves) are less
2
Gasiorowski (1986) emphasizes that measures of aggregate bilateral trade reflect interconnectedness rather than
interdependence, since the latter concept requires not only trade but countries’ vulnerability to its disruption, which depends
of the specific pattern of trade in terms of goods and number of partners.
3
See Polachek (1980, 1997); Pollins (1989a, 1989b); Oneal, et al. (1996); Oneal and Russett (1997, 1999), Russett and Oneal
(2001); Mansfield and Pevehouse (2000); Gartzke and Li (2003); and Oneal, et al. (2003).
4
See Gasiorowski (1986) and Barbieri (1996, 2002).
5
See Beck, Katz, and Tucker (1998); Goenner (2004); Keshk, Pollins, and Reuveny (2004); and Kim and Rousseau (2005).
6
For an extensive review see Baldwin (1980).
7
Empirical studies on renewable resources are mostly about water scarcity, and show that states tend to cooperate when they
have shared water resources. Empirical studies on non-renewable resources are mostly focused on the effects of oil or
diamonds abundance on local conflict. They identify two causal mechanisms: resource scarcity for renewable resources (with
low market value) leads to fight-for-survival conflicts rarely observed in quantitative studies; while abundance of nonrenewable resources has been clearly documented but leads mostly to local (internal) conflicts as shown by Homer-Dixon
(1999). Koubi, Spilker, Bohmelt and Bernauer (2014) present the essential findings in these studies.
4
likely to reduce conflict than trade of more differentiated products (inelastic curves). Dorussen (2006)
finds pacifying effects for apparel, low-tech, high-tech, and machinery, and he fails to find the
expected pacifying effect for chemicals and electronics.
Goenner (2010) also shows that trade in strategic commodities is more likely to lead to conflict when
the exporter is concentrated in a few commodities to a few destinations or also when production is
concentrated within a country, since in these cases the producing country is a potential target for
plundering. Concentration of international trade partners is especially important for goods with very
high transportation costs that are almost exclusively traded with neighbors, as in the case of electricity.
Another relevant hypothesis recently put forward by Peterson and Thies (2012) suggests that the effect
of trade on conflict depends on whether trade is intra-industry or inter-industry. In the first case, trade
is associated with reduced conflict propensity, because exchange of similar products resulting from
economies of scale and consumer tastes for variety is mostly a cooperative sort of relationship. On the
other hand, inter-industry trade provokes vulnerability in trading partners. The authors find empirical
support for this distinction.
These last papers address the issue of the content of trade by means of a decomposition of trade by
sectors, a strategy that makes particularly difficult to deal with endogeneity concerns and only allows
extracting conclusions on the role of particular kinds of products. In this paper we propose a different
approach, taking advantage of theoretically founded descriptive measures of the content of trade for
each dyad. Therefore we propose to qualify trade flows instead of decomposing them. The main
advantage is that our strategy expands the possibilities for dealing with endogeneity, and it also avoids
an arbitrary selection of sectors.
2 Conceptual framework
A model to explain conflict among countries needs to be based on a rational justification about the
decision of engaging in military confrontations. The consequences of conflict on trade are a crucial
element for the evaluation of the expected gains or losses produced by an interstate conflict. The
expected utility approach has been a workhorse in this field, assuming in general that the higher the
volume of bilateral trade the larger the costs of conflict (Polachek 1980, 1992; Polachek, Robst, and
Chang, 1999; Robst, Polachek, and Chang, 2007). In these models the cost of lost trade comes from
conflict reducing a country’s supply for its imports and demand for its exports, increasing thus the
domestic price of imported products and decreasing the price received for exported products, i.e. a
terms of trade effect.
Li and Reuveny (2011, LR hereafter) propose a more general model, in which Polachek’s approach
becomes a particular case, admitting the possibility of differential effects of conflict on the demand of
imports of a country and the supply of these same products by a partner. Depending on the magnitudes
of the shifts produced by conflict on a partial equilibrium demand and supply model, and depending
also on the price elasticities of these curves, the effect of conflict on the price of imports/exports can
be positive or negative. Thus, rational political leaders who maximize social utility (subject to some
level of trade surplus in each good) will respond to higher exports with higher conflict when the price
of exports rises with conflict, and will respond to higher exports with lower conflict when the price of
exports decreases with conflict. An analogous reasoning works for imports, where faced with higher
imports the leader responds with higher conflict if the price of imports decreases with conflict and
responds with lower conflict if the price of imports increases with conflict. Since elasticities vary by
5
sector, their strategy is to decompose trade selecting specific sectors and use the elasticities estimated
in Reuveny (2001) to verify if the effect of each sector trade flow is the expected one.
Our approach is based on an extension of LR’s partial equilibrium two-country model to the case of
many countries and products. As in LR we consider countries as unitary actors that rationally decide
the levels of economic relations (trade) and political relations (conflict) among each other. Thus, each
country will maximize a utility function that depends on economic consumption and the levels of
conflict they send to other countries (assuming that utility rises with higher consumption and with
higher conflict).
We start by analyzing the market for one product, admitting the possibility of it being bilaterally
traded in both directions. The model assumes countries are small, nevertheless the particular price in
each bilateral relation can vary due to changes in bilateral supply and demand as well as specific costs
or restrictions to trade.
A crucial feature in a directed model of trade and conflict is how far conflict distortions on supply and
demand curves of countries are allowed to go. The simplest option is to assume that conflict from
to ( ) only shifts market curves in one country. If changes occur in the own market curves, i.e.
supply for exports (� � ) and demand for imports (� ) are shifted to the left, then the model will
predict a gain in terms of trade for country together with a decrease in the volume of trade.
Polacheck’s (1980) micro-foundation for liberalism takes an opposite view, and assuming that conflict
will always worsen terms of trade predicts unambiguous welfare losses for country when he
increases conflict towards . This reasoning is equivalent to shift only foreign market curves, meaning
that an increase in
will reduce the demand for ’s exports (� ) and the supply for ’s imports (� � ).
A key aspect in LR’s model is that conflict from to affects both the supply of exports done by
country and the demand for these exports in the importing partner . With higher conflict between a
country and a partner , both supply and demand for exports from to will move to the left, so
traded quantities will fall but the price of exports (and exporter surplus) can be higher. Thus conflict
might have a welfare increasing or decreasing effect through exports, depending on the magnitude of
the different shifts in supply and demand. Similar effects occur in the market for imports from in
country .
Figure 1
Relevant trade relations and the role of third countries
Panel A
�ℎ
Panel B
�
�
Panel C
Panel D
�
�ℎ
ℎ
Panel E
�ℎ
ℎ
�
ℎ
Panel F
�ℎ
�ℎ
ℎ
�ℎ
6
The extension to the three-country case allows considering new channels through which country
could gain or lose when increasing the level of conflict sent towards . Figure 1 represents the main
mechanisms, starting by the direct impact on exports and imports considered in Polachek and LR
(Panels A and B). On the one hand, losses in the market of bilateral exports to could be partially or
totally offset by an increase in exports to country ℎ (Panel C), and the same occurs with the bilateral
market of imports from (Panel D) where country ℎ could substitute country as a provider of goods.
If substitutability was perfect conflict would only produce a reallocation effect with no associated
losses. On the other hand, when third countries are included in the analysis the effects of conflict on
supply and demand curves can be taken further, considering how an increase in
affects the supply
of ’s products in ℎ (� �ℎ ) and ’s demand for products from ℎ (�ℎ ). In this case conflict could be used
by country to improve his position in country ℎ, seeking to produce a retreat of as a buyer or a
seller in that market.
A direct consequence of extending LR’s approach to three countries is that the model loses its intuitive
and parsimonious results. The model is presented and derived in Appendix 1 the simplest case in
which conflict from to affects only country ’s supply and demand curves. We show that in this
case the optimum level of
is affected by four of the six trade flows in the system: � , � , � ℎ , and
�ℎ (see equations A7 to A10) 8. In each case the sign of the effect depends on an intricate function of
all the parameters in the model and is theoretically ambiguous.
The one-product and three-country case is still a very simplified situation, since countries trade
thousands of products and have almost two hundred potential partners, although a huge proportion of
the product-specific bilateral trade flows are zero. The main patterns shown in Figure 1 still
nonetheless relevant, the problem being how to weigh the importance of each arrow when the whole
range of products and all possible third-countries are taken into account. The next section presents six
measures matching the panels in Figure 1, all of them built as the probability of finding the
corresponding pattern of arrows in the bilateral relation between and .
For country , we call “downstream complementarity of ” (
) the probability of finding a
product imported by given the set of products exported by country , i.e. the probability with which
the arrow in Panel A will exist. Inversely, we compute the “upstream complementarity of ”
(
) as the probability of finding a product exported by given the set of products imported by
country (Panel B). We define as “downstream substitutability of ” (
) the probability of
finding alternative countries that import the different products being exported from to (Panel C),
and “upstream substitutability of ” (
) the probability of finding alternative countries that
export the different products being imported in from (Panel D). Finally, we measure “downstream
rivalry of ” (
) as the probability of finding markets where both and export the same
products (Panel E), and “upstream rivalry of ” (
) as the probability of finding markets from
where both and import the same products (Panel F).
In the next section we propose an operationalization of these variables, and in Section 4 we present our
empirical strategy, including the set of control variables comprised in matrix � � in equation (1),
where the main theoretical explanations of conflict are taken into account. Notably, bilateral imports
and exports variables are encompassed in matrix �.
It can also be shown that in the case of case in which conflict from to affects also country ’s supply and demand curves
the optimum level of
will depend also on � ℎ and �ℎ .
8
7
�
=
+
+
�
+
� + ��
�
� +
+
�
�
+
�
+
�
(1)
From a Polachek’s approach we should expect
< and
< , but given we admit prices can
increase or decrease in each market we could also find
and
. Also, from a liberal point of
view it should be the case that
> and
> since an easier substitution of the trading partner
would mean a lower opportunity cost of conflict, i.e. a less costly outside option. On the contrary, a
realist or Marxist approach would expect
and
since countries would tend to increase
conflict with those partners with which dependency and vulnerability are the highest, in an extreme
case a unique provider/consumer of some strategic good. This last result, together with the direct
effects of exports and imports on conflict, will give an innovative insight over the old liberal peace
debate. We clearly expect
>
and > , and going beyond the liberal peace debate the
significance of the presented coefficients would tell how far trade interests can be seen as a source of
militarized conflict.
3 Complementarity, substitutability, and rivalry
In this section we propose an innovative way of operationalizing these three dimensions in a common
setting. 9
In order to discard irrelevant trade flows, we consider that a country exports a product only in the case
he does it with Revealed Comparative Advantage as proposed by Balassa (1965), i.e. we require the
country to export the product with a weight in his total exports that is larger than the weight of the
product’s trade in total world trade. Thus, for a generic country = , , ℎ, …, and for a specific
product in time , we have an indicator variable such that:
�����
����
∑� ����
=�
∑� ����
∑ ∑
{ � � ����
(2)
}
The same notion is applied for the case of imports, where the dummy for Revealed Comparative
Disadvantage as Importer (Ng and Yeats, 1999) is defined as:
���
Where
���
represents imports of product
���
∑�
=�
∑�
∑� ∑�
{
���
���
���
(3)
}
by country in time .
9
The proposed measures are based on the different country networks taken from Flores and Vaillant (2013) and Flores
(2014), an extension in turn to what Hidalgo, Klinger, Barabási and Hausmann (2007) define as the Product Space.
8
3.1
Complementarity
To measure the extent of complementarity between exports and imports at the bilateral level we will
focus on the existence of comparative advantages and disadvantages. If the importer has a comparative
disadvantage in products in which the exporter has a comparative advantage then we observe some
degree of trade complementarity. For brevity’s sake we will refer to a country exporting a product
when he does it with ��, and the same for the case of importing.
A frequency-of-products approach is used to calculate the probabilities of countries exporting or
importing products (where the index
refers to HS 6-digit products). The downstream
complementarity of , i.e. probability of importing a product that exports, is given by:
=� (
�
� �
= |
��� � = ) =
∑��=
∑��=
� �
��� �
��� �
On the other hand, the upstream complementarity of , i.e. the probability of
imports, is given by:
�
=� (
��� � = |
��
= )=
∑��=
∑��=
���
�
(4)
exporting a product
��
��
(5)
Given these are new measures for complementarity, in Appendix 2 we compare our results with two
other complementarity measures proposed by Anderson and Nordheim (1993) and Michaely (1996).
Comparing product shares in exports and imports, both measures take into account the value of trade
in each good. This is the main difference with the index proposed here, since our trade
complementarity measures respond almost exclusively to changes in the extensive margin of trade
(only reacting to changes in the intensive margin that lead a product to surpass the specific threshold
considered in the definition of the
�s). Results show strong correlations among the three
complementarity measures as well as a stable behavior of our variable during conflict peaks.
3.2
Substitutability
The true opportunity cost of conflict is likely to depend on the ease with which one country can
substitute imports from and export to a belligerent partner with imports from and exports to other
partners. In other words, we need a measure of how dependent each country is on its trade with
potentially belligerent partners. We compute the probability for exporter of finding alternative
destinations for the products exported to ; as well as alternative origins for the products imported
from . Thus, downstream substitutability of is given by the probability of finding a country ℎ =
, … , � importing the products exports to :
�
=� (
�ℎ� |
��� � ,
� �)
=�
�
∑�
ℎ= ∑�=
∑��=
�ℎ�
��� �
��� �
� �
� �
(6)
Analogously, upstream substitutability of is given by the probability of finding a country ℎ exporting
the products imports from :
�
=� (
���ℎ� |
� �,
��� � ) = �
�
∑�
ℎ= ∑�=
∑��=
���ℎ�
��
��
���
�
���
�
(7)
9
The higher the probabilities the easier for country to substitute country as a destination for its
exports or as an origin for its imports.10 Then, both are inverse measures of trade dependency, and
their inclusion in a model for conflict should reflect this strategic dimension of the trading partner for
each of the members of the dyads.
The effects of substitutability on conflict could be subject of debate, being associated with higher
conflict from a liberal approach paying attention to outside options and opportunity costs. Contrarily, a
realist approach would expect higher conflict in the cases of low substitutability, because of risk and
vulnerability reasons. Also, this is related to Carlson’s (1995) observation that a state that can
demonstrate high “cost tolerance” has an advantage in bargaining.
3.3
Rivalry
Finally, we seek to capture rivalry relations in every specific third market. These measures are based
on the probability of country and country coinciding as common exporters or common importers in
any third market ℎ. Even if we name these measures as “rivalry” we have to acknowledge that
coincidence in third markets could increase competition and thus rivalry, or could also reflect greater
cooperation or even participation in global value chains, in which case we would expect that
coincidence fosters peace instead of conflict.
Downstream rivalry with will be given by the probability of exporting a product that exports to ℎ:
�
=� (
��� � |
��� � ,
�ℎ� ) =
�
∑�
��� � ��� �
ℎ= ∑�=
�
�
∑ℎ= ∑�=
��� �
�ℎ�
�ℎ�
(8)
In other words,
� measures the proportion of ’s product-specific destination markets in which
country is also present as a provider of goods. Analogously, upstream rivalry with will be given by
the probability of importing a product that imports from ℎ:11
�
=� (
�
�|
� �,
���ℎ� ) =
�
∑�
ℎ= ∑�=
�
∑�
ℎ= ∑�=
� �
��
��
���ℎ�
���ℎ�
(9)
The role played by different partners in the trade network could also affect the probability of bilateral
conflict. Indeed, the effects of trade on conflict could be very different when the two countries in the
dyad are providers of primary products or when one of them is a provider of primary products and the
other an industrial economy. In other words the proximity of specialization patterns among countries
in the networks could be an important characteristic when evaluating rivalries.
4 Empirical strategy
Equation (1) being a directed model for the level of conflict, its estimation requires the use of a
continuous measure for the level of conflict sent from each country to country each country . The
10
Note that with simple algebraic transformations
� can be expressed in terms of
� , showing that
upstream substitutability of j is the share of the upstream complementarity with j in which j can be replaced by other
providers (and the share is obtained in terms of product-country specific markets). The same occurs with
� , which
can be expressed as a share of
�.
11
Here again, some transformations allow expressing
� as the matching between downstream complementarities of
countries and across third countries, and the same occurs with upstream rivalries.
10
empirical literature tends to use binary and undirected variables of war, or Militarized Interstate
Disputes (MIDs)12, which is constraining both from a theoretical and an empirical point of view.13
Additionally, there are few observations of MIDs in comparison with the pacific dyad-year
observations, so estimation using MIDs could be based in very few particular cases. This problem is
even worse when using war dummies (Lin and Seiglie, 2014).
We use a continuous variable of directed conflict built as proposed in Flores (2016). The variable is
based on event data, i.e. coded information on actions taken by countries (sources) and directed
towards other countries (targets), as reported in international press and newswire agencies cables. The
original event information is taken from GDELT database, and the Goldstein Scale (GS) allows
classifying events as conflict (negative) or cooperation (positive) actions (Goldstein, 1992). Our
conflict variable is then obtained as the yearly sum of (minus) GS scores for conflict events in a
directed pair.
Some additional comments are necessary. Cooperation and conflict are not necessarily the opposite
extremes of a single scale, since a country can simultaneously cooperate and have conflict with a
partner (Pollins, 1989a). Our computation drops purely cooperative actions (events where actors unite
their efforts towards a certain goal, like giving humanitarian or economic aid, sharing intelligence
information or providing military aid), keeping cooperative actions that lead to a de-escalation in
conflict levels (like declaring truce or ceasefire, surrendering, demobilizing armed forces, receiving
peacekeepers or easing military or administrative sanctions). In the same manner, we drop those
conflict events that are just a dismantling of cooperation schemes among actors.
Another distinction done by the GS is between material and verbal actions. We work only with
material actions, and more specifically with a subgroup of military-related events (the detail of the
type of events used is in Appendix 2). This decision is based on our focus on militarized conflict, as it
is the one involving the more serious costs and receiving most theoretical and empirical attention.
Finally, GDELT actors’ dictionary allows identifying official national actors, and we keep only the
events involving this kind of actors. This means we drop all the sub-national or supra-national actors,
as well as non-official national actors. This decision is based on our focus on interstate conflict, and
has the value of comparability with other studies in the field.
For most dyads there are many events in a year, each one with a score given by the Goldstein Scale.
Thus, a whole distribution of GS events’ values is available for each directed dyad-year observation,
and the new conflict variable requires choosing an appropriate summary measure, being the count, the
mean, the median, the maximum and the sum all natural candidates. Given we want to capture both the
extensive and the intensive margins of conflict (variations in the number of events and in its
seriousness, respectively), we work with the sums of GS scores for the events found in each directeddyad-year observation.
12
MIDs are one of the two typical sources of conflict data, the other being events datasets. MIDs are defined as events of
conflict consisting in a “threat, display or use of military force by one state, explicitly directed towards the government,
official representatives, official forces, properties or territories of another state”. The variable has five potential hostility
levels: 1-no militarized action, 2-threat to use force, 3-display of force, 4-use of force, and 5-war. In this context a War is a
MID causing the death of more than 1000 soldiers in battle (Gochman and Maoz, 1984; Jones, Bremer, and Singer 1996).
13
If conflict is seen as an undirected measure then every effort to model the decisions taken by one country will clash with
the impossibility of disentangling each country’s role. On the other hand, the fact of considering conflict as a discrete
phenomenon precludes any consideration of the magnitudes of conflict, forcing to model the determinants of conflict
initiation or conflict duration. Additionally, many empirical specification problems are difficult to treat in the case of a
limited dependent variable, even more in the context of panel data models.
11
Another important challenge for the identification of effects in equation (1) comes from the fact that
aggregate bilateral imports and exports are endogenous in the model. As mentioned, many recent
papers have shown the existence of a deterring effect of conflict on trade, meaning that reverse
causality has to be addressed in order to obtain a consistent estimation. We will follow an instrumental
variable strategy, exploiting an innovative instrument presented in Flores (2016) as synthetic trade
flows.
For each country we first find the � nearest neighbors in terms of economic size, as measured by
similarity in GDP levels. The idea is that countries of similar economic sizes will tend to have similar
bilateral flows with third countries. Thus, a synthetic destination ̃ is the result of averaging �
neighbors of , and once neighbors have been chosen we average aggregate exports from the origin
country to the different destination countries included in the synthetic destination :̃
� �̃� =
�
�
∑�
=
�
(10)
An analogous reasoning applies for imports, where a synthetic origin is built using the same set of ’s
neighbors:
�̃ �
=
�
�
∑
=
�
(11)
These counterfactual flows are used to instrument exports from to the real country and imports in
from the real . We argue that these variables should not be correlated with conflict from to , since
this criterion excludes their bilateral trade, and none of it components should be systematically related
to � . Our instrument would be questionable if e.g. disrupted trade after an increase in ’s conflict
towards was systematically redirected to countries being similar in size with . Even if this can
eventually happen in some cases, our identification strategy relies on the assumption of random
distribution of spillovers among country sizes. In other words, we are supposing that the trade-network
effects of an increase in � to not have any special tendency follow size similarity, so the averaged
neighbors ̃ randomly receive negative, null, and positive effects. Also, risks are minimized when
using enough neighbors to construct the synthetic partners.
Given we analyze the decision in country with respect to every partner we prefer to use synthetic
versions of while using the actual country . Thus, our main instrumental variables will be exports
from to ̃ (exp_synth_d) and imports of from ̃ (imp_synth_o), but we will use also the exports from a
synthetic origin ̃ to the actual country (exp_synth_o) as an additional instrument that allows testing
for overidentification restrictions. As an additional strategy to avoid endogeneity because of
simultaneity, we take two-period lags in all the time-varying explanatory variables.
Endogeneity could be also caused by omitted relevant variables, i.e. unobserved confounders that
could affect both conflict and (lagged) trade patterns. Our approach to tackle this potential problem is
twofold. On the one hand we include a large set of control variables in matrix � � in equation (1),
gathering the main theoretical explanations for conflict. On the other hand we check the robustness of
our results to the inclusion of different kinds of fixed effects, like exporter and importer fixed effects
or exporter and importer time-varying fixed effects.
Regarding the set of control variables in matrix � , like in most of the empirical literature on
international conflict we use a gravity-type specification, where the likelihood of conflict depends on
12
country size and geographic distance (Boulding, 1962; Hegre, 2008).14 Distance is measured by the
distance between capitals (
), and as usual, it is complemented with a contiguity dummy
variable ( _
), signaling the existence of a common border between the two countries.
Geographic variables are taken from CEPII Gravity database. Country sizes are measured with origin
and destination GDPs in current U.S. Dollars (� � and � � ) taken from World Bank’s World
Development Indicators (although other sources had to be used to fill some missing countries
especially relevant for conflict analysis.).
We are including the two typical liberal variables, measuring trade and democracy. Trade is supposed
to measure interdependence, so high current bilateral trade flows mean higher opportunity costs in
case of disruption of trade because of bilateral conflict. The opposing realists approach affirms that
trade intensifies competition and can increase dependence on strategic goods, an argument strongly
related to the substitutability measures included here. Our approach allows testing the significance and
sign of these theoretically loaded coefficients once the main mechanisms linked to the content of the
trade flows have been controlled for. A distinctive feature of our approach is that directedness of the
model allows including separate effects for exports and imports, being thus possible to empirically test
the usual restriction of equal coefficients.15 Exports and imports are measured in current U.S. Dollars
and come from CEPII – BACI database (Gaulier and Zignago, 2010).
Democracy variables are also important, as shown by the extensive literature on the “democratic
peace” hypothesis. Also trade literature has shown that democracies tend to trade more than
autocracies (Russett and Oneal, 2001; Bueno de Mesquita and Lalman 1992; Maoz and Russett, 1993;
Ellis, Mitchell, and Prins, 2010). Joint democracy should be associated to less conflict, since in these
cases disputes are expected to be diplomatically settled, and this pattern has been empirically observed
(Barbieri, 1996; Goenner, 2004; Oneal and Russett, 1999). Finally, some evidence exists on the joint
authoritarian dyads sharing this same pacifying effect (Peceny, Beer, and Sanchez-Terry, 2002). We
use Polity IV data, where the
variable is a combined score of institutionalized democracy and
autocracy in the country, resulting from the subtraction of the autocracy score from the democracy
score. The resulting variables vary in a range from -10 to +10, so we add 11 to the result before taking
logs.
The number of years of peace (years since the end of the last war) has been widely used since Beck,
Katz, and Tucker (1998) recommended to introduce it in a natural cubic spline when estimating a
nonlinear model for a binary dependent variable. As we have a linear model for a continuous variable
we just include the variable
� linearly (and the inclusion of powers of the variable -see
Carter and Signorino (2010) – keep the rest of the results unchanged). We use COW MID database
(version 4.01) to compute the number of cumulated consecutive years of peace since 1816 for each
dyad-year observation.
A final important issue has to do with the existence of internal conflicts or civil wars. Examples of
domestic conflicts that produced interstate wars are abundant, the Arab Spring having added a lot of
14
In a recent opposing view, Keshk, Reuveny, and Pollins (2010) have argued that distance is not important in conflict
models using trade.
15
The operationalization of dependence is an issue of debate: some authors use traded values while others argue in favor of
the ratio of trade over the GDP (or total trade) of the country or countries. We use traded values since some flows can be
perceived as strategically important (or important for some lobbying groups) even if their weight is insignificant in terms of
country’s GDP. Also, as shown by Goldsmith (2013), while GDP shares of bilateral trade can be relevant in the explanation
of conflict onset they are hardly associated to escalation, while traded volumes can have a reasonable role both in conflict
onset and escalation.
13
recent cases. Third countries’ pacifying interventions are just one of the possible mechanisms of this
causal relation, which also can be produced because domestic fights literally cross the border to
contiguous countries, or because important domestic conflicts weaken the state capacity to defend the
country against external attacks and the opportunity may be taken by rivals, to mention some. The
relationship between these two kinds of conflict has been documented (Walt, 1996; Davies, 2002;
Trumbore, 2003; Gleditsch, 2007; Schultz, 2010; Yonamine, 2013), and an extensive research shows
also that internal conflict tends to disrupt trade (Long, 2008; Blomberg and Hess, 2004; Bayer and
Rupert, 2004). In order to measure internal conflict in each country we build a set of variables
completely analogous to the described international conflict variables, based on GDELT data and the
use of the Goldstein scale. The only difference is that in the case of domestic conflict (
�
and
� ) all kinds of domestic actors are taken into account.
Other included variables are typical in the gravity models of trade literature, and we kept them in our
model because of a possible association with conflict. A variable for common religion ( _
� )
is probably the most important one from a theoretical point of view, especially after Huntington
(1996). Nonetheless, Russett, Oneal, and Cox (2000) have found that country-pairs split across
civilizational boundaries are no more likely to engage in conflict than other states. Also, we have
included dummies for having been the same country in the past ( _
) or having ever been in a
common colonial relationship in which case our variables signal whether was the hegemon and the
colony ( _ℎ �_ _ ) or vice-versa ( _ _ _ℎ � ). All these dummy variables are provided by
CEPII gravity datasets.
In sum, the estimable version of equation (1) is:
ln
�
=
+
ln
+ ln
�−
+ ln
+ ln
�−
+ ln � �− + ln
+
�−
+ ln
+ ln
�−
+
ln
�− +
+
_
� +
_
+
_ _ _ℎ � + �
�−
�−
ln �
+
�−
+
+
�−
ln
ln
+ ln �
ln
�−
+
_
+
_ℎ �_ _
�−
+
�−
�−
ln
�−
(12)
A final concern comes from the fact that having a panel structure it is possible to control for
unobserved heterogeneity, assuming that � = � + � is a composite error term including a specific
directed country-pair component.16 In order to control for � we also estimate the model including
country-pair fixed effects, which slightly alters the parameter being identified. While importer and
exporter fixed effects (XMFE), or even importer and exporter time-varying fixed effects (XMTVFE)
preserve the cross-section identification, showing the effects of the regressors on the expected level of
conflict for different dyads, the country-pair fixed effects (CPFE) will lead to identification of a
Within estimator identifying the parameter vector based on time variation for each dyad. In every
estimation we also include year fixed effects.
16
Equation (12) leaves aside some popular variables, like relative power variables or major power dummies (which signal a
few large and powerful countries particularly prone to participate in conflicts). In our econometric specification these timeunvarying country-specific variables will be subsumed within origin and destination fixed effects. Finally, the inclusion of
formal alliances and preferential trade agreements variables is as relevant as problematic, since several papers show a reverse
causality issue, where different kinds of RTA are more probable among potentially conflictive countries (Vicard, 2008;
Martin, Mayer, and Thoenig, 2010).
14
Our database includes 149 countries over the period 1995-2013 (see the list of countries in Appendix
4), which means 22,052 directed country pairs in 19 years.17
5 Results
5.1
Determinants of conflict and the role of trade patterns
The baseline estimations of equation (12) are presented in Table 1, where the first column reports the
OLS results, while the following columns are the IV estimations. We use exports to synthetic
destinations and imports from synthetic origins as instruments for exports and imports, as well as
exports from a synthetic origin in order to test overidentification restrictions. Columns 3 to 5 include
and combine the mentioned fixed effects.
Results clearly show that trade patterns are relevant to explain bilateral militarized conflict. Trade
complementarity positively affects the level of conflict sent against a partner, both when the partner is
evaluated as a provider of imports or as a destination market for exports. By definition, observed trade
flows require complementarity, hence our result means that once actual imports and exports have been
controlled for, the remaining complementarity (e.g. goods exporter by one country and imported by
the other but not traded between them) could bring about higher conflict. These effects are also present
in the within-dyad estimations, meaning that for a given country-pair, an increase in a partner’s
complementarity (both upstream and downstream) will favor higher conflict.
The degree of substitutability of a trade partner has to be interpreted in terms of the liberal notions of
(inverse) exit costs or (direct) outside options. Our results show that the easiest to substitute a partner
the lower the conflict level, or in other words, countries will send higher levels of conflict when their
partners are hard to substitute as imports’ providers or as destination markets. This finding brings
support to the realist approach, showing that countries tend to resort to the use of force in order to deal
with their vulnerabilities. The within-dyad estimator shows that this effect is also important in
choosing the time for a conflict, promoting higher hostility when the partner is more difficult to
substitute.
Downstream rivalries are also significant as a cause of conflict when the cross-section dimension is
considered, telling that dyads selling the same products to the same markets tend to have higher levels
of conflict. However, evidence shows that upstream rivalry does not increase conflict but, instead, is
pacifying. This casts doubts on the adequacy of calling the variable as “rivalry” since in fact shows
how often the two partners meet in third markets. In this regard, when two countries tend to have
similar providers for similar imported products they will be likely to have less conflict between them.
Thus, what we called upstream rivalry could be, in fact, a variable showing different kinds of
similarity (cultural, economic, etc.) between partners. Moreover, this is a purely cross-country effect,
and the within-dyad results show no effects when two countries’ match in upstream markets increase.
Contrarily, when a given dyad start to meet in new downstream markets the level of conflict between
them will decrease.
17
All the estimations are carried out in Stata 14.
15
Table 1
Determinants of International Conflict: Baseline Results
OLS and IV estimations using different fixed effects
OLS
IV
Pooled +
TVXMFE
1.182
1.242***
1.598***
Pooled +
XMFE
0.598*
(second lag in logs)
[0.136]
[0.157]
[0.346]
[1.202]
[0.264]
[3.185]
Downstream complementarity
0.099
1.162***
1.614***
3.441***
0.857***
2.825***
VARIABLES
Upstream complementarity
(second lag in logs)
Upstream substitutability
(second lag in logs)
Downstream substitutability
(second lag in logs)
Upstream rivalry
(second lag in logs)
Downstream rivalary
(second lag in logs)
Exports
(second lag in logs)
Imports
(second lag in logs)
Peace Years
(second lag)
Democracy in origin
(second lag in logs)
Democracy in destination
Pooled
Pooled
Panel
0.677**
[0.095]
[0.129]
[0.198]
[0.600]
[0.119]
[1.093]
-2.614***
-4.060***
-2.490***
-2.284***
-0.780***
-0.968***
[0.357]
[0.278]
[0.303]
[0.273]
[0.387]
[0.217]
-0.572***
-1.107***
-0.891***
-0.837**
-0.434***
0.291
[0.128]
[0.143]
[0.154]
[0.397]
[0.104]
[0.253]
-0.392***
-0.386***
-0.275***
-0.999***
-0.102
-0.432
[0.094]
[0.097]
[0.102]
[0.211]
[0.084]
[0.287]
0.839***
0.139
2.820***
4.987***
-1.309***
-1.417**
[0.091]
[0.109]
[0.115]
[0.167]
[0.129]
[0.568]
0.016***
-0.094***
-0.177***
-0.348***
-0.113***
-0.436*
[0.002]
[0.012]
[0.034]
[0.129]
[0.027]
[0.236]
0.015***
-0.006
0.079**
0.134
0.070**
-0.452**
[0.002]
[0.015]
[0.037]
[0.129]
[0.033]
[0.227]
-0.007***
-0.007***
-0.006***
-0.005***
-0.005***
-0.003**
[0.000]
[0.001]
[0.001]
[0.000]
[0.000]
[0.000]
0.273***
0.440***
-0.120***
-0.119***
[0.017]
[0.023]
[0.027]
[0.026]
0.075***
0.178***
-0.155***
-0.152***
(second lag in logs)
[0.018]
[0.022]
[0.029]
[0.027]
GDP in origin
0.160***
0.314***
0.081***
0.048**
(second lag in logs)
GDP in destination
(second lag in logs)
Domestic conflict in origin
(second lag in logs)
Domestic conflict in destination
(second lag in logs)
Distance
Panel +
TVXMFE
8.712***
[0.005]
[0.013]
[0.021]
[0.019]
0.079***
0.185***
-0.046***
0.046***
[0.005]
[0.013]
[0.018]
[0.016]
0.362***
0.358***
0.304***
0.296***
[0.008]
[0.008]
[0.008]
[0.007]
0.405***
0.403***
0.286***
0.287***
[0.007]
[0.008]
[0.007]
-0.655***
-0.818***
-0.827***
[0.007]
-0.944***
(in logs)
[0.011]
[0.018]
[0.035]
[0.082]
Border
0.866***
0.988***
1.022***
1.064***
[0.059]
[0.061]
[0.064]
[0.078]
Common religion
0.072***
0.120***
0.069***
0.089***
[0.015]
[0.016]
[0.016]
[0.022]
Same country in the past
-0.463***
-0.262***
-0.226**
-0.143
[0.083]
[0.085]
[0.088]
[0.114]
Hegemon-to-colony
1.169***
1.283***
1.017***
1.123***
[0.110]
[0.115]
[0.119]
[0.140]
Colony-to-hegemon
1.004***
1.114***
0.991***
1.103***
[0.114]
[0.116]
[0.115]
[0.134]
Observations
Time FE
Origin & Destination FE
Origin & Destination TVFE
Country-Pair FE
Hansen J p-value
Underidentification K-P p-value
Weak Identif. K-P F Statistic
Weak Identif CD F Statistic
372,910
YES
NO
NO
NO
372,910
YES
NO
NO
NO
0
0
399.8
1501
372,910
YES
YES
NO
NO
0.231
0
59.93
159.9
372,910
NO
NO
YES
NO
0.396
0.0002
5.670
18.18
372,910
YES
NO
NO
YES
0.267
0
76.70
147.2
372,910
NO
NO
YES
YES
0.676
0.0141
2.799
6.059
Pair-clustered standard errors in brackets. Results obtained using ivreg2 (Baum, Schaffer, and Stillman, 2010) and reghdfe (Correia, 2015).
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
16
To test our instruments’ performance we run overidentification tests checking if excluded instruments
are distributed independently of the error term, i.e. they are valid instruments. This is done using the
Sargan-Hansen J statistic, reported for every result in Table 1 (note that a rejection indicates that the
instruments have been improperly excluded from the regression model). Additionally, being identified
by the order and rank conditions, with weak instruments an equation may be effectively unidentified in
a finite sample, so we need to test for the weakness of the instruments in our context even if we now
that first stage F-tests are significant at the usual levels (Staiger and Stock, 1997). In each case we will
also report under-identification tests as well as weak instruments tests, showing the instruments have a
reasonably good performance in the model. 18 These results are robust to the use of different lags or
event current values of time-varying explanatory variables, as shown in Table A5.1 in Appendix 5.
In sum, the full set of six trade-pattern variables say that countries evaluate their partners both as
importers and exporters of different kinds of goods, having higher conflict with complementary
partners, with countries with which trade is difficult to substitute, and with downstream rivals, while
coincidence in provider markets tends to be pacifying.
The effects of aggregate values of imports and exports are also theoretically relevant results, and we
obtain opposite effects of exports and imports on conflict, verifying the findings presented by Flores
(2016). Countries tend to have higher levels of conflict with the origins of their imports and lower
levels with the destinations of their exports. This seems to reflect a mercantilist approach on trade
balance, since � −
would be the true figure orienting leaders’ decisions, instead of the liberal
peace hypothesis of aggregate trade in both directions � +
as the critical variable to be considered.
Other control variables have the expected signs and tend to be significant. The gravity forces are at
work with the expected signs for distance (negative) and border (positive). Democracy variables show
the usual pacifying effect (at least for the preferred specifications including some kind of fixed
effects): democracies tend to have lower conflict levels with others and receive lower conflict from
them. Domestic conflict is, as expected, associated with a higher level of interstate conflict. A
common religion has a positive effect, a surprising result that requires further investigation. Finally,
countries that shared colonial relationships, currently or in the past, tend to have more conflict, while
countries that have been the same country in the past tend to be relatively peaceful to each other.
5.2
Frequency and intensity of conflict
Some dyads can have few actions of conflict with a very high hostility level; while others can maintain
very frequent low-intensity actions for long periods. So far we considered the volume of conflict for
each dyad-year observation, adding the scores of every action occurred in the period. This measure
ignores the composition of conflict in terms of frequency of events and importance of the actions.
Table 2 shows that the main conclusions obtained for the volume of conflict hold for the frequency
(count of events of pure conflict minus count of events of de-escalation) and the intensity (mean of GS
scores for the observed events). The same set of instruments is used for these new IV estimations, and
their performance stills acceptable.
18
We test for weak instruments using Cragg-Donald Wald F statistics as well as Kleibergen-Paap rk Wald F statistic. In both
cases the null hypothesis is that instruments are weak, and both tests allow for the presence of non-i.i.d. errors. We use Stock
and Yogo (2005) critical values.
17
Table 2
Determinants of the frequency and intensity of conflict
IV estimations using different fixed effects
VARIABLES
Upstream complementarity
(second lag in logs)
Downstream complementarity
(second lag in logs)
Upstream substitutability
(second lag in logs)
Downstream substitutability
(second lag in logs)
Upstream rivalry
(second lag in logs)
Downstream rivalry
(second lag in logs)
Exports
Volume of events
Pooled +
Panel
TVXMFE
1.182
0.677**
Frequency of events
Pooled +
Panel
TVXMFE
1.977**
0.555***
Intensity of events
Pooled +
Panel
TVXMFE
-2.323***
0.043
[1.202]
[0.264]
[0.819]
[0.173]
[0.645]
[0.143]
3.441***
0.857***
2.501***
0.432***
0.664**
0.485***
[0.600]
[0.119]
[0.411]
[0.074]
[0.318]
[0.067]
-2.284***
-0.780***
-1.569***
-0.485***
-0.703***
-0.472***
[0.387]
[0.217]
[0.273]
[0.136]
[0.225]
[0.119]
-0.837**
-0.434***
-0.748***
-0.264***
0.067
-0.350***
[0.397]
[0.104]
[0.271]
[0.066]
[0.214]
[0.058]
-0.999***
-0.102
-0.782***
0.004
-0.138
-0.187***
[0.211]
[0.084]
[0.146]
[0.054]
[0.113]
[0.048]
4.987***
-1.309***
3.592***
-0.538***
1.120***
-0.902***
[0.167]
[0.129]
[0.120]
[0.088]
[0.084]
[0.067]
-0.348***
-0.113***
-0.234***
-0.067***
-0.122*
-0.053***
(second lag in logs)
[0.129]
[0.027]
[0.088]
[0.017]
[0.068]
[0.016]
Imports
0.134
0.070**
0.009
0.042**
0.251***
0.032*
(second lag in logs)
Peace Years
(second lag)
[0.129]
[0.033]
[0.088]
[0.020]
[0.069]
[0.019]
-0.005***
-0.005***
-0.004***
-0.005***
-0.001***
0.001***
[0.001]
[0.000]
[0.001]
[0.000]
[0.000]
-0.119***
Democracy in origin
(second lag in logs)
-4.494***
[0.000]
-1.994***
[0.026]
[0.858]
[0.700]
-0.152***
-5.845***
-3.482***
(second lag in logs)
[0.027]
[0.912]
[0.694]
GDP in origin
0.048**
0.013
0.044***
[0.019]
[0.012]
[0.011]
0.046***
0.016
0.055***
Democracy in destination
(second lag in logs)
GDP in destination
(second lag in logs)
Domestic conflict in origin
(second lag in logs)
Domestic conflict in destination
(second lag in logs)
Distance
[0.016]
[0.010]
[0.009]
0.296***
0.209***
0.081***
[0.007]
[0.005]
[0.003]
0.287***
0.204***
0.077***
[0.007]
-0.944***
[0.005]
-0.692***
[0.003]
-0.147***
(in logs)
[0.082]
[0.055]
[0.045]
Border
1.064***
0.788***
0.192***
[0.078]
[0.057]
[0.033]
Common religion
0.089***
0.054***
0.029**
Same country in the past
[0.022]
[0.015]
[0.011]
-0.143
-0.106
-0.108**
[0.114]
[0.081]
[0.055]
Hegemon-to-colony
1.123***
0.879***
0.116**
[0.140]
[0.103]
[0.054]
Colony-to-hegemon
1.103***
0.847***
0.152***
Observations
Time FE
Origin & Destination FE
Origin & Destination TVFE
Country-Pair FE
Hansen J p-value
Underidentification K-P p-value
Weak Identif. K-P F Statistic
Weak Identif CD F Statistic
372,910
NO
NO
YES
NO
0.396
0.0002
5.670
18.18
[0.134]
[0.098]
372,910
YES
NO
NO
YES
0.267
0
76.70
147.2
372,910
NO
NO
YES
NO
0.323
0.0002
5.670
18.18
[0.048]
372,910
YES
NO
NO
YES
0.450
0
76.66
147.1
372,910
NO
NO
YES
NO
0.973
0.0002
5.670
18.18
372,910
YES
NO
NO
YES
0.0851
0
76.66
147.1
Pair-clustered standard errors in brackets. Results obtained using ivreg2 (Baum, Schaffer, and Stillman, 2010) and reghdfe (Correia, 2015).
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
18
Results for the frequency and intensity of actions are remarkably similar to those shown for the
volume of conflict in Table 1, partially reproduced in the first two columns of Table 2. The main
difference is the effect of upstream complementarity, where the positive impact on volumes can now
be seen as two opposing effects: when a partner is more complementary as a provider the frequency of
conflict events significantly increases while their intensity is significantly lower.
We performed a set of robustness checks extending the definition of conflict in our variable, taking the
sums of GS scores for verbal actions (in addition to the material actions considered as far), and for
non-official actors (in addition to the official actors considered as far). Table A5.2 in Appendix 5
shows that with slight variations in coefficients’ values, and almost no variation in significance levels,
it is possible to assert our results are robust to the kind of actions and actors considered.
Frequency and intensity of events are two different components of the volume of conflict. However,
our results for complementarity, substitutability and rivalry effects could be biased due to the
existence of a large proportion of country-pairs where the volume of conflict is null.
5.3
Extensive and intensive margins in conflict
A censoring problem is prevalent in our data, since 73% of the country-pairs in the sample have zero
conflict. Estimation methods for limited or censored dependent variables in panel data have several
limitations in the context of endogenous regressors, so in this section we briefly explore whether
important differences exist in the role of our trade patterns variables when modeling the binary
variable of existence of any degree of positive conflict (with a Linear Probability Model) and when
modeling the level of conflict in uncensored observations. Additionally, to address the potential
existence of unobserved effect causing correlation between the error terms in the selection equation
and the equation in levels, we estimate a Heckman’s selection model for the pooled samples.
Results show that no substantive difference exists in the role of our main variables when explaining
the discrete existence of positive conflict or when explaining the level of conflict in the restricted
sample. In both cases all the significant coefficients have the same sign than in previous results.
19
Table 3
Zero conflict and selection
IV estimations using different fixed effects
VARIABLES
Upstream complementarity
(second lag in logs)
Downstream complementarity
(second lag in logs)
Upstream substitutability
Linear Probability
Model
Pooled +
Panel
TVXMFE
-0.718***
0.003
Restricted sample:
positive conflict
Pooled +
Panel
TVXMFE
0.948
-0.354
Heckman's selection
model
Pooled +
Pooled +
XMFE
TVXMFE
-0.841
2.283
[0.268]
[0.063]
[1.327]
[0.569]
[0.584]
[1.735]
0.425***
0.217***
2.665***
-0.155
1.215***
2.425***
[0.133]
[0.030]
[0.538]
[0.290]
[0.287]
[0.483]
-0.329***
-0.170***
-2.161***
-1.485***
-2.680***
-2.272***
(second lag in logs)
[0.091]
[0.053]
[0.749]
[0.522]
[0.539]
[0.723]
Downstream substitutability
-0.016
-0.102***
-1.719**
0.251
0.224
-1.533**
(second lag in logs)
Upstream rivalry
(second lag in logs)
Downstream rivalry
(second lag in logs)
Exports
(second lag in logs)
Imports
(second lag in logs)
Peace Years
(second lag)
Democracy in origin
(second lag in logs)
Democracy in destination
[0.089]
[0.025]
[0.684]
[0.246]
[0.322]
[0.701]
-0.100**
-0.050**
-0.928***
0.166
-0.245
-0.902***
[0.047]
[0.021]
[0.247]
[0.171]
[0.154]
[0.233]
0.615***
-0.408***
2.108***
-0.056
1.748***
2.416***
[0.035]
[0.030]
[0.226]
[0.237]
[0.161]
[0.204]
-0.059**
-0.023***
-0.260***
-0.012
-0.169***
-0.222**
[0.029]
[0.007]
[0.088]
[0.061]
[0.049]
[0.088]
0.088***
0.015*
0.108
0.116
0.219***
-0.001
[0.029]
[0.008]
[0.112]
[0.075]
[0.062]
[0.145]
-0.000***
0.000***
-0.003***
-0.002**
-0.003***
-0.003***
[0.000]
[0.000]
[0.000]
[0.001]
[0.000]
[0.000]
-0.213***
-0.173***
-0.104***
[0.019]
[0.045]
[0.049]
0.114***
-0.423***
-0.294***
(second lag in logs)
[0.014]
[0.046]
[0.048]
GDP in origin
0.018***
-0.022
-0.047
(second lag in logs)
[0.005]
[0.043]
[0.043]
GDP in destination
-0.032
-0.039
-0.086***
(second lag in logs)
Domestic conflict in origin
(second lag in logs)
Domestic conflict in destination
(second lag in logs)
[0.023]
[0.033]
[0.033]
0.092***
0.126***
0.162***
[0.025]
[0.012]
[0.009]
0.113***
0.135***
0.163***
[0.022]
[0.013]
[0.012]
Distance
-0.449
-0.752***
-0.480***
(in logs)
[0.314]
[0.076]
[0.023]
[0.026]
Border
-0.830***
0.513***
0.405***
0.500***
[0.311]
[0.063]
[0.048]
[0.060]
Common religion
0.018***
0.063**
0.008
0.017
[0.005]
[0.025]
[0.019]
[0.022]
0.018***
-0.022
-0.183**
-0.069
[0.004]
[0.094]
[0.085]
[0.085]
Hegemon-to-colony
0.039***
0.674***
0.471***
0.632***
[0.002]
[0.106]
[0.085]
[0.094]
Colony-to-hegemon
0.038***
0.691***
0.497***
0.622***
[0.001]
[0.095]
Same country in the past
Heckman's Lambda
Observations
Time FE
Origin & Destination FE
Origin & Destination TVFE
Country-Pair FE
Hansen J p-value
Underidentification K-P p-value
Weak Identif. K-P F Statistic
Weak Identif CD F Statistic
372,910
NO
NO
YES
NO
0.509
0.0002
5.670
18.18
372,910
YES
NO
NO
YES
0.361
0
76.66
147.1
102,942
NO
NO
YES
NO
0.292
2.18e-07
9.885
27.39
100,041
YES
NO
NO
YES
0.694
0
17.03
52.83
-0.596***
[0.075]
[0.085]
-0.005
-0.036**
[0.005]
[0.017]
102,860
YES
YES
NO
NO
0.794
0
26.66
73.34
102,847
NO
NO
YES
NO
0.395
6.93e-05
6.134
16.10
Pair-clustered standard errors in brackets. Results obtained using ivreg2 (Baum, Schaffer, and Stillman, 2010) and reghdfe (Correia, 2015). ***
p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
20
6 Conclusions
This paper seeks to exploit two underemployed dimensions of trade flows in the assessment of the role
of trade relations on interstate conflict. On one hand we have detailed information about the products
being traded among countries, and on the other hand we know the whole structure of the international
trade network. The main purpose of the preceding sections has been to combine these two dimensions
to characterize some relevant dimensions of each trade flow.
The theoretical background for our approach is based on an extension of Li and Reuveny’s (2011)
expected utility model, a partial equilibrium analysis for the two-country case. The extension to the
three-country case allows considering new channels through which a country could gain or lose when
increasing the level of conflict sent towards a country . A direct consequence of extending LR’s
approach to three countries is that the model loses its intuitive and parsimonious results, giving rise to
a complex system of equations where every supply and demand in each market could be affected by an
increase of conflict from to . However, we are able to identify three specific mechanisms through
which country could have commercial gains or reduce his losses when increasing conflict against .
Firstly, if more peace (or more conflict) allows increasing trade, it is relevant to know the scope of
potential trade between the two countries, which we measured with complementarity variables.
Secondly, could be substitutable as a trade partner, which in the extreme case of perfect
substitutability will reduce bilateral losses to zero. Thirdly, conflict against could be oriented to
collecting benefits in third countries because of a withdrawal of from that market.
Our main results show that countries evaluate their partners both as importers and exporters of
different kinds of goods, having higher conflict with complementary partners, with countries with
which trade is difficult to substitute, and with downstream rivals, while coincidence in provider
markets tends to be pacifying.
21
References
Anderson K, Nordheim H, 1993. From imperial to regional trade preferences: Its effects on Europe's
intra and extra-regional trade. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 129(1): 78-101.
Balassa BA, 1965. Trade Liberalization and 'Revealed' Comparative Advantage. The Manchester
School of Economic and Social Studies, 33(2): 99-123.
Baldwin DA, 1980. Interdependence and power: A conceptual analysis. International Organization,
34(4): 471-506.
Barbieri K, 1996. Economic interdependence: A path to peace or a source of interstate conflict?
Journal of Peace Research, 33(1): 29-49.
Barbieri K, 2002. The liberal illusion. Does trade promote peace? The University of Michigan, Ann
Arbor Press.
Baum CF, Schaffer ME, Stillman S, 2010. IVREG2: Stata module for extended instrumental
variables/2SLS,
GMM
and
AC/HAC,
LIML
and
k-class
regression.
http://ideas.repec.org/c/boc/bocode/s425401.html
Bayer R, Rupert MC, 2004. Effects of civil wars on international trade, 1950-92. Journal of Peace
Research, 41(6): 699-713.
Beck N, Katz JN, Tucker R, 1998. Taking time seriously: TS-CS Analysis with a binary dependent
variable. American Journal of Political Science 42(4): 1260-1288.
Blanchard JMF, Ripsman NM, 1996. Measuring economic interdependence: A geopolitical
perspective. Geopolitics, 1(3): 225-246.
Blomberg SB, Hess GD, 2004. How much does violence tax trade? CESifo Working Paper, No. 1222.
Boulding KE, 1962. Conflict and defense: A general theory. New York: Harper & Brothers.
Bueno de Mesquita B, Lalman D, 1992. War and reason: Domestic and international imperatives. New
Heaven: Yale University Press.
Carlson L, 1995. A theory of escalation and international conflict. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 39:
511-534.
Carter DB, Signorino CS, 2010. Back to the future: Modeling time dependence in binary data.
Political Analysis, 18(3): 271-292.
Choucri N, North RC, 1975. Nations in Conflict: National Growth and International Violence. San
Francisco: W.H. Freeman & Co.
Correia S, 2015. REGHDFE: Stata module to perform linear or instrumental-variable regression
absorbing
any
number
of
high-dimensional
fixed
effects.
https://ideas.repec.org/c/boc/bocode/s457874.html
Davies GAM, 2002. Domestic strife and the initiation of international conflicts. A directed dyad
analysis, 1950-1982. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46(5): 672-692.
22
Dorussen H, 2006. Heterogeneous trade interests and conflict: What you trade matters. Journal of
Conflict Resolution, 50(1): 87-107.
Ellis G, Mitchell SM, Prins BC, 2010. How democracies keep the peace: Contextual factors that
influence conflict management strategies. Foreign Policy Analysis, 6(4): 373-398.
Flores M, 2014. Asimetrías en el modelo gravitatorio de comercio: Una reconsideración empleando el
espacio de países. Unpublished. Master Thesis, Universidad de la República, Uruguay.
Flores M, 2016. Love the buyer and loathe the seller: A directed approach on trade and conflict,
Mimeo.
Flores M, Vaillant M, 2013. Geographic nature of trade specialization: Economic distance in the
country space. Paper presented at the Arnoldshain Seminar XI, University of Antwerp, Belgium, June.
Gartzke E, Li Q, 2003. All's well that ends well. A reply to Oneal, Barbieri & Peters. Journal of Peace
Research, 40(6): 727–732.
Gasiorowski M, 1986. Economic interdependence and international conflict: Some cross-national
evidence. International Studies Quarterly, 30(1): 23-38.
Gaulier G, Zignago S, 2010. BACI: International Trade Database at the Product-Level. The 1994-2007
Version. Document de Travail du CEPII, Vol 2010-23.
Gleditsch KS, 2007. Transnational dimensions of civil war. Journal of Peace Research, 44(3): 712–
724.
Gochman CS, Maoz Z, 1984. Militarized interstate disputes, 1816-1976. Procedures, patterns, and
insights. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 28(4): 585-616.
Goenner CF, 2004. Uncertainty of the liberal peace. Journal of Peace Research, 41(5): 589-605.
Goenner CF, 2010. From toys to warships: Interdependence and the effects of disaggregated trade on
militarized disputes. Journal of Peace Research, 47(5): 547-559.
Goldsmith BE, 2013. International trade and the onset and escalation of interstate conflict: More to
fight about, or more reasons not to fight? Defence and Peace Economics, 24(6): 555-578.
Goldstein JS, 1992. A Conflict-Cooperation Scale for WEIS Events Data. Journal of Conflict
Resolution, 36: 369-385.
Hegre H, 2008. Gravitating toward war. Preponderance may pacify, but power kills. Journal of
Conflict Resolution, 52(4): 566-589.
Hidalgo CA, Klinger B, Barabási AL, Hausmann R, 2007. The product space conditions the
development of nations. Science, 317(5837): 482-487.
Homer-Dixon TF, 1999. Environment, scarcity, and violence. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Press.
Huntington SP, 1996. The clash of civilizations? Foreign Affairs, 72(3).
Jones DM, Bremer SA, Singer JD, 1996. Militarized interstate disputes 1816-1992. Rationale, coding
rules and empirical pattern. Conflict Management and Peace Science, 15(2): 163-213.
23
Keohane RO, Nye JS, 1977. Power and interdependence. World politics in transition. Boston: VS
Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.
Keshk OMG, Pollins BM, Reuveny R, 2004. Trade still follows the flag. The primacy of politics in a
simultaneous model of intedependence and armed conflict. The Journal of Politics, 66(4): 1155-1179.
Keshk OMG, Reuveny R, Pollins BM, 2010. Trade and conflict: Proximity, country size and
measures. Conflict Management and Peace Science, 27(1): 13-27.
Kim HM, Russeau DL, 2005. The classical liberals were half right (or half wrong): New tests of the
'liberal peace', 1960-1988. Journal of Peace Research, 42(5): 523-543.
Koubi V, Spilker G, Bohmelt T, Bernauer T, 2014. Do natural resources matter for interstate and
intrastate conflict? Journal of Peace Research, 52: 227-243.
Li Q, Reuveny R, 2011. Does trade prevent or promote interstate conflict initiation? Journal of Peace
Research, 48(4): 437-453.
Lin SY, Seiglie C, 2014. Same evidences, different interpretations -A comparison of the conflict index
between the interstate dyadic events data and militarized interstate disputes data in peace-conflict
models. Peace Economics, Peace Science, and Public Policy, 54(4): 421-433.
Long AG, 2008. Bilateral trade in the shadow of armed conflict. International Studies Quarterly, 52:
81-101.
Mansfield ED, Pevehouse JC, 2000. Trade blocs, trade flows and international conflict. International
Organization, 54(4): 775–808.
Maoz Z, Russett BM, 1993. Normative and Structural Causes of Democratic Peace 1946-1986.
American Political Science Review, 87(3), 624-638.
Martin P, Mayer T, Thoenig M, 2010. The geography of conflicts and regional trade agreements.
American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 4(4): 1-35.
Michaely M, 1996. Trade preferential agreements in Latin America: An ex ante assessment. World
Bank Policy Research Working Paper, No. 1583.
Ng F, Yeats A, 1999. Production Sharing in East Asia. Who Does What for Whom and Why? World
Bank Policy Research Working Paper, October, Issue 2197: 1-57.
Oneal JR, Oneal FH, Maoz Z, Russett BM, 1996. The liberal peace: Interdepence, democracy, and
international conflict, 1950-1985. Journal of Peace Research, 33(1): 11-28.
Oneal JR, Russett BM, 1997. The classical liberals were right. Democracy, interdependence and
conflict, 1950-1985. International Studies Quarterly, 41(2): 267-294.
Oneal JR, Russett BM, 1999. Assessing the liberal peace with alternative specifications. Trade still
reduces conflict. Journal of Peace Research, 36(4): 423-442.
Oneal JR, Russett BM, Berbaum ML, 2003. Causes of peace. Democracy, interdependence, and IGOs,
1885-1992. International Studies Quarterly, 47(3): 371-393.
Peceny M, Beer CC, Sanchez-Terry S, 2002. Dictatorial peace?. The American Political Science
Review, 96(1): 15-26.
24
Peterson TM, Thies CG, 2012. Beyond Ricardo. The link between intra-industry trade and peace.
British Journal of Political Science, 42(4): 747-767.
Polachek SW, 1980. Conflict and trade. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 24(1): 55-78.
Polachek SW, 1992. Conflict and trade. An economics approach to political international interactions.
In W. Isard and C.H. Anderton, eds. Economics of Arms Reduction and the Peace Process. New York:
Elsevier Science. pp. 89-120.
Polachek SW, 1997. Why democracies cooperate more and fight less. The relationship between
international trade and cooperation. Review of International Economics, 5(3): 295-309.
Polachek SW, Robst J, Chang YC, 1999. Liberalism and interdependence: Extending the trade-conflict
model. Journal of Peace Research, 36(4): 405-422.
Pollins BM, 1989. Conflict, cooperation, and commerce: The effect of international political
interactions on bilateral trade flows. American Journal of Political Science, 33(3): 737-761.
Pollins BM, 1989. Does trade still follow the flag? American Political Science Review, 83(2): 465480.
Reuveny R, 2001. Bilateral import, export, and conflict/cooperation simultaneity. International Studies
Quarterly, 45(1): 131-158.
Reuveny R, Kang H, 1998. Bilateral trade and political conflict/cooperation: Do goods matter? Journal
of Peace Research, 35(5): 581-602.
Robst J, Polachek SW, Chang YC, 2007. Geographic proximity, trade, and international
conflict/cooperation. Conflict Management and Peace Science, 24(1).
Russett BM, Oneal JR, 2001. Triangulating peace. Democracy, interdependence and IGOs. The
Norton Series in World Politics, New York.
Russett BM, Oneal JR, Cox M, 2000. Clash of civilizations, or realism and liberalism déja vu? Some
evidence. Journal of Peace Research, 37(5): 583-608.
Schultz K, 2010. The enforcement problem in coercive bargaining: Interstate conflict over rebel
support in civil wars. Defense Economics, 13(1): 215–243.
Staiger D, Stock JH, 1997. Instrumental variables regression with weak instruments. Econometrica,
65(3): 557-586.
Stock JH, Yogo M, 2005. Testing for weak instruments in linear IV regression. In Andrews DWK
Identification and Inference for Econometric Models. New York: Cambridge University Press
Trumbore PF, 2003. Victims or Aggressors? Ethno‐Political Rebellion and Use of Force in Militarized
Interstate Disputes. International Studies Quarterly, 47(2): 183-201.
Vicard V, 2008. Trade, conflict, and political integration: Explaining the heterogeneity of regional
trade agreements. European Economic Review, 56(1): 54–71.
Walt SM, 1996. Revolution and War. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
25
Waltz KN, 1979. Theory of International Politics. Addison-Wesley series in Political Science.
Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley Pub. Co.
Yonamine JE, 2013. The effects of domestic conflict on interstate conflict: An event data analysis of
monthly level onset and intensity. Mimeo.
26
Appendix 1: Three-country version of the LR model
Country ’s maximization problem is:
,
. .
ℎ
,
�
=∑
,
ℎ
�
�� ∙ ��� − �� ∙ ��� + ∑
�=
(A1)
�=
�� ℎ ∙ ��� ℎ − ��ℎ ∙ ���ℎ
The solution of this maximization problem can be found maximizing the Lagrangian ℒ with respect to
, ℎ , and the shadow price of the trade surplus constraint �:
ℒ=
(
,
,
The three first order conditions are:
�ℒ
=
�
�ℒ
=
� ℎ
�
+ � [∑
�=
ℎ
�ℒ
= [−
��
�
+ � [∑
�
�=
+∑
�=
��
��
ℎ)
+ � [−
+∑
�
=
+∑
�
ℎ
�
=
∙ ��
�
ℎ
∙ ��
−�
ℎ
−�
∙ ��
ℎ
]
∙ ��
����
����
���� ℎ
����ℎ
]=
− ��
+ �� ℎ
− ��ℎ
�
�
�
�
����
����
���� ℎ
����ℎ
]=
− ��
+ �� ℎ
− ��ℎ
� ℎ
� ℎ
� ℎ
� ℎ
�
�� ��� − �� ��� + ∑
�=
�� ℎ ��� ℎ − ��ℎ ���ℎ ] =
(A2)
(A3)
(A4)
(A5)
The usual economic interpretation of these first order conditions apply, and the detail for (A3) can be
found in Li and Reuveny (2011) online appendix.
The computation of comparative statistics of the first order condition in
will give, after some
rearrangements and simplifications, the partial derivatives of
with respect to exports and imports of
a specific good ̃ , the market in which we will analyze partial equilibrium results. To proceed we need
to obtain the four partial derivatives of (�ℒ⁄� ) with respect to ��̃ , ��̃ , ��̃ ℎ , and ��̃ℎ :
Starting with the comparative statics with respect to ��̃ , we have:
�
����̃
+�[
���̃
�
� ��� �
� ��� �
� ��� ℎ �
+ ��
+ �� ℎ
�
�
��
�
�
��
�
� ���̃
�=
�̃
�̃
� ���ℎ �
]=
+ ��ℎ
� � ���̃
�
+∑
And rearranging:
�
=
���̃
��
+ � ∑��= (��
� ���
� �
����̃
−� �
� ���
� ��� ℎ
� ���ℎ
+ ��
+ �� ℎ
+ ��ℎ
)
� �
� �
� �
(A6)
(A7)
27
For country the effect of exports to on conflict to depends on how conflict affects the price of
exports from to , and also on how
affects the other prices relevant for country .
In an analogous manner we compute the other three comparative statics.
�
=
���̃
�
=
���̃ ℎ
�
=
���̃ℎ
+ � ∑��= (��
� ���
� �
+ � ∑��= (��
� ���
� �
+ � ∑��= (��
� ���
� �
����̃
−� �
� ���
� ��� ℎ
� ���ℎ
+ ��
+ �� ℎ
+ ��ℎ
)
� �
� �
� �
����̃ ℎ
−� �
� ���
� ��� ℎ
� ���ℎ
+ ��
+ �� ℎ
+ ��ℎ
)
� �
� �
� �
����̃ℎ
−� �
� ���
� ��� ℎ
� ���ℎ
+ ��
+ �� ℎ
+ ��ℎ
)
� �
� �
� �
(A8)
(A9)
(A10)
Assuming that every bilateral market is independent from the others, most of the second derivatives
included in the comparative statics equations would be null, except for the one that gathers de effect
�2� �
�
on the export price in the same direction than the conflict under study (�
in equations A7 to A10).
However, once bilateral demands and supplies are assumed to reflect what happens in other bilateral
relations for the same product, the remaining second order derivatives are no longer null.
In the following system of linear demands and supplies for all the possible bilateral markets among
three countries importing and exporting a product , we assume that each country has a linear supply
function for exports which is specific for each destination market and, analogously, each country has a
linear demand function for imports specific for each origin country. As usual, demand and supply
functions depend on the relevant prices and on incomes ( , ). Also, we assume that every function is
shifted to the left by an increase in the conflict the own country has against the partner (meaning that
the effect of received conflict from the partner is restricted to be zero). Finally, all demands and
supplies are residual functions, meaning that the supply to a particular partner is what remains after
sales to the third country.
��� =
�� =
��� ℎ
=
�� ℎ =
�
��ℎ
=
��ℎ =
��� ℎ
��
ℎ
=
=
�
��ℎ
=
��ℎ =
���
=
�� =
+
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
−
+
−
+
−
+
−
+
−
+
−
��� +
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
��� +
��� ℎ +
��� ℎ +
���ℎ +
���ℎ +
���
���
ℎ
ℎ
+
+
���ℎ +
���ℎ +
��� +
��� +
−
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
−
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
−
−
−
−
−
−
−
−
−
−
−
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
−
−
−
ℎ
ℎ
−
ℎ
−
ℎ
−
ℎ −
ℎ
ℎ
−
−
−
−
�� ℎ
��ℎ
��
ℎ
��
ℎ
ℎ
��ℎ
��
(A11)
��
ℎ
ℎ
�� ℎ
��ℎ
��
��
ℎ
��ℎ
28
From this system, a price equation for every flow can be obtained:
��� =
��� ℎ =
���ℎ =
���
ℎ
+
ℎ
=
���ℎ =
��� =
ℎ
(
+
ℎ
+
ℎ
+
+
(
ℎ
(
ℎ
(
(
(
+
−
−
+
−
ℎ
−
ℎ
−
−
+
ℎ
+
ℎ
+
+
ℎ
−
−
−
ℎ
−
ℎ
−
ℎ
+
+
−
+
ℎ
+
ℎ
+
ℎ
+
ℎ
ℎ
−
ℎ
−
ℎ
−
ℎ
−
ℎ
ℎ
+
ℎ
−
ℎ
ℎ
−
ℎ
−
��ℎ +
ℎ
−
−
��
ℎ
+
�� +
ℎ
−
−
�� ℎ +
�� +
−
��ℎ +
�� ℎ )
(A12)
ℎ
��ℎ )
(A14)
��ℎ )
(A16)
ℎ
�� )
(A13)
�� )
(A15)
(A17)
�� ℎ )
This new system shows how an increase in conflict from to will produce changes in prices of other
trade flows. Direct effects are reflected in equations (A12) and (A17) respectively shifting supply for
exports to country and demand for imports from country to the left. The reduction in quantities ��
will in turn make country to offer more to country ℎ (A13) and country to demand more from
country ℎ (A14). Thus, ��� ℎ will fall while ���ℎ will rise. On the other hand, the reduction in
quantities �� will shift to the right the demand of country for products form country ℎ (A16) and
the supply of exports from country to country ℎ (A15), producing an increase in ���ℎ and a decline
in ��� ℎ .
Going back to the maximization problem in country , only the four effects involving are relevant,
and these are the terms involved in the derivatives of equations (A7) to (A10). The algebraic
expressions for these derivatives require finding the general equilibrium solution of the following
system of equations:
+
�� =
�� ℎ =
��ℎ =
��
ℎ
=
��ℎ =
�� =
ℎ
ℎ
+
ℎ
+
+
+
ℎ
+
ℎ
+
+
+
ℎ
+
+
+
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
+
+
+
+
+
+
+
ℎ
ℎ
+
ℎ
ℎ
+
+
ℎ
ℎ
+
+
+
ℎ
ℎ
+
+
+
ℎ
ℎ
+
+
+
ℎ
+
ℎ
ℎ
+
+
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
+
+
−
ℎ ℎ
ℎ ℎ
+
−
−
−
−
−
ℎ
ℎ
+
ℎ
ℎ
+
+
ℎ
+
+
ℎ
−
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
−
−
−
−
−
+
+
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
+
+
ℎ
+
+
−
ℎ
ℎ
−
ℎ
−
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
−
−
−
+
+
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
+
+
ℎ
+
+
��ℎ −
ℎ
ℎ
��
ℎ
−
�� −
ℎ
�� ℎ −
�� −
��ℎ −
+
+
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
+
+
+
+
ℎ
�� ℎ
ℎ
ℎ
��
��ℎ
ℎ
��
��
ℎ
(A18)
��ℎ
An analytical solution can be attained, where the six trade flows depend on the six bilateral conflicts
and the three income variables. These equilibrium trade flows can then be used in the price equations
(A12) to (A17) to obtain the derivatives. However the solutions are far too intricate to give an intuitive
interpretation, and it suffices to mention that every derivative depends on all the parameters in the
model.
29
Appendix 2: Trade complementarity measures
Anderson and Nordheim (1993) develop a measure of trade intensity, which can be decomposed in a
complementarity index and an unexplained country bias term. Defining product shares in the exports
�
�
�
�
from the origin country ( = � ⁄ � ), in the imports to the destination country (
=
⁄
),
and in world total imports (net of country
complementarity index is obtained as:
imports:
�
�
� 9 =∑
�=
�
=
.
�
�
�
−
�
⁄
−
), then the
(A3.1)
When
� 9 > some complementarity exists between the products exported by and those
imported by , and high values can be attained. Values near to zero indicate that the products exports
are very different from those imports.
Michaely (1996) proposes a measure of complementarity that is being increasingly used (see e.g.
UNCTAD, 2012). Using the same definitions of shares of product in country exports and country
imports, his index of compatibility is obtained as:
96 =
�
− ∑
�=
|
�
−
�
|
(A3.2)
Table A3.1 shows that previous complementarity measures mostly show complementarity of the other
country as a destination for exports, with significant but low correlation with the complementarity of
the other country as a source for imports. Michaely’s measure outperforms the others, while Anderson
and Nordheim’s seems to be the poorest in terms of predicting exports and imports. Even if our
measures have an intermediate performance in predicting trade, they have the crucial advantage of
decomposing the imports and exports sides of complementarity, and Table A3.1 results allow taking
them as reasonable measures.
Table A3.1
Correlations among complementarity measures and with trade variables
lcomplUS
lcomplDS
lcomplAN93
lcomplM96
lcomplUS
1
0.3954*
0.0691*
0.1021*
lcomplDS
lcomplAN93
lcomplM96
1
0.3885*
0.3950*
1
0.5884*
1
Note: Correlations are calculated for the whole period 1995-2012, with products
defined by HS 6 digit classification. Stars indicate significance at a 99%
confidence level.
30
Appendix 3: CAMEO, Goldstein Scale and Conflict variable
Table A2.1 shows the CAMEO codes used in GDELT database, as well as the Goldstein Scale scores
in each case and the frequency of observed events for the whole set of national, subnational and
supranational actors. Some of the listed categories will be dropped when restricting our conflict
variable to actions among official actors.
Table A2.1
Actions considered for the conflict variable and their Goldstein Scores
CAMEO Description
Retreat or surrender militarily
Allow international involvement, not specified below
Receive deployment of peacekeepers
Receive inspectors
Allow humanitarian access
De-escalate military engagement
Declare truce, ceasefire
Ease military blockade
Demobilize armed forces
Return, release, not specified below
Return, release person(s)
Return, release property
Ease economic sanctions, boycott, embargo
Ease administrative sanctions, not specified below
Ease restrictions on political freedoms
Ease ban on political parties or politicians
Ease curfew
Ease state of emergency or martial law
Ease political dissent
Impose administrative sanctions, not specified below
Impose restrictions on political freedoms
Ban political parties or politicians
Impose curfew
Impose state of emergency or martial law
Arrest, detain, or charge with legal action
Expel or deport individuals
Halt negotiations
Expel or withdraw, not specified below
Expel or withdraw peacekeepers
Expel or withdraw inspectors, observers
Coerce, not specified below
Demonstrate military or police power, not specified below
Increase police alert status
Increase military alert status
Mobilize or increase police power
Mobilize or increase armed forces
Impose embargo, boycott, or sanctions
Use as human shield
Attempt to assassinate
Use tactics of violent repression
Use unconventional violence, not specified below
Abduct, hijack, or take hostage
Sexually assault
Torture
Seize or damage property, not specified below
Confiscate property
Destroy property
GS
Score
Frequency
(1979-2013)
10
9
9
9
9
9
9
9
9
7
7
7
7
5
5
5
5
5
5
-5
-5
-5
-5
-5
-5
-5
-7
-7
-7
-7
-7
-7.2
-7.2
-7.2
-7.2
-7.2
-8
-8
-8
-9
-9
-9
-9
-9
-9.2
-9.2
-9.2
7'802
378
494
118
61
539
1'457
180
363
9'363
15'410
749
1'442
2'892
37
8
72
2
323
10'684
1'304
309
312
255
60'032
3'855
3'756
398
9
32
1'601
4'202
524
901
704
4'124
3'938
13
316
1'600
7'864
8'983
786
1'477
590
1'355
2'483
31
Table A2.1 (cont’)
Correlations between complementarity measures and with trade variables
CAMEO Description
Physically assault, not specified below
Impose blockade, restrict movement
Occupy territory
Violate cease fire
Engage in mass expulsion
Kill by physical assault
Conduct suicide, car, or other non-military bombing, NES
Carry out suicide bombing
Carry out vehicular bombing
Carry out roadside bombing
Assassinate
Use conventional military force, not specified below
Fight with small arms and light weapons
Fight with artillery and tanks
Employ aerial weapons, not specified below
Engage in mass killings
Engage in ethnic cleansing
GS
Score
Frequency
(1979-2013)
-9.5
-9.5
-9.5
-9.5
-9.5
-10
-10
-10
-10
-10
-10
-10
-10
-10
-10
-10
-10
4'942
1'409
7'242
73
36
548
1'689
302
225
12
3'618
77'945
18'493
3'465
3'464
800
446
Using the sums of GS scores for the events found in each directed-dyad-year observation we can
represent the obtained network structure, and also compare it with the trade relations network
structure. In Figure A2.1 we assume a country has a directed link to if the bilateral trade flow share
in the exports from plus the share in the total imports of is greater than 15% (this has the desired
effect of giving higher weight to flows in which small countries are involved, since many countries
would be isolated if absolute values were used instead).
Figure A2.1
Network representations of conflict and trade relations (average 2010-2012)
Trade Network
Conflict Network
As expected, both networks have very different structures, being the conflict network much more
centralized both in terms of sources and targets of conflict. Also, the United States and Europe play a
crucial role in the network.
32
Appendix 4: Sample of countries
Afghanistan (AFG)
Angola (AGO)
Albania (ALB)
United Arab Emirates (ARE)
Argentina (ARG)
Armenia (ARM)
Australia (AUS)
Austria (AUT)
Azerbaijan (AZE)
Burundi (BDI)
Benin (BEN)
Burkina Faso (BFA)
Bangladesh (BGD)
Bulgaria (BGR)
Bahrain (BHR)
Bosnia and Herzegovina (BIH)
Belarus (BLR)
Bolivia (BOL)
Brazil (BRA)
Bhutan (BTN)
Central African Republic (CAF)
Canada (CAN)
Switzerland (CHE)
Chile (CHL)
China (CHN)
Ivory Coast (CIV)
Cameroon (CMR)
Congo (COG)
Colombia (COL)
Costa Rica (CRI)
Cuba (CUB)
Cyprus (CYP)
Czech Republic (CZE)
Germany (DEU)
Djibouti (DJI)
Denmark (DNK)
Dominican Republic (DOM)
Algeria (DZA)
Ecuador (ECU)
Egypt (EGY)
Eritrea (ERI)
Spain (ESP)
Estonia (EST)
Finland (FIN)
Fiji (FJI)
France (FRA)
Gabon (GAB)
United Kingdom (GBR)
Georgia (GEO)
Ghana (GHA)
Guinea (GIN)
Gambia (GMB)
Guinea-Bissau (GNB)
Equatorial Guinea (GNQ)
Greece (GRC)
Guatemala (GTM)
Guyana (GUY)
Honduras (HND)
Croatia (HRV)
Haiti (HTI)
Hungary (HUN)
Indonesia (IDN)
India (IND)
Ireland (IRL)
Iran (IRN)
Iraq (IRQ)
Israel (ISR)
Italy (ITA)
Jamaica (JAM)
Jordan (JOR)
Japan (JPN)
Kazakhstan (KAZ)
Kenya (KEN)
Kyrgyzstan (KGZ)
Cambodia (KHM)
South Korea (KOR)
Kuwait (KWT)
Laos (LAO)
Lebanon (LBN)
Liberia (LBR)
Libya (LBY)
Sri Lanka (LKA)
Lithuania (LTU)
Latvia (LVA)
Morocco (MAR)
Moldova (MDA)
Madagascar (MDG)
Mexico (MEX)
Macedonia (MKD)
Mali (MLI)
Myanmar (MMR)
Mongolia (MNG)
Mozambique (MOZ)
Mauritania (MRT)
Mauritius (MUS)
Malawi (MWI)
Malaysia (MYS)
Niger (NER)
Nigeria (NGA)
Nicaragua (NIC)
Netherlands (NLD)
Norway (NOR)
Nepal (NPL)
New Zealand (NZL)
Oman (OMN)
Pakistan (PAK)
Panama (PAN)
Peru (PER)
Philippines (PHL)
Papua New Guinea (PNG)
Poland (POL)
North Korea (PRK)
Portugal (PRT)
Paraguay (PRY)
Qatar (QAT)
Romania (ROM)
Russia (RUS)
Rwanda (RWA)
Saudi Arabia (SAU)
Senegal (SEN)
Singapore (SGP)
Solomon Islands (SLB)
Sierra Leone (SLE)
El Salvador (SLV)
Suriname (SUR)
Slovakia (SVK)
Slovenia (SVN)
Sweden (SWE)
Syria (SYR)
Chad (TCD)
Togo (TGO)
Thailand (THA)
Tajikistan (TJK)
Turkmenistan (TKM)
Trinidad and Tobago (TTO)
Tunisia (TUN)
Turkey (TUR)
Tanzania (TZA)
Uganda (UGA)
Ukraine (UKR)
Uruguay (URY)
United States of America (USA)
Uzbekistan (UZB)
Venezuela (VEN)
Yemen (YEM)
South Africa (ZAF)
Dem Rep Congo (ZAR)
Zambia (ZMB)
Zimbabwe (ZWE)
28
Appendix 5: Robustness checks
Table A5.1
Robustness Checks I: Lags in explanatory variables
IV estimations using different fixed effects
VARIABLES
Upstream complementarity
(corresponding lag in logs)
Downstream complementarity
(corresponding lag in logs)
Upstream substitutability
(corresponding lag in logs)
Downstream substitutability
(corresponding lag in logs)
Upstream rivalry
No lags
Pooled +
Panel
TVXMFE
3.000**
1.228***
First lags
Pooled +
Panel
TVXMFE
1.784
0.640**
Third lags
Pooled +
Panel
TVXMFE
1.119
0.470*
[1.247]
[0.247]
[1.195]
[0.253]
[1.125]
[0.269]
3.388***
0.694***
3.364***
0.636***
2.891***
0.539***
[0.612]
[0.112]
[0.584]
[0.115]
[0.563]
[0.123]
-2.610***
-0.952***
-2.359***
-0.779***
-1.876***
-0.576**
[0.381]
[0.192]
[0.380]
[0.196]
[0.368]
[0.230]
-1.368***
-0.506***
-1.021***
-0.418***
-0.437
-0.299***
[0.399]
[0.093]
[0.386]
[0.098]
[0.360]
[0.108]
-1.060***
-0.255***
-1.004***
-0.092
-0.862***
-0.146*
(corresponding lag in logs)
[0.199]
[0.077]
[0.199]
[0.079]
[0.202]
[0.088]
Downstream rivalry
4.812***
-1.318***
4.894***
-1.390***
5.117***
-0.874***
(corresponding lag in logs)
Exports
[0.164]
[0.119]
[0.162]
[0.125]
[0.162]
[0.134]
-0.287**
-0.044*
-0.321***
-0.070***
-0.254**
-0.090***
(corresponding lag in logs)
[0.130]
[0.023]
[0.124]
[0.024]
[0.121]
[0.030]
Imports
-0.029
-0.019
0.073
0.053*
0.103
0.098***
(corresponding lag in logs)
Peace Years
(corresponding lag)
[0.131]
[0.028]
[0.126]
[0.030]
[0.121]
[0.035]
-0.005***
-0.008***
-0.005***
-0.006***
-0.005***
-0.004***
[0.001]
[0.000]
[0.001]
[0.000]
[0.000]
-0.048*
Democracy in origin
(corresponding lag in logs)
Democracy in destination
-0.077***
[0.001]
-0.127***
[0.025]
[0.025]
[0.027]
-0.070**
-0.099***
-0.172***
(corresponding lag in logs)
[0.027]
[0.028]
[0.028]
GDP in origin
0.006
-0.001
0.045**
(corresponding lag in logs)
[0.017]
[0.017]
[0.020]
GDP in destination
0.019
0.014
0.045***
(corresponding lag in logs)
Domestic conflict in origin
(corresponding lag in logs)
Domestic conflict in destination
(corresponding lag in logs)
Distance
[0.014]
[0.015]
[0.017]
0.427***
0.337***
0.272***
[0.007]
[0.007]
[0.008]
0.446***
0.341***
0.248***
[0.007]
-1.057***
[0.007]
-0.977***
[0.008]
-0.865***
(in logs)
[0.083]
[0.082]
[0.073]
Border
1.103***
1.073***
1.029***
[0.082]
[0.079]
[0.073]
Common religion
0.112***
0.096***
0.074***
Same country in the past
[0.021]
[0.021]
[0.020]
-0.042
-0.112
-0.191*
[0.116]
[0.114]
[0.108]
Hegemon-to-colony
1.232***
1.168***
1.078***
[0.142]
[0.140]
[0.133]
Colony-to-hegemon
1.169***
1.130***
1.053***
Observations
Time FE
Origin & Destination FE
Origin & Destination TVFE
Country-Pair FE
Hansen J p-value
Underidentification K-P p-value
Weak Identif. K-P F Statistic
Weak Identif CD F Statistic
416,500
NO
NO
YES
NO
0.715
0.0003
5.280
17.42
[0.138]
[0.134]
416,500
YES
NO
NO
YES
0.574
0
92.49
181.0
394,666
NO
NO
YES
NO
0.755
0.0002
5.788
18.86
[0.128]
394,666
YES
NO
NO
YES
0.0818
0
86.73
167.0
351,096
NO
NO
YES
NO
0.463
0.0002
5.486
17.09
351,096
YES
NO
NO
YES
0.0919
0
68.45
127.7
Pair-clustered standard errors in brackets. Results obtained using ivreg2 (Baum, Schaffer, and Stillman, 2010) and reghdfe (Correia, 2015).
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
29
Table A5.2
Robustness Checks II: Operationalization of interstate conflict
IV estimations using different fixed effects
VARIABLES
Upstream complementarity
(second lag in logs)
Downstream complementarity
(second lag in logs)
Upstream substitutability
(second lag in logs)
Downstream substitutability
(second lag in logs)
Upstream rivalry
(second lag in logs)
Downstream rivalry
(second lag in logs)
Exports
Material actions
All actors
Pooled +
Panel
TVXMFE
0.955
0.722***
All actions
Official actors
Pooled +
Panel
TVXMFE
0.308
0.622**
All actions
All actors
Pooled +
Panel
TVXMFE
0.201
0.715***
[1.206]
[0.271]
[1.222]
[0.266]
[1.221]
[0.272]
3.351***
0.804***
3.367***
0.791***
3.263***
0.763***
[0.601]
[0.122]
[0.609]
[0.120]
[0.609]
[0.122]
-2.265***
-0.669***
-1.854***
-0.936***
-1.822***
-0.799***
[0.388]
[0.221]
[0.391]
[0.221]
[0.392]
[0.226]
-0.677*
-0.430***
-0.567
-0.462***
-0.424
-0.470***
[0.397]
[0.106]
[0.403]
[0.104]
[0.403]
[0.106]
-0.954***
-0.081
-0.941***
-0.148*
-0.897***
-0.142*
[0.212]
[0.087]
[0.215]
[0.084]
[0.215]
[0.086]
4.999***
-1.274***
5.171***
-1.490***
5.152***
-1.489***
[0.168]
[0.131]
[0.168]
[0.130]
[0.168]
[0.131]
-0.336***
-0.113***
-0.348***
-0.098***
-0.330**
-0.100***
(second lag in logs)
[0.129]
[0.028]
[0.131]
[0.028]
[0.131]
[0.028]
Imports
0.158
0.093***
0.201
0.068**
0.215
0.086**
(second lag in logs)
Peace Years
(second lag)
[0.129]
[0.034]
[0.131]
[0.033]
[0.131]
[0.034]
-0.005***
-0.005***
-0.005***
-0.004***
-0.005***
-0.004***
[0.001]
[0.000]
[0.001]
[0.000]
[0.000]
-6.133***
Democracy in origin
(second lag in logs)
Democracy in destination
-4.292***
[0.001]
-5.283***
[1.356]
[1.368]
[1.395]
-8.043***
-6.962***
-7.970***
(second lag in logs)
[1.395]
[1.373]
[1.400]
GDP in origin
0.046**
0.036*
0.037*
(second lag in logs)
GDP in destination
(second lag in logs)
Domestic conflict in origin
(second lag in logs)
Domestic conflict in destination
(second lag in logs)
Distance
[0.020]
[0.019]
[0.020]
0.055***
0.041**
0.057***
[0.016]
[0.016]
[0.016]
0.302***
0.293***
0.298***
[0.007]
[0.007]
[0.007]
0.294***
0.277***
0.284***
[0.007]
-0.918***
[0.007]
-0.895***
[0.007]
-0.875***
(in logs)
[0.082]
[0.084]
[0.084]
Border
1.021***
0.969***
0.929***
[0.077]
[0.076]
[0.076]
Common religion
0.089***
0.091***
0.092***
Same country in the past
[0.022]
[0.022]
[0.022]
-0.168
-0.189*
-0.202*
[0.114]
[0.114]
[0.114]
Hegemon-to-colony
1.100***
1.063***
1.043***
[0.139]
[0.135]
[0.135]
Colony-to-hegemon
1.077***
1.100***
1.071***
[0.134]
[0.129]
[0.128]
Observations
Time FE
Origin & Destination FE
Origin & Destination TVFE
Country-Pair FE
Hansen J p-value
Underidentification K-P p-value
Weak Identif. K-P F Statistic
Weak Identif CD F Statistic
372,910
NO
NO
YES
NO
0.343
0.000184
5.670
18.18
372,910
YES
NO
NO
YES
0.291
0
76.66
147.1
372,910
NO
NO
YES
NO
0.249
0.000184
5.670
18.18
372,910
YES
NO
NO
YES
0.283
0
76.66
147.1
372,910
NO
NO
YES
NO
0.245
0.000184
5.670
18.18
372,910
YES
NO
NO
YES
0.315
0
76.66
147.1
Pair-clustered standard errors in brackets. Results obtained using ivreg2 (Baum, Schaffer, and Stillman, 2010) and reghdfe (Correia, 2015).
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
30