THE WORLD BANK
POVERTY
REDUCTION
AND ECONOMIC
MANAGEMENT
NETWORK (PREM)
Economic Premise
JUNE 2010
•
Number 16
Dealing with Dutch Disease
Milan Brahmbhatt, Otaviano Canuto, and Ekaterina Vostroknutova1
This note looks at so-called Dutch disease, a phenomenon reflecting changes in the structure of production in the
wake of a favorable shock (such as a large natural resource discovery, a rise in the international price of an
exportable commodity, or the presence of sustained aid or capital inflows). Where the natural resources discovered
are oil or minerals, a contraction or stagnation of manufacturing and agriculture could accompany the positive
effects of the shock, according to the theory. The note considers channels through which such natural resource wealth
can affect the economy. It also focuses on the development implications of Dutch disease, particularly the potential
negative effects related to productivity dynamics and volatility; and concludes with a summary of possible policy
responses, including the mix of fiscal, exchange rate, and structural reform policies.
The recent boom in primary commodity prices has once
more stimulated interest in the issue of “Dutch disease.” This
term refers to changes in the structure of production that
are predicted to occur in the wake of a favorable shock, such
as discovery of a large natural resource or a rise in the international price of an exportable commodity that is perceived
to be permanent. Such structural changes are expected to
include, in particular, a contraction or stagnation of other
tradable sectors of the economy; and to be accompanied by
an appreciation of the country’s real exchange rate (Gelb
and Associates 1988). Where the booming sector is oil or
minerals, the declining tradable sectors would include manufacturing and agriculture, according to the theory. In principle, such changes in the structure of production should be
welfare improving, reflecting changes in demand associated
with an improvement in national income. They may, however, be a matter of concern for policy makers if the declining sectors are thought to have some special characteristics
that would stimulate growth and welfare in the long term—
such as increasing returns to scale, learning by doing, or positive technological externalities. Concerns about Dutch disease may also arise in the context of large, sustained private
capital or foreign aid inflows (Auty 2001).
This note lays out a basic model of Dutch disease, following Corden and Neary (1982), and considers channels
through which natural resource wealth can affect the economy; it focuses on the development implications of Dutch
disease, particularly the potential negative effects related to
productivity dynamics and volatility; and it concludes with
a summary of possible policy responses, including the mix
of fiscal, exchange rate, and structural reform policies.
1 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT (PREM) NETWORK
www.worldbank.org/economicpremise
A Model of Dutch Disease
When studying Dutch disease, researchers typically model
the economy as consisting of three sectors: the natural resource sector, the nonresource tradables sector (usually understood as agriculture and manufacturing), and the
2 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT (PREM) NETWORK
more open to capital flows and in relatively less capital-intensive manufacturing sectors, consistent with the theoretical model developed in the study.
One of the measurement issues with Dutch disease is the
difficulty in finding the counterfactual size of the tradables
sector—that is, determining how large the tradables sector
would have been in the absence of the natural resources. We
use the Chenery and Syrquin (1975) norms approach to estimate a norm for the size of the tradables (manufacturing
and agriculture) sector for all countries over time, after controlling for per capita income, population, and time trend.
Figure 2 shows the difference between the actual size of the
Figure 1. Terms-of-Trade Shocks and Real Appreciation, 2004–08
change in log of REER
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
–0.4
–0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
–0.2
–0.4
change in log of terms of trade
Source: Authors’ calculations, using the International Monetary Fund’s
Information Notice System.
Note: REER = real effective exchange rate; y = 0.3825x + 0.0481; R 2 =
0.2364.
Figure 2. Dutch Disease Measure for Resource-Rich and Other
Countries, 1975–2005
0.05
percent of GDP
0
–0.05
–0.10
–0.15
–0.20
19
75
19
77
19
79
19
81
19
83
19
85
19
87
19
89
19
91
19
93
19
95
19
97
19
99
20
01
20
03
20
05
nontradables sector (including nontradable services and construction), as presented in Corden and Neary (1982). The
prices for both the natural resource and nonresource tradables sectors are set in the world market, and those in the
nontradables sector are set in the domestic economy. The
real exchange rate is defined as the price of nontradables relative to the price of tradables. There generally are two types
of effects leading to Dutch disease and real exchange rate
appreciation:
1. The spending effect comes into play when increased domestic income from the booming natural resource sector leads to higher aggregate demand and spending by
the public and private sectors. Increased demand for
nontradables leads to higher prices and output in the
nontradables sector. Wages in the economy will tend
to rise, squeezing profits in the nonresource tradables
sector (“manufacturing”), where prices are fixed at international levels.
2. The resource movement effect takes place when a boom
in the natural resource sector attracts capital and labor
from other parts of the economy. It tends to reduce
output in the rest of the economy. In particular, reduced output in the nontradables sector causes the
price of nontradables to rise relative to the price of
tradables, which are set in the world market. This effect in less likely in low-income economies, where
most inputs used in the natural resource “enclave” are
imported from abroad.
Both effects result in a fall in the output share of nonresource tradables relative to nontradables, and a real exchange
rate appreciation—that is, a rise in the price of nontradables
relative to that of tradables.
What about empirical evidence? There is relatively robust
evidence that terms-of-trade increases cause real appreciation in natural-resource-rich countries (for example, see
Spatafora and Warner [1995]). Figure 1 displays changes in
real effective exchange rates compared with terms-of-trade
changes, and it reveals a correlation during the recent
episode of high commodity prices.
The evidence on the shrinking of the manufacturing sector in response to terms-of-trade shocks and real appreciation has been somewhat mixed (Sala-i-Martin and
Subramanian 2003). Recently, though, much stronger evidence of Dutch disease is presented by Ismail (2010), who
studies the impact of oil price shocks using detailed, disaggregated sectoral data for manufacturing and allowing for
the possibility that the extent of Dutch disease will depend
on the capital intensity of the manufacturing sector and the
economy’s openness to capital flows. Ismail finds that, in
general, a 10.0 percent increase in an oil windfall is associated with a 3.4 percent fall in value added across manufacturing sectors. Such effects are larger in economies that are
year
resource rich
other
Source: Authors’ calculations, based on Chenery and Syrquin (1975).
www.worldbank.org/economicpremise
Development Implications of Dutch Disease
In general, an increase in wealth resulting from the discovery
of a natural resource or a permanent rise in the terms of
trade is a positive development: it leads to a new equilibrium
with higher incomes and higher consumption of both nontradables and tradables (the latter supplied to a greater extent than before through imports). Moreover, rents from
mineral resources collected by government can provide resources for investment in public goods and other development expenditures that would have been unaffordable in
different circumstances. Analyzing the historical development of several European countries and the United States,
Gelb and Associates (1988) conclude that “there is evidence
that, at least in some cases, high-rent activities. . . have provided an important stimulus to growth” (see also the historical review in Lederman and Maloney [2008]).
There is, however, a long tradition of economic research
arguing that these obvious gains may have come at the expense of growth in the long term, based on the idea that
manufacturing and other nonresource tradables possess specific long-term, growth-enhancing qualities (such as the
presence of positive technological spillovers, learning by
doing effects, or increasing returns to scale in production).
Other considerations relate to resource depletion and employment. Given increasing returns and costly, time-consuming learning in manufacturing, the economy would
struggle to rebuild sources of growth upon depletion of its
natural resource. Also, if Dutch disease affects labor-intensive
industries more than capital-intensive ones and increases
capital intensity in general—as found by Ismail (2010)—it
could increase unemployment as it did originally in the
Netherlands and the United Kingdom
Research on these questions typically has not attempted to
directly demonstrate the presence of spillovers or other growthenhancing qualities in the tradables sector that tends to decline
as a result of Dutch disease. The evidence is generally more indirect, and a number of threads can be distinguished.
Figure 3. Manufacturing Growth and Resource Exports, Selected
Economies
log of growth of manufacturing
exports x initial share in 1970
tradables sector (as defined) and the Chenery-Syrquin norm,
for both resource-rich and non–resource-rich countries. For
the purpose of this figure, resource-rich countries are defined as those in which the resource sector produces more
than 30 percent of GDP. On average, the tradables sector in
such countries is lower than the norm by approximately 15
percent of GDP.
HKG
TAI
JPN
SGP
FRA
BEL
PRT
HTI
USA
IND
NLD
IRL
MYS
CAN
TUN
ISL
BHR
MUS
OMN
MEX
PRY
VEN
GHA
SAU
QAT
KWT
LBY
log of natural resources exports as a share of GDP in 1970
Source: Sachs and Warner 2001.
Note: y = 0.74x – 7.49; R 2 = 0.26.
centage points in the ratio of natural resource exports to
GDP in a cross-section of countries during 1970–90 was associated with reduced manufactured export growth (figure
3) and with as much as 0.4–0.7 percentage points lower annual per capita growth in GDP.
On the other hand, Lederman and Maloney (2007) challenge the robustness of these findings on a number of
grounds, including the econometric drawbacks associated
with the use of cross-section data and the need for a measure
of natural resource abundance better grounded in economic
theory. Using panel data and measuring resource abundance
as net exports of natural resources per worker, they find natural resource abundance to have a positive effect on growth.
They also argue that productivity growth in services or the
natural resource sector may not be inferior to that in manufacturing, and they question whether manufacturing really
possesses such special characteristics. “If the natural resource
sector is not inferior in terms of its growth potential, then
this sectoral shift would be of similar import to the canonical
displacement of agriculture by manufacturing. . . .”
Natural Resource Abundance and Growth
The influential studies by Sachs and Warner (1995, 2001)
are representative of a stream of literature that finds that
natural resource abundance has a strong negative impact on
growth. In particular, they show that an increase of 10 per-
Exchange Rate Overvaluation and Growth
In principle, the real exchange rate appreciation that is a part
of Dutch disease is an equilibrium phenomenon that reflects
a change in underlying fundamentals. However, to the extent that the real exchange rate overshoots and becomes
overvalued—for example, if agents mistakenly overestimate
the permanence of a terms-of-trade improvement—research
on the relationship of overvaluation and growth is also relevant. Empirical evidence on this issue generally suggests
that substantial exchange rate overvaluation has a strong
negative impact on growth. Perhaps among the most carefully designed and well-known of these studies is that of
Aguirre and Calderón (2005). Other studies include those
of Williamson (2008); Razin and Collins (1999); and Prasad,
Rajan, and Subramanian (2006).
3 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT (PREM) NETWORK
www.worldbank.org/economicpremise
Volatility as a Transmission Channel
Dutch disease may result in high export concentration in
commodities that have exhibited statistically higher price
volatility than that of manufacturing products (Jacks,
O’Rourke, and Williamson 2009). Natural resource prices
and revenues tend to be volatile because of the low shortterm supply elasticity of natural resource output. If government spending is closely related to natural resource
revenues, it also will become more volatile. Spending volatility, in turn, will drive volatility in the real exchange rate
(through the spending effect described above). A large body
of empirical work documents the adverse impact of economic volatility on investment and growth. Among other
types of volatility, that in real exchange rates is often found
to have an especially clear adverse impact on economic performance. Loayza et al. (2007) provide a recent survey. Serven (2003) documents the impact of real exchange rate
volatility on investment. Van der Ploeg and Poelhekke
(2009) also show that economic growth declines with the
volatility of unanticipated output growth.
Overborrowing
High commodity prices in the 1970s encouraged many resource-abundant countries to use their resources as collateral
to borrow abroad to finance large investment projects and
high public consumption. When prices plunged in the
1980s, these countries were left with balance-of-payments
crises and unsustainable external debt levels (Manzano and
Rigobon 2007). A recent paper by Reinhart and Rogoff
(2010) suggests that when external debt rises above 60 percent of GDP, annual growth declines on average by 2 percent; and for high levels of debt, growth is cut in half.
Reconciling the Evidence: The Importance of Governance
and Policies
Recent work attempts to reconcile the somewhat disparate
evidence on the relationship, if any, between natural resource abundance and growth—particularly between crosssection results that find strong evidence of a natural resource
curse and time series studies that find primary commodity
booms to be generally positive for growth. Collier and
Goderis (2007) adopt a panel cointegration methodology
that enables them to disentangle the short- and long-term
effects of commodity prices on growth, looking at 130 countries during 1963–2003. They find that commodity price
booms do have positive short-term impacts on growth, but
that the impacts are significantly negative in the long term.
However, these negative long-term effects exist only for
“point source” natural resources like oil and minerals, and
only in countries with bad governance.
The literature suggests that natural resource riches create
or exacerbate institutional weaknesses. First, the discovery
4 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT (PREM) NETWORK
of natural resources or a natural resource boom might induce
a deterioration in governance, for example, by stimulating
greater corruption or by provoking powerful interest groups
to engage in more intense political or bureaucratic battles
for control and redistribution of natural resource rents, leading even to armed conflict or civil war. Tornell and Lane
(1999), for example, model a “voracity effect” in which a
terms-of-trade improvement leads to lower growth by provoking a struggle between powerful groups, leading to an increase in unproductive fiscal redistribution that is more than
proportional. As large increases in spendable revenues divert
production and the focus of bureaucrats away from the productive activities, revenues from rents could lead to a detachment of the governments from their tax bases, like in
“rentier” states (Levi 1988).
The panel data study by Collier and Goderis (2007), however, does not find statistically significant evidence that natural resources directly worsen governance or institutional
quality, although it does find evidence that the quality of existing institutions conditions the quality of economic policies
that countries use to deal with natural resource abundance—
that is, with how natural resources affect growth. Mehlum,
Moene, and Torvik (2006) suggest that, in countries with
“grabber-friendly” institutions, a natural resource boom will
lead to a shift out of productive activity into unproductive
rent seeking. In countries with “producer-friendly” institutions, on the other hand, a natural resource boom attracts resources to move into productive activity. In the empirical
part of their study Mehlum, Moene, and Torvik find that the
negative impact of natural resources on growth steadily falls
as institutional quality increases. When institutional quality
is sufficiently high, the natural resource effect becomes positive. Robinson, Torvik, and Verdier (2006) develop a model,
in countries with weak institutional controls on the use of
clientelism and patronage to influence elections, where a natural resource boom creates incentives for politicians to use
revenues on expanded public sector spending and employment to improve their chances of staying in power.
Excessive public spending appears to be at the heart of
economic mismanagement in the wake of natural resource
booms. The following section looks at this and other policy
considerations that have been found useful to control the
potential negative impacts from Dutch disease.
Policy Responses
The actual impacts of natural resources on an economy will
depend to a large extent on policies.
Fiscal Policy
Highlighting the role of fiscal policy in the natural resource
boom episodes in the 1970s and 1980s, Gelb and Associates
www.worldbank.org/economicpremise
(1988) conclude that “the most important recommendation
to emerge from this study is that spending levels should have
been adjusted to sharp rises in income levels more cautiously
than they actually were.” Fiscal policy is the main instrument
for dealing with the negative impacts of Dutch disease for
the following reasons: it is a tool that can make the increase
in wealth permanent, it can constrain the spending effect
(the main channel of negative impacts transmission in lowincome countries), and it can smooth expenditures to reduce volatility.
There is empirical evidence that government spending is
correlated with the increases in resource revenues. (For example, see Katz et al. [2004] for the case of African countries.)
Saving revenue proceeds abroad and reducing aggregate
spending will help if the spending effect is believed to be
one of the main transmission channels. Smoothing spending
over time also would help reduce volatility and its harmful
impacts on the economy.
The smoothing of spending is achieved through a detachment of spending from the resource revenues, and the introduction of fiscal rules for how much of the resource
revenues can be spent and how much saved in a natural resource fund (see Davis, Ossowski, and Fedilino [2003]). The
use of a medium-term expenditure framework was found
useful for successful implementation of fiscal policy in resource-rich countries.
Much has been written on the best institutional arrangements to govern nonrenewable natural resource revenues
(see Barnett and Ossowski [2002] for a review). Although
adequate revenue management does not always require setting up a special fund, an increasing number of countries
have institutionalized fiscal rules to express their preferences
over management of the resource revenues by creating an
explicit natural resources fund, with strict rules governing
payments into and out of the fund. Depending on the purpose of the fund (reducing volatility, constraining the spending effect, or investing in future growth), a stabilization fund,
savings fund, or investment fund can be created. Incorporating the natural resources fund into the general budgetary
system helps in making decisions on striking a balance between dealing with the impacts of Dutch disease and pursuing development objectives. A fund—however simple and
transparent—cannot resolve complex fiscal policy issues by
itself; it can only aid in implementing an already sound fiscal
policy.
An adequate fiscal policy would be balanced between the
need to implement development objectives and the need to
constrain the spending effect. A fiscal rule called the “permanent income approach” provides an important benchmark for fiscal policy (van Wijnbergen 2008). Applied only
to exhaustible resources, this approach recommends first
calculating the expected net present value of all expected
net future revenues from these resources; and then calculating the constant real amount (or annuity) that, received forever, would yield the same net present value. The permanent
income approach then recommends restricting government
spending from these exhaustible natural resource revenues
to only this constant annuity amount, while saving the rest
abroad. Later, when exhaustible natural resources have run
out, the government would be able to draw on its accumulated financial assets to continue spending the same constant
annuity amount.
Whereas saving most of the revenues in order to smooth
consumption may be part of the development strategy in
some countries, the development needs may be too great in
other (especially, low-income) countries. Collier et al.
(2009) argue that directing all resource revenues to current
consumption is wasteful and inequitable; however, postponing the consumption into the far-distant future is wasteful
and inequitable as well. They suggest an “optimal” fiscal rule
for a developing country. This rule would make it possible to
save some of the revenues (less at the beginning and more
at the end of the high-resource-revenues period) and allow
for more investment and consumption from the resource
revenues than in the permanent income strategy. Perfect implementation of this approach would require strict fiscal discipline and clear spending rules.
5 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT (PREM) NETWORK
www.worldbank.org/economicpremise
Spending and Structural Policies
Spending policies also can help curb Dutch disease. Directing spending toward tradables (including imports) rather
than nontradables would help slow the impacts through the
spending effect. Improving the quality of spending to ensure
that productivity in nontradable sectors increases alongside
the structural changes also would be important. If the spending effect works also through private spending, general policies toward improving productivity of the private firms
would help reduce the impacts.
Policies that encourage demand for imports—for example, trade liberalization—would help reduce demand pressure on the nontradables sector and, therefore, may be part
of the structural policy response to Dutch disease.
To the extent that the country continues to experience
some real exchange rate appreciation and other adverse effects of rising natural resource revenues, there may be a case
for orienting spending especially to investments that would
help enhance productivity in the nontradables sector of the
economy—such as investments in transport and logistics infrastructure, expanded investment in education and skills
training to foster faster absorption of foreign technology and
innovation, and so on. Building rural roads is usually one of
the most powerful poverty-reducing investments, and it
could involve more local labor. However, special care needs
to be taken to ensure that there is adequate capacity to pri-
Aghion, P., P. Bacchetta, R. Rancière, and K. S. Rogoff. 2009. “Exchange
Rate Volatility and Productivity Growth: The Role of Financial Development.” Journal of Monetary Economics 56: 494–513.
Aguirre, A., and C. Calderón. 2005. “Real Exchange Rate Misalignments
and Economic Performance.” Working Paper 315. Central Bank of Chile,
Economic Research Division, Santiago.
Auty, R. M., ed. 2001. Resource Abundance and Economic Development. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.
Barnett, S., and R. Ossowski. 2002. “Operational Aspects of Fiscal Policy in
Oil-Producing Countries.” Working Paper 02/177. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Budina, N., G. Pang, and S. van Wijnbergen. 2007. “Nigeria’s Growth
Record: Dutch Disease or Debt Overhang.” Policy Research Working
Paper 4256. World Bank, Washington, DC.
Buiter, W., and D. Purvis. 1983. “Oil, Disinflation, and Export Competitiveness: A Model of the ‘Dutch Disease.’” In Economic Interdependence and
Flexible Exchange Rates, ed. J. S. Bhandari and B. H. Putnam, with J. H.
Levin, 221–47. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Calvo, G. A., L. L. Leiderman, and C. M. Reinhart. 1996. “Inflows of Capital
to Developing Countries in the 1990s.” Journal of Economic Perspectives
10 (2): 123–39.
Calvo, G. A., and C. M. Reinhart. 2002. “Fear of Floating.” Quarterly Journal
of Economics 107 (2): 379–408.
Chenery, H., and M. Syrquin. 1975. Patterns of Development, 1950–1970.
Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.
Collier, P., and B. Goderis. 2007. “Commodity Prices, Growth and the Natural Resources Curse: Reconciling a Conundrum.” Working Paper 276.
Centre for the Study of African Economies, Oxford, UK.
Collier, P., and A. Hoeffler. 2009. “Testing the Neocon Agenda: Democracy
and Natural Resource Rents.” European Economic Review 52 (3): 293–
308.
Collier, P., F. van der Ploeg, M. M. Spence, and A. J. Venables. 2009. “Managing Resource Revenues in Developing Economies.” IMF Staff Papers
(2010) 57: 84–118.
Corden, W. M., and P. J. Neary. 1982. “Booming Sector and Deindustrialization in a Small Open Economy.” Economic Journal 92: 825–48.
Davis, J. M., R. Ossowski, and A. Fedilino, eds. 2003. Fiscal Policy Formulation and Implementation in Oil-Producing Countries. Washington, DC:
International Monetary Fund.
Frankel, J. A. 2009. “A Comparison of Monetary Anchor Options for Commodity-Exporters in Latin America and the Caribbean.” Paper presented
at the World Bank workshop “Myths and Realities of Commodity Dependence: Policy Challenges and Opportunities for Latin America and
the Caribbean,” Washington, DC, September 17–18.
Gelb, A., and Associates. 1988. Oil Windfalls: Blessing or Curse? Washington,
DC: World Bank.
Giavazzi, F., J. R. Sheen, and C. Wyplosz. 1988. “The Real Exchange Rate
and the Fiscal Aspects of a Natural Resource Discovery.” Oxford Economic Papers 40 (3): 427–50.
Hausmann, R., and R. Rigobon. 2003. “An Alternative Interpretation of the
‘Resource Curse’: Theory and Policy Implications.” Working Paper 9424.
National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Ismail, K. 2010. “The Structural Manifestation of the ‘Dutch Disease’: The
Case of Oil Exporting Countries.” Working Paper 10/103. International
Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Jacks, D. S., K. H. O’Rourke, and J. G. Williamson. 2009. “Commodity Price
Volatility and World Market Integration Since 1700.” Working Paper
14748. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Kaminsky, G. L., C. M. Reinhart, and C. A. Vegh. 2005. “When It Rains It
Pours: Procyclical Capital Flows and Macroeconomic Policies.” In NBER
Macroeconomics Annual 2004, Volume 19, ed. M. Gertler and K. Rogoff,
11–82. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Katz, M., U. Bartsch, H. Malothra, and M. Cuc. 2004. “Lifting the Oil
Curse—Improving Petroleum Revenue Management in Sub-Saharan
Africa.” International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Lederman, D., and W. F. Maloney, eds. 2007. Natural Resources: Neither
Curse nor Destiny. Washington, DC: World Bank.
6 POVERTY REDUCTION AND ECONOMIC MANAGEMENT (PREM) NETWORK
www.worldbank.org/economicpremise
oritize and implement public projects, especially in low- income countries.
The country also may undertake other reforms that do
not necessarily involve large expenditures, but that enhance
economywide productivity: improvements in business regulations, reductions in red tape, reduction of monopolistic
barriers that discourage innovation, and other improvements
in the overall business climate. Such policies will reduce the
regulatory burden on the nonresource economy. Other policies, such as ones that promote foreign direct investment,
could create conditions for learning by doing through
spillover effects.
Monetary and Exchange Rate Policies
The choice of an appropriate anchor for monetary policy is
especially important for macroeconomic management in
commodity-exporting countries. For example, inflation targeting has been an extremely successful instrument, although
it may result in a monetary policy that is so tight it puts appreciation pressure on the exchange rate when commodity
prices increase. Recently, there has been discussion of developing more appropriate forms of price targeting in commodity-exporting countries. Whereas Consumer Price Index
inflation targeting has worked in many countries, it has been
less successful in stabilizing relative tradables/nontradables
prices in commodity exporters. Frankel (2009) shows that
targeting of a more specific price index that has a higher
share of export commodity prices and/or production prices
(such as the Producer Price Index or the Export Price Index)
would have been more appropriate, although more difficult
to administer or make transparent to the general population.
Note
1. The authors would like to thank Manu Sharma for his
excellent research assistance.
About the Authors
Milan Brahmbhatt is economic adviser, Poverty Reduction and
Economic Management (PREM) Network, World Bank. Otaviano Canuto is vice president, PREM. Ekaterina Vostroknutova is senior economist, East Asia and Pacific Poverty Reduction
and Economic Management Unit, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Bibliography
———. 2008. “In Search of the Missing Resource Curse.” Policy Research
Working Paper 4766. World Bank, Washington, DC.
Lederman, D., and L. C. Xu. 2007. “Comparative Advantage and Trade Intensity: Are Traditional Endowments Destiny?” In Natural Resources:
Neither Curse nor Destiny, ed. D. Lederman and W. F. Maloney, 289–
322. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Levi, M. 1988. Of Rule and Revenue. Berkeley, CA: University of California
Press.
Loayza, N. V., R. Rancière, L. Serven, and J. Ventura. 2007. “Macroeconomic
Volatility and Welfare in Developing Countries: An Introduction.”
World Bank Economic Review 21 (3): 343–57.
Manzano, O., and R. Rigobon. 2007. “Resource Curse or Debt Overhang.”
In Natural Resources: Neither Curse nor Destiny, ed. D. Lederman and
W. F. Maloney. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Mehlum, H., K. Moene, and R. Torvik. 2006. “Institutions and the Resource
Curse.” Economic Journal 116 (508): 1–20.
Prasad, E., R. Rajan, and A. Subramanian. 2006. “Foreign Capital and Economic Growth.” Paper presented at a Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
City conference, Jackson Hole, WY, August 25.
———. 2007. “Foreign Capital and Economic Growth.” Working Paper
13619. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Razin, O., and S. M. Collins. 1999. “Real-Exchange-Rate Misalignments and
Growth.” In The Economics of Globalization: Policy Perspectives from Public Economics, ed. A. Razin and E. Sadka. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge
University Press.
Reinhart, C. M., and K. S. Rogoff. 2010. “Growth in a Time of Debt.” Working Paper 15639. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge,
MA.
Robinson, J. A., R. Torvik, and T. Verdier. 2006. “Political Foundations of
the Resource Curse.” Journal of Development Economics 79 (2): 447–68.
Sachs, J. D., and A. M. Warner. 1995. “Natural Resource Abundance and
Economic Growth.” Working Paper 5398. National Bureau of Economic
Research, Cambridge, MA.
———. 2001. “The Curse of Natural Resources.” European Economic Review
45 (4–6): 827–38.
Sala-i-Martin, X., and A. Subramanian. 2003. “Addressing the Natural Resource Curse: An Illustration from Nigeria.” Working Paper 03/139. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Serven, L. 2003. “Real-Exchange-Rate Uncertainty and Private Investment
in LDCS.” Review of Economics and Statistics 85 (1):212–18.
Spatafora, N., and A. Warner. 1995. “Macroeconomic Effects of Terms-ofTrade Shocks.” Policy Research Working Paper 1410. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Tornell, A., and P. R. Lane. 1999. “The Voracity Effect.” American Economic
Review 89 (1): 22–46.
van der Ploeg, F., and S. Poelhekke. 2009. “Volatility and the Natural Resource Curse.” Oxford Economic Papers 61: 727–60.
van Wijnbergen, S. 2008. “The Permanent Income Approach in Practice.”
Unpublished manuscript. Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Network, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Williamson, J. 2008. “Exchange Rate Economics.” Working Paper 2. Commission on Growth and Development, Washington, DC.
Zanello, A., and D. Desruelle. 1997. “A Primer on the IMF’s Information
Notice System.” Working Paper 97/71. International Monetary Fund,
Washington, DC.
The Economic Premise note series is intended to summarize good practices and key policy findings on topics related to economic policy. It is produced by the Poverty
Reduction and Economic Management (PREM) Network Vice-Presidency of the World Bank. The views expressed here are those of the authors and do not necessarily
reflect those of the World Bank. The notes are available at www.worldbank.org/economicpremise.