European Politics and Society
ISSN: 2374-5118 (Print) 2374-5126 (Online) Journal homepage: https://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rpep21
In the name of the people: left populists versus
right populists
José Rama & Andrés Santana
To cite this article: José Rama & Andrés Santana (2020) In the name of the people:
left populists versus right populists, European Politics and Society, 21:1, 17-35, DOI:
10.1080/23745118.2019.1596583
To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/23745118.2019.1596583
Published online: 22 Mar 2019.
Submit your article to this journal
Article views: 428
View related articles
View Crossmark data
Citing articles: 1 View citing articles
Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at
https://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=rpep21
EUROPEAN POLITICS AND SOCIETY
2020, VOL. 21, NO. 1, 17–35
https://doi.org/10.1080/23745118.2019.1596583
In the name of the people: left populists versus right populists
José Rama
and Andrés Santana
Edificio de Ciencias Jurídicas, Autonomous University of Madrid, Madrid, Spain
ABSTRACT
KEYWORDS
Using the 8th Round of the European Social Survey, we analyse
the electoral competition between left-wing (LWPPs) and rightwing populist parties (RWPPs) in the six European countries
where this type of competition has occurred (France, Germany,
Iceland, Italy, Lithuania and The Netherlands). By focusing on
the competition between populist parties in the same sample
of countries we can resolve what tells apart a LWPP voter from
a RWPP voter. Thus, we study the factors that explain their
different voting behaviour and confine our attention to the four
main factors that affect populist competition: anti-elite attitudes,
material deprivation, euro-scepticism and anti-immigration
attitudes. Our results show that LWPPs and RWPPs voters are
similar in their attitudes towards immigration and the European
Union (EU) but differ in their attitudes towards elites and
material deprivation.
Populism; left-wing populist
parties; right-wing populist
parties; vote; electoral
behaviour; globalisation;
immigration; material
deprivation; European Union;
political elites
Populism is on the rise. From Central and Eastern European countries (e.g. Jobbik in
Hungary, and Law and Justice in Poland) to Western and Southern ones (e.g. Party for
Freedom in The Netherlands, and Podemos in Spain), populist parties have attracted a
notable electoral support in recent elections. Accordingly, a growing corpus of academic
work has examined the determinants of their electoral success.1
Given that the populist upsurge has involved parties with different ideologies, some
studies have analysed the cultural and economic determinants of the support for populist
parties at large (Inglehart & Norris, 2016; Rovny & Rovny, 2017; Springford & Tilford, 2017;
van der Waal & Koster, 2017). Indeed, there are scholars who defend that it is not useful to
distinguish between populism on the left and on the right (Clark, Bottom, & Copus, 2008;
Judis, 2016; Rivero, Zarzalejos, & del Palacio, 2017) and populist parties’ leaders often argue
that the traditional left-right divide is no longer valid.
Nevertheless, most works have pointed out that populist parties are not only characterised by their populist element but also by their thick ideology (Mudde, 2004). There is also
increasing agreement that belonging to one or the other breed of populist parties has
important implications, which even affect how the pure people are portrayed (Otjes & Louwerse, 2015, p. 61).
These differences should not obscure the fact that populist parties from different ideological blocks share important characteristics. Rooduijn and Akkerman (2015) argue that
CONTACT José Rama
jose.rama@uam.es
Edificio de Ciencias Jurídicas, Autonomous University of Madrid, 1ª
Planta, Office D01, C/Marie Curie, 1, Ciudad Universitaria de Cantoblanco, Madrid 28049, Spain
© 2019 Informa UK Limited, trading as Taylor & Francis Group
18
J. RAMA AND A. SANTANA
radical left and radical right parties ‘do not differ significantly from each other when it
comes to their populism’ (p. 8) and have the same message: ‘corrupt elites neglect the
interests of ordinary people’ (p. 9). Let us illustrate this with a few examples: in Great
Britain, Clark et al. (2008) compare the British Nationalist Party (BNP) and the Respect
Party (the first one a RWPP and the second, a LWPP), and find that they are remarkably
similar in terms of authoritarianism, anti-elitism and community-focused politics
(p. 527). Likewise, the coalition built by Syriza and ANEL after the 2015 Greek general elections (respectively, a LWPP and a RWPP) has reinforced the so-called theory of the two
extremes whereby left and right populists have essential (proto-extremist) commonalities
(Anastasakis, 2013). The coalition between Di Maio’s Five Star Movement (M5S) and Salvini’s Lega is another recent case of a government conformed by populist parties which
differ in their ideological dimension. In fact, these examples are consistent with the socalled horseshoe hypothesis (Faye, 2002), which states that supporters of LWPPs and
RWPPs are quite similar and share individual characteristics (hence, the predictors of
voting for a LWPP or RWPP would be largely the same).
The question is: to what extent do these common characteristics imply that LWPPs and
RWPPs compete for a similar electoral base? And, when they do, how does their ideological
leaning shape this competition? The bulk of our knowledge on the electoral bases of
populist parties stems from case studies and comparative studies that are circumscribed
to either LWPPs (March, 2011) or RWPPs (Mudde, 2007).
Comparative studies highlight that young, highly educated urban dwellers are more
prone to support LWPPs (Segatti & Capuzzi, 2016). Those with lower class positions have
also been shown to be more likely to vote for populist radical left parties (Lubbers &
Scheepers, 2007), and those who identify with the working class are more likely to
vote for the radical left (Ramiro, 2016). Several case studies point in the same direction:
for instance, the contributions of Fernández-Albertos (2015) and Orriols and Cordero
(2016) for Podemos in Spain, or Teperoglou, Tsatsanis, and Nicolacopoulos (2015) for
Syriza in Greece. Comparative investigations focused on RWPPs point out that their
support grows among males who belong to the youngest and oldest age cohorts (Arzheimer & Carter, 2006), the low educated (Arzheimer, 2009), the unemployed (Lubbers,
Gijsberts, & Scheepers, 2002) and the lower social classes (Van der Brug et al., 2000).2 By
and large, the common understanding is that LWPPs attract people with high levels of
education, middle class and young, whereas RWPPs gain their strongest support from
the less educated, old and working class (Hernández & Kriesi, 2016). Both types of
voters do, however, come from similar social strata, in that both are more likely to be
manual workers, unemployed and with low incomes (Visser, Lubbers, Kraaykamp, &
Jaspers, 2014).
Although these are certainly relevant insights, it is essential not to overlook that they
rest ultimately on the comparison of different sets of countries. In the case of RWPP, the
sample of countries is likely to include Austria, Belgium, Finland, Great Britain, Hungary,
Slovenia, Sweden and Switzerland, as well as some that are also considered in studies on
LWPPs. Studies on LWPPs, in turn, are bound to include countries not present in studies
on RWPPs, such as Spain and Estonia. Visser et al. (2014) as well as Rooduijn (2017)
include both LWPPs and RWPPs in their studies with the explicit goal of comparing
voters from both, but most of the countries analysed have only one type of populist
party.
EUROPEAN POLITICS AND SOCIETY
19
Hence, despite the important progress in the state of the art, comparisons of the supporters’ characteristics of the two populist families have usually been indirect, and we still
lack a systematic comparison of LWPPs and RWPPs with the same sample of countries for
both. Filling this gap is important because the conclusions regarding the effects of any set
of independent variables upon a variable of interest (in this case, support for LWPPs or
RWPPs) may be an artefact of the characteristics of electoral competition within countries.
For instance, lower social strata do not have the option to vote for a LWPP in countries
where there only is a RWPP. Perhaps they would have voted for a LWPP if there had
been one in their country. This problem is solved in the current study: we offer more
robust conclusions because we focus on those countries where both kinds of populist
parties exist, i.e. our inferences are derived from the same sample (in this case, countries),
not from indirect comparisons of different cases.
Our work concentrates on electoral populist competition. The main question we
address is: what tells apart a LWPP voter from a RWPP voter?3 We confine our attention
to four factors that are especially related to populist competition: anti-elite and anti-immigration attitudes, material deprivation, and euro-scepticism. We draw on the 8th round of
the ESS (ESS Round 8: European Social Survey Round 8 Data, 2016), from now on, ESS
(2016).
1. Theory and hypotheses
1.1. Material deprivation
Economic factors have been recurrently singled out to understand the renewed success of
populist parties. Some investigations have underlined the importance of economic downturns (Kriesi & Pappas, 2015), the worsening of personal economic conditions (Eatwell,
2003, p. 53), or the perception that the country’s economy is performing poorly (Mols &
Jetten, 2017). At the aggregate level, numerous scholars have held the Great Recession
(the global financial crisis that set out in 2008) responsible for the rise of populist
parties (Funke, Schularick, & Trebesch, 2015). Country case-studies show that the
regions most severely exposed to the crisis have witnessed more significant increases in
the support for populist parties – see Kestilä and Söderlund (2007) and Ivalid, Lanzone,
and Dutozia (2016) for the 2004 and 2015 French regional elections, respectively. For
instance, in the 2016 American Presidential elections, Trump obtained the largest increase
in support (as compared to the Republican record four years before) in the poorest and
most hardly hit regions, i.e. the most depressed regions and those offering fewer economic opportunities (Fernández-Albertos, 2018, pp. 37–38). Moreover, Trump was most
effective at capturing voters among the most economically vulnerable individuals,
which indicates that the strong negative correlation between support for him and good
economic performance extends to the individual level.
More generally, changes in the occupational structure in the West that derive from the
technological economy have generated rising economic insecurity and social deprivation
among the most vulnerable citizens (Oesch & Rennwald, 2018). This certainly includes the
unemployed, but also unskilled workers, whose wages and social prestige have been
falling steadily under Republicans and Democrats, conservatives and social democrats,
mainstream right-wing and left-wing parties (Kitschelt & Rhem, 2015). Feeling that
20
J. RAMA AND A. SANTANA
social democrats and socialists are no longer able or willing to improve their situation
(McGann & Kitschelt, 2005), unskilled workers are increasingly ready to listen to whomever
promises to address their concerns. RWPPs leaders have identified the culprits of unskilled
workers’ worsening situation and sketched out a plan to revert it. Professional politicians of
traditional parties, international elites, and immigrants are among the usual culprits. Solutions emphasise restrictions to the mobility of goods (more protectionism) and
persons (barriers to immigrants, who steal ‘our’ work). As it happened with the sirens,
whose song lured Ulysses’ sailors to shipwreck, the promises of easy solutions have
been for many voters too attractive to ignore. Millions have abandoned their social democrat and socialist parties and embraced RWPPs in the developed world (Ivarsflaten, 2005).
That vulnerable individuals may also be lured by the populist promises of LWPPs should
come as no surprise. Hobolt and Tilley (2016) argue that, after the Great Recession, the
voters most affected by the economic crisis were more prone to support challenger
parties of the left than cast a vote for mainstream parties. Consistently, Bosch and
Durán (2017) show that economic variables were the key explanatory factors to account
for the success of Podemos in the 2015 Spanish general elections, and Teperoglou et al.
(2015) report that unemployed people were more likely to support Syriza in the 2014 European elections in Greece. Santana and Rama (2018) extend this line of thought and argue
that the vulnerable electors attracted by LWPPs may have a different social profile.
Especially in Southern Europe, were youth unemployment is remarkably high4, a significant contingent of youngsters with university education feels attracted to LWPPs
because their discourse focuses on the economy (Hobolt & Tilley, 2016) while mainstream
parties are unable to solve their economic and social problems. Considering that vulnerable electors are mobilised by RWPP and LWPP, we expect the following:
H1: Those who anticipate material deprivation will tend to support LWPPs and RWPPs in the
same way. In operational terms, we expect that being unemployed or lacking the money to
make ends meet will not have statistically significant effects on the decision to vote for
LWPPs or RWPPs.
1.2. Protest voting and anti-elite attitudes
The most characteristic defining trait of populism is the distinction between a pure, virtuous people and a corrupt, dishonest elite (Mudde, 2004, p. 543). Moved perhaps by the
desire to show their discontent with the elites, people who distrust the political elite are
especially prone to vote for populist parties (Bergh, 2004; Bowler, Denemark, Donovan,
& McDonnell, 2016; Oesch, 2008). Given that the distinction between the two antagonistic
groups, the people and the elite, should apply to both LWPPs and RWPPs, anti-elite attitudes and beliefs should favour both.
Yet, little is known as to which of the populist families is more successful at capitalising
the potential of protest voting. The depiction of elites as a corrupt cartel acting only on
behalf of their own interests and against the bulk of the population is perhaps the most
characteristic trait of LWPPs. Indeed, leaders such as Pablo Iglesias (Podemos) in Spain,
Beppe Grillo (M5S) in Italy, and Alexis Tsipras (Syriza) in Greece have coined the term
casta to refer to the political establishment as a whole. Likewise, the diatribes against
the traditional politicians are part of the daily menu of the speeches of Geert Wilders
(PVV) in the Netherlands, Marine Le Pen (FN) in France, or Nigel Farage (UKIP) in the UK.
EUROPEAN POLITICS AND SOCIETY
21
Thus, many studies have shown that the discourse of RWPPs recurrently employs a Manichean distinction between the pure people and the corrupt elite (Mudde & Rovira Kaltwasser, 2018). Taking all this into account, we advance our first hypothesis:
H2: Those who mistrust in political parties will tend to support both LWPPs and RWPPs, but
this will not provide any comparative advantage to either of them. In operational terms,
we do not expect distrust to have statistically significant effects on the decision to vote for
LWPPs or RWPPs.
1.3. Parochialism, globalisation, and attitudes towards the EU
The role of cultural factors has also been emphasised by many scholars. According to the
globalization hypothesis, the processes of denationalisation and political and economic
integration have produced a contrast between the winners and the losers of globalisation.
The losers (low-skilled) are supposed to be mobilised by populist right parties, whereas the
winners (high-skilled) by left (populist or not) parties (Hernández & Kriesi, 2016).
One of the key explanatory factors in this hypothesis, in its Western European version, is
the European Union process of integration (the other is immigration and will be discussed
later). Many scholars have found that negative attitudes towards EU integration explain
the support for RWPP and that the link between RWPPs and their voters tends to be stronger when the former adopt extremely negative positions on this issue (Gómez-Reino & Llamazares, 2015). Yet, there are reasons to expect that LWPPs will also mobilise those who
are critical of European integration. According to Hooghe and Marks (2017), ‘radical left
parties reject European integration on the grounds that it hurts those who cannot take
advantage of transnational mobility’ (p. 17). Moreover, protectionism has historically
been an important issue in LWPPs’ rhetoric (March, 2008, p. 128) and seems to be a relevant dimension on radical left parties’ competition (Burgoon, 2013). Empirical evidence
also suggests that those who are critical towards EU integration are more likely to vote
for LWPP (March & Rommerskirchen, 2015). For Halikiopoulou, Nanou, and Vasilopoulou
(2012, p. 524, 531), ‘issues of cultural identity and European integration’, including the
‘national-populism of the left’ mean that ‘Radical right- and left-wing parties side together’
(see in March, 2017).
Taking all this into consideration, it seems reasonable to expect that critical attitudes
towards globalisation and EU integration will be important for both LWPPs and RWPPs.
Hence, we formulate our third hypothesis:
H3: Those with overall negative attitudes towards the EU will be equally likely to vote for
LWPPs and RWPPs. In operational terms, we do not expect attitudes towards the EU to
have statistically significant effects on the decision to vote for LWPPs or RWPPs.
1.4. Nativism and attitudes towards migration
One of the leitmotivs of the research on populism is that those who perceive immigration
as a threat to their way of life tend to support challenger parties of the right (Hobolt &
Tilley, 2016). Indeed, as Paul Taggart has pointed out in his contribution to the Oxford
Handbook of Populism, ‘there has been an almost universal tendency to treat the
parties that focus on this issue as being synonymous with populist parties in Western
Europe’ (2017, p. 251). Not in vain, ‘the rise of populist radical right parties is linked to
22
J. RAMA AND A. SANTANA
mass immigration and multiculturalism, and support for these parties is mostly an
expression of nativism’ (Mudde & Rovira Kaltwasser, 2018, p. 13).
The issue is less clear for LWPPs. On the one hand, Hooghe and Marks (2017) defend
that ‘radical left parties (…) retain a commitment to working-class internationalism and
do not take a strong position against immigration’ (p.17). However, Halikiopoulou et al.
(2012) argue that ‘nationalism is the underlying feature that unites the radical right and
the radical left’ (p. 505), and some case studies suggest that, even if the leaders of
LWPPs do not emphasise the issue of migration in their programmes and speeches,
their voters may feel more strongly about it: ‘Sinn Féin supporters are more likely to feel
that there are already too many immigrants in Ireland’ (O’Malley, 2008, p. 971). In fact,
in a comparative study of the 2014 European Parliament elections, Santana and Rama
(2018) show that voters with anti-immigration attitudes are more prone to support
LWPPs than other left parties. Given that the arguments are consistent for RWPPs but
highly controversial for LWPPs, we expect the following:
H4: Negative attitudes towards migration and immigrants will work in favour of RWPPs.
In operational terms, we expect that having negative attitudes towards immigrants will
have statistically significant positive effects on the decision to vote for a RWPP instead
of a LWPP.
2. Data
We use Round 8th of the ESS, 2016, which contains data on 44,387 individuals from 23
countries, including six European countries where RWPPs and LWPPs coexist (Germany,
France, Italy, Iceland, Lithuania and The Netherlands). Data were collected during 2016
and 2017,5 using random probability sampling and face to face interviews.
Our dependent variable distinguishes between respondents who declare having voted
for a LWPP (Y = 1) and those who have opted for a RWPP (Y = 0). Abstainers and voters of
non-populist parties are recoded as missing. We have drawn on other scholars’ work for
the classification of parties as LWPP or RWPP. Classifications are liable to potential criticism
and different authors have put forward different classifications of populist parties (Inglehart & Norris, 2016; Mair, 2013; van Kessel, 2015). Our approach has been rather conservative because we have followed the most widely accepted criteria in this field. Table 1
exhibits the parties analysed in this inquiry.
The operationalisation of our independent variables is as follows (see Table A1 in the
Appendix with the number of observations, mean, standard deviation, minimum and
maximum for each variable). In model 1, we consider two indicators of expected material
deprivation: the perception that one is likely to be unemployed in the next 12 months (a
four-item ordinal variable, recoded as a dummy, 1 = likely or very likely, 0 = not at all or
not very likely) and the belief that one’s household necessities will be uncovered due to
money shortages in the next 12 months (again, a four-item ordinal variable recoded as a
dummy, 1 = likely or very likely, 0 = not at all or not very likely).
Model 2 focuses on the anti-elite dimension which, to a varying extent, characterises
populist parties. The best measure available in the ESS, 2016 questionnaire is mistrust in
political parties (an eleven-point scale variable, rescaled to grow with mistrust, 0 = complete trust, 10 = no trust at all). Although it would have been interesting to include mistrust
in the national parliament as well, its correlation with the former was above 0.7.
Table 1. Classification of parties into LWPPs and RWPPs.
Family
France (FR)
LWPPb
RWPPc
Iceland (IS)
LWPP
RWPP
Italy (IT)
LWPPd
RWPPe,f
Party name
GEa
EP
LR
LRE
AE
CS
EUP
EUB
RI
1.7
9.6
1.1
5.7
9.0
9.5
7.2
7.9
3.3
2.2
1.3
1.1
2.4
9.8
4.7
8.9
6.7
7.9
3.4
7.3
7.0
5.6
10.0
8.8
4.0
6.3
9.8
6.4
3.2
5.8
3.3
2.8
n.a.
3.8
1.3
1.1
2.1
1.4
4.3
9.5
7.8
8.8
Front de Gauche (FG); then La France insoumise (FI)
Front National (FN)
Left Front; then Unbowed France
National Front
19.6 (#4)
21.3 (#2)
6.6 (#6)
24.8 (#1)
Píratar (P)
Framsóknarflokkurinn
Flokkur fólksins (F)
The Pirate Party
Progressive Party
People’s Party
9.2 (#6)
10.7 (#5)
6.9 (#7)
n.a. (not applicable)
Five Star Movement
Northern League; then League
Forward Italy / Let’s Go Italy
Brothers of Italy
32.7
17.4
14.0
4.4
21.2
6.2
16.8
3.7
Socialist Party
50PLUS
Party for Liberty
9.1 (#6)
3.1 (#10)
13.1 (#2)
9.6 (#5)
3.7 (#10)
13.3 (#3)
1.0
5.3
9.3
1.0
3.7
4.6
6.6
5.8
9.4
3.3
2.5
5.0
3.3
n.a.
1.3
1.5
5.5
1.0
4.4
5.0
9.9
The Left
National Democratic Party of Germany
Alternative for Germany
7.4 (#5)
0.1 (#11)
12.6 (#3)
9.7 (#4)
1.0 (#11)
7.1 (#5)
1.2
n.a.
8.9
1.3
5.3
8.3
5.4
9.1
7.8
3.1
3.0
3.8
5.3
1.9
2.4
2.7
1.2
2.5
4.0
9.0
9.3
4.4
6.6
4.7
4.4
4.7
7.5
3.6
6.3
4.7
n.a.
4.3
2.9
4.4
6.5
Movimento 5 Stelle (M5S)
Lega Nord (LN); then La Lega (L)
Forza Italia (FI)
Fratelli d’Italia (FdI)
The Netherlands (NL)
LWPP
Socialistische Partij (SP)
RWPP
50PLUS
Partij voor de Vrijheid (PVV)
Germany (DE)
LWPP
Die Linke
RWPP
Nationaldemokratische Partei Deutschlands (NPD)
Alternative für Deutschland (AfD)
Lithuania (LT) g
LWPP
Darbo Partija (DP)
RWPP
Tvarka ir Teisingumas (TT)
Labour Party
Order and Justice
(#1)
(#3)
(#4)
(#5)
4.9 (#8)
5.6 (#7)
(#2)
(#4)
(#3)
(#7)
12.4 (#5)
14.3 (#4)
23
GE: percentage of votes and position in the ranking of votes obtained in the country’s most recent general elections, which took place in April 2017 (France, presidential, 1st round), March 2018 (Italy), March
2017 (The Netherlands), September 2017 (Germany) and October 2016 (Lithuania). EP: As in GE, but for the 2014 European Parliament elections. LR: Overall LR placement. LRE: Economic LR placement. AE:
Anti-elite salience (salience of anti-establishment and anti-elite rhetoric: 0 = not salient at all, 10 = extremely important). CS: Salience of reducing political corruption (0 = not salient at all, 10 = extremely
important). EUP: position of the party leadership in 2014 on the powers of the European Parliament (1 = strongly opposes, 7 = strongly in favour). EUB: position of the party leadership on EU authority over
member states’ economic and budgetary policies (1 = strongly opposes, 7 = strongly in favour). RI: Restrictive immigration policy (0 = fully opposed to a restrictive policy on immigration, 10 = fully in favour).
b
FG was a coalition of the Parti Communiste Français (PCF), Parti de Gauche (PG) and Gauche Unitaire (GU), among other far, radical or illiberal left parties. Jean-Luc Mélenchon was its leading candidate in the
2014 EP elections. In 2016, he founded FI (known in English as Unbowed France, Unsubmissive France, or Untamed France), being its leading candidate in the 2017 Presidential elections.
c
On 1 June 2018, the FN was renamed as Rassemblement National (RN), i.e. National Rally.
d
Although we justify why we consider the M5S as a LWPP (see the source of this table) we want to reinforce our decision by the results exhibited on the expert survey conducted by Di Virgilio, Giannetti, and
Pedrazzani (2015) during the 2013 national elections, which shows that the mainstream centre-left Democratic Party (PD) and the M5S are very close to each other on the economic left-right dimension. In
this vein, the Comparative Manifestos Project (CMP) locates the M5S on the left of both the PD and Left Ecology Freedom (SEL). For more information, see (Franchino & Negri, 2018).
e
On 28 January 2018, LN was rebranded as Lega, although the official name was not formally changed.
f
On 29 March 2009, Il Popolo della Libertà was created to assemble Berlusconi’s Forza Italia (FI) and Fini’s Alleanza Nazionale. On 16 November 2013, it was dissolved and FI was relaunched.
g
Following van Kessel (2015, p. 58) we do not include The Way of Courage as an RWPP due to its idiosyncratic character.
Source: own elaboration based on Segatti and Capuzzi (2016, p. 54) and Fella and Ruzza (2013, p. 49) for the case of the M5S, Bobba and Roncarlo (2018) for the PdL (also Pappas, 2016, p. 34) and the FdI, and
Rensmann, de Lange, and Couperus (2017, p. 155) for the League in Italy; Otjes and Louwerse (2015) for the SP, Hameleers, Bos, and de Vreese (2017, p. 138) for 50PLUS and Rensmann et al. (2017, p. 155) for
the PVV in the Netherlands; Alekonis and Matkeviciené (2016) for the DP and the TT in Lithuania; Rensmann et al. (2017, p. 155) for the FN and Stockemer (2018) for the FDG in France; March (2007) for Die
Linke, Rensmann et al. (2017, p. 155) for AfD and Nociar and Thomeczek (2018) for the NPD in Germany; finally, Eiermann, Mounk, and Gultchin (2017) for P, F and the Progressive Party in Iceland. Data on the
last columns have been obtained from the 2014 Chapell-Hill Expert Survey, or CHES 2014 (Bakker et al., 2015).
EUROPEAN POLITICS AND SOCIETY
a
Party name (English)
24
J. RAMA AND A. SANTANA
In model 3, we contemplate two eleven-point scale variables capturing attitudes
towards the EU, which we inverted so that smaller values correspond to more cosmopolitan and bigger values to more parochial orientations: how unfavourable to EU unification
are the interviewees (10 = EU unification has gone too far, 0 = unification should be
pushed further) and emotional detachment from Europe (10 = not at all emotionally
attached, 0 = very emotionally attached).
In model 4, we include two variables related to attitudes towards migrants, which we
rescaled so that smaller values correspond to more positive attitudes towards them and
bigger ones to more negative ones. The first one is an eleven-point scale on the effect
of immigrants on the country’s economy (rescaled as 10 = bad, 0 = good), which captures
the economic dimension of citizens’ attitudes towards migration. The second is a question
on how inclined interviewees are to allow immigrants of different races to live in the country
(a four-item ordinal variable, recoded as a dummy, 0 = allow some or many, 1 = allow a few
or none), and captures the cultural dimension of attitudes towards migration.
Model 5 is the full model, in which all the variables of models 1–4 are simultaneously
considered; this is possible, as the VIFs (variance inflation factors) of all independent variables are well below the levels that would rise concerns of collinearity problems (Table A1).
In all models, we control for ideology (0 = left, 10 = right) and for a series of sociodemographic variables, namely gender (1 = woman, 0 = man), age (in years), and education (university level = 1). All the models include survey weights (post-stratification weights, which
subsume design weights and therefore redress the different probabilities of being surveyed as well as the differences in the response rates), country dummies and country clusters (to address the hierarchical structure of the data).6
3. Results
Figure 1 displays the results of the logistic regressions of the main models7 (see also Table
A2 in the Appendix). The graph shows the independent variables standardised (standard
deviation = 1). As we have mentioned, we run the logistic regression with country clusters
and employing the survey weights. Additionally, we run all the models with the same
number of observations to prevent results from changing because of the number of
cases. Model 1, focused on the economic deprivation thesis, evinces that neither the probability of being unemployed in the next 12 months nor the probability that household
necessities will be uncovered in the next 12 months have a statistically significant effect
on the probability of voting for a LWPP instead of a RWPP. Model 2 reveals that the mistrust in political parties does not condition the casting of a vote in favour of a LWPP or a
RWPP. Model 3, related to the EU dimensions, exhibits a negative relationship of parochial
attitudes to EU unification with LWPP support: the belief that EU unification has gone too
far reduces the propensity to vote for LWPPs as compared to RWPPs. Model 4 shows that
attitudes towards immigrants (including perceptions about the impact of immigrants on
the country’s economy and attitudes towards allowing immigrants of different races to
live in their country) do not condition the support for a LWPP as against a RWPP.
However, the full model (Model 5) amends the results of Model 2: those who mistrust
political parties are more prone to support a LWPP than a RWPP. The elite dimension fits
better with LWPPs than RWPPs, at least when both types of parties compete in the same
country. Thus, although RWPPs also employ a discourse that criticises the corrupt elite and
EUROPEAN POLITICS AND SOCIETY
25
Figure 1. Coefficient plots for LWPP support vs RWPP.
extols the good people, LWPPs enjoy an advantage on this dimension. Additionally, Model 5
reveals that those with difficulties to pay for their household necessities are more likely to
vote for a LWPP, whereas the probability of being unemployed is not statistically significant.
On top of the country dummies, all models include controls for gender, age, education and
left-right ideology (see Table A2 for the detailed results). Age displays consistently negative
effects, indicating that older individuals are less prone to vote for LWPPs than for RWPPs.
Unsurprisingly, left-right ideological self-placement also displays a significantly negative
effect. Although the effects of being female and having high education are negative, they
fail to attain statistical significance in any of the models (a more nuanced measure of education, distinguishing among four levels of education, also fails to attain statistical significance). Given that Lithuania is the only Eastern European country and that its parties
appear relatively centrist from the position data (Table 1), we have rerun Model 5 excluding
Lithuania: as Figure A1 in the Appendix show, results remain almost unaltered.
Figures 2–5 display the effects of our four key groups of independent variables upon
the probability of voting for LWPPs vis à vis RWPPs (all other variables are held at their
means). Figure 2 confirms that in those countries in which LWPPs and RWPPs coexist,
voters feel that both can solve their unemployment problems equally well (or bad). The
95 confidence intervals of the predicted probability of voting of those who feel likely or
very likely to become unemployed clearly overlap with the ones for those who feel unlikely
or very unlikely to lose their jobs and, as the footnote clarifies, a formal contrast of the
difference between both clearly fails to attain statistical significance. Yet, as the right
panel shows, those who fear to experience difficulties to pay for their household necessities are more prone to vote for LWPP. Hence, our first hypothesis is partially rejected. The
significant effect of the second measure of material deprivation may owe to the left-wing
parties’ traditional emphasis on economic redistribution (Lipset, Lazarsfeld, Barton, & Linz,
1954) and the consequent alignment between voters and parties along this dimension.
Figure 3 underlines that the propensity to cast a vote for a LWPP increases as the mistrust in political parties grows. This effect is not only statistically but also substantively significant: whereas for those who have complete trust in political parties the predicted
26
J. RAMA AND A. SANTANA
Figure 2. Predictive margins for the effects of key independent variables upon the probability of voting
LWPPs vs RWPPs, material deprivation.
Figure 3. Predictive margins for the effects of key independent variables upon the probability of voting
LWPPs vs RWPPs, elite dimension.
probability of voting for a LWPP is 0.37, this figure rises to 0.54 for those who do not trust in
them at all. Thus, in those countries in which LWPPs and RWPPs coexist, LWPPs take advantage of their competitors of the right on the populist anti-elite dimension. This runs
EUROPEAN POLITICS AND SOCIETY
27
Figure 4. Predictive margins for the effects of key independent variables upon the probability of voting
LWPPs vs RWPPs, EU dimension.
Figure 5. Predictive margins for the effects of key independent variables upon the probability of voting
LWPPs vs RWPPs, immigration dimension.
28
J. RAMA AND A. SANTANA
counter to our second hypothesis, which must therefore be rejected. What could explain
this unexpected result? Our take is that the anti-elite discourses of RWPP leaders are often
intertwined with Eurosceptic and anti-immigration arguments; for instance, they justify
their criticism towards elites because they claim that the latter facilitate the uncontrolled
entrance of migrants. Using Mudde and Rovira Kaltwasser’s words: ‘these parties use populist rhetoric to blame “the elite” for help bringing the “aliens” into the country and for
ignoring the problems that “natives” are suffering’ (2018, p. 12). As compared to this somewhat diffuse reproach, the criticism of LWPPs tends to be more focused and recurrent as
they portray the casta as enemy number one.
However, Figure 4 underlines that none of the measures of parochialism affect the competition among populist parties, given the very large confidence intervals associated to the
predictions related to both variables. At most, it can be noticed that those who believe that
EU integration should be pushed further or has not gone too far (values 0–5 of the ‘EU integration has gone too far’ variable) are more likely to vote for LWPPs than those who think
that it has gone too far (values 6–10). These minor differences may owe to the fact that
LWPPs voters do not consider belonging to the EU as a bad thing per se; however, the overlapping of the confidence intervals and the lack of significance of the variable in Figure 1
and Table A2 suggest that their acceptance of the EU integration process is, at most, conditional. That is, they believe in a different type of EU which is not an elitist capitalist
project that ignores the interests of ‘the common working man’ (Kriesi & Pappas, 2015).
As to the other measure of parochialism (right panel of Figure 4), even if the slope of
the effect of emotional detachment to Europe is also negative, the slope is rather flat,
and the 95 per cent confidence intervals are very large, precluding any possible effects
of this variable on the propensity to vote for a LWPP or a RWPP. Hence, our third hypothesis is confirmed, and it is so for the two measures of parochialism.
Finally, Figure 5 displays the propensity to cast a vote for a LWPP instead of a RWPP
upon the immigration dimensions. Contrary to our fourth hypothesis, the perception
that immigrants are bad for the county’s economy and the opposition to the prospect
that immigrants of different race come and live in the country, do not condition the
support for a LWPP or a RWPP. Although the left panel illustrates that on a 0–10 scale,
the propensity to vote for a LWPP is higher among those who consider immigrants
good for the country’s economy, the 95 per cent confidence intervals overlap for all
values of this first measure of nativism. The overlapping among the two categories of
the binary measure of the opposition to the entrance of immigrants of other races is
even more evident (see the right panel). Again, the lack of significance is confirmed by
a formal contrast of the predictive margins of this variable (the p-value of the Wald test
being 0.120). Thus, nativist attitudes do not affect the left versus right populist competition, and our fourth hypothesis must be rejected. This result fits well the thesis of Dancygier and Margalit (2018), who argue that mainstream parties from the left and right
converge on immigration issues since the good days of anti-immigration parties. It is
also consistent with the situation in Italy, Germany or the Netherlands, where LWPPs
have adopted the common RWPPs’ discourses against immigration. This is the recent
case of the German party Die Linke: notwithstanding the fact that almost 400,000 electors
switched from Die Linke to AfD, the co-founder of the radical left party, Sahra Wagenknecht, created a new movement inside the party, called Aufstehen (Get Up) that
favours tighter controls for migrants trying to enter the labour market.8
EUROPEAN POLITICS AND SOCIETY
29
4. Conclusions
In this paper, we focus on the factors favouring the vote for left-wing populist parties
(LWPPs) versus right-wing populist parties (RWPPs). Instead of drawing conclusions
about the profiles of RWPP and LWPP voters from the comparison of results obtained
for different sets of countries and, therefore, samples, we study only those countries
where both LWPPs and RWPPs compete.
Although there are other interesting questions in the comparative electoral sociology of
LWPPs and RWPPs voters, such as the extent to which different sociodemographic characteristics shape the competition between the two populist families, our endeavour focuses
on the factors related to the support for populist parties, namely material deprivation, attitudes towards political elites, parochial and anti-globalisation motivations, and nativist
attitudes. Figure 6 will help to summarise our main results and enrich the scope of our conclusions beyond the direct competition of LWPPs and RWPPs by using a nominal specification of the dependent variable (LWPPs = 2, RWPPs = 1, non-populist parties = NPP = 0):
Our results have important theoretical implications. First, material deprivation theories
state that the so-called losers of globalisation tend to support RWPPs; our results show
that, when they compete with LWPPs, this effect is fully absorbed by LWPPs (material
deprivation increases the likelihood of voting for LWPPs instead of either RWPPs or
NPPs, without significant differences among the latter two).
Second, the core distinction between populist and non-populist parties should relate to
attitudes towards elites; our results show that when both breeds of populist parties
Figure 6. Coefficient plots for LWPP vs RWPP vs NPP support (baseline, NPP).
30
J. RAMA AND A. SANTANA
compete, such attitudes only increase the likelihood of voting LWPPs (again, RWPPs and
NPPs are indistinguishable).
Third, the globalisation hypothesis has been used to justify support for both types of
populist parties. Our results confirm that this is true for the detachment from Europe,
which increases the likelihood of voting a populist party (RWPPs and LWPPs being indistinguishable) versus NPPs. Nevertheless, attitudes against EU unification only favour
RWPPs.
Finally, nativist arguments have recurrently proven to be useful to understand support
for RWPPs. Interestingly, negative attitudes towards immigration, whether cultural or
economic oriented, do not have a statistically significant effect when we focus the attention on the populist ground, but the second measure of nativism (restricting immigrants of
other races) increases the propensity of voting for RWPPs instead of NPPs. All in all, when
the two breeds of populist parties are on the same playing field, they appear to be more
similar in the eyes of their voters than what it is usually assumed.
Notes
1. See Rydgren (2007) for a review of demand- and supply-side explanations of the success of
radical right-wing parties.
2. Findings are neither monolithic for LWPPs nor for RWPPs. For instance, Cordero, Orriols, and
Teperoglou (2018) fail to find statistically significant effects of age for SYRIZA or education for
Podemos. And while the main electoral support for the United Kingdom Independence Party
(UKIP) is among the oldest and without university education (Ford & Goodwin, 2014), the supporters of Golden Down in Greece and the National Front in France are young and highly educated (Stockemer, 2017; Teperoglou et al., 2015, pp. 348–350).
3. In empirical terms it means that we select those voters of a LWPP and those who vote for a
RWPP in those countries where both parties coexist. Thus, our dependent variable values 1
when a voter supports a LWPP and 0 when (s)he supports a RWPP. In other words, our aim
is not to find differences among the electoral bases of right-wing parties, socialdemocratic
parties, radical left parties, and populist from the left and the right, but to determine the
effect of a set of variables on the competition among populist parties.
4. See the ECB report ‘The impact of the Economic Crisis in the Euro Area Labour Market’. Online
access: https://goo.gl/7n3A3X.
5. The specific months for each country can be consulted in the ESS’ Data Documentation
Report: https://www.europeansocialsurvey.org/docs/round8/survey/ESS8_data_documentat
ion_report_e02_1.pdf.
6. Given the low number of level two observations, random effects multilevel models are
strongly discouraged. We also estimated a multilevel fixed effects regression which yielded
qualitatively the same results. However, as the statistical program (Stata) does not allow us
to include weights at the individual level using this kind of technique, and given the importance of weights in the ESS, we opt to report the results for the most similar approximation:
logistic regression with country dummies.
7. Each horizontal line in Figure 1 represents an independent variable of the model, the point
standing for the best estimation of its effect upon the dependent variable, and the line, for
its 95 per cent confidence interval. If a confidence interval crosses the vertical line drawn at
the origin (zero) of the horizontal axis, the effect of the variable is not statistically significant.
If it does not cross it and is located at its right, the effect is positive, whereas if it is located at its
left, the effect is negative.
8. See the articles published in The Guardian: https://www.theguardian.com/world/2018/sep/04/
german-politicians-launch-leftwing-stand-up-movement and CNN: https://edition.cnn.com/
2018/09/07/opinions/sahra-wagenknecht-opinion-intl/index.html.
EUROPEAN POLITICS AND SOCIETY
31
Acknowledgement
We wish to express our gratitude to Susana Aguilar (UCM) for her assistance on the revision of this
manuscript, to the anonymous reviewers for their insightful comments on the first version of this
manuscript, and to the participants in the First Spanish Congress of the European Social Survey
held in September 2018 in Madrid.
ORCID
José Rama
http://orcid.org/0000-0002-3990-1696
Andrés Santana
http://orcid.org/0000-0003-2594-1360
References
Alekonis, G., & Matkeviciené, R. (2016). Populism in Lithuania: Defending the research tradition. Baltic
Journal of Law and Politics, 9(1), 26–48.
Anastasakis, O. (2013). The far right in Greece and the theory of the two extremes. OpenDemocracy.
Retrieved
from
http://www.opendemocracy.net/othon-anastasakis/far-right-in-greece-andtheory-of-twoextremes-0
Arzheimer, K. (2009). Contextual factors and the extreme right vote in Western Europe, 1980–2002.
American Journal of Political Science, 53(2), 259–275.
Arzheimer, K., & Carter, E. (2006). Political opportunity structures and right-wing extremist party
success. European Journal of Political Research, 45, 419–443.
Bakker, R., Edwards, E., Hooghe, L., Jolly, S., Marks, G., Polk, J., … Vachudova, M. (2015). 2014 Chapel
Hill expert survey. Version 2015.1. Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill. Retrieved
from chesdata.eu.
Bergh, A. (2004). The universal welfare state: Theory and the case of Sweden. Political Studies, 52(4),
745–766.
Bobba, G., & Roncarlo, F. (2018). The likeability of populism on social medial in the 2018 Italian
General Election. Italian Political Science, 13(1), 51–62.
Bosch, A., & Durán, I. M. (2017). How does economic crisis impel emerging parties on the road to elections? The case of the Spanish Podemos and Ciudadanos. Party Politics. doi:10.1177/
1354068817710223
Bowler, S., Denemark, D., Donovan, T., & McDonnell, D. (2016). Right-wing populist party supporters:
Dissatisfied but not direct democrats. European Journal of Political Research, 56, 70–91.
Burgoon, B. (2013). Inequality and anti-globalization backlash by political parties. European Union
Politics, 14(3), 408–435.
Clark, A., Bottom, K., & Copus, C. (2008). More similar than they’d like to admit? Ideology, policy and
populism in the trajectories of the British National Party and respect. British Politics, 3, 511–534.
Cordero, G., Orriols, L. L., & Teperoglou, E. (2018). Syriza, M5S y Podemos: Los tres campeones del
votante enfadado en el Sur de Europa. Revista Jurídica de la Universidad Autónoma de Madrid,
37, 105–131.
Dancygier, R. M., & Margalit, Y. (2018). The evolution of the immigration debate: A study of party positions over the last half-century. doi:10.2139/ssrn.3192913
Di Virgilio, A., Giannetti, D., & Pedrazzani, A. (2015). Party competition in the 2013 Italian elections:
Evidence from an expert survey. Government and Opposition, 50(1), 65–89.
Eatwell, R. (2003). Ten theories of the extreme right. In P. Merkl & L. Weinberg (Eds.), Right-wing extremism in the twenty-first century. London: Frank Cass. Retrieved from http://opus.bath.ac.uk/11126/
Eiermann, M., Mounk, Y., & Gultchin, L. (2017). European populism: Trends, threats and future prospects.
Tony Blair Institute for Global Change. Retrieved from https://institute.global/insight/renewingcentre/european-populism-trends-threats-and-future-prospects
ESS Round 8: European Social Survey Round 8 Data. (2016). Data file edition 2.0. NSD – Norwegian
Centre for Research Data, Norway – Data Archive and distributor of ESS data for ESS ERIC.
32
J. RAMA AND A. SANTANA
Faye, J.-P. (2002). Le Siècle des idéologies. Paris: Pocket Agora.
Fella, S., & Ruzza, C. (2013). Populism and the fall of the centre-right in Italy: The end of the Berlusconi
model or a new beginning? Journal of Contemporary European Studies, 21(1), 38–52.
Fernández-Albertos, J. (2015). Los Votantes De Podemos: Del Partido De Los Indignados Al Partido De
Los Excluidos (Colección Alternativas, 12). Madrid: Los Libros de la Catarata y Fundación
Alternativas.
Fernández-Albertos, J. (2018). Antisistema. Madrid: Libros de la Catarata.
Ford, R., & Goodwin, M. (2014). Understanding UKIP: Identity, social change and the left behind. The
Political Quarterly, 85(3), 277–284.
Franchino, F., & Negri, F. (2018). The fiscally moderate Italian populist voter: Evidence from a survey
experiment. Party Politics. doi:10.1177/1354068818761180
Funke, M., Schularick, M., & Trebesch, C. (2015). Going to extremes: Politics after financial crisis, 1870–
2014 (CESIFO Working Papers n° 5553 Category 7). Monetary Policy and International Finance.
Gómez-Reino, M., & Llamazares, I. (2015). New left populism in contemporary Spain? The upsurge of
Podemos. Paper presented at the 22nd international conference of Europeanists, Paris.
Halikiopoulou, D., Nanou, K., & Vasilopoulou, S. (2012). The paradox of nationalism: The common
denominator of radical right and radical left euroscepticism. European Journal of Political
Research, 51(4), 504–539.
Hameleers, M., Bos, L., & de Vreese, C. (2017). The Netherlands: A heartland full of insights into populist communication. In T. Aalberg, F. Esser, C. Reinemann, J. Stromback, & C. de Vreese (Eds.),
Populist political communication in Europe (pp. 138–150). New York, NY: Routledge.
Hernández, E., & Kriesi, H. (2016). The electoral consequences of the financial and economic crisis in
Europe. European Journal of Political Research, 55(2), 203–224. doi:10.1111/1475-6765.12122
Hobolt, S. B., & Tilley, J. (2016). Fleeing the centre: The rise of challenger parties in the aftermath of
the euro crisis. West European Politics, 39(5), 971–991.
Hooghe, L., & Marks, G. (2017). Cleavage theory meets Europe’s crises: Lipset, Rokkan, and the transnational cleavage. Journal of European Public Policy, 25(1), 109–135.
Inglehart, R., & Norris, P. (2016). Trump, Brexit and the rise of populism: Economic have-nots and cultural
backlash (Faculty Research Working Paper Series).
Ivalid, G., Lanzone, M. E., & Dutozia, J. (2016). Explaining regional support for national-populist parties:
The case of FN in France. Populism, Regionalism and Nationalism in Western European Party
Mobilisation. The Territorial Dimension. Lausanne.
Ivarsflaten, E. (2005). The vulnerable populist right parties: No economic realignment fuelling their
electoral success. European Journal of Political Research, 44(3), 465–492.
Judis, J. B. (2016). The populist explosion: How the great recession transformed American and European
politics. New York, NY: Columbia Global Reports.
Kestilä, E., & Söderlund, P. (2007). Subnational political opportunity structures and the success of the
radical right: Evidence from the March 2004 regional elections in France. European Journal of
Political Research, 46(6), 773–796.
Kitschelt, H., & Rhem, P. (2015). Party alignments: Change and continuity. In P. Beramendi, S.
Häusermann, H. Kitschelt, & H. Kriesi (Eds.), Politics of advanced capitalism (pp. 179–201).
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Kriesi, H., & Pappas, T. (Eds.). (2015). European populism in the shadow of the great recession.
Colchester: ECPR Press.
Lipset, S. M., Lazarsfeld, P. F., Barton, A. H., & Linz, J. J. (1954). The psychology of voting: An analysis of
political behavior. In G. Lindzey (Ed.), Handbook of social psychology (pp. 1124–1175). Cambridge,
MA: Addison-Wesley.
Lubbers, M., Gijsberts, M., & Scheepers, P. (2002). Extreme right-wing voting in Western Europe.
European Journal of Political Research, 41(3), 345–378.
Lubbers, M, & Scheepers, P. (2007). Explanations of Political Euroescepticism at the Individual
Regional and National Levels. European Societies, 9(4), 643–689.
Mair, P. (2013). Ruling the void. The hollowing of western democracy. London: Verso Books.
March, L. (2007). From Vanguard of the proletariat to Vox Populi: Left-populism as a ‘shadow’ of contemporary socialism. SAIS Review of International Affairs, 27(1), 63–77.
EUROPEAN POLITICS AND SOCIETY
33
March, L. (2011). Radical left parties in contemporary Europe. Abingdon: Routledge.
March, L. (2017). Left and right populism compared: The British case. The British Journal of Politics and
International Relations, 19(2), 282–203.
March, L. (2008). Contemporary far left parties in Europe: From marxism to the mainstream. Bonn:
Friedrich Ebert Stiftung.
March, L., & Rommerskirchen, C. (2015). Out of left field? Explaining the variable electoral success of
European radical left parties. Party Politics, 21(1), 40–53.
McGann, A. J., & Kitschelt, H. (2005). The radical right in the Alps. Party Politics, 11(2), 147–171.
Mols, F., & Jetten, J. (2017). The wealth paradox. Economic prosperity and the hardening of attitudes.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Mudde, C. (2004). The populist zeitgeist. Government and Opposition, 39(4), 541–563. doi:10.1111/j.
1477-7053.2004.00135.x
Mudde, C. (2007). Populist radical right parties in Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Mudde, C., & Rovira Kaltwasser, C. (2018). Studying populism in comparative perspective: Reflections
on the contemporary and future research agenda. Comparative Political Studies. doi:10.1177/
0010414018789490
Nociar, T., & Thomeczek, P. (2018). Far right politics in Germany: From fascism to populism? The London
School of Economics and Political Science. Retrieved from http://blogs.lse.ac.uk/europpblog/2018/
01/24/far-right-politics-in-germany-from-fascism-to-populism/
Oesch, D. (2008). Explaining workers’ support for right-wing populist parties in Western Europe:
Evidence from Austria, Belgium, France, Norway, and Switzerland. International Political Science
Review, 29(3), 349–373.
Oesch, D., & Rennwald, L. (2018). Electoral competition in Europe’s new tripolar political space: Class
voting for the left, centre-right and radical right. European Journal of Political Research, 57(4),
783–807.
O’Malley, E. (2008). Why is there no radical right party in Ireland? West European Politics, 31(5),
960–977.
Orriols, L., & Cordero, G. (2016). The breakdown of the Spanish two-party system: The upsurge of
Podemos and Ciudadanos in the 2015 general election. South European Society and Politics, 21
(4), 469–492.
Otjes, S., & Louwerse, T. (2015). Populists in parliament: Comparing left-wing and right-wing populism in the Netherlands. Political Studies, 63(1), 60–79.
Pappas, T. (2016). Distinguishing liberal democracy’s challengers. Journal of Democracy, 27(4), 22–36.
Ramiro, L. (2016). Support for radical left parties in Western Europe: Social Background, ideology and
political orientations. European Political Science Review, 8(1), 1–23.
Rensmann, L., de Lange, S., & Couperus, S. (2017). Populism and the remaking of (il)liberal democracy
in Europe. Politics and Governance, 5(4). doi:10.17645/pag.v5i4.1328
Rivero, A., Zarzalejos, J., & del Palacio, J. (2017). Geografía del Populismo: Un viaje por el universo del
populismo desde sus orígenes hasta Trump. Madrid: Tecnos.
Rooduijn, M. (2017). What unites the voter bases of populist parties? Comparing the electorates of 15
populist parties. European Political Science Review. doi:10.1017/S1755773917000145
Rooduijn, M., & Akkerman, T. (2015). Flank attacks: Populism and left-right radicalism in Western
Europe. Party Politics. doi:10.1177/1354068815596514
Rovny, A., & Rovny, J. (2017). Outsiders at the ballot box: Operationalizations and political consequences of the insider–outsider dualism. Socio-Economic Review, 15(1), 161–185. https://doi.org/
10.1093/ser/mww039
Rydgren, J. (2007). The sociology of the radical right. Annual Review of Sociology, 33(1), 241–262.
Santana, A., & Rama, J. (2018). Electoral support for left wing populist parties in Europe: Addressing
the globalization cleavage. European Politics and Society, 19(5), 558–576.
Segatti, P., & Capuzzi, F. (2016). Five star movement, Syriza and Podemos: A mediterranean model? In
A. Martinelli (Ed.), Populism on the rise. Democracies under challenge? (pp. 47–73). Milan: Instituto
per gli Studi di Politica Internazionale.
Springford, J., & Tilford, S. (2017). Populism – culture or economics? Insight, Centre for European
Reform.
34
J. RAMA AND A. SANTANA
Stockemer, D. (2017). The economic crisis (2009–2013) and electoral support for the radical right
in Western Europe – some new and unexpected findings. Social Science Quarterly, 98(5), 1536–
1553.
Stockemer, D. (2018). Populism around the world. A comparative perspective (pp. 27–48). Cham:
Springer.
Taggart, P. (2017). Populism in Western Europe. In C. Rovira Kaltwasser, P. A. Taggart, P. Ochoa Espejo,
& P. Ostiguy (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of populism (pp. 248–264). Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Teperoglou, E., Tsatsanis, E., & Nicolacopoulos, E. (2015). Habituating to the new normal in a postearthquake party system: The 2014 European election in Greece. South European Society and
Politics, 20(3), 333–355.
Van der Brug, W, Fennema, M, & Tillie, J. (2000). Anti-immigrant parties in Europe: Ideological or
protest vote? European Journal of Political Research, 37, 77–102.
van der Waal, J., & Koster, W. (2017). Populism and support for protectionism: The relevance of opposition to trade openness for leftist and rightist populist voting in the Netherlands. Political Studies.
doi:10.1177/0032321717723505
van Kessel, S. (2015). Dutch populism during the crisis. In H. Kriesi & T. S. Pappas (Eds.), Populism in the
shadow of the great recession (pp. 109–124). Colchester: ECPR Press.
Visser, M., Lubbers, M., Kraaykamp, G., & Jaspers, E. (2014). Support for radical left ideologies in
Europe. European Journal of Political Research, 53, 541–558.
Appendix
Figure A1. Coefficient plots for LWPP support vs RWPP with and without Lithuania.
35
EUROPEAN POLITICS AND SOCIETY
Table A1. Summary statistics of the dependent, independent and control variables
Count
Weight
Dependent variable
- LWPP instead of RWPP
1372
1287
Main independent variables
- Probability of being unemployed
34,100
34,347
- Probability of necessities uncovered
40,612
40,546
- Mistrust in parties
43,532
43,465
- EU unification gone too far
40,776
40,648
- Detachment from Europe
43,699
43,668
- Immigrants bad for economy
42,825
42,791
- Restrict immigrants of other races
43,136
43,131
Control variables:
- Sex (female)
44,378
44,379
- Age (years)
42,993
42,510
- Education (university)
44,170
44,157
- LR Ideology
38,583
38,415
Notes: statistics computed using post-stratification weights (including
Source: Own elaboration (ESS, 2016).
Mean
SD
Min
Max
vif
0.48
0.50
0
1·
0.22
0.25
6.35
5.08
4.53
4.98
0.46
0.42
0.43
2.38
2.66
2.72
2.52
0.50
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
1
1
10
10
10
10
1
1.37
1.40
1.16
1.39
1.31
1.75
1.51·
0.52
0.50
48.30
18.02
0.22
0.41
5.17
2.23
design weights).
0
18
0
0
1
100
1
10
1.02
1.06
1.08
1.19
Table A2. Logistic regressions for LWPP support vs RWPP
M1
Material deprivation
Likely to be unemployed
Likely to have financial
needs
Anti-elitism
Mistrust in parties
Parochialism
EU unification gone too
far
Detachment from Europe
Nativism
Immigrants bad for
economy
Restrict immigrants of
other races
Control variables
Female
Age (years)
University
LR Ideology
Country fixed effects
Germany
M2
M3
M4
0.136 (0.078)
0.238 (0.152)
0.141 (0.088)
0.391* (0.155)·
0.058 (0.044)
0.106* (0.052)·
−0.075 (0.039)
−0.090*
(0.039)
−0.010 (0.039)
−0.213 (0.174)
−0.027*
(0.013)
0.395 (0.345)
−0.617***
(0.087)
M5
−0.200 (0.168)
−0.028*
(0.013)
0.379 (0.359)
−0.620***
(0.088)
−0.201 (0.171)
−0.028*
(0.013)
0.259 (0.385)
−0.595***
(0.082)
−0.012 (0.054)·
−0.105 (0.069)
−0.100 (0.073)
−0.397 (0.279)
−0.363 (0.249)·
−0.175 (0.145)
−0.028*
(0.011)
0.172 (0.286)
−0.581***
(0.069)
−0.130 (0.137)
−0.026* (0.011)
0.244 (0.281)
−0.576***
(0.068)·
1.743***
1.622***
1.499***
1.595*** (0.074)
(0.084)
(0.069)
(0.073)
Iceland
1.283***
1.100***
0.719***
0.963*** (0.213)
(0.130)
(0.129)
(0.215)
Italy
2.009***
1.960***
1.971***
1.975*** (0.212)
(0.236)
(0.221)
(0.212)
Lithuania
0.492***
0.371***
0.337***
0.277*** (0.082)
(0.109)
(0.051)
(0.079)
1.181***
1.293***
1.154***
0.989***
1.228*** (0.146)
The Netherlands
(0.107)
(0.119)
(0.104)
(0.086)
N
972
972
972
972
972
aic
953
953
945
936
921
Notes: Robust models clustered by country, using post-stratification weights (including design weights). An additional
model with an ordinal specification of education (less than lower secondary, lower secondary, upper secondary and university) has also been tested and yields the same results. This is also true for a model including only the control variables.
Missing values are delated, i.e. not considered in the analyses. Standard errors in parentheses.
Source: Own elaboration (ESS, 2016).
*p < .05, **p < .01, ***p < .001.
1.691***
(0.081)
1.223***
(0.123)
1.974***
(0.241)
0.249** (0.082)