Journal of Applied Corporate Finance
S U M M E R
1 9 9 6
V O L U M E
9. 2
The Role of Financial Relationships in the History of American Corporate Finance
by Charles W. Calomiris,
Columbia University, and
Carlos D. Ramirez,
George Mason University
THE ROLE OF FINANCIAL
RELATIONSHIPS IN THE
HISTORY OF AMERICAN
CORPORATE FINANCE
by Charles W. Calomiris,
Columbia University, and
Carlos D. Ramirez,
George Mason University*
he history of the financing of the American corporation has many aspects:
changes in the relative importance of
particular contracting forms (such as
debt vs. equity) as sources of funds; shifts in the
relative use of retained earnings vs. external finance;
and changes in the relative importance of lending by
commercial banks or similar intermediaries (sometimes referred to as “inside” or private lending) vs.
financing by public markets. The evolution of U.S.
corporate finance along these dimensions is the
history of alternating expansions and contractions of
the range of possible relationships between corporations and particular intermediaries. Such continuous shifts in relationships can be viewed as collective
attempts by companies and intermediaries to minimize the cost of finance in response to changes in
technology and, most important, in the legal and
regulatory environment.
One insight offered by this historical overview
is that virtually every financial transaction involves
some kind of intermediary and, thus, a “relationship.” Indeed, the distinction between raising capital
through intermediaries and going directly to “the
market” is a false dichotomy. The issuance of public
securities requires intermediaries such as investment
bankers or commercial paper dealers to perform
services similar to those provided by banks when
making loans, or by life insurance companies when
originating private placements, or by venture capitalists when raising private equity. Each of these
intermediaries can be seen as providing a different
mechanism for solving a combination of problems
that confront firms when attempting to raise capital.
The American corporate financing system, unlike that of most other countries, has not been
organized around a set of “universal banks” that
perform a variety of functions for their clients.
Indeed, the single feature that distinguishes American financial history from that of other countries is
the number and variety of financial intermediaries
and their independence from one another. And, as
we argue in this paper, it is the changing menu of
such intermediaries and their relationships with
corporations (and with one another) that has been
the driving force behind the evolution of American
corporate finance.
In the pages that follow, we view U.S. financial history as a series of institutional and financial
innovations designed in large part to work around
costly restrictions on relationships—particularly,
limits on the size and activities of U.S. banks—that
are not faced by corporations in most other
countries. Notable among such innovations are
new financial claims like preferred stock and
commercial paper, and new intermediaries like
venture capitalists and commercial paper houses.
But also important are new forms of cooperation
among intermediaries—especially among banks,
venture capitalists, trusts, pensions, and investment banks—that enable them to provide some of
the key advantages of universal banking systems.
Some of the largest U.S. commercial banks today
can be viewed as positioning themselves to play
a central coordinating role in these new coalitions
of intermediaries. To the extent they succeed,
such banks may become the platform for a distinctively American universal banking system.
*This paper is a condensed and amended version of “Financing the American
Corporation: The Changing Menu of Financial Relationships,” which appears as a
chapter in The Corporation and Modern Society: A Second Look, edited by Carl
Kaysen (Oxford University Press, 1996). The authors thank Don Chew, Carl Kaysen,
and other contributors to The Corporation and Modern Society for helpful
suggestions.
T
52
JOURNAL OF
APPLIEDOF
CORPORATE
FINANCE FINANCE
BANK OF AMERICA
JOURNAL
APPLIED CORPORATE
As we also suggest, such a view of the future of
U.S. commercial banking contrasts sharply with
popular predictions that “transactional” finance will
all but supplant relationship banking. Although
technological advances may have worked profound
changes in corporate financing by allowing many
firms more direct access to public markets, computers have not repealed the laws of economics. They
have not provided a magical solution to creditors’
traditional problems of monitoring and controlling
the behavior of owners, or to stockholders’ problems
of controlling managers. Nor have they fundamentally altered the fact that, for the vast majority of firms,
corporate finance is still based upon relationships of
one kind or another.
What’s more, computers and technology may
actually now be helping to push the American
financial system toward a new form of universal
banking. By expanding the menu of financial services that a single intermediary can provide, technological progress may end up strengthening rather
than severing long-term relationships between clients and their intermediaries.
incentives to invest in those projects once they
have received funding. For example, managers
with little equity ownership may have incentives to
choose value-reducing projects—say, an acquisition that increases the size of the firm in order to
increase the managers’ prestige or compensation or
job security. Debt contracts tend to constrain such
managerial behavior more effectively than, say,
common equity because failure to make debt payments can trigger a formal mechanism—Chapter
11—that is capable of wresting control of the firm
from managers.
On the other hand, managers of highly leveraged companies acting in the interests of their
shareholders may have incentives to turn down
value-increasing projects because of pressure to
meet debt service. Or, like a number of owners of
now-defunct savings and loans, managers in thinly
capitalized firms may even find it in their interest to
choose riskier, value-reducing projects as a result of
the incentives created by the contract between
creditors and the firm. In such cases, debt contracts
(by giving the debtholders much of the downside
risk but no upside participation) can provide managers with incentives to bet the ranch on high-risk
projects with low-probability, but potentially very
large, payoffs to shareholders.2
Third is a class of control costs that we will call
monitoring costs. Even if there is sufficient information about the company and the investment choices
of managers can be controlled easily by suppliers of
funds, managers may be able to exploit the fact that
it is costly to verify the outcome of the investment on
which the financial claims of suppliers are based.3
Consider the case of income bonds or preferred
stock, where the coupon payment or dividend can
be waived if reported net income is insufficient. In
such a case, managers may try to “hide” profits to
reduce the profit-contingent payments they have
promised suppliers of funds. Recognizing such
incentives, suppliers of funds cannot trust the reports
of managers, and will have to invest in “costly state
verification”—that is, a court audit or bankruptcy
proceeding to verify outcomes. Ordinary debt contracts effectively reduce such monitoring costs by
reducing the number of states of the world in which
FINANCE THEORY: THE MENU OF
INTERMEDIARY RELATIONSHIPS
Financial Frictions and the Role of
Intermediaries
What would prevent a corporation with a valueincreasing project from being able to secure financing? Four broad categories of frictions, or sources of
“costs,” can prevent efficient capital allocation from
taking place.
First are information costs. Suppliers of funds
may not be able to identify “good” firms—that is,
companies with value-increasing projects. If so,
“bad” firms may have an incentive to pretend to be
good firms. The difficulty of distinguishing good
from bad firms raises the cost of borrowing for good
firms and may even lead to a collapse of the market
for funds to the pooled class of firms.1
Second are control costs. Even if all firms
seeking to raise funds do have value-increasing
projects, managers may not have the necessary
3. The connection between costly verification and debt was first noted in
Townsend (1979).
1. See Stiglitz and Weiss (1981), Myers and Majluf (1984), and Calomiris and
Hubbard (1990). For full citations of all articles cited in footnotes or the text, see
the references section at the end of the article.
2. The classic statements of these “agency” and “asset substitution” problems
can be found in Jensen and Meckling (1976), Myers (1977), and Jensen (1986).
53
VOLUME 9 NUMBER 2
SUMMER 1996
verification must occur (only those in which the firm
fails to make its promised payment).
Fourth and finally, market segmentation—due,
for example, to natural boundaries that impose
physical barriers between savers and investors—can
prevent efficient transfers of funds from occurring,
even in the absence of the problems of information
and control discussed above. Moreover, such physical costs also imply related problems of information
and control. To the extent that ultimate suppliers of
funds are scattered and distant from ultimate users,
information and control costs will be higher. Problems of market segmentation have been particularly
severe in the U.S. because of its highly fragmented
commercial banking system. Such segmentation has
been reflected historically in substantial variation
across locations in the cost of funds and the profits
of corporations.
The role for intermediaries comes from the
advantages of appointing specialists to transfer funds,
screen applicants, monitor managerial performance
and company profits, and design and enforce specific contractual covenants that discipline managers.
Virtually every model of a “bank” has as one of its
fundamental features some advantage from delegating decision-making to a specialist while at the same
time ensuring that the “delegated monitor” faces
incentives to behave appropriately. A useful definition of a viable financial intermediary is a financial
agent that reduces net incentive and control problems—the sum of those that result from the frictions
outlined above and those that are introduced as the
result of the actions of the intermediary.
Why is it beneficial to use an intermediary? First
and foremost, given the multiple suppliers of funds
to any use, intermediaries avoid redundancy of
screening, monitoring, and enforcement costs, and
enjoy physical law-of-large-numbers economies in
cash management (netting of transfers). Given transaction costs in securities markets, intermediaries also
offer low-cost portfolio diversification. The concentration of claims in the hands of an intermediary also
avoids coordination costs in the relationship between firms and their funds suppliers. For example,
debt renegotiation costs are much lower when the
number of parties to the renegotiation is small.
Information costs and coordination costs are often
related. If a banker has all or most of the outstanding
debt of the firm, then it pays for the banker to invest
more in monitoring the firm because the banker’s
ability to make use of information is greater when he
can act with greater authority in an out-of-court
renegotiation or a bankruptcy. Firms with large
numbers of claimants can play one off against the
other, and can reduce the benefit to any claimant of
investing effort in monitoring the firm.
From the standpoint of a firm in need of funds,
the menu of intermediaries and contracting forms
offers alternative “mechanisms”—each represents a
different answer to the question of how one might
raise funds. And it is presumably the least costly
mechanism that is chosen by the firm after taking
account of and weighing the advantages and disadvantages of each potential relationship along a
variety of dimensions. For example, some forms of
intermediation cost more “up front” than others.
Some intermediaries charge higher fees, or impose
tighter restrictions on the firm’s behavior in the form
of debt covenants, or create a powerful new outside
stockholder with direct control over management—
and these outside constraints may prevent some
potentially profitable behavior. But these higher upfront costs may be warranted if the restrictions imply
significant contingent benefits to the firm (such as
lower costs of finance if earnings drop sharply in the
future), or if other forms of finance are unavailable
because of prohibitive incentive and control problems facing the firm.
For large, well-established companies with a
wide range of choices about which form of intermediation or financing mechanism to use, choosing the lowest-cost mechanism requires consideration of different possible levels of future profitability, and of the benefits of each financing alternative
under the different outcomes. For example, hiring
an underwriter to place a widely held bond issue
may offer the advantage of a higher price of debt
(or larger amount of debt) than could be secured
from a bank. But, if the firm ends up being unable
to cover its interest expenses with current income,
the costs of that distress (in the form of reduced
investment and other disruptions) will likely be
greater if its debt is held by public bondholders
than by a small group of banks. The costs of
financial distress are also likely to vary among
different kinds of companies. Companies with few
profitable investment opportunities, but valuable
tangible asset holdings, should lose relatively little
value in reorganization. And companies with clearly
observable profitable investment opportunities
should suffer less of a reduction in value in financial distress than firms whose opportunities are
54
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
The history of American financial intermediation—or the history of the menu of
financial relationships available to corporations—can be described as the history of
finding “second-best” solutions in the face of restrictions on the scale and scope of
activities of U.S. banks.
more difficult to communicate to outsiders. Thus,
one possible interpretation of a firm’s decision to
use public debt as opposed to bank loans is that it
perceives the probability and anticipated costs of
financial distress to be low.
There are many other contingencies to consider
when raising capital, and there are many more
dimensions to corporate financing choices than the
decision whether to use public debt or bank loans.
For example, companies will be concerned about
the implications of their financing relationships for
the costs of finance under circumstances much less
extreme than financial distress—say, if they should
experience a sudden decline in earnings. Managers
are aware that an unexpected drop in earnings can
restrict their firm’s access to funds on “economic”
terms—and such constraints represent one of the
potentially significant costs of external finance.
Several studies have demonstrated the importance
of internally generated funds in maintaining corporate investment during periods of reduced operating
cash flow, and these studies have attributed their
findings to the high costs of financing activity from
external sources.4
For our purposes, what is most important about
the potential costs of external finance is their connection to choices about financial relationships. From
this perspective, two important points have been
stressed in the literature. First, companies facing the
greatest frictions in capital markets tend to rely more
on close relationships with intermediaries. Some
markets—notably, the public bond and commercial
paper markets—are not accessible to all firms because of the prohibitive costs of financial frictions.
Firms tend to progress through a financial “life
cycle.” They begin with access only to a close-knit
group of entrepreneurs. Over time they rely on
lending from banks or venture capitalists, which
retain close control over the firm. Later, as companies’ prospects become a matter of common knowledge, and as their internal resources become larger
relative to their funding needs, they tend to rely on
“outside” sources of funds in public markets. At this
stage, intermediaries take on the role of underwriters
rather than suppliers of funds through loans or
equity investments.
Second, a company’s ability to raise funds during
times when cash flow is low relative to investment
opportunities depends heavily on whether it has a preexisting financing relationship, and on the strength of
that relationship. The uniqueness of bank lending
relationships has been the subject of many recent
studies of banking. Other bank-like intermediaries
such as finance companies and life insurance companies also make loans that are similar to bank loans.
They too can be thought of as “private” lenders with
access to special information; and, like banks, they
monitor and control the borrower’s behavior through
the verification and enforcement of covenants.5
Lest one be carried away by the wonders of
“discipline,” it is worth bearing in mind that discipline also has its costs, which explains why it is not
the preferred financing relationship for all firms. In
Japan, for example, companies sometimes opt out of
close bank relationships, and in so doing increase
their potential reliance on high-cost sources of funds
(public markets) if internal funds fall.6 Why would
value-maximizing firms voluntarily increase their
costs of raising external funds in the future? One
simple explanation is that there are fixed costs to
establishing and maintaining financing relationships—for example, the costs of designing and
enforcing appropriate standards of behavior.
Another cost to buying discipline may be the
inflexibility of the disciplinarian. For example, financial covenants are a form of regulation that could be
viewed as a substitute for constant scrutiny of the
firm. By establishing a set of easily verified covenants, the firm is able to reduce the costs charged
by the intermediary for monitoring. Other covenants
typically restrict the use of funds, as well as changes
in the operations of the firm. Despite the obvious
benefits of such covenants in reducing costs of
control, they may be costly by limiting the flexibility
of the firm to respond to changing circumstances.
Thus, as companies reach the advanced stage of the
financial life cycle and become seasoned credit risks
with smaller relative reliance on external finance, the
costs of strong relationships may be greater than the
benefits, and such companies may accordingly choose
to switch to financing relationships that involve
weaker ties to intermediaries.
4. Such studies find that the higher the shadow cost of external finance (which
reflects the extent to which firms are vulnerable to the various frictions mentioned
above), the greater the sensitivity of investment to cash flow. See Fazzari, Hubbard,
and Petersen (1988) and Calomiris and Hubbard (1995).
5. For empirical evidence of the value of banking relationships, see James
(1987), Billett, Flannery, and Garfinkel (1995), Slovin, Sushka, and Polonchek
(1992), and Hoshi, Kashyap, and Scharfstein (1990a, 1990b, 1991).
6. See Hoshi, Kashyap, and Scharfstein (1990b).
55
VOLUME 9 NUMBER 2
SUMMER 1996
the equity-holding powers of intermediaries. Finally,
government restrictions that forced intermediaries to
specialize in particular functions have limited the
beneficial combining of activities within the same
intermediary.
In discussing the costs of prohibiting “universal
banking” in the U.S., it is useful to consider the
advantages that other countries have enjoyed from
such a system. Universal banking takes different
forms in different countries, and there is no clear
agreement about its essential or defining characteristics. For our purposes, we define universal banks
to be intermediaries with three sets of characteristics:
(1) they operate large networks over a wide geographic range; (2) they provide customers with
access to a wide scope of activities, including
lending, underwriting, portfolio management, and
deposit-taking; and (3) they are permitted to hold a
variety of types of claims (e.g., debt and equity) on
their corporate customers. In our historical discussion of the U.S., this definition will prove useful for
distinguishing between the U.S. and German banking systems, and between “full-fledged” universal
banking in Germany and the partial and sporadic
attempts to concentrate and combine financial services that have occurred throughout U.S. history.
The benefits of universal banking can be divided into four categories.
First, there are the simple benefits of concentration
that come from allowing banks to be large—in
particular, lower costs of coordination among claimants, thus strengthening the intermediary’s incentives to screen, monitor, control, and negotiate with
the firm efficiently.
Second, there are information and network economies from combining various functions within the
same intermediary. Intermediaries that can combine
different functions can save on information and
enforcement costs and on “brick and mortar” costs
by spreading fixed costs over more transactions.
Third, there are incentive and signaling benefits
from combining activities. Providing a variety of
services and holding various claims on a firm can
strengthen the incentives of intermediaries to monitor and enforce properly, and can improve their
ability to signal information to outsiders when
marketing securities. A bank may find it easier and
more desirable to monitor a borrower in which it
Intermediaries in Securities Markets
Intermediaries that specialize in the creation of
insider debts of corporations—commercial banks,
finance companies, and life insurance companies—
are not the only intermediaries that develop beneficial relationships with firms. Although somewhat
neglected by financial economists in the past, the
role of investment bankers and institutional buyers
of securities in facilitating the marketing of securities
is now receiving more attention. Both the theoretical
models of investment banking and empirical studies
of the costs of securities flotations have emphasized
the importance of investment bankers’ reputations,
information-and-sales networks, and long-term relationships in reducing financing costs. Relationships
among investment bankers and their institutional
buyers, and concentrations of shares (and voting
power) in small numbers of investors (pensions,
mutuals, and trusts) help to reduce issuing costs by
reducing both information and corporate control
problems.7
American Financial Fragmentation and
Relationship Constraints
One of the most remarkable features of American finance—perhaps the single feature that has set
American financial history apart from that of other
countries—is the number and variety of intermediaries and their independence from one another.
Unlike most other countries, the American corporate
financing system is not organized around a set of
“universal banks” performing a variety of functions
for their clients.
We will argue that limits on the size and scope
of banks in the U.S. have placed important constraints on the feasible menu of financing relationships of corporations. In the U.S. it has been harder
to concentrate ownership of the financial claims on
firms. The concentration of debt claims has been
limited by the relatively small size of U.S. banks,
which can be attributed to restrictions on branching
and consolidation. Furthermore, intermediaries have
been prohibited from involvement in selling, managing, and holding large equity interests in firms,
sometimes by limitations on the size and geographic
range of intermediaries, and sometimes by limits on
7. Theoretical models include Benveniste and Spindt (1989), Benveniste and
Wilhelm (1990), and Chemmanur and Fulghieri (1994).
56
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
Providing a variety of services and holding various claims on a firm can strengthen
the incentives of intermediaries to monitor and enforce properly, and can improve
their ability to signal information to outsiders when marketing securities.
maintains a junior stake. Also, it may be easier for a
bank to underwrite equity of a company in which it
maintains a stake. For example, if a bank holds (or
controls for its trust customers) stock in a corporation, the bank stands to lose from managerial errors
or misbehavior of that corporation. Potential buyers
of equity are more likely to trust the opinion of a
universal bank underwriter that is taking a junior
stake in the firm whose shares are being sold,
especially if the underwriter retains significant control of the firm after the issue.
Fourth, universal banking can promote low-cost
diversification of the intermediary, and thereby
reduce its cost of funds.8
From the perspective of these theoretical arguments, regulatory restrictions on the geographic
range and scope of activities of intermediaries may
have significantly raised the cost of financing for U.S.
companies. Indeed, we will argue that such costly
restrictions explain the peculiar history of the development of American financial intermediaries, and
the high costs of industrial finance in the U.S.
In the next part of this paper, we describe the
historical circumstances that gave rise to the peculiar
constraints of American corporate finance, discuss
the costs of those constraints on U.S. firms, and then
consider the forces that changed those constraints
over time. We argue that during its early history, the
U.S. was able to develop a very efficient intermediation system, particularly in New England before the
Civil War. In many respects, that system enjoyed the
advantages of a universal banking system by virtue
of the close ties among industrial borrowers, commercial banks, underwriters, and securities portfolio
managers.
But that system of “insider finance” broke down
by the 1890s in the face of restrictions on bank
branching and consolidation and the expansion in
the scale of industrial firms. Other limitations on
bank involvement in boards of directors (the Clayton
Act of 1914), and the forced separation of commercial and investment banking (the Glass-Steagall Act
of 1933) further restricted intermediaries’ abilities to
reap the gains outlined above.
The subsequent history of American financial
intermediation—or the history of the menu of finan-
cial relationships available to corporations—can be
described as the history of finding “second-best”
solutions in the face of these restrictions. Such
solutions included the creation of new intermediaries and new financial claims. Prominent among them
were commercial paper houses helping firms to
place commercial paper, insurance companies originating private placements, and pensions, mutuals,
and venture capitalists participating in venture capital funds and investment banking syndicates. These
financial developments involved new methods of
cooperation among intermediaries—especially
among venture capitalists, trusts, pensions, and
investment bankers—that had some elements in
common with early arrangements in New England
and universal banking systems. Today commercial
banks themselves have become involved in these
new coalitions of intermediaries—and, through such
involvement, the banks themselves may become the
platform on which true American universal banks
will be built.
AMERICAN CORPORATE FINANCE:
A CHANGING MENU OF RELATIONSHIPS
Pseudo-Universal Banking in New England
New England banking and financial markets
were the best developed in the early U.S., and recent
empirical work has provided evidence of the relative
efficiency of New England banks. Perhaps surprisingly, New England enjoyed a universal banking
system of a sort long before “true” universal banking
was established in Germany in the last three decades
of the 19th century. The relationship between the
non-bank corporation and the bank remained the
focus of the corporation’s financial relationship, but
that relationship became increasingly complex, and
involved securities flotations and investments by
related intermediaries (such as savings banks), as
well as funding by commercial banks.9
During the first half of the 19th century leading
up to the Civil War (the “antebellum” period), New
England’s banks were a primary source of funding
for New England industrialists. The links between
industry and banking in New England were very
8. Two studies have argued from the evidence of limited universal banking
in the U.S. (current as well as historical) that universal banks are better able to
diversify because the incomes from the various services they offer are not highly
correlated.Eugene White (1986) and Elijah Brewer (1989)
9. Calomiris and Kahn (1996) argue for the relative efficiency of New England
banks. Davis (1957, 1960) and Lamoreaux (1991a, 1994) provide detailed analyses
of the links between New England banks and industrial enterprises.
57
VOLUME 9 NUMBER 2
SUMMER 1996
close, and the banks were closely affiliated with
other financial institutions that underwrote securities
issues and managed securities portfolios. The banks
were chartered to provide credit to their industrialist
founders. In many cases, the officers and directors of
the banks were their principal borrowers.
The stock of antebellum New England banks—
like that of German universal banks, but unlike U.S.
banks later in the 19th century—was widely issued.
New England banks were able to attract large
numbers of outside stockholders and pay lower
returns on equity than other banks because their
institutional arrangements helped to control information problems. Each bank’s borrower-insiders
had strong incentives to monitor one another to
ensure the continuation of the flow of credit to their
own enterprises in the future. Moreover, interbank
relationships ensured monitoring among members
of the private interbank clearing coalition known as
the “Suffolk system” and among commercial banks
and savings banks (which financed much of commercial banks’ activities).
the scale of production, the challenges faced by the
financial system to resolve information and control
problems were enormous.
Financial and economic historians generally
have argued that the U.S. financial system had only
limited success in adapting to these new challenges.
U.S. regional financial markets remained largely
isolated from one another during the late 19th
century, and financial markets were slow to channel
funds from low-growth sectors to high-growth sectors. Large, persisting regional differences in interest
rates—an indication of a fragmented financial system—were a distinctive if not unique feature of
American financial markets.
Although these differences declined over time
they remained large relative to those of other countries
both before and after World War I. As late as the 1920s,
bank loan interest rate differentials across regions on
similar types of loans were as large as three percent.
Such regional differences in interest rates do not show
up in the data before the Civil War.10
Moreover, a study of U.S. manufacturing operations during the postbellum period finds large
persistent differences in profitability across both
regions and sectors.11 Such evidence reinforces the
impression that there were significant impediments
to moving capital from low-profit to high-profit uses.
Evidence on the role of commercial banks in
the industrialization process is consistent with the
view that sources of funding for industrial firms
were inadequate. Links between industrial firms
and banks were much weaker in the U.S. than in
other countries (notably, much weaker than in
Germany’s universal banking system). This reflected
primarily the small size of incorporated banks relative to the large needs of industrial borrowers.
There were more than 26,000 banks operating in
1914, and the overwhelming majority of these were
not permitted to operate branches, even within
their home state. Small banks operating in a restricted location were simply incapable of financing, monitoring, and disciplining large industrial
borrowers operating throughout the nation.
To the extent banks were involved with industrial finance, much bank financing occurred without
any direct (much less ongoing) relationship between
Postbellum Industrial Finance and the
Shrinking Role of Commercial Banks
The industrialization of the U.S. after the Civil
War posed new challenges for the financial system,
and these challenges seem not to have been met as
effectively as before by banks. As Alfred Chandler
(1977) and others have stressed, the “second industrial revolution” of the postbellum era saw the
creation of whole new industries (electricity, steel,
and chemicals) and the development of a transcontinental network of railroads. This era also gave rise
to the large modern corporation—vertically and
horizontally integrated, and controlled by a large
bureaucratic managerial hierarchy.
As we have argued, two of the most important
roles of a financial intermediary are to reduce the
information “gap” between lenders and borrowers,
and to provide a credible means for controlling
management’s use of the funds allocated to it. In a
rapidly growing industrial economy, with many new
products, new forms of producing, organizing, and
distributing products, and an enormous increase in
10. Baskin (1988), Davis (1966), and Calomiris (1993a, 1995) describe the
development of American capital markets and their limitations. Davis (1963, 1965),
Sylla (1969), James (1978), and Calomiris (1993a) examine data on postwar interest
rate differences relevant for commercial and industrial lending. Riefler (1930)
provides data on actual bank lending rates during the 1920s. Bodenhorn (1990)
examines regional interest rate differences during the antebellum period.
11. Atack and Bateman (1994).
58
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
U.S. regional financial markets remained largely isolated from one another during
the late 19th century, and financial markets were slow to channel funds from lowgrowth sectors to high-growth sectors. Large, persisting regional differences in
interest rates—an indication of a fragmented financial system—were a distinctive if
not unique feature of American financial markets.
the bank and the firms it financed. Intermediaries’
claims on firms primarily took the form of corporate
bond holdings placed through syndicates. During
the period 1901-1912, for example, bonds held by all
intermediaries accounted for 18% of funds supplied
by external sources to non-financial firms. (And, at
the end of this period, commercial banks accounted
for two thirds of corporate bond holdings by intermediaries.) By comparison, bank loans accounted
for only 12% of externally supplied funds over this
period. Moreover, bank loans amounted to only
about 10% of corporate debts, while bonds and notes
accounted for roughly half of corporate debts, and
trade debt constituted 15%.12
Reliance on bank loans was relatively high for
small firms. Large, established manufacturing firms
relied more on bond issues as a means of indirect
bank finance and less on loans from banks as a
source of financing, especially prior to the 1940s.13
Under the U.S. unit banking system, large-scale firms
operating throughout the country would have had to
borrow from many small unit banks simultaneously.
Bond market syndications facilitated this transaction
by providing a means for banks to share risk and
coordinate capital allocations.
A study of funding sources for a sample of 14
large manufacturing firms from 1900-1910, based
on accounting records of sources of net inflows of
funds, indicates little reliance on bank lending. For
the period 1900 to 1910, these firms reported a total
financial inflow of $1.2 billion, of which $357
million came from external finance. Of this only $29
million was in the form of short-term debt. Some
bank loans during this period also took the form of
long-term debt, but long-term loans from commercial banks were relatively uncommon around the
turn of the century.14
While small firms relied more on banks, it does
not follow that banks contributed to the financing of
industrial capital expansion by small firms any more
than they did to that of large firms. Two detailed
studies of the sources of capital in manufacturing
provide a glimpse of the contribution of banks to
industrial expansion in Illinois and California in the
mid-to-late 19th century.15 In the case of California,
33 of 71 manufacturing firms studied over the period
1859 to 1880 financed their investment entirely from
internal sources. The others incorporated, took in
partners, and supplemented these sources with
earnings of existing partners from other sources, sale
of stock or real estate, “Eastern capital” (in three
cases), and loans from a private banker. Clearly,
commercial banks had no role in the expansion of
manufacturing capital in California prior to 1880.
Illinois’ experience was similar. In Illinois there
is evidence of limited access to funds for relatively
mature firms owned by bank stockholders.16 While
banks may have played some role in financing
industrial expansion in Illinois, the importance of
this role was greatest during the “adolescent” stage
of the firm’s life cycle—that is, after the firm had
become mature enough to invest in becoming a
bank insider, but before it had become too large to
rely on a bank for its funding needs. Even this role
of bank lending in industrial finance is apparent in
the histories of only about half of the case studies
examined.
Why were commercial banks unable to expand
to meet the challenges of financing the new largescale industrial producers? Naomi Lamoreaux’s (1991a,
1991b, 1994) studies of New England banking provide an interesting perspective on that question. She
shows that large-scale banking would have been
profitable in New England, but that profitable consolidation was not permitted by bank regulators.
Many New England banks wanted to merge in
response to the growing scale of firms, and the
consequent economies of scope and scale in providing industrial finance. When banks were able to
merge, their profits increased substantially. Ultimately, however, national and state banking laws
stood in the way of bank mergers or branching, as
unit bankers blocked attempts to liberalize branching laws and prevented attempted mergers.
Regulatory barriers to the scale of banking
changed the functions of New England banks. As
already discussed, New England banks had been
important sources of finance, monitoring, and con-
12. Goldsmith (1958, 222, 335) gives intermediaries’ holdings of bonds. On
pages 339-340 he provides data on commercial banks’ bond holdings, decomposed
according to type of issuer. Goldsmith, Lipsey, and Mendelsohn (1963, 146) provide
data on composition of debts for non-financial corporations.
13. Goldsmith (1958, 217-218).
14. Goldsmith (1958, 335, 339) is the source for data on short- and long-term
lending by commercial banks. The study of large manufacturing firms is described
in Dobrovolsky and Bernstein (1960, 141-142).
15. Marquardt (1960) studies enterprises in Illinois, while Trusk (1960) studies
firms in California.
16. Marquardt (1960, 507).
59
VOLUME 9 NUMBER 2
SUMMER 1996
trol for antebellum industrial enterprises, and the
manager/owners of those enterprises were bank
“insiders.” But those arrangements had changed by
the late 19th century. By 1900, New England’s banks
had moved toward financing the commercial (rather
than industrial) undertakings of bank outsiders.
These changes reflected the growing mismatch
between large-scale firms and inherently small unit
banks. As firms became larger, small banks found it
increasingly difficult to satisfy the investment-financing needs of large customers, given the banks’ desire
to maintain diversified loan portfolios.
made it easier to sell paper in the secondary market. Even for high-quality borrowers, the high costs
and high frequency of rollover in the commercial
paper market meant that long-term financing needs
could not be addressed adequately through commercial paper finance.
The vehicle for long-term finance was the
investment banking syndicate. Investment banking
syndicates operated as multi-tiered financing mechanisms. At the top were Wall Street investment
bankers who planned, priced, and underwrote the
issue. Sales occurred through a network of local
dealers, many of whom maintained close ties with
local commercial banks, which bought securities
for themselves and for their customers. As Vincent
Carosso (1970) points out in his classic study of
investment banking, this selling network developed
during the Civil War as a means of placing large
issues of government bonds. The network of relationships remained after the Civil War, and provided a basis for continuing distributions of private
securities.
The central challenge facing an investment
banking syndicate is convincing buyers to purchase
the securities of firms about which they know little
or nothing. How could a Wall Street financier assure
potential American (and foreign) investors that
American railroad and industrial securities were
sound investments? Why should buyers believe that
investment bankers or their dealers will truthfully
identify which are the good companies and which
are the bad ones?
Clearly, reputation-building, effective signaling, and information-sharing are the keys to resolving the problems of marketing securities to outsiders.
The marketing of securities also can be enhanced by
the continuing involvement of the investment banker
with the issuing firm. As we noted earlier, some of
the frictions that discourage outside investors from
financing firms come from the inability of outside
investors to prevent firms from misusing funds (for
example, by taking on excessive risk after placing a
large debt issue). For investment bankers to be
successful in marketing securities, they must be able
to convince outside investors both that the firm’s
prospects are good, and that they are in a position
to control opportunistic behavior by the firm’s
managers after the offering.
Filling the Gap: The Dawn of
“Financial Capitalism”
The fragmented banking system’s inability to
finance industrial growth provided the stimulus for
innovative new financing methods for corporate
borrowers. These included the development of a
market for commercial paper (which was held
mainly by banks) and the rise of investment banking
syndicates. Both of these financing mechanisms
were available only to the largest, most established
firms. Syndicates were also used to finance corporate
consolidations and reorganizations, as well as to
market new issues of bonds and preferred stocks.
The commercial paper market, which was a
unique innovation of the American financial system,
met the short-term borrowing needs of large, highquality borrowers. The growth of this market spurted
in the 1870s, and it reached its pre-World War II peak
in 1920 at $1.3 billion, consisting of the debts of over
4,000 borrowers.17 Commercial paper houses provided a means for the highest-quality borrowers to
locate cheaper sources of funds outside their local
markets. Commercial paper brokers received shortterm bridge financing from local banks, which was
repaid once they had sold their paper (generally to
banks in relatively low-credit-demand locations).
The commercial paper market was not open to
all firms and was not useful for all purposes.
Because commercial paper was used as a money
substitute (essentially, a form of interest-bearing
bank reserves), only the lowest-risk borrowers were
permitted to enter the market, and the maturity of
paper was kept short. These restrictions ensured
that credit risk was very small in the market, and
17. For reviews of the history of the commercial paper market, see Greef
(1938), Foulke (1931), and Selden (1963).
60
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
The challenge to financing growth on such a large scale was to find a means to
intermediate between creditworthy firms and a large number of uninformed
suppliers of funds—to design an effective mechanism to screen, monitor, and
control large-scale users of funds raised in centralized capital markets.
An important tradition in American corporate
finance emerged as a response to these concerns—
the presence of a powerful financier on the board of
directors of a corporation seeking funding through
an investment banking syndicate. This became a
prevalent practice during the last two decades of the
19th century. Indeed, the rise of “financial capitalism”—as this practice came to be known—has its
American origins with the railroad financings of the
1870s and 1880s.
banks; they increased the need for involvement of
investment bankers in corporate decision-making.
For most of the 19th century, the U.S. lacked a
comprehensive law on bankruptcy. The frequent
episodes of financial distress that resulted in a large
number of railroad failures had not influenced policy
makers enough to motivate the formation of a
bankruptcy law until 1898. The process of equity
receivership underwent constant change in response
to ongoing legal innovations in the bankruptcy
process. Revisions in the 19th-century legal process
included (1) the right of receivers to issue claims with
a seniority level higher than the prior senior claimants; (2) the right of courts to secure the claims of
unsecured debtholders; and (3) the imposition of
“fees” on stakeholders as a method of raising funds
to complete the reorganization.
Along with these legal innovations in the bankruptcy process, new methods of financial reorganization were being introduced during this period.
These methods included the more frequent use of
preferred stock, the collection of assessments to raise
cash during reorganizations, and the use of voting
trusts. These developments occurred partly as a
response to the recurring financial problems from
which many corporations were suffering. Preferred
stock, for example, was more frequently used during
the reorganizations of the 1890s because the bond
financing and floating debt used during previous
organizations often resulted only in an increased
chance of default. After the unsuccessful reorganizations of the 1870s, railroad financiers and investors
experimented with new methods of reorganization
designed to restore the financial health of their
troubled companies.
Extensive use of the voting trust along with the
more widespread use of preferred stock as a tool for
raising capital in external markets increased the
demand for banker representation on the boards of
directors of client corporations. The complexity of
these financial innovations, and the use of (riskier)
preferred stock rather than simple debt magnified
the importance of investment bankers as advisers
and controllers of corporate decision-making.
Clearly, episodes of financial distress furthered
the movement toward investment banker involvement in corporate management by encouraging the
Investment Banking and Corporate Finance
Prior to World War I
The rise of the modern industrial corporation
during the last quarter of the 19th century encouraged this type of affiliation between bankers and
companies, which made the rapid industrial growth
of that period possible. Spectacular growth of “mass
production” with “mass distribution” took place
during the 1890s and the first decade of the 20th
century. This process required huge outlays of
capital—more than any single lender could command or risk. The challenge to financing growth on
such a large scale was to find a means to intermediate between creditworthy firms and a large number
of uninformed suppliers of funds—to design an
effective mechanism to screen, monitor, and control large-scale users of funds raised in centralized
capital markets.
The growth of financial capitalism reflected
other changes in the economy in addition to the
growth of new large-scale industries. Three other
influences were particularly important, and they all
operated largely through the incentives that they
created for developing more efficient means of
restructuring existing financial claims. One key
factor was changes in law—especially bankruptcy
law—that promoted innovations in financial instruments (preferred stock issues) and encouraged the
restructuring of corporate balance sheets. A second
was episodes of macroeconomic financial distress
that encouraged corporate restructurings and consolidations. A third was the incentives for consolidation created by the Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890.18
These three influences not only created increased
demand for securities marketing by investment
18. For a discussion of the origins of preferred stock, see Tufano (1992).
Campbell (1938) and Carosso (1970) discuss the importance of restructurings, and
Smith and Sylla (1993) provide a lively analysis of the biggest of these cases — the
formation of U.S. Steel. Bittilingmayer (1985) and Cleveland and Huertas (1986)
discuss bankruptcy law changes and the Sherman Act.
61
VOLUME 9 NUMBER 2
SUMMER 1996
legal innovations of the late 19th century and the
financial innovations that responded to them. Experiences with distress also taught firms the potential
advantages of maintaining an ongoing relationship
with an investment banking firm as a form of
insurance against the costs of future financial distress. The investment banker’s role in this respect
depended on his ability to buy and sell large amounts
of securities in a short period of time. In times of
precarious financial conditions such as the panics of
1861, 1873, and 1893, prestigious investment banking firms were very much in demand for representation and financial advice. During economic downturns, when the rate of railroad and commercial
failures increased, reorganizations and necessary
mergers were more easily performed by a financial
expert who was “inside” the corporation.
The Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890 also added
to the demand for investment bank involvement in
corporate management. While banning trusts, the
Sherman Act did not explicitly prohibit the formation
of holding companies. Banker representation facilitated the circumventing of the new regulations by
creating legal holding companies to replace the now
illegal trusts. In this fashion, the Sherman Antitrust
Act actually encouraged the biggest merger movement in U.S. history.19
More formal empirical analysis of financial
capitalism confirms its importance in facilitating
the financing of industry. Recent studies have shown
that maintaining a close relationship with a major
investment banking house was associated with
both improved corporate performance and greater
access to external finance, allowing firms to fund
investment more easiy when internal funds were
scarce.20
Although financial capitalism was evolving
during the last two decades of the 19th century and
the first decade of the 20th, it never developed into
universal banking in the German sense, or into the
zaibatsu system that existed in Japan before World
War II. Despite its successes, the U.S. system entailed
higher costs of external finance for all corporate
borrowers than the German universal banking system. And the costs were especially high for immature
firms, which lacked access to the high-flying financial capitalism of Morgan and his counterparts.
A 1995 study by one of the present writers found
evidence of the relatively high costs of American
corporate finance in a number of comparisons
between German and American corporations in the
early 1900s.21 In particular, the high fees for issuing
common stock in the U.S. and the paucity of stock
issues (especially of common stock) by American
firms at this time suggest that information and control
problems were better solved by German capital
markets. German firms issued far more public equity
than debt, most of which was in the form of new
common stock issues. In fact, American firms issued
very little common stock on the public market prior
to World War I. The commissions on common stock
flotations charged by German universal banks were
roughly 4% and did not significantly vary with the
size of the firm or the size of the issue. In the U.S.,
commissions averaged above 20%, and the costs
were prohibitive for all but the largest firms.
The paucity of equity issues and the high
commissions charged in U.S. underwritings reflected
the difficulty of credibly communicating information
about firms and controlling corporate behavior. J.P.
Morgan was willing to make a large investment in
information about and control over his established
industrial clients. But U.S. industry in large measure
was left behind by the capital markets. In Germany
the situation was different. Even small firms and firms
in growing industries could gain access to capital
markets, typically through stock issues.
The key difference between the German and
American financial system was that German universal banks could take deposits, lend, underwrite
securities, place issues, and manage portfolios all
within the same financial institution, and that institution could operate throughout Germany. Because
German banks could branch freely, they were able
to use the same network of offices for all these
functions. This allowed them to “internalize” the
costs and benefits of monitoring and controlling
their industrial clients. Before underwriting a security, they had generally lent to and developed a
relationship with the issuing firm for some time. After
19. Bittilingmayer (1985, 77) estimates that as much as one half of U.S.
manufacturing capacity took part in the mergers during the years 1898-1902. The
U.S. Steel merger, orchestrated by J.P. Morgan & Co. was by far the largest of these
in capitalization.
20. DeLong (1991) finds that the performance of firms affiliated with Morgan
was superior to that of non-affiliated firms, and Ramirez (1995) finds that Morgan
firms were more likely to continue investing heavily when earnings were down
than non-Morgan firms.
21. Calomiris (1995).
62
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
The high fees for issuing common stock in the U.S. compared to those in Germany
around the turn of the century, and the paucity of stock issues by American firms at
this time, suggest that information and control problems were then better solved by
German capital markets.
underwriting the issue, they placed it internally with
their own trust customers. After placing an equity
issue, the bank retained control over the votes of the
shareholders, which concentrated control in the
bank.
German banks thus had pre-existing knowledge at the time of the underwriting that helped to
reduce information costs. More important, the bank’s
function as a portfolio manager gave it a way to
control the subsequent behavior of the firm, and a
continuing incentive to monitor and signal the
quality of its industrial clients accurately (since it
competed with other banks for the privilege of
managing customers’ portfolios).22
Another indicator of the high relative costs of
finance in the U.S. is the choice of factors of
production. The U.S. tendency to avoid fixed capital
in the production process has been widely noted by
economic historians, and linked to the high cost of
external finance. Firms facing high external finance
costs are likely to rely more on liquid assets in the
production process (such as materials) because
liquid assets are easy to sell during a cash crunch, and
they command better terms as collateral for bank
loans. Historical analysis of the U.S. production
process has revealed a sharp increase during the late
19th and early 20th centuries in American firms’
reliance on substitutes for capital in the production
process, especially natural resources. The American
reliance on natural resources, and related phenomena such as the emergence of high-throughput
production and distribution processes, have been
attributed in part to the high cost of raising funds to
finance fixed capital investment.23, 24
The initial failure of universal banking in the
U.S., as we have argued, can be attributed to
constraints on the ability of commercial banks to
branch, since this limited any intermediary’s ability
to lend to (much less underwrite for) large-scale
firms on a national scale. But those initial barriers
were not the only limitations that would be imposed
on the relationships of financial capitalism. In the
wake of populist Congressional “investigations,” first
in 1912, later in 1932, Congress acted to circumscribe
banking powers and limit financial capitalism. The
second intervention, in 1933, was the more important. The early legislation had little effect, and other
trends began to favor the development of “incipient”
universal banking in the 1920s—notably, the wave
of deregulation of bank consolidation and branching
during the 1920s. The restrictions imposed by the
Banking Act of 1933 and the revival of protection for
unit banks brought an end to these experiments.
During the first decade of the 20th century, there
was a growing public perception that financial capitalism was growing too concentrated and that a
“Money Trust” had been formed among the few and
powerful investment banking houses during the
period. This negative view of financial capitalism,
which was magnified by the Panics of 1902 and 1907,
became the source of a bitter political debate that
culminated in a Congressional investigation of the
so-called Money Trust. Progressives such as Arsene
Pujo, a Louisiana representative who chaired the
Money Trust investigation, and Louis Brandeis, a
very influential and ambitious Boston lawyer (who
would later become Supreme Court Justice), questioned the influence and power that these few investment banking houses had over a large sector of the
economy. The committee cross-examined members
of the largest investment banking houses and their
client firms during the hearings. Although they never
accomplished it, their intention was to show the
existence of trusts that controlled a substantial share
of capital and abused their strategic position.
U.S. regulation evolved largely in response to
public perceptions of who or what was wrong in the
existing system. The Pujo Investigation of 1912 and
the enactment of the Clayton Act of 1914 were clearly
products of this public outcry.
But the momentum of legislation from the
Progressive Era waned substantially after 1914 due
to the involvement of investment banks in the war
22. Competition is key to the effectiveness of universal banking. The current
German system of universal banking displays few of the advantages of its historical
predecessor, possibly because of cross-holdings of bank stock that allow German
banks to avoid competition.
23. By 1928, resource intensity of exports was 50% higher than its 1879 level
(Wright 1990, 658).
24. Studies of variation in asset structures across firms using post-World War
II data are also consistent with this argument. These studies find that high fixed
capital intensivity is associated with lower-cost access to external finance (as
measured either by cross-sectional differences in underwriting costs or by
differences in access to bond and commercial paper markets). For example,
Calomiris, Himmelberg, and Wachtel (1995) find that commercial paper issuers (the
firms with the lowest costs of external finance in the U.S. currently) maintain
average ratios of inventories-to-fixed capital of 0.58, while firms without access to
public debt markets maintain inventory-to-fixed capital ratios of 1.26 on average,
and this difference is not explained by industry effects.
Changes in Financial Capitalism During the
Interwar Era: A Brief Experiment with
Universal Banking
63
VOLUME 9 NUMBER 2
SUMMER 1996
effort. The perception changed in favor of Wall Street
once again, as it came to be viewed as a major
contributor to the financing of the Allies’ war expenditures. During this period, the role of the investment
and commercial bankers shifted from financing
domestic corporations to financing domestic and
foreign governments. In the wake of these changes,
there was little effort to enforce and strengthen the
Clayton Act’s weak limitations on bank involvement
in boards of directors.
Two mutually reinforcing developments during
the 1920s changed the menu of feasible relationships
between financiers and corporations, and led to
“incipient” universal banking. First, partly as a consequence of how the war was financed, the American public had increased its appetite for financial
securities. Even small, unsophisticated investors
wanted to partake in the securities boom of the
1920s. Second, largely in response to a wave of bank
failures caused by the decline in agricultural incomes
after World War I, many states liberalized their
regulations on bank branching and consolidation.
From 1920 to 1929, nearly 4,000 banks were absorbed by merger. At the same time, the number of
bank offices operated by branching banks rose from
1,811 to 4,117.
This meant a substantial increase in the scale
and geographic range of many U.S. banks. It also
meant that many commercial banks were becoming
large enough to reap the advantages of scope from
becoming universal banks. Commercial banks were
not permitted to sell or own stock directly but could
do so through wholly-owned affiliates that effectively operated as organs of the bank. The first three
investment affiliates of national banks were organized between 1908 and 1917, and they served as
models for the growth of affiliates in the 1920s. By
1929, 591 banks operated investment affiliates.25
In 1929, securities market optimism was suddenly shattered. The stock market crash and the
subsequent Great Depression left a bitter taste with
the public and, once again, the negative sentiment
against the financial community had been awakened. Soon another Congressional investigation was
initiated, this time under the chairmanship of
Ferdinand Pecora. This investigation intended to
show the rampant abuses, fraud, and conflict of
interest that resulted in the systematic fooling of
securities investors.
These critics argued for the end of bank affiliates
because they believed that pre-existing (senior) debt
obligations of issuing firms, if held by the bank
managing a new issue, created a conflict of interest.
It was argued that banks had an incentive to mislead
investors when selling junior securities of the firm
because doing so would increase the value of
existing bank-held debts of issuing firms. Others
opposed to affiliates based their opposition on the
supposed connection between the stock market
collapse and subsequent bank failures.
These hearings, unlike their Progressive Era
predecessor, did culminate in far-reaching regulations in the financial community. Most important
were the Securities Acts of 1933 and 1934, which
require complete disclosure of financial information, and the (Glass-Steagall) Banking Act of 1933,
which separated commercial banking activities from
investment banking, created federal deposit insurance, and imposed Regulation Q ceilings on bank
deposits.26
From the standpoint of incipient universal banking, these changes meant the end of a brief experiment. That was clearly the intent of Congress. The
Banking Act of 1933 was a compromise among
various positions, and there were great differences
between Glass’s and Steagall’s regulatory goals. The
compromise they reached was intended to reverse
the demise of small banks and to remove commercial
banks from their connections to securities markets.
Deposit insurance, which was Representative
Steagall’s hobbyhorse, was understood to be a
mandated subsidy from large banks to small banks,
and was viewed as an alternative to expanding
branching and consolidation as a means to stabilize
the banking system. The separation of commercial
and investment banking followed from Glass’s view
that the stock market had been the ruin of the
banking system. Glass pushed for Regulation Q as a
further means to insulate banks from securities
markets. He argued that removing interest on deposits would discourage banks from reserve pyramiding
in New York, and thereby break the link between the
25. Peach (1941, 18-20, 61-64).
26. See Carosso (1970), Smith and Sylla (1993), Calomiris and Raff (1995), and
Calomiris and White (1994) for descriptions of the New Deal financial market and
banking reforms and their effects.
64
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
Two mutually reinforcing developments during the 1920s changed the menu of
feasible relationships between financiers and corporations, and led to “incipient”
universal banking. One was the dramatic increase in the American public’s appetite
for financial securities. The second was the liberalization of many states’ restrictions
on bank branching and consolidation.
banking system and the call loan market for brokers
and dealers on Wall Street.
It is ironic how this “new” negative perception
in Washington contrasts with the one prevalent during
the Progressive Era. During the Pujo Investigations,
Brandeis focused on the oligopolistic behavior of the
financial community as the main source of evil that
plagued the industry. Indeed, the concept of a “Money
Trust” derived from the public perception that the
financial industry was too concentrated, and thus
easily controllable by a few influential financiers.
The Pecora investigation of the 1930s, by contrast,
effectively blamed the competitiveness of the securities industry for the “evils” that beset the market
during the late 1920s. As one example, market critics
alleged that bank affiliates were unloading securities
of poor quality onto the innocent public largely
through “misleading” advertisements. But these advertisements were, of course, a symptom not of financial monopoly, but of the increased competition
and entry that had taken place in the 1920s.
The principal accusations of the Pecora hearings have been discredited by recent research.
Benston (1989) criticizes the methods of the hearings
and finds no evidence to support their “findings.”
White (1986) finds that banks that operated affiliates
were less likely to fail than other banks, and traces
this fact to the income diversification that non-bank
activities offered. Kroszner and Rajan (1994) argue
that the alleged conflicts of interest that supposedly
led bank-affiliated investment bankers to cheat their
clients did not exist. They show that the securities
promoted by commercial bank affiliates were of
comparable quality to those underwritten and sponsored by investment banking houses. Bank affiliates
likely avoided conflicts of interest, in part by purchasing sufficient quantities of junior issues themselves and holding for sufficient lengths of time to
quell any suspicions that the issues were being
deliberately overpriced. For example, Harris Bank
and Trust in Chicago prided itself on its willingness
to purchase shares that it underwrote, and incorporated that fact into its motto (“we sell and hold”).
Furthermore, reputational considerations discourage underwriters from overpricing securities. Such
behavior would be punished by less demand for
purchases in the future, and by the loss of trust
accounts of securities purchasers who suffered losses
on the transaction.
It now seems clear that one of the principal
effects of the New Deal reforms was to undermine
beneficial relationships between firms and their
bankers. As shown in a 1994 study by Ramirez and
DeLong, before the New Deal legislation companies
affiliated with banks had higher market values than
otherwise comparable firms without such affiliations. After the New Deal, however, bank-firm
relationships had no significant effect on firms’
market values. From this standpoint, the enactment
of the New Deal reforms appears to have imposed
significant financing costs on corporations.
Why would bank-affiliated firms have higher
market values before the New Deal reforms, but not
after? The New Deal reforms limited the relationship
between financial intermediaries and corporations.
By separating investment banking from commercial
banking, the Glass-Steagall Act reduced the influence that both commercial and investment banks
had over client corporations. For commercial banks
this was clearly the case since now they were not
allowed to own corporate securities as assets. It also
reduced the influence of investment banks since
the contacts and financial resources that these banks
had with the commercial banks had been eliminated. Investment bankers had to rely solely on
their ability to search for clients to sell the underwritten securities, and not on the financial backing
of commercial banks that stood ready to purchase
blocks of securities. For the client corporations, it
indirectly increased the cost of raising funds in
external markets. To the extent that financiers were
representing shareholders, the separation of ownership and control of public corporations described
by Berle and Means in their 1932 classic had
become more acute. Judging from the patterns of
corporate finance in the next 20 to 30 years that we
discuss below, this separation appears to have had
the effect of dramatically increasing shareholders’
required rates of return and, hence, the corporate
cost of public equity.
There is a good deal of indirect evidence
supporting the claim that the cost of raising funds in
public financial markets increased in the aftermath
of the New Deal financial reforms. Private placements (private debt issues held by life insurance
companies) increased dramatically after the 1930s.
Other factors may have contributed to the long-term
growth of private placements during the late 1940s
and 1950s, but the timing of the early growth spurt
in the late 1930s and early 1940s supports the notion
that private placements were favored by the rising
cost of issuing public securities.
65
VOLUME 9 NUMBER 2
SUMMER 1996
The financial devastation of the Great Depression (and the restrictive financial regulations that
followed) increased the cost of corporate finance
and reduced the relative importance of finance from
sources other than retained earnings. Flow of funds
data indicate that the corporate sector as a whole
obtained more than 100% of its financing from retained earnings. There was a net repayment of debt
claims and virtually no stock issues during this period. Over the period 1940-1945, retained earnings
still accounted for 80% of corporate finance sources.27
To the extent that sources other than earnings
were forthcoming in the late 1930s and 1940s, they
increasingly took the form of private placements.
From 1934 to 1937, private placements accounted for
12% of a small total of corporate offerings. By 1951,
private placements accounted for 44% of all corporate offerings, 58% of all debt issues, and 82% of all
debt issues of manufacturing firms. From the beginning, life insurance companies have accounted for
the overwhelming majority of these purchases, with
the remainder held largely by banks. For the period
1990-1992, for example, life insurance companies
and banks (broadly defined) had respective shares
of 83% and 11% of the private placement market.28
Bank loans also increased in importance in the
1940s and 1950s. Indeed, the growth in private
placements during the 1940s was matched by growth
in commercial bank lending to corporations. From
1939 to 1952, life insurance companies’ outstanding
holdings of corporate debt rose from $10.4 billion to
$34.7 billion. From 1939 to 1952, total outstanding
loans from operating commercial banks to nonfinancial corporations increased from $6.2 billion to
$21.9 billion. Over that same period, bank holdings
of bonds barely increased at all—from $3.0 billion to
$3.4 billion.29
financial relationships of the 1920s? There are two
(closely related) reasons: (1) inside debt was in the
form of the most senior obligations of corporations;
and (2) inside debt remained small relative to assets.
These phenomena are related in the sense that the
seniority of debt is enhanced when senior debt
remains small relative to total assets. The information
and control requirements of relationships that entail
the supply of small quantities of senior debt are very
limited. Banks and insurance companies are able to
protect themselves by restricting debt ratios, holding
secured (collateralized) debt, and designing and
enforcing financial and behavioral covenants defined in ways that are relatively easy to observe.
Limits on financial relationships not only raised
the cost of finance for new firms, they weakened
stockholder discipline of managers in existing public companies. As Michael Jensen (1986) has argued, managers of mature companies with more
cash than they can profitably reinvest have incentives to use that “free cash flow” in ways that reduce
stockholder value—for example, in low-return investments designed to preserve market share or,
perhaps worse, diversifying acquisitions. In such
cases, the use of large quantities of debt can have
the beneficial effect of forcing managers to maximize operating profits to avoid financial distress.
For this reason, financing arrangements in which
banks and insurance companies hold small amounts
of corporate debt (relative to assets) are likely to be
a poor substitute for universal banks that are both
junior and senior stakeholders in the firm, and that
control a significant share of the voting power of
the stockholders.
The 1940s and 1950s, besides being a period of
relatively high cash flow, were a time of unusually
low debt ratios in the U.S. compared with both earlier
and later periods. For example, data on the ratio of
the market value of corporate debt to the market
value of corporate assets indicate debt-to-asset ratios
during the 1940s and 1950s of roughly 15%. Estimates for the same measure average over 30% for
four selected years between 1900 and 1929. Leverage
ratios rose significantly beginning in the 1960s and
Regressive Changes in Financing
Relationships after the 1930s
Apart from the Ramirez and DeLong study cited
earlier, why do we believe that private placements
and bank debt were inadequate substitutes for the
27. For periods of similar length prior to and after the Depression, internal
funds typically provided between one-half and two-thirds of funding. Data on the
shares of external and internal funding are from Taggart (1985, 26). Part of this
reliance on retained earnings during the early 1940s may reflect the crowding out
of corporate fundraising by government bond issues. Much of the growth in
insurance company holdings of private debt in the late 1940s and 1950s, for
example, coincided with a decline in holdings of government debt.
28. Data on private placements are from Securities and Exchange Commission
(1952, 3-6) and Carey, Prowse, Rea, and Udell (1993).
29. Data on bank holdings of bonds and notes are from Goldsmith (1958,
339,364). Producer price data are from Council of Economic Advisers (1974, 252).
66
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
It now seems clear that one of the principal effects of the New Deal reforms was to
undermine beneficial relationships between firms and their bankers.
reached the 25-40% range for most of the 1970s and
1980s.30 Several studies have argued that the unusually low debt ratios of the 1940s and 1950s exerted
too little discipline over managers.31
To summarize, in the immediate postwar period, the continuing growth of the size of corporations and the lack of any external concentration of
power to control corporate decision-making weakened the efficiency of capital market allocations and
thereby increased the costs of corporate finance. The
concentration of power over the resources of the
corporation had shifted in significant measure from
the hands of owners (and their financier agents) to
those of management.
short-term profits that some investors realized from
rapid sales of initially underpriced IPOs, most institutional investors bought stocks in the primary
market to hold as long-term investments. (Seventy
percent of institutional IPO purchases remained
unsold after 12 weeks.) Institutional investors did not
discriminate in their purchasing according to the size
of the issuer, but did tend to deal only with the largest
underwriters.
Involvement by institutional investors has been
an important contributor to the decline in the cost
of public issues of equity after the 1950s. As Friend,
Blume, and Crockett noted in a study published in
1970:
Institutional Investors and
the New Financial Capitalism32
These institutions, which first sparked the cult of
common stocks, later attracted public attention to
“growth” stocks and created the fashion for instant
performance. Innovative and inventive, institutional
money managers have ventured into areas where
older and more prudent investment men feared to
tread, taking positions in the stocks of unseasoned
companies, setting up hedge funds, devising new
types of securities (emphasis added). (vii)
The relative importance of retained earnings
and senior inside debt finance during the 1940s and
1950s was a short-lived phenomenon. Private placements as a percentage of securities offerings peaked
in the mid-1960s. The resurgence in public offerings
of bonds and stocks that began in the 1950s reduced
the share of private placements to only 14% of total
securities issues by 1970. That trend accelerated in
the early 1970s, and has continued into the present,
with dramatic growth over the 1980s and 1990s in
public issues of debt and equity, and a relative
decline in the share of inside debt relative to total
financing sources. What caused this resurgence of
public debt and equity issuance?
The boom in equity issues, beginning in the
1960s, was so dramatic that in 1971 the Securities and
Exchange Commission published an enormous multivolume study and Congress held hearings examining these changes. That study concluded that, in the
market for new common stock issues, institutional
investors such as pensions, mutuals, and trusts had
changed the way equity issues were sold. By acting
as purchasers of large amounts of stock, particularly
in unseasoned companies, these investors reduced
the marketing costs normally associated with placing
such stock. The SEC found that institutional investors
accounted for 24% of all purchases of 1,684 initial
public offerings (IPOs) of common stock from
January 1967 to March 1970. Despite enormous
Part of the SEC’s 1971 study focuses on the
impact of institutional investors on corporate issuers.
It emphasizes that, by selling in block to institutional
buyers of primary public common stock offerings,
investment bankers could economize on the costs of
marketing securities. It was easier for underwriters to
communicate an issuer’s “story” to a few block buyers, especially if those block buyers were institutional investors with large trust accounts managed by
New York banks. Additionally, the concentration of
stockholdings of unseasoned firms may have facilitated control over management, and thus reduced
the potential risk of stock purchases and the need for
information about the firm at the time of the offering.
The SEC argued that the benefits of institutional
purchasing for reducing issue costs on public equity
went beyond the direct transaction-cost savings of
placing shares in the hands of institutional investors.
The participation of institutional buyers in an offering also made it easier to sell the remainder of the
offering to individual investors. In the words of the
SEC study:
30. Data on debt ratios are from Taggart (1985, 24-28).
31. Myers (1976) points to unprofitable mergers as an example of lack of
discipline over corporate management during the 1960s.
32. The discussion in this section borrows heavily from Calomiris and Raff
(1995).
67
VOLUME 9 NUMBER 2
SUMMER 1996
market as well. In addition to their $1.4 billion in
public IPO purchases during the period 1967-1970,
institutional investors purchased $3.5 billion of nonpublicly traded “restricted” securities (venture capital investments in equity or debt with equity features). Venture capitalists provide a combination of
discipline and funding for a class of firms very
different from those affiliated with Morgan in the preWorld War I era. Whereas Morgan tended to deal
with the largest and best-seasoned credit risks in the
economy, venture capitalists finance unseasoned
firms that lack access to public markets and play an
important role in managing the financial arrangements of those firms.
Venture capital funds, which became especially
popular in the 1970s, operate as two-tiered sets of
relationships. Large institutional investors hold shares
of the fund, which invests in multiple firms selected
and monitored by the venture capitalist. To ensure
the alignment of its interests with those of its limited
partners, the venture capitalist also retains a stake in
the fund. Such relationships among the institutional
investors, venture capitalists, and start-up firms often
have spillover effects as the firms mature. Institutional investors often participate in the IPOs of the
firms that they helped finance earlier.
Not only have the new institutional investors
relaxed constraints on the financing of new enterprises, they have acted to strengthen stockholder
discipline over managers by concentrating stock
ownership and by financing efficient restructurings.
For example, bank venture capital funds have been
particularly active in LBOs, MBOs, and industry
consolidations.
Government policy has had important influences on the venture capital market, and on the
involvement of institutional investors and commercial banks in venture capital funds. Regulatory
changes that favored limited commercial bank entry
into equity funds to finance small businesses (under
the Small Business Investment Company Act of 1958)
provided an early impetus for expansion. In 1971 the
Bank Holding Company Act further relaxed restrictions on bank entry into venture capital, and there
was a significant influx of bank capital into venture
Retail members of the syndicate have been known
to advise their customers in advance of the offering
that institutions have indicated their intent to buy the
issue...While this knowledge of institutional interest
may increase the public’s appetite for any stock, the
effect is greater for small, less established issuers than
for large established issuers and still more so for first
offerings of such small companies....The possible
public impression that institutions, with their purported research capabilities and sophistication, would
not allow themselves to be bilked helps explain individual investors’ attitudes toward institutional interest. The result, then, of supposed or revealed institutional interest in an offering is to enhance retail
interest as well. (p. 2393)
More formal empirical studies have reported a
dramatic reduction in issuing costs from 1950 to
1970, and have identified small, unseasoned issuers
(those for which information problems and marketing costs are greatest) as the largest beneficiaries of
such reductions. These studies attribute the decline
in the costs of public issues to the role of institutional
investors in making block purchases of stock, which
in turn reduces costs of information and control in
the market for public securities.33
The growth of pension funds’ and mutual funds’
holdings of equity in the late 1950s and 1960s was
dramatic. In 1946, investment companies (mutual
funds) and private pension funds held 2% and 0.8%
respective shares of corporate equities. By 1980,
private pensions held 10.4% of corporate equity, and
investment companies held 4.6%. Private pension
funds’ holdings of common stock grew from 12% of
their total assets in 1951 to 68% in 1971.34
The continuing growth of these intermediaries
reflects their unique abilities and incentives to invest
in information and control corporate performance.
The principal sources of early growth in pension
funds were the wage controls of World War II (which
favored the use of non-wage compensation) and the
tax exemptions enjoyed by pensions, which became
increasingly valuable during the 1960s.
As the 1971 SEC study also showed, institutional
investors were very active in the venture capital
33. The above paragraph refers to studies by Mendelson (1967) and Calomiris
and Raff (1995), which conclude that the costs of public common stock issues
(measured by underwriting commissions, or commissions plus expenses) fell
dramatically from 1950 to 1970, and that this decline was especially pronounced
for small, relatively unseasoned firms. The benefits of institutional purchases are
also visible in cross-sectional differences in underwriting costs. In a study of the
determinants of underwriting fees for recent common stock issues, Hansen and
Torregrossa (1992) show that institutional investor purchases of common stock
issues are associated with lower issuing costs.
34. Useful studies of the development of institutional investors include
Andrews (1964), Greenough and King (1976), Ture (1976), and Munnell (1982).
68
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
While new foreign entrants enjoyed a cost-of-funds advantage, domestic U.S. banks
enjoyed an information cost advantage in loan origination and monitoring that
helped them retain customers for which those costs were an important component
of the cost of providing loans.
capital affiliates. Bank holding companies, moreover, have come to play an increasingly important
role in the growth of private equity finance. In some
of the largest American bank holding companies
(including Citicorp, Chemical, Chase, First Chicago,
and Continental), venture capital earnings contributed substantially to net profits during the 1980s.
Finally, a redefinition of ERISA’s “prudent man rule”
in the late 1970s has helped overcome pension
funds’ earlier reluctance to invest in venture capital,
and pension funds today routinely hold up to five
percent of their funds in such investments.
One indicator of the demise of relationships—
the significant decline in domestic commercial bank
holdings as a percentage of total corporate debt
(from 30% in 1983 to 16% in 1993)—has been
misinterpreted. This drop in the percentage of
domestic bank loans has been roughly equal to the
increased market share of two categories: foreign
bank loans and market (notably, asset-backed) securities. What tends to be overlooked in arguments
about the demise of U.S. bank lending is that, for
many borrowers, such changes in the identities of
the ultimate holders of debt did not amount to
changes in their banking relationships.
Take the case of the rise of foreign bank loans.
In many cases, domestic banks either originated and
then sold loans to foreign banks, or they managed
syndicated loans in which foreign banks participated. A study by Calomiris and Carey (1994)
concludes that foreign banks’ success in gaining U.S.
corporate market share during the 1980s reflected
their cost-of-funds advantage over U.S. banks—an
advantage that arose from foreign banks’ higher
capital ratios during that period. But, as the same
study also showed (see Table 1), foreign banks
significantly underpriced domestic banks only in the
case of high-quality borrowers. In the case of lowquality borrowers, foreign banks’ interest rates were
about the same as that of domestic banks, and their
percentage market share in relation to U.S. banks
was considerably lower. Foreign banks’ lack of preexisting lending relationships presumably made it
more difficult for them to compete for this business
where information costs are likely to be significant.
In other words, while new foreign entrants enjoyed
a cost-of-funds advantage, domestic U.S. banks
enjoyed an information cost advantage in loan
origination and monitoring that helped them retain
customers for which those costs were important.
The relationship-cost advantage of U.S. banks is
also visible in performance differences between
U.S.-owned and foreign-owned banks after the
foreign-entry wave of the ’80s. Nolle (1994) finds that
foreign-owned banks had much lower returns on
assets in the ’90s, and that this difference reflects both
higher overhead costs and higher loan-loss rates for
foreign banks.
Also worth noting is that another major category
of new growth—asset-backed securitizations—requires origination, and often “credit enhancement,”
services that are typically provided by relationship
bankers. Thus, while bankers may have changed the
Why Technology Has Not Done Away With
Relationship Financing
The growth of new institutional investors after
the 1960s brought with it a new scope to financial
relationships—one reminiscent of pre-Depression
financial capitalism. A multi-tiered intermediation
arrangement involving institutional investors, trust
bankers, venture capitalists, large commercial banks,
and investment bank underwriters has emerged.
This has been accompanied by the formation of
long-term relationships among all of these different
groups, and with the corporations in need of funds.
While these arrangements are still a far cry from
universal banking, they share some important advantages. The scale of funding sources is large
relative to the needs of firms (which economizes on
the costs of placement); there is often continuity in
the relationships between firms and intermediaries
over time; and intermediaries are junior as well as
senior claimants of the firm (which provides incentives and means for intermediaries to monitor and
control corporations).
It has become common to argue that the rapid
growth in securities transactions during the 1980s,
domestically and internationally, is evidence that
financial relationships are no longer important. Such
arguments usually point vaguely toward computers
as the source of the new technological breakthroughs. Such advances have led to developments
like the expansion of common stock markets in
developing countries, the surge of bank loan sales,
syndications, and asset-backed securitizations in the
U.S., and the remarkable growth of derivative transactions worldwide.
Has innovation made it possible to resolve
information and control problems without resort to
traditional relationships? We think not.
69
VOLUME 9 NUMBER 2
SUMMER 1996
TABLE 1
MEAN SPREADS
ON REVOLVERS
BY LENDER TYPE AND
BORROWING RATING
1986-1993
Borrower Rating
A:
U.S. Owned Banks
Foreign Owned Banks
Mixed U.S. and
Foreign Owned Banks
Mean Spread
(Number)
82
(64)
40
(35)
47
(125)
BBB: Mean Spread
(Number)
89
(90)
67
(30)
80
(226)
BB:
Mean Spread
(Number)
158
(217)
165
(33)
146
(188)
B:
Mean Spread
(Number)
229
(229)
210
(45)
220
(161)
banking activities, including securities underwriting,
derivatives sales, mutual fund management, and
venture capital finance. There are still important
legislative and regulatory barriers to universal banking in the U.S.; but the tide clearly has turned, and
many academics and regulators have come out in
support of removing existing barriers. Although
Congressional efforts to repeal Glass-Steagall outright stalled in 1996, the Fed once again relaxed
limitations on bank involvement in securities underwriting and other activities.
Why the sudden change? In the 1980s and
1990s, as in the 1920s, regulators and politicians
relaxed restrictions and expanded bank powers in
response to a crisis. In the 1920s, it was the collapse of small, rural banks that prompted a bank
consolidation movement, which in turn encouraged the expansion of powers. Most states relaxed
branching laws between 1920 and 1939 to encourage entry by banks amid widespread economic
distress. In the 1980s, it was once again the collapse of many small banks and thrifts that prompted
action. Between 1979 and 1990, most states significantly relaxed their internal branching laws prior to
any federal action.
Federal regulators, notably Alan Greenspan,
were also concerned about declining profits of large
banks in the late 1980s and the increased competition banks faced from abroad, which was the single
most important source of lost commercial and industrial lending business for domestic banks. Regulators
argued that expanded powers were necessary to
level the playing field between universal banks in
other countries and American commercial banks.
An emphasis on the relationship benefits of
universal banking raises interesting issues for current
packaging of their credit services, they continue to
play their familiar roles as screeners, monitors, and
marketers for their client firms.
In short, computers have not repealed the laws
of economics. They have not provided a magical
solution to creditors’ age-old problems of monitoring and controlling the behavior of owners, or of
stockholders’ problems of controlling managers.
Computers have facilitated the dissemination of
statistical credit analysis, and thus encouraged financial innovations that allow the sharing of risk among
institutions, nationally and internationally. But they
have not fundamentally changed the fact that, for the
vast majority of firms, corporate finance is still based
on relationships.
Indeed, one could argue that new financial
innovations are more rapidly propelling financial
intermediaries toward universal banking. Once the
fixed costs of providing multiple products are reduced, there is more room for “relationship economies of scope” to influence the structure of the
financial services industry. By expanding the menu
of services that a single intermediary can provide,
technological progress may end up strengthening
long-term relationships between clients and their
intermediaries.
THE PROSPECTS FOR UNIVERSAL BANKING
The most recent major change in corporate
finance technology has come from relaxation of
restrictions on bank scale and scope. Limits on
branching—the single most important impediment
to an efficient system of corporate finance throughout American history—have been virtually eliminated. Banks have gained entry to non-traditional
70
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
One could argue that new financial innovations are more rapidly propelling
financial intermediaries toward universal banking. By expanding the menu of
services that a single intermediary can provide, technological progress may end up
strengthening long-term relationships between clients and their intermediaries.
regulatory reform. For example, repeal of restrictions on equity holdings by banks would have likely
have greater economic benefits (by reducing the
costs of corporate governance and financial distress
that are built into the cost of corporate finance) than
allowing banks to sell insurance. But, it is insurance
proposals that are receiving far more attention in
current discussions of universal banking. Furthermore, repealing underwriting restrictions has the
potential to yield greater relationship-cost savings if
U.S. banks (like German banks) were also allowed
to sell the issues they underwrite to their own
customers and thus retain control over stock voting
rights of client firms.
Three relatively successful periods—the antebellum
New England system, incipient universal banking in
the 1920s, and modern-day financial capitalism—
are separated by periods that saw dramatic reductions in the menu of financial relationships. Thus,
although there may be a tendency for efficient
financial relationships (like those that grow up in a
universal banking system) to prevail over the very
long run, there are significant interim periods (some
lasting decades) in which government interventions
have stood in the way of these beneficial relationships. The history of U.S. corporate finance has by
no means been a process of steady or rapid convergence toward the most efficient set of relationships.
Whether recent trends toward the expansion of
the scale and scope of commercial bank operations
will usher in a lasting era of universal banking and
low-cost corporate finance in the U.S. remains an
open question. We suspect that the road ahead will
be as bumpy as that which has already been
travelled. The future menu of relationships is hard
to predict; institutional change is path-dependent
and subject to the unforeseeable influences of
financial crises and government policy. Despite the
potential for improvement in banking regulation
brought by global competition, the next financial
crisis—say, a costly bank failure stemming from
complicated derivative transactions—could reverse
some of the progress that has been made in broadening banks’ involvement in non-traditional corporate finance.
CONCLUSION
The history of the American system of corporate
finance, and of corporate financial relationships
within that system, reflects the interplay among
financial frictions (such as information and control
costs of corporate finance), government policies (in
the form of bank and financial market regulations,
tax policies, pension laws, bankruptcy laws), financial crises, and financial innovations. These influences have together determined the menu of financial relationships available to corporations over time.
In terms of its ability to reduce the information
and control costs of corporate finance, the history
of the American financial system includes periods
of significant progress, as well as major reversals.
CARLOS D. RAMIREZ
CHARLES CALOMIRIS
is Professor of Economics at George Mason University.
is Paul M. Montrone Professor of Finance and Economics at
Columbia University’s Graduate School of Business and a
Faculty Research Fellow of the National Bureau of Economic
Research.
71
VOLUME 9 NUMBER 2
SUMMER 1996
REFERENCES
Andrews, V.L. (1964). “Noninsured Corporate and State and Local
Government Retirement Funds in the Financial Structure,” in Private
Capital Markets, Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, Inc., 381-531.
Atack, J. and F. Bateman (1994). “Did the United States Industrialize
Too Slowly?” Working paper, Vanderbilt University.
Baskin, J. (1988). “The Development of Corporate Financial Markets in
Britain and the United States, 1600-1914: Overcoming Asymmetric
Information,” Business History Review 62, 199-237.
Benston, G.J. (1989). The Separation of Commercial and Investment
Banking: The Glass-Steagall Act Revisited and Reconsidered, Norwell:
Kluwer Academic.
Benveniste, L.M., and P.A. Spindt (1989). “How Investment Bankers
Determine the Offer Price and Allocation of New Issues,” Journal of
Financial Economics 24 (October), 343-361.
Benveniste, L.M., and W.J. Wilhelm (1990). “A Comparative Analysis
of IPO Proceeds Under Alternative Regulatory Environments,” Journal
of Financial Economics 28 (November-December), 173-207.
Berle, A., and G. Means (1932). The Modern Corporation and Private
Property, New York: Macmillan.
Billett, M.T., M.J. Flannery, and J.A. Garfinkel (1995). “The Effect of
Lender Identity on a Borrowing Firm’s Equity Return,” Journal of Finance
50 (June), 699-718.
Bittilingmayer, G. (1985). “Did Antitrust Policy Cause the Great Merger
Wave?” Journal of Law and Economics 28 (April), 77-118.
Bodenhorn, H. (1990). “Capital Mobility and Financial Integration in
Antebellum America,” Journal of Economic History 52 (September), 585-610.
Brewer, E. (1989). “Relationship between Bank Holding Company Risk
and Nonbank Activity,” Journal of Economics and Business 41 (November), 337-353.
Butters, J.K., and J. Lintner (1945). Effects of Federal Taxes on Growing
Enterprises, Boston: Harvard University Press.
Calomiris, C.W. (1993a). “Regulation, Industrial Structure, and Instability in U.S. Banking: An Historical Perspective,” in Structural Change in
Banking, M. Klausner and L.J. White (Eds.), Homewood, Illinois:
Business One-Irwin, 19-115.
Calomiris, C.W. (1995). “The Costs of Rejecting Universal Banking:
American Finance in the German Mirror, 1870-1914,” in The Coordination of Acitivity Within and Between Firms, N. Lamoreaux and D.M.G.
Raff (Eds.), Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 257-315.
Calomiris, C.W., and M. Carey (1994). “Loan Market Competition
Between Foreign and U.S. Banks: Some Facts About Loans and Borrowers,” in Proceedings of the 30th Annual Conference on Bank Structure
and Competition, Chicago: Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.
Calomiris, C.W., C.P. Himmelberg, and P. Wachtel (1995). “Commercial Paper, Corporate Finance, and the Business Cycle: A Microeconomic
Perspective,” Carnegie-Rochester Series on Public Policy, forthcoming.
Calomiris, C.W., and R.G. Hubbard (1995). “Internal Finance and
Investment: Evidence from the Undistributed Profits Tax of 1936-1937,”
Journal of Business 68 (October), 443-482.
Calomiris, C.W., and R.G. Hubbard (1990). “Firm Heterogeneity, Internal Finance and ‘Credit Rationing’,” Economic Journal 100 (March), 90-104.
Calomiris, C.W., and C.M. Kahn (1996). “The Efficiency of SelfRegulated Payments Systems: Learning from the Suffolk System,” Journal
of Money, Credit, and Banking, forthcoming.
Calomiris, C.W., and D.M.G. Raff (1995). “The Evolution of Market
Structure, Information, and Spreads in American Investment Banking,”
in Anglo-American Finance: Financial Markets and Institutions in
20th-Century North America and the U.K., R. Sylla and M. Bordo (Eds.),
Homewood, Illinois: Business One-Irwin, forthcoming.
Calomiris, C.W., and E.N. White (1994). “The Origins of Federal
Deposit Insurance,” in The Regulated Economy: A Historical Approach to
Political Economy, C. Goldin and G. Libecap (Eds.), Chicago: University
of Chicago Press, 145-188.
Campbell, E.G. (1938). The Reorganization of the American Railroad
System, 1893-1900, New York: Columbia University Press.
Carey, M., S. Prowse, J. Rea, and G. Udell (1993). “The Economics of
Private Placements: A New Look,” Financial Markets, Institutions, and
Instruments 2(3), 1-67.
Carosso, V.P. (1970). Investment Banking in America, Cambridge:
Harvard University Press.
Chandler, A.D. (1977). The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in
American Business, Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Chemmanur, T.J. and P. Fulghieri (1994). “Investment Bank Repudiation, Information Production, and Financial Intermediation,” Journal of
Finance 49 (March), 57-79.
Cleveland, H. and T. Huertas (1986). Citibank, 1812-1970, Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Council of Economic Advisers (1974). Economic Report of the President, Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
Davis, L. (1957). “Sources of Industrial Finance: The American Textile
Industry, A Case Study,” Explorations in Entrepreneurial History 9, 190203.
Davis, L. (1960). “The New England Textile Mills and the Capital Markets:
A Study of Industrial Borrowing, 1840-1860,” Journal of Economic
History 20, 1-30.
Davis, L. (1963). “Capital Immobilities and Finance Capitalism: A Study
of Economic Evolution in the United States, 1820-1920,” Explorations in
Entrepreneurial History (Fall), 88-105.
Davis, L. (1965). “The Investment Market, 1870-1914: The Evolution of a National Market,” Journal of Economic History 25 (Sept.),
355-399.
Davis, L. (1966). “The Capital Markets and Industrial Concerns: The
U.S. and the U.K., A Comparative Study,” Economic History Review
19, 255-272.
De Long, J.B. (1991). “Did J. P. Morgan’s Men Add Value? An Economist’s
Perspective on Financial Capitalism,” in Inside the Business Enterprise:
Historical Perspectives on the Use of Information, P. Temin (Ed.) Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 205-236.
Dobrovolsky, S.P., and M. Bernstein (1960). “Long Term Trends in
Capital Financing,” in Capital in Manufacturing and Mining: Its Formation and Financing, D. Creamer, S.P. Dobrovolsky, I. Borenstein (Eds.).
Princeton: Princeton University Press, 109-193.
Fazzari, S.M., R.G. Hubbard, and B.C. Petersen (1988). “Financing
Constraints and Corporate Investment,” Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity, (1), 141-195.
Foulke, R.A. (1931). The Commercial Paper Market, New York: Bankers’
Publishing Co.
Friend, I., M. Blume, and J. Crockett (1970). Mutual Funds and Other
Institutional Investors, New York: McGraw-Hill.
Goldsmith, R.W. (1958). Financial Intermediaries in the American
Economy Since 1900, Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Goldsmith, R.W., R.E. Lipsey, and M. Mendelsohn (1963). Studies in
the National Balance Sheet of the United States, Princeton: Princeton
University Press.
Greef, A.O. (1938). The Commercial Paper House in the United States,
Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Greenough, W.C., and F.P. King (1976). Pension Plans and Public
Policy, New York: Columbia University Press.
72
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
Myers, S.C. (1977). “Determinants of Corporate Borrowing,” Journal of
Financial Economics 5, 147-175.
Myers, S.C. and N. Majluf (1984). “Corporate Financing and Investment
Decisions When Firms Have Information That Investors Do Not Have,”
Journal of Financial Economics 13, 187-221.
Nolle, D. (1994). “Are Foreign Banks Out-Competing U.S. Banks in the
U.S. Market?,” Economic and Policy Analysis Working Paper 94-5, Office
of the Comptroller of the Currency (May).
Peach, W. P. (1941). The Security Affiliates of National Banks, Baltimore:
Johns Hopkins University Press.
Petersen, M., and R. Rajan (1994). “The Benefits of Lending Relationships: Evidence from Small Business Data,” Journal of Finance 49
(March), 3-37.
Ramirez, C.D. (1995). “Did J.P. Morgan’s Men Add Liquidity? Corporate
Investment, Cash Flow, and Financial Structure at the Turn of the
Twentieth Century,” Journal of Finance 50 (June), 661-678.
Ramirez, C.D., and J.B. De Long (1994). “Banker Influence and
Business Economic Performance: Assessing the Impact of DepressionEra Financial Market Reforms,” Working paper, George Mason University.
Riefler, W.W. (1930). Money Rates and Money Markets in the United
States, New York: Harper and Brothers.
Securities and Exchange Commission (1952). Privately-Placed Securities: Cost of Flotation, Washington D.C.: The Commission.
Securities and Exchange Commission (1971). Cost of Flotation of
Registered Equity Issues, 1963-1965, Washington, D.C.: The Commission.
Selden, R. T. (1963). “Trends and Cycles in the Commercial Paper
Market.” NBER Occasional Paper No. 85, New York: National Bureau of
Economic Research.
Slovin, M.B., M.E. Sushka, and J.A. Polonchek (1992). “The Value of
Bank Durability: Borrowers as Bank Stakeholders,” Journal of Finance
48 (March), 247-266.
Smith, G.D. and R. Sylla (1993). “The Transformation of Financial
Capitalism: An Essay on the History of American Capital Markets,” New
York University Salomon Center Financial Markets, Institutions, and
Instruments 2 (May), 1-62.
Stiglitz, J. and A. Weiss (1981). “Credit Rationing in Markets With
Imperfect Information,” American Economic Review 71, 393-410.
Sylla, R. (1969). “Federal Policy, Banking Market Structure, and Capital
Mobilization in the United States, 1863-1913,” Journal of Economic
History 29 (December), 657-686.
Taggart, R.A. (1985). “Secular Patterns in the Financing of U.S.
Corporations,” in Corporate Capital Structures in the United States, B.M.
Friedman (Ed.), Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 13-80.
Townsend, R. (1979). “Optimal Contracts and Competitive Markets with
Costly State Verification,” Journal of Economic Theory (October), 265-293.
Trusk, R.J. (1960). Sources of Capital of Early California Manufacturers,
1850 to 1880, Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Illinois.
Tufano, P. (1992). “Business Failure, Legal Innovation, and Financial
Innovation in Historical Perspective,” Working paper, Harvard University.
Ture, Norman B. (1976). The Future of Private Pension Plans, Washington D.C.: American Enterprise Institute.
White, E. N. (1986). “Before the Glass-Steagall Act: An Analysis of the
Investment Banking Activities of National Banks,” Explorations in
Economic History 23 (January), 33-55.
Hansen, R.S., and P. Torregrossa (1992). “Underwriter Compensation
and Corporate Monitoring,” Journal of Finance 47 (September), 15371555.
Hoshi, T., A. Kashyap, and D. Scharfstein (1990a). “The Role of Banks
in Reducing the Costs of Financial Distress,” Journal of Financial
Economics 27 (September), 67-88.
Hoshi, T., A. Kashyap, and D. Scharfstein (1990b). “Bank Monitoring
and Investment: Evidence from the Changing Structure of Japanese
Corporate Banking Relationships,” in Asymmetric Information, Corporate Finance, and Investment, R.G. Hubbard (Ed.), Chicago: University
of Chicago Press, 105-126.
Hoshi, T., A. Kashyap, and D. Scharfstein (1991). “Corporate Structure, Liquidity, and Investment: Evidence from Japanese Industrial
Groups,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 106, 33-60.
James, C. (1987). “Some Evidence on the Uniqueness of Bank Loans,”
Journal of Financial Economics 19, 217-235.
James, J. (1978). Money and Capital Markets in Postbellum America,
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Jarrell, G.A. (1981). “The Economic Effects of Federal Regulation of the
Market for New Security Issues,” Journal of Law and Economics 24
(December), 613-675.
Jensen, M.C. (1986). “Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate
Finance and Takeovers,” American Economic Association Papers and
Proceedings 76 (May), 323-329.
Jensen, M.C., and W.H. Meckling (1976). “Theory of the Firm:
Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure,” Journal
of Financial Economics 3, 305-360.
Kaufman, G., and L. Mote (1990). “Glass-Steagall: Repeal By Regulatory and Judicial Reinterpretation,” Banking Law Journal (SeptemberOctober), 388-421.
Kroszner, R. S., and R. G. Rajan (1994). “Is the Glass-Steagall Act
Justified? A Study of the U.S. Experience with Universal Banking before
1933,” American Economic Review 84 (September), 810-832.
Lamoreaux, N. (1991a). “Information Problems and Banks: Specialization in Short-Term Commercial Lending, New England in the 19th
Century,” in Inside the Business Enterprise: Historical Perspectives on the
Use of Information, P. Temin (Ed.), Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
154-195.
Lamoreaux, N. (1991b). “Bank Mergers in Late 19th-Century New
England: The Contingent Nature of Structural Change,” Journal of
Economic History 51 (September), 537-558.
Lamoreaux, N. (1994). Insider Lending: Banks, Personal Connections,
and Economic Development in Industrial New England, 1784-1912,
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Marquardt, M. O. (1960). Sources of Capital of Early Illinois Manufacturers, 1840-1880, Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Illinois.
Martin, A. (1972). “Railroads and the Equity Receivership: An Essay on
Institutional Change,” Journal of Economic History 34 (September), 685709.
Mendelson, M. (1967). “Underwriting Compensation,” in Investment
Banking and the New Issues Market, I. Friend, J.R. Longstreet, M.
Mendelson, E. Miller, and A.P. Hess, Jr. (Eds.), New York: The World
Publishing Company, 394-479.
Munnell, A.H. (1982). The Economics of Private Pensions, Washington
D.C.: The Brookings Institution.
73
VOLUME 9 NUMBER 2
SUMMER 1996
Journal of Applied Corporate Finance (ISSN 1078-1196 [print], ISSN
1745-6622 [online]) is published quarterly on behalf of Morgan Stanley by
Blackwell Publishing, with offices at 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148,
USA,andPOBox1354,9600GarsingtonRoad,OxfordOX42XG,UK.Call
US:(800)835-6770,UK:+441865778315;faxUS:(781)388-8232,UK:
+441865471775,ore-mail:subscrip@bos.blackwellpublishing.com.
Information For Subscribers For new orders, renewals, sample copy requests, claims, changes of address, and all other subscription correspondence, please contact the Customer Service Department at your nearest
Blackwelloffice.
Subscription Rates for Volume 17 (four issues) Institutional Premium
Rate*TheAmericas†$330,RestofWorld£201;CommercialCompanyPremium Rate, The Americas $440, Rest of World £268; Individual Rate, The
Americas$95,RestofWorld£70,105‡;Students**,TheAmericas$50,
RestofWorld£28,42.
*Includes print plus premium online access to the current and all available
backfiles.Printandonline-onlyratesarealsoavailable(seebelow).
†
CustomersinCanadashouldadd7%GSTorprovideevidenceofentitlement
toexemption
‡
CustomersintheUKshouldaddVATat5%;customersintheEUshouldalso
addVATat5%,orprovideaVATregistrationnumberorevidenceofentitlementtoexemption
** Students must present a copy of their student ID card to receive this
rate.
FormoreinformationaboutBlackwellPublishingjournals,includingonlineaccessinformation,termsandconditions,andotherpricingoptions,pleasevisit
www.blackwellpublishing.com or contact our customer service department,
tel:(800)835-6770or+441865778315(UKoffice).
BackIssuesBackissuesareavailablefromthepublisheratthecurrentsingle-
issuerate.
MailingJournalofAppliedCorporateFinanceismailedStandardRate.Mailing to rest of world by DHL Smart & Global Mail. Canadian mail is sent by
Canadian publications mail agreement number 40573520. Postmaster
SendalladdresschangestoJournalofAppliedCorporateFinance,Blackwell
PublishingInc.,JournalsSubscriptionDepartment,350MainSt.,Malden,MA
02148-5020.
JournalofAppliedCorporateFinanceisavailableonlinethroughSynergy,
Blackwell’sonlinejournalservicewhichallowsyouto:
• B
rowsetablesofcontentsandabstractsfromover290professional,
science,socialscience,andmedicaljournals
• C
reateyourownPersonalHomepagefromwhichyoucanaccessyour
personalsubscriptions,setupe-mailtableofcontentsalertsandrun
savedsearches
•Performdetailedsearchesacrossourdatabaseoftitlesandsavethe
searchcriteriaforfutureuse
•LinktoandfrombibliographicdatabasessuchasISI.
Signupforfreetodayathttp://www.blackwell-synergy.com.
DisclaimerThePublisher,MorganStanley,itsaffiliates,andtheEditorcannot
beheldresponsibleforerrorsoranyconsequencesarisingfromtheuseof
informationcontainedinthisjournal.Theviewsandopinionsexpressedinthis
journaldonotnecessarilyrepresentthoseofthePublisher,MorganStanley,
itsaffiliates,andEditor,neitherdoesthepublicationofadvertisementsconstituteanyendorsementbythePublisher,MorganStanley,itsaffiliates,and
Editor of the products advertised. No person should purchase or sell any
securityorassetinrelianceonanyinformationinthisjournal.
MorganStanleyisafullservicefinancialservicescompanyactiveinthesecurities,investmentmanagementandcreditservicesbusinesses.MorganStanley
may have and may seek to have business relationships with any person or
companynamedinthisjournal.
Copyright©2004MorganStanley.Allrightsreserved.Nopartofthispublicationmaybereproduced,storedortransmittedinwholeorpartinanyform
or by any means without the prior permission in writing from the copyright
holder.Authorizationtophotocopyitemsforinternalorpersonaluseorforthe
internalorpersonaluseofspecificclientsisgrantedbythecopyrightholder
forlibrariesandotherusersoftheCopyrightClearanceCenter(CCC),222
Rosewood Drive, Danvers, MA 01923, USA (www.copyright.com), provided
theappropriatefeeispaiddirectlytotheCCC.Thisconsentdoesnotextend
tootherkindsofcopying,suchascopyingforgeneraldistributionforadvertisingorpromotionalpurposes,forcreatingnewcollectiveworksorforresale.
Institutionswithapaidsubscriptiontothisjournalmaymakephotocopiesfor
teachingpurposesandacademiccourse-packsfreeofchargeprovidedsuch
copiesarenotresold.Forallotherpermissionsinquiries,includingrequests
torepublishmaterialinanotherwork,pleasecontacttheJournalsRightsand
PermissionsCoordinator,BlackwellPublishing,9600GarsingtonRoad,Oxford
OX42DQ.E-mail:journalsrights@oxon.blackwellpublishing.com.