DISCUSSION PAPERS
Institute of Economics
University of Copenhagen
04-31
Inflation, Money Growth, and I(2) Analysis
Katarina Juselius
Studiestræde 6, DK-1455 Copenhagen K., Denmark
Tel. +45 35 32 30 82 - Fax +45 35 32 30 00
http://www.econ.ku.dk
In ation, Money Growth, and I(2)
Analysis
Katarina Juselius
Studiestr de 6, 1455 Copenhagen K,
Denmark
Abstract
The paper discusses the dynamics of in ation and money
growth in a stochastic framework, allowing for double unit roots
in the nominal variables. It gives some examples of typical I(2)
'symptoms' in empirical I(1) models and provides both a nontechnical and a technical discussion of the basic di erences between the I(1) and the I(2) model. The notion of long-run and
medium-run price homogeneity is discussed in terms of testable
restrictions on the I(2) model. The Brazilian high in ation period
of 1977:1-1985:5 illustrates the applicability of the I(2) model and
its usefulness to address questions related to in ation dynamics.
JEL classi cation: C32, E41, E31.
Keywords: Cointegrated VAR, Price Homogeneity, Cagan Model,
Hyper In ation
1
Introduction1
The purpose of this paper is to give an intuitive account of the cointegrated VAR model for I(2) data and to demonstrate that the rich structure of the I(2) model is particularly relevant for the empirical analyses
of economic data characterized by highly persistent shocks to the growth
rates. Such data are usually found in applications of economic models
explaining the determination of nominal magnitudes. For example, the
explicit assumption of a nonstationary error term in some models of
money demand during periods of high or hyper in ation (Cagan, 1956,
Sargent, 1977), implies that nominal money and prices are I(2). Thus,
1
Useful comments from Michael Goldberg, S ren Johansen, and Mikael Juselius
are gratefully acknowledged. The article was produced with nacial support from
the Danish Social Sciences Research Council.
1
the empirical analysis of such models would only make sense in the I(2)
model framework.
However, as argued in Juselius and Vuojesevic (2003), prices in hyperin ationary episodes should not be modelled as an I(2) but rather as an
explosive root process. Though such episodes are (almost by de nition) short they are usually preceded by periods of high in ation rates
for which the I(2) analysis is more adequate. Even though in ationary
shocks in such periods are usually large, it is worth stressing that the
(double) unit root property, as such, is not related to the magnitude but
the permanence of shocks. Therefore, we may equally well nd double unit roots in prices during periods of low in ation rates, like the
nineties, and not just in periods of high in ation rates like the seventies.
But, while the persistence of shocks determine whether price in ation
is I(1) or I(0), the magnitude of in ationary shocks is probably much
more indicative of a risk for hyper in ation. High in ation periods are,
therefore, particularly interesting as they are likely to contain valuable
information about the mechanisms which subsequently might lead to
hyper-in ation.
The empirical application to the Brazilian high-in ation period of
1977-1985 o ers a good illustration of the potential advantages of using
the I(2) model and demonstrates how it can be used to study important aspects of the in ationary mechanism in periods preceding hyper
in ation.
The Cagan hyper in ation model is rst translated into set of testable
empirical hypotheses on the pulling and pushing forces described by the
cointegrated I(2) model in AR and MA form. The paper nds strong
empirical support for one of the hypothetical pulling forces, the Cagan money demand relation with the opportunity cost of holding money
measured by a combination of CPI in ation and currency depreciation
in the black market. The Cagan's
coe cient, de ning the average
in ation rate at which government can gain maximum seignorage, is
estimated to be approximately 40-50% which is usually considered to
describe hyper in ation. Thus, it seems likely that the seed to the subsequent Brazilian hyper in ation episode can be found in the present
data. This is further supported by the nding that (1) there is a small
explosive root in the VAR model, (2) the condition for long-run price homogeneity was strongly violated, and (3) the CPI price in ation showed
lack of equilibrium correction behavior. The latter is associated with
the widespread use of wage and price indexation, which prohibited market forces to adjust back to equilibrium after a price distortion. As a
consequence domestic price in ation gained momentum as a result of
increasing in ationary expectations in the foreign exchange market.
2
The organization of the paper is as follows: Section 2 discusses
money growth and in ation in a Cagan type of high / hyper in ation
model framework. Section 3 reformulates the high in ation problem in
a stochastic framework allowing for double unit roots in the nominal
variables. Section 4 discusses typical 'symptoms' in the VAR analysis
when incorrectly assuming that the data are I(1) instead of I(2) and
gives a rst intuitive account of the basic di erence between the I(1)
and the I(2) analysis. Section 5 de nes formally the I(2) model in the
AR and the MA form, discusses the role of deterministic components
in the I(2) model and introduces the two-step procedure for determining the two cointegration rank indices. Section 6 gives an interpretation
of the various components in the I(2) model and illustrates with the
Brazilian data. Section 7 discusses long-run and medium-run price homogeneity and how these can formulated as testable restrictions on the
I(2) model. Section 8 presents the empirical model for money growth,
currency depreciation and price in ation in Brazil. Section 9 concludes.
2
Money growth and in ation
It is widely believed that the growth in money supply in excess of real
productive growth is the cause of in ation, at least in the long run.
The economic intuition behind this is that other factors are limited in
scope, whereas money in principle is unlimited in supply (Romer, 1996).
Generally, the reasoning is based on equilibrium in the money market
so that money supply equals money demand:
M=P = L(R; Y r );
(1)
where M is the money stock, P the price level, Y r real income, R an
interest rate, and L( ) the demand for real money balances. In a high
(and accelerating) in ation period, the Cagan model for hyper in ation
predicts that aggregate money demand is more appropriately described
by :
M=P = L( e ; Y r ); L
e
< 0; LY r > 0
(2)
where e is expected in ation.
The latter model (2) is chosen as the baseline model in the subsequent
empirical analysis of the Brazilian high in ation experience in the seventies until the mid eighties. The data consists of money stock measured
as M3, the CPI price index, the black market spot exchange rate, and
the real industrial production and covers the period 1977:1,...,1985:5.
3
-10
Lm3
.15
DiLfm3
.1
-12.5
.05
0
-15
1980
-17.5
1985
Lcpi
1985
1980
1985
1980
1985
DifLcpi
.1
-20
.05
1980
-20
1980
1985
DifLexch
Lexch
.3
.2
-22.5
.1
0
-25
1980
1985
Figure 1. Nominal M3, CPI, and exchange rates in levels and
di erences.
The graphs of the data in levels and di erences (after taking logs)
gives a rst indication of the order of integration. The growth rates
of all three nominal variables in Figure 1 exhibit typical I(1) behavior,
implying that the levels of the variables are I(2). In contrast the graphs
of the log of the industrial production in levels and di erences in Figure
2 do not suggest I(2) behavior: The smooth behavior typical of I(2)
variables is not present in the level of industrial production and the
di erenced process looks signi cantly mean-reverting.
4
Industrial production
0.2
The change in industrial production
0.1
4.6
0.0
4.4
-0.1
1980
1985
The log of real M3 measured by CPI
7.4
1980
-2.75
1985
The black market excahnge rate relative to CPI
-3.00
-3.25
7.2
-3.50
1980
-20.0
1985
1980
1985
The depreciation rate in the official
and the black market
The official and black market exchange rate
0.2
-22.5
-25.0
0.0
1980
1985
1980
1985
Figure 2. The graphs of industrial production in levels and di erences
(upper part), M3 and exchange rate both de ated with CPI (middle
panel), and the black and white market exchange rate in levels and
di erences (lower panel).
The middle part of Figure 2 demonstrates how real money stock
(lnM3 - lnCPI ) and real exchange rates (lnLexch - lnCPI ) have evolved
in a nonstationary manner and increasingly so after 1981. Figure 2,
lower panel compares the levels and the di erences of the o cial and
black market exchange rate. While the o cial rate seems to have stayed
below the black market rate for some periods the graphs show that the
two major devaluations brought the two series back to the same level.
Thus, it seems likely that the black market exchange rate is a good proxy
for the 'true' value of the Brazilian currency in this period.
When data are nonstationary, the Cagan model can be formulated
as a cointegrating relation, i.e.:
(M=P )t
L( et ; Yt ) = vt
(3)
where vt is a stationary process measuring the deviation from the steadystate position at time t.
The stationarity of vt implies that whenever the system has been
shocked it will adjust back to equilibrium and is, therefore, essential for
the interpretation of (3) as a steady-state relation. If vt is nonstationary as explicitly assumed in Sargent (1977) money supply has deviated
from the steady-state value of money demand. As this case generally
5
implies a double unit root in the data, the choice of the I(2) model for
the econometric analysis seems natural. Therefore, when addressing empirical questions related to the mechanisms behind in ation and money
growth in a high or hyper in ation regime we need to understand and
interpret the I(2) model .
3
Formulating the economic problem in a stochastic framework2
Cointegration and stochastic trends are two sides of the same coin: if
there are cointegration relations there are also common stochastic trends.
Therefore, to be able to address the transmission mechanism of monetary
policy in a stochastic framework it is useful rst to consider a conventional decomposition into trend, T ; cycle, C; and irregular component,
I; of a typical macroeconomic variable.
X=T
C
I
and allow the trend to be both deterministic, Td ; and stochastic, Ts ; i.e.
T = Ts Td ; and the cyclical component to be of long duration, say 6-10
years, Cl , and of shorter duration, say 3-5 years, Cs ; i.e. C = Cl Cs :
The reason for distinguishing between short and long cycles is that a
long/short cycle can either be treated as nonstationary or stationary
depending on the time perspective of the study. For example, the graph
of the trend-adjusted industrial production in Figure 5, lower panel,
illustrates long cycles in the data that were found nonstationary by the
statistical analysis.
An additive formulation is obtained by taking logarithms:
x = (ts + td ) + (cl + cs ) + i
(4)
where lower case letters indicate a logarithmic transformation. Even if
the stochastic trends are of primary interest for the subsequent analyses,
a linear time trend is needed to account for average linear growth rates
typical of most economic data.
3.1
Stochastic and deterministic trends
As an illustration of a trend-cycle decomposition we consider the following vector of variables xt = [m; p; sb ; y r ]t ; t = 1977:1,...,1985:5; where m
is the log of M3, p is the log CPI, sb is the log of black market exchange
rate, and y r is the log of industrial production. All variables are treated
2
This section draws heavily on Section 4 in Juselius (1999a)
6
as stochastic and will be modelled, independently of whether they are
considered endogenous or exogenous in the economic model.
A stochastic trend describes the cumulated impact of all previous
permanent shocks on a variable, i.e. it summarizes all the shocks with
a long lasting e ect. This is contrary to a transitory shock, the e ect of
which cancels either during the next period or over the next few periods.
For example, the income level of a household can be thought of as the
cumulation of all previous permanent income changes (shocks), whereas
the e ect of temporary shocks, like lottery prizes, will not cumulate as
it is only a temporary change in income.
If in ation rate is found to be I(1), then the present level of in ation
can be thought of as the sum of all previous shocks to in ation, i.e.
t
=
t
P
"i +
0:
(5)
i=1
Because the e ect of transitory shocks disappears in the cumulation a
stochastic trend, ts ; P
is de ned as the cumulative sum of previous permanent shocks, ts;t = ti=1 "i : The di erence between a linear stochastic
and a linear deterministic trend is that the increments of a stochastic
trend change randomly, whereas those of a deterministic trend are constant over time. Figure 3 illustrates three di erent stochastic trends
measured as the once cumulated residuals from the money, price and
exchange rate equations.
A representation of prices is obtained by integrating (5) once, i.e.
pt =
t
P
s=1
s
=
t P
s
P
"i +
0t
+ p0 :
(6)
s=1 i=1
Thus, if in ation is I(1) with a nonzero mean (as most studies nd),
prices are I(2) with a linear trend. Figure 4 illustrates the twice and
once cumulated residuals from the CPI price equation of the VAR model
de ned in the next section.
7
.1
Sm 3
0
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
Sp
0
1977
.25
Sbm
0
-.25
1977
1978
Figure 3. The graphs of the cumulated residuals from the money, price,
and exchange rate equations of the estimated VAR.
0
SSp
-.5
-1
1977
.025
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
Sp
0
.025
1977
Figure 4. The graphs of the twice and once cumlated residuals from
the price equation.
3.2
A trend-cycle scenario
Given the set of variables discussed above, one would expect (at least)
two autonomous shocks u1;t and u2;t , of which u1;t is a nominal shock
and u2;t is a real shock. If there are second order stochastic trends in the
8
data it seems plausible that they have been generated from the nominal
shocks. We will, therefore, tentatively assume that the second order
long-run stochastic
Pt trend
Ps ts in (4) is described by the twice cumulated
nominal shocks, s=1 i=1 u1i : The long cyclical components cl in the
data will then be
Ptdescribed by a combination of the once cumulated
P
nominal shocks, i=1 u1i ; and the once cumulated real shocks, ti=1 u2i :
This allows us to distinguish
between the long-run stochastic
Pt empirically
Ps
trend in nominal levels, P
s=1
i=1 u1i ; the medium-run stochastic trend
t
in nominal growth
P rates, i=1 u1i ; and the medium-run stochastic trend
in real activity, ti=1 u2i : Figure 5 illustrates.
trad m3
0
-.0 5
19 77
.0 05
19 78
19 79
19 80
19 81
19 82
19 83
19 84
19 85
19 79
19 80
19 81
19 82
19 83
19 84
19 85
19 79
19 80
19 81
19 82
19 83
19 84
19 85
D trad m3
0
.0 05
19 77
.2
19 78
tren d ad Y
0
-.2
19 77
19 78
Figure 5. The graphs of trend-adjusted M3 in levels and di erences
(upper and lower panel) and trend-adjusted industrial production
(lower panel).
The trend-cycle formulation below illustrates the ideas:
3 2 3
2
2 3
3
d11 d12
mt
c1
g1
Pt
t P
s
6 d21 d22 7
6 pt 7 6 c2 7 P
6
7
6
6 b7 = 6 7
7 Pti=1 u1i +6 g2 7 [t]+stat.comp.
+
u
1i
4 d31 d32 5
4 st 5 4 c3 5 s=1 i=1
4 g3 5
i=1 u2i
r
yt
d41 d42
0
g4
(7)
The deterministic trend component, td = t; is needed to account for
linear growth trends present
in the levels of the variables. If g4 = 0 and
Pt
d41 = 0 in (7), then i=1 u2;i is likely to describe the long-run trend
2
9
in
Ptindustrial production. In this case it may be possible to interpret
i=1 u2;i as a "structural" unit root process (cf. the discussion in King,
Plosser, Stock and Watson (1991) on stochastic versus deterministic real
growth models).
If, on the other hand, g4 6= 0; then it seems plausible that the longrun real trend
Pcan be approximated by a linear deterministic time trend.
In this case ti=1 u2;i is likely to describe medium-run deviations from
the linear trend, i.e. the long business cycle. The graph of the trendadjusted industrial production in the lower panel of Figure 5 illustrates
such a long cycle starting from the long upturn from 1977-1980:6 and
ending with the downturn 1980:6-1984. Note also the shorter cycles of
approximately a year's duration imbedded in the long cycle.
Pt Therefore, the possibility of interpreting the second stochastic trend,
i=1 u2;i ; as a long-run structural trend depends crucially on whether
one includes a linear trend in (7) or not.
The trend components of mt ; pt ; st ; and yt in (7) can now be represented by:
P
P
PP
mt = c1 P P u1i +d11 P u1i +d12 P u2i +g1 t + stat: comp:
pt = c2 P P u1i +d21 P u1i +d22 P u2i +g2 t + stat: comp
u1i +d31 P u1i +d32 P u2i +g3 t + stat: comp
st = c 3
yt =
+d41 u1i +d42 u2i +g4 t + stat: comp
If (c1 ; c2 ; c3 ) 6= 0; then fmt ; pt ; st g
then
(8)
I(2): If, in addition, c1 = c2 = c3
P
P
pt = (d11 d21 ) P u1i +(d12 d22 ) P u2i +(g1 g2 )t +stat:comp:
st = (d21 d31 ) P u1i +(d22 d32 ) P u2i +(g2 g3 )t +stat:comp:
st = (d11 d31 ) P u1i +(d12 d32 ) P u2i +(g1 g3 )t +stat:comp:
+g4 t +stat:comp:
+d42 u2i
yt =
+d41 u1i
(9)
The real variables are at most I(1) but, unless (g1 = g2 ); (g2 = g3 ); and
(g1 = g3 ); they are I(1) around a linear trend. Figure 5 illustrates the
trend-adjusted behavior of real M3 and industrial production.
Long-run price homogeneity among all the variables implies that both
the long-run stochastic I(2) trends and the linear deterministic trends
should cancel in (9). But, even if overall long-run homogeneity is rejected, some of the individual components of fmt pt ; pt st ; mt st g
can, nevertheless, exhibit long-run price homogeneity. For example, the
case (mt pt ) I(1) is a testable hypothesis which implies that money
stock and prices are moving together in the long-run, though not necessarily in the medium-run (over the business cycle).
mt
pt
mt
10
The condition for long-run and medium-run price homogeneity is
fc11 = c21 ; and d11 = d21 g; i.e. that the nominal shocks u1t a ect
nominal money and prices in the same way both in theP
long run and
in the medium run. Because the real stochastic trend
u2i is likely
to enter mt but not necessarily pt ; testing long-run and medium-run
price homogeneity jointly is not equivalent to testing (mt pt ) I(0):
Testing the composite hypothesis is more involved than the long-run
price homogeneity alone.
It is important to note that (mt pt ) I(1) implies ( mt
pt )
I(0); i.e. long-run price homogeneity implies a stationary spread between
price in ation and money growth. In this case the stochastic trend in
in ation is the same as the stochastic trend in money growth. The
econometric formulation of long-run and medium-run price-homogeneity
in the I(2) model will be discussed in Section 7.
When overall long-run price homogeneity holds it is convenient to
transform the nominal system (8) to a system consisting of real variables
and a nominal growth rate, for example:
2
mt
6 st
6
4
3 2
d11
pt
6 d21
pt 7
7=6
pt 5 4
yt
d21 d12
d31 d22
c21
d41
2
3
g1
d22
Pt
6
u
d32 7
7 Pti=1 1;i + 6 g2
40
05
i=1 u2;i
g4
d42
3
g2
g3 7
7 [t] + :::
5
(10)
Given long-run price homogeneity all variables are at most I(1) in
(10). The nominal growth rate (measured by pt ;P mt ; or st ) is only
t
a ected by the once cumulated nominal trend,
i=1 u1;i ; but all the
other
variables
can
(but
need
not)
be
a
ected
by
both
stochastic trends,
Pt
Pt
i=1 u1;i and
i=1 u2;i .
The case (mt pt yt ) I(0); i.e. the inverse velocity of circulation is
a stationary variable, requires that d11 d21 d41 = 0; d12 d22 d42 = 0
and g1 g2 g4 = 0: If d11 = d21 (i.e. medium run price homogeneity),
d22 = 0 (real stochastic growth does not a ect prices), d41 = 0 (mediumrun in ationary movements do not a ect real income), and d12 = d42 ;
then mt pt yt I(0). In this case real money stock and realPaggregate
income share one common trend, the real stochastic trend
u2i : The
stationarity of money velocity, implying common movements in money,
prices, and income, would then be consistent with the conventional monetarist assumption as stated by Friedman (1970) that "in ation always
and everywhere is a monetary problem". This case would correspond to
model (1) in Section 2.
The case (mt pt yt ) I(1); implies that the two common stochastic trends a ect the level of real money stock and real income di erently.
11
Cagan's model of money demand in a high (hyper) in ation period suggests that the nonstationarity of the liquidity ratio is related to the
expected rate of in ation Et ( pt+1 ): The latter is generally not observable, but as long as Et ( pt+1 )
pt is a stationary disturbance, one can
replace the unobserved expected in ation with actual in ation without
loosing cointegration. The condition that fEt ( pt+1 )
pt g
I(0)
seems plausible considering that f pt+1
pt g I(0) when pt I(2):
It amounts to assuming that fEt ( pt+1 )
pt+1 g
I(0); i.e. agents'
in ationary expectations do not systematically deviate from actual ination. Therefore, from a cointegration point of view we can replace the
expected in ation with the actual in ation:
mt
pt
y t + a1 p t
(mt
pt
y t ) + a2 s t
I(0);
(11)
or, equivalently:
I(0):
where under the Cagan model a1 > 0; a2 > 0:
4
Diagnosing I(2)
VAR models are widely used in empirical macroeconomics based on the
assumption that data are I(1) without rst testing for I(2) or checking
whether a near unit root remains in the model after the cointegration
rank has been imposed. Unfortunately, when the data contains a double
unit root essentially all inference in the I(1) model is a ected. To avoid
making wrong inference it is, therefore, important to be able to diagnose
typical I(2) symptoms in the I(1) VAR model.
For the Brazilian data, the unrestricted VAR model was speci ed as:
xt =
1
xt
1
+ xt 2 + 1 t + 0 + p Dp83:8t +
"t Np (0; ); t = 1; :::; T
s Qst
+ "t ;
(12)
where xt = [mt ; pt ; sbt ; ytr ]; mt = ln(M 3); pt = ln(CP It ); sbt = ln(Exchbt ); ytr =
0
ln(industrial production); t =1977:1,...,1985:5, =
; 1=
1;
01 =
;
and
(
;
;
;
;
)
are
unrestricted.
The
estimates
have
been
1
p
s
01
0
calculated using CATS for RATS, Hansen and Juselius (1994). Misspeci cation tests are reported in the Appendix.
The data are distinctly trending and we need to allow for linear
trends both in the data and in the cointegration relations when testing for cointegration rank (Nielsen and Rahbek, 2000). The industrial
production, ytr ; exhibits strong seasonal variation and we include 11 seasonal dummies, Qst ; and a constant, 0 in the VAR model. Finally, the
12
graphs of the di erenced black market exchange rate and nominal M3
money stock exhibited an extraordinary large shock at 1983:8, which
was accounted for by an unrestricted impulse dummy Dp83:8t = 1 for
t = 1983:8 and 0 otherwise. A permanent shock to the changes corresponds to a level shift in the variables, which may or may not cancel in
the cointegration relations. To account for the latter possibility the shift
dummy, Ds83:8t = 0 for t = 1983:8 and 1 otherwise, was restricted to be
in the cointegration relations. It was found to be insigni cant (p-value
0.88) and was left out.
The I(1) estimation procedure is based on the so called R-model in
which the short-run e ects have rst been concentrated out:
R0t =
0
R1t + "t :
(13)
where R0t and R1t are de ned by:
^11 xt 1 + const + B13 Dpt + R0t
x =B
|{z}
|{z}t
| {z }
(14)
^21 xt 1 + const + B23 Dpt + R1t :
xt 1 = B
|{z}
| {z }
|{z}
(15)
I(1)
and
I(2)
I(0)
I(1)
I(2)
I(1)
Dpt is a catch-all for all the dummy variables. If xt I(2) then xt
I(1) and (14) is a regression of an I(1) process on its own lag. Thus,
the regressand and the regressor contain the same common trend which
will cancel in regression. This implies that R0t I(0); even if xt I(2):
On the other hand equation (15) is a regression of an I(2) variable, xt 1 ;
on an I(1) variable, xt 1 : Because an I(2) trend cannot be canceled by
regressing on an I(1) trend, it follows that R1t I(2):
Therefore, when xt
I(2) (13) is a regression of an I(0) variable
(R0t ) on an I(2) variable (R1t ): Under the (testable) assumption that
"t
I(0); either 0 R1t = 0 or 0 R1t
I(0) for the equation (13) to
0
hold. Because the linear combination R1t transforms the process from
I(2) to I(0), the estimate ^ is super-super consistent (Johansen, 1992).
Even though is precisely estimated in the I(1) model when data are
I(2), the interpretation of 0 xt as a stationary long-run relation has to
be modi ed as will be demonstrated below.
It is easy to demonstrate the connection between 0 x~t 2 and 0 R1t
by inserting (15) into (13) :
13
0
R0t =
R1t + "t
(~
xt 1 B2 xt 1 ) + "t
0
0
= ( x~t 1
B2 xt 1 ) + "t
= ( 0 x~t 1 ! 0 xt 1 ) + "t
| {z }
| {z }
0
I(1)
|
I(1)
{z
I(0)
(16)
}
where ! = 0 B2 : It appears that the stationary relations 0 R1t consists
of two components 0 x~t 1 and ! 0 xt 1 both of which are generally I(1).
The stationarity of 0 R1t is, therefore, a consequence of cointegration
between 0 x~t 1 I(1) and ! 0 xt 1 I(1):
Thus, when data are I(2), 0i x~t I(1); while 0i R1t I(0) for at least
one i; i = 1; :::; r: It is, therefore, a clear sign of double unit roots (or,
alternatively, a unit root and an explosive root) in the model when the
graphs of 0i x~t exhibits nonstationary behavior whereas 0i R1t looks stationary. As an illustration we have reported the graphs of all four cointegration relations (of which 01 R1t and 02 R1t are stationary) in Figures
6-9. The upper panels contain the relations, 0i x~t ; and the lower panels
the cointegration relations corrected for short-run dynamics, 0i R1t :
V1 ` * Zk(t)
68.4
67.2
66.0
64.8
63.6
62.4
61.2
60.0
58.8
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1984
1985
V1 ` * Rk (t)
4
3
2
1
0
-1
-2
-3
1977
1978
Figure 6. The graphs of
1979
0
1 xt
1980
1981
1982
1983
(upper panel) and
14
0
1 R1t
(lower panel).
V2 ` * Zk(t)
-39.6
-40.8
-42.0
-43.2
-44.4
-45.6
-46.8
-48.0
-49.2
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1982
1983
1984
1985
V2 ` * Rk (t)
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
-0.5
-1.0
-1.5
-2.0
1977
1978
Figure 7. The graphs of
1979
0
2 xt
1980
1981
(upper panel) and
0
2 R1t
(lower panel).
V 3` * Zk (t)
121
120
119
118
117
116
115
114
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1982
1983
1984
1985
V 3` * Rk (t)
3.2
2.4
1.6
0.8
0.0
-0.8
-1.6
-2.4
1977
1978
Figure 8. The graphs of
1979
0
3 xt
1980
1981
(upper panel) and
15
0
3 R1t
(lower panel).
V 4` * Zk (t)
-35.2
-36.0
-36.8
-37.6
-38.4
-39.2
-40.0
-40.8
-41.6
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1984
1985
V 4` * Rk (t)
2
1
0
-1
-2
-3
1977
1978
1979
Figure 9. The graphs of
1980
0
4 xt
1981
1982
1983
(upper panel) and
0
4 R1t
(lower panel).
Among the graphs in Figures 6 and 7 01 x~t and 02 x~t exhibit distinctly
nonstationary behavior whereas the graphs of the corresponding 0i R1;t
look reasonably stationary. This is strong evidence of double roots in
the data. As all the remaining graphs seem de nitely nonstationary, this
suggests r = 2 and at least one I(2) trend in the data.
Another way of diagnosing I(2) behavior is to calculate the characteristic roots of the VAR model for di erent choices of the cointegration
rank r. When xt I(2) the number of unit roots in the characteristic
polynomial of the VAR model is s1 +2s2 ; where s1 and s2 are the number
of autonomous I(1) and I(2) trends respectively and s1 + s2 = p r.
The characteristic roots contain information on unit roots associated
with both and ; whereas the standard I(1) trace test is only related to
the number of unit roots in the matrix. If the data are I(1) the number
of unit roots (or near unit roots) should be p r; otherwise p r + s2 :
Therefore, if for any reasonable choice of r there are still (near) unit
roots in the model; it is a clear sign of I(2) behavior in at least some of
the variables. Because the additional unit root(s) are related to xt 1 ;
i.e. belong to the matrix = I
1 , lowering the value of r does not
remove the s2 additional unit root associated with the I(2) behavior.
In the Brazilian nominal model there are altogether p k = 4 2 =
8 eigenvalue roots in the characteristic polynomial which are reported
below for r = 1; :::; 4. Unrestricted near unit roots are indicated with
16
bold face.
V AR(p) 1:002 0:97 0:90 0:90 0:38
r=3
1:0 1:002 0:91 0:91 0:38
r=2
1:0
1:0 0:99 0:86 0:38
r=1
1:0
1:0 1:0 1:001 0:61
0:33
0:33
0:32
0:33
0:06
0:06
0:09
0:09
0:06
0:06
0:07
0:00
In the unrestricted model two of the roots are very close to the unit
circle, one is larger than unity possibly indicating explosive behavior,
the other is a stable near unit root. In addition there is a complex
pair of two fairly large roots. The presence of an unstable root can be
seen in the graph of the rst cointegration relation 01 x
~t in Figure 6:
The equilibrium error in the `steady-state' relation in levels grows in an
unstable manner at the end of the period, but is `compensated' by a
similar increase in the in ation rate, so 01 R1;t looks stationary. This
suggests that the seed to the Brazilian hyper in ation in the subsequent
period can already be found in the present data.
However, the explosive part of the root is very small and might not
be statistically signi cant. In such a case we would expect the unstable
root to disappear when restricting the rank. We notice that for r = 3 and
r = 1 the explosive root is still left in the model, whereas for r = 2 it has
disappeared. Independently of the choice of r; a near unit root remains
in the model consistent with I(2), or moderately explosive, behavior.
Therefore, we continue with r = 2 and disregard the possibility of an
explosive root in the econometric analysis. Subsequently we will use
the empirical results to demonstrate where in the model the seed to the
subsequent hyper in ationary behavior can be found.
In most cases a graphical inspection of the data is su cient to detect I(2) behavior and it might seem meaningless to estimate the I(1)
model when xt is in fact I(2): However, a variety of hypotheses can be
adequately tested using the I(1) procedure with the caveat that the interpretation of the cointegration results should be in terms of CI(2; 1)
relations, i.e. relations which cointegrated from I(2) to I(1), and not
from I(1) to I(0). One of the more important hypotheses which can be
tested is the long-run price homogeneity of to be discussed in Section
7.
5
De ning the I(2) model
It is useful to reformulate the VAR model de ned in the previous section
in acceleration rates, changes and levels:
2
xt =
xt
1
+ xt 1 +
"t Np (0;
p Dp;t
+ s Qs;t +
); t = 1; :::; T
17
0
+
1t
+ "t ;
(17)
where = (I
Section 5.3).
5.1
1)
and
1
=
1:0
is restricted to lie in sp( ) (cf.
The AR formulation
The hypothesis that xt is I(2) is formulated in Johansen (1992) as two
reduced rank hypotheses:
0
=
, where ;
are p
r
are (p
r)
(18)
and
0
?
?
0
=
; where ;
s1 :
(19)
The rst condition is the usual I(1) reduced rank condition associated
with the variables in levels, whereas the second condition is associated
with the variables in di erences. The intuition is that the di erenced
process also contains unit roots when data are I(2). Note, however, that
(19) is formulated as a reduced rank condition on the transformed :
The intuition behind this can be seen by pre-multiplying (17) with ?
0
(and post-multiplying by ? ): This makes the levels component
xt 2
disappear and reduces the model to a ((p r) (p r))-dimensional
system of equations in rst- and second order di erences. In this system
the hypothesis of reduced rank of the matrix 0? ? is tested in the
usual way. Thus, the second reduced rank condition is similar to the
rst except that the reduced rank regression is on the p r common
driving trends. Using (19) it is possible to decompose ? and ? into
the I(1) and I(2) directions:
?
=f
?1 ;
?2 g
and
?
=f
?1 ;
?2 g;
(20)
and ?;1 = ? ( 0? ? ) 1 is p s1 ; ?2 =
s2 ; and ? ; ? are the orthogonal com? ? and
?2 =
? ? is p
plements of and ; respectively. Note that the matrices ?1 ; ?2 ; ?1 ;
and ?2 are called 1 ; 2 ; 1 and 2 in the many papers on I(2) by Johansen and coauthors. The reason why we deviate here from the simpler
notation is that we need to distinguish between di erent and vectors in the empirical analysis and, hence, use the latter notation for this
purpose.
While the I(1) model is only based on the distinction between r cointegrating relations and p r non-cointegrating relations, the I(2) model
makes an additional distinction between s1 I(1) trends and s2 I(2) trends.
Furthermore, when r > s2 ; the r cointegrating relations can be divided
into r0 = r s2 directly stationary CI(2; 2) relations (cointegrating from
I(2) to I(0)) and s2 polynomially cointegrating relations. This distinction
will be illustrated in Section 6 based on the Brazilian data.
where
?1
=
0
?( ?
?)
1
18
5.2
The moving average representation
The moving average representation of (17) describes the variables as a
function of stochastic and deterministic trends, stationary components,
initial values and deterministic dummy variables. It is given by:
xt = C2
+C1
t
P
t P
s
P
s=1 i=1
"i + C2 21
"s + C1
p
t
P
2
0 t + C2
Dps + C2
p
s
+Yt + A + Bt; t = 1; :::; T
Dpi + C2
s
s
t P
P
Qsi
s=1 i=1
s=1 i=1
t
P
s=1
s=1
s=1
s
t P
P
Qss + (C1 + 21 C2 ) 0 t +
1t
(21)
where Yt de nes the stationary part of the process, A and B are functions
of the initial values x0 ; x 1 ; :::; x k+1 ; and the coe cient matrices satisfy:
C2 =
0
?2 ( ?2
?2 )
1
0
0
?2 ;
0
C1 =
C2 ;
0
?1 C1
0
+I
where =
1 and the shorthand notation
used: See Johansen (1992, 1995).
We denote e?2 = ?2 ( 0?2 ?2 ) 1 so that
C2 = e?2
0
?2
=
0
?1 (I
= (
0
C2 )
(22)
) 1 is
(23)
i:e: the C2 matrix has a similar reduced rank representation as C1 in the
0
I(1) model. It is, therefore, natural to interpret ?2 "i as the second
order stochastic trend that has a ected the variables xt with weights e?2 :
However, the C1 matrix cannot be decomposed similarly. It is a more
complex function of the AR parameters of the model and the C2 matrix
and the interpretation of the parameters ?1 and ?1 is less intuitive.
The MA representation (22) together with (23) can be used to obtain
ML estimates of the stochastic and deterministic trends and cycles and
their loadings in the intuitive scenario (8) of Section 3. This will be
illustrated in Section 6.
5.3
Deterministic components in the I(2) model
It appears from (21) that an unrestricted constant in the model is consistent with linear and quadratic trends in the data. Johansen (1992)
suggested the decomposition of the constant term 0 into:
0
=
0
+
where
19
1
+
2;
0
is a constant term in the stationary cointegration relations,
1
is the slope coe cient of linear trends in the variables, and
2
is the slope coe cient of quadratic trends in the variables.
Quadratic trends in the levels of the variables is consistent with linear
trends in the growth rates, i.e. in in ation rates, which generally does
not seem plausible (not even as a local approximation). Therefore, the
empirical model will be based on the assumption that the data contain
linear but no quadratic trends, i.e. that 2 = 0:
Similar arguments can be given for the dummy variables. An unrestricted shift dummy, such as Ds83:8t ; in the model is consistent with a
broken quadratic trend in the data, whereas an unrestricted blip dummy,
such as Dp83:8t = Ds83:8t ; is consistent with a broken linear trend in
the data. Thus, a correct speci cation of dummies is important as they
are likely to strongly a ect both the model estimates and the asymptotic
distribution of the rank test.
In many cases it is important to allow for trend-stationary relations
in the I(2) model (Rahbek, Kongsted, and J rgensen, 1999). In this case
1 t 6= 0 and the vector 1 needs to be decomposed in a similar way as
the constant term:
1
=
0
0
+
1
+
2;
where
is the slope coe cient of a linear trend in the cointegration
relations,
0
1
is the slope coe cient of quadratic trends in the variables, and
2
is the slope coe cient of cubic trends in the variables.
Since the presence of deterministic quadratic or cubic trends are not
very plausible we will assume that 1 = 2 = 0.
5.4
The determination of the two rank indices
The cointegration rank r can be determined either by the two-step estimation procedure in Johansen (1995) based on the polynomial cointegration property of 0 xt , or by the F IM L procedure in Johansen (1997)
based on the CI(2; 1) property of 0 xt and 0?1 xt : The idea of the twostep procedure is as follows: The rst step determines r = r based on
the trace test in the standard I(1) model and the estimates ^ and ^ : The
20
Table 1: Testing the two rank indices in the I(2) model
p-r r FIML test procedure: Q(s1 ; r) Q(r)
i
4 0 323:87 220:09 149:68 99:01 95:91 0.43
[0:00]
3
1
2
2
1
3
s2
[0:00]
[0:00]
[0:00]
[0:00]
141:95
73:89
51:69
44:16
0.24
48:92
24:14
19:67
0.12
13:40
7:29
0.05
1
0
[0:00]
[0:02]
[0:05]
[0:08]
[0:47]
[0:34]
4
3
2
[0:04]
[0:25]
[0:32]
second step determines s1 = s1 by solving the reduced rank problem for
the matrix (^ 0? ^ ? ): The practical procedure is to calculate the trace
test for all possible combinations of r and s1 so that the joint hypothesis
(r; s1 ) can be tested using the procedure in Paruolo (1996).
Based on a broad simulation study Nielsen and Rahbek (2003) show
that the F IM L procedure has better size properties than the two-step
procedure. The estimates here are, therefore, based on the F IM L procedure using the new version 2.0 of CATS for RATS developed by Jonathan
Dennis.
Table 1 reports the test of the joint hypothesis (r; s1 ) with the 95%
quantiles of the simulated distribution given in brackets. They are derived for a model with a linear trend restricted to be in the cointegration space. The test procedure starts with the most restricted model
(r = 0; s1 = 0; s2 = 4) in the upper left hand corner, continues to the
end of the rst row (r = 0; s1 = 4; s2 = 0), and proceeds similarly rowwise from left to right until the rst acceptance. The rst acceptance
is at (r = 1; s1 = 1; s2 = 1) with a p-value of 0.08. However, the case
(r = 2; s1 = 1; s2 = 1) is accepted with a much higher p-value 0.47 and
will be our preferred choice. As a matter of fact, the subsequent results
will demonstrate that the second relation plays a crucial role in the price
mechanisms which led to hyper in ation.
To improve the small sample properties of the test procedures, a
Bartlett correction can be employed (Johansen, 2000). Even though it
signi cantly improves the size of the cointegration rank, the power of
the tests is generally very low for I(2) or near I(2) data.
The Paruolo procedure delivers a correct size asymptotically, but
does not solve the problem of low power. Because economic theory is
often consistent with few rather than many common trends, a reversed
order of testing might be preferable from an economic point of view.
However, in that case the test will no longer deliver a correct asymptotic
21
size.
Furthermore, when the I(2) model contains intervention dummies
that cumulate to trends in the DGP , standard asymptotic tables are no
longer valid. For example, an unrestricted impulse dummy, like Dp83.8 t ,
will cumulate to a broken linear trend in the data. The asymptotic
distributions for the I(2) model do not account for this feature. Since
the null of a unit root is not necessarily reasonable from an economic
point of view, the low power and the impact of the dummies on the
distributions can be a serious problem. This can sometimes be a strong
argument for basing the choice of r and s1 on prior information given by
the economic insight as well as the statistical information in the data. As
demonstrated in Section 4 such information can be a graphical inspection
and the number of (near) unit roots in the characteristic polynomial of
the VAR.
For the present choice of rank (r = 2; s1 = 1; s2 = 1) the characteristic roots of the V AR model became
1:0 1:0 1:0 0:89 0:39 0:06
0:09
0:32
leaving a fairly large root in the model. Therefore, another possibility
would have been to choose r = 2 ; s1 = 0; s2 = 2:
6
Interpreting the I(2) structure
It is no easy task to give the intuition for the di erent levels of integration
and cointegration in the I(2) model and how they can be translated into
economically relevant relationships. Table 2 illustrates the I(2) decomposition of the Brazilian data, which is based on the following assumptions
(anticipating the subsequent results):
mt
I(2); pt
I(2); sbt
I(2); ytr
I(1)
and
r| {z
= 2} ; and
r0 =1;r1 =1
p r =2
| {z }
s1 =1;s2 =1
The left hand side of Table 2 illustrates the decomposition of xt into
two and two ? directions corresponding to r = 2 and p r = 2. This
decomposition de nes two stationary polynomially cointegrating relations, 01 xt + ! 01 xt and 02 xt + ! 02 xt ; and two nonstationary relations,
0
I(1) and 0?2 xt
I(2): Note that 0?1 xt is cointegrating from
?1 xt
I(2) to I(1), and can become I(0) by di erencing once, whereas 0?2 xt is
not cointegrating at all and, thus, can only become I(0) by di erencing
twice.
22
Table 2: Decomposing the data vector using the I(2) model
The ; ? decomposition of xt
The ; ? decomposition
r=2
[ 0:1 xt + ! 0:1 xt ] I(0)
1 :short-run adjustment coe cients
| {z
} | {z }
I(1)
I(1)
[ 0:2 xt + ! 0:2 xt ]
| {z
} | {z }
I(1)
I(0)
2:
short-run adjustment coe cients
Pt
I(1)
s1 = 1
0
?1 xt
I(1)
0
?1
s2 = 1
0
?2 xt
I(2)
0
?2
i=1
Pt
s=1
"i : I(1) stochastic trend
Ps
i=1
"i : I(2) stochastic trend
When r > s2 the polynomially cointegrating relations can be further
decomposed into r0 = r s2 = 1 directly cointegrating relations, 00 xt ;
and r1 = r r0 = s2 = 1 polynomially cointegrating relations, 01 xt +
0
xt ; where is a p s2 matrix proportional ?2 :
The right hand side of Table 2 illustrates the corresponding decomposition into the
and the ? directions, where 1 and 2 measure
the short-run adjustment coe cients associated with the polynomially
cointegrating relations, whereas ?1 and ?2 measure the loadings to
the rst and second order stochastic trends.
Both 0 xt and 0?1 xt are CI(2; 1) but they di er in the sense that
the former can become stationary by polynomial cointegration, whereas
the latter can only become stationary by di erencing. Thus, even in the
I(2) model the interpretation of the reduced rank of the matrix is that
there are r relations that can become stationary either by cointegration
or by multi-cointegration, and p r relations that only become stationary
by di erencing.
Thus, the I(2) model can distinguish between the CI(2; 1) relations
between levels f 0 xt ; 0?1 xt g; the CI(1; 1) relations between levels and
di erences f 0 xt 1 + ! 0 xt g; and nally the CI(1; 1) relations between
di erences f 0?1 xt g: As a consequence, when discussing the economic
interpretation of these components, we need to modify the generic concept of "long-run" steady-state relations accordingly. We will here use
the interpretation of
0
0 xt as a static long-run equilibrium relation;
0
0
xt as a dynamic long-run equilibrium relation,
1 xt +
23
Table 3: Unrestricted estimates of the I(0), I(1), and I(2) directions of
and
m
p
sb
yr
The stationary cointegrating relations
^0
1.00
-0.07
-0.91
-1.22
^1
-0.67
1.00
-0.06
0.37
-4.87
-3.78
-5.48
-0.30
The adjustment coe cients
^0
0.04
-0.03
0.17
0.01
^1
0.10
0.04
0.11
-0.01
The nonstationary relations
^
4.54
0.46
-3.99
6.69
?1
^
0.52
0.40
0.58
-0.03
?2
The common stochastic trends
^ ?1 0.038
-0.007 -0.012 0.122
^ ?2 -0.053 -0.078 -0.016 -0.023
^"
0.016
0.010
0.054
0.028
0
?1
xt as a medium-run equilibrium relation:
As mentioned above the parameters of Table 2 can be estimated either by the two-step procedure or by the F IM L procedure. Paruolo
(2000) showed that the two-step procedure gives asymptotically e cient
M L estimates. The F IM L procedure solves just one reduced rank problem in which the eigenvectors determine the space spanned by ( ; ?1 );
i.e. the p s2 I(1) directions of the process: Independently of the estimation procedure, the crucial estimates are f ^ ; ^ ?1 g; because for given
values of these it is possible to derive the estimates of f ; ?1 ; ?2 ; ?2 g
and, if r > s2 ; to further decompose and into = f 0 ; 1 g and
= f 0 ; 1 g:
The parameter estimates in Table 3 are based on the two-step procedure for r = 2, s1 = 1; and s2 = 1. We have imposed identifying
restrictions on two cointegration relations by distinguishing between the
directly stationary relation, 00 xt ; and the polynomially cointegrated rext ; where is proportional to ?2 : Note, however, that
lation, 01 xt +
this is just one of many identi cation schemes which happen to be possible because r s2 = 1: In Section 8 we will present another identi ed
structure where both relations are polynomially cointegrating.
0
The b?1 xt relation is a CI(2; 1) cointegrating relation which only
can become stationary by di erencing. We interpret such a relation as
24
a medium long-run steady-state relation. The estimated coe cients of
b suggest a rst tentative interpretation:
?1
ytr = 0:60 sbt
0:68 mt
i.e. real industrial production has increased in the medium run with the
currency depreciation relative to the growth of money stock.
The estimate of ?2 determines the stochastic I(2) trend ^ 0?2 ^"i =
u
b2i ; where ^"i is the vector of estimated residuals from (17) and u
b2t =
^ 0?2^"t : Permanent shocks to money stock relative to price shocks, to
black market exchange rates and to industrial production seem to have
generated the I(2) trend in this period. The standard deviations of the
VAR residuals are reported in the bottom row of the table.
P
The
estimate
of
describes
the
second
I(1)
stochastic
trend,
u
b2i =
?1
P
b 0?1 ^"i . The coe cient to real industrial production has by far the
largest weight in b ?1 suggesting that it measures an autonomous real
shock. This is consistent with the hypothetical scenario (7) of Section 3.
I2 tren d
.5
19 77
.0 2
19 78
19 79
19 80
19 81
19 82
19 83
19 84
19 85
19 78
19 79
19 80
19 81
19 82
19 83
19 84
19 85
19 78
19 79
19 80
19 81
19 82
19 83
19 84
19 85
I1 n tren d
.0 1
0
-.0 1
19 77
.2
Sy
.1
0
-.1
19 77
Figure 10. The graphs of the estimated I(2) trend in the upper panel,
the nominal I(1) trend (i.e. the di erenced I(2) trend) in the middel
panel and the real I(1) trend in the lower panel.
Figure
P P 10, upper panel, shows the graph of the I(2) stochastic trend,
^"i ; where ^ ?2 is from Table 3. The graph in the middle panel
is the di erenced I(2) trend
Pand the graph in the lower panel is the real
stochastic trend given by
^"y;i :
^ 0?2
25
The vector ^ ?2 describes the weights ci ; i = 1; ::; 4 of the I(2) trend in
the scenario (7) of Section 3 for the Brazilian variables. Nominal money,
prices and exchange rates have large coe cients of approximately the
same size, whereas the coe cient to real income is very small. This
suggests that only the nominal variables are I(2) consistent with the
assumption behind the scenario in (7).
7
Nominal growth in the long run and the medium
run3
The notion of price homogeneity plays an important role for the analysis
of price adjustment in the long run and the medium run. Both in the
I(1) and the I(2) model, long-run price homogeneity can be de ned
as a zero sum restriction on : Under the assumption that industrial
production is not a ected by the I(2) trend, long-run price homogeneity
for the Brazilian data can be expressed as:
0
i
0
?1
0
?2
= [ai ; ! i ai ; (1 ! i )ai ; ; ]; i = 1; :::; 2;
= [b; ! 3 b; (1 ! 3 )b; ];
= [c; c; c; 0]:
(24)
where and ?1 de ne CI(2; 1) relations and ?2 de ne the variables
which are a ected by the I(2) trends. Overall price homogeneity is
testable either as a joint hypothesis of the rst two conditions or as a
single hypothesis of the last condition in (24) (see, Kongsted, 2004). The
rst condition in (24) describes price homogeneity between the levels of
the nominal variables. It can be easily tested in the standard I(1) model
as a linear hypothesis on either expressed as R0 i = 0; i = 1; 2; :::; r,
where for the Brazilian data R0 = [1; 1; 1; 0; 0] or, equivalently, as =
H' where ' is a (p1 1) r matrix of free coe cients and
2
3
1 000
6 1 1 0 07
6
7
7:
0
1
0
0
H=6
6
7
4 0 0 1 05
0 001
The hypothesis of price homogeneity was strongly rejected based on
a LR test statistic of 41.9, asymptotically distributed as 2 (2): We note
that the rst three coe cients of ^ 1 in Table 3 do not even approximately
sum to zero, whereas those of ^ 0 are much closer to zero.
The ^ ?2 estimates in Table 3 suggest that nominal money stock
and black market exchange rate have been similarly a ected by the I(2)
3
This Section draws heavvily on Section 2 in Juselius (1999b)
26
trend, whereas the CPI price index has a smaller weight. Furthermore,
the coe cient to industrial production is close to zero, consistent with
the hypothesis that the latter has not been a ected by the I(2) trend.
This can be formally tested based on the LR procedure (Johansen, 2004)
as an hypothesis that industrial production is I(1). The test, distributed
as 2 (1), was accepted based a test statistic of 1.30 and a p-value of
0.25.
In the I(2) model, there is the additional possibility of mediumrun price homogeneity de ned as homogeneity between nominal growth
rates. This is, in general, associated with real variables being I(1). For
example, if (m p) I(1) and (sb p) I(1); then ( m
p) I(0)
and ( sb
p) I(0) and there is medium-run price homogeneity in
the sense of nominal growth rates being pairwise cointegrated (1, -1).
Hence, a rejection of long-run price homogeneity implies a rejection of
homogeneity between the nominal growth rates. We note that the rst
three coe cients of ^ ?1 in Table 3 do not even roughly sum to zero
consistent with the rejection of long-run price homogeneity.
The previous section demonstrated that the levels component, xt 2
and the di erences component,
xt 1 in (17) are closely tied together
by polynomial cointegration. In addition
xt 1 contains information
0
about ? xt 1 ; i.e. about the medium long-run relation between growth
rates. Relying on results in Johansen (1995) the levels and di erence
components of model (17) can be decomposed as:
xt
1
+ xt
1
=(
)
0
|
I(0)
0
+(
x
{z t }1
?1
+
?1 )
0
x
| ?1 {z t }1
I(0)
0
+(
+
+
1
0
?2 )
0
x
| 1{zt }1
|
0
?2
x
{z t }1
(25)
I(1)
I(1)
0
0 xt 1
| {z }
I(0)
where = ( 0 ) 1 and is similarly de ned. The matrix is decomposed into three parts describing di erent dynamic e ects from the
growth rates, and the matrix into two parts describing the e ects from
the stationary relation, 00 xt 1 ; and the nonstationary relation, 01 xt 1 .
The matrices in brackets correspond to the adjustment coe cients.
The interpretation of the rst component in (25), ( ) 0 xt 1 ; is
that prices not just adjusting to the equilibrium error between the price
27
levels, 0 xt 2 ; but also to the change in the equilibrium error, 0 xt 1 .
Under long-run price homogeneity it would have represented a homogeneous e ect in in ation rates.
The second component, ( 0 ?1 + ?1 ) 0?1 xt 1 ; corresponds to
a stationary medium long-run relation between growth rates of nominal
magnitudes. Because of the rejection of long-run price homogeneity, this
represents a non-homogeneous e ect in nominal growth rates.
The third component, ( 0 ?2 ) 0?2 xt 1 ; and the fourth component, 1 01 xt ; are both I(1) relations which combine to a stationary
I(0); where
polynomial cointegration relation, 1 ( 01 xt 1 + 0 xt 1 )
0
0
0
=(
1
?2 ) ?2 .
The long-run matrix is the sum of the two levels components measured by:
=
0
0 0
+
0
1 1:
Hypothetically, the matrix is likely to satisfy the condition for long-run
price homogeneity in a regime where in ation is under control. Thus,
the lack of price homogeneity is likely to be the rst sign of in ation
running out of control.
The growth-rates matrix is the sum of the three di erent components measured by
=(
)
0
+(
0
?1
+
?1 )
0
?1
+(
0
?2 )
0
?2 :
The matrix is, however, not likely to exhibit medium-run price homogeneity, even under the case of long-run price homogeneity. This is
because R0 = 0 implies R0 ?2 6= 0: The intuition is as follows: When
0
xt
I(0); a non-homogeneous reaction in nominal growth rates is
needed to achieve an adjustment towards a stationary long-run equilibrium position. Therefore, medium-run price homogeneity interpreted as
a zero sum restriction of rows of would in general be inconsistent with
overall long-run price homogeneity.
0
Table 4 reports the estimates of
= (I
1) =
? and
?
0
=
: We notice that the coe cients of each row do not sum to
zero. Next section will show that the di erence is statistically signi cant. The diagonal elements of the matrix are particularly interesting
as they provide information of equilibrium correction behavior, or the
lack of it, of the variables in this system. We notice a signi cant positive coe cient in the diagonal element of the domestic prices, which in a
single equation model would imply accelerating prices. In a VAR model
absence of equilibrium correction in one variable can be compensated
by a su ciently strong counteracting reaction from the other variables
28
in the system. It is noticeable that the only truely market determined
variable, the black market exchange rate, is signi cantly equilibriumcorrecting variable, whereas money stock is only borderline so.
Section 3 demonstrated that the unrestricted characteristic roots of
the VAR model contained a small explosive root, which disappeared
when two unit roots were imposed. Nevertheless, the positive diagonal
element of prices suggest that the spiral of price increases which subsequently became hyper in ation had already started at the end of this
sample.
8
Money growth, currency depreciation, and price
in ation in Brazil
Long-run price homogeneity is an important property of a nominal system and rejecting it is likely to have serious implications both for the
interpretation of the results and for the validity of the nominal to real
transformation. The empirical analysis of Durevall (1998) was based on
a nominal to real transformation without rst testing its validity. We will
here use the I(2) model for the empirical investigation of the money-price
spiral without having to impose invalid long-run price homogeneity.
8.1
Identifying the
relations
The estimates of 0 ; 1 and in Table 3 are uniquely identi ed by the
CI(2; 2) property of 00 xt : However, other linear combinations of 0 and
1 may be more relevant from an economic point of view, but these will
be I(1) and will, therefore, have to be combined with the di erenced
I(2) variables to become stationary.
To obtain more interpretable results three overidentifying restrictions
have been imposed on the two relations (see johansen and Juselius,
1994). The LR test of overidentifying restrictions, distributed as 2 (3)
became 1:41 and the restrictions were accepted based on a p-value of
0.70. The estimates of the two identi ed relations became:
c0
1;t xt
= mt
c0
2;t xt
= pt
1
1
stb
1
ytr
0:64 (mt
(18:3)
1
1
0:005trend
( 2:5)
r
yt 1 )
0:008trend
(26)
( 2:5)
The rst relation is essentially describing a trend-adjusted liquidity ratio,
except that the black market exchange rate is used instead of the CPI
as a measure of the price level. The liquidity ratio with CPI instead of
the exchange rate was strongly rejected. This suggests that in ationary
expectations were strongly a ected by the expansion of money stock and
that these expectations in uenced the rise of the black market nominal
exchange rate.
29
Both relations need a linear deterministic trend. The estimated trend
coe cient of the rst relation in suggests that 'the liquidity ratio' grew
on average with 6% (0.005 12 100) per year in this period. The
second relation shows that prices grew less than proportionally with
the expansion of M3 money stock relative to industrial production after having accounted for an average price increase of approximately 9%
(0.008 12 100) per year.
3.0
Lm3-Lcpi-LY
2.8
2.6
2.4
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1982
1983
1984
1985
Lm3-Lexc-LY
6.25
6.00
5.75
5.50
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
Figure 11. The graphs of inverse velocity with CPI as a price variable
(upper panel) and with nominal exchange rate (lower panel).
The graphs in Figure 11 of the liquidity ratio based on the nominal exchange rate and on the CPI index, respectively, may explain why
nominal exchange rates instead of domestic prices were empirically more
relevant in the rst relation. It is interesting to note that the graphs
are very similar until the end of 1980, whereafter the black market exchange rate started to grow faster than CPI prices. Thus, the results
suggest that money stock grew faster than prices in the crucial years
before the rst hyper in ation episode, but also that the depreciation
rate of the black market currency was more closely related to money
stock expansion. This period coincided with the Mexican moratorium,
the repercussions of which were strongly and painfully felt in the Brazilian economy. The recession and the major decline of Brazilian exports
caused the government to abandon its previous more orthodox policy of
ghting in ation by maintaining a revalued currency and, instead, engage in a much looser monetary policy. For a comprehensive review of
30
the Brazilian exchange rate policy over the last four decades, see Bobomo
and Terra (1999).
Under the assumption that the black market exchange rate is a fairly
good proxy for the `true' value of the Brazilian currency, the following
scenario seems plausible: The expansion of money stock needed to nance the recession and devaluations in the rst case increased in ationary expectations in the black market, which then gradually spread to
the whole domestic economy. Because of the widespread use of wage
and price indexation in this period there were no e ective mechanisms
to prevent the accelerating price in ation.
8.2
Dynamic equilibrium relations
This scenario can be further investigated by polynomial cointegration.
In the I(2) model 0 xt
I(1) has to be combined with the nominal
growth rates to yield a stationary dynamic equilibrium relation. The
two identi ed relations, 01;1 xt and 01;2 xt in (26) need to be combined
with nominal growth rates to become stationary. Table 5 reports various
versions of the estimated dynamic equilibrium relations.
The rst dynamic steady-state relation corresponds essentially to Cagan's money demand relation in periods of hyper in ation. However, the
price level is measured by the black market nominal exchange rate and
the opportunity cost of holding money is measured both by the CPI
in ation and by the currency depreciation. The coe cient to in ation
corresponds to Cagan's coe cient which de nes the average in ation
rate (1= ) at which the government can obtain maximum seignorage.
The present estimate suggests average in ation rates of an order of magnitude of 0.40-0.50 which corresponds to the usual de nition of hyper
in ation periods.
The second relation is more di cult to interpret from a theoretical
point of view but seems crucial for the mechanisms behind the increasingly high in ation of this period and the hyper in ation of the subsequent periods. Eq. (3) shows that the `gap' between prices and `excess'
money as measured by 01;2 xt is cointegrated with changes in money
stock and prices, but not with currency depreciation. Eq. (4) combines
0
m; and price in ation, p; Eq. (5) with
1;2 xt with money growth,
p and Eq. (6) with m: Although both nominal growth rates are
individually cointegrating with 01;2 xt , there is an important di erence
between them: The relationship between money growth and the relation 01;2 xt suggests error-correcting behavior in money stock, whereas
the one between price in ation and 01;2 xt indicates lack error-correcting
behavior in prices. The latter would typically describe a price mechanism leading ultimately to hyper in ation unless counterbalanced by
31
Table 4: The unrestricted parameter estimates
The estimated = 0? ? matrix
mt
pt
s bt
y rt
2
mt :
-1.07 -0.06 0.00
0.02
2
pt :
-0.02 -0.55 0.01
-0.01
2 b
-0.42 0.42 -0.92
0.03
st :
2 r
yt :
-0.13 0.20
0.04
-1.32
0
The estimated =
matrix
b
mt 1
pt 1
st 1
ytr 1
trend
2
mt :
0:03 0:11
0:05 0:00 -0:001
( 1:7)
2
pt :
2 b
st
:
2 r
yt
:
0:05
(7:5)
( 3:3)
(0:4)
( 6:6)
0:03
0:03
0:05
0:00
( 5:1)
(3:3)
0:11
0:15
(1:9)
0:02
0:7
(3:1)
0:19
(2:8)
( 3:9)
-0:01
0:01
0:3
0:5
(4:8)
(0:1)
0:15
0:002
(4:2)
( 2:6)
-0:02
0:00
0:6
( 0:1)
Table 5: Estimates of the polynomially cointegrated relations
The dynamic equilibrium relations 0 xt + ! 0 xt
^ 0 xt ! 1;1 m t ! 1;2 p t ! 1;3 s b
1;1
t
(1)
1.0
0:62
2:52
0:59
(1:1)
(3:4)
(2:7)
(2)
1.0
-
2:02
0:53
(3)
^ 0 xt
1;2
1.0
! 2;1 m t
5:80
! 2;2 p t
11:32
! 2;3 s bt
0:34
(67)
(9:9)
(1:0)
(4)
1.0
6:02
11:38
(3:4)
(7:1)
(5)
(2:5)
-
(10:0)
1.0
16:57
-
(15:4)
(6)
1.0
11:42
(12:4)
32
-
-
other compensating measures, such as currency control.
8.3
The short-run dynamic adjustment structure
The in ationary mechanisms will now be further investigated based on
the estimated short-run dynamic adjustment structure. Current as well
as lagged changes of industrial production were insigni cant in the system and were, therefore, left out. Thus, real growth rates do not seem to
have had any signi cant e ect on the short-run adjustment of nominal
growth rates which is usually assumed to be the case in a high in ation
regime. Furthermore, based on a F-test the lagged depreciation rate was
also found insigni cant in the system and was similarly left out. Table 6
reports the estimated short-run structure of the simpli ed model. Most
of the signi cant coe cients describe feed-back e ects from the dynamic
steady-state relations de ned by Eq. (2) and Eq. (4) in Table 5 and the
medium-run steady-state relation between growth rates, 0?1 xt de ned
in Table 3. It is notable that the residual correlations are altogether
very small, so that interpretation of the results should be robust to linear transformations of the system.
The short-run adjustment results generally con rm the previous ndings. Price in ation has not been equilibrium correcting in the second
steady-state relation, whereas the growth in money stock has been so in
both of the two dynamic steady-state relations. The depreciation of the
black market exchange rate has been equilibrium correcting to the rst
steady-state relation measuring the liquidity ratio relation and has been
strongly a ected by the second price 'gap' relation. Furthermore, it has
reacted strongly to changes in money stock con rming the above interpretation of the important role of in ationary expectations (measured
by changes in money stock) for the currency depreciation rate.
After the initial expansion of money stock at around 1981 (which
might have been fatal in terms of the subsequent hyper in ation experience) money supply seems primarily to have accommodated the increasing price in ation. The lack of equilibrium correction behavior in
the latter was probably related to the widespread use of wage and price
indexation in this period. Thus, the lack of market mechanism to correct for excessive price changes allowed domestic price in ation to gain
momentum as a result of high in ationary expectations in the foreign
exchange market.
9
Concluding remarks
The purpose of this paper was partly to give an intuitive account of the
cointegrated I(2) model and its rich (but also complicated) statistical
structure, partly to illustrate how this model can be used to address
33
important questions related to in ationary mechanisms in high in ation
periods. The empirical analysis was based on data from the Brazilian
high in ation period, 1977:1-1985:5. An additional advantage of this period was that it was succeeded by almost a decade of hyper-in ationary
episodes. The paper demonstrates empirically that it is possible to uncover certain features in the data and the model which at an early stage
may suggest a lack of control in the price mechanism. Thus, a violation
of two distinct properties, price homogeneity and equilibrium correction,
usually prevalent in periods of controlled in ation, seemed to have a high
signal value as a means to detect an increasing risk for a full-blown hyper
in ation. The paper demonstrates that:
1. prices started to grow in a non-homogeneous manner at the beginning of the eighties when the repercussions of the Mexican moratorium strongly and painfully hit the Brazilian economy. The expansion of money stock needed to nance the recession and the
subsequent devaluations increased in ationary expectations in the
black market, which then spread to the whole domestic economy.
2. the widespread use of wage and price indexation in this period
switched o the natural equilibrium correction behavior of the
price mechanism. Without other compensating control measures
which might have dampened in ationary expectations, it was not
possible to prevent price in ation to accelerate.
Acknowledgement 1 Useful comments from Michael Goldberg are gratefully acknowledged. The paper was produced with nancial support from
the Danish Social Sciences Research Councel.
10
Appendix A: Misspeci cation diagnostics
The univariate normality test in Table A.1 is a Jarque-Bera test, distributed as 2 (2): The multivariate normality test is described in Doornik
and Hansen (1995) distributed as 2 (8). The AR-test is the F-test described in Doornik (1996), page 4. P-values are in brackets.
34
Table 6: Dynamic adjustment and feed-back e ects in the nominal system
Ref.
Regressors:
mt 1
pt
Table 5 (2)
Table 5 (4)
Eq.:
0:59
0:76
(5:6)
w^1;1 x)t
1
( ^ 1;2 x
w^1;2 x)t
1
Table 3
pt
0:11
(4:2)
1
( ^ 1;1 x
^0
?1
mt
0:33
0:03
AR(1)
0:19
(0:66)
(0:43)
0:00
(0:95)
0:03
0:06
0:02
0:06
(4:3)
0:005
( 2:2)
(2:1)
1.0
-0.02
0.08
1.0
-0.12
(0:84)
0:03
(0:87)
p
1:67
(0:43)
1:27
(0:26)
Skewness
-0.13 0.21
0.09 -0.21
Kurtosis
3.06 3.29
2.62
3.27
Multivariate misspeci cation tests
Normality, 2 (8)
4.43 (0.82)
AR(1)
5.59 (0.99)
AR(4)
62.21 (0.54)
35
0:08
(1:9)
Table 7: Misspeci cation tests
Univariate misspeci cation tests
yr
sb
m
2
Normality, (2) 0:66 1:71
0:36
(0:72)
(12:1)
( 2:9)
+0:008
Residual correlations:
(2:7)
( 2:3)
(6:4)
xt
(2:4)
s bt
0:91
(2:0)
-
1.0
LY
LY
LUSDbm
Lcpi
1
1
0
0
0
0
1
5
-1
10
1
5
10
-1
1
5
-1
10
1
1
1
1
0
0
0
0
-1
Lm3
Lm3
1
-1
1
5
-1
10
1
5
10
-1
1
5
-1
10
1
1
1
1
0
0
0
0
-1
Lcpi
LUSDbm
1
1
5
-1
10
1
5
10
-1
1
5
-1
10
1
1
1
1
0
0
0
0
-1
1
5
-1
10
1
5
10
-1
1
5
-1
10
1
5
10
1
5
10
1
5
10
1
5
10
Figure A.1: Residual autocorrelograms and crosscorrelograms with
95% con dence bands.
LY
LU SD bm
25
25
20
20
15
15
10
10
5
5
0
-4
-2
0
2
0
-4
4
-2
Lm 3
25
20
20
15
15
10
10
5
5
-2
0
2
4
2
4
Lc pi
25
0
-4
0
2
0
-4
4
-2
0
Figure A.2: Residual histograms for the four equations.
Figure A.1 shows the residual auto-correlograms and cross-correlograms
of order 10 for all four equations. Figure A.2 shows the residual histograms compared to the normal distribution for all equations. Both
gures have been produced with the program Me2, described in Omtzigt
(2003)
36
11
References
Bonomo, M. and Terra, C., (1999). The political economy of exchange
rate policy in Brazil: 1964-1997, Graduate School of Economics, Getulio
Vargas Foundation, Rio de Janeiro, Brazil.
Cagan, P., (1956). The monetary dynamic of hyperin ation, in: M.
Friedman (Ed.), Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money, University
Press, Chicago.
Doornik, J.A. (1996), \Testing vector error autocorrelation and heteroscedasticity", Available at http://www.nu .ox.ac.uk/users/doornik
Doornik, J.A. and H. Hansen (1994), \An ominbus test for univariate
and multivariate normality",. Technical report, Nu eld College, Oxford.
Durevall, D., (1998). The dynamics of chronic in ation in Brazil,
1968-1985. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 16, 423-432.
Friedman, M., (1970). The counterrevolution in monetary theory.
Institute of Economic A airs, Occasional Paper 33.
Hansen, H. and Juselius, K., (1995). CATS in RATS. Manual to
Cointegration Analysis of Time Series, Estima, Evanston.
Johansen, S., (1992). A representation of vector autoregressive processes integrated of order 2. Econometric Theory, 8, 188-202.
Johansen, S., (1995). A statistical analysis of cointegration for I(2)
variables. Econometric Theory 11, 25-59.
Johansen, S., (1997). A likelihood analysis of the I(2) model. Scandinavian Journal of Statistics 24, 433-462.
Johansen, S., (2002). A small sample correction of the test for cointegrating rank in the vector autoregressive model. Econometrica 70,
1929-1961.
Johansen, S., (2004). Statistical analysis of hypotheses on the cointegrating relations in the I(2) model. Forthcoming Journal of Econometrics
Johansen, S. and Juselius, K., (1994). Identi cation of the longrun and the short-run structure. An application to the ISLM model.
Journal of Econometrics 63, 7-36.
Juselius, K., (1999a). Models and relations in economics and econometrics. Journal of Economic Methodology 6:2, 259-290.
Juselius, K. (1999b), \Price convergence in the long run and the
medium run. An I(2) analysis of six price indices", in (ed.) R. Engle
and H. White, `Cointegration, Causality, and Forecasting' Festschrift in
Honour of Clive W.J. Granger". Oxford University Press, 1999.
Juselius, K. and Vuojosevic, Z., (2003). High in ation, hyper in ation, and explosive roots. The case of Yugoslavia. Preprint, Institute of
Economics, University of Copenhagen.
37
King, R.G., Plosser, C.I., Stock, J.H. and Watson, M.W., (1991).
Stochastic trends and economic uctuations. American Economic Review 81, 819-40.
Kongsted, H.C., (2004). Testing the Nominal-to-Real Transformation. Forthcoming in the Journal of Econometrics.
Nielsen, B. and A. Rahbek (2000), \Similarity Issues in Cointegration
Analysis", Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol 62(1), pp.522.
Nielsen, H.B. and Rahbek, A., (2003). Likelihood ratio testing for
cointegration ranks in I(2) models. Discussion Paper 2003-42, Institute
of Economics, University of Copenhagen.
Omtzigt, P. (2003), \Me2: A computer package for the maximum
likelihood estimation of I(2) systems", Tecnical report, University of
Amsterdam.
Paruolo, P., (1996). On the determination of integration indices in
I(2) systems. Journal of Econometrics 72, 313-356.
Parulo, P., (2000). Asymptotic e ciency of the two stage estimator
in I(2) systems, Econometric Theory 16, 4, 524-550.
Rahbek, A., Kongsted, H.C. and J rgensen, C., (1999). Trendstationarity in the I(2) cointegration model. Journal of Econometrics.
90, 265-289.
Romer, D., (1996). Advanced Macroeconomics. McGraw Hill, New
York.
Sargent, T., (1977). The demand for money during hyperin ation
under rational expectations: I. International Economic Review 18, 1,
59-82.
38