Policy Concertation in Europe:
Understanding Government Choice
Lucio Baccaro
Institute for Work and Employment Research
Massachusetts Institute of Technology
baccaro@mit.edu
Marco Simoni
European Institute
London School of Economics and Political Science
m.simoni@lse.ac.uk
Forthcoming in Comparative Political Studies, October 2008
Keywords: concertation, corporatism, trade unions, European politics, industrial relations
Policy Concertation in Europe: Understanding Government Choice
Abstract
This paper focuses on the European governments’ decision to involve unions and employers in
the design and implementation of public policy. Based on new measures of the phenomenon, it
argues that between 1974 and 2004 no convergence on a pluralist model of policy formation is
visible. The paper then uses these measures to identify and analyze the clearest cases of
adoption or demise of concertation, namely the contrasting responses of the British and Irish
governments to wage policy, and of the Austrian and Italian governments to pension reform. It
argues that governments are willing to share their policy-making prerogatives when they are
politically weak, and when unions, while still representing a credible threat to policy
implementation, have been declining in the recent past. Additionally, a combination of
partisanship and policy learning reinforces the push for change.
1
Policy Concertation in Europe: Understanding Government Choice
The literature on corporatism and policy concertation has shown a tendency to conflate a
number of questions that it would be best to keep separate: (1) Why are governments willing (or
unwilling in some cases) to share their policy making prerogatives with trade unions and
employer associations, not just informally, by incorporating their inputs, but, formally, by setting
up a bargaining table and engaging in negotiations with them over the content of public policy?
(2) In what conditions, contingent on government’s decision to in- (or de-)volve, does a
negotiated agreement emerge? (3) In what circumstances does negotiated regulation cease to
reflect the contingencies and power balance of the time in which the deal is struck and becomes a
durable way of processing public policy? (4) In what respects, if any, is policy concertation
more or less effective than alternative policy-making processes? 1
Despite its massive size, most of the literature has focused so far on questions two and
four, while it has been much less vocal on the other two. Possibly due to an implicit assumption
of corporatist convergence (see Streeck, 2004), much of the neo-corporatist literature of the
1970s and 1980s did not systematically distinguish between the reasons motivating governments
and those motivating unions and employers. Policy concertation was assumed to be a functional
necessity of advanced societies (Schmitter, 1974; Lehmbruch, 1979), such that all governments
would, sooner or later, want to engage in it. From this vantage point, the interesting questions
were not those about the conditions in which certain governments (and not others) would
develop a demand for policy concertation, but those about the conditions in which policy
concertation would be supplied by the interest group system (Schmitter and Lehmbruch, 1979;
Lehmbruch and Schmitter, 1982; Berger, 1981; Goldthorpe, 1984; Molina and Rhodes 2002).
Another strand of research (by now probably larger than the former) dealt with the
2
macroeconomic consequences of policy concertation, especially centralized or coordinated
collective bargaining (for recent analyses, see Garrett, 1998; Iversen, 1999; Traxler et al., 2001;
Kenworthy, 2003; Traxler, 2003; Mares, 2006).
In this paper we are interested in question number one, which we regard as analytically
prior to the others. Governments, accountable to national parliaments (or directly to the
electorate), are the sole institutions with a clear mandate to take binding decisions. The
constitutional standing and democratic legitimacy of mixed systems of policy-making granting
private actors access to the public policy sphere have always been considered dubious (see Lowi,
1979; Habermas, 1989[1964]; 1996), including by theorists of neo-corporatism itself (see
Schmitter, 1983, for an example). It needs to be explained why democratically elected
governments are, in some circumstances but not in others, willing to share their policy-making
prerogatives with the “social partners” rather than using them at full and proceeding unilaterally.
To address this question, this paper begins by measuring the phenomenon of interest. We
present two indicators of government willingness to engage in policy concertation in Europe, one
pertaining to wage policy and the other to welfare policy, covering 15 European countries
between 1974 and 2003. These indicators show that the propensity of governments to engage in
negotiations with the social partners in at least one of the two policy areas has remained virtually
stable over time, while the proportion of governments that are willing to bundle the two issues
and deal with them simultaneously has grown.
We then utilize these indicators as criteria for case selection in a small-n design aimed at
contributing to an inductive theory of government choice. By selecting cases in which
government’s willingness increased and decreased the most, according to our measures, while
keeping background factors as much as possible constant (Mill, 1946: book 3, ch. 8; King et al.,
3
1994), we identify four exploratory case studies: (1) the shift from decentralized wage bargaining
to social partnership in Ireland; (2) the transition from the social contract to Thatcherism in
Britain; (3) the move from policy inertia to negotiated pension reforms in Italy; and (4) the recent
unilateral restructuring of public pensions in Austria.
The stylized analysis of these cases identifies a particular configuration of factors, rather
than single elements (Ragin 1987). Based on the case study evidence, we argue that the decision
to involve private actors in policy bargains can be conceived of as the striking of an alliance
between weak governments and weakened unions. In other words, governments are willing to
share their policy-making prerogatives with unions when they are politically weak, and when the
unions have seen their organizational fortunes decline in recent years, while still maintaining a
capacity for oppositional mobilization.
The Trajectory of Policy Concertation between 1974 and 2003
Both the early literature on corporatism/concertation and the more recent literature on
social pacts often lack a measure of the object of analysis. To start obviating to this, we have
designed an indicator of “government willingness to engage in concertation”, which captures
government’s decision to involve formally the “social partners”, i.e. capital and labor, in policy
making. The indicator does not capture whether or not there is a concertation agreement, but
focuses on the initial intention of the government. 2
This indicator was created for two policy areas: wage policies (including income policies
and centralized wage bargaining) and welfare policies (that is, spending policies aimed at
providing social insurance of various kinds) for 15 European countries between 1974 and 2003. 3
The measures were based on information reported monthly in the European Industrial Relations
4
Review. By considering the whole period from the first oil shock to the present day, we do not
assume that the conditions leading to policy concertation have changed over time (as it has been
argued for the transition from “old” to “new” social pacts, see Negrelli, 2000; Hassel, 2003), but
leave the issue to be determined empirically.
For each country, year, and policy area, the government willingness index takes a value
of 1 when: (a) there is textual evidence that, in the course of the year, the government publicly
invites the social partners to negotiate a national agreement to set wage increases, or to design
social security policies/welfare institutions; or that (b) the social partners are invited to design or
implement autonomously, i.e. via bipartite agreements, any of the aforementioned policies. 4 If,
instead, there is textual evidence that a government designs and/or implements policies without
the formal involvement of social partners, the willingness score is 0. It must be emphasized that a
government could rely on the implicit consensus of one or more of the social partners when
designing policy, and still receive a 0 score, since our construct of interest, policy concertation,
refers to formal involvement rather than informal influence. Graphs in Figure 1 plot the
trajectory of government willingness over time.
Figure 1(a) on wage policies shows a pronounced cyclical component, thus providing
some support for the thesis articulated by Schmitter and Grote (1997) of a cyclical pattern of
policy concertation over time. There appears to be a very mild downwards trend, however
largely overshadowed by very pronounced cycles, which emerges clearly by comparing the
values of this indicator in peaks and troughs. In 1977, 83 percent of European governments in
our sample were willing to pursue concerted wage policies. 5 Only in France and Portugal,
according to our measure, the governments were unwilling to do so. 6 This percentage dropped
to 47 percent in 1985 (and 1986) when concerted wage policies were attempted only in Finland,
5
Greece, Sweden, Spain, Denmark, Austria, and Italy. A second trough is recorded in 1995, when
only 40 percent of European countries pursued income policies or centralized wage negotiations,
including Austria, Finland, Ireland, Norway, Greece, and Italy. Our data end in 2003 with
another peak: 73 percent of European governments were willing to have some form of negotiated
income policy, namely all except France, Denmark, Britain, and Italy.
(Figure 1 about here)
The trend in Figure 1(b) on welfare policy is markedly different. The graph shows a clear
growing trend since 1974, peaking in 2000 when, according to our information, all governments,
except in Austria and the United Kingdom, were willing to adopt a participatory approach. After
2000 the share of governments declined slightly. It was 60 percent in 2003: in that year, the
governments of Austria, Britain, Greece, Italy, Denmark, and Portugal took a unilateral approach
to welfare policy. The welfare policy graph shows a cyclical component which is much milder
than in the wage policy graph.
Some authors have proposed what we call a bundling hypothesis, namely that changes in
international macroeconomic conditions in the 1990s have pushed governments to seek
coordination in multiple areas simultaneously as opposed to single areas, as a way to increase
national competitiveness (Ebbinghaus and Hassel, 2000; Rhodes, 2001). Figure 2 plots the
number of governments that are willing to engage in concertation in at least one policy area
(black line), and the number of governments that are willing to engage concertation in both
policy areas at the same time (bars). The first curve is cyclical around a rather stable mean,
suggesting no long-term growth or decline in government willingness to involve. On average,
slightly more than 12 European countries per year (out of 15) have attempted some form of
policy concertation. The second curve is instead growing over time at a decreasing rate. This
6
confirms the bundling hypothesis, even though, contrary to expectations, most of the growth in
bundling seems to have taken place in the 1970s and 1980s, rather than in the 1990s. Indeed, in
the 1990s, the tendency of governments to approach both wage and welfare issues through policy
concertation seems to have reached a plateau.
(Figure 2 about here)
Linked to the bundling argument, scholars have also suggested that specific external
pressures, coming from the run up to and the establishment of EMU, have increased the
propensity of governments to seek explicit policy cooperation with the major interest groups,
especially for those countries in which the established thresholds for qualification were more
difficult to reach (Schmitter and Grote 1997; Crouch 2000; Rhodes 2001; Hassel 2003; Hancké
and Rhodes 2004).
To address this argument, Figure 3 distinguishes between EMU countries and non-EMU
countries in the 1985-2003 period. On average, the former are more willing to engage in income
policies than the latter throughout, but there is no appreciable growth trend in the 1990s
compared with the beginning of the period. The picture changes slightly when one considers
welfare policies. In the Euro group there is a fairly clear increase in willingness as the Euro
approaches, and a decrease after qualification. However, this graph must be read against the
evidence presented in Figure 1(b), which shows a growing trend of willingness in European
countries in general. Against this backdrop, the EMU seems to have reinforced a tendency that
was already present. 7
(Figure 3 about here)
Overall, our measures suggest that government willingness to involve labor and capital in
policy-making is not simply confined to the decades of the ‘Keynesian consensus’ (Goldthorpe
7
1984; Hall 1989), but is a rather stable feature of European politics in the last thirty years.
European governments are not moving towards greater unilateralism in policy-making, to say the
least. In this respect, theories predicting convergence towards a pluralist system of interest
intermediation, and the demise of concertative/corporatist models of policy-making, do not find
confirmation in our data (Streeck and Schmitter, 1991; Streeck, 1993). 8 The evidence illustrated
above has nothing say, however, about the specific factors or combination of factors explaining
government choice of cooperation vs. unilateralism. To explore these, the paper now moves to
case study analysis.
Case Selection
We averaged our government willingness scores over five-year periods for each country
(1974 to 1978; 1979 to 1983; 1984 to 1988; 1989 to 1993; 1994 to 1998; 1999 to 2003) and
calculated the differences between the periods. By doing so, we created a quantitative measure
of change in government willingness to engage in policy concertation and used it to identify the
countries that had undergone the largest policy changes in either direction. We then selected one
country at or near the top and one at or near bottom of the list. The specific choice attempted to
match (and, hence, control for) background conditions in the two countries. In other words, we
used an approximated “method of difference” research design (Mill, 1946: book 3, ch. 8), which
allowed for maximum variation on the dependent variable, while controlling for as many
background conditions as possible. The goal of the empirical analysis, based for the most part on
secondary sources, was to identify the differences that could explain the stark divergence in
outcomes.
For wage policy, we decided to contrast Britain (1979-83/1974-78) – namely the
transition from the “Social Contract” to Thatcherism – and Ireland (1989-93/1984-88) –
8
approximately, the emergence of social partnership in this country. For Britain, the choice was
straightforward since this was the case which seemed to have undergone the greatest decline in
government willingness to negotiate. Ireland, instead, had the second greatest increase in
government willingness score after Germany 1999-2003/1994-98 (the Social Democratic-Green
Party coalition’s unsuccessful attempt at producing a social pact), but was a good match to
Britain in other respects. Indeed, the Irish economy is considered very similar to the British from
various viewpoints, and especially from the point of view of the industrial relations system (see
Murphy and Roche, 1997; Gunnigle et al., 1999).
For welfare policy, we chose Austria (1999-2003/ 1994-98) as our negative case,
corresponding to the Austrian government’s decision to abandon the traditional partnership
approach and engage in unilateral pension restructuring, and Italy (1994-98/ 1989-93),
approximately the transition from policy inertia to negotiated pension reforms, as our positive
case. While Austria was at the bottom of our list, exhibiting the highest decrease in government
willingness to engage in concertation over social policy issues, Italy was one of three countries at
the top, together with Greece (1994-98/ 1989-93) and Norway (1989-93/ 1983-88). We chose
Italy because in Italy (unlike other countries) the bone of contention was exactly the same as in
Austria, namely pension reform, which the two countries tackled in dramatically different
fashions. We provide stylized reconstructions of the four case studies.
Ireland: from Free-For-All Collective Bargaining to Social Partnership
During most of the 1980s, the Irish government was unwilling to regard collective actors,
and especially trade unions, as more than “lobbying interests” (Hardiman, 1988: 225). In this
period collective bargaining was decentralized and private sector negotiations took place at the
9
enterprise level. The government sought to influence wage settlements indirectly by taking a
tougher bargaining stance towards public sector bargaining renewals than in the past.
This approach was reversed in 1987, when the Irish government officially involved
unions and employers in an ambitious and wide-ranging reform plan known as “Programme for
National Recovery” (PNR). The PNR, a three-year agreement, committed the actors to seek
stabilization of the exchange rate, reduction of public spending, and tax reform. By signing the
agreement, the Irish Congress of Trade Unions (ICTU) accepted the principles of social peace
and wage moderation, to be achieved, inter alia, through a ban on local bargaining. In exchange,
government agreed to reform the tax system to increase take-home pay.
The PNR was the first in a series of six successive three-year social partnership
agreements, which last to date. In all these years, the basic structure of the agreements has
remained more or less the same: against the backdrop of fiscal conservatism and monetary
orthodoxy, these agreements have exchanged wage restraint for tax cuts, while targeting social
inequalities and exclusion, first by keeping constant the real value of transfers, and then through
more substantive measures (see Omitted).
Three elements seem to have determined the adoption of social partnership: the electoral
weakness of the government, the organizational weakening of unions, and the high problem load
Ireland was facing at the time of change. First, the government that initiated social partnership
was a one-party minority government by the Fianna Fail party, which held 48.8 percent of seats
in the Irish lower chamber (Dáil). Its predecessor, a Fine Gael-Labor coalition, could instead
count on 54.8 percent of the seats. The weakness of the Fianna Fail government was
compounded by the party’s own interclass nature, which made it difficult for the leadership to
pass policy decisions that penalized the party’s labor constituency (Hardiman 1988: 200-204).
10
Government weakness paired in Ireland with weakened unions, both in terms of membership and
capacity to bring out workers on strike. Between 1983 and 1987, union membership declined
from 57 to 50 percent. 9 However, they still maintained a considerable capacity to make life very
difficult for government in case they decided to do so (Hardiman 1988: 215), which explains
why government had an interest in involving them. These factors combined with an exceptional
load of problems: all major actors in Ireland were aware that, with no growth, high
unemployment, and public finance imbalances, the economy was out of control, and that
something drastic needed to be done to bring it back on track. This is brought out clearly by the
1986 report produced by the National Economic and Social Council (NESC), a tripartite
institution, which outlined clearly the gravity of the macroeconomic situation. Interestingly, the
report was subscribed to unanimously by both government and the social partners, including the
unions (Hardiman 1992; NESC 1986).
Britain: The Shift to Neo-Liberal Orthodoxy
A shift in the opposite direction – from concertation to unilateralism in wage policy – can
be found in Britain. In 1973, when it was still in opposition, the Labour party signed a “social
contract” with the Trade Unions Congress (TUC). The contract signaled that the party was ready
to adopt a policy of partnership once in office, and this is exactly what it did. Since 1974, a
number of labor-friendly measures – including price controls, lower income taxes, rent-controls,
and various subsidies – were introduced, in exchange for the unions’ commitment to moderate
wage claims (Pelling 1987: 291; Peden 1991: 203-204).
However, the social contract did not deliver the expected economic results. Wage drift
was so high in this period, that de facto average wage increases were twice or three time as high
11
as the agreed levels (Peden 1991: 204). Thus inflation was not brought down, and
unemployment started to rise. Wildcat strikes dominated the industrial relations scene,
culminating in the “winter of discontent” wave of protests between 1978 and 1979 (Scharpf
1991: 83-88; Mares 2006: 202).
In retrospect, it is not especially surprising, given circumstances, that the Labour party
lost the next elections (despite an attempt at rekindling the partnership with the unions through a
new “social contract”) and Margaret Thatcher became the next PM in May 1979. The
touchstone of the Tory Party’s industrial relations policy was the curtailment of trade union
power (Letwin 1992: 130-158). To this purpose, various pieces of legislation were passed
including the 1980, 1982, and 1988 Employment Acts, and the Trade Union Act in 1984.
Instead of relying on unions’ voluntary restraint, the government centered its anti-inflation
strategy on a monetarist approach (Peden 1991: 214-215), which it continued to pursue even
when unemployment began to rise (Letwin 1992: 118-123).
In contrast to the Irish case, the Thatcher government that terminated concertation in
Britain was an exceptionally strong one, thanks to the largest electoral swing since WWII (Peden
1991: 214). Additionally, during its tenure, it faced an extremely fragmented and weakened
opposition (Thorpe 2001: 190-193). British unions were at the peak of their organizational
strength at the time of the policy shift. They were so strong that they were able to deadlock any
negotiation with the government until all their requests were secured. Indeed, the excessive
power of the unions featured prominently in the Conservative program and was one of the main
arguments put forward by the Tories to support their requests for a demise of peak-level
concertation as well as unions’ reform (Dale 2000: 268; Powell 1992: 138). However, in so
doing, they reversed a long-standing tradition that considered policy concertation a crucial tool to
12
keep society stable and united (Letwin 1992: 130-132 Thomsen 1996: 96-98). The Thatcher
government was convinced that the “country [was] faced with its most serious problems since
the Second World War” (Dale 2000: 266), and that the unions were part of them.
Austria: Unilateral Welfare Restructuring in a Quintessentially Corporatist Country
The case of Austria is a striking example of government’s disengaging from policy
concertation on welfare policies. From the end of WWII to 1999, Austria had been a model of
corporatist governance. All policy issues, including welfare, were discussed with organized
interests, including the trade unions confederation (ÖGB), the Chamber of Labor (BAK), the
Economic Chamber (WKÖ), and the Chamber of Agriculture (PKLWK). In spite of a few
divisive issues which had emerged in the late 1990s, the “forum for interest representation and
[the] platform for consensus bargaining between the large societal groups ha[d] remained
remarkably stable” (Tàlos and Kittel 2002: 48). In Austria, “virtually no decision of
consequence [wa]s made that ha[d] not been intensively discussed by the social partners.”
(Tomandl and Fuerboeck 1986: 12).
Throughout the 1990s a number of concerted policies on issues of social security and
welfare reform were agreed by the government and the social partners, including unemployment
benefits (1994), 10 plans to cut public expenditure (1995), and a relatively minor pension reform
(1997). 11 The situation became more difficult, however, in early 2000, when a new grand
coalition government involving the SPÖ (the Social Democratic party) and the ÖVP (the
People’s Party), tabled a proposal to reform the pension system by focusing on expenditure cuts.
This proposal met with outright opposition from the ÖGB, which led to intense disputes between
the union and the two coalition parties. As a consequence of this rift, the ÖVP pulled out of the
13
alliance with the SPÖ and formed a cabinet with the populist Freedom Party (FPÖ) (Fallend
2001: 242-246).
Faced with growing deficit and increasing pension expenditures, the program of the new
government contained a pension reform that was very similar to the one that had failed to be
passed by the previous cabinet led by the SPÖ. Again, the ÖGB staunchly opposed the reform.
This time, however, it was approved against the unions’ will in July 2000. 12
The demise of policy concertation was not just limited to pensions, but included other
areas and institutions of the welfare state. In 2001, the governance of the Association of Social
Security Providers (HSV), the central institution of the social insurance system, was altered in an
unfavorable way for unions. For the first time in its history, the ÖGB called all its members to
mobilize against the law. 13 In December 2002, the government presented another far-reaching
pension reform, which included an increase in retirement age and benefit cuts. Again, the ÖGB
refused to accept the new reform proposals and called for industrial action against them. 14
Strikes and demonstrations involved 1 million workers across the country. Mobilizations
notwithstanding, the new reform was approved in July 2003. 15
Given the specificity of Austrian system of corporatist governance, whereby the social
partners are institutionally embedded in policy-making and policy-implementation in virtually all
areas, the demise of concertation in 2000 is particularly striking. The relative strength of the
government seems again to play a role in this shift: in this case it pertains specifically to the issue
on which concertation broke up. In the 1995-1999 legislature, over a fourth of SPÖ MPs were
trade unions officials, while very few union officials were members of the FPÖ or ÖVP political
groups. It was remarkably difficult for the grand coalition government to overcome the unions’
veto power on a key issue like pensions. The new coalition was instead free from direct union
14
influence and was much stronger vis-à-vis the major opponents, the trade unions, in this
particular respect (Schludi 2003: 180). The Freedom Party – for the first time holding cabinet
posts – had built its electoral fortunes, among other things, on a populistic critique of ‘union
privileges’ in the corporatist system (Viebrok, 2003) and, unlike the socialist and the Christian
democrats, did not have any special relationship with the interest representation bodies (Schludi
2003: 191-193; Tàlos and Kittel 2002: 39).
Additionally, union density had been declining constantly in Austria from 60 percent in
1973 to 36 percent in 2000 – one of the biggest declines in advanced countries (OECD 2001;
Golden, Lange and Wallerstein, 2002). The major problem, however, was not membership per
se, which remained non-negligible, as mobilization capacity and strategic isolation. Unlike in
Italy (and France), where union mobilizations were supported by the general public, in Austria
citizens largely ignored the unions’ protests against pensions reform and the other unilateral
welfare changes (Schludi 2003: 180, 191).
Italy: From Inertia to Negotiated Pension Reform
The Italian experience with pension reform provides a neat contrast to the Austrian, and
presents a number of similarities with Ireland, the other case of increased governmental
willingness to engage in concertation. In the late 1990s, Austria and Italy were the countries
with the highest proportion of pension expenditures on GDP (see Schludi, 2001: Table 1, p. 7).
Yet, unlike the Austrian, the Italian governments, for the most part, pursued a policy of
negotiation with the trade unions during the 1990s, as opposed to unilateral reform.
During the 1980s, the financial situation of the Italian pension system became
increasingly difficult. Due to declining fertility rates and growing life expectancy, fewer young
15
people were being asked to support growing cohorts of retired. These phenomena were common
to all advanced countries, but were particularly severe in Italy (Ferrera, 1996). In 1990 and
1991, two unsuccessful attempts were made by coalition governments, where Socialists occupied
key cabinet posts, to reform the public pension system (Regonini 1996; Ferrera and Gualmini,
1999: Table 3.3., p. 115). The first comprehensive effort to tackle the pension problem was
made in 1992, when the government, lead by a prominent socialist politician, faced with a
difficult political and economic crisis, passed a drastic pension reform plan. This was not
formally negotiated with the unions, but was tolerated by them because it took into account the
most important union demand, name the safeguard of “seniority pensions” (Cazzola, 1995: 55).
A second unilateral attempt at pension reform was made in 1994 by the center-right
government of Silvio Berlusconi, which devised a far-reaching reform (Mascini, 2000: 16-77).
In response, the major labor confederations organized the most impressive demonstration of
union strength since the Hot Autumn wave of strikes in the late 1960s. Due, inter alia, to the
unions’ massive mobilizations, the parliamentary coalition supporting the Berlusconi
government began to fray and government was forced to scrap the reform plan.
In 1995, a technocratic government, which lacked a clear parliamentary majority but was
supported by the previous center-left opposition, engaged in negotiations over pension reform
with the unions and the main employers’ association. While the latter withdrew early on,
arguing that the proposed reform was not incisive enough, the unions and the government carried
on and eventually agreed on a reformed pension system that contained several important
innovations, including a “defined contribution” method for pension determination (in lieu of the
previous “defined benefit” system) and the gradual phasing out of seniority pensions. A further
negotiated reform to shorten the transition period to the new regime was passed in 1997. These
16
measures were key for Italy’s ability to qualify for the second phase of the European Monetary
Union.
The Cases Revisited
The analysis of the Irish, British, Austrian, and Italian cases leads to interesting
conclusions as regards both the particular combinations of factors that seem to explain both
adoption and demise of policy concertation by governments, and those that, surprisingly, seem to
hold no holding explanatory power at all. We begin with the latter.
a) Plausible Hypotheses Ruled Out
The four cases illustrated above suggest that the preferences of employer organisations
and the macroeconomic regime (Keynesian vs. Monetarist) in which the government operates
play little or no role in shaping governments’ approach to concertation vs. unilateralism. This is
surprising because recent interpretations have instead contended that employer preferences and
the macroeconomic regime are key to determining the interaction between state and organised
interest groups.
A simple version of the employer preference argument would state that the choice of
governments reflects the preferences of organized employers. This hypothesis has not been
explicitly formulated in exactly these terms, possibly due to its similarity to a coarse MarxistLeninist view of the state (Marx and Engels, 1978: 475). 16 However, it resonates with the recent
emphasis in comparative political economy on the strategic choices of organized employers as
the main determinants of policy outcomes (Hall and Soskice, 2001; Thelen, 2001, Swenson,
2002; Mares, 2003; Culpepper, 2007).
17
This hypothesis finds no corroboration in our case studies. In Britain, the monetarist shift
implemented by the Thatcher government met with the opposition of the Confederation of
British Industry, for it entailed a steep rise in interest rates. During the fall of 1980, “British
industrialists had begun a sustained campaign against the government’s monetary policy” (Walsh
2000: 497). In Ireland, at the time of policy change, the Irish organized employers were
relatively happy with the decentralization of collective bargaining they had been so keen to
promote (Hardiman, 1988: 200, 221, 236). In December 1986 and then again in June 1987, the
General Council of the major employer association “asserted that negotiations with the trade
unions on pay and related matters should continue to take place at local level” (Hardiman, 1988:
236; see also Hardiman, 1992: 350). Finally, in Italy, not only did the employers withdraw from
negotiations over pension reform in 1995, they also actively lobbied Berlusconi (who seemed
uncertain) to take a draconian approach to reform in 1994 (Mascini, 2000: 181). 17
The second argument our case studies rule out states that the government’s interest in
policy concertation on wage policy is a function of its macroeconomic stance. It has been argued
that, in a Keynesian regime, the state has incentives to seek to involve the unions in negotiated
wage moderation, while moderation is a strictly dominated strategy for the unions (namely
irrational), since government is committed to full employment (Scharpf 1991). So, governments
actively seek policy concertation in a Keynesian regime (even though they often fail to obtain it)
but not in a monetarist one. In a monetarist regime inflation is exogenous to the collective
bargaining system (for example because it is set by an independent central bank) and
governments have little incentives to engage in negotiations with the unions over wage
moderation, while the unions have incentives to moderate spontaneously their demands because
of the negative effects of lower real money supply (in case the target inflation rate of the central
18
bank is exceeded) on employment (Sharpf, 1991; Streeck, 1994; Hassel, 2003). This hypothesis
directly applies to government’s choice whether or not to engage in concerted wage policies. It
also indirectly applies to choices concerning the welfare state because the latter is an important
determinant of labor costs and wage inflation, especially in Continental welfare systems
(Ebbinghaus and Hassel, 2000).
We find no confirmation for this hypothesis in our sample. In Italy, progressively over
the course of the 1980s, price stability took priority over unemployment and the increasingly
independent central bank sought to mirror the behavior of the Bundesbank. Yet (some) of the
governments of the 1990s explicitly pursued policy concertation on both wages (the 1992 and
1993 agreements) and pensions (1995 and 1997 agreements). The Austrian Central Bank (ÖNB)
adopted a monetarist stance in the early 1980s, whose effect was a steady reduction of inflation
levels and a temporary surge of unemployment. Under this macroeconomic regime there was no
major disruption to the social partnership framework until 2000, when social partnership was
cast aside by the right-wing government. The macroeconomic stance of the country seems to
have had no influence, neither pro-concertation nor anti-concertation, on this particular policy
choice (Kittel 2001: 125). In Ireland, the hypothesis seems to find outright disconfirmation, as a
hard currency policy was accompanied by the staunch pursuit of a centralized wage agreement
by government (Omitted). 18
b) Plausible Hypotheses Corroborated
In our sample of countries, the governments that most dramatically increased their
willingness to concert (Ireland and Italy) were all peculiarly weak from an electoral point of
view. In Italy, the technocratic government of 1995 (similar to the government that initiated
concertation on wage policy in 1993) lacked a clear popular mandate because it replaced the
19
Berlusconi’s government not after general elections, but thanks to a change in parliamentary
alliances. The 1997 reform, in turn, was promoted by a very fragile coalition government, which
was forced to resign less than one year later by a party in its own majority. In Ireland, the 1987
Fianna Fail government was also a minority government. Vice versa, the governments that
moved away from concertation (Britain and Austria) were both holding comfortable majorities in
parliament. This argument about strength needs to be qualified in the case of Austria. Here, the
kind of strength at issue is not so much numerical as issue-specific. While the Social Democratic
party was unable to overcome the opposition of an internal faction, which was able to block
previous attempts at pension reform, the center-right coalition was free from direct influence
from this group.
The second factor which, in combination with the first, seems to explain a change in
government willingness to engage in concertation is related to union strength and may be linked
to the government’s expectations about the likely supply of partnership by the unions (Esping
Andersen and Regini 2000). The analysis of our cases suggests a curvilinear relationship
between union strength and government willingness to concert public policy. In other words,
governments are interested in concertation when unions are neither too strong nor too weak. In
Ireland and Italy, electorally weak governments were confronted with national union movements
that had experienced losses in union density, even though they still maintained considerable
mobilization capacities. Strong governments facing unions that are either so weakened that the
government may not fear their reaction (as it may have been the case in Austria), or so strong
that they are able to deadlock or highjack the negotiations, or worse undo the outcomes of
negotiated regulation through collective action at the plant level (like in Britain), tend to abstain
from concertation.
20
Overall, the four case studies both corroborate, in some respects, and qualify, in other
respects, a particular line of argument in the literature on corporatism and concertation, which
emphasizes the role of governments and regards the choice to engage in concerted policy-making
with trade unions as essentially the response to a “governability” problem (Schmitter 1981;
Lehmbruch, 1979). In a seminal contribution, Pizzorno (1978) pointed to the role that trade
unions played in the mobilization of political consensus within democracies. He argued that
because trade unions commanded the loyalty of thousands of workers, they had the potential to
be valuable allies for governments, especially when these sought to pass controversial policies
that might imply short-term costs in exchange for uncertain future long-term benefits (see also
Regini, 1981). He referred to the ensuing entente between trade unions and governments as
“political exchange,” an exchange in which the unions delivered consensus and were, in turn,
repaid with access to the policy-making sphere and with the political/institutional resources that
flowed from there. Pizzorno considered this type of arrangement as inherently unstable. The
unions’ choice to enter the policy-making sphere led them to violate the representational
mandate of at least a portion of their constituency. This created a representation gap, which, in
turn, spurred a grass-root mobilization and the collapse of political exchange institutions.
While the evidence presented here agrees with the basic thrust of this argument, it also
suggests that concertation is not a general feature of all governments, independent of
circumstances, but a peculiarity of electorally weak governments facing weakened unions.
Concertation allows them to activate a non-parliamentary channel of consensus mobilization, In
other words, sharing policy-making responsibility with the organizations representing those that
are most likely to bear the brunt of policy changes, namely workers, protects weak governments
from popular discontent they may be unable to handle otherwise. 19 Incidentally, in contrast to
21
Pizzorno’s argument, we find no evidence that concertative institutions are necessarily doomed
to failure due to representation crises. Indeed, in Ireland social partnership has so far lasted for
twenty years, and there are no signs that it may come to an end soon.
From our analysis it also emerges that the combination of partnership and learning may
lead to a change in policy regime. The Austrian and British were conservative governments and,
in both cases, had come to the conclusion, based on past experience, that policy concertation had
caused or compounded existing problems and needed to be disposed of. These two elements
have to be considered in combination because both the Tory party in Britain and the People’s
Party in Austria had, in the past, displayed completely different, and positive, attitudes towards
policy concertation. The cases of adoption of concertation are, unlike the cases of demise, less
clear cut. In Ireland, the government that engaged in concertation (Fianna Fail) and the one that
preceded it and kept unions at arm’s lengths (a Fine Gael-Labor Party coalition) were probably
equivalent in terms of represented interests (Mair 1992: 408). However, Ireland may be an
outlier, also due to the difficulty of classifying the party system of this country along a left-right
axis. Some corroboration for the partnership plus learning hypothesis comes from the Italian
case, where governments that included socialist members did not attempt to concert policy
solutions in the early 1990s, but did so later, when it became clear (especially after the
Berlusconi government’s failure to pass pension reform) that a unilateral approach would be
politically impractical. In other words, it seems that the element of partnership alone cannot
explain the policy shift. It needs to be combined with a learning element, namely with the
recognition that the past policy regime has been a failure.
Concluding Remarks: Policy Concertation as a Political Phenomenon
22
This paper has sought to understand the European governments’ decisions to engage in
policy concertation with unions and employers. To address this question, it has used both a
large-N and small-n research strategy. The large-N results suggest there is no downward trend of
government willingness to share policy prerogatives with the social partners. Between 1974 and
2003, the number of European governments that were willing to engage in at least one policy
area between wage and welfare policy oscillated around a constant mean of 12 out of 15
countries. Additionally, there was a greater tendency over time to deal concertatively with both
policy areas simultaneously.
Government approach to concerted wage policies shows a strongly cyclical pattern, while
the trend in welfare policies is markedly positive. The effects of EMU on government
willingness to engage in policy negotiations seem less remarkable than is generally argued. The
strongest impact is on the welfare policy domain, where the run-up to EMU seems to have
provided further incentives for participating countries to engage in negotiations with the social
partners. This conclusion needs to be qualified, however, because the overall 1974-2003 trend
for government willingness to engage in concertative welfare policies is growing. Thus, the
impact of EMU can at best be considered an accelerating element within a general growing
trend.
To understand the specific factors shaping government choice in favor or against policy
concertation, the paper has then moved to a small-n study in which the measures of government
willingness have been used to identify four extreme cases of policy change in both directions:
Ireland, Britain, Italy, and Austria. The analysis of these four cases has aimed at contributing to
a theory of government choice by identifying particular combinations of factors that could
explain the adoption or the demise of concertation by national governments.
23
The results of this analysis suggest that the emergence of policy concertation can be
likened to the building of an alliance between the “weak” and the “weakened.” Governments are
willing to share their policy-making prerogatives with the social actors when they are politically
weak, either because they lack strong and united parliamentary majorities, or because they are
otherwise marred by internal struggles and legitimacy crises. In these circumstances associating
trade unions to policy formation can be expedient for governments, as it allows them to activate
supplementary channels of consensus mobilization. In particular, governments are willing to
bring the trade unions on board when these still pose a credible threat for the smooth
implementation of policy but their organizational fortunes have been declining in recent times,
thus moderating their bargaining policies.
Strong governments facing either unions that are too weak, so that the government does
not fear their opposition, or that are too strong, so that they are able to deadlock any negotiation
until their objectives are met, prefer a more unilateral approach to policy-making. In particular,
strong governments are likely to change the policy regime, from concertative to unilateral and
vice-versa, when their partisan orientation combines with a negative assessment of previous
experiences. In other words, governments might move decisively away from concertation when
they are of conservative orientation and when they have reached the conclusion that a system of
policy codetermination has been a failure and has aggravated the problems it was intended to
address. Conversely, centre-left governments might decide to adopt concertative approaches
when unilateral policy-making has proved to trigger formidable social opposition.
It should be emphasized that these are working hypotheses that have been inductively
drawn from a structured comparison of the most dramatic cases of change in policy regime by
governments. Not only do they need to be tested against cross-country evidence, but, even at a
24
purely theoretical level, they need to be refined and made more nuanced. For example, the
argument that governments may be willing to engage in participatory policy-making when they
are electorally weak seems acceptable only as a first pass. Clearly, not just minority
governments may be interested in policy concertation, but also more electorally stable
governments, when the opposition is well poised to benefit from unpopular policy choices
(Kitschelt, 2001). Also, while the case study evidence suggests that there may be elective
affinities, mediated by learning processes, between partisanship and particular modes of policymaking (concertative vs. unilateral), the conditions under which partisanship shapes the
government’s choice of concertation vs. unilateralism do not seem entirely clear. 20
Even at this stage, however, one firm conclusion can be drawn from our study: policy
concertation is an eminently political phenomenon that needs to be framed against the backdrop
of the strategic configuration of the political system. Until now, most literature has relied on
structural explanations, and has shown a tendency to read off presence or absence of concertation
from structural grids of institutional and organizational preconditions. Yet, as witnessed by the
case studies analyzed above, all cases of transition from one policy mode to another, concertation
is not a stable characteristic of countries, but is more appropriately conceptualized as a set of
possibilities that governments activate in some configurations of circumstances (potentially
multiple, but not infinite), then drop, then perhaps reactivate again. Understanding exactly what
these configurations might be is the task of future research, including our own.
25
References
Berger, S. and Joint Committee on Western Europe. (1981). Organizing interests in Western
Europe : pluralism, corporatism, and the transformation of politics. Cambridge [Eng.] ;
New York: Cambridge University Press.
Bonoli, G. (2001). Political Institutions, Veto Points, and the Process of Welfare State
Adaptation. In P. Pierson, The New Politics of the Welfare State.(238-264) Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Cazzola, G. (1995). Le nuove pensioni degli Italiani. Bologna: Il Mulino.
Compston, H. (1997). Union Power, Policy Making and Unemployment in Western Europe,
1972-1993. Comparative Political Studies 30(6): 732-751.
Compston, H. (2002). The Strange Persistance of Policy Concertation. In S. Berger and H.
Compston, Policy concertation and social partnership in Western Europe : lessons for
the 21st century.(1-16) New York, Oxford: Berghahn Books.
Crouch, C. (2000). The Snakes and Ladders of Twenty-First-Century Trade Unionism. Oxford
Review of Economic Policy 16(1): 70-83.
Culpepper, P. (2007). The Politics of Common Knowledge: Ideas and Institutional Change in
Wage Bargaining. Forthcoming in International Organization.
Dale, I., Ed. (2000). Conservative Party General Election Manifestos, 1900-1997. London and
New York: Routledge.
Ebbinghaus, B. and A. Hassel (2000). Striking deals: concertation in the reform of continental
European welfare states. Journal of European Public Policy 7(1): 44-62.
26
Ebbingghaus, B. and B. Kittel (2005). European Rigidity versus American Flexibility? The
Institutional Adaptability of Collective Bargaining. Work and Occupations 32(2): 163195.
Esping Andersen, G. and M. Regini, Eds. (2000). Why Deregulate Labour Markets?: Oxford
University Press.
Fallend, F. (2001). Austria. European Journal of Political Research (7-8): 238-253.
Ferrera, M. (1996). The Southern Model of Welfare in Social Europe. Journal of European
Social Policy 6(1): 17-33.
Ferrera, M. and E. Gualmini (1999). Salvati dall'Europa? Bologna: Il Mulino.
Garrett, G. (1998). Partisan Politics in the Global Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Golden, M., P. Lange, et al. (2002). Union Centralization among Advanced Industrial Societies.
Dataset available at /www.shelley.polisci.ucla.edu/data(Version dated July 28, 2004).
Goldthorpe, J. H., Ed. (1984). Order and Conflict in Contemporary Capitalism. Oxford:
Clarendon.
Gunnigle, P., G. McMahon, et al., Eds. (1999). Industrial Relatons In Ireland: Theory and
Practice. Dublin: Gill & Macmillan.
Habermas, J. (1989[1964]). The Structural Transformation of the Public Sphere. Cambridge,
Mass: MIT University Press.
Hall, P. A., Ed. (1989). The Political Power of Economic Ideas : Keynesianism across Nations.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Hall, P. A. and D. Soskice, Eds. (2001). Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations
of Comparative Advantage. New York: Oxford University Press.
27
Hancké, B. and M. Rhodes (2004). EMU and Labor Market Institutions in Europe. The Rise and
Fall of National Social Pacts. Work and Occupations 32(2): 196-228.
Hardiman, N. (1988). Pay, Politics, and Economic Performance in Ireland 1970-1987. Oxford:
Clarendon Press.
Hardiman, N. (1992). The State and Economic Interests: Ireland in Comparative Perspective. In
J. H. Goldthorpe and C. T. Whelan, The State and Economic Interests: Ireland in
Comparative Perspective Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Hassel, A. (2003). The Politics of Social Pacts. British Journal of Industrial Relations 41(4):
707-726.
Iversen, T. (1999). Constested Economic Institutions. The Politics of Macroeconomics and Wage
Bargaining in Advanced Democracies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Katzenstein, P. (1985). Small States in World Markets: Industrial Policy in Europe. Ithaca:
Cornell Univeristy Press.
Kenworthy, L. (2003). Quantitative Indicators of Corporatism. International Journal of
Sociology 33(3): 10-44.
King, G., R. O. Keohane, et al. (1994). Designing Social Inquiry : Scientific Inference in
Qualitative Research. Princeton, N.J: Princeton University Press.
Kitschelt, H. (2001). Partisan Competition and Welfare State Retrenchment: When Do
Politicians Choose Unpopular Policies? In P. Pierson, The New Politics of the Welfare
State.(265-302) Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Kittel, B. (2001). Deaustrification? The Policy-Area-Specific Evolution of Austrian Social
Partnership. West European Politics 23(1): 109-129.
28
Lehmbruch, G. (1979). Consociational Democracy, Class Conflict, and New Corporatism. In P.
C. Schmitter and G. Lehmbruch, Trends toward corporatist intermediation.(53-61)
London: Sage Publications.
Lehmbruch, G. and P. C. Schmitter, Eds. (1982). Patterns of Corporatist Policy-Making. Sage
modern politics series ; v.7. London: Sage.
Letwin, S. R. (1992). The Anatomy of Thatcherism. Glasgow: HarperCollins.
Lowi, T. (1979). The End of Liberalism: The Second Republic of the United States. New York:
WW Norton.
Mair, P. (1992). Explaining the Absence of Class Politics in Ireland. In J. H. Goldthorpe and C.
T. Whelan, The development of industrial society in Ireland : the third joint meeting of
the Royal Irish Academy and the British Academy.(383-410) Oxford: Published for the
British Academy by Oxford University Press.
Mares, I. (2003). The Politics of Social Risk: Business and Welfare State Development.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Mares, I. (2006). Taxation, Wage Bargaining, and Unemployment. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Marx, K. and F. Engels (1978). Manifesto of the Communist Party. In R. C. Tucker, The MarxEngels Reader New York and London: Norton & Company.
Mascini, M. (2000). Profitti e salari. Bologna: Il Mulino.
Mill, J. S. (1946). A System of Logic. New York: Harper &Brothers.
Molina, O. and M. Rhodes (2002). Corporatism: the Past, Present and Future Of a Concept.
Annual Review of Political Science 5: 305-331.
29
Murphy, T. and W. E. Roche, Eds. (1997). Irish Industrial Relations in Practice. Revised and
Expanded Edition. Dublin: Oak Tree Press.
Negrelli, S. (2000). Social Pacts in Italy and Europe: Similar Strategies and Structures;
Different Models and National Stories. In G. Fajertag and P. Pochet, Social Pacts in
Europe - New Dynamics.(85-113) Bruxelles: ETUI.
NESC (1986). A Strategy for Development. 1986-90. Dublin: National Economic and Social
Council.
OECD (2001). Statistical Compendium, OECD.
Peden, G. C. (1991). British Economic and Social Policy: Lloyd George to Margaret Thatcher.
Oxford: Philip Allan.
Pelling, H. (1987). A History of British Trade Unionism. London: MacMillan.
Pierson, P. (1996). The New Politics of the Welfare State. World Politics 48(2): 143-179.
Pizzorno, A. (1978). Political Exchange and Collective Identity in Industrial Conflict. In C.
Crouch and A. Pizzorno, eds. (1978), The Resurgence of Class Conflict in Western
Europe since 1968 London: Macmillan.
Poulantzas, N. (1973). Political Power and Social Classes. New York: Verso.
Powell, D. (1992). British Politics and the Labour Question, 1868-1990. New York: St. Martin's
Press.
Ragin, C. (1987). The Comparative Method: Moving Beyond Qualitative and Quantitative
Strategies. Berkley: University of California Press.
Regini, M. (1981). I dilemmi del sindacato. Bologna: Il Mulino.
Regonini, G. (1996). Partiti e pensioni: legami mancanti. Un gigante dai piedi d’argilla. . In P.
Isernia, Partiti, risorse e politiche nella crisi italiana.(73-139) Bologna: Il Mulino.
30
Rhodes, M. (2001). The Political Economy of Social Pacts: 'Competitive Corporatism' and
European Welfare Reform. In P. Pierson, The New Politics of the Welfare State.(165194) Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Scharpf, F. W. (1991). Crisis and choice in European social democracy. Ithaca, N.Y: Cornell
University Press.
Schludi, M. (2001). The Politics of Pensions in European Social Insurance Countries.
Discussion Paper 01/11, Köln, Max-Planck-Institut für Gesellschaftsforschung.
Schludi, M. (2003). The Reform of Bismarckian Pension Systems. A Comparison of Pension
Politics in Austria, France, Germany, Italy, and Sweden. PhD Thesis. Humboldt
University, Berlin.
Schmitter, P. (1974). Still the Century of Corporatism? Review of Politics 36: 85-131.
Schmitter, P. (1981). Interest Intermediation and Regime Governability in Contemporary
Western Europe and North America. In S. Berger, Organizing interests in Western
Europe : pluralism, corporatism, and the transformation of politics.(285-327) Cambridge
[Eng.] ; New York: Cambridge University Press.
Schmitter, P. (1983). Teoria della democrazia e pratica neo-corporativa. Stato e Mercato 9
(December).
Schmitter, P. C. and J. R. Grote (1997). The Corporatist Sisyphus: Past, Present and Future. EUI
Working Paper SPS. Florence: 22.
Schmitter, P. C. and G. Lehmbruch, Eds. (1979). Trends Toward Corporatist Intermediation.
Contemporary political sociology ; vol. 1. London: Sage Publications.
31
Streeck, W. (1993). The Rise and Decline of Neocorporatism. In L. Ulman, B. Eichengreen and
W. T. Dickens, Labor and an Integrated Europe Washington, D.C.: The Brookings
Institution.
Streeck, W. (2005). The Study of Interest Groups: Before "The Century" and After. Philippe C.
Schmitter's retirement from the European University Institute, Florence September 17-18.
Streeck, W. and L. Kenworthy (2004). Theories and Practices of Neo-Corporatism. In Janoski,
Alford, Hicks and Schwartz, A Handbook of Political Sociology Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Streeck, W. and P. Schmitter (1991). From National Corporatism to Transnational Pluralism.
Politics and Society 19: 133-164.
Swenson, P. A. (2002). Capitalists Against Markets: The Making of Labor Markets and Welfare
States in the United States and Sweden. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Tàlos, E. and B. Kittel (2002). Austria in the 1990s: The Routine of Social Partnership in
Question? In H. Compston, Policy Concertation and Social Partnership in Western
Europe Oxford: Berghahn Books.
Thelen, K. A. (2001). Varieties of Labor Politics in the Developed Democracies. In P. A. Hall
and D. Soskice, Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative
Advantage New York: Oxford University Press.
Thomsen, J. P. F. (1996). British Politics and Trade Unions in the 1980s: Governing Against
Pressure. Aldershot: Dartmouth.
Thorpe, A. (2001). A History of the British Labour Party. New York: Palgrave.
Tomandl, T. and K. Fuerboeck (1986). Social Partnership: The Austrian System of Industrial
Relations and Social Insurance. Ithaca, N.Y.: ILR Press.
32
Traxler, F. (2003). Bargaining (De)centralization, Macroeconomic Performance and Control
over the Employment Relationship. British Journal of Industrial Relations 41(1): 1-27.
Traxler, F., S. Blaschke, et al. (2001). National Labour Relations in Internationalized Markets.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Viebrok, E. (2003). Coping with Corporatism's Legitimation Deficit: Recent Attempts at
Reforming the Austrian Chamber System. Unpublished Manuscript, Geneva,
International Institute for Labour Studies.
Walsh, J. I. (2000). When Do Ideas Matter? Explaining the Successes and Failures of Thatcherite
Ideas. Comparative Political Studies 33(4): 483-516.
33
Figure 1 – Government Willingness To Engage in Concerted Policies
Three-years moving averages
Share of European Countries
.8
.7
.6
.5
a) Wage Policy
.4
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
Share of European Countries
.8
.7
.6
.5
.4
b) Welfare Policy
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
34
Figure 2 – Bundling of Policy Issues Over Time
Number of European Governments
Yearly values
15
10
5
0
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
Concertation willingness in both income and welfare policies
Concertation willingness in at least one policy area
35
Figure 3 – Government Willingness to Engage in Concerted Policies: EMU vs. non-EMU countries
Yearly values
Share of European Countries
.9
.8
.7
.6
.5
.4
.3
.2
.1
a) Wage Policy
0
1985
1990
1995
2000
2003
Share of European Countries
.9
.8
.7
.6
.5
.4
.3
.2
.1
b) Welfare Policy
0
1985
1990
1995
2000
2003
EMU Government Willingness
Non-EMU Government Willingness
36
1
In this paper, the expression “policy concertation” is used as defined by Compston (Compston 2002), namely as a
policy-making method whereby “employers and trade unions are involved in the making of decisions that are
ultimately the exclusive province of the state, in particular decisions on the contents of legislation, regulations and
administrative orders.” Policy concertation allows for the formal involvement of societal interests and is, in this
sense, different form a pluralist model in which groups exercise informal influence on the governmental sphere. This
definition is similar to the definition of corporatism as provided, for example, by Streeck and Kenworthy (2004: 11):
“Corporatist theory and practice blur the boundary between state and society as the state shares authority with
private interest associations, using the latter as agents of public policy by coordinating their behavior or delegating
public functions and decisions to them. In a corporatist context, private interest representation thus shades into
public governance.”
2
Our indicator shares some similarities with the Union Participation Index in Compston (1997), which is available
for 13 OECD countries between 1970 and 1992. The goal of that index was to measure union influence in economic
policy-making (except wage policy), ranging from no participation to narrow consultation to broad agreement
(Compston, 1997: 737). Our goal is different: we focus on government’s propensity towards concertation
independently of whether or not a concertation agreement materializes. This allows us to distinguish between the
intentions of governments from the intentions of the social partners. We have also designed and measured an
indicator of “social compacting” which captures weather or not, contingent on the government’s willingness to
engage in concertation, a negotiated policy agreement is actually reached, and the extent to which the social partners
underwrite it. We do not present it here because its reach is beyond the scope of this paper.
3
The 15 countries include the EU15 except Luxemburg and including Norway.
4
In the absence of information, we assume policy inertia. In other words, unless there is textual evidence that a
change occurs in the process, the variable keeps the same score as in the previous year.
5
Notice that this does not transpire from the graphs in Figure 1 as these plot three-year averages and not annual
data.
6
Notice, however, that we have no information on Spain, Finland, and Greece for that year.
7
We have also run a quick test of what we refer to as the “Katzenstein hypothesis” (1985), contending that greater
exposure to international trade makes a government more willing to look for negotiated solutions to commonly
37
perceived problems. Our results (not displayed for reasons of space) suggest, at best, scant empirical confirmation
for it.
8
Our data also show considerable within-country variation between concertation willingness and lack thereof, thus
providing support for an argument emphasizing the institutional flexibility of several European countries (see
Ebbinghaus and Kittel 2005).
9
Here and elsewhere union data are based on the OECD union membership database.
10
See EIRR 1994, 4
11
http://www.eiro.eurofound.eu.int/1997/11/feature/at9711144f.html; see also Schludi 2003: 186-190
12
http://www.eiro.eurofound.eu.int/2000/08/feature/at0008228f.html
13
http://www.eiro.eurofound.eu.int/2001/08/inbrief/at0108225n.html;
http://www.eiro.eurofound.eu.int/2002/01/feature/at0201206f.html
14
http://www.eiro.eurofound.eu.int/2003/01/feature/at0301203f.html
15
http://www.eiro.eurofound.eu.int/2004/01/feature/at0401203f.html
16
A more refined Marxist theory of the state recognizes its relative autonomy and its capacity to pursue policies that
may be in conflict which the immediate, short-term interests of the dominant class (Poulantzas, 1973)
17
For Austria we do not have sufficient information to pass a judgment.
18
This hypothesis is not testable in the case of Britain. Indeed, the shift to a monetarist regime – where inflation
becomes the main priority and it is controlled through strict regulation of money supply – emerged simultaneously
to the demise of policy concertation on wage policies.
19
In this regard, some of the recent literature on welfare state reform has proceeded on similar lines to classic
corporatist theory, emphasizing the importance for governments of mustering the necessary popular consensus both
through parliamentary and non-parliamentary means, but has at the same time made it very clear that only certain
governments, and not all, take a participatory approach (see, for example, Kitschelt 2001; Schludi, 2001; 2003;
Bonoli, 2001; Pierson, 1996).
20
See Omitted for a more elaborate theory of the decision of social democratic parties to engage with trade unions.
The theory is based on the intuition that, at a time of electoral realignment, concertation allows social democratic
parties to maintain strong links with organized working-class constituencies, while simultaneously pursuing policies
that appeal to a shifting median voter.
38
39