Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

Discover millions of ebooks, audiobooks, and so much more with a free trial

From $11.99/month after trial. Cancel anytime.

How the West Came to Rule: The Geopolitical Origins of Capitalism
How the West Came to Rule: The Geopolitical Origins of Capitalism
How the West Came to Rule: The Geopolitical Origins of Capitalism
Ebook816 pages12 hours

How the West Came to Rule: The Geopolitical Origins of Capitalism

Rating: 5 out of 5 stars

5/5

()

Read preview
  • Uneven & Combined Development

  • Capitalism

  • International Relations

  • Eurocentrism

  • Geopolitics

  • Historical Fiction

  • Power Struggle

  • Political Intrigue

  • Academic Discourse

  • War & Conquest

  • Epic Saga

  • Fish Out of Water

  • Forbidden Love

  • Coming of Age

  • Mentor

  • Transition to Capitalism

  • Geopolitical Competition

  • Imperialism

  • Global History

  • Capitalism's Origins

About this ebook

*Winner of International Studies Association (ISA)'s International Political Sociology Best Book Prize for 2017*

*Winner of British International Studies Association (BISA)'s International Political Economy Working Group Book Prize of 2016*

*Shortlisted for the ISA Book Prize*

Mainstream historical accounts of the development of capitalism describe a process which is fundamentally European - a system that was born in the mills and factories of England or under the guillotines of the French Revolution. In this groundbreaking book, a very different story is told.

How the West Came to Rule offers a interdisciplinary and international historical account of the origins of capitalism. It argues that contrary to the dominant wisdom, capitalism's origins should not be understood as a development confined to the geographically and culturally sealed borders of Europe, but the outcome of a wider array of global processes in which non-European societies played a decisive role.

Through an outline of the uneven histories of Mongolian expansion, New World discoveries, Ottoman-Habsburg rivalry, the development of the Asian colonies and bourgeois revolutions, Alexander Anievas and Kerem Nisancioglu provide an account of how these diverse events and processes came together to produce capitalism.

LanguageEnglish
PublisherPluto Press
Release dateJun 20, 2015
ISBN9781783713240
How the West Came to Rule: The Geopolitical Origins of Capitalism
Author

Alexander Anievas

Alexander Anievas is Assistant Professor of Political Science in the Department of Political Science at the University of Connecticut. He is the author of Capital, the State, and War 1914-1945 (University of Michigan Press, 2014), How the West Came to Rule (Pluto, 2015) and editor of Marxism and World Politics: Contesting Global Capitalism (Routledge, 2010).

Related to How the West Came to Rule

Related ebooks

Economics For You

View More

Related articles

Reviews for How the West Came to Rule

Rating: 4.75 out of 5 stars
5/5

4 ratings0 reviews

What did you think?

Tap to rate

Review must be at least 10 words

    Book preview

    How the West Came to Rule - Alexander Anievas

    HOW THE WEST CAME TO RULE

    How the West

    Came to Rule

    The Geopolitical Origins

    of Capitalism

    Alexander Anievas and

    Kerem Nişancıoğlu

    First published 2015 by Pluto Press

    345 Archway Road, London N6 5AA

    www.plutobooks.com

    Copyright © Alexander Anievas and Kerem Nişancıoğlu 2015

    The right of Alexander Anievas and Kerem Nişancıoğlu to be identified as the authors of this work has

    been asserted by them in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988.

    British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data

    A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library

    ISBN 978 0 7453 3521 6 Hardback

    ISBN 978 0 7453 3615 2 Paperback

    ISBN 978 1 7837 1323 3 PDF eBook

    ISBN 978 1 7837 1325 7 Kindle eBook

    ISBN 978 1 7837 1324 0 EPUB eBook

    This book is printed on paper suitable for recycling and made from fully managed and sustained forest sources. Logging, pulping and manufacturing processes are expected to conform to the environmental standards of the country of origin.

    10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1

    Typeset by Curran Publishing Services, Norwich, England

    Text design by Melanie Patrick

    Simultaneously printed by CPI Antony Rowe, Chippenham, UK

    and

    Edwards Bros in the United States of America

    Contents

    List of figures

    Acknowledgements

    Introduction

    The Problem of Eurocentrism

    Confronting the Problematic of Sociohistorical Difference

    What is Capitalism?

    What Is Geopolitics?

    1 The Transition Debate: Theories and Critique

    Introduction

    The ‘Commercialisation Model’ Revisited: World-Systems Analysis and the Transition to Capitalism

    The Making of the Modern World-System: The Wallerstein Thesis

    The Problem of Eurocentrism

    The Problem of Historical Specificity

    The Spatiotemporal Limits of Political Marxism

    The Brenner Thesis: Explanation and Critique

    The Geopolitical in the Making of Capitalism

    The Political Marxist Conception of Capitalism

    The Problematic of Sociohistorical Difference: Postcolonial Studies Engaging Capital

    The Eurocentrism of Historicism

    The Violence of Abstraction

    The Lacuna of Postcolonial Theory

    Conclusion

    2 Rethinking the Origins of Capitalism: The Theory of Uneven and Combined Development

    Introduction

    The Theory of Uneven and Combined Development: Exposition and Critiques

    Unevenness

    Combination

    Seeing Through a Prism Darkly? Uneven and Combined Development beyond the Eurocentric Gaze

    Trotsky beyond Trotsky? Uneven and Combined Development before Capitalism

    More Questions than Answers: Method, Abstraction and Historicity in Marx’s Thought

    Modes of Production Versus Uneven and Combined Development? A False Antithesis

    Conclusion: Towards an ‘Internationalist Historiography’ of Capitalism

    3 The Long Thirteenth Century: Structural Crisis, Conjunctural Catastrophe

    Introduction

    Pax Mongolica as a Vector of Uneven and Combined Development

    The Nomadic Mode of Production and Uneven and Combined Development

    The World-Historical Significance of the Mongol Empire

    Trade, Commerce, and Socio-Economic Development under the Pax Mongolica

    Apocalypse Then: The Black Death and the Crisis of Feudalism

    Class Struggle and the Changing Balance of Class Forces in Europe

    Peasant Differentiation in the Age of the Black Death

    Development of the Productive Forces

    Conclusion

    4 The Ottoman–Habsburg Rivalry over the Long Sixteenth Century

    Introduction

    Unevenness: A Clash of Social Reproduction

    Ottoman–European Relations

    The Tributary and Feudal Modes of Production: Unevenness Combined

    Ottoman ‘Penalties of Progressiveness’ – European ‘Privileges of Backwardness’

    Combination: Pax Ottomana and European Trade

    The Ottoman ‘Whip of External Necessity’

    The Breakdown of Christendom

    The Ottoman Blockade and the Emergence of the Atlantic

    The Ottoman Buffer and English Primitive Accumulation

    Conclusion: The Ottoman Empire as a Vector of Uneven and Combined Development

    5 The Atlantic Sources of European Capitalism, Territorial Sovereignty and the Modern Self

    Introduction

    Imagining Europe in the Atlantic Mirror: Rethinking the Territorialised Sovereign, Self and Other

    Tearing Down the Ideological Walls of Christendom: From Sacred to Secular Universalism in the Construction of the European Self and Non-European Other

    Legitimising Colonialism: The Historical Sociological Foundations of Eurocentrism

    Culture Wars in the Americas

    The Colonial Origins of the Modern Territorialised States System

    1492 in the History of Uneven and Combined Development

    The Smithian Moment: American Treasures and So-Called Primitive Accumulation

    Sublating the Smithian Moment: From Smith to Marx via ‘the International’

    Primitive Accumulation Proper: From ‘Simple’ to ‘Expanded’ Reproduction

    The Uneven and Combined Development of Plantation Slavery

    The Sociological Unevenness of the Atlantic

    Sociological Combination in the Plantation System

    New World Slavery and the Rise of Industrial Capitalism

    Contributions to the Sphere of Circulation

    Contributions to the Sphere of Production

    Conclusion: Colonies, Merchants and the Transition to Capitalism

    6 The ‘Classical’ Bourgeois Revolutions in the History of Uneven and Combined Development

    Introduction

    The Concept of Bourgeois Revolution

    Reconceptualising Bourgeois Revolutions: A Consequentialist Approach

    Reconstructing Consequentialism through Uneven and Combined Development

    The Origins of Capitalism and the Bourgeois Revolution in the Low Countries

    The Rise of Dutch Capitalism: An International Perspective

    The Making of the Dutch Revolt

    The English Revolution in the History of Uneven and Combined Development

    Rediscovering the English Revolution

    Social Forces in the Making of the British Revolution

    1789 in the History of Uneven and Combined Development

    Peculiarities of the French Revolution?

    Capitalism and the Absolutist State in France

    The Origins of the Capitalist Revolution in France

    Capitalist Consequences of the French Revolution

    Conclusion

    7 Combined Encounters: Dutch Colonisation in Southeast Asia and the Contradictions of ‘Free Labour’

    Introduction

    The Specificity and Limits of Dutch Capitalism

    Dutch Institutional Innovations

    The Limits of Dutch ‘Domestic’ Capitalism

    Unevenness and Combination in the Pre-Colonial Indian Ocean Littoral

    The Intersocietal System of the Indian Ocean

    South Asia beyond the Eurocentric Gaze

    The Dutch Encounter: A Policy of Combination

    The Specificities and ‘Success’ of Dutch Strategies of Integration and Domination in Southeast Asia

    The Moluccas

    The Banda Islands

    Indian Textiles

    Conclusion

    8 Origins of the Great Divergence over the Longue Durée: Rethinking the ‘Rise of the West’

    Introduction

    Rethinking the ‘Rise of the West’: Advances and Impasses in the Revisionist Challenge

    Points of Agreement: European ‘Backwardness’ and the Role of the Colonies

    Late and Lucky: Contingences, the Eurasian Homogeneity Thesis, and the Great Divergence

    Structure and Conjuncture in the ‘Rise of the West’

    The Geopolitical Competition Model and Its Limits

    Feudalism, Merchants, and the European States System in the Transition to Capitalism

    Unevenness Combined: North–South Interactions in the ‘Rise of the West’

    The Conjunctural Moment of ‘Overtaking’: Britain’s Colonisation of India

    The Significance of India’s Colonisation to the ‘Rise of the West’

    The Mughal Empire and the Tributary Mode of Production

    The Imperial Revenue System and Agricultural Decline in the Mughal Empire

    European Trade and Colonial Conquest: Towards 1757

    Conclusion

    Conclusion

    Notes

    Index

    Figures

    * please note that the maps are not precisely to scale.

    Acknowledgements

    This book has been almost three years in the making. Its origins lie in a collaborative article written for Millennium – Journal of International Studies in 2012–13 entitled ‘What’s at stake in the transition debate? Rethinking the origins of capitalism and the rise of the West’. It was here that we first explored the possibility of rewriting the history of capitalism’s genesis by drawing on the framework of uneven and combined development. As this led us to a radical departure from histories centred on European developments, it became evident that there was a considerably more extensive and complex story to tell about the origins of capitalism. Our initially brief engagement with the global history of the 13th–17th centuries rendered evident a palpable dissatisfaction with the Eurocentrism of dominant accounts of this period. It appeared not only that vast swathes of key historical events, actors and processes had been left hidden behind the veil of Eurocentrism, but that the theorisations constructed from this narrow geohistorical vantage point had left the field of historical sociology with only a partial understanding of capitalist modernity. Moreover, it appeared that our very engagement with the historical record would demand some reconsideration of the theoretical conclusions we drew back in 2013. We were thus driven back to the drawing board – back to history, back to theory and into an enormously stimulating collaborative project of research, debate and writing. How the West Came to Rule is the result.

    We see this book as an outcome of a collective endeavour in three respects. First, although much of the research and drafting process for the book was done individually, the end product was built on constant dialogue and various moments of creative agreement and disagreement. Indeed, the chapters we are most proud of are those where our collaboration – in terms of research, discussion and drafting – were most intensive.

    Second, this book covers a roughly 600-year time span, and stretches geographically from Indonesia, along the Indian Ocean littoral, through the Middle East to Europe, West Africa, and across the Atlantic to the Americas. Such is the sweeping nature of the project that we have, out of necessity, deferred to and critically engaged with specialists in numerous areas of expertise beyond our own. We have also, out of necessity, selected and bracketed certain historical events, actors and processes from our narrative – gaps that we hope will be the source of further scholarship and critique for future researchers to follow up. As such, we appreciatively recognise that this book would not have been possible were it not for the extensive and important work carried out by the scholars we draw on. We hope that in writing this book, we will have done justice to these specialists, and hope to have made a humble yet critical contribution to the fields they work in.

    Third, we are indebted to the wider network of personal, moral and scholarly support that has undergirded this entire project. We are grateful to the many colleagues and scholars who provided helpful comments on or discussed particular aspects of earlier chapter drafts, including Jamie Allinson, Josef Ansorge, Tarak Barkawi, Duncan Bell, Gurminder Bhambra, Pepijn Brandon, Gareth Dale, Neil Davidson, Kyle Geraghty, Henry Heller, John Hobson, Joseph Kay, Rob Knox, Tor Krever, Nivi Manchanda, David Ormrod, Charlie Post, Gonzalo Pozo-Martin, Justin Rosenberg, Andrés Sáenz de Sicilia and Ben Selwyn. Special gratitude is owed to Luke Cooper, Kamran Matin and Cemal Burak Tansel who were all kind enough to read over multiple drafts of chapters. We’d also like to thank David Castle at Pluto Press for his continuing enthusiasm for the project and patience in waiting for its completion. We are also grateful to Susan Curran who did a fantastic job with the copy-editing.

    Kerem would like to thank his parents, Şule and Murat, and brother Deniz for their unflinching and unconditional love and support. Kerem is especially grateful to Hollie Hutton – without her encouragement and compassion this project would have never been started, let alone completed. Alex would like to thank his family (Arturo, Pam, Erik, Cathy, and Uncle Ralph), and friends, particularly Luke, Vin, Andy, Dominic, Craig, and the dearly missed Matt Gibney and Lisa Smirl – to the latter of whom this book is dedicated. He would also like to thank his wife, Linda Szilas, who not only gave a fair amount of her own time in designing the map illustrations in this book, but also provided her wholehearted and unwavering love and support throughout the writing and researching of this project. Finally, Alex would like to acknowledge the generous funding and support provided by the Leverhulme Trust.

    In addition to the above-noted Millennium article from which this project originated, we published two further articles based upon the research for this book: ‘The Ottoman origins of capitalism: uneven and combined development and Eurocentrism’, Review of International Studies, Vol. 40, No. 2 (2014): 325–47; and, ‘Revolutions and international relations: rediscovering the classical bourgeois revolutions’, European Journal of International Relations, forthcoming. Some of the materials originally published in these articles are reproduced in the following pages, and we are grateful to the journal publishers for their permission to use those materials.

    Alexander Anievas

    Kerem Nişancıoğlu

    April 2015

    Dedicated to the loving memory of Lisa Smirl

    Introduction

    History is the Nightmare from which I am trying to awake.

    James Joyce, 1922¹

    The writing of historical sociologies is inescapably wedded to the contexts in which they emerge; we write history but do not do so in conditions of our choosing. For decades, these conditions have been marked by ‘End of History’ triumphalism and claims that ‘there is no alternative’ to liberal capitalism. In turn, capitalism as a transient, historically specific and contradictory unit of study has been bracketed out of – if not completely wiped off – the scholarly and political agenda. Yet, after stock markets came crashing down in 2008, the force of history reasserted itself in a series of revolutions, occupations of public places, anti-austerity protests, strikes, riots and anti-state movements taking place from London to Ferguson (Missouri), Athens, Cairo, Istanbul, Rojava, Santiago and beyond. Such movements have torn at the hubristic certainties of ‘capitalist realism’ and started to sporadically – if inconsistently – challenge such long-held ‘common sense’ truisms and the power structures that undergird them.

    Consequently, capitalism and critiques of it have reentered the public discourse in ways previously unimaginable. From mainstream media outlets to traditional academic publishing media, the tide has seemingly turned against the concept’s long banishment to the margins of radical Left critique and returned as a ‘respectable’ object of analysis. Indeed, a number of the most celebrated publications of recent years have in different ways oriented themselves around reinvestigating and understanding (both theoretically and historically) the meaning of capitalism, be they social democratic, Marxist, Keynesian or neoconservative.² In universities across the world, students and scholars are now collaborating in ways that seek to challenge ruling class orthodoxies.³ As a recent New York Times article put it, ‘A specter is haunting university history departments: the specter of capitalism’.⁴

    This renewed attention to the study of capitalism is a welcome development, particularly as capitalism’s return to the limelight as the dramatis persona of modern history has come fit with a certain renaissance in Karl Marx’s critique of it. ‘Marx is Back’, lamented the Economist,⁵ and with it so too are an array of novel avenues for renewed Marxist-inspired understandings and critiques of capitalism, and particularly its formation as a historical mode of production. Why was capitalism successful in supplanting other modes of production? What propelled it to global dominance? And finally, what are its historical limits?

    This book cannot hope to offer complete answers to all of these questions. Rather, our aim is to provide new theoretical and historical perspectives in which these questions can be re-examined and answered anew, hopefully better than previous attempts. Simply stated, we argue that the origins and history of capitalism can only be properly understood in international or geopolitical terms, and that this very ‘internationality’ is constitutive of capitalism as a historical mode of production. Although this may seem intuitively obvious to many readers, in what follows we show that existing conceptions of capitalism have hitherto failed to take this internationality seriously. This has led to problematic theorisations of its origins and development that limit not only our histories, but also our critiques of the present.

    This distinctly geopolitical character of the origins of capitalism is brilliantly anticipated in German Renaissance painter Hans Holbein’s 1532 masterpiece The Ambassadors (Figure 0.1), which illustrates a meeting between French envoys Jean de Dinteville and George de Selve in London. The painting astounds because these two aristocratic subjects are placed at the periphery, and the only explicitly religious symbol, a cross, is veiled by a curtain. While these two pillars of medieval power – the church and aristocracy – are symbolically pushed to the side, an anamorphic skull and a table littered with objects – with commodities – occupy the focal point of the painting. Was this a prophetic, if unwitting, forecast of feudalism’s imminent decline? Did it anticipate a capitalist future where social relations would come to be ‘mediated by things’?⁶

    Notwithstanding such speculation, these objects constitute a vivid record of the geopolitical milieu that defined European⁷ international relations in the early 16th century.⁸ The morbidity portrayed by the skull reminds us that death was at the forefront of European consciousness in this period – indeed, Holbein’s own life would be taken by plague in the autumn of 1543 in England just ten years after the painting was completed.⁹ In the immediate time of the painting, peasant revolts were sweeping through Christendom, leaving the ashes of serfdom in their wake. In preceding centuries, Europe had been ravaged by disease, precipitating a demographic crisis that had reduced Europe’s population by between 30 and 60 per cent by the 15th century.

    On the bottom right-hand side of the table in the painting, a book of Lutheran hymns sits by a broken lute, signifying the discord in Christendom between Protestants and the Catholic Church. To the left of these items rests Martin Benhaim’s terrestrial globe, made under the commission of Nuremberg merchants seeking to break the Portuguese hold on the spice trade. The globe is tilted so that after European towns, ‘Affrica’ and ‘Brisilici R’. (Brazil) are the most legible markers. We can also see the Linea Divisionis Castellanorum et Portugallenum (‘Line of division between Spain and Portugal’) demarcating the division of the New World between Habsburg Spain (west of the line) and Portugal (east of the line), here signifying the importance of these discoveries and the subsequent competition between European states over commercially profitable territories.

    Figure 0.1 Hans Holbein, The Ambassadors, 1533

    In front of the globe is Peter Apian’s A New and Well Grounded Instruction in All Merchant’s Arithmetic, an early textbook of commercial scholarship that covered profit–loss calculation, trading customs, navigation and route mapping. Placed alongside Benhaim’s globe, it demonstrates the inseparability of commercial interests from maritime exploration, as well as the increasingly global – and competitive – character of trade. Above these items, on the top of the table, numerous scientific instruments highlight the rapid development of techniques in seafaring. Continuing the theme of Christendom’s decline, these also indicate a mounting shift away from the divinity of religion as the predominant episteme and towards the rationality of scientific inquiry and humanism. Finally, linking the resting arms of the two ambassadors, and tying the objects together, is a Turkic rug, indicating the rivalry between the Ottoman and Habsburg empires. The presence of this ‘Eastern’ commodity indicates that the numerous changes taking place in Europe in this period were often undergirded by processes emanating from non-European sources, by social formations and actors that were unambiguously more powerful than anything seen in Europe at the time.

    Let us run through these themes once more: a demographic crisis brought about by the Black Death; the Ottoman–Habsburg rivalry; the discovery of the New World and its division along linearly demarcated spaces of sovereignty; the festering atmosphere of revolt and rebellion; the economic significance of colonisation. Each in their own way either captures or anticipates the central dynamics and historical processes behind the collapse of feudalism and the emergence of capitalist modernity. Moreover, running throughout the themes of the painting is a resolute awareness of the geopolitics behind these processes. The emphasis on the New World and the Ottoman Empire reminds us that the making of capitalism in Europe was not simply an intra-European phenomenon, but a decidedly international (or intersocietal) one: one in which non-European agency relentlessly impinged upon and (re)directed the trajectory and nature of European development. Tracing this international dimension in the origins of capitalism and the so-called ‘rise of the West’ is what concerns us in this book.

    Our primary motivation in making this argument is to subvert, and we hope displace, the dominant wisdom in the historiography and theoretical analyses of the period. For despite the latent centrality of ‘the international’ implied by Holbein’s painting, dominant theorisations of early modern Europe have been constructed with non-European societies in absentia. Whether in the sphere of politics, economy, culture or ideology, the emergence of capitalist modernity is generally understood as a sui generis development unique to Europe. Where non-European societies do figure, they are typically relegated to the status of a passive bystander, at the receiving end of Europe’s colonial whip, or a comparative foil – an Other – against which the specificity and superiority of Europe is defined. In short, the history of capitalism’s origins is an unmistakably Eurocentric history.

    The Problem of Eurocentrism

    So what exactly is Eurocentrism? At its core, it represents a distinctive mode of inquiry constituted by three interrelated assumptions about the form and nature of modern development.¹⁰ First, it conceives of the origins and sources of capitalist modernity as a product of developments primarily internal to Europe. Based on the assumption that any given trajectory of development is the product of a society’s own immanent dynamics, Eurocentrism locates the emergence of modernity exclusively within the hermetically sealed and socioculturally coherent geographical confines of Europe. Thus we find in cultural history that the flowering of the Renaissance was a solely intra-European phenomenon.¹¹ Analyses of absolutism and the origins of the modern state form are similarly conducted entirely on the terrain of Europe, with non-European cases appearing (if at all) comparatively.¹² Dominant accounts of the rise of capitalism as either an economic form¹³ or a social system¹⁴ similarly place its origins squarely in Western Europe, while non-Europe is relegated to an exploited and passive periphery.¹⁵

    This internalist story of an autonomous and endogenous ‘rise of the West’ constitutes the founding myth of Eurocentrism.¹⁶ By positing a strong ‘inside-out’ model of social causality (or methodological internalism) – whereby European development is conceptualised as endogenous and self-propelling – Europe is conceived as the permanent ‘core’ and ‘prime mover’ of history. In its worst forms, this can lend itself to an interpretation of European society and culture as somehow superior to the rest of the world. This second normative assumption of Eurocentrism can be termed historical priority, which articulates the historical distinction between tradition and modernity through a spatial separation of ‘West’ and ‘East’. Through this method, non-European societies have been opposed to Europe as an ideological Other against which the specificity and distinctiveness of Western modernity has been and continues to be defined.¹⁷ Through numerous sociological trends, the ‘East’ has in turn been (re)constructed as an intransigent and threatening foe representing a fundamental and irreconcilable challenge to the values of the ‘West’.¹⁸

    In establishing this ‘Iron Curtain’¹⁹ of mutual obstinacy, both Eurocentric internalism and notions of historical priority have been reinforced, not only ideologically but also materially. Expressed through either the comparative approach²⁰ or ‘methodological nationalism’,²¹ Eurocentrism tends to overlook the multiple and interactive character of social development. In doing so, it sets up an epistemological distinction between Europe and ‘the Rest’ as theoretically incommensurable objects of study, turning the study of the origins of capitalism into an exclusionary process in which the agency of non-European societies is erased or overlooked.

    From these two assumptions emerges a third predictive proposition: that the European experience of modernity is a universal stage of development through which all societies must pass. This stadial assumption posits a linear developmentalism in which endogenous processes of social change – from tradition to modernity, feudalism to capitalism and so on – are conceived as universal stages which encompass all societies of the world, at different times and different places. These three propositions (methodological internalism, historical priority and linear developmentalism) make up the core of Eurocentric accounts.

    Confronting the Problematic of Sociohistorical Difference

    How the West Came to Rule challenges these assumptions by examining the ‘extra-European’ geopolitical conditions and forms of agency conducive to capitalism’s emergence as a distinctive mode of production over the longue durée. We do so by tracing the processes of societal transformation through an analysis of the various internationally determined historical dynamics, structures and agencies that emerged and unfolded over the late Medieval and early modern epochs. In this respect, we hope to contribute to what has proven in recent years to be a veritable historiographical revolution in the study of the early modern epoch. This has come from a disparate group of scholars challenging what they see as the fundamentally Eurocentric nature of extant theoretical and historical approaches to the genesis of capitalist modernity.²² Debates over the origins of capitalism have subsequently taken on new dimensions as scholars have forcefully problematised notions of a self-propelling ‘rise of the West’ while relativising the uniqueness of Western modernity.²³ Once sidelined to the margins of historical and sociological investigation, the non-European sources, dynamics and experiences of capitalist modernity have thus been at the forefront of these literatures, acting as a much needed corrective to the essentialising, self-aggrandising narratives of an internally generated ‘European miracle’.

    Perhaps the most significant contribution of this body of literature has been the resolute focus on the relations of interconnection and co-constitution between ‘the West’ and ‘the Rest’ in their joint, if uneven, making of the modern world. This attention to ‘the international’ as a thick space of social interaction and mutual constitution should put International Relations (IR) scholars in a unique position to make important contributions to these debates. Yet thus far, post-colonial and world history critiques²⁴ have made little impact on the mainstream of the discipline, even after the historical sociological ‘turn’ in IR.²⁵ Instead, historical sociological approaches to IR have been criticised for reproducing Eurocentric assumptions, as they predominately conduct their analysis on the basis of European history.²⁶ Many of the foundational engagements with history in IR have been – and continue to be – primarily carried out on the terrain of European history and intra-European dynamics.²⁷ Where they do exist, substantive engagements with non-European societies tend to emphasise the ‘Iron Curtain’ of ideological-cultural difference.²⁸

    Calls for a genuinely ‘international historical sociology’²⁹ have thus remained locked within this Eurocentric cage, as they have yet to fully provincialise Europe, treating it instead as the privileged locale and organic birthplace of capitalist modernity (see Chapter 1). To change this perspective is the central aim of How the West Came to Rule. Widening the spatial optic of capitalism’s emergence beyond Europe over the longue durée, we offer a fundamental rethinking of the origins of capitalism and the emergence of Western domination that puts non-Western sources (both structural and agential) at the forefront of analysis. In doing so, we elucidate the manifold ways that ‘the West’ itself, as both an ideo-political and a socioeconomic entity, was only formed in and through its interactive relations with the extra-European world. These international dimensions are explored in the substantive historical chapters (Chapters 3 to 8). In each, we shift or decentre the sites of analysis on which most theoretical attention to the origins of capitalism and the ‘rise of the West’ has focused. Some of these sites are relatively unfamiliar or overlooked in the existing debates, as exemplified by the Mongolian and Ottoman Empires’ ‘contributions’ to the development of capitalism (see Chapters 3 and 4 respectively). However, we also revisit more familiar sites common to contemporary debates – for example, the role of the American ‘discoveries’ in the making of global capitalism (Chapter 5), the ‘classical’ bourgeois revolutions in European history (Chapter 6), and the colonisation of Asia (Chapter 7 and 8) – precisely in order to make them unfamiliar through a more ‘international’, non-Eurocentric framework.

    In so doing, we also seek to go beyond extant contributions in world history and postcolonial literatures. That is, How the West Came to Rule does not aim simply to add new, non-European perspectives that might expand the empirical scope of the study of capitalism’s origins. Rather, it offers an alternative framework through which our theorisation of capitalism might be significantly revised. We do so by drawing on and further refining Leon Trotsky’s theory of uneven and combined development which, we argue, uniquely incorporates a distinctly international dimension of causality into its very conception of development (see Chapter 2).³⁰

    The debate on the transition to capitalism is a particularly apposite body of literature for assessing uneven and combined development’s efficacy in theorising social change as positions within it well demonstrate the very methodological problems the theory seeks to overcome: specifically, the hardened division between ‘internalist’ and ‘externalist’ modes of explanation. In particular, the debates within (neo-)Marxist approaches have largely split between these two ‘internalist’ and ‘externalist’ poles. On the one side, scholars such as Maurice Dobb,³¹ Robert Brenner³² and Ellen Meiksins Wood³³ locate the generative sources of capitalist social relations in the internal contradictions of feudal European societies, and particularly England. On the other, Paul Sweezy³⁴ and Immanuel Wallerstein³⁵ view capitalism as having developed from the growth of markets, commerce and trade in Europe over the Long Sixteenth Century (1450–1650). The main issue between these different positions revolves around whether the intensification of exchange relations (trade) or class conflict was the prime mover in the transition to capitalism. More recently, anti-Eurocentric scholars have broadened the debate in considering the emergence of antecedent forms of capitalism (or ‘proto-capitalism’) in the non-West, while further emphasising the contingent, or accidental, factors explaining the rise of a globally dominant Western European capitalism.³⁶ Yet, for the most part, the anti-Eurocentrics have moved within the main methodological parameters set out by the original debate, accepting an essentially externalist explanation of the genesis of capitalism. By highlighting the spread of commerce and markets as the prime movers, they equate ‘antediluvian forms’ of capital³⁷ with capitalism.³⁸

    What is Capitalism?

    The stark disagreements over precisely what factors were central in the making of capitalism beg the question: what is capitalism? In some respects this is a trick question, in that it conceals from view more than it opens to enquiry, since the content of capitalism is of a complexity that resists any single-line definition. Treating capitalism as ‘generalized commodity production’³⁹ or ‘competitive accumulation of capital through the exploitation of wage-labour’⁴⁰ or ‘market dependence’⁴¹ captures, in some respects, a ‘hard core’ around which it functions. However, the argument we advance in this book is that there is a wider complex web of social relations that stretch our understanding of capitalism far beyond what is captured in any of these phrases. We explicate further what these social relations are over the course of the book, progressively introducing more determinations and categories that we consider crucial to the origins and reproduction of capitalism. For the time being, then, we restrict ourselves to identifying a basic heuristic framework through which we may theorise capitalism.

    To say what capitalism ‘is’ runs the risk of reducing capitalism to a thing, which tends to obscure the multivalent connections in society that facilitate, structure and ultimately limit its reproduction. More specifically, it carries the implication that any given social factor contains an essence that is logically independent of other factors to which it is related. Capital ‘as a thing’ is often understood simply as ‘profit’, or an accumulated pool of money, or perhaps machinery, whose existence is independent of wider social relations. Treating capital solely as a ‘thing’ therefore tends to naturalise and eternalise capitalism.

    In contrast, we follow Marx in conceiving capitalism as encompassing historically specific configurations of social relations and processes. Such a relational-processual approach helps us move away from ‘abstract one-sided’ self-representations of capitalism and toward uncovering the ‘concrete living aggregate’ of ‘definite social relationships’.⁴² For example, Marx’s observation that some categories (such as capital) necessarily presuppose others (such as wage-labour) allowed him to uncover, analyse and criticise an array of structural conditions of exploitation and power that reproduce the capitalist mode of production. This reminds us that just as social relations are historically specific and constructed, they can be transformed, abolished and reconstructed. Similarly, the emphasis on process further begs a historicisation of the development of capitalism not as a fixed entity, but as one that morphs and reconfigures social relations according to certain historical problems, challenges, struggles, contradictions, limits and opportunities.

    We hope this emphasis on process will assist us in moving away from any sociological or political position that posits a certain phase (or place) in capitalism’s history or geography as ‘pure’, ‘ideal-typical’, ‘unchanging’ or its ‘highest stage’. From such a perspective, we seek to subvert any attempts to read the history of capitalism as a linear progression of clearly discernible stages. Finally, ‘process’ should help us capture one of the defining characteristics of capital as social relation, the necessity of its movement and motion – in production, circulation and realisation.

    In both senses, then – as social relations and as process – it might appear to make more sense to talk about capitalisms rather than capitalism. Indeed, a central thesis of this book is that the history of capitalism is a multiple, polyvalent one, irreducible to any singular process or social relation. Nonetheless, we argue that there is a certain unity to its functioning that renders necessary the study of the capitalist mode of production as an intelligible (albeit contradictory) object of analysis.

    Treating capitalism in such terms – as a contradictory social totality – helps us trace the ways in which multiple relations of domination, subordination and exploitation intersect with and reproduce each other. From this perspective, we argue that capitalism is best understood as a set of configurations, assemblages, or bundles of social relations and processes oriented around the systematic reproduction of the capital relation, but not reducible – either historically or logically – to that relation alone. By placing an emphasis on such configurations and assemblages, we also seek to highlight how the reproduction and competitive accumulation of capital through the exploitation of wage-labour presupposes a wide assortment of differentiated social relations that make this reproduction and accumulation possible. These relations may take numerous forms, such as coercive state apparatuses, ideologies and cultures of consent, or forms of power and exploitation that are not immediately given in or derivative of the simple capital–wage-labour relation, such as racism and patriarchy.

    To take one example, one of the great achievements of feminist scholarship has been to show how the existence of wage-labour presupposes a vast ‘reproductive sphere’ that sits outside (albeit related to) the immediate production process. Here, non-waged forms of production – cooking, house-keeping, child-bearing and so on – are fundamental to the reproduction of wage-labour, and capitalism as such. As we demonstrate throughout the book, such relations (and others) were absolutely crucial to both making the accumulation and reproduction of capital possible, and producing forms of subordination, exploitation and social stratification that were at the heart of alienating workers from their labour and from each other. We argue that an analysis of the making of capitalism should thus be one that seeks to disclose ever more complex webs, assemblages and bundles of social relations that feed into the origins and reproduction of capitalism as a mode of production.

    In this book we argue that uneven and combined development provides a way into disclosing and analysing the historical emergence and development of such assemblages, which were and still are constitutive of capitalism. By constitutive, we mean historically constitutive: that is, those historical processes that fed into the emergence and development of capitalism. But we also use ‘constitutive’ to designate those relations and processes that continued to function (albeit in different forms) over the course of subsequent centuries, and persist today: that is, social relations that capitalism cannot do without. As we shall argue, what we consider ‘constitutive’ is considerably broader than many existing theorisations of capitalism. We argue that this necessitates a broader historical and geographical scope for the proper study of the origins of capitalism, and a theoretical framework capable of making this wider scope intelligible.

    Nonetheless, it must be stressed that what follows is not intended to be a ‘total’ account of the origins of capitalism and the ‘rise of the West’. Indeed, our historical account cannot help but be partial, emphasising certain processes and leaving out others. Similarly, we must recognise that this is not a total history but one that privileges those processes that were central to the making of capitalism in Europe. This carries within itself its own dangers of Eurocentrism, in that non-European societies are studied only insofar as they are relevant to European development. We acknowledge the potential concerns that arise from this, but insist that something unique did happen in Europe that propelled it to global dominance at the expense of non-European societies. Uncovering the histories of subjugation and exploitation that lay behind this ‘rise’ is therefore crucial to critiquing the mythologising of European (or Western) exceptionalism. Taking Europe as an object of study in the telling of this history is both essential and unavoidable. Yet, insofar as gaps exist, we hope that the framework we offer nonetheless provides scope and avenues for future research, and the incorporation of further historical processes that may complement our analysis. In this respect, we seek to provide a more inclusive account of the origins of capitalism that highlights hitherto significantly neglected aspects of the story: particularly, regarding the role of ‘the international’, ‘intersocietal’ and ‘geopolitics’. Of course, this then begs the question: what are ‘the international’ and ‘geopolitics’?

    What Is Geopolitics?

    Most broadly defined, geopolitics and ‘the geopolitical’ can be conceived as encompassing both: first, the variegated processes and practices of communities, societies and states occupying, controlling, socialising, organising, protecting, and competing over territorial spaces and their inhabitant peoples and resources; and second, the multivalent forms of knowledge, discourses, representations, ideologies and strategies, along with the articulations, modes and relations of power generated from such processes. From this perspective, we may then examine how the (re)production, structuring and organisation of space and the construction of human ‘territoriality’ itself are inherently social processes rooted in, conditioned by, and articulated through historically specific and changing power relations. This allows for the conceptualisation of territorial spaces and the exchanges that take place within, across and between them as pivotal sites of social contestation, change and transformation.⁴³

    Under capitalism, for example, specific forms of territoriality and other socially constructed spaces are being persistently constituted and reconstituted, borders continually drawn and redrawn, human geographies constantly fashioned and refashioned in and through the uneven development, production, accumulation and circulation of capital across time and space, as well as by the resulting differentiated relations of power, domination, exploitation and conflict accompanying the global reproduction of capitalism as a social whole. Our focus on these geopolitical dimensions of development and reproduction is, then, not intended to reproduce the well-worn problems of geographical or geopolitical determinism. Rather, it aims to spatially broaden our analytical optic to the multiplicity of different ‘geo-social’ processes and determinations through which capitalism emerged. We would argue that such a spatial widening of our analytical imaginary is in fact a necessary methodological first step in any endeavour to furnish a genuinely non-Eurocentric theorisation of capitalism’s genesis and development.

    In order to avoid (neo)realist (mis)conceptions of ‘the international’ as an absolutely autonomous, suprasocial sphere of geopolitical interactions,⁴⁴ our uses of the concepts of ‘the international’ and ‘international system’ do not denote a permanent state of anarchy, or necessarily imply competition between discretely constituted political units in which the autonomous logic of this competition dictates their strategies. To make the realist move of deriving intersocietal competition from political multiplicity is to unproblematically accept the anthropologically dubious assumption that societies necessarily threaten each other.⁴⁵

    We must call out all such ahistorical reificatory and essentialist perspectives for what they really are: thinly veiled rationalisation (intentional or not) of power politics in attaining states’ putative ‘national interests’. In short, they are particular representations and articulations of the hegemonic ideologies of modern world politics masquerading as social ‘scientific’ theories⁴⁶ – traditional IR as ‘the Discipline of Western Supremacy’, as Kees van der Pijl aptly terms it.⁴⁷ In direct contrast to such approaches, geopolitics, human territoriality and intersocietal/international conflict, along with the very demarcation of the geopolitical as such, must be conceptualised as emergent properties of a wider, interactive and uneven process of development.⁴⁸

    But with these definitions of ‘geopolitics and ‘the geopolitical’ at hand, honesty compels us to admit that the subtitle of this book (The Geopolitical Origins of Capitalism) is something of a misnomer. While we do indeed examine a wide range of sociohistorical processes that are, strictly speaking, geopolitical (such as great power rivalries, colonialism and war), many other developments we investigate are more properly captured under the rubric of ‘intersocietal’ or ‘international’ relations, as exemplified by cross-cultural diffusions of trade, commerce, ideas, technologies and disease. We nonetheless settled on this subtitle not simply because it was catchier than, say, The Intersocietal Origins of Capitalism, but rather because it captures a fundamental point we are at pains to make throughout this book: that capitalism could only emerge, take root and reproduce itself – both domestically and internationally – through a violent, coercive, and often war-assisted process subjugating, dominating, and often annihilating many of those social forces that stood in its way – processes that continue to this day.

    In this sense, our book seeks to offer a ‘counter-history’ to the many liberal-inspired narratives emphasising the fundamentally pacifying and ‘civilising’ nature of capitalist development. They present a world where the spread of free trade and markets is equated with the promotion of a more cooperative and peaceful international order; one in which ‘globalisation’ is viewed as transforming contemporary international politics into a series of ‘positive-sum’ games whereby states can realise absolute gains; where increasingly integrated transnational circuits of capital and global market relations are in turn identified as advancing more liberal-democratic civic cultures, identities and norms.⁴⁹ As we demonstrate through the pages that follow, this is a conception of capitalist development that is fundamentally at odds with the historical record, both past and present.

    CHAPTER 1

    The Transition Debate:

    Theories and Critique

    In order to examine the object of our investigation in its integrity, free from all disturbing subsidiary circumstances, we must treat the whole world as one nation, and assume that capitalist production is everywhere established and has possessed itself of every branch of industry.

    Karl Marx, 1867¹

    … events strikingly analogous but taking place in different historic surroundings led to totally different results. By studying each of these forms of evolution separately and then comparing them one can easily find the clue to this phenomenon, but one will never arrive there by the universal passport of a general historico-philosophical theory, the supreme virtue of which consists in being super-historical.

    Karl Marx, 1877²

    Introduction

    In this chapter, we critically assess a number of influential Marxist-inspired theorisations of the transition to capitalism. We focus on such Marxist-inspired perspectives not because they exhaust the range of possible approaches to theorising the transition or because we think other perspectives have nothing to offer. Rather, we centre our attention on them because the Marxist tradition has arguably examined and debated the subject of capitalism’s genesis more than any other social theoretical tradition. For these reasons, our critical examination of other important perspectives to capitalism’s origins is in later chapters – Smithian approaches in Chapter 5, new institutionalism in Chapter 7, and neo-Weberian historical sociology and the California School in Chapter 8.

    The chapter is divided into three sections. The first section examines World-Systems approaches to the origins of capitalism, particularly through an engagement with the works of its most influential representative and ‘founder’, Immanuel Wallerstein. While highlighting the important contributions that World-System Theory (WST) has made to the study of capitalism’s genesis over the longue durée, we nonetheless argue that this approach – especially Wallerstein’s rendition of it – remains hamstrung by two particularly debilitating problems: the unwitting reproduction of Eurocentrism that erases non-European agency; and the inability to provide a sufficiently historicised conception of capitalism.

    The next section investigates the ‘Brenner thesis’ and the theoretical apparatus (Political Marxism) that Robert Brenner’s works on the transition to capitalism have engendered. We focus on three particularly problematic and interconnected issues in their theorisation of capitalism’s inception: first, their commitment to a methodologically internalist and concomitant Eurocentric (or Anglo-centric) analysis of the origins of capitalism; second, the resulting deficiencies in their examination of the relationship between the making of capitalism and geopolitics; and third, their highly abstract and minimalist conception of capitalism.

    In the third section, we consider the merits and problems of postcolonialism. The inclusion of postcolonial studies in our overview of the different approaches within the transition debate might seem unusual given that postcolonial scholars have predominantly focused on the experiences of modernity outside – and subsequent to – the emergence of capitalism in Europe. The existence of capitalism is then something largely taken for granted by postcolonial studies – a point that we argue limits their ability to fully ‘provincialise’ Europe. We nonetheless also draw out the important methodological and theoretical contributions postcolonialism offers in the study of capitalism’s origins – contributions that we seek to take up and further develop in the chapters that follow.

    The ‘Commercialisation Model’ Revisited: World-Systems Analysis and the Transition to Capitalism

    The Making of the Modern World-System: The Wallerstein Thesis

    The most systematic exposition of WST can be found in the works of Immanuel Wallerstein, who sought to bring together longue durée history writing with the anti-hegemonic politics of the 1960s Third World movements. From dependency theorists Wallerstein took the importance of colonisation in order to explain unequal regional differentiation between the capitalist core and periphery. From Sweezy and Braudel came the emphasis on the ‘world-system’ as the unit of analysis, and relatedly the importance of trade and exchange.³ Finally, Wallerstein emphasised the historical specificity of the crisis of feudalism and the collapse of world empires as a precondition for the emergence of the capitalist world-system. This was because Wallerstein was additionally concerned with how to denaturalise capitalism, and so explore the possibility of its eventual demise.⁴ At the heart of this project was then establishing the historical specificity of capitalism by:

    reopen[ing] the question of how and when the capitalist world-economy was created in the first place; why the transition took place in feudal Europe and not elsewhere; why it took place when it did and not earlier or later [and]; why earlier attempts of transition failed.

    The specificity of the capitalist world-system is explained through a negative comparison with the social form that preceded it, world empires. The latter were integrated systems of political rule which controlled and exploited differentiated communities on a regional and sometimes inter-regional basis. According to Wallerstein, world empires restricted economic development because large state bureaucracies would absorb surpluses appropriated from agrarian production, hindering or precluding the accumulation of capital and (re)investment in production.⁶ The collapse of world empires was a precondition for the emergence of capitalism, for it released profit-seeking commercial activities from the fetters of overarching imperial states. Now unrestrained, production would be ‘constantly expanded as long as further production is profitable’, and capitalists would ‘constantly innovate new ways of producing things that expand their profit margin’.⁷ Consequently, trade tended towards constant expansion and subsumption – ‘an expansion of the geographical size of the world in question’⁸ – which created a capitalist world economy by progressively ‘incorporating’ greater proportions of economic activity into its own ‘logic’. This subsumption of ‘non-capitalist zones’ into the capitalist world-system took place ‘through colonization, conquest, or economic and political domination’.⁹

    At the heart of this expansion was an ever-increasing regional specialisation and a world division of labour.¹⁰ From this perspective, Wallerstein distinguished the emergence of the world-system via overseas expansion from the freeing of labour, deriving the latter from the former.¹¹ That is, the world-system is capitalist not because it involves the systematic exploitation of formally free wage-labour throughout its regions, but rather because it is characterised by different societies’ integration into a transnational network of market exchanges and trade.¹² Wallerstein effectively denies the necessity of the wage-labour side of the capital relation for his definition of capitalism itself, writing for example that:

    The point is that the ‘relations of production’ that define a system are the ‘relations of production’ of the whole system, and the system at this point in time is the European world-economy. Free labor is indeed a defining feature of capitalism, but not free labor throughout the productive enterprises. Free labor is the form of labor control used for skilled work in core countries whereas coerced labor is used for less skilled work in peripheral areas. The combination thereof is the essence of capitalism.¹³

    It is only with the capitalist world-system that we find different localities integrated into a single but differentiated world-system – a unified division of labour distinguished along the hierarchical axes of core, semi-periphery and periphery.¹⁴ This unequal relationship is the sine qua non of capitalism for Wallerstein, in which differences between core (Western) and peripheral (non-Western) states determine the transfer of surplus from the latter to the former. This allowed for the observation that just as the core was experiencing an extensive freeing of labour, it was also siphoning off, via unequal exchange, huge amounts of surplus from unfree, coerced labour in the periphery, leaving the periphery in a permanent condition of developmental ‘backwardness’.

    Hence, part of the value of WST is to situate capitalist exploitation in this broader – international – grid of power and economic relations, beyond the singular act of an individual wage-labourer being exploited within the unit of production.¹⁵ As such, the importance of international hierarchy, exploitation, and more broadly unequal power relations, is revealed. And by distinguishing this world-system from preceding world empires, Wallerstein’s approach usefully emphasises the historical specificity and transience of such a hierarchical, exploitative system. These two elements – historical specificity and global hierarchies – can most certainly be considered the potential primary strengths of WST. However, on both counts WST ultimately fails to deliver. As we shall see, its identification of historical specificity is ill defined, to the point of missing it, and core–periphery relations are circumscribed by a problematic Eurocentrism that elides ‘peripheral agency’. We now turn to these criticisms in further detail.

    The Problem of Eurocentrism

    One of the benefits of Wallerstein’s emphasis on the world-system as the appropriate unit of analysis is that it has necessitated the study of societies outside of Europe. WST is prolific in this regard, with applications as diverse as the Ottoman Empire¹⁶ and Turkey,¹⁷ Africa,¹⁸ South Asia,¹⁹ East Asia²⁰ and Latin America.²¹ But, for all of Wallerstein’s emphasis on the world-system as the unit of analysis, we find within his version of WST a pervasive internalism which underpins some unfortunate – if not intentional²² – Eurocentric assumptions.

    First and foremost, the operative concepts in WST such as ‘division of labour’ and ‘specialization’ are derived from an internalist classical social theory par excellence, Adam Smith’s The Wealth of Nations.²³ These are then extrapolated in an unmediated fashion onto the international scale without considering how it might refashion such concepts. Falling prey to the ‘fallacy of the domestic analogy’,²⁴ WST leaves the distinct determinations arising from the coexistence and interaction of a multiplicity of differentiated societies (‘the international’) untheorised as their own unique domain of social interactions.²⁵ Instead, these intersocietal determinations are functionally subsumed under the overriding operative logic of a singularly conceived world-system.²⁶

    This inside-out method is replicated in WST’s study of history. Despite the high degree of emphasis on exogenous, global factors, WST cannot get away from an ontologically singular Eurocentric ‘logic of immanence’.²⁷ Consequently, Wallerstein reproduces the typically Eurocentric view that the transition from feudalism to capitalism took place uniquely and autonomously within the clearly demarcated spatial confines of Europe.²⁸ Although Asian empires displayed signs of potential development towards capitalism,²⁹ it was the crisis of feudalism in Europe between 1300 and 1450 ‘whose resolution was the historic emergence of a capitalist world-economy located in that particular geographical arena’.³⁰

    World history subsequently became about how this European creation spread outwards and ‘eventually expanded to cover the entire globe, eliminating in the process all remaining redistributive world-economies and reciprocal mini-systems’.³¹ In short, social transformations from the 16th century onwards are understood in the Eurocentric terms of linear developmentalism, in which European social forms are transmitted to ‘the East’. In this approach, we find a typically Eurocentric distinction between an atavistic and despotic East and a capitalist West, now recast as periphery and core respectively. In this schema, ‘the West’ is once again presented ‘as the pioneering creator of modernity’, and ‘the East’ as ‘a regressive and unexceptional entity that is incapable of capitalist self-generation’;³² an undifferentiated, passive transmitter of surplus to the core. This leads to a double ‘elision of Eastern agency’.³³ ‘Eastern’ elites are seen to voluntarily follow ‘Western dictates in order to better secure their own material reproduction within the capitalist world-system’.³⁴ Meanwhile, non-Western forms of resistance are either overlooked or seen to unintentionally and passively reproduce the capitalist world-system.³⁵

    This latter issue is especially striking given Marx’s theorisation of the distinct processes of subsumption through which capitalism could expand. For Marx, subsumption involved the possession, subordination

    Enjoying the preview?
    Page 1 of 1