1. Introduction
In the realm of financial markets, the continuous trading of securities such as stocks forms the backbone of economic dynamics. This paper delves into a market comprising
N securities operating within a fixed time horizon. The price trajectories of these securities are modeled by geometric Brownian motion: each is characterized by distinct drifts and volatilities. We explore the scenario of an investor investing his/her initial endowment into these
N securities. The investor’s portfolio,
, represents the proportion of wealth invested in each stock. The notation
represents the investor’s wealth trajectory under the self-financing portfolio strategy
. In the context of modern portfolio theory, investors aim to balance risk and reward, with risk-averse individuals prioritizing predictability and lower risk over potentially higher but uncertain returns; see, for example, [
1,
2,
3,
4]. This preference underscores the importance of understanding the risk associated with a portfolio, particularly through the probability of the wealth process
falling within a specific interval.
Therefore, a natural question is: Can we obtain the maximal and minimal distributions of the wealth process
on any specific interval over the portfolio set
. If this is possible, how can these two optimal portfolios,
and
, be constructed to achieve the maximal and minimal distributions, respectively? This is, for any given positive numbers
and
,
and
In the above proposed financial market model, the drift terms of the securities’ price processes are not precisely known, introducing ambiguity into the market dynamics. This ambiguity reflects the real-world uncertainty that investors face when the true probabilities of future events are unclear or indeterminate. Unlike risk, which can be quantified and managed through probabilistic models, ambiguity challenges traditional decision-making frameworks and necessitates novel approaches to portfolio optimization.
The current study addresses this ambiguity by considering the range of possible drift values within known bounds . By doing so, we aim to characterize the maximal and minimal distributions of the wealth process , which represent the best- and worst-case scenarios for an investor’s wealth at time T given the uncertain drift terms. These distributions provide valuable insights for investors, particularly those who are risk-averse, as they offer a way to gauge the potential outcomes of their investment strategies in the face of ambiguous market conditions.
The study on ambiguity models dates back to Frank [
5], who explains how uncertainty can create imperfect market structures. The portfolio optimization problem is studied by Hansen and Sargent [
6], who model the volatility of stocks as a stochastic process such that the volatility of stocks is uncertain. Chen and Epstein [
2] conceptualize the theoretical framework of ambiguity, risk and asset return with respect to a set of ‘objective’ probability measures. Cvitanic, Ma and Zhang [
7] study the problem of computing hedging portfolios for options that may have discontinuous payoffs. Schied [
8] uses risk assessment operators to solve the portfolio maximization problem. A robust mean-variance maximization problem is studied by Maccheroni, Marinacci and Ruffino [
9]. Bielecki, Jin, Pliska and Zhou [
10] study continuous-time mean-variance portfolio selection with bankruptcy prohibition. Jin and Zhou [
11] study continuous-time portfolio selection under ambiguity, in which the appreciation rates are only known to be in a certain convex closed set, and the portfolios are allowed to be only based on historical stock prices. Bai, Ma and Xing [
12] study a class of optimal dividend and investment problems with the assumption that the underlying reserve process follows the Sparre Andersen model. Hu, Jin and Zhou [
13] study portfolio selection in a complete, continuous time market, in which the preference is dictated by the rank-dependent utility. Chen, Feng and Zhang [
14] study sampling-strategy-driven limit theorems that generate the maximum or minimum average reward in the two-armed bandit problem.
To date, the above model has been widely studied. However, the explicit formulations of the maximal and minimal distributions remain unknown. The present study introduces a new method to investigate the above model. Specifically, based on the theory of backward stochastic differential equations (BSDEs), a confirmed answer can be obtained for the above question. That is, the explicit expression of
and
would be established, and the closed form of
and
would be obtained. Actually, we shall show that the maximal and minimal distributions are closely related to a BSDE that is nonlinear in
. Nonlinear BSDEs were initially studied by Pardoux and Peng [
15]. It has been widely recognized that BSDEs provide a useful framework for formulating problems in various fields, such as financial mathematics, stochastic optimal control, and partial differential equations (PDEs). For example, El Karoui, Peng and Quenez [
16] study different properties of BSDEs and their applications in finance, especially contingent claim valuation and recursive utility (independently introduced by Duffie and Epstein [
17]). Pardoux and Peng [
18] establish some estimates and regularity results for the solution of BSDEs and provide a Feynman–Kac representation for solutions to some nonlinear parabolic PDEs. Peng [
19] obtain the general stochastic maximum principle through the theory of BSDEs. Yong [
20] discusses the solvability of BSDEs with possibly unbounded coefficients and their applications in a Black–Scholes type security market with unbounded risk premium processes and/or interest rates. Chen and Epstein [
21] study a central limit theorem for a sequence of random variables with a mean uncertainty, and it was revealed that the limit is defined by a BSDE, which can be interpreted as modeling an ambiguous continuous-time random walk.
Although BSDEs have been used in various problems, this method still has some limitations since the properties of
and the explicit solution of general nonlinear BSDEs cannot be easily established. For the
part, Chen, Kupperger and Wei [
22] obtain an interesting comonotonic theorem of
for a nonlinear but special generator. Although it is difficult to obtain the explicit formulations for the solution of a general nonlinear BSDE, Chen, Liu, Qian and Xu [
23] obtain explicit solutions to an interesting class of nonlinear BSDEs, which is the
k-ignorance model that arose from modeling the ambiguity of asset pricing (e.g., Chen and Epstein [
2]).
Motivated by these above results, the present paper uses BSDEs to study the optimal investment problem. The main ideas are as follows: First, the correlation between the maximal distribution and the solution for a special kind of nonlinear BSDE (Theorem 1) is established. Second, through the formulation of the BSDE, the corresponding optimal portfolio is constructed (Theorem 2). Third, after obtaining the explicit solution for the derived BSDE, the maximal distribution is explicitly computed (Theorem 4). Similarly, the minimal distribution and the corresponding optimal portfolio are similarly studied. For wider applications, a general utility function including the indicator function is considered (Theorem 3). From the explicit formulations of the optimal strategy and the optimal distribution, it can easily be observed that diversified portfolios with two stocks would be better than portfolios with only one stock.
The present study is organized as follows.
Section 2 presents the definition of maximal and minimal distributions and some basic results for the BSDEs used for the study.
Section 3 presents the explicit representations of optimal portfolios
and
, which correspond to the maximal and minimal distributions, respectively. The explicit expressions for the maximal and minimal distributions and a general utility function case are presented in
Section 4. The maximal distribution is applied to explain the benefits of diversified portfolios in
Section 5.
2. Preliminaries
In this section, some notations and lemmas are provided. Let
refer to the probability space,
refer to the standard Brownian motion on this probability space, and
refer to the
-filtration generated by the Brownian motion, which is augmented by all
-null sets
. That is,
. Let
refer to the set of all
-measurable and square-integrable random variables,
refer to the set of all real-valued
-adapted processes with
, and
refer to the set of all
-progressively measurable real-valued processes with
Throughout the study,
represents the indicator function on set
A,
denotes the expectation under probability measure
, and the sign function
is given by
The definition of a maximal distribution is initially given. The minimal distribution is similarly defined.
Definition 1 (Maximal distribution)
. Let refer to the family of random variables over a given index set Θ. The maximal distribution of over the set Θ is denoted by the following: We now introduce the model of our study, which is set within a finite time horizon
. The price dynamics of the securities are governed by the following system of stochastic differential equations (SDEs):
where
represents the drift,
is the volatility,
is the initial price, and
is a Brownian motion within the probability space
. A feature of our model is the ambiguity of the exact values of
, with only their maximum and minimum known. For simplicity, we only consider the case
and
for
. This simplification does not detract from the generality of our results, which can be extended to scenarios with
.
We explore the scenario of an investor investing his/her initial endowment into two stocks. The investor’s portfolio,
, represents the proportion of wealth invested in each stock. The evolution of the investor’s wealth,
, is governed by the stochastic differential equation:
The set of all possible self-financing portfolios,
, is defined as:
where
refer to two fixed numbers that represent the constraints on the investment proportion of these two stocks.
At the end of this section, nonlinear BSDEs are briefly introduced, which were initially investigated in [
15]:
Lemma 1 ([
15])
. Assume that is uniformly Lipschitz continuous. Hence, for any and , the BSDE (5) has a unique pair of solution Usually, it is difficult to obtain the closed form for the solution of the BSDE (5) when
g is nonlinear. Interestingly, as shown in the following lemma, for cases
and
, the following BSDE has a pair of explicit solutions:
where
satisfies the following assumption:
Hypothesis 1. There exists some such that φ is symmetric on c. That is, for all.
Lemma 2 ([
23])
. Assume that satisfies (H.1) for some , and (where ) have, at most, polynomial growth. Then BSDE (6) has a pair of explicit solutions with H defined as follows:(i) If and on , then (ii) If and on , thenwhere is the joint distribution of and its local time with respect to ℓ and is given by 5. Do Not Put All the Eggs in One Basket
‘Do not put all your eggs in the same basket’ is a widespread proverb that means that diversified investment is necessary in order to avoid great losses due to a single investment. On the one hand, this advice can be partly formalized by considering the volatility of the portfolio. For example, by constructing portfolios with assets that are imperfectly correlated with one another, the risk inherent in the portfolio would decline as more assets are added to the portfolio until, eventually, the volatility of the portfolio would converge to the average covariance of assets that comprise the portfolio. Therefore, diversified risks can be reduced when compared to undiversified risks. On the other hand, after obtaining the explicit formulation for the maximal distribution and the corresponding portfolio, the benefits of the diversified portfolios can be explained and the proverb from the probability framework can be formalized, as shown in the following results.
Let and . Then, and refer to two self-financing portfolios. By applying Theorem 4, the following result can be obtained.
Proposition 1. For ,where , is defined in (19), and are the wealth processes corresponding to portfolios and , respectively: that is, investing only in the first stock and only in the second stock respectively. Furthermore, let , and for some ; we have The two portfolios,
and
, correspond to the cases for which all wealth is invested solely in the first and second stock, respectively. From (
25), it can be observed that neither of the above portfolios is optimal in the probability framework. Instead, investing in both stocks according to
would deduce a larger probability on any interval around the larger drift/return, thereby achieving a greater coverage probability to win a larger drift/return and reducing the risk. Therefore, a diversified portfolio with two stocks is better than a portfolio with only one stock (even when the stock has a larger drift/return). That is, the existence of a stock with a smaller drift/return does not always cause bad influences on the market. Interestingly, the combination of these two stocks would induce a larger coverage probability of wealth on any specific interval, consequently reducing the risk of the investment. Therefore, this verifies the benefits of diversified portfolios and implies the mathematical explanations for the proverb.
Remark 3. The results for the maximal and minimal distributions can be extended to a case with more than two stocks. For example, consider that there are stocks in the financial market; the wealth process would follow the following SDE:in which , and the set of self-financing portfolios isLetThen, similar to Theorem 1, it can be proved that is equal to of BSDE (9), with and given by (27). Thus, through solving BSDE (9), the maximal distributions of this case can be obtained based on Theorem 4. Furthermore, the minimal distribution can be similarly obtained.