Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

Optimal Portfolios

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 32

Lecture 5

Optimal portfolios

Learning outcomes
By the end of this lecture you should:
Be familiar with the separation theorem
Know why this implies that every investors
optimal risky portfolio is the market portfolio
Be able to solve the portfolio problem in the
presence of a risk free asset and the market
portfolio
Understand how this implies the CAPM

The optimal portfolio


Last time we found the optimal portfolio by picking
the portfolio on the efficient frontier that touched
our highest indifference curve (gave the highest
utility).
E(r)

Introduce a risk free asset


Suppose that in addition to the risky assets that
we talked about last lecture, we could also invest
in some risk free asset
Well call the return of this asset the risk free
return, rf
By definition of risk free, we have Var rf 0 E r r
During our first three lecture we were only
concerned with these kind of assets
For simplicity we will assume that we have a flat
and constant term structure of interest rates
f

Combining the risk free asset with a risky


portfolio into a complete portfolio
Suppose we want to combine some risky
portfolio, P, with the risk free asset
Lets denote the fraction invested in the risky
asset y and the fraction invested in the risk
free asset (1-y)
The return of our complete portfolio, C, is
defined as before:

rC 1  y rf  yrP

The expected return of a complete


portfolio
As usual, we are interested in the risk and
expected return of this portfolio. Lets start with
the expected return:
E r E > 1  y r  yr @

E r 1  y r  yE r

Like before the portfolio expected return is a
weighted average of the asset expected returns
It will be convenient to express this equation as:
E r r  y>E r  r @

By varying y, we can choose our expected return
C

The risk of a complete portfolio


We figured out in the last lecture how to calculate
the variance of a two asset portfolio:
r 1  y r  yr

Var r Var > 1  y r  yr @

Var r 1  y Var r  y Var r  2 1  y yCov r , r
The neat thing here is that rf is a constant, so Var(rf) =
0 and Cov(rf, rP) = 0:

Var r y Var r y V
V
yV
yV

We find that C is linear in P
C

2
P

2
P

These are linear combinations


We have found that:

E rC rf  y>E rP  rf @
V C yV P

So y determines what fraction of the distance between
the risk free asset and P is covered in both dimensions
When y = 0 we are in the risk free asset, e.g. C = 0 and
E(RC) = rf
When y = 0.5 we are halfway between the risk free asset
and P, e.g. C = 0.5P and E(RC) = rf + 0.5[E(RC) - rf]
When y = 1 we are in portfolio P, e.g. C = P and E(RC) =
E(RP)

Lets plot it
Graphically, this means that all our complete portfolios
plot on a straight line between the risk free asset and P
Lets call the line associated with the risky portfolio P
for CALP (for reasons that will become clear later)
E(r)
P

CALP

rf

Lets plot it
Last lecture, we learned only to consider risky
portfolios on the efficient frontier, so lets
chose P from that set

E(r)
P

CALP

rf

Apply the mean variance criterion


We see that some of our complete portfolios
dominate some portfolios on the efficient frontier
Which ones are dominated depends on the risky
portfolio we choose
P2

E(r)

CALP2

CALP1
rf

P1

Apply the mean variance criterion


Were interested in choosing the P that dominates the most portfolios
This turns out to be the portfolio where the line of complete portfolios is
tangent to the efficient frontier
We call this P the optimal risky portfolio, P*
The associated line CALP* is often simply denoted CAL

CALP* = CAL
E(r)

P*

rf

Apply the mean variance criterion

A different way to phrase this is to note that we only consider risky portfolios on the efficient
frontier
We can then forget about the efficient frontier and only compare CALs
We note that for any portfolio on CAL1 there is a dominating portfolio just above it on CAL2
Portfolios on CALs with higher slopes will always dominate portfolios on CALs with lower
slopes
The optimal risky portfolio is the portfolio associated with the CAL that has the highest slope

CAL2
E(r)
CAL1
rf

The optimal risky portfolio


All portfolios other than P* on the efficient
frontier are dominated by some combination of
the optimal risky portfolio, P*, and the risk free
asset
This means that all efficient portfolios consist of
some such combination
The reason we call the corresponding line CAL is
that all capital will be allocated along it
CAL is an acronym for the Capital Allocation Line

The separation theorem


All efficient portfolios (in the presence of a risk free
asset) are on the CAL
The CAL is determined by the optimal risky portfolio
We pick the portfolio on the CAL that offers the
amount of risk we want to take. This is expressed in our
choice of y.
Thus, our entire portfolio choice problem can be
separated into two parts:
Find the optimal risky portfolio, P*
Choose how much risk we want by choosing the fraction of
our wealth that we invest in that portfolio, y

Step 1: Choosing P* (and implicitly the


CAL)
The CAL is a line in risk-return space
Its slope, S, determines how much reward in terms of
E(r) we get for taking on one more unit of risk
We can easily calculate this slope from our two known
points on the line:

'y E r  E r E r  r
S
V 0
V
'x

We usually refer to the slope of a CAL associated with a
given portfolio as the Sharpe ratio of that portfolio


P*

P*

P*

P*

Step 1: Choosing P*
Recall from the construction of our utility function that
we only care about E(r) and
This means we always prefer a higher Sharpe ratio, S
We find the optimal portfolio, P*, by choosing its
portfolio weights, wP, so as to maximizes SP:

E r  r
max S
V

This gets messy (at least when we can choose between
many assets)
You can do this using the Excel solver or some other
suitable computer program


P

wP

Step 2: Choosing the risky share, y


We choose y according to our risk preference, which is
modeled in our utility function by A
We may again illustrate this choice using indifference curves:


E(r)

P*
C

rf

Step 2: Choosing the risky share, y


Once we have determined P*, we know from
before that our risk and return will be:
>

E rC rf  y E rP  rf

VC

yV P

We also know that our utility will depend on


these quantities in the following manner:
U E r  1 2 AV 2

Lets combine these equations:
U r  y>E r  r @ A yV r  y>E r  r @ Ay V
f

P*

P*

P*

2
P*

Step 2: Choosing the risky share, y


By choosing y, we choose where to end up on the CAL
Lets choose y so as to maximize our utility:
max U rf  y>E rP*  rf @ 1 2 Ay 2V P2*

y
We set the first derivative equal to zero and solve for y:
wU

>E r  r @ AyV 0
wy

E r  r
1 E r  r
y

V
V
A
A

E r  r
is known as the reward-to-risk ratio (and has an interpretation that
V
is very similar to the Sharpe ratio)
y* is increasing in this ratio, meaning that the more rewards in terms of
E(r) we get for taking on extra risk, the more we invest in the risky
portfolio
y* is decreasing in A, meaning that the more risk-averse we are, the less
we invest in the risky portfolio
P*

P*

2
P*

P*

2
P*

2
P*

P*

2
P*

Leveraged positions
There is nothing in principle that prevents us
from choosing y > 1
This means that well take a short position in
the risk-free asset, i.e. (1 - y) < 0
The interpretation of this is that we borrow
money
We say that we take a leveraged position in P*

Borrowing constraints
In practice, we must borrow at a higher rate
than we can invest at
This is because lending money to us is not
really risk free
Graphically we get a kink in the CAL when y =
1
Since wed have higher default risks for more
leveraged positions, the CAL may also be
concave when y > 1

Implications of the separation theorem


The rational way to increase risk taking is to
increase leverage (not to buy more tech
stocks)
All investors will end up holding the same risky
portfolio
Since prices adjust to set the supply of stocks
equal to the demand for stocks, the portfolio
demanded must be the portfolio supplied
P* is the market portfolio, M

Implications of the separation theorem


The attractiveness of a stock is determined by
its risk and return effects on this portfolio
We saw last lecture that the expected return
effect of a stock on a portfolio is linear and
that the risk effect depends crucially on its
covariance with the other stocks in the
portfolio

A note on expected returns

A company that issues a stock is basically selling a claim to its future


profits
These profits are determined by the operations of the company
Since the profits are risky, the company has to sell the claims at a price
that is lower than their expected value
If the price is lower, the expected return of the investors is higher
Since these high expected returns are used to induce investors to hold
unattractive risky stocks, high expected returns signify unattractive
stocks, which may seem counterintuitive
Of course, high expected returns are not themselves unattractive
In equilibrium, expected returns are set so as to make all stocks equally
attractive
Some times we emphasize this by referring to a stocks expected return as
its required return (to make it as attractive as all other stocks)

The market portfolio


Recall that the market portfolio is the optimal
risky portfolio for all investors
Each investor buys a small fraction of the
portfolio
The entire market portfolio simply consists of all
assets
Just like in other portfolios, the weight of each
asset in the market portfolio is the assets total
market value divided by the total value of the
portfolio:
V
wi

V
j

The expected return of the market


portfolio

The return of the market portfolio, rM, is


N

wr
We calculate expectations just like with any other portfolio
N
E rM wi E ri

rM

i i

i 1

i 1

It is clear that the contribution of asset i to the expected return of the


market portfolio is
wi E ri

It will be useful to express this as the contribution of asset i to the market
portfolios excess return, i.e. its return over and above the risk-free rate
N

E rM  rf wi >E ri  rf @
i 1

The contribution of asset i to the market excess return is

>

wi E ri  rf

The variance of the market portfolio


We calculate the variance just like any other
portfolio variance, i.e. by setting up the
covariance matrix and summing the elements:



Note that every asset corresponds to one row
in the matrix

w1r1

w2r2

wNrN

w1r1

Cov(w1r1,w1r1)

Cov(w1r1,w2r2)

Cov(w1r1,wNrN)

w2r2

wNrN

Cov(w2r2,w1r1)

Cov(wNrN,w1r1)

Cov(w2r2,w2r2)

Cov(wNrN,w2r2)

Cov(w2r2,wNrN)

Cov(wNrN,wNrN)

The variance of the market portfolio


The contribution of each asset to the variance
of the market portfolio is captured by the sum
of the elements in its row
Lets view the row for asset i in isolation:

This matrix corresponds to the matrix we
would set up to calculate

wiri

w1r1

w2r2

wNrN

Cov(w1r1,w1r1)

Cov(w1r1,w2r2)

Cov(w1r1,wNrN)

Cov wi ri , w j rj
j 1

The risk-return ratio of the market


portfolio
We see that the contribution of asset i to the
variance of the market portfolio is

Cov w r , w r Cov w r , r w Cov r , r


Note that the reward-to-risk ratio of the market


portfolio is:
E r  r
V

The contribution of asset i to this ratio is:
N

i i

j j

i i

j 1

2
M

>

wi E ri  rf

wi Cov ri , rM

E ri  rf

Cov ri , rM

The risk-return ratio of the market


portfolio
Since the market portfolio is the portfolio with
the best risk-return ratio, it cannot be
improved by changing the portfolio weights
This means that no isolated investment can
make a larger contribution to the risk-return
ratio than any other investment:
E r  r
E r  r

Cov r , r Cov r , r
This is also true for the market portfolio itself:
i

E ri  r f

Cov ri , rM

E rM  rf

Cov rM , rM

E rM  rf

V M2

The CAPM
We can rewrite this equation as
E r  r
E r  r

V
Cov r , r
Cov r , r

E r  r
E r r 
V
This equation expresses a relation that must hold
between an assets expected return and its
covariance with the market
We call this model the Capital Asset Pricing
Model or the CAPM
It will be the focus of our coming lectures
i

2
M

i
2
M

You might also like