About The Authors
About The Authors
About The Authors
ETTI BARANOFF
Dr. Etti Baranoff is an associate professor of risk management, insurance, and finance
at the School of Business at Virginia Commonwealth University (VCU) in Richmond,
Virginia, where she has taught since 1995. She has been in the insurance field for over
thirty years. Prior to entering academia, she worked in the insurance industry and as a
Texas insurance regulator. She began her insurance career as a pension administrator
and market and product research analyst at American Founder’s Life Insurance Com-
pany in Austin, Texas, in 1978. In 1982 she began a twelve-year career as a Texas insur-
ance regulator, beginning with actuarial work for the rate promulgation of property/
casualty lines of insurance, following with legislative research work on all topics.
Dr. Baranoff has spoken at many insurance and finance forums and won various
awards for her research and teaching. She is a member of the prestigious Risk Theory
Seminar and has published in prominent journals, including the Journal of Risk and In-
surance, the Journal of Banking and Finance, the Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance,
the Journal of Insurance Regulation, Best’s Review, and Contingencies of the American
Academy of Actuaries, among others. She is also one of the authors of another textbook: Risk Assessment by the American Institute
for CPCU.
Dr. Baranoff has authored or co-authored more than fifty papers relating to risk management and insurance. Her work, which
considers issues such as capital structure, detection of potential insolvencies, asset allocation and performance, and market discip-
line, is all within the context of enterprise risk and enterprise risk management. She has received various honors and recognitions
during her career, including five awards given by the International Insurance Society (2008, 2006, 2004, 1996, and 1995). She was re-
cognized as the 2005 Distinguished Scholar by the VCU School of Business and was a seven-time winner of research awards given by
the business school. She was also the recipient of the 1990 Spencer Scholarship Award (RIMS) and the 1989 Vestal Lemmon Presid-
ential Scholarship at the University of Texas at Austin.
Along with her articles published in academic and nonacademic journals and periodicals, her textbooks, and countless present-
ations at various meetings and conferences, Dr. Baranoff is often quoted in major newspapers and has appeared on various TV sta-
tions on matters of insurance and risk management. Her presentations are available at the VCU School of Business Web site, which
features a video, “On the Topic,” about her expertise in risk management.
Dr. Baranoff has been a member of several professional societies, including the already noted Risk Theory Seminar (an
invitation-only society), the Financial Management Association (FMA), the American Risk and Insurance Association (ARIA), the
Western Risk and Insurance Association (WRIA), and the Southern Risk and Insurance Association (SRIA).
In addition to her PhD in finance with minors in insurance and statistics from the University of Texas at Austin in 1993 and her
BA in economics and statistics from the University of Tel Aviv, Israel, in 1971, Dr. Baranoff also holds the fellow of Life Manage-
ment Institute designation with distinction. She was a high school economics and social sciences teacher and earned a teaching cer-
tificate in social sciences from the University of Tel Aviv in 1974. She has served as an expert in a number of cases.
E-mail: ebaranoff@vcu.edu or ettib@earthlink.net.
Site: http://www.professorofinsurance.com.
2 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
PATRICK L. BROCKETT
Dr. Patrick L. Brockett holds the Gus S. Wortham Memorial Chair in Risk Manage-
ment and Insurance in the Department of Information, Risk, and Operations Manage-
ment at the University of Texas at Austin. He is the director of the risk management
program and the director of the Center for Risk Management and Insurance Research
and holds a joint appointment as a full professor in the departments of Information,
Risk, and Operations Management; Finance; and Mathematics. Prior to becoming the
director of the risk management program, he served as the director of the actuarial sci-
ence program at the University of Texas at Austin. He is the former director of the
Center for Cybernetic Studies and is a fellow of the Institute of Risk Management, a fel-
low of the Institute of Mathematical Statistics, a fellow of the American Statistical Asso-
ciation, a fellow of the Royal Statistical Society, and a fellow of the American Associ-
ation for the Advancement of Science.
Dr. Brockett has taught and done research in the fields of risk, insurance, and actu-
arial science for almost thirty years. His research articles have won awards from the
American Risk and Insurance Association, the American Statistical Association, the Society of Actuaries, the International Insur-
ance Society, and the Casualty Actuarial Society, as well as from the Faculty of Actuaries of Scotland and Institute of Actuaries in
England. He is listed as one of the top ten most published researchers in the world in the seventy-five-year history of the Journal of
Risk and Insurance (the premier academic journal in risk management and insurance in the world) in terms of the number of pages
published. He was presented with the American Risk and Insurance Association Outstanding Achievement Award, won the Robert
I. Mehr Award given by the American Risk and Insurance Association “for that journal article making a ten-year lasting contribu-
tion to risk management” and having “withstood the test of time,” and won the Halmsted Prize for the Most Outstanding English
Language Publication in Actuarial Science in the World, presented by the Society of Actuaries. He served as editor of the Journal of
Risk and Insurance for nine years and in this capacity also became familiar with multiple aspects of insurance, including institutional
details, market performance, agent behavior and responsibilities, and standard practice in the insurance industry.
Dr. Brockett worked with the Texas Department of Insurance on credit scoring and did a study for the Texas legislature on
credit scoring as well. He currently serves as a member of the board of directors of the Texas Property and Casualty Guaranty Asso-
ciation. He is a past president of the American Risk and Insurance Association, the premier academic organization in risk manage-
ment and insurance in the world. He has published four books or monographs and over 130 scientific research papers. He regularly
teaches classes involving insurance and risk management. He received his PhD in mathematics in 1975 from the University of Cali-
fornia at Irvine, California.
E-mail: utpatrickbrockett@gmail.com.
YEHUDA KAHANE
Dr. Yehuda Kahane is active in both the academic and business areas. He is a professor
of insurance and finance, Faculty of Management, Tel Aviv University, and head of the
Akirov Institute for Business and the Environment. He founded and served as the dean
of the first academic school of insurance in Israel (now a part of Netanya Academic
College). At Tel Aviv University he directed the Erhard Insurance Center and the actu-
arial studies program and coordinated the executive development program. He is a life
and nonlife actuary.
Over more than forty years, Dr. Kahane has taught at universities around the
globe, including the Wharton School at the University of Pennsylvania, the University
of Texas at Austin, the Hebrew University of Jerusalem, the University of Florida, and
the University of Toronto, among others. He founded and has directed the Israel CLU
program. He has also organized and lectured in hundreds of seminars and conferences.
Dr. Kahane, the author of several books and numerous articles, was ranked among
the most prolific researchers in insurance (Journal of Risk and Insurance, June 1990). In
the late 1960s he was among the pioneers that applied multiple regressions for insurance rate making. In the early 1970s he de-
veloped the concept of balancing assets and liabilities of financial intermediaries, in works that are still quoted thirty years later.
These studies laid the foundations for theories of insurance rate making, solvency, insurance regulation, and the vast area that is
now known as ERM—enterprise risk management. He has major contributions to the theory and practice of loss reserving, agricul-
ture and crop insurance, and the use of data mining in insurance.
Dr. Kahane also has a rich entrepreneurial experience. He is a co-founder, director, and major shareholder in Ituran Location
and Control (ITRN). He was a co-initiator of the concept of “new” balanced pension funds in Israel and was the co-founder and co-
owner of the managing firm of the first fund (Teshura) that became the fourth largest fund in Israel in 1995. He is highly involved in
the formation and management of start-up companies in a variety of advanced and high-tech areas, specializing in seed money
ABOUT THE AUTHORS 3
investments. He owns the Weizman Hi-Tech Incubator and is a co-owner of Capital Point Ltd. (traded on TASE), which owns
Ofakim and Kazrin technological incubators. In addition, he is involved in many voluntary NGO activities, including the
PIBF—Palestinian International Business Forum—and chairman of the Association of Visually Impaired People in Sharon District,
Or Yarok—an association for prevention of traffic accident victims.
He started his business career in a large multinational corporation and in the management of various businesses. In addition, he
served as a consultant on risk management, insurance, and actuarial and financial topics to the government, large organizations, and
major companies both in Israel and internationally. Dr. Kahane has served on the Israeli Insurance Council and on several govern-
ment committees on a variety of insurance-related topics.
Dr. Kahane earned a BA in economics and statistics in 1965, an MA in business administration, cum laude, in 1967, and a PhD
in finance in 1973, all from the Hebrew University of Jerusalem. He has served as an associate editor of the leading journals on risk
and insurance. He has taught courses in technological forecasting (the first teacher of this subject in Israel), finance, insurance, risk
management, and actuarial topics. His research focus is on the portfolio implications for insurance, rate making, automobile insur-
ance, natural hazards, pension and life insurance, reserving, and environmental risks.
E-mail: kahane@post.tau.ac.il.
Site: http://recanati.tau.ac.il/~kahane.
Preface
INTRODUCTION AND BACKGROUND
This textbook is designed to reflect the dynamic nature of the field of risk management as an introduction to intermediate-level stu-
dents. With co-author experts Etti Baranoff, Patrick L. Brockett, and Yehuda Kahane, the timely issues of the field are kept alive. The
catastrophes of the first decade of the new millennium, including the credit crisis of 2008–2009, are well depicted and used to illus-
trate the myriad of old and new risks of our times. With such major man-made and natural catastrophes, this field is of utmost im-
portance for sustainability. The need to educate students to consider risks at every phase in a business undertaking is central, and
this textbook provides such educational foundation.
This field requires timeliness as new risk management techniques and products are being developed in response to risks derived
from innovations and sophistication. As such, this book allows the reader to be on the forefront of knowledge in the arena of risk
management. Tomorrow’s leaders in business and politics and tomorrow’s citizens, consumers, and voters need to understand risks
to make successful decisions. This book provides you with the background for doing so.
With the pedagogical enhancements of Flat World Knowledge and the ability to make changes dynamically, this textbook
brings the best to educators. An important advantage of this book’s publication format is that it can be updated in real time online as
new risks appear (e.g., pandemic risk, financial crisis, terrorist attacks). Risk management consequences can be discussed
immediately.
The management of risk is, essentially, the strategy for surviving and thriving in a volatile, uncertain, complex, and ambiguous
world. Prior to the industrial revolution and the advanced communication age, decisions could be made easily using heuristics or
“gut level feel” based on past experience. As long as the world faced by the decision maker was more or less the same as that faced
yesterday, gut level decision making worked fairly well. The consequences of failure were concentrated in small locations. Entire vil-
lages were extinguished due to lack of crop risk planning or diseases. There were no systemic contagious interlocking risks, such as
those that brought the financial markets to their knees worldwide in 2008–2009.
Today the stakes are higher; the decision making is more complex, and consequences more severe, global, and fundamental.
Risk managers have become part of executive teams with titles, such as chief risk officer (CRO), and are empowered to bridge across
all business activities with short-term, long-term, and far-reaching goals. The credit crisis revealed that lack of understanding of
risks, and their combined and correlated ramifications has far-reaching consequences worldwide. The study of risk management is
designed to give business stakeholders the weapons necessary to foresee and combat potential calamities both internal to the busi-
ness and external to society overall. The “green movement” is an important risk management focus.
At the time of this writing (December 2009), more than 190 nations’ leaders are gathered at the Copenhagen Climate Summit to
come to some resolutions about saving Earth. The evolution into industrialized nations brought a sense of urgency to finding risk
management solutions to risks posed by the supply chain of production with wastes flowing into the environment, polluting the air
and waters. The rapid population growth in countries such as China and India that joined the industrialized nations accelerated the
ecological destruction of the water and air and has impacted our food chain. The UN 2005 World Millennium Ecosystem Report—a
document written by thousands of scientists—displays a gloomy picture of the current and expected future situation of our air, wa-
ter, land, flora, and fauna. The environmental issue has become important on risk managers’ agendas.
Other global worries that fall into the risk management arena are new diseases, such as the mutation in the H1N1 (swine) flu
virus with the bird flu (50 percent mortality rate of infected). One of China’s leading disease experts and the director of the Guang-
zhou Institute of Respiratory Diseases predicted that the combined effect of both H1N1 (swine) and the H5N1 (bird) flu viruses
could become a disastrous deadly hybrid with high mortality due to its efficient transmission among people. With systemic and per-
vasive travel and communication, such diseases are no longer localized environmental risks and are at the forefront of both indi-
viduals’ and firms’ risks.
With these global risks in mind and other types of risks, as are featured throughout the textbook, this book enables students to
work with risks effectively. In addition, you will be able to launch your professional career with a deep sense of understanding of the
importance of the long-term handling of risks.
Critical to the modern management of risk is the realization that all risks should be treated in a holistic, global, and integrated
manner, as opposed to having individual divisions within a firm treating the risk separately. Enterprise-wide risk management was
named one of the top ten breakthrough ideas in business by the Harvard Business Review in 2004.
L. Buchanan, “Breakthrough Ideas for 2004,” Harvard Business Review 2 (2004): 13–16.
Throughout, this book also takes this enterprise risk management perspective as well.
PREFACE 5
FEATURES
< An emphasis on the big picture—the Links section. Every chapter begins with an introduction and a links section to high-
light the relationships between various concepts and components of risk and risk management, so that students know how
the pieces fit together. This feature is to ensure the holistic aspects of risk management are always upfront.
< Every chapter is focused on the risk management aspects. While many solutions are insurance solutions, the main object-
ive of this textbook is to ensure the student realizes the fact that insurance is a risk management solution. As such there are
details explaining insurance in many chapters—from the nature of insurance in Chapter 5, to insurance operations and
markets in Chapter 6 and Chapter 7, to specifics of insurance contracts and insurance coverage throughout the whole text.
< Chapter 1 and Chapter 2 are completely dedicated to explaining risks and risk measurement.
< Chapter 4 was created by Dr. Puneet Prakash to introduce the concepts of attitudes toward risk and the solutions.
< Chapter 3 and Chapter 13 provide risk management techniques along with financial risk management.
< [MISSING REF: #baranoff-ch17]–[MISSING REF: #baranoff-ch22] focus on all aspects of risk management throughout
the life cycle. These can be used to study employee benefits as a special course.
< Cases are embedded within each chapter, and boxes feature issues that represent ethical dilemmas. [MISSING REF:
#baranoff-ch23] provides extra risk management and employee benefits cases.
< Student-friendly. A clear, readable writing style helps to keep a complicated subject from becoming overwhelming. Most
important is the pedagogical structure of the Flat World Knowledge system.
6 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
CHAP TER 1
The Nature of Risk: Losses
and Opportunities
In his novel A Tale of Two Cities, set during the French Revolution of the late eighteenth century, Charles Dickens
wrote, “It was the best of times; it was the worst of times.” Dickens may have been premature, since the same might
When we think of large risks, we often think in terms of natural hazards such as hurricanes, earthquakes, or
tornados. Perhaps man-made disasters come to mind—such as the terrorist attacks that occurred in the United
States on September 11, 2001. We typically have overlooked financial crises, such as the credit crisis of 2008.
However, these types of man-made disasters have the potential to devastate the global marketplace. Losses in
multiple trillions of dollars and in much human suffering and insecurity are already being totaled as the U.S.
Congress fights over a $700 billion bailout. The financial markets are collapsing as never before seen.
Many observers consider this credit crunch, brought on by subprime mortgage lending and deregulation of
the credit industry, to be the worst global financial calamity ever. Its unprecedented worldwide consequences have
hit country after country—in many cases even harder than they hit the United States.[1] The world is now a global
village; we’re so fundamentally connected that past regional disasters can no longer be contained locally.
We can attribute the 2008 collapse to financially risky behavior of a magnitude never before experienced. Its
implications dwarf any other disastrous events. The 2008 U.S. credit markets were a financial house of cards with a
1. Lenders gave home mortgages without prudent risk management to underqualified home buyers, starting
2. Many mortgages, including subprime mortgages, were bundled into new instruments called mortgage-
backed securities, which were guaranteed by U.S. government agencies such as Fannie Mae and Freddie
Mac.
3. These new bundled instruments were sold to financial institutions around the world. Bundling the
investments gave these institutions the impression that the diversification effect would in some way protect
4. Guarantees that were supposed to safeguard these instruments, called credit default swaps, were designed
to take care of an assumed few defaults on loans, but they needed to safeguard against a systemic failure of
many loans.
5. Home prices started to decline simultaneously as many of the unqualified subprime mortgage holders had
to begin paying larger monthly payments. They could not refinance at lower interest rates as rates rose after
6. These subprime mortgage holders started to default on their loans. This dramatically increased the number
7. Financial institutions guaranteeing the mortgage loans did not have the appropriate backing to sustain the
large number of defaults. These firms thus lost ground, including one of the largest global insurers, AIG
8. Many large global financial institutions became insolvent, bringing the whole financial world to the brink of
9. Individuals and institutions such as banks lost confidence in the ability of other parties to repay loans, causing
10. Governments had to get into the action and bail many of these institutions out as a last resort. This unfroze
the credit mechanism that propels economic activity by enabling lenders to lend again.
As we can see, a basic lack of risk management (and regulators’ inattention or inability to control these overt
failures) lay at the heart of the global credit crisis. This crisis started with a lack of improperly underwritten
mortgages and excessive debt. Companies depend on loans and lines of credit to conduct their routine business. If
such credit lines dry up, production slows down and brings the global economy to the brink of deep recession—or
even depression. The snowballing effect of this failure to manage the risk associated with providing mortgage
loans to unqualified home buyers has been profound, indeed. The world is in a global crisis due to the prevailing
(in)action by companies and regulators who ignored and thereby increased some of the major risks associated with
mortgage defaults. When the stock markets were going up and homeowners were paying their mortgages,
everything looked fine and profit opportunities abounded. But what goes up must come down, as Flannery
O’Conner once wrote. When interest rates rose and home prices declined, mortgage defaults became more
common. This caused the expected bundled mortgage-backed securities to fail. When the mortgages failed
because of greater risk taking on Wall Street, the entire house of cards collapsed.
Additional financial instruments (called credit derivatives)[2] gave the illusion of insuring the financial risk of the
bundled collateralized mortgages without actually having a true foundation—claims, that underlie all of risk
management.[3] Lehman Brothers represented the largest bankruptcy in history, which meant that the U.S.
government (in essence) nationalized banks and insurance giant AIG. This, in turn, killed Wall Street as we
previously knew it and brought about the restructuring of government’s role in society. We can lay all of this at the
feet of the investment banking industry and their inadequate risk recognition and management. Probably no other
risk-related event has had, and will continue to have, as profound an impact worldwide as this risk management
failure (and this includes the terrorist attacks of 9/11). Ramifications of this risk management failure will echo for
decades. It will affect all voters and taxpayers throughout the world and potentially change the very structure of
American government.
How was risk in this situation so badly managed? What could firms and individuals have done to protect
themselves? How can government measure such risks (beforehand) to regulate and control them? These and other
questions come immediately to mind when we contemplate the fateful consequences of this risk management
fiasco.
CHAPTER 1 THE NATURE OF RISK: LOSSES AND OPPORTUNITIES 9
With his widely acclaimed book Against the Gods: The Remarkable Story of Risk (New York City: John Wiley &
Sons, 1996), Peter L. Bernstein teaches us how human beings have progressed so magnificently with their
mathematics and statistics to overcome the unknown and the uncertainty associated with risk. However, no one
fully practiced his plans of how to utilize the insights gained from this remarkable intellectual progression. The
terrorist events of September 11, 2001; Hurricanes Katrina, Wilma, and Rita in 2005 and Hurricane Ike in 2008; and
the financial meltdown of September 2008 have shown that knowledge of risk management has never, in our long
history, been more important. Standard risk management practice would have identified subprime mortgages and
their bundling into mortgage-backed securities as high risk. As such, people would have avoided these investments
or wouldn’t have put enough money into reserve to be able to withstand defaults. This did not happen.
Accordingly, this book may represent one of the most critical topics of study that the student of the twenty-first
Risk management will be a major focal point of business and societal decision making in the twenty-first
century. A separate focused field of study, it draws on core knowledge bases from law, engineering, finance,
economics, medicine, psychology, accounting, mathematics, statistics, and other fields to create a holistic decision-
making framework that is sustainable and value-enhancing. This is the subject of this book.
1. Links
1. LINKS
Our “links” section in each chapter ties each concept and objective in the chapter into the realm of
globally or holistically managing risk. The solutions to risk problems require a compilation of tech-
niques and perspectives, shown as the pieces completing a puzzle of the myriad of personal and busi-
ness risks we face. These are shown in the “connection” puzzle in Figure 1.1. As we progress through
the text, each chapter will begin with a connection section to show how links between personal and en-
terprise holistic risk picture arise.
10 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
Even in chapters that you may not think apply to the individual, such as commercial risk, the connec-
systemic financial risk
tion will highlight the underlying relationships among different risks. Today, management of personal
Risk that affects everything, as and commercial risks requires coordination of all facets of the risk spectrum. On a national level, we
opposed to individuals being experienced the move toward holistic risk management with the creation of the Department of Home-
involved in risky enterprises.
land Security after the terrorist attacks of September 11, 2001.[4] After Hurricane Katrina struck in
2005, the impasse among local, state, and federal officials elevated the need for coordination to achieve
efficient holistic risk management in the event of a megacatastrophe.[5] The global financial crisis of
2008 created unprecedented coordination of regulatory actions across countries and, further, govern-
mental involvement in managing risk at the enterprise level—essentially a global holistic approach to
managing systemic financial risk. Systemic risk is a risk that affects everything, as opposed to indi-
viduals being involved in risky enterprises. In the next section, we define all types of risks more
formally.
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
< In this section, you will learn the concept of risk and differentiate between risk and uncertainty.
< You will build the definition of risk as a consequence of uncertainty and within a continuum of
decision-making roles.
The notion of “risk” and its ramifications permeate decision-making processes in each individual’s life
and business outcomes and of society itself. Indeed, risk, and how it is managed, are critical aspects of
decision making at all levels. We must evaluate profit opportunities in business and in personal terms
in terms of the countervailing risks they engender. We must evaluate solutions to problems (global,
political, financial, and individual) on a risk-cost, cost-benefit basis rather than on an absolute basis.
Because of risk’s all-pervasive presence in our daily lives, you might be surprised that the word “risk” is
hard to pin down. For example, what does a businessperson mean when he or she says, “This project
should be rejected since it is too risky”? Does it mean that the amount of loss is too high or that the ex-
pected value of the loss is high? Is the expected profit on the project too small to justify the consequent
CHAPTER 1 THE NATURE OF RISK: LOSSES AND OPPORTUNITIES 11
risk exposure and the potential losses that might ensue? The reality is that the term “risk” (as used in
the English language) is ambiguous in this regard. One might use any of the previous interpretations.
Thus, professionals try to use different words to delineate each of these different interpretations. We
will discuss possible interpretations in what follows.
In general, we widely believe in an a priori (previous to the event) relation between negative risk and
profitability. Namely, we believe that in a competitive economic market, we must take on a larger pos-
sibility of negative risk if we are to achieve a higher return on an investment. Thus, we must take on a
larger possibility of negative risk to receive a favorable rate of return. Every opportunity involves both
risk and return.
Identify the overlapping area as the set in which we both minimize risk and maximize value.
Figure 1.3 will help you conceptualize the impact of risk. Risk permeates the spectrum of decision
making from goals of value maximization to goals of insolvency minimization (in game theory terms,
maximin). Here we see that we seek to add value from the opportunities presented by uncertainty (and
its consequences). The overlapping area shows a tight focus on minimizing the pure losses that might
accompany insolvency or bankruptcy. The 2008 financial crisis illustrates the consequences of exploit-
ing opportunities presented by risk; of course, we must also account for the risk and can’t ignore the re-
quisite adverse consequences associated with insolvency. Ignoring risk represents mismanagement of
risk in the opportunity-seeking context. It can bring complete calamity and total loss in the pure loss-
avoidance context.
We will discuss this trade-off more in depth later in the book. Managing risks associated with the
context of minimization of losses has succeeded more than managing risks when we use an objective of
value maximization. People model catastrophic consequences that involve risk of loss and insolvency
in natural disaster contexts, using complex and innovative statistical techniques. On the other hand,
risk management within the context of maximizing value hasn’t yet adequately confronted the poten-
tial for catastrophic consequences. The potential for catastrophic human-made financial risk is most
dramatically illustrated by the fall 2008 financial crisis. No catastrophic models were considered or de-
veloped to counter managers’ value maximization objective, nor were regulators imposing risk con-
straints on the catastrophic potential of the various financial derivative instruments.
Our perception of risk arises from our perception of and quantification of uncertainty. In scientific
settings and in actuarial and financial contexts, risk is usually expressed in terms of the probability of
occurrence of adverse events. In other fields, such as political risk assessment, risk may be very qualitat-
ive or subjective. This is also the subject of Chapter 2.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
< In this section, you will learn that people’s attitudes toward risk affect their decision making.
< You will learn about the three major types of “risk attitudes.”
An in-depth exploration into individual and firms’ attitudes toward risk appears in Chapter 4. Here we
risk averse
touch upon this important subject, since it is key to understanding behavior associated with risk man-
Refers to shying away from agement activities. The following box illustrates risk as a psychological process. Different people have
risks and preferring to have as
different attitudes toward the risk-return tradeoff. People are risk averse when they shy away from
much security and certainty
as is reasonably affordable. risks and prefer to have as much security and certainty as is reasonably affordable in order to lower
their discomfort level. They would be willing to pay extra to have the security of knowing that unpleas-
ant risks would be removed from their lives. Economists and risk management professionals consider
most people to be risk averse. So, why do people invest in the stock market where they confront the
possibility of losing everything? Perhaps they are also seeking the highest value possible for their pen-
sions and savings and believe that losses may not be pervasive—very much unlike the situation in the
fall of 2008.
risk seeker A risk seeker, on the other hand, is not simply the person who hopes to maximize the value of re-
tirement investments by investing the stock market. Much like a gambler, a risk seeker is someone who
Someone who will enter into
an endeavor as long as a
will enter into an endeavor (such as blackjack card games or slot machine gambling) as long as a posit-
positive long run return on ive long run return on the money is possible, however unlikely.
the money is possible,
however unlikely.
CHAPTER 1 THE NATURE OF RISK: LOSSES AND OPPORTUNITIES 15
Finally, an entity is said to be risk neutral when its risk preference lies in between these two ex-
risk neutral
tremes. Risk neutral individuals will not pay extra to have the risk transferred to someone else, nor will
they pay to engage in a risky endeavor. To them, money is money. They don’t pay for insurance, nor When one’s risk preference
lies between the extremes of
will they gamble. Economists consider most widely held or publicly traded corporations as making de- risk averse and risk seeking.
cisions in a risk-neutral manner since their shareholders have the ability to diversify away risk—to
take actions that seemingly are not related or have opposite effects, or to invest in many possible unre- diversify away risk
lated products or entities such that the impact of any one event decreases the overall risk. Risks that the To take actions that are
corporation might choose to transfer remain for diversification. In the fall of 2008, everyone felt like a seemingly not related or have
gambler. This emphasizes just how fluidly risk lies on a continuum like that in Figure 1.3. Financial opposite effects or to invest
theories and research pay attention to the nature of the behavior of firms in their pursuit to maximize in many possible unrelated
products or entities such that
value. Most theories agree that firms work within risk limits to ensure they do not “go broke.” In the
the impact of any one event
following box we provide a brief discussion of people’s attitudes toward risk. A more elaborate discus- decreases the overall risk.
sion can be found in Chapter 4.
fortuitous
Feelings Associated with Risk A matter of chance.
Early in our lives, while protected by our parents, we enjoy security. But imagine yourself as your parents (if you
can) during the first years of your life. A game called “Risk Balls” was created to illustrate tangibly how we
handle and transfer risk.[7] See, for example, Figure 1.4 below. The balls represent risks, such as dying prema-
turely, losing a home to fire, or losing one’s ability to earn an income because of illness or injury. Risk balls
bring the abstract and fortuitous (accidental or governed by chance) nature of risk into a more tangible con-
text. If you held these balls, you would want to dispose of them as soon as you possibly could. One way to dis-
pose of risks (represented by these risk balls) is by transferring the risk to insurance companies or other firms
that specialize in accepting risks. We will cover the benefits of transferring risk in many chapters of this text.
Right now, we focus on the risk itself. What do you actually feel when you hold the risk balls? Most likely, your
answer would be, “insecurity and uneasiness.” We associate risks with fears. A person who is risk averse—that
is, a “normal person” who shies away from risk and prefers to have as much security and certainty as pos-
sible—would wish to lower the level of fear. Professionals consider most of us risk averse. We sleep better at
night when we can transfer risk to the capital market. The capital market usually appears to us as an insurance
company or the community at large.
As risk-averse individuals, we will often pay in excess of the expected cost just to achieve some certainty about
the future. When we pay an insurance premium, for example, we forgo wealth in exchange for an insurer’s
promise to pay covered losses. Some risk transfer professionals refer to premiums as an exchange of a certain
loss (the premium) for uncertain losses that may cause us to lose sleep. One important aspect of this kind of
exchange: premiums are larger than are expected losses. Those who are willing to pay only the average loss as
a premium would be considered risk neutral. Someone who accepts risk at less than the average loss, perhaps
even paying to add risk—such as through gambling—is a risk seeker.
Risk Balls
K E Y T A K E A W A Y
< Differentiate among the three risk attitudes that prevail in our lives—risk averse, risk neutral, and risk
seeker.
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
< In this section, you will learn what a risk professional means by exposure.
< You will also learn several different ways to split risk exposures according to the risk types in-
volved (pure versus speculative, systemic versus idiosyncratic, diversifiable versus
nondiversifiable).
< You will learn how enterprise-wide risk approaches combine risk categories.
Most risk professionals define risk in terms of an expected deviation of an occurrence from what they
anticipated variability
expect—also known as anticipated variability. In common English language, many people continue
An expected deviation of an to use the word “risk” as a noun to describe the enterprise, property, person, or activity that will be ex-
occurrence from what one
expects.
posed to losses. In contrast, most insurance industry contracts and education and training materials
use the term exposure to describe the enterprise, property, person, or activity facing a potential loss.
exposure So a house built on the coast near Galveston, Texas, is called an “exposure unit” for the potentiality of
Term used to describe the loss due to a hurricane. Throughout this text, we will use the terms “exposure” and “risk” to note those
enterprise, property, person, units that are exposed to losses.
or activity facing a potential
loss.
4.1 Pure versus Speculative Risk Exposures
Some people say that Eskimos have a dozen or so words to name or describe snow. Likewise, profes-
sional people who study risk use several words to designate what others intuitively and popularly know
as “risk.” Professionals note several different ideas for risk, depending on the particular aspect of the
“consequences of uncertainty” that they wish to consider. Using different terminology to describe
different aspects of risk allows risk professionals to reduce any confusion that might arise as they dis-
cuss risks.
pure risk As we noted in Table 1.2, risk professionals often differentiate between pure risk that features
some chance of loss and no chance of gain (e.g., fire risk, flood risk, etc.) and those they refer to as spec-
Risk that features some
chance of loss and no chance ulative risk. Speculative risks feature a chance to either gain or lose (including investment risk, repu-
of gain. tational risk, strategic risk, etc.). This distinction fits well into Figure 1.3. The right-hand side focuses
on speculative risk. The left-hand side represents pure risk. Risk professionals find this distinction use-
speculative risk ful to differentiate between types of risk.
Risk that features a chance to Some risks can be transferred to a third party—like an insurance company. These third parties can
either gain or lose.
provide a useful “risk management solution.” Some situations, on the other hand, require risk transfers
that use capital markets, known as hedging or securitizations. Hedging refers to activities that are
hedging
taken to reduce or eliminate risks. Securitization is the packaging and transferring of insurance risks
Activities that are taken to to the capital markets through the issuance of a financial security. We explain such risk retention in
reduce or eliminate risks. Chapter 3 and Chapter 13. Risk retention is when a firm retains its risk. In essence it is self-insuring
securitization against adverse contingencies out of its own cash flows. For example, firms might prefer to capture up-
Packaging and transferring
side return potential at the same time that they mitigate while mitigating the downside loss potential.
the insurance risks to the In the business environment, when evaluating the expected financial returns from the introduction
capital markets through the of a new product (which represents speculative risk), other issues concerning product liability must be
issuance of a financial considered. Product liability refers to the possibility that a manufacturer may be liable for harm
security.
caused by use of its product, even if the manufacturer was reasonable in producing it.
risk retention Table 1.2 provides examples of the pure versus speculative risks dichotomy as a way to cross classi-
When a firm retains its risk, fy risks. The examples provided in Table 1.2 are not always a perfect fit into the pure versus speculative
self-insuring against adverse risk dichotomy since each exposure might be regarded in alternative ways. Operational risks, for ex-
contingencies out of its own ample, can be regarded as operations that can cause only loss or operations that can provide also gain.
cash flows. However, if it is more specifically defined, the risks can be more clearly categorized.
product liability
Situation in which a
manufacturer may be liable
for harm caused by use of its
product, even if the
manufacturer was
responsible in producing it.
CHAPTER 1 THE NATURE OF RISK: LOSSES AND OPPORTUNITIES 17
The simultaneous consideration of pure and speculative risks within the objectives continuum of
enterprise risk
Figure 1.3 is an approach to managing risk, which is known as enterprise risk management (ERM). management (ERM)
ERM is one of today’s key risk management approaches. It considers all risks simultaneously and man-
The simultaneous
ages risk in a holistic or enterprise-wide (and risk-wide) context. ERM was listed by the Harvard Busi- consideration of all risks and
ness Review as one of the key breakthrough areas in their 2004 evaluation of strategic management ap- the management of risks in
proaches by top management.[8] In today’s environment, identifying, evaluating, and mitigating all an enterprise-wide (and
risks confronted by the entity is a key focus. Firms that are evaluated by credit rating organizations risk-wide) context.
such as Moody’s or Standard & Poor’s are required to show their activities in the areas of enterprise
risk management. As you will see in later chapters, the risk manager in businesses is no longer buried
in the tranches of the enterprise. Risk managers are part of the executive team and are essential to
achieving the main objectives of the enterprise. A picture of the enterprise risk map of life insurers is
shown later in Figure 1.5.
TABLE 1.2 Examples of Pure versus Speculative Risk Exposures
Pure Risk—Loss or No Loss Only Speculative Risk—Possible
Gains or Losses
Physical damage risk to property (at the enterprise level) such as caused by Market risks: interest risk, foreign
fire, flood, weather damage exchange risk, stock market risk
Liability risk exposure (such as products liability, premise liability, employment Reputational risk
practice liability)
Innovational or technical obsolescence risk Brand risk
Operational risk: mistakes in process or procedure that cause losses Credit risk (at the individual
enterprise level)
Mortality and morbidity risk at the individual level Product success risk
Intellectual property violation risks Public relation risk
Environmental risks: water, air, hazardous-chemical, and other pollution; Population changes
depletion of resources; irreversible destruction of food chains
Natural disaster damage: floods, earthquakes, windstorms Market for the product risk
Man-made destructive risks: nuclear risks, wars, unemployment, population Regulatory change risk
changes, political risks
Mortality and morbidity risk at the societal and global level (as in pandemics, Political risk
social security program exposure, nationalize health care systems, etc.)
Accounting risk
Longevity risk at the societal level
Genetic testing and genetic
engineering risk
Investment risk
Research and development risk
Within the class of pure risk exposures, it is common to further explore risks by use of the dichotomy
of personal property versus liability exposure risk.
Pure and speculative risks are not the only way one might dichotomize risks. Another breakdown is
between catastrophic risks, such as flood and hurricanes, as opposed to accidental losses such as those
caused by accidents such as fires. Another differentiation is by systemic or nondiversifiable risks, as op-
posed to idiosyncratic or diversifiable risks; this is explained below.
Today, there is no media that is not discussing the risks that brought us to the calamity we are enduring
during our current financial crisis. Thus, as opposed to the megacatastrophes of 2001 and 2005, our
concentration is on the failure of risk management in the area of speculative risks or the opportunity in
risks and not as much on the pure risk. A case at point is the little media coverage of the devastation of
Galveston Island from Hurricane Ike during the financial crisis of September 2008. The following box
describes the risks of the first decade of the new millennium.
However, did the myopic concentration on terrorism risk derail the holistic view of risk management and pre-
paredness? The aftermath of Katrina is a testimonial to the lack of risk management. The increase of awareness
and usage of enterprise risk management (ERM) post–September 11 failed to encompass the already well-
known risks of high-category hurricanes on the sustainability of New Orleans levies. The newly created holistic
Homeland Security agency, which houses FEMA, not only did not initiate steps to avoid the disaster, it also did
not take the appropriate steps to reduce the suffering of those afflicted once the risk materialized. This out-
come also points to the importance of having a committed stakeholder who is vested in the outcome and
cares to lower and mitigate the risk. Since the insurance industry did not own the risk of flood, there was a gap
in the risk management. The focus on terrorism risk could be regarded as a contributing factor to the neglect
of the natural disasters risk in New Orleans. The ground was fertile for mishandling the extreme hurricane cata-
strophes. Therefore, from such a viewpoint, it can be argued that September 11 derailed our comprehensive
national risk management and contributed indirectly to the worsening of the effects of Hurricane Katrina.
Furthermore, in an era of financial technology and creation of innovative modeling for predicting the most in-
frequent catastrophes, the innovation and growth in human capacity is at the root of the current credit crisis.
While the innovation allows firms such as Risk Management Solutions (RMS) and AIR Worldwide to provide
models[11] that predict potential man-made and natural catastrophes, financial technology also advanced the
creation of financial instruments, such as credit default derivatives and mortgage-backed securities. The cre-
ation of the products provided “black boxes” understood by few and without appropriate risk management.
Engineers, mathematicians, and quantitatively talented people moved from the low-paying jobs in their re-
spective fields into Wall Street. They used their skills to create models and new products but lacked the busi-
ness acumen and the required safety net understanding to ensure product sustenance. Management of large
financial institutions globally enjoyed the new creativity and endorsed the adoption of the new products
without clear understanding of their potential impact or just because of greed. This lack of risk management is
at the heart of the credit crisis of 2008. No wonder the credit rating organizations are now adding ERM scores
to their ratings of companies.
The following quote is a key to today’s risk management discipline: “Risk management has been a significant
part of the insurance industry…, but in recent times it has developed a wider currency as an emerging man-
agement philosophy across the globe…. The challenge facing the risk management practitioner of the
twenty-first century is not just breaking free of the mantra that risk management is all about insurance, and if
we have insurance, then we have managed our risks, but rather being accepted as a provider of advice and
service to the risk makers and the risk takers at all levels within the enterprise. It is the risk makers and the risk
takers who must be the owners of risk and accountable for its effective management.”[12]
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
< You should be able to delineate the main categories of risks: pure versus speculative, diversifiable versus
nondiversifiable, idiosyncratic versus systemic.
< You should also understand the general concept of enterprise-wide risk.
< Try to illustrate each cross classification of risk with examples.
< Can you discuss the risks of our decade?
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
< In this section you will learn the terminology used by risk professionals to note different risk
concepts.
< You will learn about causes of losses—perils and the hazards, which are the items increasing
the chance of loss.
As we mentioned earlier, in English, people often use the word “risk” to describe a loss. Examples in-
perils
clude hurricane risk or fraud risk. To differentiate between loss and risk, risk management profession-
als prefer to use the term perils to refer to “the causes of loss.” If we wish to understand risk, we must The causes of loss.
first understand the terms “loss” and “perils.” We will use both terms throughout this text. Both terms
represent immediate causes of loss. The environment is filled with perils such as floods, theft, death,
sickness, accidents, fires, tornadoes, and lightning—or even contaminated milk served to Chinese ba-
bies. We include a list of some perils below. Many important risk transfer contracts (such as insurance
contracts) use the word “peril” quite extensively to define inclusions and exclusions within contracts.
We will also explain these definitions in a legal sense later in the textbook to help us determine terms
such as “residual risk retained.”
TABLE 1.4 Types of Perils by Ability to Insure
Natural Perils Human Perils
Generally Insurable Generally Difficult to Insure Generally Insurable Generally Difficult to Insure
Windstorm Flood Theft War
Lightning Earthquake Vandalism Radioactive contamination
Natural combustion Epidemic Hunting accident Civil unrest
Heart attacks Volcanic eruption Negligence Terrorism
Frost Fire and smoke
Global
E-commerce
Mold
Although professionals have attempted to categorize perils, doing so is difficult. We could talk about
natural perils
natural versus human perils. Natural perils are those over which people have little control, such as
Causes of losses over which
hurricanes, volcanoes, and lightning. Human perils, then, would include causes of loss that lie within
people have little control.
individuals’ control, including suicide, terrorism, war, theft, defective products, environmental con-
tamination, terrorism, destruction of complex infrastructure, and electronic security breaches. Though human perils
some would include losses caused by the state of the economy as human perils, many professionals sep- Causes of losses that lie
arate these into a third category labeled economic perils. Professionals also consider employee within individuals’ control.
strikes, arson for profit, and similar situations to be economic perils.
economic perils
We can also divide perils into insurable and noninsurable perils. Typically, noninsurable perils in-
clude those that may be considered catastrophic to an insurer. Such noninsurable perils may also en- Causes of losses resulting
courage policyholders to cause loss. Insurers’ problems rest with the security of its financial standing. from the state of the
economy.
For example, an insurer may decline to write a policy for perils that might threaten its own solvency
(e.g., nuclear power plant liability) or those perils that might motivate insureds to cause a loss.
24 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
5.1 Hazards
Risk professionals refer to hazards as conditions that increase the cause of losses. Hazards may in-
hazards
crease the probability of losses, their frequency, their severity, or both. That is, frequency refers to the
Conditions that increase the
cause of loss.
number of losses during a specified period. Severity refers to the average dollar value of a loss per oc-
currence, respectively. Professionals refer to certain conditions as being “hazardous.” For example,
frequency when summer humidity declines and temperature and wind velocity rise in heavily forested areas, the
The number of losses during likelihood of fire increases. Conditions are such that a forest fire could start very easily and be difficult
a specified period. to contain. In this example, low humidity increases both loss probability and loss severity. The more
hazardous the conditions, the greater the probability and/or severity of loss. Two kinds of haz-
severity
ards—physical and intangible—affect the probability and severity of losses.
The average dollar value of a
loss per claim.
Physical Hazards
We refer to physical hazards as tangible environmental conditions that affect the frequency and/or
physical hazards
severity of loss. Examples include slippery roads, which often increase the number of auto accidents;
Tangible environmental poorly lit stairwells, which add to the likelihood of slips and falls; and old wiring, which may increase
conditions that affect the
frequency and/or severity of
the likelihood of a fire.
loss. Physical hazards that affect property include location, construction, and use. Building locations
affect their susceptibility to loss by fire, flood, earthquake, and other perils. A building located near a
fire station and a good water supply has a lower chance that it will suffer a serious loss by fire than if it
is in an isolated area with neither water nor firefighting service. Similarly, a company that has built a
backup generator will have lower likelihood of a serious financial loss in the event of a power loss
hazard.
Construction affects both the probability and severity of loss. While no building is fireproof, some
construction types are less susceptible to loss from fire than others. But a building that is susceptible to
one peril is not necessarily susceptible to all. For example, a frame building is more apt to burn than a
brick building, but frame buildings may suffer less damage from an earthquake.
Use or occupancy may also create physical hazards. For example, buildings used to manufacture or
store fireworks will have greater probability of loss by fire than do office buildings. Likewise, buildings
used for dry cleaning (which uses volatile chemicals) will bear a greater physical hazard than do ele-
mentary schools. Cars used for business purposes may be exposed to greater chance of loss than a typ-
ical family car since businesses use vehicles more extensively and in more dangerous settings. Similarly,
people have physical characteristics that affect loss. Some of us have brittle bones, weak immune sys-
tems, or vitamin deficiencies. Any of these characteristics could increase the probability or severity of
health expenses.
Intangible Hazards
Here we distinguish between physical hazards and intangible hazards—attitudes and nonphysical
intangible hazards
cultural conditions can affect loss probabilities and severities of loss. Their existence may lead to phys-
Attitudes and nonphysical ical hazards. Traditionally, authors of insurance texts categorize these conditions as moral and morale
cultural conditions can affect
loss probabilities and
hazards, which are important concepts but do not cover the full range of nonphysical hazards. Even the
severities of loss. distinction between moral and morale hazards is fuzzy.
Moral hazards are hazards that involve behavior that can be construed as negligence or that bor-
moral hazards ders on criminality. They involve dishonesty on the part of people who take out insurance (called
“insureds”). Risk transfer through insurance invites moral hazard by potentially encouraging those
Hazards that involve behavior
that can be construed as who transfer risks to cause losses intentionally for monetary gain. Generally, moral hazards exist when
negligence bordering on a person can gain from the occurrence of a loss. For example, an insured that will be reimbursed for the
criminality. cost of a new stereo system following the loss of an old one has an incentive to cause loss. An insured
business that is losing money may have arson as a moral hazard. Such incentives increase loss probabil-
ities; as the name “moral” implies, moral hazard is a breach of morality (honesty).
morale hazards Morale hazards, in contrast, do not involve dishonesty. Rather, morale hazards involve attitudes
of carelessness and lack of concern. As such, morale hazards increase the chance a loss will occur or in-
Hazards that involve attitudes
of carelessness and lack of
crease the size of losses that do occur. Poor housekeeping (e.g., allowing trash to accumulate in attics or
concern. basements) or careless cigarette smoking are examples of morale hazards that increase the probability
fire losses. Often, such lack of concern occurs because a third party (such as an insurer) is available to
pay for losses. A person or company that knows they are insured for a particular loss exposure may
take less precaution to protect this exposure than otherwise. Nothing dishonest lurks in not locking
your car or in not taking adequate care to reduce losses, so these don’t represent morality breaches.
Both practices, however, increase the probability of loss severity.
Many people unnecessarily and often unconsciously create morale hazards that can affect their
health and life expectancy. Such hazards include excessive use of tobacco, drugs, and other harmful
CHAPTER 1 THE NATURE OF RISK: LOSSES AND OPPORTUNITIES 25
substances; poor eating, sleeping, and exercise habits; unnecessary exposure to falls, poisoning, electro-
cution, radiation, venomous stings and bites, and air pollution; and so forth.
Hazards are critical because our ability to reduce their effects will reduce both overall costs and
variability. Hazard management, therefore, can be a highly effective risk management tool. At this
point, many corporations around the world emphasize disaster control management to reduce the im-
pact of biological or terrorist attacks. Safety inspections in airports are one example of disaster control
management that intensified after September 11. See "Is Airport Security Worth It to You?" for a dis-
cussion of safety in airports.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
b. For the pure risk situations you noted in part 1 of this exercise, name three hazards that
could be controlled by the employees of the department store.
c. If you were manager of the store, would you want all these operations? Which—if
any—would you eliminate? Explain.
20. Omer Laskwood, the major income earner for a family of four, was overheard saying to his friend
Vince, “I don’t carry any life insurance because I’m young, and I know from statistics few people
die at my age.”
a. What are your feelings about this statement?
b. How does Omer perceive risk relative to his situation?
c. What characteristic in this situation is more important than the likelihood of Mr.
Laskwood dying?
d. Are there other risks Omer should consider?
21. The council members of Flatburg are very proud of the proposed new airport they are discussing
at a council meeting. When it is completed, Flatburg will finally have regular commercial air
service. Some type of fire protection is needed at the new airport, but a group of citizens is
protesting that Flatburg cannot afford to purchase another fire engine. The airport could share
the downtown fire station, or the firehouse could be moved to the airport five miles away.
Someone suggested a compromise—move the facilities halfway. As the council members left their
meeting that evening, they had questions regarding this problem.
a. What questions would you raise?
b. How would you handle this problem using the information discussed in this chapter?
28 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
4. See http://www.dhs.gov/dhspublic/.
ENDNOTES 5. The student is invited to read archival articles from all media sources about the
calamity of the poor response to the floods in New Orleans. The insurance studies of
Virginia Commonwealth University held a town hall meeting the week after Katrina
to discuss the natural and man-made disasters and their impact both financially and
1. David J. Lynch, “Global Financial Crisis May Hit Hardest Outside U.S.,” USA Today, socially. The PowerPoint basis for the discussion is available to the readers.
October 30, 2008. The initial thought that the trouble was more a U.S. isolated
trouble “laid low by a Wall Street culture of heedless risk-taking” and the thinking 6. See http://www.dhs.gov/dhspublic/.
was that “the U.S. will lose its status as the superpower of the global financial sys-
tem…. Now everyone realizes they are in this global mess together. Reflecting that 7. Etti G. Baranoff, “The Risk Balls Game: Transforming Risk and Insurance Into Tangible
shared fate, Asian and European leaders gathered Saturday in Beijing to brainstorm Concept,” Risk Management & Insurance Review 4, no. 2 (2001): 51–59.
ahead of a Nov. 15 international financial summit in Washington, D.C.”
8. L. Buchanan, “Breakthrough Ideas for 2004,” Harvard Business Review 2 (2004): 13–16.
2. In essence, a credit derivative is a financial instrument issued by one firm, which
9. Etti G. Baranoff and Thomas W. Sager, “Integrated Risk Management in Life Insurance
guarantees payment for contracts of another party. The guarantees are provided un-
der a second contract. Should the issuer of the second contract not perform—for ex- Companies,” an award winning paper, International Insurance Society Seminar, Chica-
ample, by defaulting or going bankrupt—the second contract goes into effect. go, July 2006 and in Special Edition of the Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance.
When the mortgages defaulted, the supposed guarantor did not have enough 10. Reprinted with permission from the author; Etti G. Baranoff, “Risk Management and
money to pay their contract obligations. This caused others (who were counting on Insurance During the Decade of September 11,” in The Day that Changed Everything?
the payment) to default as well on other obligations. This snowball effect then An Interdisciplinary Series of Edited Volumes on the Impact of 9/11, vol. 2.
caused others to default, and so forth. It became a chain reaction that generated a
global financial market collapse. 11. http://www.rms.com, http://www.iso.com/index.php?option=
com_content&task=view&id=932&Itemid=587, and http://www.iso.com/
3. This lack of risk management cannot be blamed on lack of warning of the risk alone. index.php?option= com_content&task=view&id=930&Itemid=585.
Regulators and firms were warned to adhere to risk management procedures.
However, these warnings were ignored in pursuit of profit and “free markets.” See 12. Laurent Condamin, Jean-Paul Louisot, and Patrick Maim, “Risk Quantification: Man-
“The Crash: Risk and Regulation, What Went Wrong” by Anthony Faiola, Ellen agement, Diagnosis and Hedging” (Chichester, UK: John Wiley & Sons Ltd., 2006).
Nakashima, and Jill Drew, Washington Post, October 15, 2008, A01.
CHAP TER 2
Risk Measurement and
Metrics
In Chapter 1, we discussed how risk arises as a consequence of uncertainty. Recall also that risk is not the state of
uncertainty itself. Risk and uncertainty are connected and yet are distinct concepts.
In this chapter, we will discuss the ways in which we measure risk and uncertainty. If we wish to understand
and use the concepts of risk and uncertainty, we need to be able to measure these concepts’ outcomes.
Psychological and economic research shows that emotions such as fear, dread, ambiguity avoidance, and feelings
of emotional loss represent valid risks. Such feelings are thus relevant to decision making under uncertainty. Our
focus here, however, will draw more on financial metrics rather than emotional or psychological measures of risk
perception. In this chapter, we thus discuss measurable and quantifiable outcomes and how we can measure risk
A “metric” in this context is a system of related measures that helps us quantify characteristics or qualities. Any
individual or enterprise needs to be able to quantify risk before they can decide whether or not a particular risk is
critical enough to commit resources to manage. If such resources have been committed, then we need
measurements to see whether the risk management process or procedure has reduced risk. And all forms of
enterprises, for financial profit or for social profit, must strive to reduce risk. Without risk metrics, enterprises cannot
tell whether or not they have reached risk management objectives. Enterprises including businesses hold risk
management to be as important as any other objective, including profitability. Without risk metrics to measure
success, failure, or incremental improvement, we cannot judge progress in the control of risk.
Risk management provides a framework for assessing opportunities for profit, as well as for gauging threats of
loss. Without measuring risk, we cannot ascertain what action of the available alternatives the enterprise should
take to optimize the risk-reward tradeoff. The risk-reward tradeoff is essentially a cost-benefit analysis taking
uncertainty into account. In (economic) marginal analysis terms, we want to know how many additional units of risk
we need to take on in order to get an additional unit of reward or profit. A firm, for example, wants to know how
much capital it needs to keep from going insolvent if a bad risk is realized.[1] Indeed, if they cannot measure risk,
enterprises are stuck in the ancient world of being helpless to act in the face of uncertainty. Risk metrics allow us to
measure risk, giving us an ability to control risk and simultaneously exploit opportunities as they arise. No one
profits from establishing the existence of an uncertain state of nature. Instead, managers must measure and assess
their enterprise’s degree of vulnerability (risk) and sensitivity to the various potential states of nature. After reading
this chapter, you should be able to define several different risk metrics and be able to discuss when each metric is
We will discuss several risk measures here, each of which comes about from the progression of mathematical
approaches to describing and evaluating risk. We emphasize from the start, however, that measuring risk using
30 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
these risk metrics is only one step as we assess any opportunity-risk issue. Risk metrics cannot stand alone. We must
also evaluate how appropriate each underlying model might be for the occasion. Further, we need to evaluate
each question in terms of the risk level that each entity is willing to assume for the gain each hopes to receive.
Firms must understand the assumptions behind worst-case or ruin scenarios, since most firms do not want to take
on risks that “bet the house.” To this end, knowing the severity of losses that might be expected in the future
(severity is the dollar value per claim) using forecasting models represents one aspect of quantifying risk. However,
financial decision making requires that we evaluate severity levels based upon what an individual or a firm can
comfortably endure (risk appetite). Further, we must evaluate the frequency with which a particular outcome will
occur. As with the common English language usage of the term, frequency is the number of times the event is
expected to occur in a specified period of time. The 2008 financial crisis provides an example: Poor risk
management of the financial models used for creating mortgage-backed securities and credit default derivatives
contributed to a worldwide crisis. The assessment of loss frequency, particularly managers’ assessment of the
severity of losses, was grossly underestimated. We discuss risk assessment using risk metrics in the pages that follow.
As we noted in Chapter 1, risk is a concept encompassing perils, hazards, exposures, and perception (with a
strong emphasis on perception). It should come as no surprise that the metrics for measuring risk are also quite
varied. The aspect of risk being considered in a particular situation dictates the risk measure used. If we are
interested in default risk (the risk that a contracting party will be unable to live up to the terms of some financial
contract, usually due to total ruin or bankruptcy), then one risk measure might be employed. If, on the other hand,
we are interested in expected fluctuations of retained earnings for paying future losses, then we would likely use
another risk measure. If we wish to know how much risk is generated by a risky undertaking that cannot be
diversified away in the marketplace, then we would use yet another risk measure. Each risk measure has its place
and appropriate application. One part of the art of risk management is to pick the appropriate risk measure for each
situation.
1. Links
1. LINKS
The first step in developing any framework for the measuring risk quantitatively involves creating a
framework for addressing and studying uncertainty itself. Such a framework lies within the realm of
probability. Since risk arises from uncertainty, measures of risk must also take uncertainty into ac-
count. The process of quantifying uncertainty, also known as probability theory, actually proved to be
surprisingly difficult and took millennia to develop. Progress on this front required that we develop two
fundamental ideas. The first is a way to quantify uncertainty (probability) of potential states of the
world. Second, we had to develop the notion that the outcomes of interest to human events, the risks,
were subject to some kind of regularity that we could predict and that would remain stable over time.
Developing and accepting these two notions represented path-breaking, seminal changes from previ-
ous mindsets. Until research teams made and accepted these steps, any firm, scientific foundation for
developing probability and risk was impossible.
Solving risk problems requires that we compile a puzzle of the many personal and business risks.
First, we need to obtain quantitative measures of each risk. Again, as in Chapter 1, we repeat the Link
puzzle in Figure 2.1. The point illustrated in Figure 2.1 is that we face many varied risk exposures,
CHAPTER 2 RISK MEASUREMENT AND METRICS 31
appropriate risk measures, and statistical techniques that we apply for different risks. However, most
risks are interconnected. When taken together, they provide a holistic risk measure for the firm or a
family. For some risks, measures are not sophisticated and easy to achieve, such as the risk of potential
fires in a region. Sometimes trying to predict potential risks is much more complex, such as predicting
one-hundred-year floods in various regions. For each type of peril and hazard, we may well have differ-
ent techniques to measure the risks. Our need to realize that catastrophes can happen and our need to
account for them are of paramount importance. The 2008–2009 financial crisis may well have occurred
in part because the risk measures in use failed to account for the systemic collapses of the financial in-
stitutions. Mostly, institutions toppled because of a result of the mortgage-backed securities and the
real estate markets. As we explore risk computations and measures throughout this chapter, you will
learn terminology and understand how we use such measures. You will thus embark on a journey into
the world of risk management. Some measures may seem simplistic. Other measures will show you
how to use complex models that use the most sophisticated state-of-the-art mathematical and statistical
technology. You’ll notice also that many computations would be impossible without the advent of
powerful computers and computation memory. Now, on to the journey.
FIGURE 2.1 Links between Each Holistic Risk Puzzle Piece and Its Computational Measures
32 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
< In this section, you will learn how to quantify the relative frequency of occurrences of uncertain
events by using probability models.
< You will learn about the measures of frequency, severity, likelihood, statistical distributions,
and expected values.
< You will use examples to compute these values.
As we consider uncertainty, we use rigorous quantitative studies of chance, the recognition of its em-
pirical regularity in uncertain situations. Many of these methods are used to quantify the occurrence of
uncertain events that represent intellectual milestones. As we create models based upon probability and
statistics, you will likely recognize that probability and statistics touch nearly every field of study today.
As we have internalized the predictive regularity of repeated chance events, our entire worldview has
changed. For example, we have convinced ourselves of the odds of getting heads in a coin flip so much
that it’s hard to imagine otherwise. We’re used to seeing statements such as “average life of 1,000
hours” on a package of light bulbs. We understand such a phrase because we can think of the length of
life of a light bulb as being uncertain but statistically predictable. We routinely hear such statements as
“The chance of rain tomorrow is 20 percent.” It’s hard for us to imagine that only a few centuries ago
people did not believe even in the existence of chance occurrences or random events or in accidents,
much less explore any method of quantifying seemingly chance events. Up until very recently, people
have believed that God controlled every minute detail of the universe. This belief rules out any kind of
conceptualization of chance as a regular or predictable phenomenon. For example, until recently the
cost of buying a life annuity that paid buyers $100 per month for life was the same for a thirty-year-old
as it was for a seventy-year-old. It didn’t matter that empirically, the “life expectancy” of a thirty-year-
old was four times longer than that of a seventy-year-old.[2] After all, people believed that a person’s
particular time of death was “God’s will.” No one believed that the length of someone’s life could be
judged or predicted statistically by any noticed or exhibited regularity across people. In spite of the ad-
vancements in mathematics and science since the beginning of civilization, remarkably, the develop-
ment of measures of relative frequency of occurrence of uncertain events did not occur until the 1600s.
This birth of the “modern” ideas of chance occurred when a problem was posed to mathematician
Blaisé Pascal by a frequent gambler. As often occurs, the problem turned out to be less important in the
long run than the solution developed to solve the problem.
The problem posed was: If two people are gambling and the game is interrupted and discontinued
before either one of the two has won, what is a fair way to split the pot of money on the table? Clearly
the person ahead at that time had a better chance of winning the game and should have gotten more.
The player in the lead would receive the larger portion of the pot of money. However, the person losing
could come from behind and win. It could happen and such a possibility should not be excluded. How
should the pot be split fairly? Pascal formulated an approach to this problem and, in a series of letters
with Pierre de Fermat, developed an approach to the problem that entailed writing down all possible
outcomes that could possibly occur and then counting the number of times the first gambler won. The
proportion of times that the first gambler won (calculated as the number of times the gambler won di-
vided by the total number of possible outcomes) was taken to be the proportion of the pot that the first
gambler could fairly claim. In the process of formulating this solution, Pascal and Fermat more gener-
ally developed a framework to quantify the relative frequency of uncertain outcomes, which is now
known as probability. They created the mathematical notion of expected value of an uncertain event.
They were the first to model the exhibited regularity of chance or uncertain events and apply it to solve
a practical problem. In fact, their solution pointed to many other potential applications to problems in
law, economics, and other fields.
model
From Pascal and Fermat’s work, it became clear that to manage future risks under uncertainty, we
need to have some idea about not only the possible outcomes or states of the world but also how likely
A symbolic representation of
the possible outcomes.
each outcome is to occur. We need a model, or in other words, a symbolic representation of the pos-
sible outcomes and their likelihoods or relative frequencies.
CHAPTER 2 RISK MEASUREMENT AND METRICS 33
TABLE 2.2 Claims and Fire Losses ($) for Homes in Location B
Year Number of Fire Claims Fire Losses Average Loss per Claim ($)
1 15 16,500.00 1,100.00
2 5 40,000.00 8,000.00
3 12 30,000.00 2,500.00
4 10 123,000.00 12,300.00
5 9 105,000.00 11,666.67
Total 51.00 314,500.00 6,166.67
Mean 10.20 62,900.00 6,166.67
Average frequency = 10.20
Average severity = 6,166.67 for the 5-year period
As shown in Table 2.1 and Table 2.2, the total number of fire claims for the two locations A and B is the
same, as is the total dollar amount of losses shown. You might recall from earlier, the number of claims
per year is called the frequency. The average frequency of claims for locations A and B is 10.2 per year.
The size of the loss in terms of dollars lost per claim is called severity, as we noted previously. The aver-
age dollars lost per claim per year in each location is $6,166.67.
The most important measures for risk managers when they address potential losses that arise from
uncertainty are usually those associated with frequency and severity of losses during a specified period
of time. The use of frequency and severity data is very important to both insurers and firm managers
concerned with judging the risk of various endeavors. Risk managers try to employ activities (physical
construction, backup systems, financial hedging, insurance, etc.) to decrease the frequency or severity
(or both) of potential losses. In Chapter 3, we will see frequency data and severity data represented.
Typically, the risk manager will relate the number of incidents under investigation to a base, such as
the number of employees if examining the frequency and severity of workplace injuries. In the ex-
amples in Table 2.1 and Table 2.2, the severity is related to the number of fire claims in the five-year
period per 1,000 homes. It is important to note that in these tables the precise distribution (frequencies
and dollar losses) over the years for the claims per year arising in Location A is different from distribu-
tion for Location B. This will be discussed later in this chapter. Next, we discuss the concept of fre-
quency in terms of probability or likelihood.
CHAPTER 2 RISK MEASUREMENT AND METRICS 35
FIGURE 2.2 Possible Outcomes for a Roll of Two Dice with the Probability of Having a Particular
Number of Dots Facing Up
Figure 2.2 lists the probabilities for the number of dots facing upward (2, 3, 4, etc.) in a roll of two
colored dice. We can calculate the probability for any one of these numbers (2, 3, 4, etc.) by adding up
the number of outcomes (rolls of two dice) that result in this number of dots facing up divided by the
total number of possibilities. For example, a roll of thirty-six possibilities total when we roll two dice
(count them). The probability of rolling a 2 is 1/36 (we can only roll a 2 one way, namely, when both
dice have a 1 facing up). The probability of rolling a 7 is 6/36 = 1/6 (since rolls can fall any of six ways
to roll a 7—1 and 6 twice, 2 and 5 twice, 3 and 4 twice). For any other choice of number of dots facing
upward, we can get the probability by just adding the number of ways the event can occur divided by
thirty-six. The probability of rolling a 7 or an 11 (5 and 6 twice) on a throw of the dice, for instance, is
(6 + 2)/36 = 2/9.
The notions of “equally likely outcomes” and the calculation of probabilities as the ratio of “the
number of ways in which an event could occur, divided by the total number of equally likely outcomes”
is seminal and instructive. But, it did not include situations in which the number of possible outcomes
was (at least conceptually) unbounded or infinite or not equally likely.[4] We needed an extension. No-
ticing that the probability of an event, any event, provided that extension. Further, extending the the-
ory to nonequally likely possible outcomes arose by noticing that the probability of an event—any
event—occurring could be calculated as the relative frequency of an event occurring in a long run of
trials in which the event may or may not occur. Thus, different events could have different, nonequal
chances of occurring in a long repetition of scenarios involving the possible occurrences of the events.
Table 2.3 provides an example of this. We can extend the theory yet further to a situation in which the
number of possible outcomes is potentially infinite. But what about a situation in which no easily defin-
able bound on the number of possible outcomes can be found? We can address this situation by again
using the relative frequency interpretation of probability as well. When we have a continuum of pos-
sible outcomes (e.g., if an outcome is time, we can view it as a continuous variable outcome), then a
curve of relative frequency is created. Thus, the probability of an outcome falling between two numbers
x and y is the area under the frequency curve between x and y. The total area under the curve is one
reflecting that it’s 100 percent certain that some outcome will occur.
The so-called normal distribution or bell-shaped curve from statistics provides us with an example
of such a continuous probability distribution curve. The bell-shaped curve represents a situation
wherein a continuum of possible outcomes arises. Figure 2.3 provides such a bell-shaped curve for the
profitability of implementing a new research and development project. It may have profit or loss.
CHAPTER 2 RISK MEASUREMENT AND METRICS 37
FIGURE 2.3 Normal Distribution of Potential Profit from a Research and Development Project
To find the probability of any range of profitability values for this research and development project,
we find the area under the curve in Figure 2.3 between the desired range of profitability values. For ex-
ample, the distribution in Figure 2.3 was constructed to have what is called a normal distribution with
the hump over the point $30 million and a measure of spread of $23 million. This spread represents the
standard deviation that we will discuss in the next section. We can calculate the area under the curve
above $0, which will be the probability that we will make a profit by implementing the research and de-
velopment project. We do this by reference to a normal distribution table of values available in any
statistics book. The area under the curve is 0.904, meaning that we have approximately a 90 percent
change (probability of 0.9) that the project will result in a profit.
In practice, we build probability distribution tables or probability curves such as those in Figure
2.2, Figure 2.3, and Table 2.3 using estimates of the likelihood (probability) of various different states of
nature based on either historical relative frequency of occurrence or theoretical data. For example, em-
pirical data may come from repeated observations in similar situations such as with historically con-
structed life or mortality tables. Theoretical data may come from a physics or engineering assessment
of failure likelihood for a bridge or nuclear power plant containment vessel. In some situations,
however, we can determine the likelihoods subjectively or by expert opinion. For example, assessments
of political overthrows of governments are used for pricing political risk insurance needed by corpora-
tions doing business in emerging markets. Regardless of the source of the likelihoods, we can obtain an
assessment of the probabilities or relative frequencies of the future occurrence of each conceivable
event. The resulting collection of possible events together with their respective probabilities of occur-
rence is called a probability distribution, an example of which is shown in Table 2.3.
the new market. How does one calculate these gains and losses? We already demonstrated some calcu-
lations in the examples above in Table 2.1 and Table 2.2 for the claims and fire losses for homes in loca-
tions A and B. These examples concentrated on the consequences of the uncertainty about fires.
Another way to compute the same type of consequences is provided in the example in Table 2.3 for the
probability distribution for this new market entry. We look for an assessment of the financial con-
sequences of the entry into the market as well. This example looks at a few possible outcomes, not only
the fire losses outcome. These outcomes can have positive or negative consequences. Therefore, we use
the opportunity terminology here rather than only the loss possibilities.
TABLE 2.3 Opportunity and Loss Assessment Consequences of New Product Market Entry
State of Nature Probability Assessment of Financial Consequences of Being in This
Likelihood of State State (in Millions of Dollars)
Subject to a loss in a product .01 −10.2
liability lawsuit
Market acceptance is limited and .10 −.50
temporary
Some market acceptance but no .40 .10
great consumer demand
Good market acceptance and sales .40 1
performance
Great market demand and sales .09 8
performance
As you can see, it’s not the uncertainty of the states themselves that causes decision makers to ponder
the advisability of market entry of a new product. It’s the consequences of the different outcomes that
cause deliberation. The firm could lose $10.2 million or gain $8 million. If we knew which state would
materialize, the decision would be simple. We address the issue of how we combine the probability as-
sessment with the value of the gain or loss for the purpose of assessing the risk (consequences of uncer-
tainty) in the next section.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
In this section you learned about the quantification of uncertain outcomes via probability models. More spe-
cifically, you delved into methods of computing:
< Severity as a measure of the consequence of uncertainty—it is the expected value or average value of the
loss that arises in different states of the world. Severity can be obtained by adding all the loss values in a
sample and dividing by the total sample size.
< If we take a table of probabilities (probability distribution), the expected value is obtained by multiplying
the probability of a particular loss occurring times the size of the loss and summing over all possibilities.
< Frequency is the expected number of occurrences of the loss that arises in different states of the world.
< Likelihood and probability distribution represent relative frequency of occurrence (frequency of
occurrence of the event divided by the total frequency of all events) of different events in uncertain
situations.
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. A study of data losses incurred by companies due to hackers penetrating the Internet security of the firm
found that 60 percent of the firms in the industry studied had experienced security breaches and that the
average loss per security breach was $15,000.
a. What is the probability that a firm will not have a security breach?
b. One firm had two breaches in one year and is contemplating spending money to decrease the
likelihood of a breach. Assuming that the next year would be the same as this year in terms of
security breaches, how much should the firm be willing to pay to eliminate security breaches (i.e.,
what is the expected value of their loss)?
2. The following is the experience of Insurer A for the last three years:
a. Calculate the mean or average number of claims per year for the insurer over the three-year
period.
b. Calculate the mean or average dollar value of collision losses per exposure for year 2.
c. Calculate the expected value (mean or average) of losses per claim over the three-year period.
d. For each of the three years, calculate the probability that an exposure unit will file a claim.
e. What is the average frequency of losses?
f. What is the average severity of the losses?
g. What is the standard deviation of the losses?
h. Calculate the coefficient of variation.
40 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E
< In this section, you will learn how to compute several common measures of risk using various
methods and statistical concepts.
Having developed the concept of probability to quantify the relative likelihood of an uncertain event,
and having developed a measure of “expected value” for an uncertain event, we are now ready to try to
quantify risk itself. The “expected value” (or mean value or fair value) quantifying the potential out-
come arising from an uncertain scenario or situation in which probabilities have been assigned is a
common input into the decision-making process concerning the advisability of taking certain actions,
but it is not the only consideration. The financial return outcomes of various uncertain research and
development, might, for example, be almost identical except that the return distributions are sort of
shifted in one direction or the other. Such a situation is shown in Figure 2.4. This figure describes the
(continuous) distributions of anticipated profitability for each of three possible capital expenditures on
uncertain research and development projects. These are labeled A, B, and C, respectively.
FIGURE 2.4 Possible Profitability from Three Potential Research and Development Projects
Intuitively, in economic terms a risk is a “surprise” outcome that is a consequence of uncertainty. It can
be a positive surprise or a negative surprise, as we discussed in Chapter 1.
Using the terms explained in the last section, we can regard risk as the deviation from the expected
value. The more an observation deviates from what we expected, the more surprised we are likely to be-
come if we should see it, and hence the more risky (in an economic sense) we deem the outcome to be.
Intuitively, the more surprise we “expect” from a venture or a scenario, the riskier we judge this ven-
ture or scenario to be.
Looking back on Figure 2.4, we might say that all three curves actually represent the same level of
risk in that they each differ from their expected value (the mean or hump of the distribution) in
identical ways. They only differ in their respective expected level of profitability (the hump in the
curve). Note that the uncertain scenarios “B” and “C” still describe risky situations, even though
CHAPTER 2 RISK MEASUREMENT AND METRICS 41
virtually all of the possible outcomes of these uncertain scenarios are in the positive profit range. The
“risk” resides in the deviations from the expected value that might result (the surprise potential),
whether on the average the result is negative or positive. Look at the distribution labeled “A,” which de-
scribes a scenario or opportunity/loss description where much more of the possible results are on the
negative range (damages or losses). Economists don’t consider “A” to be any more risky (or more dan-
gerous) than “B” or “C,” but simply less profitable. The deviation from any expected risk defines risk
here. We can plan for negative as well as positive outcomes if we know what to expect. A certain negat-
ive value may be unfortunate, but it is not risky.
Some other uncertain situations or scenarios will have the same expected level of “profitability,”
but will differ in the amount of “surprise” they might present. For example, let’s assume that we have
three potential corporate project investment opportunities. We expect that, over a decade, the average
profitability in each opportunity will amount to $30 million. The projects differ, however, by the level
of uncertainty involved in this profitability assessment (see Figure 2.5). In Opportunity A, the possible
range of profitability is $5–$60 million, whereas Opportunity B has a larger range of possible profits,
between –$20 million and + $90 million. The third opportunity still has an expected return of $30 mil-
lion, but now the range of values is from –$40 million to +$100. You could make more from Oppor-
tunity C, but you could lose more, as well. The deviation of the results around the expected value can
measure the level of “surprise” potential the uncertain situation or profit/loss scenario contains. The
uncertain situation concerning the profitability in Opportunity B contains a larger potential surprise in
it than A, since we might get a larger deviation from the expected value in B than in A. That’s why we
consider Opportunity B more risky than A. Opportunity C is the riskiest of all, having the possibility of
a giant $100 million return, with the downside potential of creating a $40 million loss.
FIGURE 2.5 Three Corporate Opportunities Having the Same Expected Profitability but Differing in
Risk or Surprise Potential
Our discussion above is based upon intuition rather than mathematics. To make it specific, we need to
actually define quantitatively what we mean by the terms “a surprise” and “more surprised.” To this
end, we must focus on the objective of the analysis. A sequence of throws of a pair of colored dice in
which the red die always lands to the left of the green die may be surprising, but this surprise is irrelev-
ant if the purpose of the dice throw is to play a game in which the number of dots facing up determines
the pay off. We thus recognize that we must define risk in a context of the goal of the endeavor or
study. If we are most concerned about the risk of insolvency, we may use one risk measure, while if we
42 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
are interested in susceptibility of portfolio of assets to moderate interest rate changes, we may use an-
other measure of risk. Context is everything. Let’s discuss several risk measures that are appropriate in
different situations.
The Range
We can use the range of the distribution—that is, the distance between the highest possible outcome
range
value to the lowest—as a rough risk measure. The range provides an idea about the “worst-case” dis-
The distance between the persion of successive surprises. By taking the “best-case scenario minus the worst-case scenario” we
highest possible outcome
value to the lowest in a
define the potential breadth of outcomes that could arise in the uncertain situation.
distribution. As an example, consider the number of claims per year in Location A of Table 2.1. Table 2.1 shows
a low of seven claims per year to a high of fourteen claims per year, for a range of seven claims per year.
For Location B of Table 2.2, we have a range in the number of claims from a low of five in one year to a
high of fifteen claims per year, which gives us a range of ten claims per year. Using the range measure
of risk, we would say that Location A is less risky than Location B in this situation, especially since the
average claim is the same (10.2) in each case and we have more variability or surprise potential in Loca-
tion B. As another example, if we go back to the distribution of possible values in Table 2.3, the ex-
tremes vary from −$10.2 million to +$8 million, so the range is $18.2 million.
This risk measure leaves the picture incomplete because it cannot distinguish in riskiness between
two distributions of situations where the possible outcomes are unbounded, nor does it take into ac-
count the frequency or probability of the extreme values. The lower value of –$10.2 million in Table 2.3
only occurs 1 percent of the time, so it’s highly unlikely that you would get a value this small. It could
have had an extreme value of –$100 million, which occurred with probability 0.0000000001, in which
case the range would have reflected this possibility. Note that it’s extremely unlikely that you would
ever experience a one-in-a-trillion event. Usually you would not want your risk management activities
or managerial actions to be dictated by a one-in-a-trillion event.
years are all treated equally so the average squared deviation from the mean is just the simple average
of the five years squared deviations from the mean. We calculate the variance of the number of claims
only.
TABLE 2.4 Variance and Standard Deviation of Fire Claims of Location A
Year Number of Fire Difference between Observed Number of Claims and Mean Difference
Claims Number of Claims Squared
1 11 0.8 0.64
2 9 −1.2 1.44
3 7 −3.2 10.24
4 10 −0.2 0.04
5 14 3.8 14.44
Total 51 0 26.8
Mean 10.2 = (26.8)/4 = 6.7
Variance 6.70
Standard Deviation = Square Root (6.7) = 2.59
A problem with the variance as a measure of risk is that by squaring the individual deviations from the
mean, you end up with a measure that is in squared units (e.g., if the original losses are measured in
dollars, then the variance is measured in dollars-squared). To get back to the original units of measure-
ment we commonly take the square root and obtain a risk measure known as the standard deviation,
denoted by the Greek letter sigma (σ). To provide a more meaningful measure of risk denominated in
the same units as the original data, economists and risk professionals often use this square root of the
variance—the standard deviation—as a measure of risk. It provides a value comparable with the origin-
al expected outcomes. Remember that variance uses squared differences; therefore, taking the square
root returns the measure to its initial unit of measurement.
Thus, the standard deviation is the square root of the variance. For the distribution in Table 2.3,
we calculated the variance to be 7.445, so the standard deviation is the square root of 7.445 or $2.73
million. Similarly, the standard deviations of locations A and B of Table 2.1 and Table 2.2 appear in
Tables 2.4 and 2.5. As you can see, the standard deviation of the sample for Location A is only 2.59,
while the standard deviation of the sample of Location B is 2.70. The number of fire claims in Location
B is more spread out from year to year than those in Location A. The standard deviation is the numeric
representation of that spread.
If we compare one standard deviation with another distribution of equal mean but larger standard
deviation—as when we compare the claims distribution from Location A with Location B—we could
say that the second distribution with the larger standard deviation is riskier than the first. It is riskier
because the observations are, on average, further away from the mean (more spread out and hence
providing more “surprise” potential) than the observations in the first distribution. Larger standard de-
viations, therefore, represent greater risk, everything else being the same.
44 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
Of course, distributions seldom have the same mean. What if we are comparing two distributions
coefficient of variation
with different means? In this case, one approach would be to consider the coefficient of variation,
The standard deviation of a which is the standard deviation of a distribution divided by its mean. It essentially trades off risk (as
distribution divided by its
mean.
measured by the standard deviation) with the return (as measured by the mean or expected value). The
coefficient of variation can be used to give us a relative value of risk when the means of the distribu-
tions are not equal.
The Semivariance
The above measures of risk gave the same attention or importance to both positive and negative devi-
semivariance
ations from the mean or expected value. Some people prefer to measure risk by the surprises in one dir-
The average square deviation ection only. Usually only negative deviations below the expected value are considered risky and in need
of values in a distribution. of control or management. For example, a decision maker might be especially troubled by deviations
below the expected level of profit and would welcome deviations above the expected value. For this
purpose a “semivariance” could serve as a more appropriate measure of risk than the variance, which
treats deviations in both directions the same. The semivariance is the average square deviation. Now
you sum only the deviations below the expected value. If the profit-loss distribution is symmetric, the
use of the semivariance turns out to result in the exact same ranking of uncertain outcomes with re-
spect to risk as the use of the variance. If the distribution is not symmetric, however, then these meas-
ures may differ and the decisions made as to which distribution of uncertain outcomes is riskier will
differ, and the decisions made as to how to manage risk as measured by these two measures may be
different. As most financial and pure loss distributions are asymmetric, professionals often prefer the
semi-variance in financial analysis as a measure of risk, even though the variance (and standard devi-
ation) are also commonly used.
3.2 Value at Risk (VaR) and Maximum Probable Annual Loss (MPAL)
How do banks and other financial institutions manage the systemic or fundamental market risks they
Value at Risk (VaR)
face? VaR modeling has become the standard risk measurement tool in the banking industry to assess
The worst-case scenario market risk exposure. After the banking industry adopted VaR, many other financial firms adopted it
dollar value loss (up to a
specified probability level)
as well. This is in part because of the acceptance of this technique by regulators, such as conditions
that could occur for a written in the Basel II agreements on bank regulation.[8] Further, financial institutions need to know
company exposed to a how much money they need to reserve to be able to withstand a shock or loss of capital and still remain
specific set of risks. solvent. To do so, they need a risk measure with a specified high probability. Intuitively, VaR is defined
as the worst-case scenario dollar value loss (up to a specified probability level) that could occur for a
company exposed to a specific set of risks (interest rates, equity prices, exchange rates, and commodity
prices). This is the amount needed to have in reserve in order to stave off insolvency with the specified
level of probability.
In reality, for many risk exposures the absolute “worst-case” loss that could be experienced is con-
ceivably unbounded. It’s conceivable that you could lose a very huge amount but it may be highly un-
likely to lose this much. Thus, instead of picking the largest possible loss to prepare against, the firm se-
lects a probability level they can live with (usually, they are interested in having their financial risk ex-
posure covered something like 95 percent or 99 percent of the time), and they ask, “What is the worst
case that can happen up to being covered 95 percent or 99 percent of the time?” For a given level of
confidence (in this case 95 percent or 99 percent) and over a specified time horizon, VaR can measure
risks in any single security (either a specific investment represented in their investment securities or
loan from a specific customer) or an entire portfolio as long as we have sufficient historical data. VaR
provides an answer to the question “What is the worst loss that could occur and that I should prepare
for?”
In practice, professionals examine a historical record of returns for the asset or portfolio under
consideration and construct a probability distribution of returns. If you select a 95 percent VaR, then
you pick the lowest 5 percent of the distribution, and when multiplied by the asset or portfolio value,
you obtain the 95 percent VaR. If a 99 percent VaR is desired, then the lowest 1 percent of the return
distribution is determined and this is multiplied by the asset or portfolio value to obtain the 99 percent
VaR.
CHAPTER 2 RISK MEASUREMENT AND METRICS 45
FIGURE 2.6 The 95 percent VaR for the Profit and Loss Distribution of Figure 2.2
We illustrate this further with the Figure 2.6, concerning Hometown Bank.
database to track the value of the different bonds held by Hometown Bank as investment securities.
How many times over a given time period—one year, in our example—did Hometown experience neg-
ative price movement on their investments and by how much? To simplify the example, we will assume
the entire portfolio is invested in two-year U.S. Treasury notes. A year of historical data would create
approximately 250 price movement data points for the portfolio.[10] Of those 250 results, how fre-
quently did the portfolio value decrease 5 percent or more from the beginning value? What was the fre-
quency of times the portfolio of U.S. Treasury notes increased in value more than 5 percent? Homet-
own Bank can now construct a probability distribution of returns by recording observations of portfo-
lio performance. This probability distribution appears in Figure 2.7.
FIGURE 2.7 Hometown Bank Frequency Distribution of Daily Price Movement of Investment Securities
Portfolio
The frequency distribution curve of price movement for the portfolio appears in Figure 2.4. From that
data, Hometown can measure a portfolio’s 99 percent VaR for a five-day period by finding the lower
one percentile for the probability distribution. VaR describes the probability of potential loss in value
of the U.S. Treasury notes that relates to market price risk. From the chart, we observe that the bottom
1 percent of the 250 observations is about a 5 percent loss, that is, 99 percent of the time the return is
greater than –5 percent. Thus, the 99 percent VaR on the returns is –5 percent. The VaR for the portfo-
lio is the VaR on the return times $65.5 million, or –.05 × ($65.5 million) = −$3,275,000. This answers
the question of how much risk capital the bank needs to hold against contingencies that should only
occur once in one hundred five-day periods, namely, they should hold $3,275,000 in reserve. With this
amount of money, the likelihood that the movements in market values will cause a loss of more than
$3,275,000 is 1 percent.
The risk can now be communicated with the statement: Under normal market conditions, the most
the investment security portfolio will lose in value over a five-day period is about $3,275,000 with a con-
fidence level of 99 percent.[11]
CHAPTER 2 RISK MEASUREMENT AND METRICS 47
In the context of pure risk exposures, the equivalent notion to VaR is the Maximal Probable Annu-
al Loss (MPAL). As with the VaR measure, it looks at a probability distribution, in this case of losses
over a year period and then picks the selected lower percentile value as the MPAL. For example, if the
loss distribution is given by Figure 2.3, and the 95 percent level of confidence is selected, then the
MPAL is the same as the 95 percent VaR value. In insurance contexts one often encounters the term
MPAL, whereas in finance one often encounters the term VaR. Their calculation is the same and their
interpretation as a measure of risk is the same.
We also note that debate rages about perceived weaknesses in using VaR as a risk measure in fin-
ance. “In short, VaR models do not provide an accurate measure of the losses that occur in extreme
events. You simply cannot depict the full texture and range of your market risks with VaR alone.”[12] In
addition, the VaR examines the size of loss that would occur only 1 percent of the time, but it does not
specify the size of the shortfall that the company would be expected to have to make up by a distress li-
quidation of assets should such a large loss occur. Another measure called the expected shortfall is used
for this. The interested reader is referred to Brockett and Ai[13] for this calculation.
where ε denotes a random term that is unrelated to the market return. Thus the term βA × (Rm − rf )
represents a systematic return and ε represents a firm-specific or idiosyncratic nonsystematic compon-
ent of return.
Notice that upon taking variances, we have σ2A = .β2A × β2m, + σ2ε, so the first term is called the
systematic variance and the second term is the idiosyncratic or firm-specific variance.
The idea behind the CAPM is that investors would be compensated for the systematic risk and not
the idiosyncratic risk, since the idiosyncratic risk should be diversifiable by the investors who hold a
large diversified portfolio of assets, while the systematic or market risk affects them all. In terms of ex-
pected values, we often write the equation as
E[RA]= rf+βA*(E[Rm]-rf),
48 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
which is the so-called CAPM model. In this regard the expected rate of return on an asset E[RA], is the
risk-free investment, rf, plus a market risk premium equal to βA × (E[Rm] − Rf). The coefficient βA is
called the market risk or systematic risk of asset A.
By running a linear regression of the returns experienced on asset A with those returns experi-
enced on a market portfolio (such as the Dow Jones Industrial stock portfolio) and the risk-free asset
return (such as the U.S. T-Bill rate of return), one can find the risk measure βA. A regression is a statist-
ical technique that creates a trend based on the data. An actual linear regression to compute future fre-
quency and severity based on a trend is used in Chapter 3 for risk management analysis. Statistical
books show[14] that βA. = COV(RA, Rm)/β2m where COV(RA,Rm) is the covariance of the return on the
asset with the return on the market and is defined by
COV(RA, Rm) = E[{RA,−E(RA)} × { Rm,-E(Rm)}],
that is, the average value of the product of the deviation of the asset return from its expected value and
the market returns from its expected value. In terms of the correlation coefficient ρAm between the re-
turn on the asset and the market, we have βA = ρAm × (βA/βm), so we can also think of beta as scaling
the asset volatility by the market volatility and the correlation of the asset with the market.
The β (beta) term in the above equations attempts to quantify the risk associated with market fluc-
tuations or swings in the market. A beta of 1 means that the asset return is expected to move in con-
junction with the market, that is, a 5 percent move (measured in terms of standard deviation units of
the market) in the market will result in a 5 percent move in the asset (measured in terms of standard
deviation units of the asset). A beta less than one indicates that the asset is less volatile than the market
in that when the market goes up (or down) by 5 percent the asset will go up (or down) by less than 5
percent. A beta greater than one means that the asset price is expected to move more rapidly than the
market so if the market goes up (or down) by 5 percent then the asset will go up (or down) by more
than 5 percent. A beta of zero indicates that the return on the asset does not correlate with the returns
on the market.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
< Risk measures quantify the amount of surprise potential contained in a probability distribution.
< Measures such as the range and Value at Risk (VaR) and Maximal Probable Annual Loss (MPAL) focus on
the extremes of the distributions and are appropriate measures of risk when interest is focused on
solvency or making sure that enough capital is set aside to handle any realized extreme losses.
< Measures such as the variance, standard deviation, and semivariance are useful when looking at average
deviations from what is expected for the purpose of planning for expected deviations from expected
results.
< The market risk measure from the Capital Asset Pricing Model is useful when assessing systematic financial
risk or the additional risk involved in adding an asset to an already existing diversified portfolio.
CHAPTER 2 RISK MEASUREMENT AND METRICS 49
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
Calculate the average percentage of claims that close in the same year as the injury occurs.
2. From the same Texas Department of Insurance data on closed claims for medical malpractice
liability insurance referred to in Problem 1, we can estimate the number of claims in each year of
injury that will be closed in the next 16 years. We obtain the following data. Here the estimated
dollars per claim for each year have been adjusted to 2007 dollars to account for inflation, so the
values are all compatible. Texas was said to have had a “medical malpractice liability crisis”
starting in about 1998 and continuing until the legislature passed tort reforms effective in
September 2003, which put caps on certain noneconomic damage awards. During this period
premiums increased greatly and doctors left high-risk specialties such as emergency room service
and delivering babies, and left high-risk geographical areas as well causing shortages in doctors in
certain locations. The data from 1994 until 2001 is the following:
a. Calculate the mean or average number of claims per year for medical malpractice
insurance in Texas over the four-year period 1994–1997.
b. Calculate the mean or average number of claims per year for medical malpractice
insurance in Texas over the four-year period 1998–2001.
c. Calculate the mean or average dollar value per claim per year for medical malpractice
insurance in Texas over the four-year period 1994–1997 (in 2009 dollars).
d. Calculate the mean or average dollar value per claim per year for medical malpractice
insurance in Texas over the four-year period 1998–2001 (in 2009 dollars).
e. Looking at your results from (a) to (e), do you think there is any evidence to support the
conclusion that costs were rising for insurers, justifying the rise in premiums?
3. Referring back to the Texas Department of Insurance data on closed claims for medical
malpractice liability insurance presented in Problem 5, we wish to see if medical malpractice was
more risky to the insurer during the 1998–2001 period than it was in the 1994–1997 period. The
data from 1994 until 2001 was:
CHAPTER 2 RISK MEASUREMENT AND METRICS 51
a. Calculate the standard deviation in the estimated payment per claim for medical
malpractice insurance in Texas over the four-year period 1994–1997.
b. Calculate the standard deviation in the estimated payment per claim for medical
malpractice insurance in Texas over the four-year period 1998–2001.
c. Which time period was more risky (in terms of the standard deviation in payments per
claim)?
d. Using the results of (c) above, do you think the medical malpractice insurers raising rates
during the period 1998–2001 was justified on the basis of assuming additional risk?
52 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
management and its methods that are so vital to businesses and to individuals. Today’s unprecedented global
financial crisis following the man-made and natural megacatastrophes underscore the urgency for studying risk
management and its tools. Information technology, globalization, and innovation in financial technologies have all
led to a term called “enterprise risk management” (ERM). As you learned from the definition of risk in Chapter 1 (see
Figure 1.2), ERM includes managing pure opportunity and speculative risks. In this chapter, we discuss how firms
use ERM to further their goals. This chapter and Chapter 13 that follows evolve into a more thorough discussion of
ERM. While employing new innovations, we should emphasize that the first step to understanding risk
management is to learn the basics of the fundamental risk management processes. In a broad sense, they include
the processes of identifying, assessing, measuring, and evaluating alternative ways to mitigate risks.
The steps that we follow to identify all of the entity’s risks involve measuring the frequency and severity of
losses, as we discussed in Chapter 1 and computed in Chapter 2. The measurements are essential to create the risk
map that profile all the risks identified as important to a business. The risk map is a visual tool used to consider
alternatives of the risk management tool set. A risk map forms a grid of frequency and severity intersection points of
each identified and measured risk. In this and the next chapter we undertake the task of finding risk management
solutions to the risks identified in the risk map. Following is the anthrax story, which occurred right after September
11. It was an unusual risk of high severity and low frequency. The alternative tools for financial solutions to each
particular risk are shown in the risk management matrix, which provides fundamental possible solutions to risks
with high and low severity and frequency. These possible solutions relate to external and internal conditions and
are not absolutes. In times of low insurance prices, the likelihood of using risk transfer is greater than in times of
high rates. The risk management process also includes cost-benefit analysis.
The anthrax story was an unusual risk of high severity and low frequency. It illustrates a case of risk
management of a scary risk and the dilemma of how best to counteract the risks.
How to Handle the Risk Management of a Low-Frequency but Scary Risk Exposure:
The Anthrax Scare
The date staring up from the desk calendar reads June 1, 2002, so why is the Capitol Hill office executive
assistant opening Christmas cards? The anthrax scare after September 11, 2001, required these late actions. For
six weeks after an anthrax-contaminated letter was received in Senate Majority Leader Tom Daschle’s office, all
Capitol Hill mail delivery was stopped. As startling as that sounds, mail delivery is of small concern to the many
public and private entities that suffered loss due to the terrorism-related issues of anthrax. The biological
agent scare, both real and imagined, created unique issues for businesses and insurers alike since it is the type
of poison that kills very easily.
54 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
Who is responsible for the clean-up costs related to bioterrorism? Who is liable for the exposure to
humans within the contaminated facility? Who covers the cost of a shutdown of a business for
decontamination? What is a risk manager to do?
Senator Charles Grassley (R-Iowa), member of the Senate Finance Committee at the time, estimated that
the clean-up project cost for the Hart Senate Office Building would exceed $23 million. Manhattan Eye, Ear,
and Throat Hospital closed its doors in late October 2001 after a supply-room worker contracted and later died
from pulmonary anthrax. The hospital—a small, thirty-bed facility—reopened November 6, 2001, announcing
that the anthrax scare closure had cost the facility an estimated $700,000 in revenue.
These examples illustrate the necessity of holistic risk management and the effective use of risk mapping
to identify any possible risk, even those that may remotely affect the firm. Even if their companies aren’t being
directly targeted, risk managers must incorporate disaster management plans to deal with indirect atrocities
that slow or abort the firms’ operations. For example, an import/export business must protect against
extended halts in overseas commercial air traffic. A mail-order-catalog retailer must protect against long-term
mail delays. Evacuation of a workplace for employees due to mold infestation or biochemical exposure must
now be added to disaster recovery plans that are part of loss-control programs. Risk managers take
responsibility for such programs.
After a temporary closure, reopened facilities still give cause for concern. Staffers at the Hart Senate Office
Building got the green light to return to work on January 22, 2002, after the anthrax remediation process was
completed. Immediately, staffers began reporting illnesses. By March, 255 of the building’s employees had
complained of symptoms that included headaches, rashes, and eye or throat irritation, possibly from the
chemicals used to kill the anthrax. Was the decision to reopen the facility too hasty?
Sources: “U.S. Lawmakers Complain About Old Mail After Anthrax Scare.” Dow Jones Newswires, 8 May 2002; David Pilla, “Anthrax Scare Raises New
Liability Issues for Insurers,” A.M. Best Newswire, October 16, 2001; Sheila R. Cherry, “Health Questions Linger at Hart,” Insight on the News, April 15, 2002,
p.16; Cinda Becker, “N.Y. Hospital Reopens; Anthrax Scare Costs Facility $700,000,” Modern Healthcare, 12 November 2001, p. 8; Sheila R. Cherry, “Health
Questions Linger at Hart,” Insight on the News, April 15, 2002, p. 16(2).
Today’s risk managers explore all risks together and consider correlations between risks and their management.
Some risks interact positively with other risks, and the occurrence of one can trigger the other—flood can cause
fires or an earthquake that destroys a supplier can interrupt business in another side of the country. As we
discussed in Chapter 1, economic systemic risks can impact many facets of the corporations, as is the current state
In our technological and information age, every person involved in finding solutions to lower the adverse
impact of risks uses risk management information systems (RMIS), which are data bases that provide information
with which to compute the frequency and severity, explore difficult-to-identify risks, and provide forecasts and
cost-benefits analyses.
1. Links
1. LINKS
Now that we understand the notion and measurement of risks from Chapter 1 and Chapter 2, and the
attitudes toward risk in Chapter 4, we are ready to begin learning about the actual process of risk man-
agement. Within the goals of the firm discussed in Chapter 1, we now delve into how risk managers
conduct their jobs and what they need to know about the marketplace to succeed in reducing and
CHAPTER 3 EVOLVING RISK MANAGEMENT: FUNDAMENTAL TOOLS 55
eliminating risks. Holistic risk management is connected to our complete package of risks shown in
Figure 3.1. To complete the puzzle, we have to
1. identify all the risks,
2. assess the risks,
3. find risk management solutions to each risk, and
4. evaluate the results.
Risk management decisions depend on the nature of the identified risks, the forecasted frequency and
severity of losses, cost-benefit analysis, and using the risk management matrix in context of external
market conditions. As you will see later in this chapter, risk managers may decide to transfer the risk to
insurance companies. In such cases, final decisions can’t be separated from the market conditions at
the time of purchase. Therefore, we must understand the nature of underwriting cycles, which are the
business cycles of the insurance industry when insurance processes increase and fall (explained in
Chapter 5). When insurance prices are high, risk management decisions differ from those made during
times of low insurance prices. Since insurance prices are cyclical, different decisions are called for at
different times for the same assessed risks.
Risk managers also need to understand the nature of insurance well enough to be aware of which
risks are uninsurable. Overall, in this Links section, shown in Figure 3.1, we can complete our puzzle
only when we have mitigated all risks in a smart risk management process.
FIGURE 3.1 Links between the Holistic Risk Picture and the Risk Management Alternative Solutions
56 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E
< In this section you will learn about the big picture of all risk management steps.
Traditionally, a firm’s risk management function ensured that the pure risks of losses were managed
appropriately. The risk manager was charged with the responsibility for specific risks only. Most activ-
ities involved providing adequate insurance and implementing loss-control techniques so that the
firm’s employees and property remained safe. Thus, risk managers sought to reduce the firm’s costs of
pure risks and to initiate safety and disaster management.
self-insuring
Typically, the traditional risk management position has reported to the corporate treasurer. Hand-
ling risks by self-insuring (retaining risks within the firm) and paying claims in-house requires addi-
Retaining the risk within the
firm.
tional personnel within the risk management function. In a small company or sole proprietorship, the
owner usually performs the risk management function, establishing policy and making decisions. In
fact, each of us manage our own risks, whether we have studied risk management or not. Every time we
lock our house or car, check the wiring system for problems, or pay an insurance premium, we are per-
forming the same functions as a risk manager. Risk managers use agents or brokers to make smart in-
surance and risk management decisions (agents and brokers are discussed in Chapter 6).
The traditional risk manager’s role has evolved, and corporations have begun to embrace enter-
prise risk management in which all risks are part of the process: pure, opportunity, and speculative
risks. With this evolution, firms created the new post of chief risk officer (CRO). The role of CROs ex-
panded the traditional role by integrating the firm’s silos, or separate risks, into a holistic framework.
Risks cannot be segregated—they interact and affect one another.
risk map
In addition to insurance and loss control, risk managers or CROs use specialized tools to keep cash
flow in-house, which we will discuss in Chapter 5 and Chapter 6. Captives are separate insurance entit-
A visual tool used to consider
ies under the corporate structure—mostly for the exclusive use of the firm itself. CROs oversee the in-
alternatives of the risk
management tool set. creasing reliance on capital market instruments to hedge risk. They also address the entire risk
map—a visual tool used to consider alternatives of the risk management tool set—in the realm of non-
pure risks. For example, a cereal manufacturer, dependent upon a steady supply of grain used in pro-
duction, may decide to enter into fixed-price long-term contractual arrangements with its suppliers to
avoid the risk of price fluctuations. The CRO or the financial risk managers take responsibility for these
trades. They also create the risk management guideline for the firm that usually includes the following:
< Writing a mission statement for risk management in the organization
< Communicating with every section of the business to promote safe behavior
< Identifying risk management policy and processes
< Pinpointing all risk exposures (what “keeps employees awake at night”)
< Assessing risk management and financing alternatives as well as external conditions in the
insurance markets
< Allocating costs
< Negotiating insurance terms
< Adjusting claims adjustment in self-insuring firms
< Keeping accurate records
Writing risk management manuals set up the process of identification, monitoring, assessment, evalu-
ation, and adjustments.
In larger organizations, the risk manager or CRO has differing authority depending upon the
policy that top management has adopted. Policy statements generally outline the dimensions of such
authority. Risk managers may be authorized to make decisions in routine matters but restricted to
making only recommendations in others. For example, the risk manager may recommend that the
costs of employee injuries be retained rather than insured, but a final decision of such magnitude
would be made by top management.
creating plans, conducting cost-benefits analyses, and implementing programs for loss control and in-
surance. For each property risk exposure, for example, the risk manager would adopt the following or
similar processes:
< Finding all properties that are exposed to losses (such as real property like land, buildings, and
other structures; tangible property like furniture and computers; and intangible personal
property like trademarks)
< Evaluating the potential causes of loss that can affect the firms’ property, including natural
disasters (such as windstorms, floods, and earthquakes); accidental causes (such as fires,
explosions, and the collapse of roofs under snow); and many other causes noted in Chapter 1;
< Evaluating property value by different methods, such as book value, market value, reproduction
cost, and replacement cost
< Evaluating the firm’s legal interest in each of the properties—whether each property is owned or
leased
< Identifying the actual loss exposure in each property using loss histories (frequency and severity),
accounting records, personal inspections, flow charts, and questionnaires
< Computing the frequency and severity of losses for each of the property risk exposures based on
loss data
< Forecasting future losses for each property risk exposure
< Creating a specific risk map for all property risk exposures based on forecasted frequency and
severity
< Developing risk management alternative tools (such as loss-control techniques) based upon cost-
benefit analysis or insurance
< Comparing the existing solutions to potential solutions (traditional and nontraditional)—uses of
risk maps
< Communicating the solutions with the whole organization by creating reporting techniques,
feedback, and a path for ongoing execution of the whole process
< The process is very similar to any other business process.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
< The modern firm ensures that the risk management function is embedded throughout the whole
organization.
< The risk management process follows logical sequence just as any business process will.
< The main steps in the risk management process are identifying risks, measuring risks, creating a map,
finding alternative solutions to managing the risk, and evaluating programs once they are put into place.
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E
< In this section you will learn how to identify risks and create a risk map to communicate the im-
portance of each risk on a severity and frequency grid.
Risk Profiling
Discovering all risks, their assessments and their relationships to one another becomes critical to learn-
risk profiling
ing and understanding an organization’s tolerance for risk. This step comes after a separate and thor-
A process that evaluates all ough review of each risk. Holistic risk mapping is the outcome of risk profiling, a process that evalu-
the risks of the organizations
and measures the frequency
ates all the risks of the organizations and measures the frequency and severity of each risk. Different
and severity of each risk. kinds of organizations pose very different types of risk exposures, and risk evaluations can differ vastly
among industries. Boeing, for example, has a tremendous wrongful death exposure resulting from
plane crashes. Intellectual property piracy and property rights issues could have a big impact upon the
operations of an organization like Microsoft.
CHAPTER 3 EVOLVING RISK MANAGEMENT: FUNDAMENTAL TOOLS 59
A risk map puts the risks a company faces into a visual medium to see how risks are clustered and to
understand the relationships among risks. The risks are displayed on a severity and frequency grid after
each risk is assessed. Risk maps can be useful tools for explaining and communicating various risks to
management and employees. One map might be created to chart what risks are most significant to a
particular company. This chart would be used to prioritize risk across the enterprise. Another map
might show the risk reduction after risk management action is adopted, as we will show later in this
chapter.[2]
Figure 3.2 presents an example of a holistic risk map for an organization examining the dynamics
of frequency and severity as they relate to each risk. By assigning the probability of occurrence against
the estimate of future magnitude of possible loss, risk managers can form foundations upon which a
corporation can focus on risk areas in need of actions. The possible actions—including risk avoidance,
loss control, and insurance (loss transfer)—provide alternative solutions during the discussion of the
risk management matrix in this chapter.
Note that risk maps include plotting intersection points between measures of frequency (on an x-
axis) and severity (on a y-axis) and visually plotting intersection points. Each point represents the rela-
tionship between the frequency of the exposure and the severity of the exposure for each risk
measured.
huge man-made and natural catastrophes. For example, more than 1,200 World Bank employees were
sent home and barred from corporate headquarters for several days following an anthrax scare in the
mailroom.[4] This possibility exposes firms to large potential losses associated with an unexpected in-
terruption to normal business operations. See the box in the introduction to this chapter "How to
Handle the Risk Management of a Low-Frequency but Scary Risk Exposure: The Anthrax Scare".
Financial risks arise from changing market conditions involving financial risks
< prices, Uncertainty regarding the
< volatility, outcome of financial
decisions, as influenced by
< liquidity, factors such as prices,
< credit risk,
volatility, liquidity, credit
markets, currency exchange,
< foreign exchange risk, and and general market
< general market recession (as in the third and fourth quarter of 2008). conditions.
The credit crisis that arose in the third and fourth quarters of 2008 affected most businesses as econom-
ies around the world slowed down and consumers retrench and lower their spending. Thus, risk factors
that may provide opportunities as well as potential loss as interest rates, foreign exchange rates are em-
bedded in the risk map. We can display the opportunities—along with possible losses (as we show in
Chapter 13 in Figure 13.1).
In our example, we can say that because of its global customer base, Notable Notions has a tre-
mendous amount of exposure to exchange rate risk, which may provide opportunities as well as risks.
In such cases, there is no frequency of loss and the opportunity risk is not part of the risk map shown in
Figure 3.2. If Notable Notions was a highly leveraged company (meaning that the firm has taken many
loans to finance its operations), the company would be at risk of inability to operate and pay salaries if
credit lines dried out. However, if it is a conservative company with cash reserves for its operations,
Notable Notions’ risk map denotes the high number (frequency) of transactions in addition to the high
dollar exposure (severity) associated with adverse foreign exchange rate movement. The credit risk for
loans did not even make the map, since there is no frequency of loss in the data base for the company.
Methods used to control the risks and lower the frequency and severity of financial risks are discussed
in Chapter 13.
One example of business risks is reputation risk, which is plotted in the high-frequency/high-
severity quadrant. Only recently have we identified reputation risk in map models. Not only do manu-
facturers such as Coca-Cola rely on their high brand-name identification, so do smaller companies
(like Notable Notions) whose customers rely on stellar business practices. One hiccup in the distribu-
tion chain causing nondelivery or inconsistent quality in an order can damage a company’s reputation
and lead to canceled contracts. The downside of reputation damage is potentially significant and has a
long recovery period. Companies and their risk managers currently rate loss of good reputation as one
of the greatest corporate threats to the success or failure of their organization.[5] A case in point is the
impact on Martha Stewart’s reputation after she was linked to an insider trading scandal involving the
biotech firm ImClone.[6] The day after the story was reported in the Wall Street Journal, the stock price
of Martha Stewart Living Omnimedia declined almost 20 percent, costing Stewart herself nearly $200
million.
Operational risks are those that relate to the ongoing day-to-day business activities of the organiz-
ation. Here we reflect IT system failure exposure (which we will discuss in detail later in this chapter).
On the figure above, this risk appears in the lower-left quadrant, low severity/low frequency. Hard data
shows low down time related to IT system failure. (It is likely that this risk was originally more severe
and has been reduced by backup systems and disaster recovery plans.) In the case of a nontechnology
firm such as Notable Notions, electronic risk exposure and intellectual property risk are also plotted in
the low-frequency/low-severity quadrant.
A pure risk (like workers’ compensation) falls in the lower-right quadrant for Notable Notions.
The organization experiences a high-frequency but low-severity outcome for workers’ compensation
claims. Good internal record-keeping helps to track the experience data for Notable Notions and allows
for an appropriate mitigation strategy.
The location of each of the remaining data points on Figure 3.2 reflects an additional risk exposure
for Notable Notions.
Once a company or CRO has reviewed all these risks together, Notable Notions can create a cohes-
ive and consistent holistic risk management strategy. Risk managers can also review a variety of effects
that may not be apparent when exposures are isolated. Small problems in one department may cause
big ones in another, and small risks that have high frequency in each department can become exponen-
tially more severe in the aggregate. We will explore property and liability risks more in Chapter 8 and
Chapter 9.
62 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
< Communication is key in the risk management processes and there are various mediums in use such as
policy statement and manuals.
< The identification process includes profiling and risk mapping.
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. Design a brief risk management policy statement for a small child-care company. Remember to include
the most important objectives.
2. For the same child-care company, create a risk identification list and plot the risks on a risk map.
3. Identify the nature of each risk on the risk map in terms of hazard risk, financial risk, business risk, and
operational risks.
4. For the child-care company, do you see any speculative or opportunity risks? Explain.
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
< In this section we focus on an example of how to compute the frequency and severity of losses
(learned in Chapter 2).
< We also forecast these measures and conduct a cost-benefit analysis for loss control.
Dana, the risk manager at Energy Fitness Centers, identified the risks of workers’ injury on the job and
risk management matrix
collected the statistics of claims and losses since 2003. Dana computed the frequency and severity using
Matrix that provides her own data in order to use the data in her risk map for one risk only. When we focus on one risk
alternative financial action to
only, we work with the risk management matrix. This matrix provides alternative financial action to
undertake for each
frequency/severity undertake for each frequency/severity combination (described later in this chapter). Dana’s computa-
combination on the risk map. tions of the frequency and severity appear in Table 3.1. Forecasting, on the other hand, appears in
Table 3.2 and Figure 3.3. Forecasting involves projecting the frequency and severity of losses into the
forecasting
future based on current data and statistical assumptions.
Projecting the frequency and
severity of losses into the TABLE 3.1 Workers’ Compensation Loss History of Energy Fitness Centers—Frequency and Severity
future based on current data
and statistical assumptions. Year Number of WC Claims WC Losses Average Loss per Claim
2003 2,300 $3,124,560 $1,359
2004 1,900 $1,950,000 $1,026
2005 2,100 $2,525,000 $1,202
2006 1,900 $2,345,623 $1,235
2007 2,200 $2,560,200 $1,164
2008 1,700 $1,907,604 $1,122
Total 12,100 $14,412,987
Frequency for the whole period Severity for the whole period
Mean 2,017 $2,402,165 $1,191
(See Chapter 2 for the computation)
CHAPTER 3 EVOLVING RISK MANAGEMENT: FUNDAMENTAL TOOLS 63
TABLE 3.2 Workers’ Compensation Frequency and Severity of Energy Fitness Centers—Actual and
Trended
WC Frequency Linear Trend Frequency WC Average Claim Linear Trend Severity
2003 2,300 2,181 $1,359 $1,225
2004 1,900 2,115 $1,026 $1,226
2005 2,100 2,050 $1,202 $1,227
2006 1,900 1,984 $1,235 $1,228
2007 2,200 1,918 $1,422 $1,229
2008 1,700 1,852 $1,122 $1,230
2009 Estimated 1,786.67 Estimated $1,231.53
FIGURE 3.3 Workers’ Compensation Frequency and Severity of Energy Fitness Centers—Actual and
Trended
Dana installed various loss-control tools during the period under study. The result of the risk reduction
investments appear to be paying off. Her analysis of the results indicated that the annual frequency
trend has decreased (see the negative slope for the frequency in Figure 3.2). The company’s success in
decreasing loss severity doesn’t appear in such dramatic terms. Nevertheless, Dana feels encouraged
that her efforts helped level off the severity. The slope of the annual severity (losses per claim) trend
line is 1.09 per year—and hence almost level as shown in the illustration in Figure 3.2. (See the Section
7 to this chapter for explanation of the computation of the forecasting analysis.)
64 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
The key to good decision making lies in the risk managers’ ability to analyze large amounts of data
data warehousing
collected. A firm’s data warehousing (a system of housing large sets of data for strategic analysis and
operations) of risk data allows decision makers to evaluate multiple dimensions of risks as well as over- A system of housing large
sets of data for strategic
all risk. Reporting techniques can be virtually unlimited in perspectives. For example, risk managers analysis and operations.
can sort data by location, by region, by division, and so forth. Because risk solutions are only as good as
their underlying assumptions, RMIS allows for modeling data to assist in the risk exposure measure-
ment process. Self-administered retained coverages have experienced explosive growth across all indus-
tries. The boom has meant that systems now include customized Web-based reporting capabilities. The
technological advances that go along with RMIS allows all decision makers to maximize a firm’s risk/
reward tradeoff through data analysis.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y
< The student learned how to trend the frequency and severity measures for use in the risk map. When this
data is available, the risk manager is able to conduct cost-benefit analysis comparing the benefit of
adopting a loss-control measure.
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. Following is the loss data for slip-and-fall shoppers’ medical claims of the grocery store chain Derelex for
the years 2004–2008.
a. Calculate the severity and frequency of the losses.
b. Forecast the severity and frequency for next year using the appendix to this chapter.
c. If a new mat can help lower the severity of slips and falls by 50 percent in the third year from
now, what will be the projected severity in 3 years if the mats are used?
d. What should be the costs today for this mats to break even? Use cost-benefit analysis at 6
percent.
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
< In this section you will learn about the alternatives available for managing risks based on the
frequency and severity of the risks.
< We also address the risk manager’s alternatives—transferring the risk, avoiding it, and man-
aging it internally with loss controls.
Once they are evaluated and forecasted, loss frequency and loss severity are used as the vertical and ho-
rizontal lines in the risk management matrix for one specific risk exposure. Note that such a matrix
differs from the risk map described below (which includes all important risks a firm is exposed to). The
risk management matrix includes on one axis, categories of relative frequency (high and low) and on
the other, categories of relative severity (high and low). The simplest of these matrices is one with just
four cells, as shown in the pure risk solutions in Table 3.4. While this matrix takes into account only
two variables, in reality, other variables—the financial condition of the firm, the size of the firm, and
external market conditions, to name a few—are very important in the decision.[7]
66 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
TABLE 3.4 The Traditional Risk Management Matrix (for One Risk)
Pure Risk Solutions
Low Frequency of Losses High Frequency of Losses
Low Severity of Losses Retention—self-insurance Retention with loss control—risk reduction
High Severity of Losses Transfer—insurance Avoidance
manufacturers typically not only replace defective parts but also pay for labor, within certain con-
straints. The owner has, in effect, transferred a large part of the risk of purchasing a new automobile
back to the manufacturer. The buyer, of course, is still subject to the inconvenience of having repairs
made, but he or she does not have to pay for them.
Other types of contractual arrangements that transfer risk include leases and rental agreements,
hold-harmless clauses[8] and surety bonds.[9] Perhaps the most important arrangement for the transfer
of risk important to our study is insurance.
Insurance is a common form of planned risk transfer as a financing technique for individuals and
most organizations. The insurance industry has grown tremendously in industrialized countries, devel-
oping sophisticated products, employing millions of people, and investing billions of dollars. Because
of its core importance in risk management, insurance is the centerpiece in most risk management
activities.
example might be a firm that is considering construction of a building on the east coast of Florida in
Key West. Flooding and hurricane risk would be high, with significant damage possibilities.
Of course, we cannot always avoid risks. When Texas school districts were faced with high severity
and frequency of losses in workers’ compensation, schools could not close their doors to avoid the
problem. Instead, the school districts opted to self-insure, that is, retain the risk up to a certain loss lim-
it.[11]
Not all avoidance necessarily results in “no loss.” While seeking to avoid one loss potential, many
efforts may create another. Some people choose to travel by car instead of plane because of their fear of
flying. While they have successfully avoided the possibility of being a passenger in an airplane accident,
they have increased their probability of being in an automobile accident. Per mile traveled, automobile
deaths are far more frequent than aircraft fatalities. By choosing cars over planes, these people actually
raise their probability of injury.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
< One of the most important tools in risk management is a road map using projected frequency and severity
of losses of one risk only.
< Within a framework of similar companies, the risk manager can tell when it is most appropriate to use risk
transfer, risk reduction, retain or transfer the risk.
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
< In this section we return to the risk map and compare the risk map created for the identifica-
tion purpose to that created for the risk management tools already used by the business.
< If the solution the firm uses does not fit within the solutions suggested by the risk manage-
ment matrix, the business has to reevaluate its methods of managing the risks.
At this point, the risk manager of Notable Notions can see the potential impact of its risks and its best
risk management strategies. The next step in the risk mapping technique is to create separate graphs
that show how the firm is currently handling each risk. Each of the risks in Figure 3.4 is now graphed
according to whether the risk is uninsured, retained, partially insured or hedged (a financial technique
to lower the risk by using the financial instrument discussed in Chapter 5), or insured. Figure 3.4 is the
new risk map reflecting the current risk management handling.
CHAPTER 3 EVOLVING RISK MANAGEMENT: FUNDAMENTAL TOOLS 69
When the two maps, the one in Figure 3.2 and the one in Figure 3.4, are overlaid, it can be clearly seen
that some of the risk strategies suggested in Table 3.4 differ from current risk handling as shown in Fig-
ure 3.4. For example, a broker convinced the risk manager to purchase an expensive policy for e-risk.
The risk map shows that for Notable Notions, e-risk is low severity and low frequency and thus should
remain uninsured. By overlaying the two risk maps, the risk manager can see where current risk hand-
ling may not be appropriate.
Using holistic risk mapping methodology presents a clear, easy-to-read presentation of a firm’s
overall risk spectrum or the level of risks that are still left after all risk mitigation strategies were put in
place. It allows a firm to discern between those exposures that after all mitigation efforts are still
1. unbearable,
2. difficult to bear, and
3. relatively unimportant.
In summary, risk mapping has five main objectives:
1. To aid in the identification of risks and their interrelations
2. To provide a mechanism to see clearly what risk management strategy would be the best to
undertake
3. To compare and evaluate the firm’s current risk handling and to aid in selecting appropriate
strategies
4. To show the leftover risks after all risk mitigation strategies are put in place
5. To easily communicate risk management strategy to both management and employees
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
< In this section we return to the risk map and compare the risk map created for the identification purpose
to that created for the risk management tools already used by the business. This is part of the decision
making using the highly regarded risk management matrix tool.
< If the projected frequency and severity indicate different risk management solutions, the overlay of the
maps can immediately clarify any discrepancies. Corrective actions can be taken and the ongoing
monitoring continues.
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. Use the designed risk map for the small child-care company you created above. Create a risk management
matrix for the same risks indentified in the risk map of question 1.
2. Overlay the two risk maps to see if the current risk management tools fit in with what is required under the
risk management matrix.
3. Propose corrective measures, if any.
4. What would be the suggestions for ongoing risk management for the child-care company?
7. APPENDIX: FORECASTING
,where the “residual” e is a random variable with mean of zero. The coefficients a and b are determined
by the condition that the sum of the square residuals is as small as possible. For our purposes, we do
not discuss the error term. We use the frequency and severity data of A for 5 years. Here, we provide
the scientific notation that is behind Figure 3.5 and Figure 3.6.
72 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
In order to determine the intercept of the line on the y-axis and the slope, we use m (slope) and b
(y-intercept) in the equation.
Given a set of data with n data points, the slope (m) and the y-intercept (b) are determined using:
nΣ(xy) − ΣxΣy
m=
nΣ(x2) − (Σx)2
Σy − mΣx
b= n
Most commonly, practitioners use various software applications to obtain the trends. The student is in-
vited to experiment with Microsoft Excel spreadsheets. Table 3.6 provides the formulas and calcula-
tions for the intercept and slope of the claims to construct the trend line.
TABLE 3.6 Method of Calculating the Trend Line for the Claims
(1) (2) (3) = (1) × (2) (4) = (1)2
Year Claims
X Y XY X2
1 11 11.00 1
2 9 18.00 4
3 7 21.00 9
4 10 40.00 16
n=5 14 70.00 25
Total 15 51 160 55
m = nΣ(xy) − ΣxΣy
= (5(5××160) − (15 × 51)
M = Slope = 0.7 = 2 2
nΣ(x ) − (Σx) 55) − (15 × 15)
51 − (0.7 × 15)
=
Σy − mΣx 5
b = Intercept = 8.1 b = n
CHAPTER 3 EVOLVING RISK MANAGEMENT: FUNDAMENTAL TOOLS 73
10. Brooks Trucking, which provides trucking services over a twelve-state area from its home base in
Cincinnati, has never had a risk management program. Shawana Lee, Brooks Trucking’s financial
vice-president, has a philosophy that “lightning can’t strike twice in the same place.” Because of
this, she does not believe in trying to practice loss prevention or loss reduction.
a. If you were appointed its risk manager, how would you identify the pure-risk exposures
facing Brooks?
b. Do you agree or disagree with Shawana? Why?
11. Devin Davis is an independent oil driller in Oklahoma. He feels that the most important risk he
has is small property damages to his drilling rig, because he constantly has small, minor damage
to the rig while it is being operated or taken to new locations.
a. Do you agree or disagree with Devin?
b. Which is more important, frequency of loss or severity of loss? Explain.
12. Rinaldo’s is a high-end jeweler with one retail location on Fifth Avenue in New York City. The
majority of sales are sophisticated pieces that sell for $5,000 or more and are Rinaldo’s own
artistic creations using precious metals and stones. The raw materials are purchased primarily in
74 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
Africa (gold, platinum, and diamonds) and South America (silver). Owing to a large amount of
international marketing efforts, Internet and catalog sales represent over 45 percent of the total
$300 million in annual sales revenue. To accommodate his customers, Rinaldo will accept both
the U.S. dollar and other foreign currencies as a form of payment. Acting as an enterprise risk
manager consultant, create a risk map model to identify Rinaldo’s risks across the four basic
categories of business/strategic risk, operational risk, financial risk, and hazard risk.
CHAPTER 3 EVOLVING RISK MANAGEMENT: FUNDAMENTAL TOOLS 75
the buyer hired a termite inspector, etc.). Another example is where a property own-
ENDNOTES er allows a caterer to use its property to cater an event. In this example, the Catering
Company (the “Promisor”) agrees to indemnify the property owner for any claims
arising from the Catering Company’s use of the property.” From Legaldocs, a division
of U.S.A. Law Publications, Inc., http://www.legaldocs.com/docs/holdha_1.mv.
1. Etti G. Baranoff, “Mapping the Evolution of Risk Management,” Contingencies (July/
9. A surety bond is a three-party instrument between a surety, the contractor, and the
August 2004): 22–27. project owner. The agreement binds the contractor to comply with the terms and
conditions of a contract. If the contractor is unable to successfully perform the con-
2. Lee Ann Gjertsen, “‘Risk Mapping’ Helps RM’s Chart Solutions,” National Underwriter,
tract, the surety assumes the contractor’s responsibilities and ensures that the pro-
Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edition, June 7, 1999.
ject is completed.
3. The exercise is abridged for demonstrative purposes. An actual holistic risk mapping
model would include many more risk intersection points plotted along the fre- 10. President Reagan signed into law the Liability Risk Retention Act in October 1986 (an
quency/severity X and Y axes. amendment to the Product Liability Risk Retention Act of 1981). The act permits
formation of retention groups (a special form of captive) with fewer restrictions than
4. Associated Press Newswire, May 22, 2002. existed before. The retention groups are similar to association captives. The act per-
mits formation of such groups in the U.S. under more favorable conditions than have
5. “Risk Whistle: Reputation Risk,” Swiss Re publication, http://www.swissre.com. existed generally for association captives. The act may be particularly helpful to small
businesses that could not feasibly self-insure on their own but can do so within a
6. Geeta Anand, Jerry Arkon, and Chris Adams, “ImClone’s Ex-CEO Arrested, Charged
designated group. How extensive will be the use of risk retention groups is yet to be
with Insider Trading,” Wall Street Journal, June 13, 2002, 1.
seen. As of the writing of this text there are efforts to amend the act.
7. Etti G. Baranoff, “Determinants in Risk-Financing Choices: The Case of Workers’ Com-
11. Etti G. Baranoff, “Determinants in Risk-Financing Choices: The Case of Workers’ Com-
pensation for Public School Districts,” Journal of Risk and Insurance, June 2000.
pensation for Public School Districts,” Journal of Risk and Insurance, June 2000.
8. “A Hold Harmless Agreement is usually used where the Promisor’s actions could lead
12. Forecasting is part of the Associate Risk Manager designation under the Risk Assess-
to a claim or liability to the Promisee. For example, the buyer of land wants to in-
spect the property prior to close of escrow, and needs to conduct tests and studies ment course using the book: Baranoff Etti, Scott Harrington, and Greg Niehaus, Risk
on the property. In this case, the buyer would promise to indemnify the current Assessment (Malvern, PA: American Institute for Chartered Property Casualty Under-
property owner from any claims resulting from the buyer’s inspection (i.e., injury to a writers/Insurance Institute of America, 2005).
third party because the buyer is drilling a hole; to pay for a mechanic’s lien because
76 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
CHAP TER 4
Risk Attitudes: Expected
Utility Theory and Demand
for Hedging
Authored by Puneet Prakash, Virginia Commonwealth University
Whenever we look into risks, risk measures, and risk management, we must always view these in a greater
context. In this chapter, we focus on the risk within the “satisfaction” value maximization for individual and firms.
The value here is measured economically. So, how do economists measure the value of satisfaction or happiness?
Can we even measure satisfaction or happiness? Whatever the philosophical debate might be on the topic,
economists have tried to measure the level of satisfaction.[1] What economists succeeded in doing is to compare
levels of satisfaction an individual achieves when confronted with two or more choices. For example, we suppose
that everyone likes to eat gourmet food at five-star hotels, drink French wine, vacation in exotic places, and drive
luxury cars. For an economist, all these goods are assumed to provide satisfaction, some more than others. So while
eating a meal at home gives us pleasure, eating exotic food at an upscale restaurant gives us an even higher level
of satisfaction.
The problem with the quantity and quality of goods consumed is that we can find no common unit of
measurement. That prevents economists from comparing levels of satisfaction from consumption of commodities
that are different as apples are different from oranges. So does drinking tea give us the same type of satisfaction as
To get around the problem of comparing values of satisfaction from noncomparable items, we express the
value levels of satisfaction as a function of wealth. And indeed, we can understand intuitively that the level of
wealth is linked directly to the quantity and quality of consumption a person can achieve. Notice the quality and
level of consumption a person achieves is linked to the amount of wealth or to the individual’s budget. Economists
consider that greater wealth can generate greater satisfaction. Therefore, a person with greater levels of wealth is
deemed to be happier under the condition of everything else being equal between two individuals.[2] We can link
each person’s satisfaction level indirectly to that person’s wealth. The higher the person’s wealth, the greater his or
Economists use the term “utils” to gauge a person’s satisfaction level. As a unit of measure, utils are similar to
“ohms” as a measure of resistance in electrical engineering, except that utils cannot be measured with wires
utility theory This notion that an individual derives satisfaction from wealth seems to work more often than not in economic
A theory postulated in situations. The economic theory that links the level of satisfaction to a person’s wealth level, and thus to
economics to explain
behavior of individuals based consumption levels, is called utility theory. Its basis revolves around individuals’ preferences, but we must use
on the premise people can
consistently rank order their caution as we apply utility theory.[3]
choices depending upon
their preferences. In this chapter, we will study the utility theory. If utility theory is designed to measure satisfaction, and since
every individual always tries to maximize satisfaction, it’s reasonable to expect (under utility theory) that each
Then we will extend utility to one of its logical extensions as applied to uncertain situations: expected utility
(EU henceforth). So while utility theory deals with situations in which there is no uncertainty, the EU theory deals
with choices individuals make when the outcomes they face are uncertain. As we shall see, if individuals maximize
utility under certainty, they will also attempt to maximize EU under uncertainty.
However, individuals’ unabashed EU maximization is not always the case. Other models of human behavior
describe behavior in which the observed choices of an individual vary with the decision rule to maximize EU. So
why would a mother jump into a river to save her child, even if she does not know how to swim? Economists still
confront these and other such questions. They have provided only limited answers to such questions thus far.
Hence, we will touch upon some uncertainty-laden situations wherein individuals’ observed behavior departs
from the EU maximization principle. Systematic departures in behavior from the EU principle stem from “biases”
that people exhibit, and we shall discuss some of these biases. Such rationales of observed behavior under
uncertainty are termed “behavioral” explanations, rather than “rational” explanations—explanations that explore EU
In this chapter, we will apply the EU theory to individuals’ hedging decisions/purchase of insurance. Let’s start
by asking, Why would anyone buy insurance? When most people face that question, they respond in one of three
ways. One set says that insurance provides peace of mind (which we can equate to a level of satisfaction). Others
respond more bluntly and argue that if it were not for regulation they’d never buy insurance. The second reply is
one received mostly from younger adults. Still others posit that insurance is a “waste of money,” since they pay
premiums up front and insurance never pays up in the absence of losses. To all those who argue based upon the
third response, one might say, would they rather have a loss for the sake of recovering their premiums? We look to
EU theory for some answers, and we will find that even if governments did not make purchase of insurance
mandatory, the product would still have existed. Risk-averse individuals would always demand insurance for the
Thus we will briefly touch upon the ways that insurance is useful, followed by a discussion of how some
information problems affect the insurance industry more than any other industry. “Information asymmetry”
problems arise, wherein one economic agent in a contract is better informed than the other party to the same
contract. The study of information asymmetries has become a full-time occupation for some economics
researchers. Notably, professors George A. Akerlof, A. Michael Spence, and Joseph E. Stiglitz were awarded the
Nobel Prize in Economics in 2001 for their analyses of information asymmetry problems.
CHAPTER 4 RISK ATTITUDES: EXPECTED UTILITY THEORY AND DEMAND FOR HEDGING 79
1. LINKS
Preferences are not absolute but rather they depend upon market conditions, cultures, peer groups, and
surrounding events. Individuals’ preferences nestle within these parameters. Therefore, we can never
talk in absolute terms when we talk about satisfaction and preferences. The 2008 crisis, which contin-
ued into 2009, provides a good example of how people’s preferences can change very quickly. When
people sat around in celebration of 2009 New Year’s Eve, conversation centered on hopes for “making
a living” and having some means for income. These same people talked about trips around the world at
the end of 2007. Happiness and preferences are a dynamic topic depending upon individuals’ stage of
life and economic states of the world. Under each new condition, new preferences arise that fall under
the static utility theory discussed below. Economists have researched “happiness,” and continuing
study is very important to economists.[4]
FIGURE 4.1 Links between the Holistic Risk Picture and Risk Attitudes
80 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
2. UTILITY THEORY
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
utility theory
Utility theory bases its beliefs upon individuals’ preferences. It is a theory postulated in economics to
explain behavior of individuals based on the premise people can consistently rank order their choices
A theory postulated in depending upon their preferences. Each individual will show different preferences, which appear to be
economics to explain
behavior of individuals based
hard-wired within each individual. We can thus state that individuals’ preferences are intrinsic. Any
on the premise people can theory, which proposes to capture preferences, is, by necessity, abstraction based on certain assump-
consistently order rank their tions. Utility theory is a positive theory that seeks to explain the individuals’ observed behavior and
choices depending upon choices.[5] This contrasts with a normative theory, one that dictates that people should behave in the
their preferences. manner prescribed by it. Instead, it is only since the theory itself is positive, after observing the choices
positive theory that individuals make, we can draw inferences about their preferences. When we place certain restric-
Theory that seeks to explain
tions on those preferences, we can represent them analytically using a utility function—a mathemat-
an individual’s observed ical formulation that ranks the preferences of the individual in terms of satisfaction different consump-
behavior and choices. tion bundles provide. Thus, under the assumptions of utility theory, we can assume that people be-
haved as if they had a utility function and acted according to it. Therefore, the fact that a person does
normative theory not know his/her utility function, or even denies its existence, does not contradict the theory. Econom-
Theory that dictates that ists have used experiments to decipher individuals’ utility functions and the behavior that underlies in-
people should behave in the dividuals’ utility.
manner prescribed by it.
To begin, assume that an individual faces a set of consumption “bundles.” We assume that indi-
utility function viduals have clear preferences that enable them to “rank order” all bundles based on desirability, that is,
A mathematical formulation the level of satisfaction each bundle shall provide to each individual. This rank ordering based on pref-
that ranks the preferences of erences tells us the theory itself has ordinal utility—it is designed to study relative satisfaction levels.
the individual in terms of As we noted earlier, absolute satisfaction depends upon conditions; thus, the theory by default cannot
satisfaction different have cardinal utility, or utility that can represent the absolute level of satisfaction. To make this the-
consumption bundles
provide.
ory concrete, imagine that consumption bundles comprise food and clothing for a week in all different
combinations, that is, food for half a week, clothing for half a week, and all other possible
combinations.
ordinal utility
The utility theory then makes the following assumptions:
Utility that can only represent
relative levels of satisfaction
between two or more
alternatives, that is, rank
orders them.
cardinal utility
Utility that can represent the
absolute level of satisfaction.
CHAPTER 4 RISK ATTITUDES: EXPECTED UTILITY THEORY AND DEMAND FOR HEDGING 81
1. Completeness: Individuals can rank order all possible bundles. Rank ordering implies that the
completeness
theory assumes that, no matter how many combinations of consumption bundles are placed in
front of the individual, each individual can always rank them in some order based on preferences. Property in which an
This, in turn, means that individuals can somehow compare any bundle with any other bundle individual’s preferences
enable him/her to compare
and rank them in order of the satisfaction each bundle provides. So in our example, half a week of any given consumption
food and clothing can be compared to one week of food alone, one week of clothing alone, or any bundle with any other
such combination. Mathematically, this property wherein an individual’s preferences enable him bundle.
or her to compare any given bundle with any other bundle is called the completeness property
monotonicity assumption
of preferences.
The assumption that more
2. More-is-better: Assume an individual prefers consumption of bundle A of goods to bundle B. consumption is always better.
Then he is offered another bundle, which contains more of everything in bundle A, that is, the
new bundle is represented by αA where α = 1. The more-is-better assumption says that mix-is-better assumption
individuals prefer αA to A, which in turn is preferred to B, but also A itself. For our example, if The assumption that a mix of
one week of food is preferred to one week of clothing, then two weeks of food is a preferred consumption bundles is
package to one week of food. Mathematically, the more-is-better assumption is called the always better than
monotonicity assumption on preferences. One can always argue that this assumption breaks stand-alone choices.
down frequently. It is not difficult to imagine that a person whose stomach is full would turn rationality
down additional food. However, this situation is easily resolved. Suppose the individual is given The assumption that
the option of disposing of the additional food to another person or charity of his or her choice. In individuals’ preferences avoid
this case, the person will still prefer more food even if he or she has eaten enough. Thus under the any kind of circularity.
monotonicity assumption, a hidden property allows costless disposal of excess quantities of any
bundle.
3. Mix-is-better: Suppose an individual is indifferent to the choice between one week of clothing
alone and one week of food. Thus, either choice by itself is not preferred over the other. The
“mix-is-better” assumption about preferences says that a mix of the two, say half-week of food
mixed with half-week of clothing, will be preferred to both stand-alone choices. Thus, a glass of
milk mixed with Milo (Nestlè’s drink mix), will be preferred to milk or Milo alone. The mix-is-
better assumption is called the “convexity” assumption on preferences, that is, preferences are
convex.
4. Rationality: This is the most important and controversial assumption that underlies all of utility
theory. Under the assumption of rationality, individuals’ preferences avoid any kind of
circularity; that is, if bundle A is preferred to B, and bundle B is preferred to C, then A is also
preferred to C. Under no circumstances will the individual prefer C to A. You can likely see why
this assumption is controversial. It assumes that the innate preferences (rank orderings of
bundles of goods) are fixed, regardless of the context and time.
If one thinks of preference orderings as comparative relationships, then it becomes simpler to construct
examples where this assumption is violated. So, in “beats”—as in A beat B in college football. These are
relationships that are easy to see. For example, if University of Florida beats Ohio State, and Ohio State
beats Georgia Tech, it does not mean that Florida beats Georgia Tech. Despite the restrictive nature of
the assumption, it is a critical one. In mathematics, it is called the assumption of transitivity of
preferences.
Whenever these four assumptions are satisfied, then the preferences of the individual can be rep- well-behaved utility
resented by a well-behaved utility function.[6] Note that the assumptions lead to “a” function, not function
“the” function. Therefore, the way that individuals represent preferences under a particular utility A representation of the
function may not be unique. Well-behaved utility functions explain why any comparison of individual preferences of the individual
people’s utility functions may be a futile exercise (and the notion of cardinal utility misleading). Non- that satisfies the assumptions
etheless, utility functions are valuable tools for representing the preferences of an individual, provided of completeness,
the four assumptions stated above are satisfied. For the remainder of the chapter we will assume that monotonicity, mix-is-better,
preferences of any individual can always be represented by a well-behaved utility function. As we men- and rationality.
tioned earlier, well-behaved utility depends upon the amount of wealth the person owns.
Utility theory rests upon the idea that people behave as if they make decisions by assigning imagin-
ary utility values to the original monetary values. The decision maker sees different levels of monetary
values, translates these values into different, hypothetical terms (“utils”), processes the decision in util-
ity terms (not in wealth terms), and translates the result back to monetary terms. So while we observe
inputs to and results of the decision in monetary terms, the decision itself is made in utility terms. And
given that utility denotes levels of satisfaction, individuals behave as if they maximize the utility, not
the level of observed dollar amounts.
While this may seem counterintuitive, let’s look at an example that will enable us to appreciate this
distinction better. More importantly, it demonstrates why utility maximization, rather than wealth
maximization, is a viable objective. The example is called the “St. Petersburg paradox.” But before we
turn to that example, we need to review some preliminaries of uncertainty: probability and statistics.
82 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
< In economics, utility theory governs individual decision making. The student must understand an intuitive
explanation for the assumptions: completeness, monotonicity, mix-is-better, and rationality (also called
transitivity).
< Finally, students should be able to discuss and distinguish between the various assumptions underlying
the utility function.
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. Utility theory is a preference-based approach that provides a rank ordering of choices. Explain this
statement.
2. List and describe in your own words the four axioms/assumptions that lead to the existence of a utility
function.
3. What is a “util” and what does it measure?
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
< In this section we discuss the notion of uncertainty. Mathematical preliminaries discussed in
this section form the basis for analysis of individual decision making in uncertain situations.
< The student should pick up the tools of this section, as we will apply them later.
As we learned in the chapters Chapter 1 and Chapter 2, risk and uncertainty depend upon one another.
The origins of the distinction go back to the Mr. Knight,[7] who distinguished between risk and uncer-
tainty, arguing that measurable uncertainty is risk. In this section, since we focus only on measurable
uncertainty, we will not distinguish between risk and uncertainty and use the two terms
interchangeably.
As we described in Chapter 2, the study of uncertainty originated in games of chance. So when we
play games of dice, we are dealing with outcomes that are inherently uncertain. The branch of science
of uncertain outcomes is probability and statistics. Notice that the analysis of probability and statistics
applies only if outcomes are uncertain. When a student registers for a class but does not attend any lec-
tures nor does any assigned work or test, only one outcome is possible: a failing grade. On the other
hand, if the student attends all classes and scores 100 percent on all tests and assignments, then too
only one outcome is possible, an “A” grade. In these extreme situations, no uncertainty arises with the
outcomes. But between these two extremes lies the world of uncertainty. Students often do research on
the instructor and try to get a “feel” for the chance that they will make a particular grade if they register
for an instructor’s course.
Even though we covered some of this discussion of probability and uncertainty in Chapter 2, we
repeat it here for reinforcement. Figuring out the chance, in mathematical terms, is the same as calcu-
lating the probability of an event. To compute a probability empirically, we repeat an experiment with
uncertain outcomes (called a random experiment) and count the number of times the event of interest
happens, say n, in the N trials of the experiment. The empirical probability of the event then equals
n/N. So, if one keeps a log of the number of times a computer crashes in a day and records it for 365
days, the probability of the computer crashing on a day will be the sum of all of computer crashes on a
daily basis (including zeroes for days it does not crash at all) divided by 365.
For some problems, the probability can be calculated using mathematical deduction. In these
cases, we can figure out the probability of getting a head on a coin toss, two aces when two cards are
randomly chosen from a deck of 52 cards, and so on (see the example of the dice in Chapter 2). We
don’t have to conduct a random experiment to actually compute the mathematical probability, as is the
case with empirical probability.
Finally, as strongly suggested before, subjective probability is based on a person’s beliefs and ex-
periences, as opposed to empirical or mathematical probability. It may also depend upon a person’s
state of mind. Since beliefs may not always be rational, studying behavior using subjective probabilities
belongs to the realm of behavioral economics rather than traditional rationality-based economics.
CHAPTER 4 RISK ATTITUDES: EXPECTED UTILITY THEORY AND DEMAND FOR HEDGING 83
So consider a lottery (a game of chance) wherein several outcomes are possible with defined prob-
abilities. Typically, outcomes in a lottery consist of monetary prizes. Returning to our dice example of
Chapter 2, let’s say that when a six-faced die is rolled, the payoffs associated with the outcomes are $1 if
a 1 turns up, $2 for a 2, …, and $6 for a 6. Now if this game is played once, one and only one amount
can be won—$1, $2, and so on. However, if the same game is played many times, what is the amount
that one can expect to win?
Mathematically, the answer to any such question is very straightforward and is given by the expec-
ted value of the game.
In a game of chance, if W1, W2, … , WN are the N outcomes possible with probabilities
π1, π2, … , πN , then the expected value of the game (G) is
∞ ∞
E(U) = ∑ πiU(Wi) = 1
2 × ln(2) + 1
4 × ln(4) + … = ∑ 1
2i
ln(2i).
i=1 i=1
The computation can be extended to expected values of any uncertain situation, say losses, provided we
know the outcome numbers and their associated probabilities. The probabilities sum to 1, that is,
N
∑ πi = π1 + … + πN = 1.
i=1
While the computation of expected value is important, equally important is notion behind expected
expected value
values. Note that we said that when it comes to the outcome of a single game, only one amount can be
won, either $1, $2, …, $6. But if the game is played over and over again, then one can expect to win The sum of the products of
two numbers, the outcomes
E(G) = 16 1 + 16 2 … + 16 6 = $3.50 per game. Often—like in this case—the expected value is not one of and their associated
the possible outcomes of the distribution. In other words, the probability of getting $3.50 in the above probabilities.
lottery is zero. Therefore, the concept of expected value is a long-run concept, and the hidden assump-
tion is that the lottery is played many times. Secondly, the expected value is a sum of the products of
two numbers, the outcomes and their associated probabilities. If the probability of a large outcome is
very high then the expected value will also be high, and vice versa.
Expected value of the game is employed when one designs a fair game. A fair game, actuarially fair game
speaking, is one in which the cost of playing the game equals the expected winnings of the game, so
Game in which the cost of
that net value of the game equals zero. We would expect that people are willing to play all fair value playing equals the expected
games. But in practice, this is not the case. I will not pay $500 for a lucky outcome based on a coin toss, winnings of the game, so that
even if the expected gains equal $500. No game illustrates this point better than the St. Petersburg net value of the game equals
paradox. zero.
The paradox lies in a proposed game wherein a coin is tossed until “head” comes up. That is when
the game ends. The payoff from the game is the following: if head appears on the first toss, then $2 is
paid to the player, if it appears on the second toss then $4 is paid, if it appears on the third toss, then $8,
and so on, so that if head appears on the nth toss then the payout is $2n. The question is how much
would an individual pay to play this game?
Let us try and apply the fair value principle to this game, so that the cost an individual is willing to
bear should equal the fair value of the game. The expected value of the game E(G) is calculated below.
The game can go on indefinitely, since the head may never come up in the first million or billion
trials. However, let us look at the expected payoff from the game. If head appears on the first try, the
1
probability of that happening is 2 , and the payout is $2. If it happens on the second try, it means the
1 1 1
first toss yielded a tail (T) and the second a head (H). The probability of TH combination = 2 × 2 = 4 ,
and the payoff is $4. Then if H turns up on the third attempt, it implies the sequence of outcomes is
1 1 1 1
TTH, and the probability of that occurring is 2 × 2 × 2 = 8 with a payoff of $8. We can continue with
this inductive analysis ad infinitum. Since expected is the sum of all products of outcomes and their
1 1 1
corresponding probabilities, E(G) = 2 × 2 + 4 × 4 + 8 × 8 + … = ∞.
It is evident that while the expected value of the game is infinite, not even the Bill Gateses and
Warren Buffets of the world will give even a thousand dollars to play this game, let alone billions.
Daniel Bernoulli was the first one to provide a solution to this paradox in the eighteenth century.
His solution was that individuals do not look at the expected wealth when they bid a lottery price, but
the expected utility of the lottery is the key. Thus, while the expected wealth from the lottery may be in-
finite, the expected utility it provides may be finite. Bernoulli termed this as the “moral value” of the
84 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
game. Mathematically, Bernoulli’s idea can be expressed with a utility function, which provides a rep-
resentation of the satisfaction level the lottery provides.
Bernoulli used U(W) = ln(W) to represent the utility that this lottery provides to an individual
where W is the payoff associated with each event H, TH, TTH, and so on, then the expected utility
from the game is given by
∞ ∞
E(U) = ∑ πiU(Wi) = 1
2 × ln(2) + 1
4 × ln(4) + … = ∑ 1
2i
ln(2i,)
i=1 i=1
which can be shown to equal 1.39 after some algebraic manipulation. Since the expected utility that this
lottery provides is finite (even if the expected wealth is infinite), individuals will be willing to pay only a
finite cost for playing this lottery.
The next logical question to ask is, What if the utility was not given as natural log of wealth by
Bernoulli but something else? What is that about the natural log function that leads to a finite expected
utility? This brings us to the issue of expected utility and its central place in decision making under un-
certainty in economics.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
< Students should be able to explain probability as a measure of uncertainty in their own words.
< Moreover, the student should also be able to explain that any expected value is the sum of product of
probabilities and outcomes and be able to compute expected values.
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. Define probability. In how many ways can one come up with a probability estimate of an event? Describe.
2. Explain the need for utility functions using St. Petersburg paradox as an example.
3. Suppose a six-faced fair die with numbers 1–6 is rolled. What is the number you expect to obtain?
4. What is an actuarially fair game?
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
< In this section the student learns that an individual’s objective is to maximize expected utility
when making decisions under uncertainty.
< We also learn that people are risk averse, risk neutral, or risk seeking (loving).
We saw earlier that in a certain world, people like to maximize utility. In a world of uncertainty, it
expected utility
seems intuitive that individuals would maximize expected utility. This refers to a construct used to
A construct to explain the explain the level of satisfaction a person gets when faced with uncertain choices. The intuition is
level of satisfaction a person
gets when faced with
straightforward, proving it axiomatically was a very challenging task. John von Neumann and Oskar
uncertain choices. Morgenstern (1944) advocated an approach that leads us to a formal mathematical representation of
maximization of expected utility.
We have also seen that a utility function representation exists if the four assumptions discussed
above hold. Messrs. von Neumann and Morgenstern added two more assumptions and came up with
an expected utility function that exists if these axioms hold. While the discussions about these assump-
tions[8] is beyond the scope of the text, it suffices to say that the expected utility function has the form
CHAPTER 4 RISK ATTITUDES: EXPECTED UTILITY THEORY AND DEMAND FOR HEDGING 85
E(U) = ∑ πiui,
i=1
where u is a function that attaches numbers measuring the level of satisfaction ui associated with each
outcome i. u is called the Bernoulli function while E(U) is the von Neumann-Morgenstern expected
utility function.
Again, note that expected utility function is not unique, but several functions can model the pref-
erences of the same individual over a given set of uncertain choices or games. What matters is that such
a function (which reflects an individual’s preferences over uncertain games) exists. The expected utility
theory then says if the axioms provided by von Neumann-Morgenstern are satisfied, then the individu-
als behave as if they were trying to maximize the expected utility.
The most important insight of the theory is that the expected value of the dollar outcomes may expected utility theory
provide a ranking of choices different from those given by expected utility. The expected utility the-
Theory that says persons will
ory then says persons shall choose an option (a game of chance or lottery) that maximizes their expec- choose an option that
ted utility rather than the expected wealth. That expected utility ranking differs from expected wealth maximizes their expected
ranking is best explained using the example below. utility rather than their
Let us think about an individual whose utility function is given by u(W) = √W and has an initial expected wealth.
endowment of $10. This person faces the following three lotteries, based on a coin toss:
TABLE 4.1 Utility Function with Initial Endowment of $10
Outcome (Probability) Payoff Lottery 1 Payoff Lottery 2 Payoff Lottery 3
H (0.5) 10 20 30
T (0.5) −2 −5 −10
E(G) 4 7.5 10
We can calculate the expected payoff of each lottery by taking the product of probability and the payoff
associated with each outcome and summing this product over all outcomes. The ranking of the lotter-
ies based on expected dollar winnings is lottery 3, 2, and 1—in that order. But let us consider the rank-
ing of the same lotteries by this person who ranks them in order based on expected utility.
We compute expected utility by taking the product of probability and the associated utility corres-
ponding to each outcome for all lotteries. When the payoff is $10, the final wealth equals initial endow-
ment ($10) plus winnings = ($20). The utility of this final wealth is given by √20 = 4.472. The com-
pleted utility table is shown below.
TABLE 4.2 Lottery Rankings by Expected Utility
Outcome (Probability) Utility Lottery 1 Utility Lottery 2 Utility Lottery 3
H (0.5) 4.472 5.477 6.324
T (0.5) 2.828 2.236 0
E(U) = 3.650 3.856 3.162
The expected utility ranks the lotteries in the order 2–1–3. So the expected utility maximization prin-
ciple leads to choices that differ from the expected wealth choices.
The example shows that the ranking of games of chance differs when one utilizes the expected util-
ity (E[U]) theory than when the expected gain E(G) principle applies This leads us to the insight that if
two lotteries provide the same E(G), the expected gain principle will rank both lotteries equally, while
the E(U) theory may lead to unique rankings of the two lotteries. What happens when the E(U) theory
leads to a same ranking? The theory says the person is indifferent between the two lotteries.
From the E(U) theory perspective, we can categorize all economic agents into one of the three cat-
egories as noted in Chapter 1:
< Risk averse
< Risk neutral
< Risk seeking (or loving)
We will explore how E(U) captures these attitudes and the meaning of each risk attitude next.
n
The first thing we notice from Figure 4.2 is its concavity, which means if one draws a chord connect-
concavity
ing any two points on the curve, the chord will lie strictly below the curve. Moreover, the utility is al-
Property of a curve in which a
ways increasing although at a decreasing rate. This feature of this particular utility function is called di-
chord connecting any two
points on the curve will lie minishing marginal utility. Marginal utility at any given wealth level is nothing but the slope of the
strictly below the curve. utility function at that wealth level.[10] u ′ (W) > 0, u ″ (W) < 0u(W) = √W,LN(W), − e − 2W. The
diminishing marginal
functional form depicted in Figure 4.2 is LN(W).
utility
Feature of a utility function in
which utility is always
increasing although at a
decreasing rate.
CHAPTER 4 RISK ATTITUDES: EXPECTED UTILITY THEORY AND DEMAND FOR HEDGING 87
The question we ask ourselves now is whether such an individual, whose utility function has the
actuarially fair premium
shape in Figure 4.2, will be willing to pay the actuarially fair price (AFP), which equals expected (AFP)
winnings, to play a game of chance? Let the game that offers him payoffs be offered to him. In Game 1,
The expected loss in wealth
tables have playoff games by Game 1 in Table 4.1 based on the toss of a coin. The AFP for the game is to the individual.
$4. Suppose that a person named Terry bears this cost upfront and wins; then his final wealth is $10 −
$4 + $10 = $16 (original wealth minus the cost of the game, plus the winning of $10), or else it equals
$10 − $4 − $2 = $4 (original wealth minus the cost of the game, minus the loss of $2) in case he loses.
Let the utility function of this individual be given by √W. Then expected utility when the game costs
AFP equals 0.5√16 + 0.5√4 = 3 utils. On the other hand, suppose Terry doesn’t play the game; his util-
ity remains at √10 = 3.162. Since the utility is higher when Terry doesn’t play the game, we conclude
that any individual whose preferences are depicted by Figure 4.2 will forgo a game of chance if its cost
equals AFP. This is an important result for a concave utility function as shown in Figure 4.2.
Such a person will need incentives to be willing to play the game. It could come as a price reduc-
tion for playing the lottery, or as a premium that compensates the individual for risk. If Terry already
faces a risk, he will pay an amount greater than the actuarially fair value to reduce or eliminate the risk.
Thus, it works both ways—consumers demand a premium above AFP to take on risk. Just so, insur-
ance companies charge individuals premiums for risk transfer via insurances.
An individual—let’s name him Johann—has preferences that are characterized by those shown in
Figure 4.2 (i.e., by a concave or diminishing marginal utility function). Johann is a risk-averse person.
We have seen that a risk-averse person refuses to play an actuarially fair game. Such risk aversions also
provide a natural incentive for Johann to demand (or, equivalently, pay) a risk premium above AFP to
take on (or, equivalently, get rid of) risk. Perhaps you will recall from Chapter 1 that introduced a more
mathematical measure to the description of risk aversion. In an experimental study, Holt and Laury
(2002) find that a majority of their subjects under study made “safe choices,” that is, displayed risk
aversion. Since real-life situations can be riskier than laboratory settings, we can safely assume that a
majority of people are risk averse most of the time. What about the remainder of the population?
We know that most of us do not behave as risk-averse people all the time. In the later 1990s, the
stock market was considered to be a “bubble,” and many people invested in the stock market despite
the preferences they exhibited before this time. At the time, Federal Reserve Board Chairman Alan
Greenspan introduced the term “irrational exuberance” in a speech given at the American Enterprise
Institute. The phrase has become a regular way to describe people’s deviations from normal prefer-
ences. Such behavior was also repeated in the early to mid-2000s with a real estate bubble. People
without the rational means to buy homes bought them and took “nonconventional risks,” which led to
the 2008–2009 financial and credit crisis and major recessions (perhaps even depression) as President
Obama took office in January 2009. We can regard external market conditions and the “herd mental-
ity” to be significant contributors to changing rational risk aversion traits.
An individual may go skydiving, hang gliding, and participate in high-risk-taking behavior. Our increasing marginal utility
question is, can the expected utility theory capture that behavior as well? Indeed it can, and that brings
Feature of a utility function in
us to risk-seeking behavior and its characterization in E(U) theory. Since risk-seeking behavior exhibits
which utility is always
preferences that seem to be the opposite of risk aversion, the mathematical functional representation increasing at an increasing
may likewise show opposite behavior. For a risk-loving person, the utility function will show the shape rate.
given in Figure 4.3. It shows that the greater the level of wealth of the individual, the higher is the in-
crease in utility when an additional dollar is given to the person. We call this feature of the function, in convex utility function
which utility is always increasing at an increasing rate, increasing marginal utility. It turns out that Utility function in which the
all convex utility functions look like Figure 4.3. The curve lies strictly below the chord joining any curve lies strictly below the
chord joining any two points
two points on the curve.[11] u(W) = W2, eW . on the curve.
88 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
A risk-seeking individual will always choose to play a gamble at its AFP. For example, let us assume
that the individual’s preferences are given by u(W) = W2. As before, the individual owns $10, and has
to decide whether or not to play a lottery based on a coin toss. The payoff if a head turns up is $10 and
−$2 if it’s a tail. We have seen earlier (in Table 4.1) that the AFP for playing this lottery is $4.
The expected utility calculation is as follows. After bearing the cost of the lottery upfront, the
wealth is $6. If heads turns up, the final wealth becomes $16 ($6 + $10). In case tails turns face-up, then
the final wealth equals $4 ($6 − $2). People’s expected utility if they play the lottery is
u(W) = 0.5 × 162 + 0.5 × 42 = 136 utils.
On the other hand, if an individual named Ray decides not to play the lottery, then the
E(U) = 102 = 100. Since the E(U) is higher if Ray plays the lottery at its AFP, he will play the lottery. As
a matter of fact, this is the mind-set of gamblers. This is why we see so many people at the slot ma-
chines in gambling houses.
The contrast between the choices made by risk-averse individuals and risk-seeking individuals is
starkly clear in the above example.[12] To summarize, a risk-seeking individual always plays the lottery
at its AFP, while a risk-averse person always forgoes it. Their concave (Figure 4.1) versus convex
(Figure 4.2) utility functions and their implications lie at the heart of their decision making.
Finally, we come to the third risk attitude type wherein an individual is indifferent between playing
a lottery and not playing it. Such an individual is called risk neutral. The preferences of such an indi-
vidual can be captured in E(U) theory by a linear utility function of the form u(W) = aW, where a is a
real number > 0. Such an individual gains a constant marginal utility of wealth, that is, each additional
dollar adds the same utility to the person regardless of whether the individual is endowed with $10 or
$10,000. The utility function of such an individual is depicted in Figure 4.4.
CHAPTER 4 RISK ATTITUDES: EXPECTED UTILITY THEORY AND DEMAND FOR HEDGING 89
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
< This section lays the foundation for analysis of individuals’ behavior under uncertainty. Student should be
able to describe it as such.
< The student should be able to compute expected gains and expected utilities.
< Finally, and most importantly, the concavity and convexity of the utility function is key to distinguishing
between risk-averse and risk-seeking individuals.
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. Discuss the von Neumann-Morgenstern expected utility function and discuss how it differs from expected
gains.
2. You are told that U(W) = W2 is a utility function with diminishing marginal utility. Is it correct? Discuss,
using definition of diminishing marginal utility.
3. An individual has a utility function given by (W) = √W, and initial wealth of $100. If he plays a costless
lottery in which he can win or lose $10 at the flip of a coin, compute his expected utility. What is the
expected gain? Will such a person be categorized as risk neutral?
4. Discuss the three risk types with respect to their shapes, technical/mathematical formulation, and the
economic interpretation.
90 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E
< In this section the student learns that an individual’s behavior cannot always be characterized
within an expected utility framework. Biases and other behavioral aspects make individuals de-
viate from the behavior predicted by the E(U) theory.
Why do some people jump into the river to save their loved ones, even if they cannot swim? Why
behavioral economics
would mothers give away all their food to their children? Why do we have herd mentality where many
Realm of academic study that individuals invest in the stock market at times of bubbles like at the latter part of the 1990s? These are
deals with departures from examples of aspects of human behavior that E(U) theory fails to capture. Undoubtedly, an emotional
E(U) maximization behavior.
component arises to explain the few examples given above. Of course, students can provide many more
examples. The realm of academic study that deals with departures from E(U) maximization behavior is
called behavioral economics.
While expected utility theory provides a valuable tool for analyzing how rational people should
make decisions under uncertainty, the observed behavior may not always bear it out. Daniel Kahneman
and Amos Tversky (1974) were the first to provide evidence that E(U) theory doesn’t provide a com-
plete description of how people actually decide under uncertain conditions. The authors conducted ex-
periments that demonstrate this variance from the E(U) theory, and these experiments have withstood
the test of time. It turns out that individual behavior under some circumstances violates the axioms of
rational choice of E(U) theory.
Kahneman and Tversky (1981) provide the following example: Suppose the country is going to be
struck by the avian influenza (bird flu) pandemic. Two programs are available to tackle the pandemic,
A and B. Two sets of physicians, X and Y, are set with the task of containing the disease. Each group
has the outcomes that the two programs will generate. However, the outcomes have different phrasing
for each group. Group X is told about the efficacy of the programs in the following words:
< Program A: If adopted, it will save exactly 200 out of 600 patients.
< Program B: If adopted, the probability that 600 people will be saved is 1/3, while the probability
that no one will be saved is 2/3.
Seventy-six percent of the doctors in group X chose to administer program A.
Group Y, on the other hand, is told about the efficacy of the programs in these words:
< Program A: If adopted, exactly 400 out of 600 patients will die.
< Program B: If adopted, the probability that nobody will die is 1/3, while the probability that all
600 will die is 2/3.
Only 13 percent of the doctors in this group chose to administer program A.
The only difference between the two sets presented to groups X and Y is the description of the out-
comes. Every outcome to group X is defined in terms of “saving lives,” while for group Y it is in terms
of how many will “die.” Doctors, being who they are, have a bias toward “saving” lives, naturally.
framing effect
This experiment has been repeated several times with different subjects and the outcome has al-
ways been the same, even if the numbers differ. Other experiments with different groups of people also
The coding of alternatives,
showed that the way alternatives are worded result in different choices among groups. The coding of
which makes individuals vary
from E(U) maximizing alternatives that makes individuals vary from E(U) maximizing behavior is called the framing effect.
behavior. In order to explain these deviations from E(U), Kahneman and Tversky suggest that individuals
use a value function to assess alternatives. This is a mathematical formulation that seeks to explain
value function observed behavior without making any assumption about preferences. The nature of the value function
A mathematical formulation is such that it is much steeper in losses than in gains. The authors insist that it is a purely descriptive
that seeks to explain device and is not derived from axioms like the E(U) theory. In the language of mathematics we say the
observed behavior without value function is convex in losses and concave in gains. For the same concept, economists will say that
making any assumption the function is risk seeking in losses and risk averse in gains. A Kahneman and Tversky value function
about preferences. is shown in Figure 4.5.
CHAPTER 4 RISK ATTITUDES: EXPECTED UTILITY THEORY AND DEMAND FOR HEDGING 91
Figure 4.5 shows the asymmetric nature of the value function. A loss of $200 causes the individual to
feel more value is lost compared to an equivalent gain of $200. To see this notice that on the losses side
(the negative x-axis) the graph falls more steeply than the rise in the graph on the gains side (positive x-
axis). And this is true regardless of the initial level of wealth the person has initially.
The implications of this type of value function for marketers and sellers are enormous. Note that
the value functions are convex in losses. Thus, if $L is lost then say the value lost = − √L. Now if there
are two consecutive losses of $2 and $3, then the total value lost feels like V (lost) =
− √2 − √3 = − 1.414 − 1.732 = − 3.142. On the other hand if the losses are combined, then total loss
= $5, and the value lost feels like − √5 = − 2.236. Thus, when losses are combined, the total value lost
feels less painful than when the losses are segregated and reported separately.
We can carry out similar analysis on the Kahneman and Tversky function when there is a gain.
Note the value function is concave in gains, say, V(W) = √W. Now if we have two consecutive gains of
$2 and $3, then the total value gained feels like V (gain) = √2 + √3 = 1.414 + 1.732 = 3.142. On the oth-
er hand, if we combine the gains, then total gains = $5, and the value gained feels like √5 = 2.236. Thus,
when gains are segregated, the sum of the value of gains turns out to be higher than the value of the
sum of gains. So the idea would be to report combined losses, while segregating gains.
Since the individual feels differently about losses and gains, the analysis of the value function tells
us that to offset a small loss, we require a larger gain. So small losses can be combined with larger gains,
and the individual still feels “happier” since the net effect will be that of a gain. However, if losses are
too large, then combining them with small gains would result in a net loss, and the individual would
feel that value has been lost. In this case, it’s better to segregate the losses from the gains and report
them separately. Such a course of action will provide a consolation to the individual of the type: “At
least there are some gains, even if we suffer a big loss.”
Framing effects are not the only reason why people deviate from the behavior predicted by E(U)
theory. We discuss some other reasons next, though the list is not exhaustive; a complete study is out-
side the scope of the text.
92 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
a. Overweighting and underweighting of probabilities. Recall that E(U) is the sum of products of
availability bias
two sets of numbers: first, the utility one receives in each state of the world and second, the
Tendency to work with probabilities with which each state could occur. However, most of the time probabilities are not
whatever information is easily assigned objectively, but subjectively. For example, before Hurricane Katrina in 2005, individuals
availability.
in New Orleans would assign a very small probability to flooding of the type experienced in the
experience bias aftermath of Katrina. However, after the event, the subjective probability estimates of flooding
Tendency to assign more have risen considerably among the same set of individuals.
weight to the state of the Humans tend to give more weight to events of the recent past than to look at the entire
world that we have history. We could attribute such a bias to limited memory, individuals’ myopic view, or just easy
experienced and less to availability of more recent information. We call this bias to work with whatever information is
others.
easily availability an availability bias. But people deviate from E(U) theory for more reasons
anchoring bias than simply weighting recent past more versus ignoring overall history.
Tendency to base subjective Individuals also react to experience bias. Since all of us are shaped somewhat by our own
assessments of outcomes on experiences, we tend to assign more weight to the state of the world that we have experienced and
an initial estimate. less to others. Similarly, we might assign a very low weight to a bad event occurring in our lives,
sunk cost even to the extent of convincing ourselves that such a thing could never happen to us. That is
why we see women avoiding mammograms and men colonoscopies. On the other hand, we
Money spent that cannot be
recovered.
might attach a higher-than-objective probability to good things happening to us. No matter what
the underlying cause is, availability or experience, we know empirically that the probability
weights are adjusted subjectively by individuals. Consequently, their observed behavior deviates
from E(U) theory.
b. Anchoring bias. Often individuals base their subjective assessments of outcomes based on an
initial “guesstimate.” Such a guess may not have any reasonable relationship to the outcomes
being studied. In an experimental study reported by Kahneman and Tversky in Science (1974),
the authors point this out. The authors call this anchoring bias; it has the effect of biasing the
probability estimates of individuals. The experiment they conducted ran as follows:
First, each individual under study had to spin a wheel of fortune with numbers ranging from
zero to one hundred. Then, the authors asked the individual if the percent of African nations in
the United Nations (UN) was lower or higher than the number on the wheel. Finally, the
individuals had to provide an estimate of the percent of African nations in the UN. The authors
observed that those who spun a 10 or lower had a median estimate of 25 percent, while those who
spun 65 or higher provided a median estimate of 45 percent.
Notice that the number obtained on the wheel had no correlation with the question being
asked. It was a randomly generated number. However, it had the effect of making people anchor
their answers around the initial number that they had obtained. Kahneman and Tversky also
found that even if the payoffs to the subjects were raised to encourage people to provide a correct
estimate, the anchoring effect was still evident.
c. Failure to ignore sunk costs. This is the most common reason why we observe departures from
E(U) theory. Suppose a person goes to the theater to watch a movie and discovers that he lost $10
on the way. Another person who had bought an online ticket for $10 finds he lost the ticket on
the way. The decision problem is: “Should these people spend another $10 to watch the movie?”
In experiments conducted suggesting exactly the same choices, respondents’ results show that the
second group is more likely to go home without watching the movie, while the first one will
overwhelmingly (88 percent) go ahead and watch the movie.
Why do we observe this behavior? The two situations are exactly alike. Each group lost $10.
But in a world of mental accounting, the second group has already spent the money on the
movie. So this group mentally assumes a cost of $20 for the movie. However, the first group had
lost $10 that was not marked toward a specific expense. The second group does not have the
“feel” of a lost ticket worth $10 as a sunk cost, which refers to money spent that cannot be
recovered. What should matter under E(U) theory is only the value of the movie, which is $10.
Whether the ticket or cash was lost is immaterial. Systematic accounting for sunk costs (which
economists tell us that we should ignore) causes departures from rational behavior under E(U)
theory.
The failure to ignore sunk costs can cause individuals to continue to invest in ventures that
are already losing money. Thus, somebody who bought shares at $1,000 that now trade at $500
will continue to hold on to them. They realized that the $1,000 is sunk and thus ignore it. Notice
that under rational expectations, what matters is the value of the shares now. Mental accounting
tells the shareholders that the value of the shares is still $1,000; the individual does not sell the
shares at $500. Eventually, in the economists’ long run, the shareholder may have to sell them for
$200 and lose a lot more. People regard such a loss in value as a paper loss versus real loss, and
individuals may regard real loss as a greater pain than a paper loss.
CHAPTER 4 RISK ATTITUDES: EXPECTED UTILITY THEORY AND DEMAND FOR HEDGING 93
By no mean is the list above complete. Other kinds of cognitive biases intervene that can lead to deviat-
ing behavior from E(U) theory. But we must notice one thing about E(U) theory versus the value func-
tion approach. The E(U) theory is an axiomatic approach to the study of human behavior. If those ax-
ioms hold, it can actually predict behavior. On the other hand the value function approach is designed
only to describe what actually happens, rather than what should happen.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
< Students should be able to describe the reasons why observed behavior is different from the predicted
behavior under E(U) theory.
< They should also be able to discuss the nature of the value function and how it differs from the utility
function.
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. Describe the Kahneman and Tversky value function. What evidence do they offer to back it up?
2. Are shapes other than the ones given by utility functions and value function possible? Provide examples
and discuss the implications of the shapes.
3. Discuss similarities and dissimilarities between availability bias, experience bias, and failure to ignore sunk
costs.?
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
< In this section we focus on risk aversion and the price of hedging risk. We discuss the actuar-
ially fair premium (AFP) and the risk premium.
< Students will learn how these principles are applied to pricing of insurance (one mechanism to
hedge individual risks) and the decision to purchase insurance.
From now on, we will restrict ourselves to the E(U) theory since we can predict behavior with it. We
are interested in the predictions about human behavior, rather than just a description of it.
The risk averter’s utility function (as we had seen earlier in Figure 4.2) is concave to the origin.
Such a person will never play a lottery at its actuarially fair premium, that is, the expected loss in wealth
to the individual. Conversely, such a person will always pay at least an actuarially fair premium to get
rid of the entire risk.
Suppose Ty is a student who gets a monthly allowance of $200 (initial wealth W0) from his par-
ents. He might lose $100 on any given day with a probability 0.5 or not lose any amount with 50 per-
cent chance. Consequently, the expected loss (E[L]) to Ty equals 0.5($0) + 0.5($100) = $50. In other
words, Ty’s expected final wealth E (FW) = 0.5($200 − $0) + 0.5($200 − $100) = W0 − E(L) = $150. The
question is how much Ty would be willing to pay to hedge his expected loss of $50. We will assume
that Ty’s utility function is given by U(W) = √W —a risk averter’s utility function.
To apply the expected utility theory to answer the question above, we solve the problem in stages.
In the first step, we find out Ty’s expected utility when he does not purchase insurance and show it on
Figure 4.6 (a). In the second step, we figure out if he will buy insurance at actuarially fair prices and use
Figure 4.6 (b) to show it. Finally, we compute Ty’s utility when he pays a premium P to get rid of the
risk of a loss. P represents the maximum premium Ty is willing to pay. This is featured in Figure 4.6
(c). At this premium, Ty is exactly indifferent between buying insurance or remaining uninsured. What
is P?
94 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
Thus, risk aversion is a necessary condition for transfer of risks. Since insurance is one
mechanism through which a risk-averse person transfers risk, risk aversion is of paramount
importance to insurance demand.
The degree of risk aversion is only one aspect that affects insurance prices. Insurance prices
also reflect other important components. To study them, we now turn to the role that
information plays in the markets: in particular, how information and information asymmetries
affect the insurance market.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
< In this section, students learned that risk aversion is the key to understanding why insurance and other risk
hedges exist.
< The student should be able to express the demand for hedging and the conditions under which a risk-
averse individual might refuse to transfer risk.
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. What shape does a risk-averse person’s utility curve take? What role does risk aversion play in market
demand for insurance products?
2. Distinguish between risk premium and AFP. Show the two on a graph.
3. Under what conditions will a risk-averse person refuse an insurance offer?
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E
< Students learn the critical role that information plays in markets. In particular, we discuss two
major information economics problems: moral hazard and adverse selection. Students will un-
derstand how these two problems affect insurance availability and affordability (prices).
We all know about the used-car market and the market for “lemons.” Akerlof (1970) was the first to
information asymmetry
analyze how information asymmetry can cause problems in any market. This is a problem en-
A problem encountered countered when one party knows more than the other party in the contract. In particular, it addresses
when one party knows more
than the other party in the
how information differences between buyers and the sellers (information asymmetry) can cause market
contract. failure. These differences are the underlying causes of adverse selection, a situation under which a
person with higher risk chooses to hedge the risk, preferably without paying more for the greater risk.
adverse selection Adverse selection refers to a particular kind of information asymmetry problem, namely, hidden
Situation in which a person information.
with higher risk chooses to A second kind of information asymmetry lies in the hidden action, wherein one party’s actions are
hedge the risk, preferably not observable by the counterparty to the contract. Economists study this issue as one of moral hazard.
without paying more for the
greater risk.
7.1 Adverse Selection
Consider the used-car market. While the sellers of used cars know the quality of their cars, the buyers
do not know the exact quality (imagine a world with no blue book information available). From the
buyer’s point of view, the car may be a lemon. Under such circumstances, the buyer’s offer price
reflects the average quality of the cars in the market.
When sellers approach a market in which average prices are offered, sellers who know that their
cars are of better quality do not sell their cars. (This example can be applied to the mortgage and hous-
ing crisis in 2008. Sellers who knew that their houses are worth more prefer to hold on to them, instead
of lowering the price in order to just make a sale). When they withdraw their cars from market, the av-
erage quality of the cars for sale goes down. Buyers’ offer prices get revised downward in response. As a
result, the new level of better-quality car sellers withdraws from the market. As this cycle continues,
CHAPTER 4 RISK ATTITUDES: EXPECTED UTILITY THEORY AND DEMAND FOR HEDGING 97
only lemons remain in the market, and the market for used cars fails. As a result of an information
asymmetry, the bad-quality product drives away the good-quality ones from the market. This phe-
nomenon is called adverse selection.
It’s easy to demonstrate adverse selection in health insurance. Imagine two individuals, one who is
healthy and the other who is not. Both approach an insurance company to buy health insurance
policies. Assume for a moment that the two individuals are alike in all respects but their health condi-
tion. Insurers can’t observe applicants’ health status; this is private information. If insurers could find
no way to figure out the health status, what would it do?
Suppose the insurer’s price schedule reads, “Charge $10 monthly premium to the healthy one, and monopolistic market
$25 to the unhealthy one.” If the insurer is asymmetrically informed of the health status of each applic-
A market with only one
ant, it would charge an average premium (10 + 25
2 )
= $17.50 to each. If insurers charge an average supplier.
premium, the healthy individual would decide to retain the health risk and remain uninsured. In such a
case, the insurance company would be left with only unhealthy policyholders. Note that these less-
healthy people would happily purchase insurance, since while their actual cost should be $25 they are
getting it for $17.50. In the long run, however, what happens is that the claims from these individuals
exceed the amount of premium collected from them. Eventually, the insurance company may become
insolvent and go bankrupt. Adverse selection thus causes bankruptcy and market failure. What is the
solution to this problem? The easiest is to charge $25 to all individuals regardless of their health status.
In a monopolistic market of only one supplier without competition this might work but not in a
competitive market. Even in a close-to-competitive market the effect of adverse selection is to increase
prices.
How can one mitigate the extent of adverse selection and its effects? The solution lies in reducing
the level of information asymmetry. Thus we find that insurers ask a lot of questions to determine the
risk types of individuals. In the used-car market, the buyers do the same. Specialized agencies provide
used-car information. Some auto companies certify their cars. And buyers receive warranty offers when
they buy used cars.
Insurance agents ask questions and undertake individuals’ risk classification according to risk deductibles
types. In addition, leaders in the insurance market also developed solutions to adverse selection prob-
Initial part of the loss
lems. This comes in the form of risk sharing, which also means partial insurance. Under partial insur-
absorbed by the person who
ance, companies offer products with deductibles (the initial part of the loss absorbed by the person incurs the loss.
who incurs the loss) and coinsurance, where individuals share in the losses with the insurance com-
panies. It has been shown that high-risk individuals prefer full insurance, while low-risk individuals coinsurance
choose partial insurance (high deductibles and coinsurance levels). Insurance companies also offer Situation where individuals
policies where the premium is adjusted at a later date based on the claim experience of the policyholder share in the losses with the
during the period. insurance companies.
Table 4.3 shows that when he has an accident, his car is a total loss. The probabilities of “loss” and “no
loss” are reversed when he decides to drive without care. The E(L) equals $2,500 in case he drives with
care and $7,500 in case he does not. Wonku’s problem has four parts: whether to drive with or without
care, (I) when he has no insurance and (II) when he has insurance.
We consider Case I when he carries no insurance. Table 4.4 shows the expected utility of driving
with and without care. Since care costs $3,000, his initial wealth gets reduced to $10,000 when driving
with care. Otherwise, it stays at $13,000. The utility distribution for Wonku is shown in Table 4.4.
TABLE 4.4 Utility Distribution without Insurance
Drives with Care Drives without Care
Probability U (Final Wealth) Probability U (Final Wealth)
0.25 0 0.75 54.77
0.75 100 0.25 114.02
When he drives with care and has an accident, then his final wealth (FW)
(FW) = $13,000 − $3,000 − $10,000 = $0, and the utility = √0 = 0. In case he does not have an accident
and drives with care then his final wealth (FW) = (FW) = $13,000 − $3,000 − $0 = $10,000 (note that
the cost of care, $3,000, is still subtracted from the initial wealth) and the utility = √10,000 = 100.
Hence, E(U) of driving with care = 0.25 × 0 + 0.75 × 100 = 75. Let’s go through it in bullets and make
sure each case is clarified.
< When Wonku drives without care he does not incur cost of care, so his initial wealth = $13,000. If
he is involved in an accident, his final wealth (FW) = $13,000 − $10,000 = $3,000, and the utility
= √3,000 = 54.77. Otherwise, his final wealth (FW) = $13,000 − $0 = $13,000 and the utility =
√13,000 = 114.02. Computing the expected utility the same way as in the paragraph above, we get
E(U) = 0.75 × 54.77 + 0.25 × 114.02 = 69.58.
< In Case I, when Wonku does not carry insurance, he will drive carefully since his expected utility
is higher when he exercises due care. His utility is 75 versus 69.58.
< In Case II we assume that Wonku decides to carry insurance, and claims to the insurance
company. He is a careful driver. Let us assume that his insurance policy is priced based on this
claim. Assuming the insurance company’s profit and expense loading factor equals 10 percent of
AFP (actuarially fair premium), the premium demanded is $2,750 = $2,500(1 + 0.10). Wonku
needs to decide whether or not to drive with care.
< We analyze the decision based on E(U) as in Case I. The wealth after purchase of insurance
equals $10,250. The utility in cases of driving with care or without care is shown in Table 4.5
below.
TABLE 4.5 Utility Distribution with Insurance
Drives with Care Drives without Care
Probability U (FW) Probability U (FW)
0.25 85.15 0.75 101.24
0.75 85.15 0.25 101.24
CHAPTER 4 RISK ATTITUDES: EXPECTED UTILITY THEORY AND DEMAND FOR HEDGING 99
Notice that after purchase of insurance, Wonku has eliminated the uncertainty. So if he has an acci-
dent, the insurance company indemnifies him with $10,000. Thus, when Wonku has insurance, the fol-
lowing are the possibilities:
< He is driving with care
< And his car gets totaled, his final wealth =
$10,250 − $3,000 − $10,000 + $10,000 = $7,250, and associated utility = √7250 = 85.15.
< And no loss occurs, his final wealth = $10,250 − $3,000 = $7,250.
So the expected utility for Wonku = 85.15 when he drives with care.
< He does not drive with care
< And his car gets totaled, his final wealth = $10,250 − $10,000 + $10,000 = $10,250, and
associated utility = √10250 = 101.24.
< And no loss occurs, his final wealth = $10,250 and utility = 101.24.
So the expected utility for Wonku = 101.24 when he drives without care after purchasing
insurance.
The net result is he switches to driving with no care.
Wonku’s behavior thus changes from driving with care to driving without care after purchasing
insurance. Why do we get this result? In this example, the cost of insurance is cheaper than the cost of
care. Insurance companies can charge a price greater than the cost of care up to a maximum of what
Wonku is willing to pay. However, in the event of asymmetric information, the insurance company will
not know the cost of care. Thus, inexpensive insurance distorts the incentives and individuals switch to
riskier behavior ex post.
In this moral hazard example, the probabilities of having a loss are affected, not the loss amounts.
In practice, both will be affected. At its limit, when moral hazard reaches a point where the intention is
to cheat the insurance company, it manifests itself in fraudulent behavior.
How can we solve this problem? An ideal solution would be continuous monitoring, which is pro-
hibitively expensive and may not even be legal for privacy issues. Alternatively, insurance companies
try and gather as much information as possible to arrive at an estimate of the cost of care or lack of it.
Also, more information leads to an estimate of the likelihood that individuals will switch to riskier be-
havior afterwards. So questions like marital status/college degree and other personal information might
be asked. Insurance companies will undertake a process called risk classification. We discuss this im-
portant process later in the text.
So far we have learned how individuals’ risk aversion and information asymmetry explain behavi-
or associated with hedging. But do these reasons also hold when we study why corporations hedge their
risks? We provide the answer to this question next.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
< Students should be able to define information asymmetry problems, in particular moral hazard and
adverse selection.
< They must also be able to discuss in detail the effects these phenomena have on insurance prices and risk
transfer markets in general.
< Students should spend some effort to understand computations, which are so important if they wish to
fully understand the effects that these computations have on actuarial science. Insurance companies make
their decisions primarily on the basis of such calculations.
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. What information asymmetry problems arise in economics? Distinguish between moral hazard and
adverse selection. Give an original example of each.
2. What effects can information asymmetry have in markets?
3. Is risk aversion a necessary condition for moral hazard or adverse selection to exist? Provide reasons.
4. What can be done to mitigate the effect of moral hazard and adverse selection in markets/insurance
markets?
100 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
Now, assume somebody promises you sure sums of money so as to induce you to not play
the lotteries. What is the sure sum of money you will be willing to accept in case of each lottery: a
or b? Is your decision “rational”?
18. Partial insurance:[15] This problem is designed to illustrate why partial insurance (i.e., a policy
that includes deductibles and coinsurance) may be optimal for a risk-averse individual.
Suppose Marco has an initial wealth of $1,000 and a utility function given by U(W) = √W .
He faces the following loss distribution:
Prob Loss
0.9 0
0.1 500
a. If the price per unit of insurance is $0.10 per dollar of loss, show that Marco will
purchase full insurance (i.e., quantity for which insurance is purchased = $500).
b. If the price per unit of insurance is $0.11 per dollar of loss, show that Marco will
purchase less than full insurance (i.e., quantity for which insurance is purchased is less
than $500). Hint: Compute E(U) for full $500 loss and also for an amount less than $500.
See that when he insures strictly less than $500, the EU is higher.
19. Otgo has a current wealth of $500 and a lottery ticket that pays $50 with probability 0.25;
otherwise, it pays nothing. If her utility function is given by U(W) = W2 , what is the minimum
amount she is willing to sell the ticket for?
20. Suppose a coin is tossed twice in a row. The payoffs associated with the outcomes are
< “Money Doesn’t Make People Happy,” by Tim 9. At this juncture, we only care about that notion of risk, which captures the inherent
variability in the outcomes (uncertainty) associated with each lottery.
Harford.
10. Mathematically, the property that the utility is increasing at a decreasing rate can be
But marriage, sex, socializing and even middle written as a combination of restrictions on the first and second derivatives (rate of
change of slope) of the utility function, u ′ (W) > 0, u ″ (W) < 0. Some functions
age do.
that satisfy this property are u(W) = √W, LN(W), − e −aW .
http://www.forbes.com/2006/02/11/
tim-harford-money_cz_th_money06_0214 11. The convex curve in Figure 4.2 has some examples that include the mathematical
function u(W) = W2, eW.
harford.html
< “Shall I Compare Thee To A Summer’s Sausage?” 12. Mathematically speaking, for a risk-averse person, we have E(U[W]) ≤ U[E(W)]. Sim-
ilarly, for a risk-seeking person we have E(U[W)] ≥ U[E(W)]. This result is called
by Daniel Gilbert. Jensen’s inequality.
Money can’t make you happy, but making the 13. The complete set of principal-agent problems comprises all situations in which the
agent maximizes his own utility at the expense of the principal. Such behavior is con-
right comparisons can. trary to the principal-agent relationship that assumes that the agent is acting on be-
half of the principal (in principal’s interest).
http://www.forbes.com/2006/02/11/
daniel-gilbert-happiness_cx_dg_money06_0214 14. This problem has been adopted from D. Kahneman and D. Lovallo, “Timid Choices
and Bold Forecasts: A Cognitive Perspective on Risk Taking,” Management Science 39,
gilbert.html no. 1 (1993): 17–31.
< “Money, Happiness and the Pursuit of Both,” by El- 15. Challenging problem.
izabeth MacDonald.
When it comes [to] money and happiness, eco-
nomists and psychologists have got it all wrong.
http://www.forbes.com/2006/02/11/
money-happiness-consumption_cz_em_money
06_0214pursuit.html
< “The Happiness Business,” by Paul Maidment.
CHAP TER 5
The Insurance Solution and
Institutions
In Part I of this book, we discussed the nature of risk and risk management. We defined risk, measured it, attempted
to feel its impact, and learned about risk management tools. We statistically measured risk using the standard
deviation and coefficient of variance, for example. We are going to emphasize the fact that risk decreases as the
number of exposures increases as the most important foundation of insurance. This is called the law of large
numbers. This law is critical to understanding the nature of risk and how it is managed. Once there are large
numbers of accidental exposures, the next questions are (1) How does insurance work? and (2) What is insurable
risk? This chapter responds to these questions and elaborates on insuring institutions.
The transfer of risk to insurers reduces the level of risk to society as a whole. In the transfer of risk to insurers, the
risk of loss or no loss that we face changes. As we learned in Chapter 4, we pay premiums to get the security of no
loss. When we transfer the risk, insurers take on some risk. To them, however, the risk is much lower; it is the risk of
missing the loss prediction. The insurer’s risk is the standard deviation we calculated in Chapter 2. The larger the
number of exposures, the lower the risk of missing the prediction of future losses. Thus, the transfer of risk to
insurers also lowers the risk to society as a whole through the law of large numbers. Even further, insurance is one
of the tools that maintains our wealth and keeps the value of firms intact. As we elaborated in Chapter 13, people
and firms work to maximize value. One essential element in maximizing the value of our assets is preservation and
sustainability. If purchased from a credible and well-rated insurance company, insurance guarantees the
preservation of assets and economic value. In this chapter, we will cover the following:
1. Links
1. LINKS
The adverse, or negative, effects of most of the risks can be mitigated by transferring them to insurance
companies. The new traveler through the journey of risk mitigation is challenged to ensure that the
separate risks receive the appropriate treatment. In Figure 5.1, each puzzle piece represents a fragment
of risk, each with its associated insurance solution or an indication of a noninsurance solution. Despite
having all of the risks in one completed puzzle to emulate a notion of holistic risk, the insurance solu-
tions are not holistic. Insurers sell separate policies that cover the separate risks. Each policy specifically
excludes the coverage that another policy provides. For example, the auto policy excludes the coverage
provided by the homeowners’ policy. These exclusions are designed to prevent double dipping, or
double coverage. Every risk has its unique policy or a few layers of coverages from various sources. For
the risk of dying prematurely, we can purchase life insurance policies as well as receive coverage from
Social Security. For the risk of becoming ill and not being able to pay for medical care, we have health
insurance. For the risk of losing our income because of injury, we have disability insurance (or workers’
compensation if the injury occurred on the job). Throughout this text, you will learn about all the
104 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
policies and how to create an entire portfolio to complete the puzzle of the insurance solution within
the risk management activities.
FIGURE 5.1 Links between the Holistic Risk Puzzle Pieces and Insurance Coverages
CHAPTER 5 THE INSURANCE SOLUTION AND INSTITUTIONS 105
2. NATURE OF INSURANCE
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
A brief survey of insurance literature reveals differences of opinion among authors concerning how the
insurance
term insurance should be defined. Regardless, however, the literature agrees that insurance has to con-
tain both of the following elements: (1) risk pooling and (2) risk transfer. The risk pooling creates a A social device in which a
large sample of risk exposures and, as the sample gets larger, the possibility of missing future loss pre- group of individuals transfer
risk to another party in such a
dictions gets lower. This is the law of large numbers, discussed further in the box below, “Law of Large way that the third party
Numbers.” The combination of risk pooling and risk transfer (from the owner of the risk to a third, un- combines or pools all the risk
related party) physically reduces the risk, both in number and in the anxiety it causes. As such, we re- exposures together.
gard insurance as a social device in which a group of individuals transfer risk to another party in such
insureds
a way that the third party combines or pools all the risk exposures together. Pooling the exposures to-
gether permits more accurate statistical prediction of future losses. Individuals who transfer risk to a Individuals who transfer risk
to a third-party.
third-party are known as insureds. The third party that accepts the risks transferred by insureds is
known as the insurer. insurer
The third party that accepts
the risks transferred by
insureds.
< Insurers pool similar risk exposures together to compute their own risk of missing the prediction.
< Insurers discriminate via underwriting—the process of evaluating a risk and classifying it with
similar risks (see the box below, "Fitting into a Lower Risk-Exposure Pooling Group"). Both the
transfer of risk to a third party and the pooling lead to reduced risk in society as a whole and a
sense of reduced anxiety.
Risk Transfer
Insurance is created by an insurer that, as a professional risk-bearer, assumes the financial aspect of
insurer assumes risk
risks transferred to it by insureds. The insurer assumes risk by promising to pay whatever loss may
The insurer promises to pay occur as long as it fits the description given in the policy and is not larger than the amount of insurance
whatever loss may occur as
long as it fits the description
sold. The loss may be zero, or it may be many thousands of dollars. In return for accepting this variab-
given in the policy and is not ility in outcomes (our definition of risk), the insurer receives a premium. Through the premium, the
larger than the amount of policyholder has paid a certain expense in order to transfer the risk of a possible large loss. The insur-
insurance sold. ance contract stipulates what types of losses will be paid by the insurer.
Most insurance contracts are expressed in terms of money, although some compensate insureds by
providing a service. A life insurance contract obligates the insurer to pay a specified sum of money
upon the death of the person whose life is insured. A liability insurance policy requires the insurer not
only to pay money on behalf of the insured to a third party but also to provide legal and investigative
services needed when the event insured against occurs. The terms of some health insurance policies are
fulfilled by providing medical and hospital services (e.g., a semiprivate room and board, plus other hos-
pital services) if the insured is ill or injured. Whether the insurer fulfills its obligations with money or
with services, the burden it assumes is financial. The insurer does not guarantee that the event insured
against will not happen. Moreover, it cannot replace sentimental value or bear the psychological cost of
a loss. A home may be worth only $80,000 for insurance purposes, but it may have many times that
value to the owner in terms of sentiment. The death of a loved one can cause almost unbearable mental
suffering that is in no way relieved by receiving a sum of money from the insurer. Neither of these as-
pects of loss can be measured in terms of money; therefore, such risks cannot be transferred to an in-
surer. Because these noneconomic risks create uncertainty, it is apparent that insurance cannot com-
pletely eliminate uncertainty. Yet insurance performs a great service by reducing the financial uncer-
tainty created by risk.
(prices) for coverage, estimate the frequency and severity of losses and the loss distribution discussed in
Chapter 2. These estimates are made for a series of categories of insureds, with each category intended
to group insureds who are similar with regard to their likelihood. An underwriter then has the job of
determining which category is appropriate for each insured (see the discussion in Chapter 6). Actuaries
combine the information to derive expected losses. Estimates generally are based on empirical (in this
case, observed) data or theoretical relationships, making them objective estimates. When the actuary
must rely on judgment rather than facts, the estimates are termed subjective. In most cases, both object-
ive and subjective estimates are used in setting rates. For example, the actuary may begin with in-
dustry—determined rates based on past experience and adjust them to reflect the actuary’s instincts
about the insurer’s own expected experience. A life insurer may estimate that 250 of the 100,000 risk
exposures of forty-year-old insureds it covers will die in the next year. If each insured carries a $1,000
policy, the insurer will pay out $250,000 in claims (250 × $1,000). To cover these claims, the insurer re-
quires a premium of $2.50 from each insured ($250,000/100,000), which is the average or expected cost
per policyholder. (An additional charge to cover expenses, profit, and the risk of actual losses exceeding
expected losses would be included in the actual premium. A reduction of the premium would result
from the insurer sharing its investment earnings with insureds.) In Chapter 6, we provide the loss de-
velopment calculations that are performed by the actuary to determine the rates and calculate how
much the insurer should keep on reserve to pay future expected claims. Chapter 6 also explains the re-
lationship between rates and investment income of insurers.
Safe driving is the key to maintaining reasonable auto insurance premiums because you will be placed in the
less risky pool of drivers. The possibility of being placed in a high-risk pool and paying more premiums can be
reduced in other ways, too:
< Avoiding traffic violations and accidents helps reduce the probability of loss to a level that promotes
the economic feasibility of premiums.
< Steering clear of sports cars and lavish cars, which place you in a group of similar (homogeneous)
insureds. Furthermore, a car that is easily damaged or expensive to repair will increase your physical
damage premiums.
< Costs can be reduced further if you use your car for pleasure only instead of driving to and from work.
Riding the bus or in a friend’s car will lower the probability of an accident, making you a more
desirable policyholder. Living outside the city limits has a similar effect.
< Passing driving courses, maintaining a grade point average of at least B, and not drinking earn
discounts on premiums.
This phenomenon of selecting an insurer that charges lower rates for a specific risk exposure is known
as adverse selection because the insureds know they represent higher risk, but they want to enjoy lower
rates. Adverse selection occurs when insurance is purchased more often by people and/or organiza-
tions with higher-than-average expected losses than by people and/or organizations with average or
lower-than-average expected losses. That is, insurance is of greater use to insureds whose losses are ex-
pected to be high (insureds “select” in a way that is “adverse” to the insurer). On this basis alone, no
problem exists because insurers could simply charge higher premiums to insureds with higher expected
losses. Often, however, the insurer simply does not have enough information to be able to distinguish
completely among insureds, except in cases of life insurance for younger versus older insureds. Fur-
thermore, the insurer wants to aggregate in order to use the law of large numbers. Thus, some tension
exists between limiting adverse selection and employing the law of large numbers.
Adverse selection, then, can result in greater losses than expected. Insurers try to prevent this
problem by learning enough about applicants for insurance to identify such people so they can either
be rejected or put in the appropriate rating class of similar insureds with similar loss probability. Many
insurers, for example, require medical examinations for applicants for life insurance.
Some insurance policy provisions are designed to reduce adverse selection. The suicide clause in
life insurance contracts, for example, excludes coverage if a policyholder takes his or her own life with-
in a specified period, generally one or two years. The preexisting conditions provision in health insur-
ance policies is designed to avoid paying benefits to people who buy insurance because they are aware,
or should be aware, of an ailment that will require medical attention or that will disable them in the
near future.[2]
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
Soon after the devastation of Hurricane Katrina became known, the Mississippi attorney general filed a
lawsuit against insurers claiming that the flood should be covered by homeowner’s insurance policies.
The controversy over coverage was explored in the September 8, 2005, New York Times article,
“Liability Issue: Wind or Water?” Is this question so open-ended?
Are all pure risks insurable by private (nongovernmental) insurers? No. The private insurance
device is not suitable for all risks. Many risks are uninsurable. This section is devoted to a discussion of
the requirements that must generally be met if a risk is to be insurable in the private market. As a prac-
tical matter, many risks that are insured privately meet these requirements only partially or, with refer-
ence to a particular requirement, not at all. Thus, in a sense, the requirements listed describe those that
would be met by the ideal risk. Nevertheless, the bulk of the risks insured fulfill—at least approxim-
ately—most of the requirements. No private insurer can safely disregard them completely.[3] A risk that
was perfectly suited for insurance would meet the following requirements:
1. The number of similar exposure units is large.
2. The losses that occur are accidental.
3. A catastrophe cannot occur.
4. Losses are definite.
5. The probability distribution of losses can be determined.
6. The cost of coverage is economically feasible.
The sixth requirement in the list above influences the consumer demand for insurance and looks at
what is economically feasible from the perspective of potential insureds. The other requirements in-
fluence the willingness of insurers to supply insurance.
Mass
A major requirement for insurability is mass; that is, there must be large numbers of exposure units in-
volved. For automobile insurance, there must be a large number of automobiles to insure. For life in-
surance, there must be a large number of persons. An automobile insurance company cannot insure a
dozen automobiles, and a life insurance company cannot insure the lives of a dozen persons. How large
is a “large group”? For insurance purposes, the number of exposure units needed in a group depends
on the extent to which the insurer is willing to bear the risk of deviation from its expectations. Suppose
the probability of damage to houses is 1/1,000. An insurer might assume this risk for 1,000 houses, with
the expectation that one claim would be made during the year. If no houses were damaged, there would
be a 100 percent deviation from expectations, but such a deviation would create no burden for the in-
surer. On the other hand, if two houses were damaged, the claims to be paid would be twice the expec-
ted number. This could be a severe burden for the insurer, assuming average or higher loss severities.
By increasing the number of similar houses insured to 10,000, the expected number of losses increases
to ten, but the stability of experience is increased. That is, there is a proportionately smaller deviation
110 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
from expected losses than would exist with a group of 1,000 houses. Similarly, if the group is increased
to 100,000 houses, the variation between actual and expected losses would be likely to increase in abso-
lute terms, but it would decline proportionately. One additional loss from 100,000 houses is propor-
tionally less than one additional loss from 10,000 houses and even less than one additional loss from
1,000 houses.
Similarity
The loss exposures to be insured and those observed for calculating the probability distributions must
have similarities. The exposures assumed by insurers are not identical, no matter how carefully they
may be selected. No two houses are identical, even though physically they may appear to be. They can-
not have an identical location and, perhaps more important, they are occupied by different families.
Nevertheless, the units in a group must be reasonably similar in characteristics if predictions concern-
ing them are to be accurate. For example, homes with brick sidings are similar for insurance purposes.
Moreover, probability distributions calculated on the basis of observed experience must also in-
volve units similar to one another. Observing the occupational injuries and illnesses of a group of
people whose ages, health conditions, and occupations were all different would not provide a basis for
calculating workers’ compensation insurance rates. For example, clerical work typically involves much
lower probabilities of work-related loss than do occupations such as logging timber or climbing utility
poles. Estimates based on experience require that the exposure units observed be similar to one anoth-
er. Moreover, such estimates are useful only in predicting losses for comparable exposures.
their concentrated exposures, several insurers suffered losses to a large percentage of their business.
The insurers were unable to pay all claims, and several went bankrupt.
A recent example of catastrophe exposure is the case of the risk of mold. Mold created a major
availability and affordability issue in the homeowner’s and commercial property insurance markets in
the early 2000s. The Wall Street Journal article, “Hit With Big Losses, Insurers Put Squeeze on
Homeowner Policies,” reported massive exclusions of mold coverage because of the “avalanche of
claims.”[4]
A second type of catastrophe exposure arises when a single large value may be exposed to loss.
September 11, 2001, represents such catastrophic loss. Tremendous value was concentrated in the
towers of the World Trade Center. The possibility of a human-made catastrophe of such magnitude
was not anticipated. Private insurers stopped short of calling the terrorist attacks “acts of war”—which
would have been excluded from coverage—and honored the policies covering the World Trade Center
and the lives of the victims. However, one consequence was the industry’s action to immediately ex-
clude terrorism coverage from new policies until the Terrorism Risk Insurance Act (TRIA) of 2002
provided stop-gap coverage from the federal government. When insurers and reinsurers (the insurers
of the insurance companies) see the peril as having a far higher probability than previously perceived,
they know that they can no longer accurately predict future losses, and their immediate reaction is to
exclude the peril. Because of regulation and oversight (see Chapter 7), however, the industry cannot
make policy changes instantaneously.[5] When private insurers can no longer provide coverage, a solu-
tion may be to create pools such as those described in the box below, “Who Should Insure Against
Megacatastrophes?” More on this topic and on reinsurance will be explained in Chapter 6.
The possible loss must also be relatively large compared to the size of the premium. If the losses
the insurer pays plus the cost of insurer operations are such that the premium must be very large in re-
lation to the potential loss, insurance is not economically feasible. From the viewpoint of the insured,
when the expected loss premium is high relative to the maximum possible loss, internal budgeting for
the risk is preferable to insurance. The use of deductibles (a form of retention) to eliminate insurance
reimbursement for frequent small losses helps make automobile collision premiums economically feas-
ible. The deductible eliminates claims for small losses. Small automobile collision losses have such high
probability and the cost of settling them is so great that the premium for covering them would be very
large compared to the size of actual losses. For example, if a policy with a $200 deductible costs $85
more than one with a $500 deductible, you may consider $85 too large a premium for $300 of lower de-
ductible. Insurance is best suited for risks involving large potential losses with low probabilities
(described in Chapter 4). Large losses are key because insureds cannot pay them, and low probabilities
for large losses make premiums relatively small compared with the possible losses. In other situations,
insurance may not be economically feasible for the person or business facing risk.
The second example in Table 5.1 is the peril/risk of fire. Fire is an insurable risk because it meets all the
required elements. Even this peril can be catastrophic, however, if fires cannot be controlled and a large
geographical area is damaged, such as the large fires in Colorado and Arizona in 2002. Disability is an-
other type of peril that is considered insurable in most cases. The last example is the risk of terrorism.
As noted above, it is no longer considered an insurable risk due to the catastrophic element associated
with this peril since the September 11, 2001, attack.
Insurance companies use cost-benefit analysis to determine whether they should bring a new
product to the market. In Chapter 3, you learned about the time value of money and computation for
such decisions.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
In this section you studied that a risk perfectly suited for insurance meets the following requirements:
< The number of similar exposure units is large.
< The losses that occur are accidental.
< A catastrophe cannot occur.
< Losses are definite.
< The probability distribution of losses can be determined.
< The cost of coverage is economically feasible.
114 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N
Explain whether the following risks and perils are insurable by private insurers:
a. A hailstorm that destroys your roof
b. The life of an eighty-year-old man
c. A flood
d. Mold
e. Biological warfare
f. Dirty bombs
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
Many types of insurance policies are available to families and organizations that do not wish to retain
their own risks. The following questions may be raised about an insurance policy:
1. Is it personal, group, or commercial?
2. Is it life/health or property/casualty?
3. Is it issued by a private insurer or a government agency?
4. Is it purchased voluntarily or involuntarily?
Property/casualty insurance covers property exposures such as direct and indirect losses of property/casualty
property caused by perils like fire, windstorm, and theft. It also includes insurance to cover the possib- insurance
ility of being held legally liable to pay damages to another person. Before the passage of multiple-line
Insurance that covers
underwriting laws in the late 1940s and early 1950s, property/casualty insurance had to be written by property exposures such as
different insurers. Now they frequently are written in the same contract (e.g., homeowner’s and com- direct and indirect losses of
mercial package policies, which will be discussed in later chapters). property caused by perils
A private insurer can be classified as either a life/health or a property/casualty insurer. Health in- such as fire, windstorm, and
surance may be sold by either. Some insurers specialize in a particular type of insurance, such as prop- theft.
erty insurance. Others are affiliated insurers, in which several insurers (and sometimes noninsurance
businesses) are controlled by a holding company; all or almost all types of insurance are offered by
some company in the group.
Mutual insurers are owned and controlled, in theory if not in practice, by their policyowners. They
mutual insurers
have no stockholders and issue no capital stock. People become owners by purchasing an insurance
policy from the mutual insurer. Profits are shared with owners as policyowners’ dividends. Com- Insurers owned and
controlled, in theory if not in
pany officers are appointed by a board of directors that is, at least theoretically, elected by policyown-
practice, by their
ers. The stated purpose of the organization is to provide low-cost insurance rather than to make a policyowners.
profit for stockholders.
Research shows that mutual and stock insurers are highly competitive in the sense that neither policyowners’ dividends
seems to outperform the other. There are high-quality, low-cost insurers of both types. A wise con- Profits shared by insurance
sumer should analyze both before buying insurance. policyholders.
Many mutual insurers in both the life/health and property/casualty fields are large and operate
over large areas of the country. These large mutuals do a general business in the life/health and prop-
erty/casualty insurance fields, rather than confining their efforts to a small geographic area or a particu-
lar type of insured. The largest property/casualty mutual insurer in the United States is State Farm,
which was established in 1922 by George J. Mecherle, an Illinois farmer who turned to insurance sales.
State Farm grew to be the leading auto and homeowner’s insurer in the United States, with twenty-five
regional offices, more than 79,000 employees, and nearly 70 million policies in force. Because of its
116 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
mutual status, State Farm is overcapitalized (holding relatively more surplus than its peer group or
stock companies).
Demutualization
When top managers of a mutual company decide they need to raise capital, they may go through a process
called demutualization. In the last decade, there was an increase in the number of companies that decided to
demutualize and become stock companies. Policyholders, who were owners of the mutual company, received
shares in the stock company. Part of the motive was to provide top management with an additional avenue of
income in the form of stock options in the company. The demutualization wave in the life insurance industry
reached its peak in December 2001, when the large mutual insurer, Prudential, converted to a stock company.
The decade between the mid-1990s and mid-2000s saw the demutualization of twenty-two life insurance
companies: Unum, Equitable Life, Guarantee Mutual, State Mutual (First American Financial Life), Farm Family,
Mutual of New York, Standard Insurance, Manulife, Mutual Life of Canada (Clarica), Canada Life, Industrial Al-
liance, John Hancock, Metropolitan Life, Sun Life of Canada, Central Life Assurance (AmerUs), Indianapolis Life,
Phoenix Home Life, Principal Mutual, Anthem Life, Provident Mutual, Prudential, and General American Mutual
Holding Company (which was sold to MetLife through its liquidation by the Missouri Department of Insur-
ance).[6]
remained. As a result of the mammoth total losses (and bankruptcy or rehabilitation for many indi-
vidual members), Lloyd’s had reduced underwriting capacity and was experiencing difficulty in attract-
ing new capital. What started in a coffeehouse was getting close to the inside of the percolator.
Among Lloyd’s reforms was the acceptance of corporate capital. By mid-1994, 15 percent of its
capital was from twenty-five corporations that, unlike individual Names, have their liability limited to
the amount of invested capital. Another reform consisted of a new system of compulsory stop-loss in-
surance designed to help members reduce exposure to large losses. Reinsurance among syndicates has
ceased.
Other forms of insurance entities that are used infrequently are not featured in this textbook.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
In our example, the standard deviations of Group 1 and Group 2 are 9.5 and 19, respectively.
√(1,000) × (.1) × (.9) = 9.5
Thus, while the mean, or expected number of losses, quadrupled with the quadrupling of the sample
size, the standard deviation only doubled. Through this illustration, you can see that the proportional
deviation of actual from expected outcomes decreases with increased sample size. The relative disper-
sion has been reduced. The coefficient of variation (the standard deviation divided by the mean) is of-
ten used as a relative measure of risk. In the example above, Group 1 has a coefficient of variation of
9.5/100, or 0.095. Group 2 has a coefficient of variation of 19/400 = 0.0475, indicating the reduced risk.
Taking the extreme, consider an individual (n = 1) who attempts to retain the risk of loss. The per-
son either will or will not incur a loss, and even though the probability of loss is only 10 percent, how
does that person know whether he or she will be the unlucky one out of ten? Using the binomial distri-
bution, that individual’s standard deviation (risk) is a much higher measure of risk than that of the in-
surer. The individual’s coefficient of variation is .3/.1 = 3, demonstrating this higher risk. More specific-
ally, the risk is 63 times (3/.0475) that of the insurer, with 4,000 units exposed to loss.
8. Hatch’s furniture store has many perils that threaten its operation each day. Explain why each of
the following perils may or may not be insurable. In each case, discuss possible exceptions to the
general answer you have given.
a. The loss of merchandise because of theft when the thief is not caught and Hatch’s cannot
establish exactly when the loss occurred.
b. Injury to a customer when the store’s delivery person backs the delivery truck into that
customer while delivering a chair.
c. Injury to a customer when a sofa catches fire and burns the customer’s living room.
Discuss the fire damage to the customer’s home as well as the customer’s bodily injury.
d. Injury to a customer’s child who runs down an aisle in the store and falls.
e. Mental suffering of a customer whose merchandise is not delivered on schedule.
9. Jack and Jill decide they cannot afford to buy auto insurance. They are in a class with 160
students, and they come up with the idea of sharing the automobile risk with the rest of the
students. Their professor loves the idea and asks them to explain in detail how it will work.
Pretend you are Jack and Jill. Explain to the class the following:
a. If you expect to have only three losses per year on average (frequency) for a total of
$10,000 each loss (severity), what will be the cost of sharing these losses per student in
the class?
b. Do you think you have enough exposures to predict only three losses a year? Explain.
122 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
5. Insurance is regulated by the states, a topic that will be covered in more detail in
ENDNOTES Chapter 6.
6. Arthur D. Postal, “Decision On Demutualization Cost Basis Sought,” National Under-
writer, Life and Health Edition, March 25, 2005. Accessed March 5, 2009.
http://www.nationalunderwriter.com/lifeandhealth/nuonline/032805/
1. The interested student should also explore it further. In the case of AIG, the finite risk L12decision.asp.
arrangements were regarded as noninsurance transactions. In early 2006, AIG agreed
to pay $1.64 billion to settle investigations by the Securities and Exchange Commis- 7. An exception: national commercial banks in communities of less than 5,000 have, for
sion and New York State Attorney General Eliot Spitzer, who brought charges against many years, had the right to sell insurance.
AIG. This recent real-life example exemplifies how the careful treatment of the defini-
tion of insurance is so important to the business and its presentation of its financial 8. Mark E. Ruquet, “Insurer-Bank Integration Stampede Unlikely,” National Underwriter,
condition. For more information on finite risk programs, see “Finite Risk Reinsurance,” Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edition, April 23, 2001.
Insurance Information Institute (III), May 2005, at http://www.iii.org/media/hottopics/
insurance/finite/; Ian McDonald, Theo Francis, and Deborah Solomon, “Rewriting the 9. Lisa S. Howard, “Tight Re Market Puts Heat On Fronts,” National Underwriter, Property
Books—AIG Admits ‘Improper’ Accounting Broad Range of Problems Could Cut & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edition, March 4, 2002.
$1.77 Billion Of Insurer’s Net Worth A Widening Criminal Probe,” Wall Street Journal, 10. President Reagan signed into law the Liability Risk Retention Act in October 1986 (an
March 31, 2005, A1; Kara Scannell and Ian McDonald, “AIG Close to Deal to Settle amendment to the Product Liability Risk Retention Act of 1981). The act permits
Charges, Pay $1.5 Billion,” Wall Street Journal, February 6, 2006, C1; Steve Tuckey, “AIG formation of retention groups (a special form of captive) with fewer restrictions than
Settlement Leaves Out Life Issues,” National Underwriter Online News Service, February existed before. The retention groups are similar to association captives. The act per-
10, 2006. These articles are representative regarding these topics. mits formation of such groups in the United States under more favorable conditions
than have existed generally for association captives. The act may be particularly help-
2. Recent health care reforms (HIPAA 1996) have limited the ability of insurers to re-
ful to small businesses that could not feasibly self-insure but can do so within a des-
duce adverse selection through the use of preexisting-condition limitations.
ignated group.
3. Governmental insurance programs make greater deviations from the ideal requisites
11. “Vermont Licenses Industry-Backed Airline Insurer,” BestWire, June 11, 2002.
for insurability. They are able to accept greater risks because they often make their
insurance compulsory and have it subsidized from tax revenues, while private in- 12. Sue Johnson, “Airline Captive May Be Formed in Second Quarter,” Best’s Review,
surers operate only when a profit potential exists. The nature of government insur- March 2002. See also the document created by Marsh to explain the program along
ance programs will be outlined later in this chapter. with other aviation protection programs (as of August 14, 2002) at
http://www.marsh.se/files/Third%20Party%20War%20Liability%20Comparison.pdf.
4. Jeff D. Opdyke and Christopher Oster, “Hit With Big Losses, Insurers Put Squeeze on
Homeowner Policies,” Wall Street Journal, May 14, 2002. 13. For detailed information about PRIMA, search its Web site at
http://www.primacentral.org/default.php.
CHAP TER 6
Insurance Operations
The decision to seek coverage is only the first of many important choices you will have to make about insurance.
Whether you are acting as your own personal risk manager or on behalf of your business, it will help you to know
how insurance companies work. This chapter will explain the internal operations of an insurance company and will
dispel the notion that insurance jobs are all sales positions. The marketing aspect of insurance is important, as it is
for any business, but it is not the only aspect. An interesting and distinctive characteristic of insurance is that it is
really a business with two separate parts, each equally important to the success of the operation. One part is the
insurance underwriting business; the other is the investment of the funds paid by insureds.
1. Links
4. Insurance operations: reinsurance, legal and regulatory issues, claims adjusting, and management
1. LINKS
As we have done in each chapter, we first link the chapter to the complete picture of our holistic risk
management. As consumers, it is our responsibility to know where our premium money is going and
how it is being used. When we transfer risk to the insurance company and pay the premium, we get an
intangible product in return and a contract. However, this contract is for future payments in case of
losses. Only when or if we have a loss will we actually see a return on our purchase of insurance. There-
fore, it is imperative that the insurance company be there when we need it. To complete the puzzle of
ensuring that our holistic risk management process is appropriate, we also need to understand how our
insurance company operates. Because the risks are not transferred to just one insurer, we must learn
about the operations of a series of insurers—the reinsurers that insure the primary insurers. The de-
scriptions provided in this chapter are typical of most insurers. However, variations should be expec-
ted. To grasp how we relate to the operations of a typical insurer, look at Figure 6.1. The figure de-
scribes the fluid process of the operations within an insurer. Each function is closely linked to all the
other functions, and none is performed in a vacuum. It is like a circular chain in which each link is as
strong as the next one. Because insurers operate in markets with major influences, especially cata-
strophes (both natural and human-made), the external conditions affecting the insurers form an im-
portant part of this chapter. The regulatory structure of insurers is shown in the second part of the link
in Figure 6.1, which separates the industry’s institutions into those that are government-regulated and
those that are non- or semiregulated. Regardless of regulation, however, insurers are subject to market
conditions.
124 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
FIGURE 6.1 Links between the Holistic Risk Picture and Insurance Company Operations
Thus, when we select an insurer, we need to understand not only the organizational structure of that
insurance firm, we also need to be able to benefit from the regulatory safety net that it offers for our
protection. Also important is our clear understanding of insurance market conditions affecting the
products and their pricing. Major rate increases for coverage do not happen in a vacuum. While past
losses are important factors in setting rates, outside market conditions, availability, and affordability of
products are also very important factors in the risk management decision.
CHAPTER 6 INSURANCE OPERATIONS 125
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
2.1 Marketing
We begin with marketing despite the fact that it is not the first step in starting a business. From a con-
sumer’s point of view, it is the first glimpse into the operations of an insurer. Insurance may be bought
through agents, brokers, or (in some cases) directly from the insurer (via personal contact or on the In-
ternet). An agent legally represents the company, whereas a broker represents the buyer and, in half of
the states, also represents the insurer because of state regulations.[1] Both agents and brokers are com-
pensated by the insurer. The compensation issue was brought to the limelight in 2004 when New York
State Attorney General Eliot Spitzer opened an investigation of contingent commissions that brokers
received from insurers; these contingent commissions were regarded as bid rigging. Contingent com-
missions are paid to brokers for bringing in better business and can be regarded as profit sharing. As a
result of this investigation, regulators look for more transparency in the compensation disclosure of
agents and brokers, and major brokerage houses stopped the practice of accepting contingency com-
mission in the belief that clients view the practice negatively.[2]
In many states, producer is another name for both agents and brokers. This new name has been producer
given to create some uniformity among the types of distribution systems. Because life/health insurance
Another name for both
and property/casualty insurance developed separately in the United States, somewhat different market- agents and brokers.
ing systems evolved. Therefore, we will discuss these systems separately.
agents provide office space and have administrative responsibilities for some customer service
activities.
personal producing A large number of life/health insurers use personal producing general agents. A personal produ-
general agent cing general agent sells for one or more insurers, often with a higher-than-normal agent’s commis-
Agent who sells for one or sion and seldom hires other agents. The extra commission helps cover office expenses. The trend is to-
more insurers, often with a ward an agent representing several different insurers. This is desirable for consumers because a single
higher-than-normal agent’s insurer cannot have the best products for all needs. To meet a client’s insurance needs more com-
commission and seldom hires pletely, the agent needs to have the flexibility to serve as a broker or a personal producing general agent
other agents. for the insurer with the most desirable policy.
Managerial (Branch Office) System
A branch office is an extension of the home office headed by a branch manager. The branch manager
branch manager
is a company employee who is compensated by a combination of salary, bonus, and commissions re-
A company employee who is lated to the productivity of the office to which he or she is assigned. The manager also employs and
compensated by a
combination of salary, bonus,
trains agents for the company but cannot employ an agent without the consent of the company. Com-
and commissions related to pensation plans for agents are determined by the company. All expenses of maintaining the office are
the productivity of the office paid by the company, which has complete control over the details of its operation.
to which he or she is
assigned. Group and Supplemental Insurance Marketing
Group life, health, and retirement plans are sold to employers by agents in one of the systems described
above or by brokers. An agent may be assisted in this specialized field by a group sales representative.
Large volumes of group business are also placed through direct negotiations between employers and
insurers. A brokerage firm or an employee benefits consulting firm may be hired on a fee-only basis by
the employer who wishes to negotiate directly with insurers, thus avoiding commissions to the agent/
broker. In these direct negotiations, the insurer typically is represented by a salaried group sales
representative.
Supplemental insurance plans that provide life, health, and other benefits to employees through
employer sponsorship and payroll deduction have become common. These plans are marketed by
agents, brokers, and exclusive agents. The latter usually work on commissions; some receive salaries
plus bonuses.
Brokers
A considerable amount of insurance and reinsurance is placed through brokers. A broker solicits busi-
broker
ness from the insured, as does an agent, but the broker acts as the insured’s legal agent when the busi-
ness is placed with an insurer. In about half the states, brokers are required to be agents of the insurer. Individual who solicits
business from the insured
In the other states, brokers do not have ongoing contracts with insurers—their sole obligation is to the and also acts as the insured’s
client. When it appears desirable, a broker may draft a specially worded policy for a client and then legal agent when the
place the policy with an insurer. Some property/casualty brokers merely place insurance with an in- business is placed with an
surer and then rely on this company to provide whatever engineering and loss-prevention services are insurer.
needed. Others have a staff of engineers to perform such services for clients. Modern brokerage firms
provide a variety of related services, such as risk management surveys, information systems services re-
lated to risk management, complete administrative and claim services to self-insurers, and captive in-
surer management.
Brokers are a more significant part of the marketing mechanism in commercial property, liability,
employee benefits, and marine insurance than in personal lines of insurance. Brokers are most active in
metropolitan areas and among large insureds, where a broker’s knowledge of specialized coverages and
the market for them is important. Some brokerage firms operate on a local or regional basis, whereas
others are national or international in their operations.
With today’s proliferation of lines and services, it is extremely difficult for brokers to understand
all the products completely. Brokers are always looking for unique product designs, but gaining access
to innovative products and actually putting them into use are two different things. Generally, each
broker selects about three favorite insurers. The broker’s concern is the underwriting standards of their
insurers. For example, a broker would like to be able to place a client who takes Prozac with an insurer
that covers such clients.
Internet Marketing
With today’s proliferation of Internet marketing, one can select an insurance product and compare
Internet marketing
price and coverage on the Internet. For example, someone interested in purchasing a life insurance
policy can click on Insweb.com. If she or he is looking for health insurance, ehealthinsurance or other Selecting an insurance
product and comparing price
such Web sites present information and a questionnaire to fill out. The site will respond with quotes and coverage on the Internet.
from insurers and details about the plans. The customer can then send contact information to selected
insurers, who will begin the underwriting process to determine insurability and appropriate rates. The
sale is not finalized through the Internet, but the connection with the agent and underwriters is made.
Any Internet search engine will lead to many such Web sites.
Most insurance companies, like other businesses, set up their own Web sites to promote their
products’ features. They set up the sites to provide consumers with the tools to compare products and
find the unique characteristics of the insurer. See the box, "Shopping for Insurance on the Internet" for
a description of Internet sites.
Mass Merchandising
Mass merchandising is the selling of insurance by mail, telephone, television, or e-mail. Mass mer- mass merchandising
chandising often involves a sponsoring organization such as an employer, trade association, university,
or creditor; however, you are likely to be asked to respond directly to the insurer. Some mass mer- The selling of insurance by
mail, telephone, television, or
chandising mixes agents and direct response (mass mailing of information, for example, that includes a e-mail.
card the interested person can fill out and return); an agent handles the initial mailing and sub-
sequently contacts the responding members of the sponsoring organization.
128 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
In some cases, you can save money buying insurance by mass merchandising methods. Direct re-
sponse insurers, however, cannot provide the counseling you may receive from a good agent or finan-
cial planner.
Financial Planners
A financial planner facilitates some insurance sales by serving as a consultant on financial matters,
financial planner
primarily to high-income clients. An analysis of risk exposures and recommendations on appropriate
Individual who facilitates risk management techniques, including insurance, are major parts of the financial planning process. A
some insurance sales by
serving as a consultant on
fee-only financial planner, knowledgeable in insurance, may direct you to good-quality, no-load insur-
financial matters, primarily to ance products when they are priced lower than comparable products sold through agents. You are
high-income clients. already paying a fee for advice from the financial planner. Why also pay a commission to an insurance
agent or broker?
In many instances, it is appropriate for the financial planner to send you to an insurance agent.
Products available through agents may have a better value than the still limited supply of no-load
products. Also, your financial planner is likely to be a generalist with respect to insurance, and you may
need advice from a knowledgeable agent. In any event, financial planners are now part of the insurance
distribution system.
Professionalism in Marketing
Ideally, an agent has several years of experience before giving advice on complicated insurance matters.
You will be interested in the agent’s experience and educational qualifications, which should cover an
extensive study of insurance, finance, and related subjects. A major route for life/health agents to gain
this background is by meeting all requirements for the Chartered Life Underwriter (CLU) designation.
The Chartered Financial Consultant (ChFC) designation from the American College (for information,
CHAPTER 6 INSURANCE OPERATIONS 129
2.2 Underwriting
Underwriting is the process of classifying the potential insureds into the appropriate risk classifica- underwriting
tion in order to charge the appropriate rate. An underwriter decides whether or not to insure expos-
The process of evaluating
ures on which applications for insurance are submitted. There are separate procedures for group un-
risks, selecting which risks to
derwriting and individual underwriting. For group underwriting, the group characteristics, demo- accept, and identifying
graphics, and past losses are judged. Because individual insurability is not examined, even very sick potential adverse selection.
people such as AIDS patients can obtain life insurance through a group policy. For individual under-
writing, the insured has to provide evidence of insurability in areas of life and health insurance or spe- underwriter
cific details about the property and automobiles for property/casualty lines of business. An individual Individual who decides
applicant for life insurance must be approved by the life insurance company underwriter, a process that whether or not to insure
is sometimes very lengthy. It is not uncommon for the application to include a questionnaire about exposures on which
applications for insurance are
lifestyle, smoking habits, medical status, and the medical status of close family members. For large
submitted.
amounts of life insurance, the applicant is usually required to undergo a medical examination.
Once the underwriter determines that insurance can be issued, the next decision is to apply the
proper premium rate. Premium rates are determined for classes of insureds by the actuarial depart-
ment. An underwriter’s role is to decide which class is appropriate for each insured. The business of in-
surance inherently involves discrimination; otherwise, adverse selection would make insurance
unavailable.
Some people believe that any characteristic over which we have no control, such as gender, race,
and age, should be excluded from insurance underwriting and rating practices (although in life and an-
nuity contracts, consideration of age seems to be acceptable). Their argument is that if insurance is in-
tended in part to encourage safety, then its operation ought to be based on behavior, not on qualities
with which we are born. Others argue that some of these factors are the best predictors of losses and ex-
penses, and without them, insurance can function only extremely inefficiently. Additionally, some ar-
gument could be made that almost no factor is truly voluntary or controllable. Is a poor resident of Ch-
icago, for instance, able to move out of the inner city? A National Underwriter article provided an in-
teresting suggestion for mitigating negative characteristics: enclosing a personalized letter with an ap-
plication to explain special circumstances.[5] For example, according to the article, “If your client is
overweight, and his family is overweight, but living a long and healthy life, note both details on the re-
cord. This will give the underwriters more to go on.” The article continues, “Sending letters with ap-
plications is long overdue. They will often shorten the underwriting cycle and get special risks—many
of whom have been given a clean bill of health by their doctor or are well on their way to recovery—the
coverage they need and deserve.”
Over the years, insurers have used a variety of factors in their underwriting decisions. A number of redlining
these have become taboo from a public policy standpoint. Their use may be considered unfair discrim-
When an insurer designates a
ination. In automobile insurance, for instance, factors such as marital status and living arrangements
geographical area in which it
have played a significant underwriting role, with divorced applicants considered less stable than never- chooses not to provide
married applicants. In property insurance, concern over redlining receives public attention periodic- insurance, or to provide it
ally. Redlining occurs when an insurer designates a geographical area in which it chooses not to only at substantially higher
provide insurance, or to provide it only at substantially higher prices. These decisions are made prices.
without considering individual insurance applicants. Most often, the redlining is in poor urban areas,
placing low-income inner-city dwellers at great disadvantage. A new controversy in the underwriting
field is the use of genetic testing. In Great Britain, insurers use genetic testing to screen for Hunting-
ton’s disease,[6] but U.S. companies are not yet using such tests. As genetic testing continues to im-
prove, look for U.S. insurance companies to request access to that information as part of an applicant’s
medical history.
Two major areas of underwriting controversies are discussed in the box below, "Keeping Score—Is
It Fair to Use Credit Rating in Underwriting?" and in "Insurance and Your Privacy—Who Knows?" in
Chapter 7. The need for information is a balancing act between underwriting requirements and pre-
serving the privacy of insureds. The tug-of-war between more and less information is a regulatory mat-
ter. The use of credit ratings in setting premiums illustrates a company’s need to place insureds in the
appropriate risk classification—a process that preserves the fundamental rules of insurance operations
(discussed in Chapter 5). We will explore underwriting further in other chapters as we look at types of
policies.
130 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
Sources: Barbara Bowers, “Giving Credit Its Due: Insurers, Agents, Legislators, Regulators and Consumers Battle to Define the Role of Insurance Scoring”
and “Insurers Address Flurry of Insurance-Scoring Legislative Initiatives,” Best’s Review, May 2002; U.S. Federal Trade Commission at http://www.ftc.gov/
bcp/conline/pubs/credit/scoring.htm. See http://www.ncoil.org/ and all media outlets for coverage of this issue, which occurs very frequently.
2.3 Administration
After insurance is sold and approved by the underwriter, records must be established, premiums col-
lected, customer inquiries answered, and many other administrative jobs performed. Administration is
defined broadly here to include accounting, information systems, office administration, customer ser-
vice, and personnel management.
Service
Service is the ultimate indicator on which the quality of the product provided by insurance depends. service
An agent’s or broker’s advice and an insurer’s claim practices are the primary services that the typical
individual or business needs. In addition, prompt, courteous responses to inquiries concerning changes The ultimate indicator upon
which the quality of the
in the policy, the availability of other types of insurance, changes of address, and other routine matters product provided by
are necessary. insurance depends.
Another service of major significance that some insurers offer, primarily to commercial clients, is
engineering and loss control. Engineering and loss control is concerned with methods of preven- engineering and loss
tion and reduction of loss whenever the efforts required are economically feasible. Much of the engin- control
eering and loss-control activity may be carried on by the insurer or under its direction. The facilities Methods of prevention and
the insurer has to devote to such efforts and the degree to which such efforts are successful is an im- reduction of loss whenever
portant element to consider in selecting an insurer. Part of the risk manager’s success depends on this the efforts required are
element. Engineering and loss-control services are particularly applicable to workers’ compensation economically feasible.
and boiler and machinery exposures. With respect to the health insurance part of an employee benefits
program, loss control is called cost containment and may be achieved primarily through managed care
and wellness techniques.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. Would you rather shop for insurance on the Internet or call an agent?
2. Advertising by the Independent Insurance Agents & Brokers of America extols the unique features of the
American agency system and the independent agent. Its logo is the Big I. Does this advertising influence
your choice of an agent? Do you prefer one type of agent to others? If so, why?
3. What does an underwriter do? Why is the underwriting function in an insurance company so important?
4. Why are insurers using credit scoring in their underwriting? In what areas is it possible to misjudge a
potential insured when using credit scoring? What other underwriting criteria would you suggest to
replace the credit scoring criterion?
132 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
Table 6.1 describes an insurance company’s incurred losses for product liability from 1994 to 2000.
incurred losses
Incurred losses are both paid losses plus known but not yet paid losses. Look at accident year 1996:
over the first twelve months after those accidents, the company posted losses of $38.901 million related Paid losses plus known, but
not yet paid losses.
to those accidents. Over the next twelve months—as more injuries came to light or belated claims were
filed or lawsuits were settled—the insurer incurred almost $15 million, so that the cumulative losses
after twenty-four developed months comes to $53.679 million. Each year brought more losses relating
to accidents in 1996, so that by the end of the sixty-month development period, the company had accu-
mulated $70.934 million in incurred losses for incidents from accident year 1996. The table ends there,
but the incurred losses continue; the ultimate total is not yet known.
To calculate how much money must be kept in reserve for losses, actuaries must estimate the ulti-
mate incurred loss for each accident year. They can do so by calculating the rate of growth of the losses
for each year and then extending that rate to predict future losses. First, we calculate the rate for each
development period. In accident year 1996, the $38.901 million loss in the first development period in-
creased to $53.679 million in the second development period. The loss development factor for the
twelve- to twenty-four-month period is therefore 1.380 million (53.679/38.901), meaning that the loss
increased, or developed, by a factor of 1.380 (or 38 percent). The factor for twenty-four- to thirty-six
months is 1.172 (62.904/53.679). The method to calculate all the factors follows the same pattern: the
second period divided by first period. Table 6.2 shows the factors for each development period from
Table 6.1.
TABLE 6.1 Incurred Losses for Accident Years by Development Periods (in Millions of Dollars)
Developed Months Accident Year
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000
12 $37.654 $38.781 $38.901 $36.980 $37.684 $39.087 $37.680
24 53.901 53.789 53.679 47.854 47.091 47.890
36 66.781 61.236 62.904 56.781 58.976
48 75.901 69.021 67.832 60.907
60 79.023 73.210 70.934
72 81.905 79.087
84 83.215
After we complete the computation of all the factors in Table 6.2, we transpose the table in order to
compute the averages for each development period. The transposed Table 6.2 is in Table 6.3. The aver-
ages of the development factors are at the bottom of the table. You see, for example, that the average of
factors for the thirty-six- to forty-eight-month development period of all accident years is 1.104. This
means that, on average, losses increased by a factor of 1.104 (or 10.4 percent, if you prefer) in that peri-
od. That average is an ordinary mean. To exclude anomalies, however, actuaries often exclude the
highest and lowest factors in each period, and average the remainders. The last line in Table 6.3 is the
average, excluding the high and low, and this average is used in Table 6.4 to complete the triangle.
134 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
TABLE 6.3 Averages of the Incurred Loss Factors for Each Accident Year
Accident Year Developed Months
12–24 24–36 36–48 48–60 60–72 72–84
1994 1.431 1.239 1.137 1.041 1.036 1.016
1995 1.387 1.138 1.127 1.061 1.080
1996 1.380 1.172 1.078 1.046
1997 1.294 1.187 1.073
1998 1.250 1.252
1999 1.225
12–24 24–36 36–48 48–60 60–72 72–84
Average 1.328 1.198 1.104 1.049 1.058 1.016
Average of last three years 1.256 1.204 1.093 1.049 1.058 1.016
Average of last four years 1.287 1.187 1.104 1.049 1.058 1.016
Average excluding high and low 1.328 1.199 1.103 1.046 1.058 1.016
In Table 6.4, we complete the incurred loss factors for the whole period of development. The informa-
tion in bold is from Table 6.2. The information in italics is added for the later periods when incurred
loss data are not yet available. These are the predictions of future losses. Thus, for accident year 1997,
the bold part shows the factors from Table 6.2, which were derived from the actual incurred loss in-
formation in Table 6.1. We see from Table 6.4 that we can expect losses to increase in any forty-eight-
to sixty-month period by a factor of 1.046, in a sixty- to seventy-two-month period by 1.058, and in a
seventy-two- to eighty-four-month period by 1.016. The development to ultimate factor is the product
of all estimated factors: for 1997, it is 1.046 × 1.058 × 1.016 × 1.02 = 1.147. Actuaries adjust the
development-to-ultimate factor based on their experience and other information.[7]
incurred but not reported
To determine ultimate losses, these factors can be applied to the dollar amounts in Table 6.1. Table
(IBNR) 6.5 provides the incurred loss estimates to ultimate payout for each accident year for this book of busi-
ness. To illustrate how the computation is done, we estimate total incurred loss for accident year 1999.
Estimated losses that
insureds did not claim yet but
The most recent known incurred loss for accident year 1999 is as of 24 months: $47.890 million. To es-
are expected to materialize in timate the incurred losses at thirty-six months, we multiply by the development factor 1.199 and arrive
the future. at $57.426 million. That $57.426 million is multiplied by the applicable factors to produce a level of
$63.326 million after forty-eight months, and $66.239 million after sixty months. Ultimately, the total
payout for accident year 1999 is predicted to be $72.625 million. Because $47.890 million has already
been paid out, the actuary will recommend keeping a reserve of $24.735 million to pay future claims. It
is important to note that the ultimate level of incurred loss in this process includes incurred but not re-
ported (IBNR) losses. Incurred but not reported (IBNR) losses are estimated losses that insureds
did not claim yet, but they are expected to materialize in the future. This is usually an estimate that is
hard to accurately project and is the reason the final projections of September 11, 2001, losses are still
in question.
TABLE 6.4 Development of the Triangles of Incurred Loss Factors to Ultimate for Each Accident Year
Developed Months Accident Year
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000
12–24 1.431 1.387 1.380 1.294 1.250 1.225 1.328
24–36 1.239 1.138 1.172 1.187 1.252 1.199 1.199
36–48 1.137 1.127 1.078 1.073 1.103 1.103 1.103
48–60 1.041 1.061 1.046 1.046 1.046 1.046 1.046
60–72 1.036 1.080 1.058 1.058 1.058 1.058 1.058
72–84 1.016 1.016 1.016 1.016 1.016 1.016 1.016
84–ultimate* 1.020 1.020 1.020 1.020 1.020 1.020 1.020
Development to ultimate† 1.020 1.036 1.096 1.147 1.265 1.517 2.014
* Actuaries use their experience and other information to determine the factor that will be used from 84
months to ultimate. This factor is not available to them from the original triangle of losses.
† For example, the development to ultimate for 1997 is 1.046 × 1.058 × 1.016 × 1.02 = 1.147.
CHAPTER 6 INSURANCE OPERATIONS 135
TABLE 6.5 Development of the Triangle of Incurred Losses to Ultimate (in Millions of Dollars)
Developed Months Accident Year
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Total
12 $37.654 $38.781 $38.901 $36.980 $37.684 $39.087 $37.680
24 53.901 53.789 53.679 47.854 47.091 47.890 50.039
36 66.781 61.236 62.904 56.781 58.976 57.426 60.003
48 75.901 69.021 67.832 60.907 65.035 63.326 66.167
60 79.023 73.210 70.934 63.709 68.027 66.239 69.211
72 81.905 79.087 75.048 67.404 71.972 70.080 73.225
84 83.215 80.352 76.249 68.482 73.123 71.201 74.396
Ultimate 84.879 81.959 77.773 69.852 74.586 72.625 75.884 537.559
Pd. to date 83.215 79.087 70.934 60.907 58.976 47.890 37.680 438.689
Reserve 1.664 2.872 6.839 8.945 15.610 24.735 38.204 98.870
The process of loss development shown in the example of Table 6.1 through Table 6.5 is used also for
rate calculations
rate calculations because actuaries need to know the ultimate losses each book of business will incur.
Rate calculations are the computations of how much to charge for insurance coverage once the ulti- The computation of how
much to charge for insurance
mate level of loss is estimated, plus factors for taxes, expenses, and returns on investments. coverage once the ultimate
level of loss is estimated plus
Catastrophe (Cat) Modeling factors for taxes, expenses,
Catastrophe (cat) modeling is composed of sophisticated statistical and technological mathematical and returns on investments.
equations and analysis that help predict future occurrences of natural and human-made disastrous
events with large severity of losses. These models are relatively new and are made possible by the expo- catastrophe (cat) modeling
nential improvements of information systems and statistical modeling over the years. Cat modeling re- The use of computer
lies on computer technology to synthesize loss data, assess historical disaster statistics, incorporate risk technology to synthesize loss
features, and run event simulations as an aid in predicting future losses. From this information, cat data, assess historical disaster
models project the impact of hypothetical catastrophes on residential and commercial properties.[8] statistics, incorporate risk
Cat modeling is concerned with predicting the future risk of catastrophes, primarily in the form of features, and run event
simulations as an aid in
natural disasters. Cat modeling has its roots in the late 1980s and came to be utilized considerably fol- predicting future losses.
lowing Hurricane Andrew in 1992 and the Northridge earthquake in 1994.[9] The parallel rapid soph-
istication of computer systems during this period was fortuitous and conducive to the growth of cat
modeling. Today, every conceivable natural disaster is considered in cat models. Common hazard
scenarios include hurricanes, earthquakes, tornados, and floods. One catastrophic event of increased
concern in recent years is that of terrorism; some effort has been made to quantify the impact of this
risk through cat models as well.[10]
Development of catastrophe models is complex, requiring the input of subject matter experts such
as meteorologists, engineers, mathematicians, and actuaries. Due to the highly specialized nature and
great demand for risk management tools, consulting firms have emerged to offer cat modeling solu-
tions. The three biggest players in this arena are AIR Worldwide, Risk Management Solutions (RMS),
and EQECAT.[11] The conclusions about exposures drawn from the models of different organizations
are useful to insurers because they allow for better loss predictions of specific events.
Based on inputs regarding geographic locations, physical features of imperiled structures, and
quantitative information about existing insurance coverage, catastrophe models render an output re-
garding the projected frequency, severity, and the overall dollar value of a catastrophic occurrence.
From these results, it is possible to place property into appropriate risk categories. Thus, cat modeling
can be extremely useful from an underwriting standpoint. Additionally, indications of high-dollar,
high-severity risks in a particular region would certainly be influential to the development of premium
rates and the insurer’s decision to explore reinsurance options (discussed in the next section of this
chapter). Cat models are capable of estimating losses for a portfolio of insured properties.[12] Clearly,
the interest that property/casualty insurers have in loss projections from hurricane catastrophes in
southern Florida would benefit from this type of modeling.
Reliance on cat models came under fire following the devastating back-to-back hurricane seasons
of 2004 and 2005. Critics argued that the models that were utilized underestimated the losses. It is im-
portant to note that the insurance industry is not the only market for cat models; consequently, differ-
ent methodologies are employed depending on the needs of the end-user. These methodologies might
incorporate different assumptions, inputs, and algorithms in calculation.[13] The unusually active 2004
and 2005 hurricane seasons could similarly be considered outside a normal standard deviation and
thus unaccounted for by the models. In response to criticisms, refinements by developers following
136 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
Hurricane Katrina included near-term projections providing probable maximum loss estimates using
short-term expectations of hurricane activity.
Life and Annuity Lines
For life insurance, actuaries use mortality tables, which predict the percentage of people in each age
mortality tables
group who are expected to die each year. This percentage is used to estimate the required reserves and
Tables that indicate the to compute life insurance rates. Life insurance, like other forms of insurance, is based on three con-
percent of expected deaths
for each age group.
cepts: pooling many exposures into a group, accumulating a fund paid for by contributions
(premiums) from the members of the group, and paying from this fund for the losses of those who die
premium elements each year. That is, life insurance involves the group sharing of individual losses. To set premium rates,
The adjustments for various the insurer must be able to calculate the probability of death at various ages among its insureds, based
factors in life insurance on pooling. Life insurers must collect enough premiums to cover mortality costs (the cost of claims). In
premiums. addition to covering mortality costs, a life insurance premium, like a property/casualty premium, must
reflect several adjustments, as noted in Table 6.6. The adjustments for various factors in life insurance
investment income
premiums are known as premium elements. First, the premium is reduced because the insurer ex-
Returns from all the assets
held by the insurers from
pects to earn investment income, or returns from all the assets held by the insurers from both capital
both capital investment and investment and from premiums. Investment is a very important aspect of the other side of the insur-
from premiums. ance business, as discussed below. Insurers invest the premiums they receive from insureds until losses
need to be paid. Income from the investments is an offset in the premium calculations. By reducing the
rates, most of an insurer’s investment income benefits consumers. Second, the premium is increased to
cover the insurer’s marketing and administrative expenses, as described above. Taxes are the third
component; those that are levied on the insurer also must be recovered. Fourth, in calculating premi-
ums, an actuary usually increases the premium to cover the insurer’s risk of not predicting future losses
accurately. The fifth element is the profits that the insurer should obtain because insurers are not “not
for profit” organizations. All life insurance premium elements are depicted in Table 6.6 below. The ac-
tual prediction of deaths and the estimation of other premium elements are complicated actuarial
processes.
TABLE 6.6 Term Premium Elements
Mortality Cost
− Investment income
+ Expense charge
+ Taxes
+ Risk change
+ Profit
= Gross premium charge
The mortality rate has two important characteristics that greatly influence insurer practices and the
nature of life insurance contracts. First, yearly probabilities of death rise with age. Second, for practical
reasons, actuaries set at 1.0 the probability of death at an advanced age, such as ninety-nine. That is,
death during that year is considered a certainty, even though some people survive. The characteristics
are illustrated with the mortality curve.
Mortality Curve
If we plot the probability of death for males by age, as in Figure 6.2, we have a mortality curve. The
mortality curve
mortality curve illustrates the relationship between age and the probability of death. It shows that the
Curve that illustrates the mortality rate for males is relatively high at birth but declines until age ten. It then rises until age
relationship between age
and the probability of death.
twenty-one and declines between ages twenty-two and twenty-nine. This decline apparently reflects
many accidental deaths among males in their teens and early twenties, followed by a subsequent de-
crease. The rise is continuous for females older than age ten and for males after age twenty-nine. The
rise is rather slow until middle age, at which point it begins to accelerate. At the more advanced ages, it
rises very rapidly.
CHAPTER 6 INSURANCE OPERATIONS 137
3.2 Investments
As noted above, insurance companies are in two businesses: the insurance business and the investment
capital and surplus
business. The insurance side is underwriting and reserving (liabilities), while the investment side is the
area of securing the best rate of return on the assets entrusted to the insurer by the policyholders seek- The equivalent of equity on
ing the security. Investment income is a significant part of total income in most insurance companies. the balance sheet of any
firm—the net worth of the
Liability accounts in the form of reserves are maintained on balance sheets to cover future claims and firm, or assets minus liabilities.
other obligations such as taxes and premium reserves. Assets must be maintained to cover the reserves
and still leave the insurer with an adequate net worth in the form of capital and surplus. Capital and
surplus are the equivalent of equity on the balance sheet of any firm—the net worth of the firm, or as-
sets minus liabilities.
The investment mix of the life/health insurance industry is shown Table 6.7 and that of the prop-
erty/casualty industry is shown in Table 6.8. As you can see, the assets of the life insurance industry in
the United States were $4.95 trillion in 2007. This included majority investments in the credit markets,
which includes bonds of all types and mortgage-backed securities of $387.5 billion. As discussed in
Chapter 1 and the box below, “Problem Investments and the Credit Crisis,” many of these securities
were no longer performing during the credit crisis of 2008–2009. In comparison, the U.S. property cas-
ualty industry’s asset holdings in 2007 were $1.37 trillion, with $125.8 billion in mortgage-backed se-
curities. In Chapter 13, we included a discussion of risk management of the balance sheet to ensure that
the net worth of the insurer is not lost when assets held are no longer performing. The capital and sur-
plus of the U.S. property/casualty industry reached $531.3 billion at year-end 2007, up from $499.4 bil-
lion at year-end 2006. The capital and surplus of the U.S. life/health insurance industry was $252.8 bil-
lion in 2007, up from $244.4 billion in 2006.[14]
138 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
The liabilities are composed mostly of reserves for loss payments. For the life insurance industry, the
largest component of liabilities is reserves for pensions. Life reserves are the second-largest component.
For property/casualty insurers, the reserves are for all lines of insurance, depending on the mix of
products sold by each company.
Many conglomerate insurance corporations own their own investment firms and provide mutual
funds. In this area, insurers, like other financial institutions, are subject to regulation by the states and
by the Securities and Exchange Commission.
CHAPTER 6 INSURANCE OPERATIONS 139
me more angry [than AIG], I can’t think of one.” He likened AIG to a “hedge fund … attached to a large and
stable insurance company” that made “irresponsible bets” in explaining the firm’s actions leading up to its fin-
ancial meltdown. Bernanke called for the Obama administration to expand the powers of the Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation (FDIC) to address the problems of large financial institutions rather than focusing on
banks alone.[23]
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. Why must insurance companies be concerned about the amount paid for a loss that occurred years ago?
2. Explain the process an actuary goes through to calculate reserves using the loss development triangle.
3. When does an actuary need to use his or her judgment in adjusting the loss development factors?
4. Compare the investment (asset) portfolio of the life/health insurance industry to that of the property/
casualty insurance industry. Why do you think there are differences?
5. Use the assets and liabilities of property/casualty insurers in their balance sheets to explain why losses
from an event like Hurricane Ike can hurt the net worth of insurers.
6. The following table shows the incurred losses of the Maruri Insurance Company for its liability line.
Development Year
Accident Year 0 1 2 3 4 5 6
2002 $27,634 $28,781 $28,901 $26,980 $27,684 $29,087 $27,680
2003 $43,901 $43,777 $43,653 $37,854 $37,091 $37,890
2004 $56,799 $51,236 $52,904 $46,777 $48,923
2005 $65,901 $59,021 $57,832 $50,907
2006 $69,023 $63,210 $60,934
2007 $71,905 $69,087
2008 $73,215
b. Plot the numbers in the table on a graph where that horizontal axis represents the development
period and the vertical axis represents the amounts. Can you describe the pattern in the form of a
graph (a free-hand drawing)? If you know regression analysis, try to describe the graph by a
nonlinear regression. Can you give your estimate for the ultimate payments (the total claims after
many more years) for a typical accident year by just looking at the graph and without any
mathematical calculations?
c. Create the noncumulative (current) claim payments triangle (the difference between the years).
d. Describe the differences you see between the cumulative plot and the noncumulative plot. Can
you say something about the “regularity” of the pattern that you see in each plot? Do you get an
“illusion” that the cumulative data are more predictable? When looking at the noncumulative
curve, do you see any points that draw your attention actuarially?
e. Can you say something about the possible trends of this portfolio?
f. What are the disadvantages of using chain ladder approach, in comparison to the new actuarial
approach?
g. Compare your answer to discussion question 6 to the analysis of this question.
142 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
4.1 Reinsurance
reinsurance
Reinsurance is an arrangement by which an insurance company transfers all or a portion of its risk
under a contract (or contracts) of insurance to another company. The company transferring risk in a
An arrangement by which an
reinsurance arrangement is called the ceding insurer. The company taking over the risk in a reinsur-
insurance company transfers
all or a portion of its risk ance arrangement is the assuming reinsurer. In effect, the insurance company that issued the policies
under a contract (or is seeking protection from another insurer, the assuming reinsurer. Typically, the reinsurer assumes re-
contracts) of insurance to sponsibility for part of the losses under an insurance contract; however, in some instances, the rein-
another company. surer assumes full responsibility for the original insurance contract. As with insurance, reinsurance in-
ceding insurer
volves risk transfer, risk distribution, risk diversification across more insurance companies, and cover-
age against insurance risk. Risk diversification is the spreading of the risk to other insurers to reduce
The company transferring risk
the exposure of the primary insurer, the one that deals with the final consumer.
in a reinsurance arrangement.
When the reinsurance agreement calls for proportional (pro rata) reinsurance, the reinsurer
proportional (pro rata)
assumes a prespecified percentage of both premiums and losses. Expenses are also shared in accord reinsurance
with this prespecified percentage. Because the ceding company has incurred operating expenses associ-
Situation in which the
ated with the marketing, evaluation, and delivery of coverage, the reinsurer often pays a fee called a reinsurer assumes a
ceding commission to the original insurer. Such a commission may make reinsurance profitable to prespecified percentage of
the ceding company, in addition to offering protection against catastrophe and improved both premiums and losses.
predictability.
ceding commission
Nonproportional reinsurance obligates the reinsurer to pay losses when they exceed a desig-
A fee paid by the reinsurer to
nated threshold. Excess-loss reinsurance, for instance, requires the reinsurer to accept amounts of the original insurer.
insurance that exceed the ceding insurer’s retention limit. As an example, a small insurer might rein-
sure all property insurance above $25,000 per contract. The excess policy could be written per contract
nonproportional
or per occurrence. Both proportional and nonproportional reinsurance may be either treaty or facultat- reinsurance
ive. The excess-loss arrangement is depicted in Table 6.9. A proportional agreement is shown in Table
6.10. Reinsurance that obligates
the reinsurer to pay losses
In addition to specifying the situations under which a reinsurer has financial responsibility, the re- when they exceed a
insurance agreement places a limit on the amount of reinsurance the reinsurer must accept. For ex- designated threshold.
ample, the SSS Reinsurance Company may limit its liability per contract to four times the ceding in-
surer’s retention limit, which in this case would yield total coverage of $125,000 ($25,000 retention plus excess-loss reinsurance
$100,000 in reinsurance on any one property). When the ceding company issues a policy for an Reinsurance that requires the
amount that exceeds the sum of its retention limit and SSS’s reinsurance limit, it would still need an- reinsurer to accept amounts
other reinsurer, perhaps TTT Reinsurance Company, to accept a second layer of reinsurance. of insurance that exceed the
ceding insurer’s retention
TABLE 6.9 An Example of Excess-Loss Reinsurance limit.
Benefits of Reinsurance
A ceding company (the primary insurer) uses reinsurance mainly to protect itself against losses in indi-
vidual cases beyond a specified sum (i.e., its retention limit), but competition and the demands of its
sales force may require issuance of policies of greater amounts. A company that issued policies no lar-
ger than its retention would severely limit its opportunities in the market. Many insureds do not want
to place their insurance with several companies, preferring to have one policy with one company for
each loss exposure. Furthermore, agents find it inconvenient to place multiple policies every time they
insure a large risk.
In addition to its concern with individual cases, a primary insurer must protect itself from cata- aggregate reinsurance
strophic losses of a particular type (such as a windstorm), in a particular area (such as a city or a block
Policy that can be purchased
in a city), or during a specified period of operations (such as a calendar year). An aggregate reinsur- for coverage against
ance policy can be purchased for coverage against potentially catastrophic situations faced by the potentially catastrophic
primary insurer. Sometimes they are considered excess policies, as described above, when the excess re- situations faced by the
tention is per occurrence. An example of how an excess-per-occurrence policy works can be seen from primary insurer.
the damage caused by Hurricane Andrew in 1992. Insurers who sell property insurance in hurricane-
prone areas probably choose to reinsure their exposures not just on a property-by-property basis but
also above some chosen level for any specific event. Andrew was considered one event and caused bil-
lions of dollars of damage in Florida alone. A Florida insurer may have set limits, perhaps $100 million,
for its own exposure to a given hurricane. For its insurance in force above $100 million, the insurer can
purchase excess or aggregate reinsurance.
Other benefits of reinsurance can be derived when a company offering a particular line of insur-
ance for the first time wants to protect itself from excessive losses and also take advantage of the
144 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
reinsurer’s knowledge concerning the proper rates to be charged and underwriting practices to be fol-
lowed. In other cases, a rapidly expanding company may have to shift some of its liabilities to a rein-
surer to avoid impairing its capital. Reinsurance often also increases the amount of insurance the un-
derlying insurer can sell. This is referred to as increasing capacity.
Reinsurance is significant to the buyer of insurance for a number of reasons. First, reinsurance in-
creases the financial stability of insurers by spreading risk. This increases the likelihood that the origin-
al insurer will be able to pay its claims. Second, reinsurance facilitates placing large or unusual expos-
ures with one company, thus reducing the time spent seeking insurance and eliminating the need for
numerous policies to cover one exposure. This reduces transaction costs for both buyer and seller.
Third, reinsurance helps small insurance companies stay in business, thus increasing competition in
the industry. Without reinsurance, small companies would find it much more difficult to compete with
larger ones.
Individual policyholders, however, rarely know about any reinsurance that may apply to their cov-
erage. Even for those who are aware of the reinsurance, whether it is on a business or an individual
contract, most insurance policies prohibit direct access from the original insured to the reinsurer. The
prohibition exists because the reinsurance agreement is a separate contract from the primary (original)
insurance contract, and thus the original insured is not a party to the reinsurance. Because reinsurance
is part of the global insurance industry, globalization is also at center stage.
4.4 Management
As in other organizations, an insurer needs competent managers to plan, organize, direct, control, and
lead. The insurance management team functions best when it knows the nature of insurance and the
environment in which insurers conduct business. Although some top management people are hired
without backgrounds in the insurance business, the typical top management team for an insurer con-
sists of people who learned about the business by working in one or more functional areas of insurance.
If you choose an insurance career, you will probably begin in one of the functional areas discussed
above.
CHAPTER 6 INSURANCE OPERATIONS 145
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. Distinguish among the different types of reinsurance and give an example of each.
2. What are the advantages of reinsuring?
3. Explain the differences between company adjusters and independent adjusters. Given the choice, who
would you prefer to deal with in managing your claim? Why?
The actuarial analysis has to project how losses will be developed into the future based on their past de-
velopment. The loss reserve is the estimate of all the payments that will be made in the future and is
still unknown. In other words, the role of the actuary is to estimate all the figures that will fill the blank
lower right part of the table. The actuary has to “square the triangle.” The table ends at development
year 6, but the payments may continue beyond that point. Therefore, the actuary should also forecast
beyond the known horizon (beyond development year 6 in our table), so the role is to “rectanglize the
triangle.”
146 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
The actuary may use a great variety of triangles in preparing the forecast: the data could be ar-
ranged by months, quarters, or years. The data could be in current figure or in cumulative figures. The
data could represent numbers: the number of reported claims, the number of settled claims, the num-
ber of still pending claims, the number of closed claims, and so forth The figures could represent claim
payments such as current payments, payments for claims that were closed, incurred claim figures (i.e.,
the actual payments plus the case estimate), indexed figures, average claim figures, and so forth.
All actuarial techniques seek to identify a hidden pattern in the triangle, and to use it to perform
the forecast. Some common techniques are quite intuitive and are concerned with identifying relation-
ships between the payments made across consecutive developing years. Let us demonstrate it on Table
6.11 by trying to estimate the expected payments for accident year 2008 during 2009 (the cell with the
question mark). We can try doing so by finding a ratio of the payments in development year 1 to the
payments in development year 0. We have information for accident years 2002 through 2007. The sum
of payments made for these years during development year 1 is $300,500 and the sum of payments
made during development year 0 is $80,500. The ratio between these sums is 3.73. We multiply this ra-
tio by the $17,000 figure for year 2008, which gives an estimate of $63,410 in payments that will be
made for accident year 2008 during development year 1 (i.e., during 2009). Note that there are other
ways to calculate the ratios: instead of using the ratio between sums, we could have calculated for each
accident year the ratio between development year 1 and development year 0, then calculated the aver-
age ratio for all years. This would give a different multiplying factor, resulting in a different forecast.
In a similar way, we can calculate factors for moving from any other development period to the
next one (a set of factors to be used for moving from each column to the following one). Using these
factors, we can fill all other blank cells in Table 6.11. Note that the figure of $63,410 that we inserted as
the estimate for accident year 2008 during development year 1 is included in estimating the next figure
in the table. In other words, we created a recursive model, where the outcome of one step is used in es-
timating the outcome of the next step. We have created a sort of “chain ladder,” as these forecasting
methods are often referred to.
In the above example, we used ratios to move from one cell to the next one. But this forecasting
method is only one of many we could have utilized. For example, we could easily create an additive
model rather than a multiplicative model (based on ratios). We can calculate the average difference
between columns and use it to climb from one cell to the missing cell on its right. For example, the av-
erage difference between the payments for development year 1 and development year 0 is $36,667
(calculated only for the figures for which we have data on both development years 0 and 1, or 2002
through 2007). Therefore, our alternative estimate for the missing figure in Table 6.11, the payments
that are expected for accident year 2008 during 2009, is $53,667 ($17,000 plus $36,667). Quite a differ-
ent estimate than the one we obtained earlier!
We can create more complicated models, and the traditional actuarial literature is full of them.
The common feature of the above examples is that they are estimating the set of development period
factors. However, there could also be a set of “accident period factors” to account for the possibility
that the portfolio does not always stay constant between years. In one year, there could have been many
policies or accidents, whereas in the other year, there could have been fewer. So, there could be another
set of factors to be used when moving between rows (accident periods) in the triangle. Additionally,
there could also be a set of calendar year factors to describe the changes made while moving from one
diagonal to the other. Such effects may result from a multitude of reasons—for example, a legal judg-
ment forcing a policy change or inflation that increases average payments. A forecasting model often
incorporates a combination of such factors. In our simple example with a triangle having seven rows,
we may calculate six factors in each direction: six for the development periods (column effects), six for
the accident periods (row effects), and six for the diagonals (calendar or payment year effects). The
analysis of such a simple triangle may include eighteen factors (or parameters). A larger triangle (which
is the common case in practice) where many periods (months, quarters, and years) are used involves
the estimation of too many parameters, but simpler models with a much smaller number of factors can
be used (see below).
Although the above methods are very appealing intuitively and are still commonly used for loss re-
serving, they all suffer from major drawbacks and are not ideal for use. Let us summarize some of the
major deficiencies:
< The use of factors in all three directions (accident year, development year, and payment year)
may lead to contradictions. We have the freedom to determine any two directions, but the third
is determined automatically by the first two.
< There is often a need to forecast “beyond the horizon”—that is, to estimate what will be paid in
the development years beyond year six in our example. The various chain ladder models cannot
do this.
< We can always find a mathematical formula that will describe all the data points, but it will lack
good predictive power. At the next period, we get new data and a larger triangle. The additional
new pieces of information will often cause us to use a completely different set of
CHAPTER 6 INSURANCE OPERATIONS 147
factors—including those relating to previous periods. The need to change all the factors is
problematic, as it indicates instability of the model and lack of predictive power. This happens
due to overparameterization (a very crucial point that deserves a more detailed explanation, as
provided below).
< There are no statistical tests for the validity of the factors. Thus, it is impossible to understand
which parameters (factors) are statistically significant. To illustrate, it is clear that a factor
(parameter) based on a ratio between only two data points (e.g., a development factor for the
sixth year, which will be based on the two figures in the extreme right corner of the Table 6.11
triangle) is naturally less reliable, although it may drastically affect the entire forecast.
< The use of simple ratios to create the factors may be unjustified because the relationships between
two cells could be more complicated. For example, it could be that a neighboring cell is obtained
by examining the first cell, adding a constant, and then multiplying by a ratio. Studies have
shown that most loss reserves calculated with chain ladder models are suffering from this
problem.
< Chain ladder methods create a deterministic figure for the loss reserves. We have no idea as to
how reliable it is. It is clear that there is zero probability that the forecast will exactly foretell the
exact future figure. But management would appreciate having an idea about the range of possible
deviations between the actual figures and the forecast.
< The most common techniques are based on triangles with cumulative figures. The advantage of
cumulative figures is that they suppress the variability of the claims pattern and create an illusion
of stability. However, by taking cumulative rather than noncumulative figures, we often lose
much information, and we may miss important turning points. It is similar to what a gold miner
may do by throwing away, rather than keeping, the little gold nuggets that may be found in huge
piles of worthless rocks.
< Many actuaries are still using triangles of incurred claim figures. The incurred figures are the sum
of the actually paid numbers plus the estimates of future payments supplied by claims
department personnel. The resulting actuarial factors from such triangles are strongly influenced
by the changes made by the claims department from one period to the other. Such changes
should not be included in forecasting future trends.
There are modern actuarial techniques based on sophisticated statistical tools that could be used for
giving better forecasts while using the same loss triangles.[24] Let us see how this works without enga-
ging in a complicated statistical discussion. The purpose of the discussion is to increase the under-
standing of the principles, but we do not expect the typical student to be able to immediately perform
the analysis. We shall largely leave the analysis to actuaries that are better equipped with the needed
mathematical and statistical tools.
A good model is evaluated by its simplicity and generality. Having a complex model with many
parameters makes it complicated and less general. The chain ladder models that were discussed above
suffer from this overparameterization problem, and the alternative models that are explained below
overcome this difficulty.
Let us start by simply displaying the data of Table 6.11 in a graphical form in Figure 6.3. The green
dots describe the original data points (the paid claims on the vertical axis and the development years on
the horizontal axis). To show the general pattern, we added a line that represents the averages for each
development year. We see that claim payments in this line of business tend to increase, reach a peak
after a few years, then decline slowly over time and have a narrow “tail” (that is, small amounts are to
be paid in the far future).
148 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
We can immediately see that the entire claims triangle can be analyzed in a completely different way:
by fitting a curve through the points. One of these tools to enable this could be regression analysis.
Such a tool can give us a better understanding of the hidden pattern than does the chain ladder meth-
od. We see that the particular curve in our case is nonlinear, meaning that we need more than two
parameters to describe it mathematically. Four parameters will probably suffice to give a mathematical
function that will describe the pattern of Figure 6.3. The use of such methods can reach a level of soph-
istication that goes beyond the scope of this book. It is sufficient to say that we can get an excellent
mathematical description of the pattern with the use of only four to six parameters (factors). This can
be measured by a variety of statistical indicators. The coefficient of correlation for such a mathematical
formula is above 95 percent, and the parameters are statistically significant.
Such an approach is simpler and more general than any chain ladder model. It can be used to fore-
cast beyond the horizon, it can be statistically tested and validated, and it can give a good idea about the
level of error that may be expected. When a model is based on a few parameters only, it becomes more
“tolerant” to deviations: it is clear that the next period payment will differ from the forecast, but it will
not force us to change the model. From the actuary’s point of view, claim payments are stochastic vari-
ables and should never be regarded as a deterministic process, so why use a deterministic chain ladder
analysis?
It is highly recommended, and actually essential, to base the analysis on a noncumulative claims
triangle. The statistical analysis does not offer good tools for cumulative figures; we do not know their
underlying statistical processes, and therefore, we cannot offer good statistical significance tests. The
statistical analysis that is based on the current, noncumulative claim figures is very sensitive and can
easily detect turning points and changing patterns.
One last point should be mentioned. The key to regression analysis is the analysis of the residuals,
that is, the differences between the observed claims and the figures that are estimated by the model.
The residuals must be spread randomly around the forecasted, modeled, figures. If they are not ran-
domly spread, the model can be improved. In other words, the residuals are the compass that guides
the actuary in finding the best model. Traditional actuarial analyses based on chain ladder models re-
gard variability as a corrupt element and strive to get rid of the deviations to arrive at a deterministic
forecast. By doing so, actuaries throw away the only real information in the data and base the analysis
on the noninformative part alone! Sometimes the fluctuations are very large, and the insurance com-
pany is working in a very uncertain, almost chaotic claims environment. If the actuary finds that this is
the case, it will be important information for the managers and should not be hidden or replaced by a
deterministic, but meaningless, forecast.
11. Claire Wilkinson, “Catastrophe Modeling: A Vital Tool in the Risk Management Box,”
ENDNOTES Insurance Information Institute, February 2008, Accessed March 6, 2009,
http://www.iii.org/media/research/catmodeling/.
12. American Insurance Association, Testimony for the National Association of Insurance
Commissioners (NAIC) 9/28/2007 Public Hearing on Catastrophe Modeling.
1. Etti G. Baranoff, Dalit Baranoff, and Tom Sager, “Nonuniform Regulatory Treatment of
Broker Distribution Systems: An Impact Analysis for Life Insurers,” Journal of Insurance 13. Claire Wilkinson, “Catastrophe Modeling: A Vital Tool in the Risk Management Box,”
Regulations, Regulations 19, no. 1 (Fall 2000): 94. Insurance Information Institute, February 2008, Accessed March 6, 2009,
http://www.iii.org/media/research/catmodeling/.
2. “2006: The Year When Changes Take Hold,” Insurance Journal, January 2, 2006, ac-
cessed March 6, 2009, http://www.insurancejournal.com/magazines/west/2006/01/ 14. Insurance Information Institute. The Insurance Fact Book, 2009, p 31, 36.
02/features/64730.htm; Steve Tuckey, “NAIC Broker Disclosure Amendment Changes
Unlikely,” National Underwriter Online News Service, April 15, 2005, accessed March 6, 15. Government-sponsored enterprise.
2009, http://www.nationalunderwriter.com/pandc/hotnews/viewPC.asp?article
=4_15_05_15_17035.xml; “NAIC Adopts Model Legislation Calling For Broker Disclos- 16. Short-term agreements to sell and repurchase government securities by a specified
ures Defers One Section for Further Consideration” at http://www.naic.org/ date at a set price.
spotlight.htm; Mark E. Ruquet, “MMC Says Contingent Fees No Longer A Plus” Na- 17. Government-sponsored enterprise.
tional Underwriter Online News Service, February 15, 2006.
18. “Getting worried downtown.” The Economist November 15, 2007.
3. Sally Roberts, “Big I Changes Name to Reflect Membership Changes,” Business Insur-
ance, May 6, 2002. 19. “U.S Foreclosure Activity Increases 75 Percent in 2007,” RealtyTrac, January 29, 2008,
Accessed March 6, 2009, http://www.realtytrac.com/ContentManagement/
4. The term direct writer is frequently used to refer to all property insurers that do not pressrelease.aspx?ChannelID=9&ItemID=3988&accnt=64847.
use the Independent Agency System of distribution, but some observers think there
are differences among such companies. 20. “Let the Blame Begin; Everyone Played Some Role—The Street, Lenders, Ratings
Agencies, Hedge Funds, Even Homeowners. Where Does Responsibility Lie? (The
5. Paul P. Aniskovich, “Letters With Apps Can Make The Difference,” National Under- Subprime Mess),” Business Week Online, July 30, 2007.
writer, Life & Health/Financial Services Edition, November 12, 2001.
21. “The Financial Meltdown of AIG and Insurers Explained.” Smallcap Network, October
6. Catherine Arnold, “Britain Backs Insurers Use of Genetic Testing,” National Underwriter, 27, 2008, http://www.smallcapnetwork.com/scb/
Life & Health/Financial Services Edition, November 27, 2000. the-financial-meltdown-of-aig-and-other-insurers-explained/2315/.
7. In this example, we do not introduce actuarial adjustments to the factors. Such ad- 22. Edmund L. Andrews, Michael J. de la Merced, and Mary Williams Walsh, “Fed’s $85 Bil-
justments are usually based on management, technology, marketing, and other lion Loan Rescues Insurer,” The New York Times, September 17, 2008, Accessed March
known functional changes within the company. The book of business is assumed to 6, 2009, http://www.nytimes.com/2008/09/17/business/17insure.html.
be stable without any extreme changes that may require adjustments.
23. Arthur D. Postal, “Fed Chief Blasts AIG for Exploiting Reg System,” National Under-
8. Claire Wilkinson, “Catastrophe Modeling: A Vital Tool in the Risk Management Box,” writer Online, Property/Casualty Edition, March 3, 2009, Accessed March 6, 2009.
Insurance Information Institute, February 2008, Accessed March 6, 2009, http://www.propertyandcasualtyinsurancenews.com/cms/nupc/Breaking+News/
http://www.iii.org/media/research/catmodeling/. 2009/03/03-AIG-HEARING-dp.
9. Michael Lewis, “In Nature’s Casino,” New York Times Magazine, August 26, 2007, Ac- 24. The interested reader should seek out publications by Professor B. Zehnwirth, a pion-
cessed March 6, 2009; http://www.nytimes.com/2007/08/26/magazine/ eer of the approach described, in actuarial literature. One of the authors (Y. Kahane)
26neworleans-t.html. has collaborated with him, and much actuarial work has been done with these tools.
The approach is now well accepted around the world. The graph was derived using
10. AIR Worldwide, Accessed March 6, 2009, http://www.air-worldwide.com/
resources developed by Insureware Pty. (www.insureware.com).
ContentPage.aspx?id=16202.
CHAP TER 7
Insurance Markets and
Regulation
The insurance industry, in fact, is one of the largest global financial industries, helping to propel the global
economy. “In 2007, world insurance premium volume, for [property/casualty and life/health] combined, totaled
$4.06 trillion, up 10.5 percent from $3.67 trillion in 2006,” according to international reinsurer Swiss Re. The United
States led the world in total insurance premiums, as shown in Table 7.1.
TABLE 7.1 Top Ten Countries by Life and Nonlife Direct Premiums Written, 2007 (Millions of U.S.$)*
Total Premiums
Rank Country Nonlife Life Amount Percentage Change Percentage of Total
Premiums[1] Premiums from Prior Year World Premiums
1 United $578,357 $651,311 $1,229,668 4.69% 30.28%
States[2]
2 United 349,740 113,946 463,686 28.16 11.42
Kingdom
3 Japan[3] 330,651 94,182 424,832 −3.31 10.46
4 France 186,993 81,907 268,900 7.47 6.62
5 Germany 102,419 120,407 222,825 10.09 5.49
6 Italy 88,215 54,112 142,328 1.27 3.50
7 South 81,298 35,692 116,990 16.28 2.88
Korea[4]
8 The 35,998 66,834 102,831 11.98 2.53
Netherlands
9 Canada[5] 45,593 54,805 100,398 14.74 2.47
10 PR China 58,677 33,810 92,487 30.75 2.28
* Before reinsurance transactions.
Source: Insurance Information Institute (III), accessed March 6, 2009, http://www.iii.org/media/facts/statsbyissue/international/.
The large size of the global insurance markets is demonstrated by the written premiums shown in Table 7.1. The
institutions making the market were described in Chapter 5. In this chapter we cover the following:
1. Links
2. Markets conditions: underwriting cycles, availability and affordability, insurance and reinsurance markets
3. Regulation of insurance
152 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
1. LINKS
As we have done in the prior chapters, we begin with connecting the importance of this chapter to the
underwriting cycles
complete picture of holistic risk management. We will become savvy consumers only when we under-
The movement of insurance stand the insurance marketplace and the conditions under which insurance institutions operate. When
prices through time. we make the selection of an insurer, we need to understand not only the organizational structure of
insurance capacity that insurance firm, but we also need to be able to benefit from the regulatory safety net available to
The quantity of coverage that
protect us. Also important is our clear understanding of insurance market conditions affecting the
is available in terms of limits products and their pricing. Major rate increases for coverage do not happen in a vacuum. As you saw
of coverage. in Chapter 3, past losses are the most important factor in setting rates. Market conditions, availability,
and affordability of products are very important factors in the risk management decision, as you saw in
Chapter 4. In Chapter 2, you learned that an insurable risk must have the characteristic of being afford-
able. Because of underwriting cycles—the movement of insurance prices through time (explained
next in this chapter)—insurance rates are considered dynamic. In a hard market, when rates are high
and insurance capacity, the quantity of coverage that is available in terms of limits of coverage, is
low, we may choose to self-insure. Insurance capacity relates to the level of insurers’ capital (net
worth). If capital levels are low, insurers cannot provide a lot of coverage. In a soft market, when insur-
ance capacity is high, we may select to insure for the same level of severity and frequency of losses. So
our decisions are truly related to external market conditions, as indicated in Chapter 4.
The regulatory oversight of insurers is another important issue in our strategy. If we care to have a
safety net of guarantee funds, which act as deposit insurance in case of insolvency of an insurer, we will
work with a regulated insurer. In case of insolvency, a portion of the claims will be paid by the guaran-
tee funds. We also need to understand the benefits of selecting a regulated entity as opposed to nonreg-
ulated one for other consumer protection actions such as the resolution of complaints. If we are un-
happy with our insurer’s claims settlement process and if the insurer is under the state’s regulatory jur-
isdiction, the regulator in our state may help us resolve disputes.
CHAPTER 7 INSURANCE MARKETS AND REGULATION 153
FIGURE 7.1 Links between the Holistic Risk Picture and the Big Picture of the Insurance Industry
Markets by Regulatory Status
As you can see, understanding insurance institutions, markets, and insurance regulation are critical to
our ability to complete the picture of holistic risk management. Figure 7.1 provides the line of connec-
tion between our holistic risk picture (or a business holistic risk) and the big picture of the insurance
industry and markets. Figure 7.1 separates the industry’s institutions into those that are government-
regulated and those that are non- or semiregulated. Regardless of regulation, insurers are subject to
market conditions and are structured along the same lines as any corporation. However, some insur-
ance structures, such as governmental risk pools or Lloyd’s of London, do have a specialized organiza-
tional structure.
154 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
FIGURE 7.2 Underwriting Cycles of the U.S. Property/Casualty Insurance Industry, 1970–2008*
* Peaks are hard markets; valleys are soft markets. † A.M. Best year-end estimate of 103.2; actual nine-month result
was 105.6.
As you can see in Figure 7.2, the ups and downs are clearly visible across the whole industry for all lines
cash flow underwriting
of business. When the combined ratio is low, the industry lowers its underwriting standards in order to
obtain more cash that can be invested—a strategy known as cash flow underwriting. The industry is Strategy pursued when the
combined ratio is low, in
regarded as competing itself to the ground, and underwriting standards are loose. The last soft market which the industry lowers its
lasted about fifteen years, ending in the late 1990s. From 1986 to 1999, the combined ratio stayed in the underwriting standards in
range of 101.6 in 1997 to 109.6 in 1990, with only one jump in 1992 to a combined ratio of 115.7. Be- order to obtain more cash
cause the break-even point of the industry combined ratio is 107, the industry was doing rather well that can be invested.
during that long period. It caused new decision makers (those without experience in underwriting
cycles) to be less careful. In addition, computerized pricing models gave a false sense of security in
making risk-selection and pricing decisions. Actual losses ended up causing rate increases, and the soft
market changed into a true hard market.
During the 1990s, the soft market conditions lasted longer than usual because the industry had
large capacity. There were speculations that the introduction of capital markets as an alternative to re-
insurance (see Chapter 4) kept rates down. In April 2005, the Insurance Information Institute reported
that the 2004 statutory rate of return on average surplus was 10.5 percent, up from 9.5 percent for cal-
endar year 2003, 1.1 percent for 2002, and −2.3 percent for 2001 (one of the worst years ever). The 2004
recovery is the most remarkable underwriting recovery in modern history, with insurers slicing 17.6
points off the combined ratio in just three years. Additional improvement is shown in 2006, a year after
Hurricane Katrina.
For each line of insurance, there is a level of combined ratio that determines whether the line is break-even combined ratio
profitable or not. The level of combined ratio that is required for each line of business to avoid losing level
money is called the break-even combined ratio level. Depending on the investment income contri- The level of combined ratio
bution of each line of insurance, the longer tail lines (such as general liability and medical malpractice) that is required for each line
have a much larger break-even level. Fire and allied lines as well as homeowner’s have the lowest break- of business to not lose
even combined ratio levels because the level of investment income is expected to be lower. Thus, if the money.
actual combined ratio for homeowner’s is 106, the industry is experiencing negative results. The break-
even for all lines of the industry is 107. If the industry’s combined ratio is 103, the industry is reaping a
profit. The largest break-even combined ratio is for the medical malpractice line, which is at 115; for
general and product liability lines, it is 113; and for worker’s compensation, it is 112. The lowest break-
even combined ratio is 103 for homeowner’s and 105 for personal auto.
The soft market climate of 2005 helped the industry recover from the devastation of hurricanes
Katrina, Rita, and Wilma. Some even regard the impact of these major catastrophes as a small blip in
156 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
the underwriting results for the property/casualty industry, except for the reinsurers’ combined ratio.
Table 7.2 shows the adjusted amounts of loss for these catastrophes. Despite the high magnitude of
these losses, market analysts projected a stable outlook for the property/casualty industry in 2006. In
fact, the actual combined ratio for that year was the lowest observed in decades, at 92.6, as indicated in
Figure 7.2.
TABLE 7.2 The Ten Most Costly Catastrophes in the United States*
Insured Loss (Millions of $)
Rank Date Peril Dollars when In 2008
Occurred Dollars[6]
1 Aug. 2005 Hurricane Katrina $41,100 $45,309
2 Aug. 1992 Hurricane Andrew 15,500 23,786
3 Sept. World Trade Center and Pentagon terrorist 18,779 22,830
2001 attacks
4 Jan. 1994 Northridge, CA, earthquake 12,500 18,160
5 Oct. 2005 Hurricane Wilma 10,300 11,355
6 Sept. Hurricane Ike 10,655[7] 10,655[8]
2008
7 Aug. 2004 Hurricane Charley 7,475 8,520
8 Sept. Hurricane Ivan 7,110 8,104
2004
9 Sept. Hurricane Hugo 4,195 7,284
1989
10 Sept. Hurricane Rita 5,627 6,203
2005
* Property coverage only. Does not include flood damage covered by the federally administered National
Flood Insurance Program.
Source: Insurance Information Institute (III). Accessed March 6, 2009. http://www.iii.org/media/hottopics/insurance/catastrophes/.
In addition to the regular underwriting cycles, external market conditions affect the industry to a great
extent. The 2008–2009 financial crisis impact on the property/casualty insurance industry is discussed
in the box below.
The property/casualty segment has been hurt by problems in the stock market, real estate, and auto industry
primarily. Underwriting alone rarely produces an industry profit; investments account for most of the industry’s
positive returns. With stocks hit hard by the recession, even the conservative investments typically made by
property/casualty insurers have posted poor returns. New home starts dropped 34 percent from 2005–2007, a
net decline of 1.4 million units. To insurers, this represents revenues foregone in the form of premiums that
could be collected on new business, potentially amounting to $1.2 billion. Auto and light trucks are projected
to have the worst unit sales in 2009 since the late 1960s with a reduction of 6 million units. The effect of poor
performance in underlying businesses is less pronounced on auto insurers than on home insurers but still sub-
stantial. Workers’ compensation insurers (to be discussed in Chapter 14) have seen their exposure base re-
duced by the high unemployment rate.
Nonetheless, the industry attributes recent financial results more to basic market conditions than the econom-
ic recession. The combination of a soft market (recall the discussion in Chapter 7) and high catastrophe experi-
ence meant a reduction in profits and slow growth. Property/casualty industry profits were 5.4 billion in 2008,
down considerably from 61.9 billion in 2007. The 2007 performance, however, was down slightly from an all-
time record industry profit in 2006. The 2008 drop is less noteworthy in the wider context of historical annual
profits, which are highly correlated with the fluctuating market cycles. Despite the dire economic condition,
two important points are made clear: the insurance industry, on the whole, is operating normally and contin-
ues to perform the basic function of risk transfer. Insurers are able to pay claims, secure new and renewal busi-
ness, and expand product offerings. The problems at American International Group (AIG) (discussed in Chapter
6) have been the exception to the rule. Low borrowing, conservative investments, and extensive regulatory
oversight have also aided insurance companies in avoiding the large-scale problems of the crisis. All of these
factors were inverted in the case of the imperiled banks and other financial institutions. Consider the follow-
ing: between January 2008 and the time of this writing, forty-one bank failures were observed. This is in com-
parison to zero property/casualty insurer failures.
The $787 billion stimulus package authorized by the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009 is fur-
ther expected to help matters. The program aims to save or create 3.5 million jobs. Of the stimulus, 24.1 per-
cent of funding is intended for spending on infrastructure, 37.9 percent on direct aid, and 38 percent on tax
cuts. Insurers will see no direct injection of capital and virtually no indirect benefits from the latter two com-
ponents of the stimulus package. As it relates to infrastructure spending, however, workers’ compensation in-
surers will be helped by the boost in employment. Considerable outlays on construction projects will also in-
crease demand for commercial property insurance. Renewed investor confidence in the stock market would
also enhance investment returns considerably. Just as insurers are indirectly harmed by the crisis, so too will
they indirectly benefit from recovery efforts.
Of course, the success of the stimulus plan remains unproven, so the insurance industry must prepare for the
uncertain future. In the current economic climate, investments cannot be relied upon as the major driver of in-
dustry profitability that they once were. This calls for even greater discipline in underwriting in order for com-
panies to remain solvent. With the federal government taking an unusually active role in correcting deficien-
cies in the market, a new wave of regulation is inevitable. New compliance initiatives will be introduced, and
existing protections may be stripped away. Still, the insurance industry may be uniquely equipped to cope
with these challenges, as exemplified by the fundamental nature of their business: risk management. By practi-
cing what they preach, insurers can be rewarded with insulation from the most detrimental effects of the re-
cession and emerge as role models for their fellow financial institutions.
Sources: Dr. Robert P. Hartwig, “Financial Crisis, Economic Stimulus & the Future of the P/C Insurance Industry: Trends, Challenges & Opportunities,”
March 5, 2009, accessed March 9, 2009, http://www.iii.org/media/presentations/sanantonio/; United States Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor
Statistics, “The Unemployment Situation: February 2009,” USDL 09-0224, March 6, 2009, accessed March 9, 2009, http://www.bls.gov/news.release/
archives/empsit_03062009.pdf; “U.S. FORECLOSURE ACTIVITY INCREASES 75 PERCENT IN 2007,” RealtyTrac, January 9, 2008, accessed March 9, 2009,
http://www.realtytrac.com/ContentManagement/pressrelease.aspx?ChannelID=9&ItemID= 3988&accnt=64847; Mark Huffman, “2008 Foreclosure
Activity Jumps 81 Percent,” ConsumerAffairs.com, January 15, 2009, accessed March 9, 2009, http://www.consumeraffairs.com/news04/2009/01/
foreclosure_jumps.html.
FIGURE 7.3 National Health Expenditures Share of Gross Domestic Product, 1993–2014
(1) Marks the beginning of the shift to managed care. (2) Projected.
Source: Insurance Information Institute per the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services, Office of the Actuary; U.S. Department of Commerce,
Bureau of Economic Analysis and Bureau of the Census.
TABLE 7.3 Top Ten Global Reinsurance Companies by Gross Premiums Written, 2007
Company Country Net Reinsurance Premiums Written (Millions of $)
Munich Re Co. Germany $30,292.9
Swiss Re Co. Switzerland 27,706.6
Berkshire Hathaway Re United States 17,398.0
Hannover Rueckversicherung AG Germany 10,630.0
Lloyd’s United Kingdom 8,362.9
SCOR SE France 7,871.7
Reinsurance Group of America, Inc. United States 4,906.5
Transatlantic Holdings, Inc. United States 3,952.9
Everest Reinsurance Co. Bermuda 3,919.4
PartnerRe Ltd. Bermuda 3,757.1
Source: Insurance Information Institute (III). The Insurance Fact Book 2009, p 42.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. Among the leading insurance markets in the world, which countries are the largest in life premiums and
which are the largest in property/casualty premiums?
2. Explain the underwriting cycle. What causes it? When would there be a hard market? When would there
be a soft market?
3. Insurance brokers were very busy in the fall of 2008, since the troubles of AIG became public knowledge.
Also there were speculations that the property/casualty markets were becoming hard as a consequence
of the credit crisis and the problems with mortgage-backed securities. What are hard markets? Why would
there be such speculations? Explain in terms of the underwriting cycles and the breakeven combined ratio
for each line of insurance.
4. Why did the world reinsurance market become hard in 2001?
160 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
3. INSURANCE REGULATION
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
Insurance delivers only future payment in case of a loss. Therefore, it has long been actively regulated.
The nature of the product requires strong regulation to ensure the solvency of insurers when claims are
filed. This is the big picture of the regulation of insurance in a nutshell. However, within this important
overall objective are many areas and issues that are regulated as interim steps to achieve the main ob-
jective of the availability of funds to pay claims. Most of the regulation has been at the state level for
many years. The possibility of federal involvement has also been raised, especially since the passage of
the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Financial Services Modernization Act (GLBA) in 1999 and subsequent activ-
ities like the optional federal charter of insurers (discussed in the box "The State of State Insurance
Regulation—A Continued Debate"). In August 2004, Representative Michael Oxley, chairperson of the
House Financial Services Committee, and Representative Richard Baker, chairperson of the Subcom-
mittee on Capital Markets, Insurance, and Government Sponsored Enterprises, released a draft of the
State Modernization and Regulatory Transparency (SMART) Act. This proposal is also regarded as the
insurance regulatory reform road map draft, and it has added fuel to the debate of state versus federal
insurance regulation. The debate has taken many shapes, including a dual (federal/state) chartering
system, similar to the banking industry’s dual regulatory system that would allow companies to choose
between the state system and a national regulatory structure.
Under the current state insurance regulation scheme, state legislatures pass insurance laws that
form the basis for insurance regulation. Common forms of insurance regulatory laws are listed in Table
7.4. To ensure the smooth operation of insurance markets and the solvency of insurers, insurance laws
are concerned not only with the operations and investments of insurers but also with licensing require-
ments for insurers, agents, brokers, and claims adjusters and with rates and policy forms and consumer
protection. The laws provide standards of financial solvency, including methods of establishing re-
serves and the types of investments permitted. Provisions are made in the states’ laws for the liquida-
tion or rehabilitation of any insurance company in severe financial difficulty. Because solvency is con-
sidered to be affected by product pricing (setting rates), rate regulation is an important part of insur-
ance regulation. Trade practices, including marketing and claims adjustment, are also part of the law.
Legislation also creates methods to make certain types of insurance readily available at affordable (that
is, subsidized) prices. In addition, the taxation of insurers at the state level is spelled out in the insur-
ance code for each state.
TABLE 7.4 Common Types of Insurance Regulatory Laws
Every state has an insurance department to administer insurance laws; it is known as the commis-
commissioner (or
sioner (or superintendent) of insurance. In some states, the commissioner of insurance also acts as superintendent) of
another official of the state government, such as state treasurer, state auditor, or director of banking. In insurance
most states, however, acting as commissioner of insurance is the person’s sole responsibility. In some State insurance department
states, the commissioner is appointed; in others, he or she is elected. Most insurance departments have that administers insurance
relatively few staff employees, but several are large, such as those in Texas, California, Illinois, Florida, laws.
and New York. The small departments are generally not equipped to provide effective regulation of
such a powerful industry.
As indicated above, the most important part of regulation is to ensure solvency of insurers. Assist- National Association of
ing in this objective are the regulatory efforts in the area of consumer protection in terms of rates and Insurance Commissioners
policy forms. Of course, regulators protect insureds from fraud, unscrupulous agents, and white-collar (NAIC)
crime. Regulators also make efforts to make coverage available at affordable prices while safeguarding A group that deals with the
the solvency of insurers. Regulation is a balancing act and it is not an easy one. Because insurance is creation of model laws for
regulated by the states, lack of uniformity in the laws and regulation is of great concern. Therefore, the adoption by the states to
National Association of Insurance Commissioners (NAIC) deals with the creation of model encourage uniformity.
laws for adoption by the states to encourage uniformity. Despite the major effort to create uniformity,
interest groups in each state are able to modify the NAIC model laws, so those that are finally adopted
may not be uniform across the states. The resulting maze of regulations is considered a barrier to the
entry of new insurers. This is an introductory text, so insurance regulation will be discussed only briefly
here. For the interested student, the NAIC Web site (http://www.naic.org) is a great place to explore
the current status of insurance regulation. Each state’s insurance department has its own Web site as
well.
The state insurance commissioner is empowered to do the following:
< Grant, deny, or suspend licenses of both insurers and insurance agents
< Require an annual report from insurers (financial statements)
< Examine insurers’ business operations
< Act as a liquidator or rehabilitator of insolvent insurers
< Investigate complaints
< Originate investigations
< Decide whether to grant all, part, or none of an insurer’s request for higher rates
< Propose new legislation to the legislature
< Approve or reject an insurer’s proposed new or amended insurance contract
< Promulgate regulations that interpret insurance laws
in the 1990s from small insurance companies in Arkansas, Mississippi, Missouri, Oklahoma, and Ten-
nessee. Three insurance executives in Arkansas were charged in connection with the case.[15]
Investment Requirements
The solvency of an insurer depends partly on the amount and quality of its assets, and how the assets’
liquidity matches the needs of liquidity to pay losses. Because poor investment policy caused the failure
of many companies in the past, investments are carefully regulated. The states’ insurance codes spell
out in considerable detail which investments are permitted and which are prohibited. Life insurers
have more stringent investment regulations than property/casualty insurers because some of the con-
tracts made by life insurers cover a longer period of time, even a lifetime or more.
CHAPTER 7 INSURANCE MARKETS AND REGULATION 163
Risk-Based Capital
For solvency regulation, the states’ insurance departments and the NAIC are looking into the invest-
risk-based capital
ment and reserving of insurers. During the 1990s, requirements for risk-based capital were implemen-
ted by the states. Remember that capital reflects the excess value a firm holds in assets over liabilities. It Assets, such as equities held
as investments, with values
represents a financial cushion against hard times. Risk-based capital describes assets, such as equities
that may vary widely over
held as investments, with values that may vary widely over time; that is, they involve more risk than do time.
certain other assets. To account for variations in risks among different assets, commissioners of insur-
ance, through their state legislators, have begun requiring firms to hold capital sufficient to produce a
level that is acceptable relative to the risk profile of the asset mix of the insurer.[19] The requirements
are a very important part of solvency regulation. The NAIC and many states also established an early
warning system to detect potential insolvencies. Detection of potential insolvencies is a fruitful area of
research. The interested student is invited to read the Journal of Insurance Regulation and The Journal
of Risk and Insurance for articles in this area.[20]
Reserve Requirements
The investment requirements discussed above concern the nature and quality of insurer assets. The
value of assets an insurer must hold is influenced by capital and surplus requirements and the regula-
tion of reserves. Reserves are insurer liabilities that represent future financial obligations to policyhold-
ers. Reserves constitute the bulk of insurance company liabilities. See more about how to calculate re-
serves in Chapter 6.
One type of property/casualty rate regulation is the prior approval approach. In states that use the
prior approval
prior approval method, an insurer or its rating bureau (such as the Insurance Services Office [ISO]
Method of regulation in discussed earlier) must file its new rates and have them approved by the commissioner before using
which an insurer or its rating
bureau must file its new rates
them. Another approach called file-and-use allows an insurer to begin using a new rate as soon as it is
and have them approved by filed with the commissioner. The commissioner can disapprove the new rate if it is determined to be
the commissioner before undesirable within a specified period, generally thirty days. A few states have adopted open competi-
using them. tion rating laws. Open competition requires no rate filings by an insurer because the underlying as-
file-and-use
sumption is that market competition is a sufficient regulator of rates. Although results are mixed, stud-
ies of the effects of different types of rate regulation generally find no significant differences in the
Method of regulation that
prices paid by consumers under different systems for the same service.
allows an insurer to begin
using a new rate as soon as it
is filed with the
commissioner. 3.6 Control of Agent’s Activities
open competition Insurance laws also prohibit certain activities on the part of agents and brokers, such as twisting, rebat-
Method of regulation that ing, unfair practices, and misappropriation of funds belonging to insurers or insureds. Twisting (also
requires no rate filings by an called churning) is inducing a policyholder to cancel one contract and buy another by misrepresenting
insurer, as the underlying the facts or providing incomplete policy comparisons. An unfair or misleading comparison of two con-
assumption is that market
tracts can be a disservice if it causes the insured to drop a policy he or she had for some time in order to
competition is a sufficient
regulator of rates. buy another that is no better, or perhaps not as good. On the other hand, sometimes changing policies
is in the best interest of the policyholder, and justified replacements are legal. Twisting regulations,
therefore, may include the requirement that the resulting policy change be beneficial to the
twisting
policyholder.
Inducing a policyholder to
cancel one contract and buy
Rebating is providing (substantial) value as an inducement to purchase insurance; for example,
another by misrepresenting the agent or broker shares his or her commission with the insured. Rebating is prohibited because:
the facts or providing < It is considered unfair competition among agents.
incomplete policy
comparisons. < Some knowledgeable consumers would buy a new policy each year when first-year commissions
are larger than renewal commissions (higher lapse rates increase long-run cost).
rebating < More sophisticated consumers could negotiate larger rebates than the less informed, and this
Providing substantial value as would be unfair.[22]
an inducement to purchase < Agents may be encouraged to engage in unethical behavior by selling new policies over renewal
insurance.
policies because of the larger first-year commissions.
Some insurers adjust to rebating laws by offering their agents and brokers two or more series of con-
tracts with the same provisions but with rates that reflect different levels of commissions. A particular
insurer’s “personal series,” for example, may include a normal level of commissions. Its “executive
series,” however, may pay the agent or broker a lower commission and offer a lower rate to potential
insureds. In competitive situations, the agent or broker is likely to propose the “executive series” in or-
der to gain a price advantage. The Florida Supreme Court decided in 1986 that the antirebate law was
unconstitutional. This decision had the potential to increase pressure on other states to reconsider the
practice, but very little activity on the subject has occurred since then. California’s Proposition 103
(passed in 1988), however, includes a provision to abandon the state’s antirebate laws. In the settlement
to resolve their Proposition 103 rollback obligations with the California state insurance department, in-
surers paid rebates to their 1989 customers.[23]
At the end of 2004, the NAIC adopted a fee disclosure amendment to the producer licensing mod-
el act in order to enhance the transparency of producer-fee arrangements. These changes were in re-
sponse to the probe of broker activities by the New York State Attorney General’s Office (mentioned in
Chapter 6), which resulted in civil action against Marsh & McLennan. The firm was accused of rigging
bids and taking incentive payments to steer business to insurers who were part of the conspiracy. Since
the passage of the amendment, the top three insurance brokers have settled with their state regulators
and agreed to stop the practice of collecting contingency fees. Most insurance and business newspapers
reported extensively about the creation of an $850 million restitution fund for policyholders by Marsh
& McLennan as part of the settlement. Many brokers changed their business models as well.[24] For ex-
ample, Willis Group Holdings Ltd. abolished profit-based contingency fees and offered complete dis-
closure of all compensation earned from underwriters for all activities relating to placing the business.
It also introduced a client bill of rights laying out its responsibilities as a client advocate and established
internal controls.
CHAPTER 7 INSURANCE MARKETS AND REGULATION 165
Unfair Practices
Unfair practice is a catch-all term that can be applied to many undesirable activities of agents, claims unfair practice
adjusters, and insurers (including misleading advertisements). Unfair practices may lead to fines, re-
A catch-all term that can be
moval of licenses, and—in extreme cases—to punitive damage awards by the courts. Misappropri-
applied to many undesirable
ation of funds refers to situations in which the agent keeps funds (primarily premiums) belonging to activities of agents, claim
the company, the policyholder, or a beneficiary. For example, suppose an insured was killed by acci- adjusters, and insurers.
dent; his $1,000 life insurance policy had a double indemnity rider. In order to impress the beneficiary
with the value of this rider, the insurer mailed two checks in the amount of $1,000 each to the agent for misappropriation of funds
delivery. The agent gave one check to the beneficiary and then induced the beneficiary to endorse the Situations in which the agent
second check to the agent, claiming that its issuance was in error, so it had to be cashed and the money keeps funds belonging to the
company, the policyholder,
returned to the insurer. The insurance department recovered the $1,000, paid it to the beneficiary, and
or a beneficiary.
revoked the agent’s license.
After the enactment of the GLBA, the NAIC issued a statement of intent to ensure the preservation
of state regulation within the GLBA prerequisites. In this statement, the commissioners pointed out,
“Fueled by enhanced technology and globalization, the world financial markets are undergoing rapid
changes. In order to protect and serve more sophisticated but also more exposed insurance consumers
of the future, insurance regulators are committed to modernize insurance regulation to meet the realit-
ies of an increasingly dynamic, and internationally competitive financial services marketplace” (see
http://www.naic.org). Among the NAIC’s commitments to change are the following:
< Amending state laws to include antiaffiliation statutes, licensure laws, demutualization statutes
(discussed later in this chapter), and various essential consumer protections, including sales and
privacy provisions.
< Streamlining and standardizing the licensing procedure for producers. One of the provisions of
Gramm-Leach-Bliley requires U.S. jurisdictions to adopt uniform or reciprocal agent- and
broker-licensing laws by November 2002 (three years after the enactment of the law). If this
requirement is not met, a National Association of Registered Agents and Brokers will be
created.[26] By leveraging work already done on the Producer Database and the Producer
Information Network and by using the Insurance Regulatory Information Network (IRIN), the
NAIC has already succeeded in meeting the requirements by having enough state legislatures
pass bills permitting reciprocity among the states.
< Building on initiatives already underway concerning national companies, such as review of
financial reporting, financial analysis and examination, and refining the risk-based approach to
examining the insurance operations of financial holding companies.
< Implementing functional regulation and sharing regulatory information to encourage the
execution of information-sharing agreements between the individual states and each of the key
federal functional regulators.
As a result of GLBA, forty-one states enacted reciprocal producer licensing laws, eight states enacted
speed-to-market
uniform insurance product approval laws, and twenty-four states have enacted property casualty insur-
Expediting the introduction ance rate deregulation as reported by the National Conference of Insurance Legislators (NCOIL).[27] In
of new insurance products
into the marketplace.
addition, the NAIC started to work on the speed-to-market concept of expediting the introduction of
new insurance products into the marketplace (a process that had been too time-consuming). The idea
regulatory reengineering is to develop state-based uniform standards for policy form and rate filings without loss of flexibility.
A movement that promotes Other areas of improvements are regulatory reengineering, a movement that promotes legislative
legislative uniformity. uniformity, and market conduct reform, which creates a process to respond to changing market
market conduct reform conditions, especially relating to e-commerce.
The debate regarding federal versus state insurance regulation has been heightened as a result of
A movement that creates a
process to respond to
the 2008–2009 economic recession. As noted in the box “The State of Insurance Regulation—A
changing market conditions, Continued Debate,” the National Insurance Consumer Protection and Regulatory Modernization Act
especially relating to is the most current proposal as of March 2009. It is anticipated that the work on regulatory changes will
e-commerce. take years, but insurance companies are in national and global markets, and they are at a disadvantage
compared with federally regulated industries such as banking and securities. The need to obtain ap-
proval for products from fifty states costs the insurance industry too much time. By contrast, securities
firms bring new products to the market within ninety days, and banks do so almost immediately.
Two pieces of federal legislation address the issue. The Health Insurance Portability and Accountability Act
(HIPAA) of 1996 authorized the Department of Health and Human Services to set minimum standards for pro-
tection of health information and gave states the right to impose tougher standards. The Financial Services
Modernization Act of 1999, better known as the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act (GLBA), gave consumers more con-
trol over the distribution of their personal financial information.
Insurance is a state-regulated business, so insurance-specific regulations fall within the authority of state insur-
ance commissioners. Thus far, thirty-six states plus the District of Columbia are following a model developed
by the National Association of Insurance Commissioners (see the model law and updates on state activity at
http://www.naic.org/1privacy). An important component of the NAIC’s model is the opt-in provision for health
information, which regulators consider to be more sensitive than financial information. As opposed to GLBA’s
opt-out provision, which gives insurers the right to share your financial information with outsiders unless you
specifically tell them not to, NAIC’s opt-in provision means insurers can’t share your health history unless you
specifically permit them to do so.
But the system is far from airtight. Under GLBA provisions, insurers do not need your permission to share your
data with its affiliates—and in these days of mega conglomerations, an insurance company can have lots of
affiliates. Insurers are even permitted to disclose, without your permission, protected (nonidentifying) financial
information to third parties with whom they have a marketing agreement.
For their part, insurers fear that further restrictions on sharing information would affect their ability to provide
timely quotes and claims settlements. Another major concern is a broker’s ability to shop a policy around to
find the best rate and coverage for his or her client. And while consumers might complain about the paper-
work involved in opting-out, insurance companies have had to develop and implement privacy policies, train
all staff who handle personal information, and set up new departments to handle the opt-out wishes of tens
of millions of customers. It’s estimated that GBLA compliance could cost the insurance industry as much as $2
billion.
Any federal or state privacy legislation must protect consumers’ right to control what happens to their person-
al data, but it also must preserve insurers’ ability to operate their businesses. Where should the line be drawn?
Questions for Discussion
1. How concerned are you about privacy? Are you more protective about your health or your financial
information?
2. When companies have to spend money to comply with the law, it’s generally the consumer who
ends up paying. Would you accept slightly higher premiums to cover the costs of keeping your
personal information private?
3. Why would increased privacy provisions make it difficult for brokers to give their customers the best
service?
Sources: National Association of Insurance Commissioners, “NAIC Privacy of Consumer Financial and Health Information,” http://www.naic.org/
1privacy; American Civil Liberties Union, “Defending Financial Privacy,” http://www.aclu.org /Privacy/PrivacyMain.cfm; American Insurance
Association, “Industry Issues: Privacy,” http://www.aiadc.org/IndustryIssues/Privacy.asp; Steven Brostoff, “Stakes Are High in Battle over Health Data
Privacy,” National Underwriter Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edition, May 27, 2002; Mark E. Ruquet, “Privacy Is Still a Hot Topic for
Agents,” National Underwriter Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edition, May 27, 2002; Lori Chordas, “Secret Identity,” Best’s Review,
June 2002; Arthur D. Postal “Privacy Rules: A Success?” National Underwriter Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edition, March 10, 2005,
accessed March 6, 2009, http://www.propertyandcasualtyinsurancenews.com/cms/NUPC/Weekly%20Issues/Issues/2005/10/
p10bank_privacy?searchfor=Privacy%20Rules:%20A%20Success.
For life insurers in particular, many of the products sold are investment vehicles. That puts life insurers in direct
competition with banks and securities firms, which are federally chartered and can bring their products to
market more quickly—and often at a competitive price, too, because they don’t have to reformat to meet
different requirements in different states.
Equitable market entry, faster review processes, and uniform rate regulation are the top goals for the many in-
surance groups who are calling for federal chartering as an option for insurance companies, as it has been for
the banking industry for 140 years. In December 2001, Senator Charles E. Schumer introduced a bill, the Na-
tional Insurance Chartering and Supervision Act, that uses the banking industry’s dual state-federal regulatory
system as a model. Under this bill, insurance companies could choose between state and federal regulation.
The following February, Representative John J. LaFalce introduced the Insurance Industry Modernization and
Consumer Protection Act, which also would create an optional federal charter for the companies but would
keep the states in charge of overseeing insurance rates. (As of March 2009, neither bill had been scheduled for
a vote.) In 2004, the State Modernization and Regulatory Transparency (SMART) Act was introduced as the na-
tional federal insurance standards conceptual framework (known also as the Oxley-Baker Roadmap) and also
invoked major debate.
The 2008–2009 economic recession has renewed interest in optional federal chartering and federal involve-
ment in insurance regulation among members of Congress. The National Insurance Consumer Protection and
Regulatory Modernization Act, proposed by Representatives Mellisa Bean and Ed Royce, calls for a national
regulatory system and supervision of nationally registered insurers, agencies, and producers; states would re-
tain responsibility over state-licensed entities. The bill would also establish separate guaranty funds for the fed-
erally regulated insurers and create federal insurance offices in every state. A vocal critic of the proposal is the
National Association of Professional Insurance Agents, who claims that the bill promotes deregulation similar
in nature to the type of failed regulation of other financial institutions that brought about the economic reces-
sion. Agents for Change, a trade organization representing both life/health and property/casualty agents, ap-
plauds the bill as a progressive step that would help insurers to address the present-day needs of consumers.
The bailout of AIG by the federal government in the fall of 2008 escalated the talk about regulatory reform of
the insurance industry. Further, there are talks about an active role nationally versus globally. Regardless of the
form of the change, all observers talk about some reform with the new administration of President Obama and
the makeup of Congress. There are serious talks about an office of insurance information within the Treasury
and a greater federal role in insurance regulation and in solutions to systemic risk issues.
Some groups doubt the wisdom of federal involvement at all and urge a reform of the state system, arguing
that state regulation is more attuned to the needs of the local consumer. Federal regulation, they contend,
would merely add another layer of bureaucracy and cost that not only would hurt the consumer, but also
might drive small, specialty insurers out of business while the larger global insurers opt for more uniformity
afforded by federal regulation.
Members of Congress say that the issue will not be easily decided, and any reform will take years to accom-
plish. Nevertheless, all agree that some kind of change is needed. “No matter what side one takes in this long-
standing debate, it has become clear to me that this is no longer a question of whether we should reform in-
surance regulation in the United States,” said Representative Paul Kanjorski, a member of the House Commit-
tee on Financial Services. “Instead, it has become a question of how we should reform insurance regulation.”
Sources: Steven Brostoff, “Optional Federal Chartering: Federal Chartering Hearings to Begin in June,” National Underwriter Online News Service, May
16, 2002; Mark A. Hofmann, “Supporters of Federal Chartering Speak Out,” Crain’s, June 17, 2002; Steven Brostoff, “Battle Lines Being Drawn Over
Federal Chartering Bill,” National Underwriter Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edition, February 25, 2002; Steven Brostoff , “Chartering
Plans Have Much in Common,” National Underwriter Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edition, January 28, 2002; Lori Chordas, “State
versus Federal: Insurers and Regulators Continue to Debate the Pros and Cons of Insurance Regulation,” Best’s Review, April 2002; Arthur D. Postal,
“NAIC Calls SMART Act Totally Flawed,” National Underwriter Online News Service, March 24, 2005, accessed March 6, 2009,
http://www.propertyandcasualtyinsurancenews.com/cms/NUPC/Breaking%20News/2005/03/24-NAIC%20Calls
%20SMART%20Act%20Totally%20Flawed?searchfor=totally%20flawed; Arthur D. Postal, “Agent Groups Split Over New OFC Bill,” National Underwriter
Online News Service, February 17, 2008, accessed March 6, 2009, http://www.propertyandcasualtyinsurancenews.com/cms/nupc/Breaking %20News/
2009/02/17-AGENTS-dp; Business Insurance Insights, “Howard Mills Speaks about Federal Insurance Regulation,” published February 2009, accessed
March 6, 2009, http://www.businessinsurance.com/cgi-bin/page.pl?pageId=987; and many more articles in the insurance media from the period
between 2004 and 2005 regarding reaction to the proposed SMART Act.
CHAPTER 7 INSURANCE MARKETS AND REGULATION 169
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
6. Read the box "Insurance and Your Privacy—Who Knows?" in this chapter and respond to the
following questions in addition to the questions that are in the box.
a. What are privacy regulations?
b. Why do you think state regulators have been working on adopting such regulation?
c. What is your opinion about privacy regulation? What are the pros and cons of such
regulation?
7. What are risk-based capital requirements, and what is their purpose?
8. How do stock insurers differ from mutuals with respect to their financial requirements?
CHAPTER 7 INSURANCE MARKETS AND REGULATION 171
18. Jim Connolly, “AIG Mess Spurring Move to Tighten Insurer Rules,” National Under-
ENDNOTES writer Online News Service, May
http://www.propertyandcasualtyinsurancenews.com/cms/NUPC/
17, 2005,
Breaking%20News/2005/05/
16-CONNOLLY-jc?searchfor=AIG%20Mess%20Spurring%20Move
%20to%20Tighten%20Insurer%20Rules (accessed March 6, 2009).
1. Includes accident and health insurance.
2. Nonlife premiums include state funds; life premiums include an estimate of group 19. See the discussion of risk-based capital laws at http://www.naic.org. The requirement
pension business. and formulas are continuously changing as the NAIC continues to study the chan-
ging environment. The basic formula prior to 1996, the Life RBC formula, comprised
3. April 1, 2007–March 31, 2008. four components related to different categories of risk: asset risk (C-1), insurance risk
(C-2), interest rate risk (C-3), and business risk (C-4). Each of the four categories of risk
4. April 1, 2007–March 31, 2008. is a dollar figure representing a minimum amount of capital required to cover the
corresponding risk. The final formula is the following:
5. Life business expressed in net premiums.
6. Adjusted to 2008 dollars by the Insurance Information Institute.
RBC Authorized Capital = (C − 4) + Square Root of [(C − 1 + C − 3)2 + (C − 2)2].
7. Estimated.
8. “Weiss: Life Profits Jump 42 Percent,” National Underwriter, Life & Health/Financial Ser- 20. For some examples, see Etti G. Baranoff, Tom Sager, and Tom Shively,
vices Edition, March 15, 2005. “Semiparametric Modeling as a Managerial Tool for Solvency,” Journal of Risk and In-
surance, September 2000; and Etti G. Baranoff, Tom Sager, and Bob Witt, “Industry
9. Insurance Information Institute (III), Insurance Fact Book 2009, 19. Segmentation and Predictor Motifs for Solvency Analysis of the Life/Health Insurance
Industry,” Journal of Risk and Insurance, March 1999.
10. Scott Patterson and Leslie Scism, “The Next Big Bailout Decision: Insurers,” Wall Street
Journal, March 12, 2009, A1. 21. New York is the only state that funds the guaranty fund prior to losses from insolvent
insurers.
11. Insurance Information Institute (III), Insurance Fact Book 2009, 23.
22. John S. Moyse, “Legalized Rebating—A Marketing View,” Journal of the American Soci-
12. Ron Panko, “Healthy Selection: Less Than a Decade After the Managed-Care Revolu- ety of CLU 40, no. 5 (1986): 57.
tion Began in Earnest, New Styles of Health Plans Are on the Market. Proponents See
Them As the Next Major Trend in Health Insurance,” Best’s Review, June 2002. 23. “Four More California Insurers Settle on Prop. 103 Rebates,” National Underwriter,
Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edition, March 18, 1996. The article
13. David Hilgen, “Bermuda Bound—Bermuda: Insurance Oasis in the Atlantic,” and explains, “Prop. 103 rebates are determined by applying a formula contained in ad-
“Bermuda Bound—The New Bermudians,” Best’s Review, March 2002. ministrative regulation RH-291 into which a company’s verifiable financial data is in-
serted. The purpose of the regulations is to determine rebate amounts so as not to
14. Raymond Dirks and Leonard Gross, The Great Wall Street Scandal (New York: McGraw- conflict with the California Supreme Court’s ruling in Calfarm v. Deukmejian that re-
Hill Book Company, 1974). bates may not deprive an insurer of a fair rate of return. After the California Supreme
Court upheld the regulations in 1994, insurance companies appealed to the U.S. Su-
15. “Three Executives Charged in Frankel Case,” Best’s Review, February 2002.
preme Court, which in February 1995 refused to review the case. Commissioner
16. The theory behind this requirement is that a company offering all lines of insurance Quackenbush re-adopted the regulations in March, 1995.”
may have greater variations of experience than a company engaged in only one or a
few lines and therefore should have a greater cushion of protection for policyhold- 24. Steven Brostoff, “Hearing Bares Insurers’ Charter Split,” National Underwriter Online
ers. It seems reasonable to believe, however, that the opposite may be the case; bad News Service, June 12, 2002.
experience in one line may be offset by good experience in another line.
25. Irene Weber, “No Sale Despite Gramm-Leach-Bliley,” Best’s Review, May 2002.
17. Andrew Balls, “Greenspan Praises Corporate Governance Law,” Financial Times, May
26. “NCOIL to Congress: Smart Act Unwarranted,” Albany, New York, September 11, 2004.
16, 2005, http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/
e7dc1c70-c568-11d9-87fd-00000e2511c8.html?nclick_check=1 (accessed March 6, 27. E. E. Mazier, “Chartering Plans: They all Have Much in Common,” National Underwriter,
2009). Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edition, January 28, 2002.
172 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
CHAP TER 8
Fundamental Doctrines
Affecting Insurance
Contracts
The insurance contract (or policy) we receive when we transfer risk to the insurance company is the only contract (or policy)
physical product we receive at the time of the transaction. As described in the Risk Ball Game in Chapter 1, the Document received when
one transfer risks to the
contract makes the exchange tangible. Now that we have some understanding of the nature of risk and insurance, insurance company; is the
only physical product
insurance company operations, markets, and regulation, it is time to move into understanding the contracts and received at the time of the
transaction.
the legal doctrines that influence insurance policies. Because contracts are subject to disputes, understanding their
relational contracts
nature and complexities will make our risk management activities more efficient. Some contracts explicitly spell out Contracts whose provisions
are dynamic with respect to
every detail, while other contracts are considered incomplete and their interpretations are subject to arguments.[1] the environment in which
they are executed.
For example, in a health contract, the insurer promises to pay for medicines. However, as new drugs come to
incomplete contracts
market every day, insurers can refuse to pay for an expensive new medication that was not on the market when the
Contracts that contain terms
contract was signed. An example is Celebrex, exalted for being easier on the stomach than other anti-inflammatory that are implicit rather than
explicit.
drugs and a major favorite of the “young at heart” fifty-plus generation. Many insurers require preauthorization to
verify that the patient has no other choices of other, less expensive drugs.[2] The evolution of medical technology
and court decisions makes the health policy highly relational to the changes and dynamics in the marketplace.
Relational contracts, we can say, are contracts whose provisions are dynamic with respect to the environment
in which they are executed. Some contracts are known as incomplete contracts because they contain terms
that are implicit, rather than explicit. In the previous example, the dynamic nature of the product that is covered by
the health insurance policy makes the policy “incomplete” and open to disputes. Fallen Celebrex rival, Vioxx, is a
noted example. New Jersey–based Merck & Co., Inc., faces more than 7,000 lawsuits claiming that its blockbuster
drug knowingly increased risk of heart attack and stroke. This chapter also delves into the structure of insurance
contracts in general and insurance regulations as they all tie together. We will explore the following:
1. Links
1. LINKS
At this point in the text, we are still focused on broad subject matters that connect us to our holistic
risk and risk management puzzle. We are not yet drilling down into specific topics such as homeown-
er’s insurance or automobile insurance. We are still in the big picture of understanding the importance
174 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
of clarity in insurance contracts and the legal doctrines that influence those contracts, and the agents or
brokers who deliver the contracts to us. If you think about the contracts like the layers of an onion that
cover the core of the risk, you can apply your imagination to Figure 8.1.[3] We know now that each risk
can be mitigated by various methods, as discussed in prior chapters. The important point here is that
each activity is associated with legal doctrines culminating in the contracts themselves. The field of risk
and insurance is intertwined with law and legal implications and regulation. No wonder the legal field
is so connected to the insurance field as well as many pieces of legislation.
FIGURE 8.1 Links between the Holistic Risk Picture, the Insurance Contract, and Regulation
Source: Etti G. Baranoff, “The Risk Balls Game: Transforming Risk and Insurance Into Tangible Concepts,” Risk Management & Insurance Review 4, no. 2 (2001): 51–59.
You, the student, will learn in this text that the field of insurance encompasses many roles and careers,
including legal ones. As the nature of the contract, described above, becomes more incomplete (less
clear or explicit), more legal battles are fought. These legal battles are not limited to disputes between
insurers and insureds. In many cases, the agents or brokers are also involved. This point is emphasized
in relation to the dispute over the final settlement regarding the World Trade Center (WTC) cata-
strophe of September 11, 2001.[4] The case at hand was whether the collapse of the two towers should
be counted as one insured event (because the damage was caused by a united group of terrorists) or
two insured events (because the damage was caused by two separate planes some fifteen minutes
apart). Why is this distinction important? Because Swiss Re, one of the principal reinsurers of the
World Trade Center, is obligated to pay damages up to $3.5 billion per insured event. The root of the
dispute involves explicit versus incomplete contracts, as described above. The leaseholder, Silverstein
Properties, claimed that the broker, Willis Group Holdings, Ltd., promised a final contract that would
interpret the attack as two events. The insurer, Swiss Re, maintained that it and Willis had agreed to a
type of policy that would explicitly define the attack as one event. Willis was caught in the middle and,
as you remember, brokers represent the insured. Therefore, a federal judge had to choose an appropri-
ate way to handle the case. The final outcome was that for some insurers, the event was to be counted
as two events.[5] This story is only one of many illustrations of the complexities of relationships and the
legal doctrines that are so important in insurance transactions.
CHAPTER 8 FUNDAMENTAL DOCTRINES AFFECTING INSURANCE CONTRACTS 175
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
2.1 Agents
Insurance is sold primarily by agents. The underlying contract, therefore, is affected significantly by the
legal authority of the agent, which in turn is determined by well-established general legal rules regard-
ing agency.
The law of agency, as stated in the standard work on the subject, “deals basically with the legal law of agency
consequences of people acting on behalf of other people or organizations.”[6] Agency involves three Law that deals basically with
parties: the principal, the agent, and a third party. The principal (insurer) creates an agency relation- the legal consequences of
ship with a second party by authorizing him or her to make contracts with third parties (policyholders) people acting on behalf of
on the principal’s behalf. The second party to this relationship is known as the agent, who is author- other people or
ized to make contracts with a third party.[7] The source of the agent’s authority is the principal. Such organizations.
authority may be either expressed or implied. When an agent is appointed, the principal expressly in- principal
dicates the extent of the agent’s authority. The agent also has, by implication, whatever authority is Individual who creates an
needed to fulfill the purposes of the agency. By entering into the relationship, the principal implies that agency relationship with a
the agent has the authority to fulfill the principal’s responsibilities, implying apparent authority. second party by authorizing
From the public’s point of view, the agent’s authority is whatever it appears to be. If the principal treats him or her to make contracts
a second party as if the person were an agent, then an agency is created. Agency law and the doctrines with third parties
of waiver and estoppel have serious implications in the insurance business. (policyholders) on the
principal’s behalf.
The agent’s relationship between the insured and the insurer is greatly affected by doctrines of waiver conditional binder
and estoppel. Agreement that implies that
coverage exists only if the
underwriter ultimately
accepts (or would have
accepted) the application for
insurance.
176 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
waiver
Waiver is the intentional relinquishment of a known right. To waive a right, a person must know
he or she has the right and must give it up intentionally. If an insurer considers a risk to be undesirable
The intentional at the time the agent assumes it on behalf of the company, and the agent knows it, the principal (the in-
relinquishment of a known
right.
surer) will have waived the right to refuse coverage at a later date. This situation arises when an agent
insures a risk that the company has specifically prohibited.
Suppose, for example, that the agent knew an applicant’s seventeen-year-old son was allowed to
drive the covered automobile and also knew the company did not accept such risks. If the agent issues
the policy, the company’s right to refuse coverage on this basis later in the policy period has been
waived.
In some policies, the insurer attempts to limit an agent’s power to waive its provisions. A business
property policy, for example, may provide that the terms of the policy shall not be waived, changed, or
modified except by endorsement issued as part of the policy.
Unfortunately for the insurer, however, such stipulations may not prevent a waiver by its agent.
For example, the business property policy provides that coverage on a building ceases after it has been
vacant for over sixty days. Let’s suppose that the insured mentions to the agent that one of the build-
ings covered by the policy has been vacant sixty days, but also adds that the situation is only temporary.
If the agent says, “Don’t worry, you’re covered,” the right of the insurer to deny coverage in the event of
a loss while the building is vacant is waived. The policy may provide that it cannot be orally waived, but
that generally will not affect the validity of the agent’s waiver. From the insured’s point of view, the
agent is the company and the insurer is responsible for the agent’s actions.
private pension
This point came to a head in the mid-1990s when many life insurance companies were confronted
by class-action lawsuits that accused their agents of selling life insurance as a private pension[9] —that
When the investment portion
or cash accumulation of a
is, when the investment portion or cash accumulation of a permanent life insurance policy is elevated
permanent life insurance to a position of a retirement account. There were also large numbers of complaints about misrepresent-
policy is elevated to a ation of the interest rate accumulation in certain life insurance policies called universal life, which was
position of a retirement discussed at length in Chapter 1.[10] The allegations were that insurers and their agents “furnished false
account. and misleading illustrations to whole life insurance policyholders, failing to show that policies would
vanishing premiums need to be active over twenty years to achieve a ‘comparable interest rate’ on their premium dollars and
policies used a ‘software on-line computer program’ and other misleading sales materials to do so.”[11] These
Policies that policyholders were dubbed vanishing premiums policies because the policyholders were led to believe that after a
were led to believe would be certain period of time, the policy would be paid in full, and they would no longer have to make premi-
paid in full after a certain um payments.[12] Though no vanishing-premium case has been tried on the merits, litigation costs and
period of time, and they settlement proceedings have cost companies hundreds of millions of dollars. Many large insurers such
would no longer have to
make premium payments.
as Prudential, Met Life,[13] Money, Northwestern Life, Life of Virginia, and more were subject to large
fines by many states’ insurance regulators and settled with their policyholders. Prudential’s settlement
with 8 million policyholders will cost the company more than $3.5 billion.[14]
compliance officer Many of these companies created the new position of compliance officer, who is charged with
Individual charged with
overseeing all sales materials and ensuring compliance with regulations and ethics.[15] Meanwhile,
overseeing all sales materials states focused on modifying and strengthening market conduct regulations. See the box "Enforcing the
and ensuring compliance Code—Ethics Officers" for a review of insurers’ efforts regarding ethics and for ethical discussion ques-
with regulations and ethics. tions. Ultimately, the insurer may hold the agent liable for such actions, but with respect to the insured,
the insurer cannot deny its responsibilities. “The vexing problem of vanishing premiums has proven to
respondeat superior
be an expensive lesson for insurance companies on the doctrine of respondeat superior—a Latin
A Latin phrase referring to the phrase referring to the doctrine that the master is responsible for the actions taken by his or her servant
doctrine that the master is
responsible for the actions
during the course of duty.”[16] Neither insurers nor regulators consider an agency relationship as an in-
taken by his or her servant dependent contractor relationship.
during the course of duty. Estoppel occurs when the insurer or its agent has led the insured into believing that coverage ex-
ists and, as a consequence, the insurer cannot later claim that no coverage existed. For example, when
estoppel an insured specifically requests a certain kind of coverage when applying for insurance and is not told it
Situation that occurs when is not available, that coverage likely exists, even if the policy wording states otherwise, because the
the insurer or its agent has agent implied such coverage at the time of sale, and the insurer is estopped from denying it.
led the insured into believing
that coverage exists, and as a Agency by Estoppel
consequence, it means that
the insurer cannot later claim An agency relationship may be created by estoppel when the conduct of the principal implies that an
that no coverage existed. agency exists. In such a case, the principal will be estopped from denying the existence of the agency
(recall the binding authority of some agents). This situation may arise when the company suspends an
agent, but the agent retains possession of blank policies. People who are not agents of a company do
not have blank policies in their possession. By leaving them with the former agent, the company is act-
ing as if he or she is a current agent. If the former agent issues those policies, the company is estopped
from denying the existence of an agency relationship and will be bound by the policy.
If an agent who has been suspended sends business to the company that is accepted, the agency re-
lationship will be ratified by such action and the company will be estopped from denying the contract’s
CHAPTER 8 FUNDAMENTAL DOCTRINES AFFECTING INSURANCE CONTRACTS 177
existence. The company has the right to refuse such business when it is presented, but once the busi-
ness is accepted, the company waives the right to deny coverage on the basis of denial of acceptance.
Sources: Vicki Lankarge, “Insurance Companies Are Not to Be Trusted, Say Consumers,” Insure.com, May 30, 2002; http://www.insure.com/gen/
trust502.html; Insurance Marketplace Standards Association, http://www.imsaethics.org; Barbara Bowers, “Higher Profile: Compliance Officers Have
Experienced Elevated Status within Their Companies Since the Emergence of the Insurance Marketplace Standards Association,” Best’s Review, October
2001; Lori Chordas, “Code of Ethics: More Insurers Are Hiring Ethics Officers to Set and Implement Corporate Mores,” Best’s Review, March 2001.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. Describe how agents can bring major liability suits from consumers against their insurers. Do you think
insurers should really be liable for the actions of their agents?
2. Explain the concepts of waiver and estoppel, and provide an example of each.
3. Henrietta Hefner lives in northern Minnesota. She uses a wood-burning stove to heat her home. Although
Ms. Hefner has taken several steps to ensure the safety of her stove, she does not tell her insurance agent
about it because she knows that most wood-burning stoves represent uninsurable hazards. Explain to Ms.
Hefner why she should tell her insurance agent about the stove.
3. REQUIREMENTS OF A CONTRACT
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
When an agent sells an insurance policy, he or she is selling a contract. A contract is an agreement en-
forceable by law. For any such agreement to be legally enforceable, it must meet the following minim-
um requirements:
< There must be an offer and an acceptance
< There must be consideration
< The parties to the contract must be competent
< Its purpose must be legal
< The contract must be in legal form
verbal, as in this case, or it may be in the form of a written application. This process differs for life and
health insurance.
3.2 Consideration
A contract also requires the exchange of consideration. Consideration is the price each party de-
consideration
mands for agreeing to carry out his or her part of the contract. The value of the consideration is usually
unimportant, but lack of consideration will cause the contract to be regarded as a gift and therefore un- The price each party
demands for agreeing to
enforceable. In many cases, insurance contracts stipulate that the consideration is both in the form of carry out his or her part of the
premium and certain conditions specified in the policy. Such conditions may include maintenance of a contract.
certain level of risk, timely notice of loss, and periodic reports to insurers of exposure values. Condi-
tions will be explained in detail in parts III and IV of the text in the descriptions of insurance contracts.
Consideration, therefore, does not necessarily imply dollars.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
In addition to the elements just discussed, insurance contracts have several characteristics that differen-
tiate them from most other contracts. Risk managers must be familiar with these characteristics in or-
der to understand the creation, execution, and interpretation of insurance policies. Insurance contracts
are the following:
< Based on utmost good faith
< Contracts of adhesion
< Contracts of indemnity
< Personal
was not strictly true, the contract was voidable. The penalty for departing from utmost good faith was
having no coverage when a loss occurred. Today, the concept of utmost good faith is implemented by
the doctrines of (1) representations and (2) concealment.[17]
Representations
When people are negotiating with insurers for coverage, they make statements concerning their expos-
representations
ures, and these statements are called representations. They are made for the purpose of inducing in-
Statements concerning an
surers to enter into contracts; that is, provide insurance. If people misrepresent material
insured’s exposures.
facts—information that influences a party’s decision to accept the contract—insurers can void their
contracts and they will have no coverage, even though they do have insurance policies. In essence, the material facts
contracts never existed. Information that influences a
Note that “material” has been specified. If an insurer wants to void a contract it has issued to a per- party’s decision to accept a
son in reliance upon the information she provided, it must prove that what she misrepresented was contract.
material. That is, the insurer must prove that the information was so important that if the truth had
been known, the underwriter would not have made the contract or would have done so only on differ-
ent terms.
If, for example, you stated in an application for life insurance that you were born on March 2 when
in fact you were born on March 12, such a misrepresentation would not be material. A correct state-
ment would not alter the underwriter’s decision made on the incorrect information. The policy is not
voidable under these circumstances. On the other hand, suppose you apply for life insurance and state
that you are in good health, even though you’ve just been diagnosed with a severe heart ailment. This
fact likely would cause the insurer to charge a higher premium or not to sell the coverage at all. The sig-
nificance of this fact is that the insurer may contend that the policy never existed (it was void), so loss
by any cause (whether related to the misrepresentation or not) is not covered. Several exceptions to this
rule apply, as presented in chapters discussing specific policies. In the case of life insurance, the insurer
can void the policy on grounds of material misrepresentation only for two years, as was discussed in
Chapter 1.
It is not uncommon for students to misrepresent to their auto insurers where their cars are
garaged, particularly if premium rates at home are lower than they are where students attend college.
Because location is a factor in determining premium rates, where a car is garaged is a material fact. Stu-
dents who misrepresent this or other material facts take the chance of having no coverage at the time of
a loss. The insurer may elect to void the contract.
Concealment
Telling the truth in response to explicit application questions may seem to be enough, but it is not. One
concealment
must also reveal those material facts about the exposure that only he or she knows and that he or she
should realize are relevant. Suppose, for example, that you have no insurance on your home because Intentionally withholding a
you “don’t believe in insurance.” Upon your arrival home one afternoon, you discover that the neigh- material fact.
bor’s house—only thirty feet from yours—is on fire. You promptly telephone the agency where you buy
your auto insurance and apply for a homeowner’s policy, asking that it be put into effect immediately.
You answer all the questions the agent asks but fail to mention the fire next door. You have intention-
ally concealed a material fact you obviously realize is relevant. You are guilty of concealment
(intentionally withholding a material fact), and the insurer has the right to void the contract.
If the insurance company requires the completion of a long, detailed application, an insured who
fails to provide information the insurer neglected to ask about cannot be proven guilty of concealment
unless it is obvious that certain information should have been volunteered. Clearly, no insurance agent
is going to ask you when you apply for insurance if the neighbor’s house is on fire. The fact that the
agent does not ask does not relieve you of the responsibility.
In both life and health insurance, most state insurance laws limit the period (usually one or two
years) during which the insurer may void coverage for a concealment or misrepresentation. Other
types of insurance contracts do not involve such time limits.
by risk managers or brokers who then seek underwriters to accept them, whereas most individuals go
to an agent to request coverage as is.
The fact that buyers usually have no influence over the content or form of insurance policies has
had a significant impact on the way courts interpret policies when there is a dispute.[18] When the
terms of a policy are ambiguous, the courts favor the insured because it is assumed that the insurer that
writes the contract should know what it wants to say and how to state it clearly. Further, the policy lan-
guage generally is interpreted according to the insured’s own level of expertise and situation, not that of
an underwriter who is knowledgeable about insurance. When the terms are not ambiguous, however,
the courts have been reluctant to change the contract in favor of the insured.
A violation of this general rule occurs, however, when the courts believe that reasonable insureds
would expect coverage of a certain type. Under these conditions, regardless of the ambiguity of policy
language (or lack thereof), the court may rule in favor of the insured. Courts are guided by the expecta-
tions principle (or reasonable expectations principle), which may be stated as follows:
The objectively reasonable expectations of applicants and intended beneficiaries regarding the
terms of insurance contracts will be honored even though painstaking study of the policy
provisions would have negated those expectations.[19]
In other words, the expectations principle holds that, in the event of a dispute, courts will read
expectations principle
insurance policies as they would expect the insured to do. Thus, the current approach to the interpreta-
The event of a dispute, courts tion of contracts of adhesion is threefold: first, to favor the insured when terms of the contract drafted
will read insurance policies as
they would expect the
by the insurer are ambiguous; second, to read the contract as an insured would; third, to determine the
insured to do. coverage on the basis of the reasonable expectations of the insured.
Insurable Interest
If a fire or auto collision causes loss to a person or firm, that person or firm has an insurable interest. A
insurable interest
person not subject to loss does not have an insurable interest. Stated another way, insurable interest
Financial interest in life or is financial interest in life or property that is subject to loss. The law concerning insurable interest is
property that is subject to
loss.
important to the buyer of insurance because it determines whether the benefits from an insurance
policy will be collectible. Thus, all insureds should be familiar with what constitutes an insurable in-
terest, when it must exist, and the extent to which it may limit payment under an insurance policy.
CHAPTER 8 FUNDAMENTAL DOCTRINES AFFECTING INSURANCE CONTRACTS 183
value of life insurance policies traded through the life settlement market to about $10 billion in 2004,
from $3 billion in 2003.”[25] There is a regulatory maze regarding these arrangements.[26]
janitor’s insurance
Because the legal concept of requiring an insurable interest only at the inception of the life insur-
ance contract has continued, it is possible to collect on a policy in which such interest has ceased. For
Inexpensive life insurance
example, if the life of a key person in a firm is insured, and the firm has an insurable interest in that key
coverage.
person’s life because his or her death would cause a loss to the firm, the policy may be continued in
corporate-owned life force by the firm even after the person leaves the firm. The proceeds may be collected when he or she
insurance (COLI) dies. This point was brought to light with the publication of the Wall Street Journal story “Big Banks
Policies in which employers Quietly Pile Up ‘Janitors’ Insurance.”[27] The article reports that banks and other large employers
own life insurance policies on bought inexpensive life coverage—or janitor’s insurance—on the lives of their employees. This prac-
employees. tice did not require informing the employees or their families. Coverage was continued even after the
employees left the company. Upon the death of the employees, the employer collected the proceeds and
padded their bottom-line profits with tax-free death benefits. Many newspapers reported the story as a
breach of ethical behavior. The Charlotte Observer (North Carolina) reported that employers were not
required to notify workers of corporate-owned life insurance (COLI) policies in which employers
own life insurance policies on employees. However, the newspaper continued, “some of the Charlotte
area’s biggest companies said they have notified all employees covered by the policies, but declined to
say how they informed the workers. Use of COLI policies has raised outcries from human rights activ-
ists and prompted federal legislation calling for disclosure.”[28] The National Association of Insurance
Commissioners (NAIC) formed a special working group to study these issues. Dissatisfaction with the
janitor insurance scandal led the state of Washington to instate a law requiring employers to obtain
written permission from an employee before buying life insurance on the employee’s life. Key employ-
ees can still be exempt from the law. In 2005, members of the U.S. House of Representative also pro-
posed legislation to limit such practices.[29]
Subrogation
The principle of indemnity is also supported by the right of subrogation. Subrogation gives the in-
subrogation
surer whatever claim against third parties the insured may have as a result of the loss for which the in-
surer paid. For example, if your house is damaged because a neighbor burned leaves and negligently Situation that gives the
insurer whatever claim
permitted the fire to get out of control, you have a right to collect damages from the neighbor because a against third parties the
negligent wrongdoer is responsible to others for the damage or injury he or she causes. (Negligence li- insured may have as a result
ability will be discussed in later chapters.) If your house is insured against loss by fire, however, you of the loss for which the
cannot collect from both the insurance company and the negligent party who caused the damage. Your insurer paid.
insurance company will pay for the damage and is then subrogated (that is, given) your right to collect
damages. The insurer may then sue the negligent party and collect from him or her. This prevents you
from making a profit by collecting twice for the same loss.
The right of subrogation is a common law right the insurer has without a contractual agreement. It
is specifically stated in the policy, however, so that the insured will be aware of it and refrain from re-
leasing the party responsible for the loss. The standard personal auto policy, for example, provides that
if we make a payment under this policy and the person to or for whom payment was made has a
right to recover damages from another, that person shall subrogate that right to us. That person
shall do whatever is necessary to enable us to exercise our rights and shall do nothing after loss to
prejudice them.
If we make a payment under this policy and the person to or for whom payment is made
recovers damages from another, that person shall hold in trust for us the proceeds of the recovery
and shall reimburse us to the extent of our payment.
example, if your kitchen has not been redecorated for a very long time and looks shabby, you may not
worry about leaving a kettle of grease unattended on the stove. The resulting grease fire will require ex-
tensive redecoration as well as cleaning of furniture and, perhaps, replacement of some clothing
(assuming that the fire is extinguished before it gets entirely out of control). Or you may simply let
your old house burn down. Insurers try to cope with these problems by providing in the policy that,
when the cost to repair or replace damage to a building is more than some specified amount, the in-
surer will pay not more than the actual cash value of the damage until actual repair or replacement is
completed. In this way, the insurer discourages you from destroying the house in order to receive a
monetary reward. Arson generally occurs with the intent of financial gain. Some insurers will insure
personal property only on an actual cash value basis because the opportunity to replace old with new
may be too tempting to some insureds. Fraudulent claims on loss to personal property are easier to
make than are fraudulent claims on loss to buildings. Even so, insurers find most insureds to be honest,
thus permitting the availability of replacement cost coverage on most forms of property.
If a loss covered by this policy is also covered by other insurance, we will pay only the proportion of
the loss that the limit of liability that applies under this policy bears to the total amount of
insurance covering the loss.
Suppose you have a $150,000 homeowners policy with Company A, with $75,000 personal prop-
erty coverage on your home in Montana, and a $100,000 homeowners policy with Company B, with
$50,000 personal property coverage on your home in Arizona. Both policies provide coverage of per-
sonal property anywhere in the world. If $5,000 worth of your personal property is stolen while you are
traveling in Europe, because of the “other insurance” clause, you cannot collect $5,000 from each in-
surer. Instead, each company will pay its pro rata share of the loss. Company A will pay its portion of
the obligation ($75,000/$125,000 = 3/5) and Company B will pay its portion ($50,000/$125,000 = 2/5).
Company A will pay $3,000 and Company B will pay $2,000. You will not make a profit on this deal,
but you will be indemnified for the loss you suffered. The proportions are determined as follows:
4.4 Personal
Insurance contracts are personal, meaning they insure against loss to a person, not to the person’s
personal
property. For example, you may say, “My car is insured.” Actually, you are insured against financial
Insuring against loss to a loss caused by something happening to your car. If you sell the car, insurance does not automatically
person, not to the person’s
property. pass to the new owner. It may be assigned,[33] but only with the consent of the insurer. The personal
auto policy, for example, provides that your rights and duties under this policy may not be assigned
without our written consent.
As you saw in Chapter 6, underwriters are as concerned about who it is they are insuring as they
are about the nature of the property involved, if not more so. For example, if you have an excellent
driving record and are a desirable insured, the underwriter is willing to accept your application for in-
surance. If you sell your car to an eighteen-year-old male who has already wrecked two cars this year,
CHAPTER 8 FUNDAMENTAL DOCTRINES AFFECTING INSURANCE CONTRACTS 187
however, the probability of loss increases markedly. Clearly, the insurer does not want to assume that
kind of risk without proper compensation, so it protects itself by requiring written consent for
assignment.
Unlike property insurance, life insurance policies are freely assignable. This is a result of the way
life insurance practice developed before policies accumulated cash values. Whether or not change of
ownership affects the probability of the insured’s death is a matter for conjecture. In life insurance, the
policyowner is not necessarily the recipient of the policy proceeds. As with an auto policy, the subject
of the insurance (the life insured) is the same regardless of who owns the policy. Suppose you assign
your life insurance policy (including the right to name a beneficiary) to your spouse while you are on
good terms. Such an assignment may not affect the probability of your death. On the other hand, two
years and two spouses later, the one to whom you assigned the policy may become impatient about the
long prospective wait for death benefits. Changing life insurance policyowners may not change the risk
as much as, say, changing auto owners, but it could (murder is quite different from stealing). Neverthe-
less, life insurance policies can be assigned without the insurer’s consent.
Suppose you assign the rights to your life insurance policy to another person and then surrender it
for the cash value before the insurance company knows of the assignment. Will the person to whom
you assigned the policy rights also be able to collect the cash value? To avoid litigation and to eliminate
the possibility of having to make double payment, life insurance policies provide that the company is
not bound by an assignment until it has received written notice. The answer to this question, therefore,
generally is no. The notice requirements, however, may be rather low. A prudent insurer may hesitate
to pay off life insurance proceeds when even a slight indication of an assignment (or change in benefi-
ciary) exists.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. Assume that you are a key employee and that your employer can buy an insurance policy on your life and
collect the proceeds, even if you are no longer with the firm at the time of your death. Clearly, if you leave
the firm, your employer no longer has an insurable interest in your life and would gain by your death.
Would this situation make you uncomfortable? What if you learned that your former employer was in
financial difficulty? Do you think the law should permit a situation of this kind? How is this potential
problem typically solved? Relate your situation to the janitor’s insurance stories described in this chapter.
2. Does the fact that an insurance policy is a contract of adhesion make it difficult for insurers to write it in
simple, easy-to-understand terms? Explain.
3. If your house is destroyed by fire because of your neighbor’s negligence, your insurer may recover from
your neighbor what it previously paid you under its right of subrogation. This prevents you from collecting
twice for the same loss. But the insurer collects premiums to pay losses and then recovers from negligent
persons who cause them. Isn’t that double recovery? Explain.
4. If you have a $100,000 insurance policy on your house but it is worth only $80,000 at the time it is
destroyed by fire, your insurer will pay you only $80,000. You paid for $100,000 of insurance but you get
only $80,000. Are you being cheated? Explain.
5. Who makes the offer in insurance transactions? Why is the answer to this question important?
5. Michelle Rawson recently moved to Chicago from a rural town. She does not tell her new auto
insurance agent about the two speeding tickets she got in the past year. What problem might
Michelle encounter? Explain.
6. You cannot assign your auto policy to a purchaser without the insurer’s consent, but you can
assign your life insurance policy without the insurer’s approval. Is this difference really necessary?
Why or why not?
190 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
a result, courts rarely enforce insurance warranties, treating them instead as repres-
ENDNOTES entations. Our discussion here, therefore, will omit presentation of warranties. See
Kenneth S. Abraham, Insurance Law and Regulation: Cases and Materials (Westbury,
NY: Foundation Press, 1990) for a discussion.
1. The origin of the analysis of the type of contracts is founded in transaction cost eco- 18. Some policies are designed through the mutual effort of insurer and insured. These
“manuscript policies” might not place the same burden on the insurer regarding
nomics (TCE) theory. TCE was first introduced by R. H. Coase in “The Nature of the ambiguities.
Firm,” Economica, November 1937, 386–405, reprinted in Oliver E. Williamson, ed., In-
dustrial Organization (Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing, 1996); Oliver E. 19. See Robert E. Keeton, Basic Text on Insurance Law (St. Paul, MI: West Publishing Com-
Williamson, The Economic Institution of Capitalism (New York: Free Press, 1985); applic- pany, 1971), 351. While this reference is now almost forty years old, it remains per-
ation to insurance contracts developed by Etti G. Baranoff and Thomas W. Sager, haps the most popular insurance text available.
“The Relationship Among Asset Risk, Product Risk, and Capital in the Life Insurance
Industry,” Journal of Banking and Finance 26, no. 6 (2002): 1181–97. 20. In some states, a valued policy law requires payment of the face amount of property
insurance in the event of total loss, regardless of the value of the dwelling. Other
2. Testimonials and author’s personal experience. policy provisions, such as deductibles and coinsurance, may also affect the insurer’s
effort to indemnify you.
3. The idea of using Risk Balls occurred to me while searching for ways to apply transac-
tion costs economic theory to insurance products. I began thinking about the risk 21. Although a person who dies suffers a loss, he or she cannot be indemnified. Because
embedded in insurance products as an intangible item separate from the contract the purpose of the principle of insurable interest is to implement the doctrine of in-
that completes the exchange of that risk. The abstract notion of risk became the in- demnity, it has no application in the case of a person insuring his or her own life.
tangible core and the contract became the tangible part that wraps itself around the Such a contract cannot be one of indemnity.
core or risk.
22. The person whose death requires the insurer to pay the proceeds of a life insurance
4. This issue was discussed at length in all financial magazines and newspapers since policy is usually listed in the policy as the insured. He or she is also known as the ces-
September 11, 2001. tuique vie or the subject. The beneficiary is the person (or other entity) entitled to
the proceeds of the policy upon the death of the subject. The owner of the policy is
5. The December 9, 2004, BestWire article, “Tale of Two Trials: Contract Language Under- the person (or other entity) who has the authority to exercise all the prematurity
lies Contradictory World Trade Center Verdicts,” explains that “the seemingly contra- rights of the policy, such as designating the beneficiary, taking a policy loan, and so
dictory jury verdicts from two trials as to whether the Sept. 11, 2001, destruction of on. Often, the insured is also the owner.
the World Trade Center was one event or two for insurance purposes is not so sur-
prising when the central question in both trials is considered: Did the language in 23. Lynn Asinof, “Is Selling Your Life Insurance Good Policy in the Long-Term?” Wall Street
the insurance agreements adequately define what an occurrence is?” Journal, May 15, 2002.
http://www3.ambest.com/Frames/FrameServer.asp?AltSrc
=23&Tab=1&Site=news&refnum=70605 (accessed March 7, 2009). 24. Ron Panko, “Is There Still Room for Viaticals?” Best’s Review, April 2002.
6. J. Dennis Hynes, Agency and Partnership: Cases, Materials and Problems, 2nd ed. 25. “Life Settlement Group Sets Premium Finance Guidelines,” National Underwriter On-
(Charlottesville, VA: The Michie Company, 1983), 4. line News Service, April 5, 2005; “Firm to Offer Regular Life Settlement Rating Reports,”
National Underwriter Online News Service, April 21, 2005; and Jim Connolly,
7. It is important to note the difference between an agent who represents the insurer “Institutions Reshape Life Settlement Market,” National Underwriter, Life/Health Edi-
and a broker who represents the insured. However, because of state insurance laws, tion, September 16, 2004.
in many states brokers are not allowed to operate unless they also obtain an agency
appointment with an insurer. For details, see Etti G. Baranoff, Dalit Baranoff, and Tom 26. Allison Bell, “Life Settlement Firms Face Jumbled Regulatory Picture,” National Under-
Sager, “Nonuniform Regulatory Treatment of Broker Distribution Systems: An Impact writer, Life/Health Edition, September 16, 2004.
Analysis for Life Insurers,” Journal of Insurance Regulations19, no. 1 (2000): 94.
27. Theo Francis and Ellen E. Schultz, “Big Banks Quietly Pile Up ‘Janitors’ Insurance,’” Wall
8. Steven Brostoff, “Agent Groups Clash On License Reform,” National Underwriter On- Street Journal, May 2, 2002.
line News Service, June 20, 2002.
28. Sarah Lunday, “Business Giants Could Profit from Life Insurance on Workers,” The
9. Donald F. Cady, “‘Private Pension’ Term Should Be Retired,” National Underwriter, Life Charlotte (North Carolina) Observer, May 12, 2002: “Some of Charlotte’s biggest com-
& Health/Financial Services Edition, March 1, 1999. panies—Bank of America Corp., Wachovia Corp. and Duke Energy Corp. in-
cluded—stand to reap profits from life insurance policies purchased on current and
10. Allison Bell, “Met Settles Sales Practices Class Lawsuits,” National Underwriter, Life & former workers. In some cases, the policies may have been purchased without the
Health/Financial Services Edition, August 23, 1999. workers or their families ever knowing.”
11. Diane West, “Churning Suit Filed Against NW Mutual,” National Underwriter, Life & 29. Arthur D. Postal, “House Revives COLI Bill,” National Underwriter Online News Service,
Health/Financial Services Edition, October 14, 1996. May 12, 2005.
12. James Carroll, “Holding Down the Fort: Recent Court Rulings Have Shown Life In- 30. Some property insurance policies are written on a valued basis, but precautions are
surers That They Can Win So-called ‘Vanishing-Premium’ Cases,” Best’s Review, taken to ensure that values agreed upon are realistic, thus adhering to the principle
September 2001. of indemnity.
13. Amy S. Friedman, “Met Life Under Investigation in Connecticut,” National Underwriter, 31. Life and health insurance companies have learned, however, that overinsurance may
Life & Health/Financial Services Edition, January 26, 1998. lead to poor underwriting experience. Because the loss caused by death or illness
cannot be measured precisely, defining overinsurance is difficult. It may be said to
14. Lance A. Harke and Jeffrey A. Sudduth, “Declaration of Independents: Proper Struc- exist when the amount of insurance is clearly in excess of the economic loss that
turing of Contracts with Independent Agents Can Reduce Insurers’ Potential Liabil- may be suffered. Extreme cases, such as the individual whose earned income is $300
ity,” Best’s Review, February 2001. per week but who may receive $500 per week in disability insurance benefits from
an insurance company while he or she is ill, are easy to identify. Life and health in-
15. Barbara Bowers, “Higher Profile: Compliance Officers Have Experienced Elevated
surers engage in financial underwriting to detect overinsurance. The requested
Status Within Their Companies Since the Emergence of the Insurance Marketplace
Standards Association,” Best’s Review, October 2001, http://www3.ambest.com/ amount of insurance is related to the proposed insured’s (beneficiary’s) financial
Frames/FrameServer.asp?AltSrc=23&Tab=1&Site=bestreview&refnum=13888 need for insurance and premium-paying ability.
(accessed March 7, 2009); and “Insurance Exec Points to Need For Strong Ethical
Standards,” National Underwriter Online News Service, May 19, 2005. 32. This is an area in which it is difficult to generalize; the statement made in the text is
approximately correct. The point is that the creditor-debtor relationship is an excep-
tion to the statement that an insurable interest need not exist at the time of the
16. Lance A. Harke and Jeffrey A. Sudduth, “Declaration of Independents: Proper Struc-
death of the insured and that the amount of payment is not limited to the insurable
turing of Contracts with Independent Agents Can Reduce Insurers’ Potential Liabil-
ity,” Best’s Review, February 2001. interest that existed at the inception of the contract. For further discussion, see Ken-
neth Black, Jr., and Harold Skipper, Jr., Life Insurance, 12th ed. (Englewood Cliffs, NJ:
17. Warranties are no longer as prevalent. However, they are stringent requirements that Prentice-Hall, 1994), 187–88.
insureds must follow for coverage to exist. They were considered necessary in the
early days of marine insurance because insurers were forced to rely on the truthful- 33. A complete assignment is the transfer of ownership or benefits of a policy.
ness of policyholders in assessing risk (often, the vessel was already at sea when cov-
erage was procured, and thus inspection was not possible). Under modern condi-
tions, however, insurers generally do not find themselves at such a disadvantage. As
CHAP TER 9
Structure and Analysis of
Insurance Contracts
As discussed in Chapter 8, an insurance policy is a contractual agreement subject to rules governing contracts.
Understanding those rules is necessary for comprehending an insurance policy. It is not enough, however. We will
be spending quite a bit of time in the following chapters discussing the specific provisions of various insurance
contracts. These provisions add substance to the general rules of contracts already presented and should give you
In Chapter 9, we offer a general framework of insurance contracts, called policies. Because most policies are
somewhat standardized, it is possible to present a framework applicable to almost all insurance contracts. As an
analogy, think about grammar. In most cases, you can follow the rules almost implicitly, except when you have
exceptions to the rules. Similarly, insurance policies follow comparable rules in most cases. Knowing the format and
general content of insurance policies will help later in understanding the specific details of each type of coverage
1. Links
2. Entering into the contract: applications, binders, and conditional and binding receipts
3. The contract: declarations, insuring clauses, exclusions and exceptions, conditions, and endorsements and
riders
1. LINKS
By now, we assume you are accustomed to connecting the specific topics of each chapter to the big pic-
ture of your holistic risk. This chapter is wider in scope. We are not yet delving into the specifics of
each risk and its insurance programs. However, compared with Chapter 8, we are drilling down a step
further into the world of insurance legal documents. We focus on the open-peril type of policy, which
covers all risks. This means that everything is covered unless specifically excluded, as shown in Figure
9.1. Nevertheless, the open-peril policy has many exclusions and more are added as new risks appear
on the horizon. For the student who is first introduced to this field, this unique element is an important
one to understand. Most insurance contracts in use today do not list the risks that are covered; rather,
the policy lets you know that everything is covered, even new, unanticipated risks such as anthrax
(described in the box “How to Handle the Risk Management of a Low-Frequency but Scary Risk Ex-
posure: The Anthrax Scare?” in Chapter 3). When the industry realizes that a new peril is too cata-
strophic, it then exerts efforts to exclude such risks from the standardized, regulated policies. Such
efforts are not easy and are met with resistance in many cases. As you learned in Chapter 5, catastroph-
ic risks are not insurable by private insurers; therefore, they are excluded from the policies. In 2005, the
topic of wind versus water was of concern as a result of hurricanes Katrina and Rita. Despite the dev-
astation, all damages caused by flood water were excluded from the policies because floods are con-
sidered catastrophic. Another case in point is the terrorism exclusion that became moot after President
Bush signed the Terrorism Risk Insurance Act (TRIA) in 2002.
192 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
FIGURE 9.1 Links between the Holistic Risk Puzzle and the Insurance Contract
Another important element achieved by exclusions, in addition to excluding the uninsurable risk of
catastrophes, is duplication of coverage. Each policy is designed not to overlap with another policy.
Such duplication would violate the contract of indemnity principal of insurance contracts. The
homeowner’s liability coverage excludes automobile liability, workers’ compensation liability, and oth-
er such exposures that are nonstandard to home and personal activities. These specifics will be dis-
cussed in later chapters, but for now, it is important to emphasize that exclusions are used to reduce the
moral hazard of allowing insureds to be paid twice for the same loss.
Thus, while each insurance policy has the components outlined in Figure 9.1, the exclusions are
the part that requires in-depth study. Exclusions within exclusions in some policies are like a maze. We
not only must ensure that we are covered for each risk in our holistic risk picture, we must also make
sure no areas are left uncovered by exclusions. At this point, you should begin to appreciate the com-
plexity of putting the risk management puzzle together to ensure completeness.
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
You may recall from Chapter 8 that every contract requires an offer and an acceptance. This is also true
for insurance. The offer and acceptance occur through the application process.
2.1 Applications
Although more insurance is sold rather than bought, the insured is still required to make an applica-
application
tion, which is an offer to buy insurance. The function of the agent is to induce a potential insured to
An offer to buy insurance
make an offer. As a practical matter, the agent also fills out the application and then asks for a signature
after careful study of the application. The application identifies the insured in more or less detail, de-
pending on the type of insurance. It also provides information about the exposure involved.
For example, in an application for an automobile policy, you would identify yourself; describe the
automobile to be insured; and indicate the use of the automobile, where it will be garaged, who will
drive it, and other facts that help the insurer assess the degree of risk you represent as a policyholder.
Some applications for automobile insurance also require considerable information about your driving
CHAPTER 9 STRUCTURE AND ANALYSIS OF INSURANCE CONTRACTS 193
and claim experience, as well as information about others who may use the car. In many cases, such as
life insurance, the written application becomes part of the policy. Occasionally, before an oral or writ-
ten property/casualty application is processed into a policy, a temporary contract, or binder, may be
issued.
2.2 Binders
As discussed in Chapter 8, property/casualty insurance coverage may be provided while the application
is being processed. This is done through the use of a binder, which is a temporary contract to provide
coverage until the policy is issued by the agent or the company.
In property/casualty insurance, an agent who has binding authority can create a contract between
the insurance company and the insured. Two factors influence the granting of such authority. First,
some companies prefer to have underwriting decisions made by specialists in the underwriting depart-
ment, so they do not grant binding authority to the agent. Second, some policies are cancelable; others
are not. The underwriting errors of an agent with binding authority may be corrected by cancellation if
the policy is cancelable. Even with cancelable policies, the insurer is responsible under a binder for
losses that occur prior to cancellation. If it is not cancelable, the insurer is obligated for the term of the
contract.
The binder may be written or oral. For example, if you telephone an agent and ask to have your
house insured, the agent will ask for the necessary information, give a brief statement about the con-
tract—the coverage and the premium cost—and then probably say, “You are covered.” At this point,
you have made an oral application and the agent has accepted your offer by creating an oral binder.
The agent may mail or e-mail a written binder to you to serve as evidence of the contract until the
policy is received. The written binder shows who is insured, for what perils, the amount of the insur-
ance, and the company with which coverage is placed.
In most states, an oral binder is as legal as a written one, but in case of a dispute it may be difficult
to prove its terms. Suppose your house burns after the oral binder has been made but before the policy
has been issued, and the agent denies the existence of the contract. How can you prove there was a con-
tract? Or suppose the agent orally binds the coverage, a fire occurs, and the agent dies before the policy
is issued. Unless there is evidence in writing, how can you prove the existence of a contract? Suppose
the agent does not die and does not deny the existence of the contract, but has no evidence in writing.
If the agent represents only one company, he or she may assert that the company was bound and the
insured can collect for the loss. But what if the agent represents more than one company? Which one is
bound? Typically, the courts will seek a method to allocate liability according to the agent’s common
method of distributing business. Or if that is not determinable, relevant losses might be apportioned
among the companies equally. Most agents, however, keep records of their communication with in-
sureds, including who is to provide coverage.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
In this section you studied that the act of entering into an insurance contract, like all contracts, requires offer
and acceptance between two parties:
< The insurance application serves as the insured’s offer to buy insurance.
< An agent may accept an application through oral or written binder in property/casualty insurance and
through conditional receipt or a binding receipt in life/health insurance
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
3. THE CONTRACT
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
Having completed the offer and the acceptance and met the other requirements for a contract, a con-
tract now exists. What does it look like? Insurance policies are composed of five major parts:
< Declarations
< Insuring agreement
< Exclusions
< Conditions
< Endorsements and riders
These parts typically are identified in the policy by headings. (A section titled “definition” is also be-
coming common.) Sometimes, however, they are not so prominently displayed, and it is much more
common to have explicit section designations in property/casualty contracts than it is in life/health
contracts. Their general intent and nature, however, has the same effect.
3.1 Declarations
Generally, the declarations section is the first part of the insurance policy. Some policies, however, have
a cover (or jacket) ahead of the declarations. The cover identifies the insurer and the type of policy.
CHAPTER 9 STRUCTURE AND ANALYSIS OF INSURANCE CONTRACTS 195
Declarations are statements that identify the person(s) or organization(s) covered by the con- declarations
tract, give information about the loss exposure, and provide the basis upon which the contract is issued
and the premium determined. This information may be obtained orally or in a written application. The Statements that identify the
person(s) or organization(s)
declarations section may also include the period of coverage and limitations of liability. (The latter may covered by a contract, give
also appear in other parts of the contract.) information about the loss
exposure, and provide the
Period of Coverage basis upon which the
contract is issued and the
All insurance policies specify the period of coverage, or the time duration for which coverage applies. premium determined.
Life and health policies may provide coverage for the entire life of the insured, a specified period of
years, or up until a specified age. Health policies and term life policies often cover a year at a time. Most period of coverage
property insurance policies are for one year or less (although longer policies are available). Perpetual The time duration for which
policies remain in force until canceled by you or the insurer. Liability policies may be for a three- coverage applies.
month or six-month period, but most are for a year. Some forms of automobile insurance may be writ-
ten on a continuous basis, with premiums payable at specified intervals, such as every six months. Such
policies remain in force as long as premiums are paid or until they are canceled. Whatever the term
during which any policy is to be in force, it will be carefully spelled out in the contract. During periods
when insureds may expect a turn to hard markets in the underwriting cycles, they may want to fix the
level of premiums for a longer period and will sign contracts for longer than one year, such as three
years.
Limitations of Liability
All insurance policies have clauses that place limitations of liability (maximum amount payable by
limitations of liability
the insurance policy) on the insurer. Life policies promise to pay the face amount of the policy. Health
policies typically limit payment to a specified amount for total medical expenses during one’s lifetime The maximum amount
payable by an insurance
and have internal limits on the payment of specific services, such as a surgical procedure. Property in- policy.
surance policies specify as limits actual cash value or replacement value, insurable interest, cost to re-
pair or replace, and the face amount of insurance. Limits exist in liability policies for the amount pay-
able per claim, sometimes per injured claimant, sometimes per year, and sometimes per event. Remem-
ber the example in Chapter 8 of the dispute between the leaseholder and the insurer over the number of
events in the collapse of the World Trade Center (WTC) on September 11, 2001. The dispute was
whether the attack on the WTC constituted two events or one. Defense services, provided in most liab-
ility policies, are limited only to the extent that litigation falls within coverage terms and the policy pro-
ceeds have not been exhausted in paying judgments or settlements. Because of the high cost of provid-
ing legal defense in recent years, however, attempts to limit insurer responsibility to some dollar
amount have been made.
Retained Losses
In many situations, it is appropriate not to transfer all of an insured’s financial interest in a potential
loss. Loss retention benefits the insured when losses are predictable and manageable. For the insurer,
some losses are better left with the insured because of moral hazard concerns. Thus, an insured might
retain a portion of covered losses through a variety of policy provisions. Some such provisions are de-
ductibles, coinsurance in property insurance, copayments in health insurance, and waiting periods in
disability insurance. Each is discussed at some length in later chapters. For now, realize that the exist-
ence of such provisions typically is noted in the declarations section of the policy.
Some insuring clauses are designated as the “insuring agreement,” while others are hidden among
policy provisions. Somewhere in the policy, however, it states that the “insurer promises to pay….”
This general description of the insurer’s promises is the essence of an insuring clause.
Most insurers had already come to the same conclusion. Generally, auto, homeowner’s, commercial property,
business interruption, and (in some states) worker’s compensation policies contain act-of-war exclusions,
meaning that insurance companies can refuse to pay claims arising from a war or a warlike act. To illustrate,
the standard commercial property policy form provided by the Insurance Services Office contains the follow-
ing exclusions:
1. War, including undeclared or civil war
2. Warlike action by a military force, including action in hindering or defending against an actual or
expected attack, by any government, sovereign or other authority using military personnel or other
agents
3. Insurrection, rebellion, revolution, usurped power, or action taken by governmental authority in
hindering or defending against any of these
Wars are not considered insurable events: they are unpredictable, intentional, and potentially catastrophic.
(Recall the discussion in Chapter 5 on insurable and uninsurable risks.) The risks of war are simply too great for
an insurance company to accept.
The war exclusion clause has given rise to few lawsuits, but in each case the courts have supported its applica-
tion “only in situations involving damage arising from a genuine warlike act between sovereign entities.” Pan
American World Airways v. Aetna Casualty and Surety Co., 505 F2d 989 (1974), involved coverage for the hijack-
ing and destruction of a commercial aircraft. The Second Circuit Court of Appeals held that the hijackers,
members of the Popular Front for the Liberation of Palestine, were not “representatives of a government,” and
thus the war exclusion did not apply. The insurers were liable for the loss. A war exclusion claim denial was up-
held in TRT/FTC Communications, Inc. v. Insurance Company of the State of Pennsylvania, 847 F. Supp. 28 (Del.
Dist. 1993), because the loss occurred in the context of a declared war between the United States and
Panama—two sovereign nations.
With some $50 billion at stake from the September 11 attacks, it wouldn’t have been surprising if some in-
surers considered taking a chance at invoking the war exclusion clause. Instead, companies large and small
were quick to announce that they planned to pay claims fairly and promptly. “We have decided that we will
consider the events of September 11 to be ‘acts of terrorism,’ not ‘acts of war,’” said Peter Bruce, Senior Execut-
ive Vice President of Northwestern Mutual Life Insurance. The industry agreed.
Sources: “Insurers: WTC Attack Not Act of War,” Insurance-Letter, September 17, 2001, http://www.cybersure.com/godoc/1872.htm; Jack P. Gibson et
al., “Attack on America: The Insurance Coverage Issues,” International Risk Management Institute, Inc., September 2001, http://www.imri.com; Tim
Reason, “Acts of God and Monsters No Longer Covered: Insurers Say Future Policies Will Definitely Exclude Terrorist Attacks,” CFO.com, November 19,
2001, http://www.cfo.com/article/1,5309,5802%7C%7CA%7C736%7C8,00.html; Susan Massmann, “Legal Background Outlined for War Risk
Exclusion,” National Underwriter Online News Service, September 18, 2001; “Northwestern Mutual Won’t Invoke War Exclusion on Claims,” The
(Milwaukee) Business Journal, September 14, 2001.
Exposures to Loss
Generally, the exposures to be covered are also defined (broadly speaking) in the insuring agreement.
For example, the liability policy states that the insurer will pay “those sums the insured is legally oblig-
ated to pay for damages….” In addition, “the Company shall have the right and duty to defend….” The
exposures in this situation are legal defense costs and liability judgments or settlements against the
insured.
In defining the exposures, important information, such as the basis of valuation and types of losses
covered, is needed. Various valuation methods have already been discussed. Actual cash value and re-
placement cost are the most common means of valuing property loss. Payments required of defend-
ants, either through mutually acceptable settlements or court judgments, define the value of liability
losses. The face value (amount of coverage) of a life insurance policy represents the value paid upon the
insured’s death. Health insurance policies employ a number of valuation methods, including an
amount per day in the hospital or per service provided, or—more likely—the lesser of the actual cost of
the service or the customary and prevailing fee for this service. Health maintenance organizations
promise the provision of services, as such, rather than a reimbursement of their cost.
198 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
The types of covered losses are also generally stated in the insuring agreement. Many property in-
direct loss
surance policies, for example, cover only direct loss. Direct loss to property is the value that is physic-
The value of property that is ally destroyed or damaged, not the loss caused by inability to use the property. Other policies that cover
physically destroyed or
damaged, not including the
loss of use of property without physical damage to the property are called consequential or indirect
loss caused by inability to use loss. In the aftermath of Hurricane Rita, many Texas coastal residents who evacuated encountered in-
the property. direct loss without damage to their homes. This included the evacuation of Galveston and Houston.
Coverage for these losses was disputed by insurers, such as Allstate, that tried to exclude these indirect
consequential or indirect
losses
losses. In addition, in the introduction to this chapter, it was explained how important the consequen-
tial loss coverage was to the businesses that suffered indirectly from the September 11 attacks. A report
A nonphysical loss such as
released by PricewaterhouseCoopers in New York City noted that business interruption claims came
loss of business.
from a wide scope of industries, including financial services, communications, media, and travel indus-
tries, that were not in the attack zone.[2] Many remote businesses were disrupted when the world trans-
portation networks were paralyzed. It was estimated that losses up to $10 billion were caused by these
indirect effects.[3]
business interruption Business interruption losses occur when an organization is unable to sell its goods or services,
and/or unable to produce goods for sale because of direct or indirect loss. Generally, these losses are
Losses that occur when an
organization is unable to sell
due to some property damage considered direct loss. Such lost revenues typically translate into lost
its goods or services and/or profits. The 1992 Chicago flood, for example, required that Marshall Fields downtown store close its
unable to produce goods for doors for several days while crews worked to clean up damage caused by the flood waters.[4] When loss
sale because of direct or is caused by property damage not owned by the business, it is considered a contingent business in-
indirect loss.
terruption. If Marshall Fields reduced its orders to suppliers of its goods, for instance, those suppliers
contingent business may experience contingent business interruption loss caused by the water damage, even though their
interruption own property was not damaged.
Loss caused by property Alternatively, some organizations choose to continue operating following property damage, but
damage not owned by the they are able to do so only by incurring additional costs known as extra expense losses. These costs
business. also reduce profits. Continuing with the 1992 Chicago flood example, consider the various accounting
firms who could not use their offices the second week in April. With the upcoming tax filing deadline,
extra expense losses these firms chose to rent additional space in other locations so they could meet their clients’ needs. The
Additional costs incurred by additional rental expense (and other costs) resulted in reduced profits to the accounting firms. Yet a
organizations that choose to variety of service organizations, including accountants, insurance agents, and bankers, prefer to incur
continue operating following such expenses in order to maintain their reputation of reliability, upon which their long-term success
property damage. and profits depend. Closing down, even temporarily, could badly hurt the organization.
Individuals and families too may experience costs associated with loss of use. For example, if your
home is damaged, you may need to locate (and pay for) temporary housing. You may also incur abnor-
mal expenses associated with the general privileges of home use, such as meals, entertainment, tele-
phones, and similar conveniences. Likewise, if your car is unavailable following an accident, you must
rent a car or spend time and money using other forms of transportation. Thus, while a family’s loss of
use tends to focus on extra expense, its effect may be as severe as that of an organization.
property damage
Liability policies, on the other hand, may cover liability for property damage, bodily injury, per-
sonal injury, and/or punitive damages. Property damage liability includes responsibility both for the
Liability that includes
responsibility both for the physical damage to property and the loss of use of property. Bodily injury is the physical injury to a
physical damage to property person, including the pain and suffering that may result. Personal injury is the nonphysical injury to
and the loss of use of a person, including damage caused by libel, slander, false imprisonment, and the like. Punitive dam-
property. ages are damages assessed against defendants for gross negligence, supposedly for the purpose of pun-
bodily injury ishment and to deter others from acting in a similar fashion. Examples of punitive damages in recent
Physical injury to a person,
cases and their ethical implications are featured in the box “Are Punitive Damages out of Control?”
including the pain and
suffering that may result.
Are Punitive Damages out of Control?
personal injury
Nonphysical injury to a In December 2005, a California jury delivered a guilty verdict and awarded $172 million in damages against
person, including damage Wal-Mart Stores, Inc., for not giving the appropriate lunch breaks to its thousands of employees. The verdict in-
caused by libel, slander, false cluded $57.3 million in general damages and $115 million in punitive damages. Wal-Mart planned to appeal.
imprisonment, and the like. In 2002, a California state court judge awarded $30 million against grocery chain Kroger, where six employees
had been verbally harassed by a store manager. The verdict was reduced to a mere $8.25 million when the up-
punitive damages
per court decided it was “grossly excessive.” A jury in Laredo, Texas, awarded $108 million to Mexican heiress
Awards intended to punish Cristina Brittingham Sada de Ayala in a lawsuit against her stepmother for failing to repay a $34 million loan. A
an offender for exceptionally
Utah jury ordered State Farm to pay a policyholder $145 million in punitive damages for handling a claim in
undesirable behavior.
bad faith and inflicting emotional distress. A Los Angeles jury ordered tobacco giant Philip Morris to pay Betty
Bullock $28 billion in punitive damages.
CHAPTER 9 STRUCTURE AND ANALYSIS OF INSURANCE CONTRACTS 199
The Bullock award of $28 billion (which was lowered to $28 million and is still being appealed by Philip Morris)
is by itself almost five times the combined amount of the top ten largest jury awards to individuals and famil-
ies in 2001. Though a Department of Justice study showed that only a small percentage of cases are awarded
punitive damages, and that the majority of awards are under $40,000, the number and amounts of punitive
awards have been geometrically increasing since the high of $10,000 in 1959.
Some people argue that a fine is the best way to punish a corporation for acting wrongly. For example, the
1994 case against McDonald’s that won an elderly woman $2.7 million for spilling hot coffee in her lap is com-
monly seen as the beginning of our frivolous lawsuit period. What the jury heard, but most people did not,
was that McDonald’s purposely kept its coffee at least forty degrees hotter than most restaurants did, as a
cost-saving measure to extract more coffee from the beans; that more than 700 people had filed complaints
of scalding coffee burns over the previous decade; and that McDonald’s knew their coffee was dangerously
hot, yet had no plans to turn the heat down or postwarning signs. The woman in the case suffered third-de-
gree burns to her groin, thighs, and buttocks that required skin grafts and a lengthy hospital stay. She filed suit
against McDonald’s only after the company refused to pay her medical bills. Even the famous multimillion-dol-
lar award was reduced on appeal to $480,000.
The true problem, many say, is not the size of such awards but the method by which we determine them.
Punitive damages are not truly “damages” in the sense of compensation for a loss or injury but rather a fine,
levied as punishment. In determining the amount of a punitive award, a jury is instructed to consider whether
the defendant displayed reckless conduct, gross negligence, malice, or fraud—but in practice, a jury award of-
ten depends on how heart-tugging the plaintiff seems to be versus how heartless the big bad corporation
appears.
Questions for Discussion
1. Were the facts behind the McDonald’s lawsuit news to you? Do they change your opinion about this
landmark case? What would you have done if you had been on the jury?
2. Betty Bullock, who has lung cancer, had been a regular smoker for forty years and blamed Philip
Morris for failing to warn her about smoking risks. Do you think Philip Morris is responsible? Do you
think learning more about the case might change your opinion?
3. Exxon was ordered to pay $125 million in criminal fines for the Exxon Valdez oil spill. In a separate trial,
a civil jury hit Exxon with a $5 billion punitive award. Is it fair for a company to pay twice for the same
crime?
4. Are juries—composed of people who have no legal training, who know only about the case they are
sitting on, who may be easily swayed by theatrical attorneys, and who are given only vague
instructions—equipped to set punitive damage awards? Should punitive awards be regulated?
Sources: Kris Hudson, “Wal-Mart Workers Awarded $172 Million,” Wall Street Journal, December 23, 2005, B3; Olson, speech at the Manhattan Institute
conference, “Crime and Punishment in Business Law,” May 8, 2002, reprinted at http://www.manhattan-institute.org/html/cjm_15.htm; “Surprise:
Judges Hand Out Most Punitive Awards,” Wall Street Journal, June 12, 2000, 2b; Steven Brostoff, “Top Court to Review Punitive Damages,” National
Underwriter Online News Service, June 27, 2002; “McFacts about the McDonalds Coffee Lawsuit,” Legal News and Views, Ohio Academy of Trial
Lawyers, http://lawandhelp.com/q298–2.htm, Michael Bradford, “Phillip Morris to Continue Appeal of Punitives Award,” Business Insurance, December
19, 2002; http://www.altria.com/media/03_06_04_03_00_Bullock.asp for update on the Bullock case.
The following is a discussion of the purposes of limiting locations, perils, property, and losses.
Excluded Locations
Some types of coverage are location-specific, such as to buildings. Other policies define the location of
coverage. Automobile policies, for example, cover the United States and Canada. Mexico is not covered
because of the very high auto risk there. In addition, some governmental entities in Mexico will not ac-
cept foreign insurance. Some property policies were written to cover movable property anywhere in the
world except the Eastern bloc countries, likely because of difficulty in adjusting claims. With the break-
up of the Communist bloc, these limitations are also being abandoned. Yet coverage may still be ex-
cluded where adjusting is difficult and/or the government of the location has rules against such foreign
insurance. For a discussion of political risk—unanticipated political events that disrupt the earning or
profit-making ability of an enterprise—see Chapter 10.
Excluded Perils
Some perils are excluded because they can be covered by other policies or because they are unusual or
catastrophic. The earthquake peril, for example, requires separate rating and is excluded from
homeowners policies. This peril can be insured under a separate policy or added by endorsement for an
extra premium. Many insureds do not want to pay the premium required, either because they think
their property is not exposed to the risk of loss caused by an earthquake or because they expect that
federal disaster relief would cover losses. Given the choice of a homeowners policy that excluded the
earthquake peril and one that included earthquake coverage but cost $50 more per year, they would
choose the former. Thus, to keep the price of their homeowners policies competitive, insurers exclude
the earthquake peril. It is excluded also because it is an extraordinary peril that cannot easily be in-
cluded with the other perils covered by the policy. It must be rated separately.
As noted above, perils, such as those associated with war, are excluded because commercial in-
surers consider them uninsurable. Nuclear energy perils, such as radiation, are excluded from most
policies because of the catastrophic exposure. Losses to homeowners caused by the nuclear meltdown
CHAPTER 9 STRUCTURE AND ANALYSIS OF INSURANCE CONTRACTS 201
at Three Mile Island in 1979, which forced homeowners to evacuate the damaged property in the area,
were not covered by their homeowners insurance. Losses due to floods are excluded and were a topic of
much discussion after hurricanes Katrina and Rita. Losses due to wear and tear are excluded because
they are inevitable rather than accidental and thus not insurable. Similarly, inherent vice, which refers
to losses caused by characteristics of the insured property, is excluded. For example, certain products,
such as tires and various kinds of raw materials, deteriorate with time. Such losses are not accidental
and are, therefore, uninsurable.
Excluded Property
Some property is excluded because it is insurable under other policies. Homeowners policies, as previ-
ously stated, exclude automobiles because they are better insured under automobile policies. Other
property is excluded because the coverage is not needed by the average insured, who would, therefore,
not want to pay for it.
Liability policies usually exclude damage to or loss of others’ property in the care, custody, or con-
trol of the insured because property insurance can provide protection for the owner against losses
caused by fire or other perils. Other possible losses, such as damage to clothing being dry cleaned, are
viewed as a business risk involving the skill of the dry cleaner. Insurers do not want to assume the risk
of losses caused by poor workmanship or poor management.
Excluded Losses
Losses resulting from ordinance or law—such as those regulating construction or repair—are excluded
from most property insurance contracts. Policies that cover only direct physical damage exclude loss of
use or income resulting from such damage. Likewise, policies covering only loss of use exclude direct
losses. Health insurance policies often exclude losses (expenses) considered by the insurer to be unne-
cessary, such as the added cost of a private room or the cost of elective surgery.
3.4 Conditions
The fourth major part of an insurance contract is the conditions section. Conditions enumerate the
conditions
duties of the parties to the contract and, in some cases, define the terms used. Some policies list them
under the heading “Conditions,” while others do not identify them as such. Wherever the conditions Clauses in a policy that
enumerate the duties of the
are stated, you must be aware of them. You cannot expect the insurer to fulfill its part of the contract parties to the contract and, in
unless you fulfill the conditions. Remember that acceptance of these conditions is part of the considera- some cases, define the terms
tion given by the insured at the inception of an insurance contract. Failure to accept conditions may re- used.
lease the insurer from its obligations. Many conditions found in insurance contracts are common to all.
Others are characteristic of only certain types of contracts. Some examples follow.
Suspension of Coverage
Because there are some risks or hazardous situations insurers want to avoid, many policies specify acts,
suspension of coverage
conditions, or circumstances that will cause the suspension of coverage or, in other words, that will
Release of the insurer from release the insurer from liability. The effect is the same as if the policy were canceled or voided, but
liability.
when a policy is suspended, the effect is only temporary. When a voidance of coverage is incurred in
voidance of coverage an insurance contract, coverage is terminated. Protection resumes only by agreement of the insured
Termination of coverage and insurer. Suspension, in contrast, negates coverage as long as some condition exists. Once the con-
under an insurance policy. dition is eliminated, protection immediately reverts without the need for a new agreement between the
parties.
Some life and health policies have special clauses that suspend coverage for those in military ser-
vice during wartime. When the war is over or the insured is no longer in military service, the suspen-
sion is terminated and coverage is restored. The personal auto policy has an exclusion that is essentially
a suspension of coverage for damage to your auto. It provides that the insurer will not pay for loss to
your covered auto “while it is used to carry persons or property for a fee,” except for use in a share-the-
expense car pool. The homeowners policy (form 3) suspends coverage for vandalism and malicious
mischief losses if the house has been vacant for more than thirty consecutive days. A property insur-
ance policy may suspend coverage while there is “a substantial increase in hazard.”
You can easily overlook or misunderstand suspensions of coverage or releases from liability when
you try to determine coverage provided by a policy. They may appear as either conditions or exclu-
sions. Because their effect is much broader and less apparent than the exclusion of specified locations,
perils, property, or losses, it is easy to underestimate their significance.
Examination
A provision peculiar to some disability income policies gives the insurer the right to have its physician
examine the insured periodically during the time he or she receives benefits under the policy. This right
cannot be used to harass the claimant, but the insurer is entitled to check occasionally to see if he or she
should continue to receive benefits. Property insurance policies have a provision that requires the
claimant to submit to examination under oath, as well as make records and property available for ex-
amination by representatives of the insurance company.
CHAPTER 9 STRUCTURE AND ANALYSIS OF INSURANCE CONTRACTS 203
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
In this section you studied the five basic parts of insurance contracts:
< Declarations—specify periods of coverage, place limitations on liability, and stipulate the insured’s loss
retention provisions
< Insuring agreement—statement of general promise made to the insured; determines whether policy
covers named-perils or open-perils; provides exposures to be covered and types of losses
< Exclusions—state what losses/causes of loss the policy does not cover because of limitations on locations,
perils, property, and losses
< Conditions—define the duties of the parties to the contract; notice and proof of loss mandates,
suspension of coverage triggers, cooperation of the insured requirement, protection of property after loss
measures, and physical examination right
< Endorsements and riders—optional elements that change the terms of property/casualty and life/health
policies; take precedence when they conflict with other parts of the contract
204 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. What are the main reasons for exclusions and for endorsements and riders in insurance policies?
2. What is the significance of an open-perils policy? In deciding between a named-perils policy and an open-
perils policy, what factors would you consider? Define both terms and explain your answer.
3. In Chapter 1 on automobile insurance, you will find that portable stereos and tape decks are excluded
from coverage. What do you think the insurance company’s rationale is for such an exclusion? What are
other reasons for insurance policy exclusions? Give examples of each.
4. Lightning struck a tree in the Gibsons’ yard, causing it to fall over and smash the bay window in their living
room. The Gibsons were so distraught by the damage that they decided to go out for dinner to calm
themselves. After dinner, the Gibsons decided to take in a movie. When they returned home, they
discovered that someone had walked through their broken bay window and stolen many of their valuable
possessions. The Gibsons have a homeowners policy that covers both physical damage and theft. As the
Gibsons’ insurer, do you cover all their incurred losses? Why or why not?
5. Your careless driving results in serious injury to Linda Helsing, a close personal friend. Because she knows
you have liability insurance and the insurer will pay for damages on your behalf, she files suit against you.
Would it be unreasonable for your insurer to expect you not to help Linda pursue maximum recovery in
every conceivable way? Explain.
8. A. J. Jackson was very pleased to hear the agent say that she was covered the moment she finished
completing the application and paid the agent the first month’s premium for health insurance. A.
J. had had some health problems previously and really didn’t expect to be covered until after she
had taken her physical and received notice from the company. The agent said that the conditional
binder was critical for immediate coverage. “Of course,” said the agent, “this coverage may be
limited until the company either accepts or rejects your application.” The agent congratulated A.
J. again for her decision. A. J. began to wonder the next morning exactly what kind of coverage, if
any, she had.
a. What kind of coverage did A. J. have?
b. Did her submission to the agent of the first month’s premium have any impact on her
coverage? Why?
c. If you were the agent, how would you have explained this coverage to A. J.?
9. LeRoy Leetch had a heck of a year. He suffered all the following losses. Based on what you know
about insurance, which would you expect to be insurable and why?
a. LeRoy’s beloved puppy, Winchester, was killed when struck by a school bus. He has
losses of burial expenses, the price of another puppy, and his grief due to Winchester’s
death.
b. LeRoy has an expensive collection of rare clocks. Most are kept in his spare bedroom and
were damaged when a fire ignited due to faulty wiring. The loss is valued at $15,000.
c. Heavy snowfall and a rapid thaw caused flooding in LeRoy’s town. Damage to his
basement was valued at $2,200.
d. Weather was hard on the exterior of LeRoy’s house as well. Dry rot led to major damage
to the first-story hardwood floors. Replacement will cost $6,500.
10. When you apply for a life insurance policy, agent Dawn Gale says, “If you will give me your check
for the first month’s premium now, the policy will cover you now if you are insurable.” Is this a
correct statement, or is Dawn just in a hurry to get her commission for selling you the policy?
Explain.
206 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
4. In April 1992, part of Chicago’s underground tunnel system was flooded when the
ENDNOTES river pushed back a wall far enough to cause a rapid flow of water into the tunnels.
Water levels rose high enough to damage stored property, force electrical supplies
to be shut off, and cause concern about the stability of structures built above the
tunnels.
1. In a few states, the conditional receipt is construed to be the same as the binding re-
5. Thomas v. Transamerica Occidental Life Ins. Co., 761 F. Supp. 709 (1991).
ceipt. See William F. Meyer, Life and Health Insurance Law: A Summary, 2nd ed.
(Cincinnati: International Claim Association, 1990), 196–217. 6. Beauregard v. Beauregard, 56 Ohio App. 158, 10 N.E.2d 227 (1937).
2. “9/11 Business Interruption Claims Analysis,” National Underwriter Online News Service, 7. “Travelers Construction Offers New Pollution Endorsements,” National Underwriter,
February 20, 2002. Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edition, March 10, 1997.
3. Diana Reitz, “9/11 Spotlights Business Interruption Threat—What Is the Art and 8. “Hartford Introduces Estate-Tax Repeal Rider,” National Underwriter Online News Ser-
Science of Establishing the Accurate Limit of Coverage?” National Underwriter, Prop- vice, April 1, 2002; “Lincoln Life Expands Estate Tax Safety Net on Life Insurance” Na-
erty/Casualty Edition, April 16, 2004, tional Underwriter Online News Service, Oct. 12, 2001.
http://www.propertyandcasualtyinsurancenews.com/cms/NUPC/Weekly%20Issues/
Issues/2004/15/p15911spotlights?searchfor= (accessed March 8, 2009). 9. Jack Crawford, “Inflation Protection: Is the LTC Industry on the Right Path?” National
Underwriter, Life & Health/Financial Services Edition, January 21, 2002.
CHAP TER 10
Property Risk Management
At this point you should feel somewhat comfortable with most of the overall picture of risk, but despite the many
examples of risk management and types of coverage you have seen, the details of each coverage are not explicit
yet. In this chapter, we will elaborate on property risks, including electronic commerce, or e-commerce, risk and
global risk exposures. In Chapter 11, we will elaborate on liability risks overall and the particulars of e-commerce
liability. Home coverage that includes both property and liability coverage will be discussed in detail in Chapter 1.
Auto coverage will be discussed in Chapter 1. [MISSING REF: #baranoff-ch13] and [MISSING REF: #baranoff-ch14]
focus on personal lines coverage. Chapter 12 and Chapter 14 take us into the world of commercial lines coverage
and workers’ compensation. In this part of the text, you will be asked to relate sections of the actual policies
provided in the appendixes at the end of the textbook to loss events. Our work will clarify many areas of property
and liability of various risks, including the most recent e-commerce risk exposures and the fundamental global risk
1. Links
2. Property risks
4. Global risks
1. LINKS
The most important part of property coverage is that you, as the first party, are eligible to receive be-
nefits in the event you or your business suffers a loss. In contrast, liability coverage, discussed in
Chapter 11, pays benefits to a third party if you cause a loss (or if someone causes you to have a loss, his
or her liability insurance would pay benefits to you). In this chapter we focus on the first type: coverage
for you when your property is damaged or lost.
In personal lines coverage such as homeowners and auto policies, the property coverage for losses
you sustain, as the owner of the property, is only part of the policies. In commercial lines, you may use
a packaged multilines policy that includes both commercial property and commercial general liability
policies. In this chapter we focus only on the part of the policies relating to the property coverage for
first-party damages to you. As part of your holistic risk and risk management, it is important to have an
appreciation of this part of the coverage.
As we develop the holistic risk management program, you now realize that you need a myriad of
policies to cover all your property exposures, including that of e-commerce, and another myriad of
policies to protect your liability exposures. In some cases, property and liability coverages are packaged
together, such as in homeowners and auto policies, but what is actually covered under each? Our ob-
jective is to untangle it all and show how to achieve a complete risk management picture. To achieve
complete holistic risk management, we have to put together a hierarchy of coverages for various expos-
ures, perils, and hazards—each may appear in one or another policy—as shown in Figure 10.1 (see the
shaded risk pieces of the puzzle that indicate property or first-party-type risks applicable to this
chapter). In addition to understanding this hierarchy, we need to have a vision of the future. E-com-
merce risk, considered one of the emerging risks, is explored in this chapter. Hazards derived from
global exposure are other important risks that receive special attention in this chapter.
208 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
2. PROPERTY RISKS
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
Property can be classified in a number of ways, including its mobility, use value, and ownership. Some-
times these varying characteristics affect potential losses, which in turn affect decisions about which
risk management options work best. A discussion of these classifying characteristics, including consid-
eration of the hot topic of electronic commerce (e-risk) exposures and global property exposures,
follows.
physical property Physical property generally is categorized as either real or personal. Real property represents
permanent structures (realty) that if removed would alter the functioning of the property. Any build-
Consists of real or personal
property.
ing, therefore, is real property. In addition, built-in appliances, fences, and other such items typically
are considered real property.
real property Physical property that is mobile (not permanently attached to something else) is considered per-
Permanent structures (realty) sonal property. Included in this category are motorized vehicles, furniture, business inventory, cloth-
that if removed would alter ing, and similar items. Thus, a house is real property, while a stereo and a car are personal property.
the functioning of the
property.
Some property, such as carpeting, is not easily categorized. The risk manager needs to consider the
various factors discussed below in determining how best to manage such property.
Why is this distinction between real and personal property relevant? One reason is that dissimilar
personal property
properties are exposed to perils with dissimilar likelihoods. When flood threatens a house, the oppor-
Physical property that is tunities to protect it are limited. Yet the threat of flood damage to something mobile may be thwarted
mobile (not permanently by movement of the item away from flood waters. For example, you may be able to drive your car out
attached to something else).
of the exposed area and to move your clothes to higher ground.
A second reason to distinguish between real and personal property is that appropriate valuation
mechanisms may differ between the two. We will discuss later in this chapter the concepts of actual
CHAPTER 10 PROPERTY RISK MANAGEMENT 209
cash value and replacement cost new. Because of moral hazard issues, an insurer may prefer to value
personal property at actual cash value (a depreciated amount). The amount of depreciation on real
property, however, may outweigh concerns about moral hazard. Because of the distinction, valuation
often varies between personal and real property.
When property is physically damaged or lost, the cost associated with being unable to use that
property may go beyond the physical loss. Indirect loss and business interruption losses discussed in
the box “Business Interruption with and without Direct Physical Loss” provides a glimpse into the im-
pact of this coverage on businesses and the importance of the appropriate wording in the policies. In
many cases, only loss of use of property that is directly damaged leads to coverage; in other cases, the
loss of property itself is not a prerequisite to trigger loss of use coverage. As a student in this field, you
will become aware of the importance of the exact meaning of the words in the insurance policy.
2005/12/20-STRIKE-dh?searchfor=transit%20strike; Mark E. Ruquet, “Business Policies May Not Cover Pandemics,” National Underwriter Online News
Service, December 7, 2005, accessed March 15, 2009, http://www.propertyandcasualtyinsurancenews.com/cms/NUPC/Breaking%20News/2005/12/
07-PANDEMIC-mr?searchfor= policies%20may%20not%20cover%20pandemics; Mark Ruquet, “Avian Flu Could Send Shipping Off Course,” National
Underwriter Online News Service, December 12,2005, accessed March 15, 2009, http://www.propertyandcasualtyinsurancenews.com/cms/NUPC/
Breaking%20News/2005/12/12-AVIAN-AON-mr?searchfor=avian%20flu; Sam Friedman, “9/11 Boosts Focus on Interruption Risks,” National
Underwriter, Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edition, April 29, 2002; Joseph B. Treaster, “Insurers Reluctant to Pay Claims Far Afield
from Ground Zero,” New York Times, September 12, 2002; John Foster, “The Legal Aftermath of September 11: Handling Attrition and Cancellation in
Uncertain Times,” Convene, the Journal of the Professional Convention Management Association, December 2001; Daniel Hays, “Zurich Loses Ruling in
a 9/11 Case,” National Underwriter Online News Service, February 11, 2005, accessed March 15, 2009,
http://www.propertyandcasualtyinsurancenews.com/cms/NUPC/Breaking%20News/2005/02/
11-Zurich%20Loses%20Ruling%20In%20A%209-11%20Case?searchfor=.
From Coast to Coast: Who Is Responsible for Earthquake and Flood Losses?
No region of the United States is safe from environmental catastrophes. Floods and flash floods, the most
common of all natural disasters, occur in every state. The Midwest’s designated Tornado Alley ranges from
Texas to the Dakotas, though twisters feel free to land just about anywhere. The Pacific Rim states of Hawaii,
Alaska, Washington, Oregon, and California are hosts to volcanic activity, most famously the May 1980 erup-
tion of Mount St. Helens in southwestern Washington, which took the lives of more than fifty-eight people.
California is also home to the San Andreas Fault, whose seismic movements have caused nine major earth-
quakes in the past one hundred years; the January 1994 Northridge quake was the most costly in U.S. history,
causing an estimated $20 billion in total property damage. (By comparison, the famous San Francisco earth-
quake of 1906 caused direct losses of $24 million, which would be about $10 billion in today’s dollars.) Along
the Gulf and Atlantic coasts, natural disaster means hurricanes. Insurers paid out more money for Hurricane
Katrina in 2005 than they collected in premiums in twenty-five years from Louisiana insureds. California in-
surers paid out more in Northridge claims than they had collected in earthquake premiums over the previous
thirty years. The year 2005 saw an unprecedented number of losses because of hurricanes Katrina, Rita, and
Wilma. The record number of hurricanes included twenty-seven named storms. The insured losses from Hur-
ricane Katrina alone were estimated between $40 and $60 billion, while the economic losses were estimated
to be more than $100 billion. Theses losses are the largest catastrophic losses in U.S. history, surpassing Hur-
ricane Andrew’s record cost to the industry of $20.9 billion in 2004 dollars. This record also surpasses the worst
human-made catastrophe of September 11, 2001, which stands at $34.7 billion in losses in 2004 dollars.
Fearing that the suffering housing, construction, and related industries would impair economic growth, state
government stepped in. The state-run California Earthquake Authority was established in 1996 to provide cov-
erage to residential property owners in high-risk areas. Disaster insurance then went to the federal level. In the
aftermath of Katrina, in December 2005, a proposal for a national catastrophe insurance program was pushed
by four big state regulators during the National Insurance Commissioners meeting in Chicago. The idea was to
change the exclusion in the policies and allow for flood coverage, while calling for a private-state-federal part-
nership to fund megacatastrophe losses and the creation of a new all-perils homeowners policy that would
cover the cost of flood losses.
Questions for Discussion
1. Lee is in favor of government-supported disaster reinsurance because it encourages economic
growth and development. Chris believes that it encourages overgrowth and overdevelopment in
environmentally fragile areas. Whose argument do you support?
2. The Gulf Coast town you live in has passed a building code requiring that new beachfront property
be built on stilts. If your house is destroyed by a hurricane, rebuilding it on stilts will cost an extra
$25,000. The standard homeowners policy excludes costs caused by ordinance or laws regulating the
construction of buildings. Is this fair? Who should pay the extra expense?
3. Jupiter Island, located off the coast of south Florida, is the wealthiest town in the country. Its 620
year-round residents earn an average of just over $200,000 per year, per person. Thus, a typical
household of two adults, two children, a housekeeper, a gardener/chauffeur, and a cook boasts an
annual income of some $1.4 million. What is the reasoning for subsidizing hurricane insurance for
residents of Jupiter Island?
4. In light of your understanding of the uninsurable nature of catastrophes, who should bear the
financial burden of natural disasters?
Sources: Insurance Information Institute at http://www.III.org; Steve Tuckey, “A National Cat Program? Insurers Have Doubts,” National Underwriter
Online News Service, December 5, 2005, accessed March 15, 2009, http://www.propertyandcasualtyinsurancenews.com/cms/NUPC/
Breaking%20News/2005/12/05-CAT-st?searchfor=national%20cat%20program; Mark E. Ruquet, “Towers Perrin: Katrina Loss $55 Billion,” National
Underwriter Online News Service, October 6, 2005, accessed March 15, 2009, http://www.propertyandcasualtyinsurancenews.com/cms/NUPC/
Breaking%20News/2005/10/06-TOWERSP-mr?searchfor =towers%20perrin%20katrina; “Louisiana Hurricane Loss Cancels 25 Years of Premiums,”
CHAPTER 10 PROPERTY RISK MANAGEMENT 211
Valuation Clause
The intent of insurance is to indemnify an insured. Payment on an actual cash value basis is most con-
replacement cost
sistent with the indemnity principle, as discussed in Chapter 8. Yet the deduction of depreciation can
be both severe and misunderstood. In response, property insurers often offer coverage on a replace- Indemnification for a
property loss with no
ment cost new (RCN) basis, which does not deduct depreciation in valuing the loss. Rather, replace-
deduction for depreciation.
ment cost new is the value of the lost or destroyed property if it were bought new or rebuilt on the day
of the loss.
Deductibles
The cost of insurance to cover frequent losses (as experienced by many property exposures) is high. To
alleviate the financial strain of frequent small losses, many insurance policies include a deductible. A
deductible requires the insured to bear some portion of a loss before the insurer is obligated to make
any payment. The purpose of deductibles is to reduce costs for the insurer, thus making lower premi-
ums possible. The insurer saves in three ways. First, the insurer is not responsible for the entire loss. Se-
cond, because most losses are small, the number of claims for loss payment is reduced, thereby redu-
cing the claims processing costs. Third, the moral and morale hazards are lessened because there is
greater incentive to prevent loss when the insured bears part of the burden.[2]
The small, frequent losses associated with property exposures are good candidates for deductibles
because their frequency minimizes risk (the occurrence of a small loss is nearly certain) and their small
magnitude makes retention affordable. The most common forms of deductibles in property insurance
are the following:
1. Straight deductible
2. Franchise deductible
3. Disappearing deductible
A straight deductible requires payment for all losses less than a specified dollar amount. For ex-
straight deductible
ample, if you have a $200 deductible on the collision coverage part of your auto policy, you pay the
total amount of any loss that does not exceed $200. In addition, you pay $200 of every loss in excess of One that requires payment
for all losses less than a
that amount. If you have a loss of $800, therefore, you pay $200 and the insurer pays $600. specified dollar amount.
A franchise deductible is similar to a straight deductible, except that once the amount of loss
equals the deductible, the entire loss is paid in full. This type of deductible is common in ocean marine franchise deductible
cargo insurance, although it is stated as a percentage of the value insured rather than a dollar amount.
One that pays the entire
The franchise deductible is also used in crop hail insurance, which provides that losses less than, for ex-
amount in full once the
ample, 5 percent of the crop are not paid, but when a loss exceeds that percentage, the entire loss is amount of loss equals the
paid. deductible.
The major disadvantage with the franchise deductible from the insurer’s point of view is that the
insured is encouraged to inflate a claim that falls just short of the amount of the deductible. If the
claims adjuster says that your crop loss is 4 percent, you may argue long and hard to get the estimate
up to 5 percent. Because it invites moral hazard, a franchise deductible is appropriate only when the in-
sured is unable to influence or control the amount of loss, such as in ocean marine cargo insurance.
212 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
The disappearing deductible is a modification of the franchise deductible. Instead of having one
disappearing deductible
cut-off point beyond which losses are paid in full, a disappearing deductible is a deductible whose
One whose amount amount decreases as the amount of the loss increases. For example, let’s say that the deductible is $500
decreases as the amount of
the loss increases.
to begin with; as the loss increases, the deductible amount decreases. This is illustrated in Table 10.1.
TABLE 10.1 How the Disappearing Deductible Disappears
Amount of Loss ($) Loss Payment ($) Deductible ($)
500.00 0.00 500.00
1,000.00 555.00 445.00
2,000.00 1,665.00 335.00
4,000.00 3,885.00 115.00
5,000.00 4,955.00 5.00
5,045.00 5,045.00 0.00
6,000.00 6,000.00 0.00
At one time, homeowners policies had a disappearing deductible. Unfortunately, it took only a few
years for insureds to learn enough about its operation to recognize the benefit of inflating claims. As a
result, it was replaced by the straight deductible.
The small, frequent nature of most direct property losses makes deductibles particularly import-
ant. Deductibles help maintain reasonable premiums because they eliminate administrative expenses of
the low-value, common losses. In addition, the nature of property losses causes the cost of property in-
surance per dollar of coverage to decline with the increasing percentage of coverage on the property.
That is, the first 10 percent value of the property insurance is more expensive than the second (and so
on) percent value. The cost of property insurance follows this pattern because most property losses are
small, and so the expected loss does not increase in the same proportion as the increased percentage of
the property value insured.
Coinsurance
A coinsurance clause has two main provisions: first, it requires you to carry an amount of insurance
coinsurance clause
equal to a specified percentage of the value of the property if you wish to be paid the amount of loss
Clause that requires one to you incur in full, and second, it stipulates a proportional payment of loss for failure to carry sufficient
carry an amount of insurance
equal to a specified
insurance. It makes sense that if insurance coverage is less than the value of the property, losses will not
percentage of the value of be paid in full because the premiums charged are for lower values. For property insurance, as long as
property in order to be paid coverage is at least 80 percent of the value of the property, the property is considered fully covered un-
the full amount of loss der the coinsurance provision.
incurred and that stipulates a What happens when you fail to have the amount of insurance of at least 80 percent of the value of
proportional payment of loss your building? Nothing happens until you have a partial loss. At that time, you are subject to a penalty.
for failure to carry sufficient Suppose in January you bought an $80,000 policy for a building with an actual cash value of $100,000,
insurance.
and the policy has an 80 percent coinsurance clause, which requires at least 80 percent of the value to
be covered in order to receive the actual loss. By the time the building suffers a $10,000 loss in Novem-
ber, its actual cash value has increased to $120,000. The coinsurance limit is calculated as follows:
The amount the insurer pays is $8,333.33. Who pays the other $1,666.67? You do. Your penalty for fail-
ing to carry at least 80 percent of the actual value is to bear part of the loss. You will see in Chapter 1
that you should buy coverage for the value of the home and also include an inflation guard endorse-
ment so that the value of coverage will keep up with inflation.
What if you have a total loss at the time the building is worth $120,000, and you have only $80,000
worth of coverage? Applying the coinsurance formula yields the following:
$80,000
$96,000 × $120,000 = $99,999.99
You would not receive $99,999.99, however, because the total amount of insurance is $80,000, which is
the maximum amount the insurer is obligated to pay. When a loss equals or exceeds the amount of in-
surance required by the applicable percentage of coinsurance, the coinsurance penalty is not part of the
calculation because the limit is the amount of coverage. The insurer is not obligated to pay more than
CHAPTER 10 PROPERTY RISK MANAGEMENT 213
the face amount of insurance in any event because a typical policy specifies this amount as its maxim-
um coverage responsibility.
You save money buying a policy with a coinsurance clause because the insurer charges a reduced
premium rate, but you assume a significant obligation. The requirement is applicable to values only at
the time of loss, and the insurer is not responsible for keeping you informed of value changes. That is
your responsibility.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. What is the difference between real and personal property? Why do insurers make a distinction between
them?
2. What is a deductible? Provide illustrative examples of straight, franchise, and disappearing deductibles.
3. What is the purpose of coinsurance? How does the policyholder become a coinsurer? Under what
circumstances does this occur?
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
This chapter, as noted above, introduces areas that are growing in importance in the world of insur-
e-commerce property risk
ance. Almost every home, family, and business has risk exposures because of the use of computers, the
Internet, and the Web; we refer to this as e-commerce property risk. Think about your own courses Business risk exposures due
to of the use of computers,
at the university. Each professor emphasizes his or her communication with you on the Web site for the Internet, and the Web.
the course. You use the Internet as a research tool. Every time you log on, you are exposed to risks from
cyberspace. Most familiar to you is the risk of viruses. But there are many additional risk exposures
from electronic business, both to you as an individual and to businesses. Businesses with a Web pres-
ence are those that offer professional services online and/or online purchasing. Some businesses are
business to consumer (BTC); others are business to business (BTB).
Regardless of the nature of the use of the Internet, cyber attacks have become more frequent and
have resulted in large financial losses. According to the 2002 Computer Security Institute/Federal Bur-
eau of Investigation (CSI/FBI) Computer Crime and Security Survey, Internet-related losses increased
from $100 million in 1997 to $456 million in 2002.[3] The 6th Annual CyberSource fraud survey indic-
ated a $700 million increase (37 percent) in lost revenue in 2004, from an estimated $2.6 billion in
2003. Small and medium businesses were hit the hardest. These losses are in line with fast revenue
growth from e-commerce.[4]
Businesses today are becoming aware of their e-commerce risk exposures. In every forum of in-
surers’ meetings and in every insurance media, e-risk exposure is discussed as one of the major “less
214 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
understood” risk exposures.[5] In this chapter, we discuss the hazards and perils of e-commerce risk ex-
posure to the business itself as the first party. In Chapter 11, we will discuss the liability side of the risk
exposure of businesses due to the Internet and online connections. Next, we discuss the hazards and
perils of electronic business in general.
Internet sales between states partly because the government has not yet determined how states should
apportion the tax revenue. As the volume of online purchases increases, so do the consequences of lost
sales tax revenue from e-commerce.
Lack of qualified lawyers to handle cases that arise out of e-commerce disputes is another new risk.
There are many areas of e-law that lawyers are not yet specialized in. Not only are laws complex and te-
dious, they are also changing rapidly. As a result, it is difficult for lawyers to stay abreast of each law
that governs and regulates cyberspace.
Trademarks Infringements
Domain name disputes are a serious concern for many businesses. In most cases, disputes over the
domain name hijacking
rights to a domain name result from two specific events. Domain name hijacking occurs when an
individual or a business reserves a domain name that uses the trademark of a competitor. The other When an individual or a
business reserves a domain
event arises when a business or an individual reserves the well-recognized name or trademark of an un- name that uses the
related company as a domain name with the intent of selling the domain name to the trademark hold- trademark of a competitor.
er. Seeking compensation for the use of a registered domain name from the rightful trademark holder
is known as cybersquatting.[8] cybersquatting
A recent case involving cybersquatting is People for the Ethical Treatment of Animals v. Doughney. Seeking compensation for
In August 2001, the Fourth Circuit Court of Appeals held that the defendant, Michael Doughney, was the use of a registered
guilty of service mark infringement and unfair competition, and had violated the Anti-Cybersquatting domain name from the
rightful trademark holder.
Consumer Protection Act (ACPA). Doughney had created a Web site at http://www.peta.org, which
contained the registered service mark PETA. People for the Ethical Treatment of Animals (PETA) is an
animal rights organization that opposes the exploitation of animals for food, clothing, entertainment,
and vivisection. When users typed in http://www.peta.org, they expected to arrive at the site for People
for the Ethical Treatment of Animals. Instead, they surprisingly arrived at People Eating Tasty Anim-
als, a “resource for those who enjoy eating meat, wearing fur and leather, hunting, and the fruits of sci-
entific research.” The site contained links to a number of organizations that held views generally op-
posing those of PETA.[9] On two occasions, Doughney suggested that if PETA wanted one of his do-
mains, or objected to his registration, it could “make me an offer” or “negotiate a settlement.”
Web site hijacking occurs when a Web site operator knowingly deceives the user by redirecting Web site hijacking
the user to a site the user did not intend to view. A recent case, Ford Motor Company v. 2600 Enter-
When a Web site operator
prises et al., caught attention in December 2001 when 2600 Enterprises automatically redirected users knowingly deceives the user
from a Web site they operate at a domain name directing profanity at General Motors to the Web site by redirecting the user to a
operated by Ford at http://www.ford.com. The defendants redirected users by programming an embed- site the user did not intend to
ded link, which utilized Ford’s mark, into the code of the defendants’ Web site.[10] Domain-name view.
hijacking, cybersquatting, and Web site hijacking for the sake of parody or satire is protected by the
First Amendment, but sometimes the pranksters’ only purpose is to harass or extract profit from the
trademark owner.[11]
Businesses today buy electronic security systems and develop many steps to reduce the risk of data and
hardware losses. Firms conduct regular system audits to test for breaches in network security. Auditors
attempt to break into various components of the company computer system, including the operating
systems, networks, databases, servers, Web servers, and business processes in general, to simulate at-
tacks and discover weaknesses.[13] Managed security services provide an option for virus protection.
They include both antivirus protection and firewall installation.
encryption
Regular system backup processes and off-site systems saved many businesses hurt by the Septem-
ber 11 attacks. One advantage of keeping backup data files off-site is having clean data in case of dam-
Allows the sender of an
age in the original files from viruses, hackers, and crackers. Because security may be breached from
e-mail to scramble the
contents of the document.
people within the company, Internet access is generally available only to authorized internal and ex-
ternal users via the use of passwords. E-mails are easy to intercept and read as they travel across the In-
ternet. Attaching a digital signature allows the recipient to discern whether the document has been
altered.[14] Another method to protect e-mails is encryption. Encryption allows the sender of an e-
mail to scramble the contents of the document. Before the recipient can read the message, he or she
needs to use a password for a private key. Encryption is used for confidential communications.
firewall
A firewall is another loss-control solution that protects the local area network (LAN) or corporate
network from unauthorized access. A firewall protects a network from intrusion by preventing access
Device that protects a
network from intrusion by
unless certain criteria are met. Another loss-control technique is the virtual private network, which
preventing access unless connects satellite offices with a central location. A virtual private network (VPN) allows remote
certain criteria are met. users to gain secure access to a corporate network. VPNs provide endless opportunities for telecom-
muters, business travelers, and multiple independent offices of a bigger company.
virtual private network
(VPN)
E-Commerce Property Insurance
Network that connects
satellite offices with a central According to the 2004 CSI/FBI Computer Crime and Security Survey described above, only 28 percent
location and allows remote of 320 respondents had any external insurance policies to help manage cyber security risks. Traditional
users to gain secure access to
property insurance covers physical damage to tangible property due to an insured peril. Electronic data
a corporate network.
can be considered property in most instances, but standard commercial insurance policies, discussed in
Chapter 1, contain exclusions that “explicitly invalidate coverage for exposures in relation to the use of
technology.”[15] Some insurers now offer customized e-commerce insurance policies that expand the
areas of coverage available for e-commerce property risk. ISO has an e-commerce endorsement that
modifies insurance provided under commercial property coverage. Under this endorsement,
insurers will pay for the cost to replace or restore electronic data which has suffered loss or damage
by a Covered Cause of Loss…including the cost of data entry, re-programming and computer
consultation services.
The endorsement has four sections. Section I describes the electronic data coverage. Section II
defines the period of coverage as well as the coverage of business income, extra expenses, and resump-
tion of e-commerce activity. Section III classifies covered and excluded perils; exclusions include mech-
anical breakdown; downtime due to viruses, unless the computer is equipped with antivirus software;
errors or omissions in programming or data processing; errors in design, maintenance, or repair; dam-
age to one computer on the network caused by repair or modification of any other computer on the
network; interruption as a result of insufficient capacity; and unexplained failure. Section IV of the en-
dorsement is for other provisions, explained in Chapter 9.
In addition to this endorsement, a few insurers have created a variety of e-commerce policies.
Some of the companies include ACE USA, Chubb, AIG, the Fidelity and Deposit Companies (members
of Zurich Financial Services Group), Gulf Insurance Group, Legion Indemnity Company, and Lloyd’s
of London. This list is by no means inclusive.[16] These companies provide not only first-party e-com-
merce property and business interruption coverage, but also liability coverage for third-party liability
risks. The liability coverage will be discussed in Chapter 11. Because e-commerce does not see geo-
graphical boundaries, many policies provide worldwide e-commerce coverage.
CHAPTER 10 PROPERTY RISK MANAGEMENT 217
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
In this section you studied the emerging exposure of e-commerce property risk:
< E-commerce property risks fall under five categories: hardware and software thefts, technological changes,
regulatory and legal changes, trademark infringements, and Internet-based telephony crimes
< Cyber attacks have become more frequent and more costly in the financial losses they cause
< Hackers, crackers, insiders, and viruses are major causes of hardware and software theft and data losses
< Technological advancements cause downtime while employees learn how to use new systems and
components
< Frequent additions to and changes in existing e-commerce laws creates compliance risks and lack of
qualified lawyers to handle disputes.
< Domain name hijacking, cybersquatting, and Web site hijacking are all ways of infringing legitimate
companies’ trademarks
< Voice-over-Internet protocol (VoIP) has inherent vulnerabilities due to the absence of effective security
measures
< Loss-control steps that can reduce e-commerce property risks include security products, system audits,
backup systems, and data protection
< While electronic data is considered property, it is typically excluded from standard commercial insurance
policies, thus leading to the rise of customized e-commerce policies and endorsements
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
As with the Internet, global exposure is rapidly growing for many companies. This forces management
global risk
to think about the unique problems that arise when companies cross national borders, also known as
global risk. Political Risk Services (http://www.prsonline.com/), an organization that ranks countries The unique problems that
arise when companies cross
for their instability, attaches a major cost to each country. This highlights the importance of under- national borders.
standing the countries that businesses decide to enter. In a survey conducted by the insurance broker
Aon[17] of Fortune 1,000 companies in the United States, 26 percent of the respondents felt comfortable
with their political risk exposure and 29 percent felt comfortable with their global financial or econom-
ic risk exposure. While most respondents felt comfortable with their property/casualty coverages, only
a small percentage felt comfortable with their political risk protection. The survey was conducted dur-
ing May 2001, before the September 11 attack. In 2005, Aon provided a map of the political and eco-
nomic risk around the world. The climate around the world has changed with the war in Iraq, a part of
the world surrounded by major economic and political hot spots.
Political risk can be defined as unanticipated political events that disrupt the earning or profit- political risk
making ability of an enterprise. In “The Risk Report: Managing Political Risks,” insurance expert Kevin
Unanticipated political events
M. Quinley describes some of the perils that can affect a global organization: nationalization, privatiza- that disrupt the earning or
tion, expropriation (property taken away by the host nation according to its laws), civil unrest, revolu- profit-making ability of an
tion, foreign exchange restrictions, labor regulations, kidnapping, terrorism, seizure, and forfeiture. enterprise.
218 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
Some of the risks are considered political risks, others are economic risks. Table 10.2 explains some of
these risks. In summary, the main categories of global risk exposure are as follows:
< Destabilized international political environment
< Heightened terrorism risk
< Legal risk due to changes in local laws
< Lack-of-data risk
< Currency inconvertibility risk
< Cultural barriers risks
According to the Risk Report, the nature of the risks has changed. Twenty years ago, the major risk was
in the area of nationalization of capital assets, while the perils of today are more related to economic in-
tegration and the power of international financial markets. Experts agree that political risk looms larger
after September 11, the war in Iraq, and the instability in the Middle East. Following the September 11
attack, Marsh and all large brokerage firms began providing political risk assessment services to clients
worldwide.[18] The consulting includes formulating and reviewing crisis management plans for events
such as natural disasters, product recalls, and terrorism. The plans are comprehensive, and they are in-
tegrated throughout the enterprise.
TABLE 10.2 Ten Ways to Tune Up Management of Political Risks
1. Look closely at foreign operations—current or planned—and identify all possible political risks.
2. Examine the locale of each foreign operation and stratify them along a risk continuum, according to
susceptibility of political risks.
3. Explore “public” political risk insurance coverage through facilities such as MIGA and OPIC.
4. Allow plenty of lead time for procuring insurance for political risk coverage.
5. Seek multiyear policies or coverage for as long a time frame as possible. Keep tightlipped about the
existence of any political risk coverage you obtain.
6. Engage an insurance broker who is specialized in procuring political risk coverage.
7. Invest in infrastructure in host countries and cultivate a strong track record of being a good corporate
citizen.
8. Fine-tune security and anti-hijacking procedures to address the potential loss from kidnapping, ransom,
extortion, or terrorism.
9. Make sure that retention of any political risks is accompanied by realistic funding mechanisms.
10. Strive to bring the same thoroughness to political risk management as the organization brings to more
mainstream risks such as fire, flood, earthquake, and workers’ compensation.
Reproduced with permission of the publisher, International Risk Management Institute, Inc., Dallas, Texas, from the Risk Report, copyright
International Risk Management Institute, Inc., author Kevin Quinley CPCU, ARM. Further reproduction prohibited. For subscription information,
phone 800-827-4242. Visit http://www.IRMI.com for practical and reliable risk and insurance information.
Nonadmitted coverage involves contracts issued by a company not authorized to write insur- nonadmitted coverage
ance in the country where a risk exposure is located. Admitted insurance is written by companies
Contracts issued by a
authorized to write insurance in the country where a risk exposure is located. Nonadmitted contracts
company not authorized to
have advantages to some U.S. policyholders: they are written in English; use U.S. dollars for premiums write insurance in the country
and claims, thus avoiding exchange rate risk; utilize terms and conditions familiar to U.S. risk man- where a risk exposure is
agers; and provide flexibility in underwriting. However, such contracts may be illegal in some coun- located.
tries, and the local subsidiary may be subject to penalties if the contracts’ existence becomes known.
admitted insurance
Further, premium payment may not be tax deductible, even in countries where nonadmitted coverage
is permitted. If nonadmitted insurance is purchased where it is prohibited, claim payments must be Contracts written by
made to the parent corporation, which then has to find a way to transfer the funds to the local companies authorized to
write insurance in the country
subsidiary.
where a risk exposure is
Coverage is also affected by the codification of the legal system in the other countries. The Napo- located.
leonic code, for example, is used in France, Belgium, Egypt, Greece, Italy, Spain, and several other
countries. Under this legal system, liability for negligence is not treated in the same way as liability is
treated under the United States system of common law; any negligence not specifically mentioned in
the code is dismissed. The common law system is based on legal precedence, and the judges play a
much more significant role.
Labor laws reflect another interesting cultural difference. In some countries, it is common to em-
ploy very young children—an act that is against the law in the United States. The families in these
countries depend heavily on the income of their children. But an American business in such a country
may be faced with an ethical dilemma: should it employ children or adhere to U.S. practices and labor
laws?[19] Islamic finance is very different from finance in the Western world; for example, in Islam, in-
terest payments are not permitted. With the expanded involvement of many businesses in the Middle
East and Islamic countries, many academics, as well as businesspeople, are learning about the special
ways to conduct business there.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
In this section you studied global risk exposures that arise from the increasingly international nature of busi-
ness operations:
< Political risk results from unanticipated governmental destabilization that disrupts an enterprise’s profit-
making ability
< Legal attitudes with respect to insurance can be very different in other parts of the world, leading many
international companies to turn to nonadmitted coverage
< International data-gathering may be limited, suspect, or inconsistent with domestic techniques, so internal
collection efforts and collaboration among businesses is often required
< Volatile currencies can create unfavorable exchange rates
< Cultural differences, especially as reflected in labor laws, pose ethical dilemmas for companies with
opposing views in conducting business
< Public insurance policies available through groups like the Overseas Private Investment Corporation (OPIC)
and the Multilateral Investment Guarantee Corporation (MIGA) provide options for mitigating global risks
such as expropriation, confiscation, war risks, civil strife, and currency inconvertibility
< Private insurers have increased political risk insurance offerings such as coverage for kidnap, ransom, and
export license cancellation in response to greater demand
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. What is different about international property exposures compared with U.S. property exposures?
2. Why might an American company operating in a foreign country choose to purchase nonadmitted
coverage?
3. Describe the steps of political risk management.
11. Monte Enbysk, “Hackers and Vandals and Worms, Oh My!” Microsoft bCentral news-
ENDNOTES letter, http://www.bcentral.com.
12. Simon London, “Government Warns Users on Risks of Internet-Based Telephony:
Voip Is Growing in Popularity as the Technology Proliferates, but Inherent in the Ser-
vice, Warns the Government, Is Increased Security and Privacy Flaws,” Financial Times,
1. For more information, read the article “Standard Fire Policy Dates Back to 19th Cen- February 6, 2005, http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/
tury,” featured in Best’s Review, April 2002. 5fca499c-7554-11d9-9608-00000e2511c8.html (accessed March 15, 2009).
2. For example, residents of a housing development had full coverage for windstorm
13. Kevin Coleman, “How E-Tailers and Online Shoppers Can Protect Themselves,” KPMG.
losses (that is, no deductible). Their storm doors did not latch properly, so wind dam-
age to such doors was common. The insurer paid an average of $100 for each loss. 14. George S. Sutcliffe, Esq., E-Commerce and Insurance Risk Management (Boston: Stand-
After doing so for about six months, it added a $50 deductible to the policies as they ard Publishing Corp., 2001), 13.
were renewed. Storm door losses declined markedly when insureds were required to
pay for the first $50 of each loss. 15. “New Policy Offered to Cover Tech Risks,” National Underwriter Online News Service,
July 2, 2002; Stand Alone E-Commerce Market Survey, by IRMI at
3. Richard Power, “Computer Security Issues & Trends,” Vol. VIII, Mo I. The survey was http://www.irmi.com/Expert/Articles/2001/Popups/Rossi02-1.aspx.
conducted by the Computer Security Institute (CSI) with the participation of the San
Francisco Federal Bureau of Investigation’s Computer Intrusion Squad. Established in 16. George S. Sutcliffe, Esq., E-Commerce and Insurance Risk Management (Boston: Stand-
1974, CSI has thousands of members worldwide and provides a wide variety of in- ard Publishing Corp., 2001), 13.
formation and education programs to assist in protecting the information assets of
corporations and governmental organizations. For more information, go to 17. Mark E. Ruquet, “Big Firms Worry About Coverage for Political Risks Abroad,” National
http://www.gocsi.com. Underwriter Online News Service, August 9, 2001. The Aon survey asked 122 risk man-
agers, chief financial officers, and others in similar positions of responsibility to assess
4. The 6th Annual CyberSource Fraud Survey was sponsored by CyberSource Corpora- various aspects of their overseas risks. The surveys were done by telephone and in
tion and undertaken by Mindwave Research. The survey was fielded September 17 some cases over the Internet.
through October 1, 2004, and yielded 348 qualified and complete responses (versus
333 the year before). The sample was drawn from a database of companies involved 18. “Marsh to Begin Crisis Consulting Led by Anti-Terror Expert,” National Underwriter On-
in electronic commerce activities. Copies of the survey are available by visiting line News Service, October 12, 2001; see Aon services at http://www.aon.com/
http://www.cybersource.com/fraudreport/. risk_management/political_risk.jsp; see Willis services at http://www.willis.com/
Services/Political%20Risk.aspx.
5. For example, see Lee McDonald,” Insurer Points out Risks of E-Commerce,” Best’s
19. Etti G. Baranoff and Phyllis S. Myers, “Ethics in Insurance,” Academy of Insurance Edu-
Review, February 2000; Ron Lent, “Electronic Risk Gives Insurers Pause,” National
Underwriter, Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edition, May 7, 2001; cation, Washington, D.C., instructional video with supplemental study guide (video
Caroline Saucer, “Technological Advances: Web Site Design Provides Clues to Under- produced by the Center for Video Education, 1997.)
writing Online Risks,” Best’s Review, December 2000. 20. Daniel Hays, “Insurer Finds Good Market in Political Risk,” National Underwriter Online
News Service, November 28, 2001.
6. George S. Sutcliffe, Esq., E-Commerce and Insurance Risk Management (Boston: Stand-
ard Publishing Corp., 2001), 13. 21. “Zurich North America Expands Political Risk Insurance to Asian Market,” National
Underwriter Online News Service, April 6, 2002; John Jennings, “Political Risk Cover De-
7. Adapted from the online glossary of Symantec, a worldwide provider of Internet se-
mand Surges: Insurers,” National Underwriter, Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits
curity solutions, at http://www.symantec.com/avcenter/refa.html.
Management Edition, April 27, 1998.
8. George S. Sutcliffe, Esq., E-Commerce and Insurance Risk Management (Boston: Stand-
22. “Armed-Conflict Risks Covered,” National Underwriter, Property & Casualty/Risk &
ard Publishing Corp., 2001), 13.
Benefits Management Edition, June 11, 2001. Many Internet sites deal with global risk.
9. People for the Ethical Treatment of Animals v. Doughney, No. 00-1918 (4th Cir2001); For example, Global Risk International at http://www.globalrisk.uk.com/ offers coun-
http://www.phillipsnizer.com/internetlib.htm. terterrorist training, kidnap and ransom management, close protection, and
surveillance.
10. Ford Motor Company v. 2600 Enterprises et al., 177 F. Supp. 2d 661, 2001, U.S. District
Court Lexis 21302 (E.D. Michigan2001); http://www.phillipsnizer.com/
int-trademark.htm.
CHAP TER 11
The Liability Risk
Management
As noted in Chapter 10, liability risk is the risk that we may hurt a third party and will be sued for bodily injury or
other damages. Most of us have heard about auto liability; pollution liability; product liability; medical malpractice;
and the professional liability of lawyers, accountants, company directors and officers, and more. In the early 2000s,
the United States was mired in the accounting scandals of Enron and WorldCom. In the mid-2000s, AIG added its
name to the list of lawsuits and criminal allegations with accounting improprieties that padded company results.
Shareholders and participants in the 401(k) plans of these companies filed lawsuits, some of which were class-
action suits. In February 2005, President Bush signed a bill to redirect class-action lawsuits in excess of $5 million
and with geographically dispersed plaintiffs from state courts to federal courts.[1] Cases of this type are expected to
continue to emerge. In 2008, the credit crisis began and the allegations of misconduct and negligence by directors
While liability insurance is for unintentional actions, the fear of having to pay liability claims because of the
errors and omissions of accountants and the directors and officers of companies have caused insurance rates in
these types of coverage to jump dramatically. The relationships between behavior and coverage will be strongly
1. Links
1. LINKS
As discussed in the Links section in Chapter 10, liability coverage is coverage for a third party that may
suffer a loss because of your actions. It also covers you in case you are hurt or your property is damaged
because of someone else’s actions, such as the actions of the accountants and executives of Enron,
WorldCom, and AIG. The harmed parties are investors and the employees of these companies who lost
all or part of their investments or pensions. In personal lines coverage, such as homeowners and auto
policies, the liability of property damage or bodily injury you may inflict on others is covered up to a
limit. In commercial lines, you may use a packaged multilines policy that also includes liability cover-
age. In this chapter, we focus only on the liability sections of these policies.
As part of your holistic risk management program, you now realize that you need a myriad of
policies to cover all your liability exposures. In many cases, both the property and liability are in the
same policies, but what liability coverage is actually included in each policy? As we delve further into
insurance policies, we find many types of liability coverage. As you will see in this chapter, businesses
have a vast number of liabilities: product, errors and omissions, professional, directors and officers, e-
commerce, medical, employment, employee benefits, and more. The aftermath of September 11, 2001,
revealed additional liabilities from terrorism. Liability risk exposure is scary for any individual or busi-
ness, especially in such a litigious society as the United States. Nonetheless, it is important to have the
224 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
recourse when someone has been wronged, for example, during the scandals of accounting irregularit-
ies and management fraud.
To better understand the complete holistic risk management process, it is imperative for us to un-
derstand all sections of the liability coverages in all the policies we hold. Figure 11.1 shows the connec-
tion among the types of coverage and the complete puzzle of risk. At this point we are drilling down in-
to a massive type of risk exposure, which is covered by a myriad of policies. Our ability to connect
them all allows us to complete the picture of our holistic risk.
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
Legal liability is the responsibility, based in law, to right some wrong done to another person or or- legal liability
ganization. Several aspects of this definition deserve further discussion. One involves the remedy of li-
The responsibility, based in
ability. A remedy is compensation for a person who has been harmed in some way. A person who has
law, to right some wrong
been wronged or harmed may ask the court to remedy or compensate him or her for the harm. Usually, done to another person or
this will involve monetary compensation, but it could also involve some behavior on the part of the organization.
person who committed the wrong, or the tortfeasor. For example, someone whose water supply has
been contaminated by a polluting business may request an injunction against the business to force the remedy
cessation of pollution. A developer who is constructing a building in violation of code may be required Compensation for a person
to halt construction based on a liability lawsuit. who has been harmed in
some way.
When monetary compensation is sought, it can take one of several forms. Special damages (or
economic damages) compensate for those harms that generally are easily quantifiable into dollar meas- tortfeasor
ures. These include medical expenses, lost income, and repair costs of damaged property. Those harms A person who commits a
that are not specifically quantifiable but that require compensation all the same are called general wrong.
damages (or noneconomic damages). Examples of noneconomic or general damages include pain
and suffering, mental anguish, and loss of consortium (companionship). The third type of monetary li- special damages (economic
ability award is punitive damages, which was discussed in "Are Punitive Damages out of Control?" in damages)
Chapter 9. In this chapter, we will continue to discuss the controversy surrounding the use of punitive Compensation for harms that
damages. Punitive damages are considered awards intended to punish an offender for exceptionally generally are easily
undesirable behavior. Punitive damages are intended not to compensate for actual harm incurred but quantifiable into dollar
measures.
rather to punish.
A second important aspect of the definition of liability is that it is based in law. In this way, liability general damages
differs from other exposures because it is purely a creation of societal rules (laws), which reflect social Compensation for harms that
norms. As a result, liability exposures differ across societies (nations) over time. In the United States, li- are not specifically
ability is determined by the courts and by laws enacted by legislatures. quantifiable but that require
The risk of liability is twofold. Not only may you become liable to someone else and suffer loss, but compensation all the same.
someone else may become liable to you and have to pay you. You need to know about both sides of the noneconomic damages
coin, so to speak. Your financial well-being or that of your organization can be adversely affected by
Compensation for harms that
your responsibility to others or by your failure to understand their responsibility to you. If you are the are not specifically
party harmed, you would be the plaintiff in litigation. The party being sued in litigation is the defend- quantifiable but that require
ant. In some circumstances the parties will be both plaintiffs and defendants. compensation all the same.
punitive damages
Awards intended to punish
an offender for exceptionally
undesirable behavior.
plaintiff
The party harmed in
litigation.
defendant
The party being sued in
litigation.
226 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
As illustrated in Figure 11.2, the field of law includes criminal law and civil law. Criminal law is con-
criminal law
cerned with acts that are contrary to public policy (crimes), such as murder or burglary. Civil law, in
Law concerned with acts that
contrast, deals with acts that are not against society as a whole, but rather cause injury or loss to an in-
are contrary to public policy
(crimes), such as murder or dividual or organization, such as carelessly running a car into the side of a building. A civil wrong may
burglary. also be a crime. Murder, for instance, attacks both society and individuals. Civil law has two branches:
one concerned with the law of contracts and the other with the law of torts (explained in the next para-
civil law graph). Civil liability may stem from either contracts or torts.
Law that deals with acts that
are not against society as a
whole but rather cause injury
or loss to an individual or
organization.
CHAPTER 11 THE LIABILITY RISK MANAGEMENT 227
Contractual liability occurs when the terms of a contract are not carried out as promised by contractual liability
either party to the contract. When you sign a rental agreement for tools, for example, the agreement
may provide that the tools will be returned to the owner in good condition, ordinary wear and tear ex- When the terms of a contract
are not carried out as
cepted. If they are stolen or damaged, you are liable for the loss. As another example, if you offer your promised by either party to
car for sale and assure the buyer that it is in perfect condition, you have made a warranty. A warranty the contract.
is a guarantee that property or service sold is of the condition represented by the seller. If the car is not
in perfect condition, you may be liable for damages because of a breach of warranty. This is why some warranty
sellers offer goods for sale on an “as is” basis; they want to be sure there is no warranty. A guarantee that property or
service sold is of the
A tort is “a private or civil wrong or injury, other than breach of contract, for which the court will
condition represented by the
provide a remedy in the form of an action for damages.”[2] That is, all civil wrongs, except breach of seller.
contract, are torts. A tort may be intentional if it is committed for the purpose of injuring another per-
son or the person’s property, or it may be unintentional. Examples of intentional torts include libel, tort
slander, assault, and battery, as you will see in the contracts provided as appendixes at the end of this
book. While a risk manager may have occasion to be concerned about liability arising from intentional A private or civil wrong or
injury, other than breach of
torts, the more frequent source of liability is the unintentional tort. By definition, unintentional torts contract, for which the court
involve negligence. will provide a remedy in the
If someone suffers bodily injury or property damage as a result of your negligence, you may be li- form of an action for
able for damages. Negligence refers to conduct or behavior. It may be a matter of doing something you damages.
should not do, or failing to do something you should do. Negligence can be defined as a failure to act
reasonably, and that failure to act causes harm to others. It is determined by proving the existence of negligence
four elements (sometimes people use three, combining the last two into one). These four elements are Failure to act reasonably,
the following: where such failure to act
causes harm to others.
< A duty to act (or not to act) in some way
< Breach of that duty proximate cause
< Damage or injury to the one owed the duty A causal connection.
< A causal connection, called a proximate cause, between the breach of a duty and the injury
An example may be helpful. When a person operates an automobile, that person has a duty to obey
traffic rules and to drive appropriately for the given conditions. A person who drives while drunk,
passes in a no passing zone, or drives too fast on an icy road (even if within set speed limits) has
breached the duty to drive safely. If that person completes the journey without an incident, no negli-
gence exists because no harm occurred. If, however, the driver causes an accident in which property
damage or bodily injury results, all elements of negligence exist, and legal liability for the resulting
harm likely will be placed on the driver.
A difficult aspect of proving negligence is showing that a breach of duty has occurred. Proof re-
quires showing that a reasonable and prudent person would have acted otherwise. Courts use a variety
of methods to assess reasonableness. One is a cost-benefit approach, which holds behavior to be un-
reasonable if the discounted value of the harm is more than the cost to avoid the harm[3] —that is, if the
present value of the possible loss is greater than the expense required to avoid the loss. In this way,
courts use an efficiency argument to determine the appropriateness of behavior.
A second difficult aspect of proving negligence is to show a proximate cause between the breach of
duty and resulting harm. Proximate cause has been referred to as an unbroken chain of events between
the behavior and harm. The intent is to find the relevant cause through assessing liability. The law is
written to encourage behavior with consideration of its consequences.
Liability will not be found in all the circumstances just described. The defendant has available a
number of defenses, and the burden of proof may be modified under certain situations.
Defenses
A number of defenses against negligence exist, with varying degrees of acceptance. A list of defenses is
assumption of risk
shown in Table 11.1. One is assumption of risk. The doctrine of assumption of risk holds that if the
plaintiff knew of the dangers involved in the act that resulted in harm but chose to act in that fashion Doctrine that holds that if the
plaintiff knew of the dangers
nonetheless, the defendant will not be held liable. An example would be a bungee cord jumper who is involved in the act that
injured from the jump. One could argue that a reasonable person would know that such a jump is very resulted in harm, but chose
dangerous. If applicable, the assumption of risk defense bars the plaintiff from a successful negligence to act in that fashion
suit. The doctrine was particularly important in the nineteenth century for lawsuits involving work- nonetheless, the defendant
place injuries, where employers would defend against liability by claiming that workers knew of job will not be held liable.
dangers. With workers’ compensation statutes in place today, the use of assumption of risk in this way
is of little importance, as you will see in Chapter 1. Many states have also abolished the assumption of
risk doctrine in automobile liability cases, disallowing the defense that a passenger assumed the risk of
loss if the driver was known to be dangerous or the car unsafe.
228 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
A second defense found in just a few states is the doctrine of contributory negligence, which disal-
contributory negligence
lows any recovery by the plaintiff if the plaintiff is shown to be negligent to any degree in not avoiding
Situation that disallows any the relevant harm. Thus, the motorist who was only slightly at fault in causing an accident may recover
recovery by the plaintiff if the
plaintiff is shown to be
nothing from the motorist who was primarily at fault. In practice, a judge or jury is unlikely to find a
negligent to any degree in plaintiff slightly at fault where contributory negligence applies. Theoretically, however, the outcome is
not avoiding the relevant possible.
harm. The trend today is a shift away from the use of contributory negligence. Instead, most states follow
the doctrine of comparative negligence. In comparative negligence, the court compares the relative
comparative negligence negligence of the parties and apportions recovery on that basis. At least two applications of the com-
Situation in which the court parative negligence rule may be administered by the courts. Assume that, in the automobile example,
compares the relative both motorists experienced damages of $100,000, and that one motorist was 1 percent at fault, the oth-
negligence of the parties and er 99 percent at fault. Under the partial comparative negligence rule, only the individual less than
apportions recovery on that 50 percent at fault in causing harm receives compensation. The compensation equals the damages mul-
basis.
tiplied by the percentage not at fault, or $99,000 ($100,000 × .99) in our example. Under the complete
partial comparative comparative negligence rule, damages are shared by both parties in relation to their levels of re-
negligence sponsibility for fault. The motorist who was 1 percent at fault still receives $99,000, but must pay the
Rule under which only the other motorist $1,000 ($100,000 × .01), resulting in a net compensation of $98,000. Because few in-
individual less than 50 stances exist when a party is completely free of negligence, and because society appears to prefer that
percent at fault in causing injured parties be compensated, comparative negligence has won favor over contributory negligence.
harm receives compensation. An important question, though, is how the relative degrees of fault are determined. Generally, a jury is
complete comparative asked to make such an estimate based on the testimony of various experts. Examples of the application
negligence of contributory and comparative negligence are shown in Table 11.2.
Rule under which both
parties share damage in TABLE 11.2 Contributory and Comparative Negligence
relation to their levels of Assume that two drivers are involved in an automobile accident. Their respective losses and degrees of fault are
responsibility for fault. as follows:
Losses ($) Degree of Fault
Dan 16,000 .60
Kim 22,000 .40
Last clear chance is a further defense to liability. Under the last clear chance doctrine, a plaintiff who
last clear chance
assumed the risk or contributed to an accident through negligence is not barred from recovery if the
Doctrine under which a defendant had the opportunity to avoid the accident but failed to do so. For instance, the motorist who
plaintiff who assumed the risk
or contributed to an accident
could have avoided hitting a jaywalker but did not had the last clear chance to prevent the accident.
through negligence is not The driver in this circumstance could not limit liability by claiming negligence on the part of the
barred from recovery if the plaintiff. Today, the doctrine has only minor application. It may be used, however, when the defendant
defendant had the employs the defense of contributory negligence against the plaintiff.
opportunity to avoid the
accident but failed to do so.
CHAPTER 11 THE LIABILITY RISK MANAGEMENT 229
Last in this list of defenses is immunity. Where immunity applies, the defendant has a complete
immunity
defense against liability merely because of status as a protected entity, professional, or other party. For
example, governmental entities in the United States were long protected under the doctrine of sover- A complete defense against
liability because of status as a
eign immunity. Sovereign immunity held that governments could do no wrong and therefore could not protected entity, professional,
be held liable. That doctrine has lost strength in most states, but it still exists to some degree in certain or other party.
circumstances. Other immunities extend to charitable organizations and family members. Like sover-
eign immunity, these too have lost most of their shield against liability.
Modifications
Doctrines of defense are used to prevent a successful negligence (and sometimes strict liability) lawsuit.
Other legal doctrines modify the law to assist the plaintiff in a lawsuit. Some of these are discussed here
and are listed in Table 11.3.
TABLE 11.3 Modifications of Negligence
Rules of negligence hold that an injured person has the burden of proof; that is, he or she must prove
res ipsa loquitur (“The
the defendant’s negligence in order to receive compensation. Courts adhere to these rules unless reas- thing speaks for itself”)
ons exist to modify them. In some situations, for example, the plaintiff cannot possibly prove negli-
Doctrine that shifts the
gence. The court may then apply the doctrine of res ipsa loquitur (“the thing speaks for itself”),
burden of proof to the
which shifts the burden of proof to the defendant. The defendant must prove innocence. The doctrine defendant.
may be used upon proof that the situation causing injury was in the defendant’s exclusive control, and
that the accident was one that ordinarily would not happen in the absence of negligence. Thus, the
event “speaks for itself.”
Illustrations of appropriate uses of res ipsa loquitur may be taken from medical or dental treat-
ment. Consider the plaintiff who visited a dentist for the extraction of wisdom teeth and was given a
general anesthetic for the operation. Any negligence that may have occurred during the extraction
could not be proved by the plaintiff, who could not possibly have observed the negligent act. If, upon
waking, the plaintiff has a broken jaw, res ipsa loquitur might be employed.
Doctrines with similar purposes to res ipsa loquitur may be available when a particular defendant
cannot be identified. Someone may be able to prove by a preponderance of evidence, for example, that
a certain drug caused an adverse reaction, but that person may be unable to prove which company
manufactured the particular bottle consumed. Courts may shift the burden of proof to the defendants
in such a circumstance.[4]
Liability may also be strict (or, less often, absolute) rather than based on negligence. That is, if you strict liability
have property or engage in an activity that is considered ultra-dangerous to others, you may become li-
Liability without regard to
able on the basis of strict liability without regard to fault. In some states, for example, the law holds fault.
owners or operators of aircraft liable with respect to damage caused to persons or property on the
ground, regardless of the reasonableness of the owner’s or operator’s actions. Similarly, if you dam a
creek on your property to build a lake, you will be liable in most situations for injury or damage caused
if the dam collapses and floods the area below. In product liability, discussed later in this chapter, a
manufacturer may be liable for harm caused by use of its product, even if the manufacturer was reason-
able in producing it. Thus, the manufacturer is strictly liable.
In some jurisdictions, the owner of a dangerous animal is liable by statute for any harm or damage
caused by the animal. Such liability is a matter of law. If you own a pet lion, you may become liable for
damages regardless of how careful you are. Similarly, the responsibility your employer has in the event
you are injured or contract an occupational disease is based on the principle of liability without fault.[5]
Both situations involve strict liability.
In addition, liability may be vicarious. That is, the vicarious liability of one person may be based vicarious liability
on the tort of another, particularly in an agency relationship. An employer, for example, may be liable
Situation in which the liability
for damages caused by the negligence of an employee who is on duty. Such an agency relationship may of one person may be based
result in vicarious liability for the principal (employer) if the agent (employee) commits a tort while on the tort of another.
acting as an agent. The principal need not be negligent to be liable under vicarious liability. The em-
ployee who negligently fails to warn the public of slippery floors while waxing them, for instance, may
cause his or her employer to be liable to anyone injured by falling. Vicarious liability will not, however,
shield the wrongdoer from liability. It merely adds a second potentially liable party. The employer and
employee in this case may both be liable. Recall the case of vanishing premiums described in Chapter 8.
Insurers were found to have liability because of the actions of their agents.
230 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
A controversial modification to negligence is the use of the joint and several liability doctrine.
joint and several liability
Joint and several liability exists when the plaintiff is permitted to sue any of several defendants indi-
Situation that exists when a vidually for the full harm incurred. Alternatively, the plaintiff may sue all or a portion of the group to-
plaintiff is permitted to sue
any of several defendants
gether. Under this application, a defendant may be only slightly at fault for the occurrence of the harm,
individually for the full harm but totally responsible for paying for it. The classic example comes from a case in which a Disney
incurred. World patron was injured on a bumper car ride.[6] The plaintiff was found 14 percent contributory at
fault; another park patron was found 85 percent at fault; Disney was found 1 percent at fault. Because
of the use of the joint and several liability doctrine, Disney was required to pay 86 percent of the dam-
ages (the percentage that the plaintiff was not at fault). Note that this case is an exceptional use of joint
and several liability, not the common use of the doctrine.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
In this section you studied the general notion of liability and the related legal aspects thereof:
< Legal liability is the responsibility to remedy a wrong done to another
< Special damages, general damages, and punitive damages are the types of monetary remedies applied to
liability
< Liability exposure arises out of statutory law or common law and cases are heard in criminal or civil court
< Negligent actions may result in liability for losses suffered as a result
< Liability through negligence is proven through existence of a duty to act (or not act) in some way, breach
of the duty, injury to one owed the duty, and causal connection between breach of duty and injury
< Defenses against liability include assumption of risk, contributory negligence, comparative negligence, last
clear chance, and immunity
< Modifications to help the plaintiff in a liability case include res ipsa loquitur, strict liability, vicarious liability,
and joint and several liability
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
Individuals, families, firms, and other organizations are exposed to countless sources of liability. These
may be related to the property they own or control, or to their activities (including using an auto-
mobile, providing professional services, manufacturing products, or being involved in e-commerce).
3.1 Property
You have a duty to the public not only with regard to your activities but also in connection with real
and personal property you own or for which you are responsible. The duty—the degree of care—varies
with the circumstances. The owner or tenant of premises, for example, does not owe the same duty to
CHAPTER 11 THE LIABILITY RISK MANAGEMENT 231
each person who enters the property. The highest degree of care is owed to invitees, whereas the stand-
ard of care is less for licensees and lowest for trespassers.
A trespasser is a person who enters the premises of another without either express or implied trespasser
permission from a person with the right to give such permission. Generally, the only duty owed to a
A person who enters the
trespasser is to refrain from taking steps to harm him or her. There are several exceptions to this, the premises of another without
most important concerning trespassing children. This exception is discussed in connection with the either express or implied
doctrine of attractive nuisance. permission from a person
A licensee is a person who enters premises with permission but (1) not for the benefit of the per- with the right to give such
permission.
son in possession, or (2) without a reasonable expectation that the premises have been made safe. If
your automobile breaks down and you ask the owners of the nearest house to use their telephone, the
permission you receive to enter the house makes you a licensee. Because a licensee is the party who re- licensee
ceives the benefit of entering the property, he or she is entitled to a minimum degree of care by the A person who enters
owner or tenant. An owner or tenant must avoid harm to licensees and must warn licensees of any premises with permission but
dangerous activity or condition of the property. They need not make the place safer, however, than it is (1) not for the benefit of the
normally. person in possession, or (2)
without a reasonable
An invitee is a person who enters the premises with permission and for the benefit of the person expectation that the
in possession. The invitee is entitled to a higher degree of care than a licensee. Thus, a customer in a premises have been made
store is an invitee, whether or not he or she makes a purchase. The property owner is expected to main- safe.
tain safe premises for invitees and to warn of dangers that cannot be corrected.
For the most part, it is a person’s reasonable expectation that determines his or her status. If you invitee
reasonably expect that the premises have been made safe for you, you are an invitee. For example, if I A person who enters the
invite you to a party at my home, you are an invitee. If you should reasonably expect to accept the premises with permission
premises as is without special effort on the part of the possessor, then you are a licensee. The distinc- and for the benefit of the
tion between a licensee and an invitee is not always clear because it depends on reasonable expecta- person in possession.
tions. Further, the courts have tended in recent years to place little weight on these distinctions. The
question becomes, What is reasonable of the property owner? Generally, the owner has the responsibil-
ity to provide a reasonably safe environment.
In one case, a guest who fell on a slippery floor was awarded damages against the homeowner. In
another case, a visitor fell down steps that were not properly lighted because a worker had failed to turn
on a light. Although it was the worker who was negligent, the homeowner had to pay because the
worker was his representative. Thus, the property owner’s liability was vicarious; he was not negligent,
but his employee was. In another case, a homeowner repaired a canopy and then hired a painter. When
the painter crawled onto the canopy, the canopy collapsed. The homeowner was held liable for the in-
juries sustained.
…That the lessor shall not be liable for any damage, either to person or property, sustained by the
lessee or by any other person, due to the building or any part thereof, or any appurtenances
thereof, becoming out of repair, or due to the happening of any accident in or about said building,
or due to any act or neglect of any tenant or occupant of said building, or of any other person.
The gist of this clause is to transfer the financial aspects of the landlord’s potential liability to the
tenant.
Animals
Ownership of pets and other animals may also result in liability. Anyone owning an animal generally is
responsible for damage or injury that the animal may cause. In many jurisdictions, if the owner acted
reasonably in controlling the animal, no liability will result. For example, in many places, a pet dog that
has been friendly and tame need not be leashed. Once that dog has bitten someone, however, more
control is required. If the dog bites a second person, the owner is likely to be held liable for the harm.
In this case, the owner had forewarning.
Likewise, anyone owning dangerous animals such as lions or poisonous snakes is held to a higher
standard of care. In this case, strict liability may be applied. Knowledge of the potential danger already
exists; thus, the owner must be given strong incentives to prevent harm.
In a recent, highly visible California case, a thirty-three-year-old woman was mauled to death by a
123-pound English mastiff/Presa Canary Island crossbreed. The owners were found guilty of second
degree murder by the jury, but the judge, in a surprise move, changed the ruling.[7] This case illumin-
ates statistics from the Center for Disease Control and Prevention in Atlanta, which reports ten to
twenty deaths annually from dog bites. Lawmakers in various states enacted laws concerning dogs. The
insurance industry also reacted to curtail the losses caused by dogs. In the Insurance Services Office
(ISO) homeowners policy (see [MISSING REF: #baranoff-chappA] in this textbook) there are “special
provisions that excludes liability coverage for any insured for bodily injury arising out of the actions of
a dangerous or vicious, and out of the insureds failure to keep the dangerous dog leashed or tethered or
confined in a locked pen with a top or locked fenced yard. The owners are required to control the dogs
and assure the safety of passersby.”[8]
Attractive Nuisance
In some cases, small children are attracted by dangerous objects or property. In such circumstances,
attractive nuisance
the owner has a special duty toward the children, especially if they are too young to be responsible for
Anything that is (1) artificial, their own safety. This is called the doctrine of attractive nuisance. An attractive nuisance is anything
(2) attractive to small
children, and (3) potentially
that is (1) artificial, (2) attractive to small children, and (3) potentially harmful. People who own power
harmful. lawn mowers, for example, must be especially watchful for small children who may be injured through
their own curiosity. If you leave your mower running while you go in the house to answer the tele-
phone and there are small children in the neighborhood who may be attracted to the mower, you may
be held financially responsible for any harm they experience. The most common attractive nuisance is
the swimming pool. Although some courts have held that those who own swimming pools are not ne-
cessarily babysitters for the community, it appears that pool owners do have the duty of keeping chil-
dren out. There have been many cases in which children entered a neighbor’s pool without permission
and drowned. The result is a suit for damages and in many cases a verdict in favor of the plaintiff.
Hazardous Waste
An increasingly important area of potential liability involving property derives from the possibility that
land may be polluted, requiring cleanup and/or compensation to parties injured by the pollution. Be-
cause of significant legislation passed in the 1970s and 1980s, the cleanup issue may be of greater con-
cern today than previously.
In 1980, the U.S. Congress passed the Comprehensive Environmental Response, Compensation,
and Liability Act (known as either CERCLA or Superfund). This act places extensive responsibilities on
organizations involved in the generation, transportation, storage, and disposal of hazardous waste. Re-
sponsibility generally involves cleaning or paying to clean polluted sites that are dangerous to the pub-
lic. Estimates of total program costs run from $100 billion to $1 trillion, giving an indication of the po-
tential severity of liability judgments. Any purchaser of realty (or creditor for that purchase) must be
aware of these laws and take steps to minimize involvement in Superfund actions. A small amendment
to the law was signed by President George W. Bush on January 11, 2002. Under the Small Business Li-
ability Relief and Brownfields Revitalization Act, certain small contributors to Superfund sites were
taken out of the liability system. The new law creates incentives for developers to purchase and restore
abandoned urban sites known as brownfields.[9]
The area of pollution liability is very complex. Decisions have been made regularly in pollution
cases. In a pollution case that went to the Ohio Supreme Court, Goodyear Tire & Rubber Co. sought to
recover the cost of environmental cleanups at some of its sites from its insurers.[10] The insurers
claimed that the coverage was excluded under the pollution exclusions provisions. The court sided with
Goodyear, however, ordering that Goodyear be allowed to choose—from the pool of triggered
policies—a single primary policy against which to make a claim.
CHAPTER 11 THE LIABILITY RISK MANAGEMENT 233
Automobile Liability
Ownership and operation of an automobile is probably the most common source of liability any indi-
vidual will encounter. Details about this liability will be given in Chapter 1.
As the driver of an automobile, you are responsible for its careful and safe operation. If you do not
operate it in a reasonable and prudent fashion and someone is injured as a result of such lack of care,
you may be held liable for damages. If, for example, you carelessly drive through a stop sign and run in-
to another car, you may be liable for the damage done.
Through either direct or vicarious liability, the owner of an automobile may be responsible for the family purpose doctrine
damage it causes when driven by another person. In some states, the family purpose doctrine makes
Doctrine that makes the
the owner of the family car responsible for whatever damage it does, regardless of which member of the owner of a family car
family may be operating the car at the time of the accident. The theory is that the vehicle is being used responsible for whatever
for a family purpose, and the owner, as head of the family, is therefore responsible. damage it does, regardless of
Many parents assume responsibility for their children’s automobile accidents without realizing which member of the family
they are doing so. In some states, minors between the ages of sixteen and eighteen are issued driver’s li- may be operating the car at
censes only if their applications are signed by a parent or guardian. What many parents do not realize the time of the accident.
is that by signing the application, they may assume responsibility for damage arising from the child’s
driving any automobile. Ordinarily, a child is responsible for his or her own torts, but the parent may
become liable by contract.
Vicarious liability is possible in other settings as well. If you lend your car to a friend, Sid Smith, so
he can go buy a case of liquor for a party you are having, he will be your agent during the trip and you
may be held responsible if he is involved in an accident. Your liability in this case is vicarious; you are
responsible for Smith’s negligence. On the other hand, if Smith is not a competent driver, you may be
held directly liable for putting a dangerous instrument in his hands. In such a case, it is your own negli-
gence for which you are responsible.
A special problem for employers is the risk known as nonownership liability, in which an em- nonownership liability
ployer is held liable for an injury caused by an employee using his or her own property when acting on
Situation in which an
the employer’s behalf. If an employee offers to drop the mail at the post office as he or she drives home employer is held liable for an
from work, the firm may be held liable if the employee is involved in an accident in the process. This injury caused by an employee
possibility is easily overlooked because the employer may not be aware that employees are using their using his or her own property
cars for company business. when acting on the
employer’s behalf.
Professional Liability
Members of a profession claim to have met high standards of education and training, as well as of char-
acter and ethical conduct. They are expected to keep up with developments in their field and maintain
the standards established for the profession. As a result, the duty a professional owes to the public is
considerably greater than that owed by others. Along with this duty, of course, comes liability for dam-
age caused by failure to fulfill it. People expect more from a professional, and when they do not get it,
some sue for damages.
As noted above, improper accounting activities to fatten the bottom line by publicly traded firms is
becoming an all-too-prevalent headline in the news. With fraud rampant, it appears that this chapter
will not be closed for a long time. The lack of trust of investors, small or large, in the accounting profes-
sion and corporate leadership in the United States led to the creation of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of
2002, as discussed in Chapter 7. The failures of the dot.com companies brought about an “onslaught of
securities litigation, increasing claims for directors, officers and accountants’ professional liability in-
surers.”[11]
Medical Malpractice
The risks to which physicians and surgeons are exposed illustrate the position of a professional. In tak-
malpractice
ing cases, doctors represent that they possess—and the law imposes upon them the duty of possess-
Failure by a professional to ing—the degree of learning and skill ordinarily possessed by others in their profession. If medical doc-
use reasonable care and tors fail to use reasonable care and diligence, and they fail to use their best judgment in exercising their
diligence, and/or failure to
use one’s best judgment in skill and applying their knowledge, they are guilty of malpractice.
exercising skill and applying Two cases demonstrate the risk to which medical doctors are exposed. A plastic surgeon who
knowledge. made his patient look worse instead of better had to pay $115,000 for the damage. A court awarded
$4.5 million to a girl suffering acute kidney failure as a result of malpractice.
Unlike the days when a family had one doctor who took care of almost all health problems, the
modern health care system is specialized; many patients are dealing primarily with doctors they do not
know. Faith in, and friendship with, the family doctor has been displaced by impersonal, brief contact
with a specialist who may be more efficient than friendly. Furthermore, publicity about fraud by some
doctors under the Medicare and Medicaid programs and about the amount of unneeded medical pro-
cedures (often performed as a defense against lawsuits) has reduced the prestige of the medical profes-
sion. As a result, there has been a decrease in confidence and an increase in willingness to sue.
Some of the increase in lawsuits, however, has been caused by a combination of unrealistic expect-
ations based on news about modern medical miracles and the belief by some that people are entitled to
perfect care. When they do not get it, they feel entitled to compensation.
One result of the surge in medical malpractice suits has been a scarcity of professional liability in-
surance in the private market and a dramatic increase in the cost of protection for both doctors and
hospitals. These costs, of course, are passed along by most doctors to the consumer. They represent one
factor contributing to rising health care costs.
Another result is the rise of defensive medicine. Doctors and hospitals are guided not only by what
is good for the patient but also by their own interests in preventing liability losses. The latter, of course,
leads to practices that may not be medically necessary and that increase the size of the patient’s bill.
The total effect of defensive medicine on the cost of health care is difficult to determine, but it is likely
significant.
Medical malpractice lawsuits continued to soar into the new millennium and the availability of
coverage became scarce in many states. Unable to find liability coverage, many doctors in risky special-
ties such as obstetrics and neurosurgery simply left the business. Medical liability rates nearly doubled
in some areas, and insurers left many states. In 2005, rates continued to climb but at a slower rate.[20]
Some published studies in 2004 and 2005 concluded that lawsuits against doctors were not necessarily
the cause of med-mal rate increases.[21] For more details, see the box, "The Medical Malpractice Crisis"
later in this chapter.
Operations
Many firms are exposed to liability from their operations. Contractors are particularly susceptible to
operations liability
operations liability, or liability arising from the ownership, maintenance, and use of premises and
Liability arising from the conduct of activity. Because they perform most of their work away from their premises, contractors’
ownership, maintenance, and
use of premises and conduct
greatest liability exposure is on the job rather than arising from their own premises. Bystanders may be
of activity. injured by equipment, excavations may damage the foundation of adjacent buildings, blasting
CHAPTER 11 THE LIABILITY RISK MANAGEMENT 235
operations may damage nearby property or injure someone. If harm is caused while performing the
job, as opposed to a negligently completed job, the liability may be an operations one.
E-Commerce Liability
As was discussed in detail in Chapter 10, e-commerce poses not only property and interruption of
business risks but also third-party liability arising from the following:[22]
< Invasion of privacy and identity theft
< Employee-related risks and harassment
< Intellectual property risks such as copyright, trademark infringement, defamation, encryption,
and discovery
< Publishing and advertising risks
< Service denial risks (contractual risks)
< Professional risks (errors and omissions risks)
Online privacy issues continue to top headlines. According to the respondents of a survey conducted
by the Yankee Group, a consulting firm focusing on global e-commerce and wireless markets, 83 per-
cent of online consumers are somewhat or very concerned about their privacy on the Internet.[23] Ac-
cording to a Fox News/Opinion Dynamics Poll, 69 percent of those polled said they’re “very con-
cerned” about their ability to keep personal information, such as medical and financial records, con-
fidential. While nearly two-thirds of Americans said they have access to the Internet at work, home, or
school, only 7 percent believed their most personal information is secure from the prying eyes of hack-
ers or bosses.[24] The reputation of the business is at stake if customers’ information does not remain
private and protected. Invasion of privacy is an issue of major public concern, as noted in the box
"Insurance and Your Privacy—Who Knows?" in Chapter 7. Businesses often collect data about their
customers or Web site visitors by having them fill out an online form or by making the user register for
permission to use the site. This information, if not protected, can create liability when the privacy of
the customer is breached. When so much information is released on the Internet, there are many op-
portunities for committing public defamation and opening the door to lawsuits.
Another e-commerce liability risk is raised with encryption, that is, the coding of Internet mes-
sages so information cannot be read by an interceptor. Because the terrorists responsible for the
September 11 attacks in New York City and Washington, D.C., presumably communicated via encryp-
ted Internet messages, some lawmakers renewed calls for restricting the use of encryption and for giv-
ing law enforcement unrestricted access to codes, or keys, for unlocking the encrypted text.
Employee privacy and the monitoring of employees’ e-mail by employers are also key privacy is-
sues. The courts appear to be on the employer’s side by agreeing that employers have the right to mon-
itor employee e-mails. In the case of United States of America v. Eric Neil Angevine, the Tenth Circuit
Court of Appeals held that, when the computer is provided to an employee (in this case, a university
professor) by the employer, the employee should not have privacy expectations.[25] Liability falls on the
employer if an employee uses e-mail while at work to commit a federal crime or send a threat. The en-
tire computer system can be subject to seizure (Federal Computer Seizure guidelines). A firm is liable
for any e-mails sent by employees; the e-mails are written proof of what the employee promised. The
company can also be held liable for any sexually harassing e-mails sent by employees.
Because a business derives much of its value from the uniqueness of its intellectual property, in-
cluding trade secrets, copyrights, and trademarks, infringement of these properties opens the firm to li-
ability lawsuits. There is increasing liability risk associated with statements posted on the Internet. Tra-
ditional publishing methods require many different people to proofread the document, checking for
potentially harmful statements. None of this is required to place information online. This point is
stressed by many professors when students are asked to write reports or do research. The validity of the
material on the Internet is as good as the trust you have in the reputation of the source of the material.
In the commercial world, advertising on the Internet brought both state and federal agencies into the
act of protecting consumers from false Web-based advertisements. In the early 2000s, the Securities
and Exchange Commission (SEC) sued to enjoin an illegal offer and sale of securities over America
Online and the Internet without a prospectus, and the Department of Transportation fined Virgin At-
lantic Airways for failing to disclose the full price of flights on its home page. The Food and Drug Ad-
ministration (FDA) is also looking into online advertisements for pharmaceuticals. The National Asso-
ciation of Attorneys General (NAAG) has formed a thirty-eight-state task force to develop enforcement
guidelines for combating illegal activity online. The Federal Trade Commission (FTC) has been in-
volved in cleaning the Internet of false advertising by finding the perpetrators and fining them with
large penalties. An example is the advertisers of Super Nutrient Program and Fat Burner Pills, who had
to pay $195,000 in penalties.[26]
Denial of service liability is caused when a third party cannot access a promised Web site. This
may be a major contractual liability.[27] For example, if a hacker penetrated a company’s Web site and
236 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
caused a shutdown, customers and other businesses may file lawsuits contending that their inability to
access the site caused them to suffer losses. These losses are different from the first-party losses of the
attacked company discussed in Chapter 10. The attacked company is covered under first-party insur-
ance of property and business interruption income or special e-commerce endorsement. Finally, the
professional liability of errors and omissions may cause a third party to have a loss of income. This may
occur when an Internet provider fails or security software fails to perform.
The possible liabilities outlined above are not a complete list. Many of the causes of losses de-
scribed in Chapter 10 may be causes for liabilities as well. The important point is that e-commerce ex-
poses businesses to liabilities not anticipated prior to the electronic age. These liabilities may not be
covered in the traditional commercial liability policy.
Product Manufacture
Product liability is one of the most widely debated sources of risk for a firm. The basis for product li-
product liability
ability may be negligence, warranty, or strict liability in tort relating to defects causing injury in
Situation in which a
products sold to the public.
manufacturer may be liable
for harm caused by use of its Product liability is a somewhat unusual aspect of common law because its development has oc-
product, even if the curred primarily within the twentieth century. One explanation for this late development is the doc-
manufacturer was reasonable trine of privity. The privity doctrine required a direct contractual relationship between a plaintiff and a
in producing it. defendant in a products suit. Thus, a consumer injured by a product had a cause of action only against
the party from whom the product was purchased. The seller, however, likely had no control over the
manufacture and design of the product, thus limiting potential liability. Consumers’ only recourse was
to claim a breach of warranty by the seller; this cause of action is still available.[28]
Once the privity doctrine was removed, negligence actions against manufacturers surfaced. De-
monstrating a manufacturer’s negligence is difficult, however, because the manufacturer controls the
production process. You may recall that the doctrine of res ipsa loquitur becomes relevant in such a
circumstance, placing the burden of proof on the manufacturer.
By 1963, members of the judiciary for the United States seemed to have concluded that consumers
deserved protection beyond res ipsa loquitur. Thus developed strict liability in products, as stated by
Justice Traynor:
A manufacturer is strictly liable in tort when an article he places on the market, knowing that it is to
be used without inspection for defects, proves to have a defect that causes injury to a human
being.[29]
These three doctrines of breach of warranty, negligence, and strict liability are available today as
causes of action by a consumer in a product liability cases. Each is briefly described below.
Breach of Warranty
Many products are warranted suitable for a particular use, either expressly or by implication. The state-
breach of warranty
ment on a container of first-aid spray, “This product is safe when used as directed…,” is an express
Situation arising when an warranty. If you use a product as directed and suffer injury as a result, breach of warranty has oc-
individual uses a product as
directed and suffers injury as
curred and the manufacturer may be held liable for damages. On the other hand, if you use the product
a result. other than as directed and injury results, the warranty has not been breached. Directions on a container
may create an implied warranty. A statement such as “Apply sparingly to entire facial surface” implies
that the product is not harmful for such use, thus creating an implied warranty. If the product is harm-
ful even when the directions are followed, the warranty has been breached.
Negligence
When a firm manufactures a product, sells a commodity, or acts in one of the other points in the mar-
keting chain, it has a duty to act reasonably in protecting users of the commodity from harm. Failure to
fulfill this duty constitutes negligence and may provide the basis for liability if harm results. According
to Noel and Phillips, “Negligence in products cases is most likely to involve a failure to warn or to warn
adequately of foreseeable dangers, a failure to inspect fully or test, a failure in either design or produc-
tion to comply with standards imposed by law or to live up to the customary standards of the in-
dustry.” For example, failure to warn that the paint you sell may burn the skin unless removed immedi-
ately may result in injury to the buyer and a liability for the seller. The product liability exposure can
extend over the life of a product, which may be a very long time in the case of durable goods. A number
of proposals have been made both nationally and at the state level to limit the time period during which
such responsibility exists.
CHAPTER 11 THE LIABILITY RISK MANAGEMENT 237
Strict Liability
A firm may be held liable for damage caused by a product even though neither negligence nor breach
of warranty is established. This is called strict liability.
The doctrine of strict liability has been applied primarily based on the description provided in
1965 by the American Law Institute in section 402 of the Second Restatement of Torts. It reads as
follows:
1. One who sells any product in a defective condition unreasonably dangerous to the user or
consumer or to his property is subject to liability for physical harm thereby caused to the ultimate
user or consumer, or to his property, if
a. the seller is engaged in the business of selling such a product, and
b. it is expected to and does reach the user or consumer without substantial change in the
condition in which it is sold.
2. The rule stated in Subsection (1) applies although
a. the seller has exercised all possible care in the preparation and sale of his product, and
b. the user or consumer has not bought the product from or entered into any contractual
relation with the seller.
The important aspects of this description are that the product was sold in a defective condition, which
makes it unreasonably dangerous, thereby causing physical harm to the ultimate user. Thus, the manu-
facturer and/or seller of the product may be held liable even if “all possible care in the preparation and
sale” of the product was undertaken, and even if the injured party was not the buyer. Because of the ex-
tent of this liability, it is not surprising that manufacturers hope to eliminate or at least limit the use of
strict liability.
As already discussed, product liability suits were rare prior to the 1960s, and awards were small by
today’s standards. Two legal changes altered the scope of the product liability system. First came the
abolition of the privity rule. With the expansion of trade to include wholesalers and retailers, especially
with respect to automobiles, the concept of privity seemed inappropriate. Then, in 1963, strict liability
was brought to the arena of products cases. With strict liability, an injured party could receive damages
by showing that the product was inherently dangerous and also defective. The result was a subtle shift
from focus on the manufacturer’s behavior to the product’s characteristics.[30]
Since 1963, the United States has seen a rapid increase in product liability litigation. One of the
most difficult and common forms of litigation today involves strict liability due to defective warnings.
Another source of consternation is the mass tort area (also referred to as class-action lawsuits), in
which thousands of people are injured by the same product or set of circumstances, such as the Dalkon
Shield and asbestos products. Some users of the Dalkon Shield, an intrauterine contraceptive device
(IUD), experienced severe medical problems allegedly due to the defective nature of the product.
Another cause for mass tort is asbestos. Asbestos is an insulation material made of tiny fibers that,
when inhaled, may cause respiratory ailments. Thousands of workers using asbestos in the 1930s and
1940s have been diagnosed with various forms of cancer. Their injuries led to class-action lawsuits. In
2005, Congress was in the process of passing legislation to create a special fund for the victims of asbes-
tos exposure. The proposal was highly debated and the constitutionality of the potential new law ques-
tioned. The proposed bill was to provide a no fault $140 billion asbestos compensation trust fund in
place of the existing litigation-based system of compensating victims of asbestos-related diseases.[31]
The increase in product liability litigation and awards is believed to have been a major cause of the
liability insurance crisis of the mid-1980s. The cost of insurance increased so much that some firms
have gone out of business, while others have discontinued production of the items that seem to be
causing the trouble. In some circumstances, the discontinuance of a product line may not be very
newsworthy. In others, however, the results could be quite detrimental. The threat of lawsuits, for in-
stance, appears to have been the impetus for several vaccine manufacturers to leave the business. Merck
& Co. is now the sole U.S. producer of the combined measles, mumps, and rubella (MMR) vaccine. In
other circumstances, companies have not only terminated the manufacture of products but have filed
for bankruptcy. Johns Manville Corporation, an asbestos manufacturer, and A. H. Robbins, a producer
of the Dalkon Shield IUD, are two examples of companies who filed for Chapter 10 bankruptcy to get
out from under liability suits.
The largest liability cases are the tobacco liability cases that started in the 1990s and are continuing
with large awards given to the plaintiffs, who are victims of cancer and other illnesses caused by
smoking cigarettes. A case that stands out is the one against R. J. Reynolds Tobacco Holdings, Inc.,
where the Kansas judge, not the jury, levied a $15 million punitive damages awards to the amputee
David Burton. The punitive damage awards were fifteen times larger than the $196,416 compensatory
award.[32] Note also the major case against Philip Morris discussed in the box "Are Punitive Damages
out of Control?" in Chapter 9.
238 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
The tobacco cases did not end in courts. The states brought lawsuits themselves. The states forced
the industry to the negotiating table, and the tobacco industry settled for $368 billion in 1997, four
years after the battle began. Some of the stories of the hurt, loss, and misery caused by cigarette
smoking and the lawsuits are described in The People vs. Big Tobacco by the Bloomberg News team of
Carrick Mollenkamp, Adam Levy, Joseph Menn, and Jeffrey Rothfeder (Princeton, NJ: Bloomberg
Press, 1998) and Cornered: Big Tobacco at the Bar of Justice, by Peter Pringle (New York: Henry Holt
Co., 1998).
As the courts provide large awards to plaintiffs and the tobacco companies find ways to curtail the
damage,[33] the next wave of lawsuits may be expected to target the food industry because of obesity.
This topic is discussed in the box “Obesity and Insurance—Litigation or Self-Discipline?” in this
chapter.
Completed Operations
Closely related to product liability is liability stemming from activities of the firm in installing equip-
completed operations
liability
ment or doing other jobs for hire off its own premises, called completed operations liability. De-
fective workmanship may cause serious injury or property damage, for which the firm may be held
Liability stemming from
activities of the firm in
liable.
installing equipment or doing
other jobs for hire off its own Contingent Liability
premises.
Generally, a firm that hires an independent contractor is not liable for damage or injury caused by the
contractor. There are a number of exceptions to this general rule, however, resulting in contingent liab-
contingent liability
ility. Contingent liability occurs in situations where the firm is liable for an independent contractor’s
Situation in which a firm is negligence because the firm did not use reasonable care in selecting someone competent. If the activity
liable for an independent
contractor’s negligence
to be performed by an independent contractor is inherently dangerous, the firm is strictly liable for
because the firm did not use damages and cannot shift its liability to the contractor. The fact that the contractor agrees to hold the
reasonable care in selecting firm harmless will not relieve it from liability. A firm that hires an independent contractor to do a job
someone competent. and then interferes in details of the work may also find itself liable for the contractor’s negligence.
Liquor Liability
Many states have liquor laws—or dramshop laws—which impose special liability on anyone engaged
dramshop laws
in any way in the liquor business. Some apply not only to those who sell liquor but also to the owner of
Laws that impose special the premises on which it is sold. The laws are concerned with injury, loss of support, and damage to
liability on anyone engaged
in any way in the liquor
property suffered by third parties who have no direct connection with the store or tavern. For example,
business. if liquor is served to an intoxicated person or a minor and the person served causes injury or damage to
a third party, the person or firm serving the liquor may be held liable. In some cases, liability has been
extended to employers providing alcohol at employee parties.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
In this section you studied the various ways that individuals, families, firms, and other entities are exposed to li-
ability in property and in activities and conduct:
< Property owners’ duties vary with respect to invitees, licensees, and trespassers; children must be specially
considered when property is an attractive nuisance.
< Tenants face liability to the public and to property owners.
< Property considered hazardous waste has the potential to be an environmental liability.
< The most common source of liability in activities/conduct is the activity of operating an automobile, which
also invites vicarious and nonownership liabilities.
< Doctors, lawyers, accountants, and other professionals are exposed to professional liability in errors in
omissions, activities of directors and officers, and medical malpractice.
< Contractors are susceptible to operations liability.
< E-commerce entails liability risks such as invasion of privacy, intellectual property risks, and contractual
service denials.
< The basis for product liability may be negligence, warranty, or strict liability.
< Completed operations, contingent liability, and liquor liability are other sources of liability in activities and
conduct.
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
4. POSSIBLE SOLUTIONS
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
A number of suggestions have been made to alleviate the problems of product liability and malpractice
(professional) liability. Some would limit the right to use or improve the defendant’s defenses; others
would reduce the incentive to sue or provide an alternative to legal action.
contingency fee
In both areas, proposals would limit the compensation available to plaintiffs’ attorneys. Most
plaintiffs compensate their attorneys with a percentage (typically one third) of their award, called a
A percentage (typically one
third) of the award to a
contingency fee. The advantage of a contingency fee system is that low-income plaintiffs are not
plaintiff, collected by the barred from litigation because of inability to pay legal fees. A disadvantage is that lawyers have incent-
attorney only if the plaintiff ives to seek very large awards, even in situations that may appear only marginally appropriate for litiga-
prevails. tion. Reduced contingency fee percentages and/or caps on lawyer compensation have been recommen-
ded as partial solutions to increases in the size of liability awards and the frequency of litigation itself.
statutes of limitation
Similarly, shorter statutes of limitation, which determine the time frame within which a claim must
Laws that determine the time be filed, have also been proposed as a means to reduce the number of liability suits.
frame within which a claim
must be filed.
Placing caps on the amount of damages available and eliminating the collateral source rule are re-
commendations that focus on the size of liability payments. Caps on damages typically limit recovery
either for general damages or for punitive damages. Often, when actually awarded, general and punit-
ive damages far exceed the special damages; thus, they dramatically increase the size of the award and
can add significant uncertainty to the system.
collateral source rule The collateral source rule is a legal doctrine that prevents including information about a
plaintiff’s financial status and/or compensation of losses from other sources in the litigation. In a set-
A legal doctrine that prevents
including information about
ting in which a plaintiff has available payments from workers’ compensation or health insurance, for
a plaintiff’s financial status example, the jury is not made aware of these other payments when determining an appropriate liability
and/or compensation of award. Thus, the plaintiff may receive double recovery.
losses from other sources in Another prominent recommendation is to abolish or limit the use of joint and several liability. As
the litigation. previously described, joint and several liability has the potential to hold a slightly-at-fault party primar-
ily responsible for a given loss. The extent of the use of the doctrine, however, is disputed.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
In this section you studied suggestions for reducing liability losses from legal and risk management
perspectives:
< Reduction in attorneys’ contingency fees would reduce the financial incentive of trying liability suits
< Shorter statutes of limitation on claims would reduce the overall number of liability cases
< Placing caps on the amount of damages and eliminating the collateral source rule are efforts designed to
limit award amounts
< In e-commerce liability, privacy procedures should first be developed
< Risk can be transferred through special e-commerce liability policies
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. How might elimination of the collateral source rule and a shortened statute of limitations affect the
availability and affordability of liability insurance?
2. How does the contingency fee system work?
3. How might the contingency fee system affect the frequency and severity of liability exposures?
242 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
to her coworkers. Before long, the whole system collapsed and business was interrupted for a day
until the backup system was brought up.
a. Describe the types of liability risk exposures Pharmacy On-Line is facing as a result of
Erin’s action.
b. If Pharmacy On-Line purchased the ISO e-commerce liability endorsement, would it be
covered for the liability?
c. If Erin penetrated into the system and obtained information about the customers, and if
she later sold that information to a competitor, what would be the liability ramifications?
Is there insurance coverage for this breach of privacy issue?
244 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
19. Michael Ha, “AIG Center of Class-Action Lawsuit,” National Underwriter Online News
ENDNOTES Service, May 13, 2005, http://www.propertyandcasualtyinsurancenews.com/cms/
NUPC/Weekly %20Issues/Issues/2005/20/News/P20AIGUPDATE?searchfor=
(accessed March 16, 2009).
1. For class-action lawsuits, see major business and insurance journals during February 20. Steven Brostoff, “Malpractice Cover Worries Docs: AHA,” National Underwriter Online
News Service, June 26, 2002; Daniel Hays, “Another Malpractice Insurer Leaving Flor-
2005. Examples include Allison Bell, “Industry Welcomes Class-Action Victory,” Na- ida,” National Underwriter Online News Service, June 24, 2002; “Study: Tort Costs Still
tional Underwriter Online News Service, February 10, 2005; Jim Drinkard, “Bush to Sign Edging Up, Albeit More Slowly,” National Underwriter Online News Service, January 17,
Bill on Class-Action Suits,” USA Today, February 18, 2005, http://www.usatoday.com/ 2005, http://www.propertyandcasualtyinsurancenews.com/cms/NUPC/Breaking
money/2005-02-17-lawsuits-usat_x.htm (accessed March 16, 2009). For AIG stories, %20News/2005/01/17-Study%20Tort%20Costs%20Still%20
see all media outlets in 2005, for example, “401(k) Participants File Class-Action Suit Edging%20Up%20Albeit%20More%20Slowly?searchfor=tort%20costs%20edging%20up
Against AIG,” BestWire, May 13, 2005. Also, review many articles in the media during (accessed March 16, 2009).
the fall of 2008 and the winter of 2009.
2. H. J. Black, Black’s Law Dictionary, 5th ed. (St. Paul, MI: West Publishing Company, 21. Rachel Zimmerman and Christopher Oster, “Insurers’ Price Wars Contributed to Doc-
tors Facing Soaring Costs; Lawsuits Alone Didn’t Inflate Malpractice Premiums,” Wall
1983), 774. Street Journal, June 24, 2002; “Report: Suits Don’t Cause Higher Med Mal Premiums,”
National Underwriter Online News Service, March 11, 2004,
3. This was first stated explicitly by Judge Learned Hand in U.S. v. Carroll Towing Co., 159
http://www.propertyandcasualtyinsurancenews.com/cms/NUPC/Breaking%20
F. 2d 169 (1947).
News/2005/03/11-Report%20Suits%20Dont%20Cause%20Higher%20Med%20
4. Two such theories are called enterprise liability and market share liability. Both rely Mal%20Premiums?searchfor=suits%20cause%20higher%20premiums (accessed
on the plaintiff’s inability to prove which of several possible companies manufac- March 16, 2009).; Arthur D. Postal, “More Conflict over What Raises Med-Mal Rates,”
tured the particular product causing injury when each company makes the same National Underwriter Online News Service, May 23, 2005,
type of product. Under either theory, the plaintiff may successfully sue a “substantial” http://www.propertyandcasualtyinsurancenews.com/cms/NUPC/Breaking
share of the market without proving that any one of the defendants manufactured %20News/2005/05/23-TORT-dp?searchfor=conflict%20raises%20rates (accessed
the actual product that caused the harm for which compensation is sought. March 16, 2009).
5. Workers’ compensation is discussed in Chapter 1. 22. George Sutcliffe, E-Commerce and Insurance Risk Management (Boston: Standard Pub-
lishing Corp., 2001); 2004 CSI/FBI Computer Crime and Security Survey at GoCSI.com.
6. Walt Disney World Co. v. Wood, 489 So. 2d 61 (Fla. 4th Dist. Ct. Appl. 1986), upheld by
the Florida Supreme Court (515 So. 2d 198, 1987). 23. “Online Privacy Continues to Be a Major Concern for Consumers,” research report,
the Yankee Group, July 27, 2001. For its 2001 Interactive Consumer (IAC) report, the
7. Coverage of the story is available in all media stories in the beginning of June 2002. Yankee Group surveyed approximately 3,000 online consumers.
8. Diane Richardson, “Bite Claims Can Dog Insurance Companies,” National Underwriter, 24. Richard S. Dunham “Who’s Worried About Online Privacy? Who Isn’t?” Business Week
Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edition, May 14, 2001; Daniel Hays, Online, June 28, 2000, in http://www.businessweek.com/bwdaily/dnflash/june2000/
“Insurers Feel the Bite of Policyholders’ Big Bad Dogs,” National Underwriter Online nf00628c.htm?scriptFramed.
News Service, January 31, 2001.
25. Thomas Jackson, “Protecting Your Company Assets and Avoiding Risk in Cyber-
9. Steven Brostoff, “New Brownfields Law Falls Short of Sought-After Superfund Re- space,” online newsletter of legal firm Phillips Nizer Benjamin Krim & Ballon LLP, July
forms,” National Underwriter Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edi- 16, 1996.
tion, March 25, 2002.
26. Thomas Jackson, “Protecting Your Company Assets and Avoiding Risk in Cyber-
10. Rodd Zolkos, “Ohio High Court Favors Policyholder in Pollution Case,” Business Insur- space,” online newsletter of legal firm Phillips Nizer Benjamin Krim & Ballon LLP, July
ance, June 27, 2002. 16, 1996.
11. Mark E. Ruquet, “Accountants Under Scrutiny Even Before Enron Failure,” National 27. George Sutcliffe, E-Commerce and Insurance Risk Management (Boston: Standard Pub-
Underwriter, Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edition, February 25, lishing Corp., 2001); 2004 CSI/FBI Computer Crime and Security Survey at GoCSI.com.
2002.
28. Dix W. Noel and Jerry J. Phillips, Products Liability in a Nutshell (St. Paul, MI: West Pub-
12. Mark E. Ruquet, “Accountants Paying More for E&O Coverage,” National Underwriter, lishing Co., 1981).
Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edition, February 25, 2002.
29. Greeman v. Yuba Power Products, Inc., 377 P.2d 897 (Cal 1963).
13. The citations are too many to list because the issues develop daily. Review informa-
tion in National Underwriter, Best’s Review, and Business Insurance to learn more. Some 30. Many people consider strict product liability to be anything but a subtle shift from
parts of these Web sites are open only to subscribers, so students are encouraged to negligence. For a discussion of the difference, however, see Barrett v. Superior Court
use their library’s subscriptions to search these publications. (Paul Hubbs), 272 Cal. Rptr. 304 (1990).
14. Best Wire, July 1, 2002. 31. “Asbestos Trust Could Face Constitutional Challenges,” BestWire, May 23, 2005; Mark
A. Hofmann, “Amendments Delay Vote on Asbestos Trust Fund Bill,” Business Insur-
15. National Underwriter Online News Service, June 17, 2002. ance, May 16, 2005; Matt Brady, “House Dems Ask Study Of Asbestos Fund Concept,”
National Underwriter Online News Service, May 13, 2005; Jerry Geisel, “Insurer Groups
16. Lisa S. Howard, National Underwriter, Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Manage-
Oppose Asbestos Legislation,” Business Insurance, April 19, 2005.
ment Edition, February 25, 2002.
17. “D&O Coverage Evolve in Unstable Regulatory Climate,” BestWire, May 23, 2005, 32. Michael Bradford, “Tobacco Firms Facing String of Legal Defeats,” Business Insurance,
http://www3.ambest.com/Frames/FrameServer.asp?AltSrc= July 1, 2002.
23&Tab=1&Site=news&refnum=74599 (accessed March 16, 2009). This article and 33. Vanessa O’Connell, “Lifting Clouds: New Tactics at Philip Morris Help Stem Tide of
those in footnotes 14 to 16 are a few examples. During the early to mid-2000s, the Lawsuits: As It Revamps Legal Team, Cigarette Giant Also Gains in Appeals-Court Rul-
student can find related stories in every media outlet. ings, Some Big Battles Still Loom,” Wall Street Journal, May 11, 2005, A1.
18. Dave Lenckus, “AIG Set to Test Its Own Cover,” Business Insurance, May 16, 2005, 34. This discussion is based on Safety ‘Net Internet Liability Policy by Chubb Group of In-
http://www.businessinsurance.com/cgi-bin/article.pl?articleId= surance Companies and Executive Risk Indemnity, Inc.
16843&a=a&bt=AIG+Set+to+Test+Its+Own+Cover (accessed March 16, 2009).
CHAP TER 12
Multirisk Management
Contracts: Business
In the preceding four chapters, you read about property and liability exposures generally and how families insure
home and auto exposures specifically. Now, we will delve briefly into business, or commercial, insurance.
Commercial insurance is a topic for an extensive separate course, but its importance has been reflected to a great
extent throughout the previous chapters. Employers who take unnecessary risks or who do not practice prudent
risk management may not only cause job losses, they may also cause the loss of pensions and important benefits
such as health insurance (discussed in later chapters).
As members of the work force, we drive our employers’ cars and spend many of our waking hours operating
machines and computers on business premises. Risks are involved in these activities that require insurance
coverage. A case in point is the damage caused by mold in many commercial buildings and schools as well as in
homes. Mold can cause headaches, discomfort, and more serious problems. Employers’ property coverage was of
great help in remedying the problem. However, as a result of the many claims, insurers have excluded mold
coverage or provided very low limits. This and more pertinent issues in different types of commercial coverage will
be discussed in this chapter. Issues such as the complexities of directors and officers coverage due to the improper
behavior of executives in many large corporations, like AIG, Enron, and WorldCom, are discussed in this chapter, as
are the dispute over the limits of coverage of the World Trade Center. The interested student is invited to study in
depth and explore the risk and insurance news media for current commercial coverage issues. Also, Case 3 in
[MISSING REF: #baranoff-ch23] relates to the types of commercial coverage embedded in integrated risk programs.
The programs described in the case use similar commercial packaged policies that are described in this chapter,
which covers the following:
1. Links
FIGURE 12.1 Links between the Holistic Risk Puzzle and Commercial Insurance
Source: ISO Common Policy Declarations Form IL DS 00 09 08. Includes copyrighted material of Insurance Services Office, Inc., with its permission.
CHAPTER 12 MULTIRISK MANAGEMENT CONTRACTS: BUSINESS 247
1. LINKS
At this point in our study, we are drilling further down into specific, more complex coverages of the
commercial world. Many types of coverage are customized to the needs of the business, but many more
use the policies designed by the Insurance Services Office (ISO), which have been approved in most
states. We have moved from the narrow realm of personal line coverages, but the basic premises are
still the same. The business risks shown in Figure 12.1 do not clearly differentiate between commercial
risk and personal hazards. The perils of fire and windstorm do not separate personal homes from com-
mercial buildings, as we saw from the devastation of hurricanes Katrina, Rita, and Wilma in 2005. Our
business may be sued for mistakes we make as employees because the business is a separate legal entity.
We cannot separate between the commercial world and our personal world when it comes to complet-
ing our risk management puzzle to ensure holistic coverage.
Figure 12.1 shows how the picture of our risk puzzles connects to the types of commercial cover-
age available as a package from the ISO. We use the common policy declarations page, which illustrates
the mechanism of this packaged policy. This program permits businesses to select among a variety of
insurance options, like a cafeteria where we can choose the items we want to eat and reject those we do
not. The program is considered a package because it combines both property and liability options in
the same policy, as well as additional coverages as listed in the common policy declarations page in Fig-
ure 12.1. Within each of the property and liability coverages are various options available to tailor pro-
tection to the particular needs of the insured, as you will see in this chapter.
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
The commercial package policy (CPP) program was started by the Insurance Services Office (ISO) in
1986. Every policy includes three standard elements: the cover page, common policy conditions, and
common declarations (shown in Figure 12.1). It is important to elaborate on the declaration page be-
cause it provides a visual aid of the various coverages that can be selected by a business, depending on
needs. Some businesses may not need specific parts of the package, but all the elements are listed for
the choice of the potential insured. More specifically, the package may include the following commer-
cial coverage elements: boiler and machinery, capital assets program, commercial automobile, com-
mercial general liability, commercial inland marine, commercial property, crime and fidelity,
employment-related practices liability, farm liability, liquor liability, pollution liability, and profession-
al liability. Some of these coverages were discussed in prior chapters. The rest of the coverages will be
described here.
Most commercial organizations have similar property exposures. Common business property ex- commercial property policy
posures, along with business income exposures, can be insured through the commercial property
Policy that provides insurance
policy form of the commercial package policy. The liability module of the commercial package policy for direct physical loss to
is the commercial general liability (CGL) policy. It replaced the liability coverage previously avail- business property and
able through the comprehensive general liability policy. In 1986, the CGL was made part of the new income.
modular approach introduced by the ISO in the form of the CPP.
commercial general
liability (CGL) policy
policyholder by identifying that policyholder’s specific exposures. The information in the declarations
must be accurate for the desired protection to exist. The remainder of the commercial property cover-
age consists of the following:
< The building and personal property (BPP) coverage form
< One of three causes of loss forms for the BPP
< Business income coverage (BIC) form
< Endorsements
Direct Property Coverage: The Building and Personal Property (BPP) Form
The BPP provides coverage for direct physical loss to buildings and/or contents as described in the
policy. Separate sections with distinct limits of insurance are available for both buildings and contents
to account for differing needs of insureds. Some insureds will be tenants who do not need building cov-
erage. Others will be landlords who have limited or no need for contents coverage. Many insureds, of
course, will need both in varying degrees.
Covered Property
What constitutes a building and business personal property may appear obvious. The insurer, however,
must be very precise in defining its intent because, as you know, insurance is a contract of adhesion.
Ambiguities, therefore, are generally construed in favor of the insured. Figure 12.2 lists the items
defined as buildings. Figure 12.3 lists those items defined as business personal property.
FIGURE 12.2 Building as Defined in ISO Building and Personal Property Coverage Form (Sample)
Source: ISO Commercial Property Building and Personal Property Coverage Form CP 00 10 06 07. Includes copyrighted material of Insurance Services
Office, Inc., with its permission.
CHAPTER 12 MULTIRISK MANAGEMENT CONTRACTS: BUSINESS 249
FIGURE 12.3 Business Personal Property as Defined in ISO Building and Personal Property Coverage
Form (Sample)
Source: ISO Commercial Property Building and Personal Property Coverage Form CP 00 10 06 07. Includes copyrighted material of Insurance Services
Office, Inc., with its permission.
In addition to limiting coverage by defining building and business personal property, the BPP lists spe-
cific property that is excluded from protection. These items are listed in Figure 12.4. Reasons for exclu-
sions in insurance were discussed earlier. Note in Figure 12.4 and in the corresponding section in the
policy the exclusion of “electronic data, except as provided under additional coverages.” In part f (4) of
Additional Coverages, discussed below and in Figure 12.5, the electronic data that is covered is limited
to a loss of up to $2,500 sustained in one year. The low limit on electronic equipment and data losses
have propelled many businesses to buy the e-commerce endorsement discussed in Chapter 10. This ex-
clusion is not always noticed by businesses. To ensure adequate coverage, insurers began to offer edu-
cation programs to risk managers about their cyber-risk exposures.
250 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
FIGURE 12.4 Listed Property Not Covered as Defined in ISO Building and Personal Property Coverage
Form (Sample)
Source: ISO Commercial Property Building and Personal Property Coverage Form CP 00 10 06 07. Includes copyrighted material of Insurance Services
Office, Inc., with its permission.
CHAPTER 12 MULTIRISK MANAGEMENT CONTRACTS: BUSINESS 251
Additional Coverages and Coverage Extensions FIGURE 12.5 Additional Coverage and
Coverage Extension as Listed in ISO
In addition to paying for repair or replacement of the listed property when caused by a Building and Personal Property Coverage
covered peril, the BPP pays for other related costs. The BPP also extends coverage un- Form
der specified conditions. These coverage additions and extensions are listed in Figure
12.5.
The value of these additional and extended coverages can be significant. Debris re-
moval, for example, is a cost that is often overlooked by insureds, but can involve thou-
sands of dollars. Recent tornadoes in the midwestern United States caused heavy prop-
erty damage, and for many insureds, the most significant costs involved removal of tree
limbs and other debris.
An interesting additional coverage is pollutant cleanup and removal, a provi-
sion that specifies the conditions under which, and the extent to which, protection for
cleanup costs are paid by the insurer. Because of large potential liabilities, coverage is
narrowly defined as those situations caused by a covered loss, and only for losses at the
described premises. The amount of available protection is also limited.
The extended coverages primarily offer protection for properties not included in
the definition of covered buildings and personal property. The intent is to provide spe-
cific and limited insurance for these properties, which is why they are separated from
the general provision. Newly acquired property and property of others, for instance, involve exposures pollutant cleanup and
distinct from the general exposures, and they require special attention in the coverage extensions. Some removal
of the coverage extensions offer protection against loss from a short list of causes to property otherwise A provision that specifies the
excluded. Outdoor equipment is an example of property otherwise excluded. conditions under which, and
the extent to which,
Valuation protection for cleanup costs
As has been discussed in prior chapters, property insurance payments may be made on either a re- are paid by the insurer.
placement cost new (RCN) basis or an actual cash value (ACV) basis. If the insured chooses actual cash
value, then the provision 7 valuation of section E, loss conditions, applies. The valuation provision in-
volves a number of parts.[1] Parts (b) through (e) explain the insurer’s intent for valuation in situations
involving RCN when ACV may be difficult to measure or inappropriate. Part (b), for instance, permits
payment at RCN for relatively small losses: those valued at $2,500 or less.
If the insured chooses replacement cost new, this optional coverage must be designated in the de-
clarations. Further, the insured ought to recognize the need for higher limits than if ACV is used. Typ-
ically, the insurer does not charge a higher rate for RCN coverage; however, more coverage is needed,
which translates into a higher premium. For RCN to be paid, the insured must actually repair or re-
place the covered property. Otherwise, the insurer will pay on an ACV basis.
Limits of Insurance
As just discussed, you need to be cautious when selecting an amount of insurance that will cover your
potential losses. The insurer will not pay more than the limit of insurance, except for the coverage ex-
tensions and coverage additions (fire department charges, pollution cleanup, and electronic data). In
addition to concern over having a sufficient amount of insurance to cover the value of any loss, some
insureds need to worry about violation of the coinsurance provision, which is found under section F,
additional conditions of the BPP. The policy provides examples of coinsurance. An example of under-
insurance in the policy is provided in Table 12.1 below.
252 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
TABLE 12.1 Example of Underinsurance in ISO Building and Personal Property Coverage Form
(Sample)
Example #1 (Underinsurance)
When: The value of the property is: $250,000
The Coinsurance percentage for it is: 80%
The Limit of Insurance for it is: $100,000
The Deductible is: $250
The amount of loss is: $40,000
Step (1): $250,000 × 80% = $200,000
(the minimum amount of insurance to meet your Coinsurance requirements)
Step (2): $100,000 ÷ $200,000 = .50
Step (3): $40,000 × .50 = $20,000
Step (4): $20,000 – $250 = $19,750
We will pay no more than $19,750. The remaining $20,250 is not covered.
Source: ISO Commercial Property Building and Personal Property Coverage Form CP 00 10 06 07. Includes copyrighted material of Insurance Services
Office, Inc., with its permission.
The BPP policy continues to include a coinsurance provision as a major condition of coverage. For
agreed value option
most insureds, however, there is a choice to override the coinsurance clause with an agreed value op-
Requires the policyholder to tion, found in section G of optional coverages. The agreed value option requires the policyholder to
buy insurance equal to 100
percent of the value of the
buy insurance equal to 100 percent of the value of the property, as determined at the start of the policy.
property, as determined at If the insured does so, then the coinsurance provision does not apply and all losses are paid in full, up
the start of the policy. to the limit of insurance. The wording in the policy is shown in Figure 12.6.
FIGURE 12.6 Agreed Value Option in ISO Building and Personal Property Coverage Form (Sample)
Source: ISO Commercial Property Building and Personal Property Coverage Form CP 00 10 06 07. Includes copyrighted material of Insurance Services
Office, Inc., with its permission.
The agreed value option, however, does not ensure that the policyholder will have sufficient limits of
inflation guard option
insurance to cover a total loss, especially in times of high inflation. To ward off unwanted retention of
Provides for automatic loss values above the limit of insurance, the insured can purchase the inflation guard option found in
periodic increases in
section G, optional coverages (which is discussed in [MISSING REF: #baranoff-ch13]). The inflation
insurance limits; the intent is
to keep pace with inflation. guard option provides for automatic periodic increases in insurance limits; the intent is to keep pace
with inflation. The amount of the annual increase is shown as a percentage in the declarations.
Causes of Loss
We have just described some major elements of the BPP form. A full understanding of the coverage re-
quires a thorough reading and consideration of the impact of each provision. As for which perils are
CHAPTER 12 MULTIRISK MANAGEMENT CONTRACTS: BUSINESS 253
covered, the property section of the CPP offers three options: the basic causes of loss form, the broad
causes of loss form, and the special causes of loss form.
Causes of Loss—Basic Form
The basic causes of loss form is a named-perils option of the commercial property policy that covers
basic causes of loss form
eleven named perils (see Figure 12.7). Some perils are defined and others are not. When exists, the
common use of the term, supplemented by court opinions, will provide its meaning. A named-perils option of the
commercial property policy
Fire, for example, is not defined because it has a generally accepted legal meaning. Insurance that covers eleven named
policies cover only certain fires. While excessive heat may be sufficient for the fire protection to apply, perils.
oxidation that results in a flame or glow is typically required. Further, the flame must be hostile, not
within some intended container. For instance, if you throw something into a fireplace, intentionally or
not, that fire is not hostile and the loss likely is not covered.
A review of the policy and [MISSING REF: #baranoff-ch13], where many of these same perils were
discussed as they apply to homeowners coverage, may clarify which loss situations are payable on the
basic causes of loss form. Review of the exclusions is just as important.
Exclusions found in the basic causes of loss form can be categorized as follows:
< Ordinance of law
< Earth movement
< Governmental action
< Nuclear hazards
< Power failure
< War and military action
< Water damage
< Fungus, wet rot, dry rot, and bacteria
< Other, involving primarily steam, electrical, and mechanical breakdown
Most of these exclusions involve events with catastrophic potential, such as floods (the water
exclusion).
Causes of Loss—Broad Form
The broad causes of loss form is a named-perils option of the commercial property policy that cov-
broad causes of loss form
ers fifteen named perils. It differs from the basic form in adding some perils, as listed in Figure 12.7.
Geography may dictate, to some extent, preference for the broad form because of its ice and snow cov- A named-perils option of the
commercial property policy
erage. Also note that the water damage peril is for the “sudden and accidental leakage of water or steam that covers fifteen named
that results from the breaking or cracking of part of an appliance or system containing water or steam perils.
(not a sprinkler system).” It does not cover floods or other similar types of catastrophic water damage.
In addition to adding these perils, the broad form includes a provision to cover collapse caused by
the named perils or by hidden decay; hidden insect or vermin damage; weight of people or personal
254 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
property; weight of rain that collects on a roof; or use of defective materials in construction, remodel-
ing, or renovation. While this “collapse” additional coverage does not increase the amount of coverage
available (as the other additional coverages do), it does expand the list of covered-loss situations.
The mold exclusion was discussed in prior chapters. The exact wording of the exclusion is excerp-
ted from the ISO Causes of Loss—Broad Form in Figure 12.8.
FIGURE 12.8 Mold Exclusion as Listed in the ISO Causes of Loss—Broad Form (Sample)
Source: ISO Commercial Property Causes of Loss—Broad Form CP 10 20 06 07. Includes copyrighted material of Insurance Services Office, Inc., with
its permission.
The additional coverage in the policy permits a coverage limit for mold for up to only $15,000, as noted
in Additional Coverage—Limited Coverage For “Fungus,” Wet Rot, Dry Rot And Bacteria.
The coverage described under D.2. of this Limited Coverage is limited to $15,000. Regardless of the
number of claims, this limit is the most we will pay for the total of all loss or damage arising out of
all occurrences of Covered Causes of Loss (other than fire or lightning) and Flood which take place
in a 12-month period (starting with the beginning of the present annual policy period). With
respect to a particular occurrence of loss which results in ‘fungus,’ wet or dry rot or bacteria, we will
not pay more than a total of $15,000 even if the ‘fungus,’ wet or dry rot or bacteria continues to be
present or active, or recurs, in a later policy period.[2]
Business income coverage will be discussed in the next section. For now, it is important to note
that, under the mold exclusion and extension of coverage, business interruption income is provided for
only thirty days. The days do not need to be consecutive.
Returning to the topic of cause of loss, it is very important to have a clear definition of what is con-
sidered a cause of loss for the limits of coverage. Whether or not the peril caused one loss or two separ-
ate losses is imperative in understanding the policy. A case in point is that of the complex decisions re-
garding whether the loss of the two World Trade Center buildings was one loss or two separate losses
from two separate causes of loss. The stakes were very high, at $3.5 billion of limit. To understand the
issue more clearly, see the box “Liability Limits: One Event or Two?”
When the two hijacked airplanes struck the World Trade Center towers on the morning of September 11,
2001, the insurance and reinsurance contracts for the property were still under binder agreements. Thus, the
wording of the binder agreements became the central issue of this case. At the time of the attacks, real estate
executive Larry A. Silverstein’s company had only recently acquired a ninety-nine-year lease on the World
Trade Center and had not yet finalized insurance coverage, which provided up to $3.5 billion in property and
liability damage per occurrence. With policies of such size, which have large reinsurance requirements, it is not
uncommon for the final policies not to be in place when the insured begins operations.
The United Kingdom-based reinsurer Swiss Re had agreed to underwrite 22 percent of coverage on the prop-
erty once the loss exceeded $10 million, translating into $3.5 billion per occurrence in this case. After the at-
tacks, Swiss Re argued that its preliminary agreement with the lessee defined occurrence as “all losses or dam-
ages that are attributable directly or indirectly to one cause or one series of similar causes” and that “all such
losses will be added together and the total amount of such losses will be treated as one occurrence irrespect-
ive of the period of time or area over which such losses occur.” Silverstein, however, argued that each of the
airplane crashes was a separate occurrence and his company was due more than $7 billion for the two attacks.
The fuzziness of the language has been very problematic. This led to two opposing verdicts in separate court
cases. In Phase I, the insurers prevailed. In Phase II, Silverstein did. The first jury found that “the form used by
broker Willis Group Holdings Ltd., rather than a rival form used by Travelers or other forms, and that the Willis
form, known as WilProp 2000, had specific language that defined what happened to the World Trade Center
as a single occurrence.” Under this WilProp form, occurrence means “all losses or damages that are attributable
directly or indirectly to one cause or to one series of similar causes. All such losses are added together and the
total amount of such losses is treated as one occurrence irrespective of the period of time or area over which
such losses occur.”
In the second case, the jury agreed with Silverstein that there were two occurrences, at least as defined by the
temporary insurance agreements that bound the group of insurers that were involved in the second case. As a
result of the second ruling, Silverstein had an open door to collect “as much as twice the $1.1 billion aggregate
insured amount per occurrence for which the nine insurers were liable.”
These two contradictory rulings stem from three tests:
1. The cause test—The question is, Was there more than one cause underlying the loss? As such, it can
be determined that the fall of the twin towers resulted from one conspiracy by Osama bin Laden.
2. The effect test (less prevalent)—The question is, Was there more than one distinct loss? As such, the
test looks at each injury or damage to determine the number of losses.
3. Unfortunate events test—This test combines the cause test with elements of the effect test; here,
proximity of the cause of loss is important. Because there were two planes causing the loss, the loss is
regarded as two separate losses.
The World Trade Center cases were heard in a federal court—the U.S. District Court for the Southern District of
New York in Manhattan. Ultimately, however, the matter was settled out of court. In March of 2007, New York
Insurance Superintendent Eric Dinallo requested that two representatives from Silverstein Properties and each
of the seven insurers involved in the WTC settlement dispute attend a meeting with the state insurance de-
partment to bring closure to the ongoing litigation. After weeks of tense negotiations, then-New York
Governor Eliot Spitzer and Superintendent Dinallo announced on May 23, 2007, that an agreement between
the parties had been successfully brokered. Travelers, Zurich, Swiss RE, Employers Insurance of Wausau, Allianz
Global, Industrial Risk Insurers, and Royal Indemnity Company agreed to settle all outstanding court cases and
related proceedings for a total of $2 billion. Spitzer and Dinallo described this as the largest settlement in regu-
latory history. Specific amounts paid each company were not disclosed due to confidentiality agreements. The
resolution to this dispute removes the last major obstacle to World Trade Center redevelopment as planned
by Silverstein Properties and the New York and New Jersey Port Authority.
To address the underlying problem in the long-delayed loss settlement, Superintendent Dinallo issued a bul-
letin on October 16, 2008, requiring insurers to provide contract certainty for coverage agreements. This con-
tract certainty called for contract language in insurance policies to be firmed up within thirty days of issuance
and the delivery of the policy before, on, or promptly after the policy’s inception date. This would ensure that
policy provisions, like the question as to whether the destruction of the twin towers was one insured event or
two, are definitively established before a loss. Insurance carriers were given twelve months from the date of
Dinallo’s bulletin to bring policies and procedures into compliance with the rule. When asked by the Risk and
Insurance Management Society (RIMS) what would happen if carriers failed to meet the compliance deadline,
the New York Insurance Department responded that it would “consider regulations spelling out more detailed
rules. Regulations have the force of law and penalties can be assessed on licensees.” Willis Group Holdings
Chairman and CEO Joe Plumeri praised the contract certainty rule, saying, “There is absolutely no excuse for
256 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
policies to be delivered months after their inception, an all too commonplace practice in this business.…
We’re in the business of keeping promises, and the insurance industry as a whole can do no less. We believe
that the industry should police itself, take a principled approach to doing business, and adopt these measures
as soon as possible.”
The protracted settlement of the World Trade Center destruction provides a high-profile example of the prob-
lems that can arise due to uncertain policy terms. This is not typically an issue with most insurance policies
written on standardized forms approved by the state insurance department. In the case of large commercial
clients, excess and surplus lines, and reinsurance markets, however, it is likely to come up due to complexity of
business scope, degree of risk, and lack of regulatory authority. Should the contract certainty rule in New York
prove successful in curtailing disputes, RIMS anticipates that additional states will follow suit in passing similar
requirements.
Questions for Discussion
1. Which ruling do you agree with in this complex case? What is the justification for the ruling against
the leaseholder in this case, and the one in favor of the leaseholder? Do you think this ruling is ethical
in light of the massive loss?
2. In ethical terms, who should really suffer the burden of the attack on America on September 11?
Should it be any private citizen or the private insurance industry?
Sources: E. E. Mazier, “Swiss Re Presses ‘One Attack’ Theory,” National Underwriter, Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edition, October 29,
2001; E. E. Mazier, “Experts View Swiss Re WTC Lawsuit as Unprecedented Legal Quagmire,” National Underwriter Online News Service, October 31,
2001; Mark E. Ruquet, “Insurers to Lose WTC Case: Agent Univ.,” National Underwriter Online News Service, July 22, 2002; E. E. Mazier, “Judges Sends
WTC Claim to Jury Trial,” National Underwriter, Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edition, June 10, 2002; E. E. Mazier, “Judge Rules WTC
Terror Is One Event,” National Underwriter Online News Service, September 25, 2002; E. E. Mazier, “Swiss Re Silverstein WTC Case in Shambles,” National
Underwriter Online News Service, September 27, 2002; “Tale of Two Trials: Contract Language Underlies Contradictory World Trade Center Verdicts,”
BestWire, December 9, 2004, accessed March 27, 2009, http://www3.ambest.com/Frames/
FrameServer.asp?AltSrc=23&Tab=1&Site=news&refnum=70605; Mark E. Ruquet, “Spitzer Spearheads $2 Billion WTC Insurance Settlement,” National
Underwriter, Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edition, May 23, 2007, accessed March 29, 2009, www.property-casualty.com/News/
2007/5/Pages/Spitzer-Spearheads--2-Billion-WTC-Insurance-Settlement.aspx; Mark E. Ruquet, “WTC Deal Gets Dinallow Off on Right Foot,” National
Underwriter, Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edition, June 18, 2007, accessed March 29, 2009, www.property-casualty.com/Issues/
2007/24/Pages/WTC-Deal-Gets-Dinallo-Off-On-Right-Foot.aspx; Daniel Hays, “New N.Y. Regulation Calls For Policy Contract Certainty,” National
Underwriter, Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edition, October 16, 2008, accessed March 29, 2009, www.property-casualty.com/News/
2008/10/Pages/New-N-Y--Regulation-Calls-For-Policy-Contract-Certainty.aspx; Daniel Hays, “RIMS Reacts to N.Y. Contract Certainty Regulation,”
National Underwriter, Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edition, October 22, 2008, accessed March 29, 2009,
www.property-casualty.com/News/2008/10/Pages/RIMS-Reacts-To-N-Y--Contract-Certainty-Regulation.aspx; Mark E. Ruquet, “Willis CEO Applauds
N.Y. Move On Contract Certainty,” National Underwriter, Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management Edition, October 17, 2008, accessed March
29, 2009, http://www.property-casualty.com/News/2008/10/Pages/Willis-CEO-Applauds-N-Y--Move-On-Contract-Certainty.aspx; See all media
coverage at the end of 2004 and afterward.
We will pay for the actual loss of Business Income you sustain due to the necessary ‘suspension’ of
your ‘operations’ during the ‘period of restoration.’ The ‘suspension’ must be caused by direct
physical loss of or damage to property at premises which are described in the Declarations and for
which a Business Income Limit of Insurance is shown in the Declarations. The loss or damage must
be caused by or result from a Covered Cause of Loss. With respect to loss of or damage to personal
property in the open or personal property in a vehicle, the described premises include the area
within 100 feet of the site at which the described premises are located.[3]
Under this policy, businesses that sustained losses because of the economic backlash and fear after
September 11, 2001, would not be covered for their loss of income. For discussion of this issue, read the
box “Business Interruption with and without Direct Physical Loss” in Chapter 10.
As noted above in the discussion of the BPP policy, this part of the commercial package also limits
coverage for interruption to computer operations under Section 4, as presented in Figure 12.10.
258 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
FIGURE 12.10 Interruption of Computer Operations Coverage Limitation in the ISO Business Income
(and Extra Expense) Coverage Form (Sample)
Source: ISO Commercial Property Business Income (and Extra Expense) Coverage Form CP 00 30 06 07. Includes copyrighted material of Insurance
Services Office, Inc., with its permission.
In Additional Coverage, the amount available for interruption of computer operation is $2,500. No
wonder many businesses today purchase the e-commerce endorsement or buy the new policies from
the companies described in Chapter 10 and Chapter 11.
Extra Expense
In addition to losing sales, a business may need to incur various expenses following property damage in
order to minimize further loss of sales. These extra expenses are also covered by the BIC. A bank, for
example, could not simply shut down operations if a fire destroyed its building because the bank’s cus-
tomers rely on having ready access to financial services. As a result, the bank is likely to set up opera-
tions at a temporary location (thus reducing the extent of lost revenues) while the damaged property is
being repaired. The rent at the temporary location plus any increase in other expenses would be con-
sidered covered extra expenses.
Causes of Loss
The same three perils options available for the BPP are also available for the BIC. Because the BIC re-
quires that the covered income loss results from direct physical loss or damage to property described in
the declarations, most insureds choose the same causes of loss form for both the BPP and the BIC.
Now, we show a more detailed example of a hypothetical loss that occurred during the Chicago flood in
1992.
This firm experienced both a reduction in revenue and an increase in expenses. The resulting profit (net in-
come) loss is the covered loss in the BIC. For this example, the loss equals $117,000, the sum of the income not
received ($45,000) that would have been expected without a loss, plus the actual lost income ($72,000) in-
curred. Such a substantial loss for a two-week period is not unusual.
Coinsurance
The coinsurance provision of the BIC is one of the more confusing parts of any insurance policy. Its
purpose is the same as that discussed earlier, which is to maintain equity in pricing. Its application is
also similar. The difficulty comes in defining the underlying value of the full exposure, which is needed
to apply any coinsurance provision. Following in Table 12.2 is an underinsurance example from a BIC
policy. More examples are provided in the policy sample.
260 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
TABLE 12.2 Example of Underinsurance in ISO Business Income (and Extra Expense) Coverage Form
(Sample)
Example #1 (Underinsurance)
When: The Net Income and operating expenses for the 12 months following the inception, or last $400,000
previous anniversary date, of this policy at the described premises would have been:
The Coinsurance percentage is: 50%
The Limit of Insurance is: $150,000
The amount of loss is: $80,000
Step $400,000 × 50% = $200,000
(1):
(the minimum amount of insurance to meet your Coinsurance requirements)
Step $150,000 ÷ $200,000 = .75
(2):
Step $80,000 × .75 = $60,000
(3):
We will pay no more than $60,000. The remaining $20,000 is not covered.
Source: ISO Commercial Property Business Income (and Extra Expense) Coverage Form CP 00 30 06 07. Includes copyrighted material of Insurance
Services Office, Inc., with its permission.
Remember that a BIC loss equals net income plus continuing operating expenses. Coinsurance,
however, applies to net income plus all operating expenses, a larger value. The amount of insurance re-
quired to meet the coinsurance provision is some percentage of this value, with the percentage determ-
ined by what the insured expects to be the maximum period of interruption. If a maximum interrup-
tion of six months is expected, for example, the proper coinsurance percentage is 50 percent (6/12). If it
is nine months, a coinsurance percentage of 75 percent (9/12) is appropriate.
Because of the complexity of the coinsurance provision, however, many insureds choose an agreed
value option. This option works under the same principles as those discussed with regard to the BPP.
Using the example illustrated in “Business Income Coverage (BIC) Hypothetical Loss,” we can demon-
strate the application of the coinsurance provision. Coinsurance requirements apply to net income plus
operating expenses ($95,000 plus $405,000 per month on average, or $6,000,000 for the year). If a 50
percent coinsurance provision is used because the expected maximum period of interruption is six
months, then the amount of insurance required is $3,000,000 (0.50 × $6,000,000). If the April figures
are representative (which is really not the case with a tax accounting office), then a six-month interrup-
tion would result in a much lower loss.
Other Options
The BIC includes a number of options designed to modify coverage for the insured’s specific needs.
Three options that affect the coinsurance provision are the monthly limit of indemnity, maximum
period of indemnity, and payroll endorsements. For better understanding, the student is invited to read
the policy in addition to reading the following explanations.
monthly limit of indemnity The monthly limit of indemnity negates the coinsurance provision of business income cover-
age; instead, a total limit is listed, as is the percentage of that limit available each month. The policy
Negates the coinsurance
provision of business income
uses the example of a $120,000 limit and ¼ monthly amount. For this example, only $30,000 (¼ ×
coverage; instead, a total limit $120,000) is available each month. An organization with stable earnings and expectations of a short
is listed, as is the percentage period of restoration would likely find this option worthwhile.
of that limit available each The maximum period of indemnity option also negates the coinsurance provision of the BIC;
month.
instead, this option limits the duration of coverage to 120 days (or until the limit is reached, whichever
comes first). Both the maximum period of indemnity and the monthly limit of indemnity address the
maximum period of fact that the standard policy cannot be used with a coinsurance provision of less than 50 percent (six
indemnity months).
Option also negates the
coinsurance provision of the
BIC; instead, this option limits
the duration of coverage to
120 days (or until the limit is
reached, whichever comes
first).
CHAPTER 12 MULTIRISK MANAGEMENT CONTRACTS: BUSINESS 261
Instead of negating the coinsurance provision, as do the two options just discussed, the payroll
payroll endorsement
endorsement allows the insured to deduct some or all payroll expenses from the value of operating
Allows the insured to deduct
expenses before calculating the coinsurance requirement. Doing so allows the insured to purchase less
some or all payroll expenses
insurance (and usually pay lower premiums) and still meet the coinsurance provision. It also excludes from the value of operating
payroll from covered expenses, however, so the insured must feel confident that payroll would not be expenses before calculating
maintained during a shutdown. A common payroll endorsement includes ninety days of payroll ex- the coinsurance requirement.
pense in the coinsurance calculation (and BIC coverage), assuming that a short shutdown might allow
the insured to continue to pay employees. For a longer shutdown, termination of employment might
be more cost effective.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
In this section you studied the commercial package policy (CPP) and the commercial property component of
the CPP:
< The commercial package policy (CPP) is a modular business insurance option that bundles coverages such
as commercial property, commercial general liability, commercial inland marine, professional liability, and
more, into a single policy.
< The CPP contains the standard elements: cover page, common policy conditions, and common
declarations.
< Common business property exposures are insured through the commercial property policy of the CPP.
< Property declarations and conditions of the commercial property policy form identify the covered location,
property values and limits, premiums, deductibles, and other items.
< The commercial property policy’s building and personal property (BPP) form provides coverage for direct
physical loss to buildings and contents and additional or extended coverages, per the insured’s valuation
provision up to the limits of insurance and subject to listed exclusions.
< Three causes of loss options are available in the BPP: basic (eleven named perils), broad (fifteen named
perils), and special (open perils), all subject to exclusions.
< The commercial property policy provides coverage of net income losses as a result of being unable to use
damaged or lost property through the business income coverage (BIC) form.
< BIC protects against business interruption and extra expense losses.
< The BIC offers the same three cause of loss options as the BPP.
< Both the BPP and the BIC are subject to coinsurance provisions; this can be modified in the BIC through
use of the monthly limit of indemnity, maximum period of indemnity, and payroll endorsements.
262 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. What types of property are covered in the BPP? What are some examples of excluded property, and why
are they excluded?
2. How can an insured get around the coinsurance provision in the BPP? Why might an insured prefer to do
this?
3. What kinds of losses are covered in the BIC? Provide examples.
4. The building where Alpha Mortgage Company’s office was located received minor smoke damage,
forcing the company to relocate its operations for one month. Assuming standard BIC coverage and the
following hypothetical conditions, what amount of benefits could the company expect to receive?
5. The Bravo Multiplex Movie Theater has a BIC coverage limit of $200,000 with a coinsurance percentage of
50 percent. Over the previous one-year period, the theater’s net income and operating expenses totaled
$400,000. If Bravo is forced to shut down one of its eight theaters for six months (incurring a total loss of
$60,000), how much will BIC cover? Does the company have enough insurance? Do they have other
options?
6. Assume that the Steinman Shoe Station owns the $1 million building in which it operates, maintains
inventory and other business properties in the building worth $700,000, and often has possession of
people’s property up to a value of $50,000 while they are being repaired. For each of the following losses,
what, if anything, will Steinman’s BPP insurer pay? Limits are $1 million on coverage A and $800,000 on
coverage B. The broad causes-of-loss form is used and there was no e-commerce endorsement. Explain
your answers.
a. Wind damage rips off tiles from the roof, costing $20,000 to replace. The actual cash value is
$17,000.
b. An angry arsonist starts a fire. The building requires repairs of $15,000, $17,000 of inventory is
destroyed, and $2,000 of other people’s property is burned.
c. A water pipe bursts, destroying $22,000 of inventory and requiring $10,000 to repair the pipe.
d. The computer system crashes for three days.
7. Steinman also bought a BIC with a limit of $250,000 and a 50 percent coinsurance clause. No other
endorsements are used. A limited income statement for last year is shown below.
CHAPTER 12 MULTIRISK MANAGEMENT CONTRACTS: BUSINESS 263
Revenues $2,000,000
Less:
Cost of goods sold $800,000
Utilities $200,000
Payroll $400,000
Other expenses $300,000
$1,700,000
Profit $300,000
a. How much in expenses does Steinman expect to be noncontinuing in the event of a shutdown?
Explain.
b. What is the longest shutdown period Steinman would expect following a loss?
c. If a three-month closing occurred following the roof collapsing due to the weight of snow, what
do you think would be the loss? Explain.
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
In this section we elaborate on the different types of optional property coverage available in the CPP
offering insurance on property otherwise excluded or to meet the special needs of businesses:
< The Crime and Fidelity insurance program
< Inland marine (IM) insurance
< Boiler and machinery (B&M) insurance
< The Capital Assets Program
< The business owners policy (BOP)
The commercial package policy is designed to accommodate separate and sometimes special property
needs of insureds. Refer again to Figure 12.1.
Historically, crime losses have been insured separately from other property losses. Perhaps the separa-
fidelity bond
tion was intended to standardize the risk; exposure to crime loss may involve quite different loss-con-
trol needs and frequency and severity estimates from those associated with exposure to fire, weather A guarantee provided to
damage, or other BPP type losses. Furthermore, within the crime coverage, employee dishonesty has employers by each employee
promising loyalty and
typically been insured separately from other property crimes, likely also in an effort to recognize vari- faithfulness and stipulating a
ations in risk and loss-control needs between the two. Employee dishonesty protection began as a bond mechanism for financial
(called a fidelity bond), which was a guarantee provided to employers by each employee promising recovery should the promise
loyalty and faithfulness and stipulating a mechanism for financial recovery should the promise be be broken.
broken. As a result, bonding companies developed to protect against employee crimes, while insurers
expanded their coverage separately to protect against other property-related crimes.
Today, ISO has a Crime and Fidelity insurance program.[4] The ISO enhancements include cover-
age for losses caused by employee theft of the following:
< Money
< Securities
264 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
The property portion of the business owners program covers both direct and consequential losses,
seasonal fluctuation
combining the types of coverage found in the BPP and BIC. An inflation guard is standard, as is a sea-
sonal fluctuation for personal property. The inflation guard increases the building’s coverage limit by Permits recovery of lost
personal property up to 125
some stated percentage automatically each year. The seasonal fluctuation permits recovery of lost
percent of the declared limit,
personal property up to 125 percent of the declared limit, as long as the average value of the personal as long as the average value
property over the prior twelve months is not greater than the limit. For organizations with fluctuating of the personal property over
stock values, this provision is helpful. Coverage is on a replacement cost new basis without a coinsur- the prior twelve months is
ance provision. not greater than the limit.
The policy also provides business income loss for one year of interruption without a stated dollar
limit or coinsurance requirement. Many small businesses are prone to ignore this exposure, which is
why the coverage is included automatically.
Coverage can be purchased either on a named-perils or an open-risk basis. The named-perils form
covers the causes of loss listed in Figure 12.7, which are the same perils available in other coverage
forms. One additional peril, transportation, is also covered in the BOP. The transportation peril affords
some inland marine protection.
The business owners program was released by the ISO in June 2002.[6] It expanded some risk cat-
egories eligible for coverage with a new section, “Commercial Lines Manual.” The BOP includes
“computer coverage, business income from dependent properties coverage, and fire extinguisher sys-
tem recharge expense.” There are some new optional endorsements, such as “coverage for food con-
tamination, water backup and sump overflow, functional building and personal property valuation, li-
quor liability, employee benefits liability, and several coverage and exclusion options for pollution liab-
ility.”[7]
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
In this section you studied the separate, special property needs of insureds that can be resolved through the
CPP:
< The Crime and Fidelity insurance program provides employers with coverage for a variety of forms of
employee theft.
< Inland marine insurance covers nonwater forms of commercial transportation.
< Boiler and machinery (B&M) insurance protects against loss from property damage to the insured’s own
property and to nonowned property caused by explosions or other breakdowns of boilers and machinery.
< The Capital Assets Program provides large and medium commercial accounts businesses coverage on a
blanket, replacement-cost basis without a coinsurance provision and options to value property at actual
cash value, agreed value, or, functional replacement cost.
< The business owners policy (BOP) provides comprehensive coverage for small businesses through
separate property and liability policies incorporating both the BPP and BIC.
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
Coverages
The CGL provides three types of coverage:
1. Bodily injury and property damage liability
2. Personal and advertising injury liability
3. Medical payments
Each coverage involves its own insuring agreement and set of exclusions. Each also provides a distinct
limit of insurance, although an aggregate limit may apply to the sum of all costs under each coverage
for the policy period. Other aggregates also apply, as discussed in the policy limits section below.
CHAPTER 12 MULTIRISK MANAGEMENT CONTRACTS: BUSINESS 267
The claims-made policy was introduced (first in medical malpractice insurance, later in other policies)
in response to increased uncertainty about future liabilities. As explained above, an occurrence policy
could be sold today, and liability associated with it could be determined thirty years later or more. With
changing legal and social norms, the inability of insurers to feel confident with their estimates of ulti-
mate liabilities (for pricing purposes) led them to develop the claims-made coverage.
Bodily injury (BI) is defined as bodily injury, sickness, or disease sustained by a person, includ- bodily injury (BI)
ing death resulting from any of these at any time. Property damage (PD) is defined as (a) physical Bodily injury, sickness, or
injury to tangible property, including all resulting loss of use of that property, or (b) loss of use of tan- disease sustained by a
gible property that is not physically injured. person, including death
In addition to covering an insured’s liability due to bodily injury or property damage, the insurer resulting from any of these at
promises to defend against suits claiming such injuries. The cost of defense is provided in addition to any time.
the limits of insurance available for payment of settlements or judgments, as is payment of interest that property damage (PD)
accrues after entry of the judgment against the insured. The insurer, however, has the general right to
settle any suit as it deems appropriate. Furthermore, the insurer’s obligation to defend against liability Physical injury to tangible
property, including all
ends when it has paid out its limits for any of the coverages in settlements or judgments. resulting loss of use of that
So far, this coverage sounds extremely broad, and it is. A long list of exclusions, however, defines property, or loss of use of
the coverage more specifically. Figure 12.11 provides the list of exclusions. tangible property that is not
physically injured.
268 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
FIGURE 12.11 Exclusions to Coverage A—Bodily Injury and Property Damage Liability in the ISO
Commercial General Liability Policy
We can discuss the exclusions as they relate to the four general reasons for exclusions, as presented
earlier. Several relate to situations that may be nonfortuitous. Exclusion (a), which denies coverage for
intentionally caused harm, clearly limits nonfortuitous events. Exclusion (b), an exclusion of contractu-
ally assumed liability, also could be considered a nonfortuitous event because the insured chose to
enter into the relevant contract. Pollution liability (exclusion f), likewise, may arise from activities that
were known to be dangerous. Damage to the insured’s own products or work (exclusions k and l) in-
dicates that the insurer is not willing to provide a product warranty to cover the insured’s poor work-
manship, a controllable situation.
A number of exclusions are intended to standardize the risk and/or to limit duplicate coverage
when other coverage does or should exist. Liquor liability (exclusion c), for instance, is not standard
across insureds. Entities with a liquor exposure must purchase separate coverage to protect against it.
Likewise, we know that workers’ compensation and employers’ liability (exclusions d and e) all are
covered by specialized contracts. Separate policies also exist for autos, aircraft, watercraft, and mobile
equipment (exclusions g and h) because these risks will not be standard for organizations with similar
general liability exposures.
The category of property owned by or in the care, custody, and control of the insured is also ex-
cluded (exclusion m). These exposures are best handled in a property insurance policy, in part because
the insured cannot be liable to itself for damage, and in part because the damage should be covered
whether or not it is caused by the insured’s carelessness.
Some exclusions apply because of the catastrophic potential of certain situations. In addition to the
possible nonfortuitous occurrence of pollution losses, the potential damages are catastrophic. Cost es-
timates to clean hazardous waste sites in the United States run into the hundreds of billions of dollars,
as discussed in Chapter 11. Similarly, war-related injuries (exclusion i) are likely to affect thousands,
possibly hundreds of thousands of people simultaneously.
The war risk practically defines catastrophe because it affects so many people from a single situ-
ation, not too unlike a product recall (exclusion n). Most manufacturers produce tens of thousands of
products in each batch. If a recall is necessary, the whole batch generally is affected. This situation also
has some element of nonfortuity, in that the insured has some control over deciding upon a recall, al-
though limited separate coverage is available for this exposure. A memorable example occurred when
Johnson & Johnson recalled all of its Tylenol products following the lethal tampering of several boxes.
CHAPTER 12 MULTIRISK MANAGEMENT CONTRACTS: BUSINESS 269
Even though Johnson & Johnson undertook the recall to prevent future injury (and possible liability),
its insurer denied coverage for the recall costs. Insureds can buy an endorsement for product recall.
Another exclusion is the fungi and bacteria exclusion. CGL has a mold exclusion that applies to
bodily injury and property damage only. The endorsement states that payment for liability is excluded
for the following:
d. “Bodily injury” or “property damage,” which would not have occurred, in whole or in part, but
for the actual, alleged or threatened inhalation of, ingestion of, contact with, exposure to,
existence of, or presence of, any “fungi” or bacteria on or within a building or structure, including
its contents, regardless of whether any other cause, event, material or product contributed
concurrently or in any sequence to such injury or damage
e. Any loss, cost or expenses arising out of the abating, testing for, monitoring, cleaning up,
removing, containing, treating, detoxifying, neutralizing, remediating or disposing of, or in any
way responding to, or assessing the effects of, “fungi” or bacteria, by any insured or by any other
person or entity[13]
Coverage B—Personal and Advertising Injury Liability
Coverage A provides protection against physical injury or damage due to the insured’s activities. Des-
pite the many exclusions, it provides broad coverage for premises, products, completed work, and oth-
er liabilities. It does not provide protection, however, against the liabilities arising out of nonphysical
injuries. Coverage B does provide that protection. The policy states,
“We will pay those sums that the insured becomes legally obligated to pay as damages because of
‘personal and advertising injury’ to which this insurance applies. We will have the right and duty to
defend the insured against any ‘suit’ seeking those damages. However, we will have no duty to
defend the insured against any ‘suit’ seeking damages for ‘personal and advertising injury’ to which
this insurance does not apply. We may, at our discretion, investigate any offense and settle any
claim or ‘suit’ that may result.[14] ”
The exclusions for Coverage B, Personal and Advertising Injury Liability, are listed in Figure 12.12.
The exclusions eliminate intentional acts (nonaccidental acts), acts that occurred before the cover-
age began, criminal acts, and contractual liability. False statements and failure to conform to state-
ments and infringements of copyrights and trademarks are also excluded. As in other coverages, elec-
tronic chat rooms and Internet businesses are excluded (see Chapter 11). In this context, insureds in
the Internet and media businesses are completely excluded from coverage B under the 2001 CGL
policy. The particular exclusion of unauthorized use of another’s name and product was also noted in
Chapter 11. Because pollution and pollution related-risks are considered catastrophic, they are ex-
cluded as well.
270 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
FIGURE 12.12 Exclusions to Coverage B—Personal and Advertising Injury Liability in the ISO
Commercial General Liability Policy
FIGURE 12.13 Exclusions to Coverage C—Medical Payment in the ISO Commercial General Liability
Policy
Supplementary Payments
Supplementary payments are for bodily injury, property damage, and personal injury coverage. The in-
surer pays for the claim or suit, the cost for bonds up to $250, all expenses for investigations it con-
ducts, and “all reasonable expenses incurred by the insured.” As long as the list of conditions detailed
in the policy is met, the insurer pays all attorneys’ fees that it incurs in the defense of the insured. The
obligation to defend and to pay for attorneys’ fees and necessary litigation expenses as supplementary
CHAPTER 12 MULTIRISK MANAGEMENT CONTRACTS: BUSINESS 271
payments ends when the insurer has reached the applicable limit of insurance in the payment of judg-
ments or settlements.
Who Is an Insured?
Section II of the CGL is very specific and detailed in defining whose liability is covered. The following
are insureds:
< An individual
< A partnership or joint venture
< A limited liability company
< An organization other than a partnership, joint venture, or limited liability company
< A trust
The volunteer workers of the business are also insured. However, none of the employees or volunteer
workers are insureds for bodily injury or personal and advertising injury to the insured or damage to
property that is owned or occupied by the insured.
Limits of Insurance
The limits of insurance, as you know by now, define the maximum responsibility of the insurer under
specified situations. A portion of the declaration for CGL is shown in Figure 12.14.
FIGURE 12.14 Section of the ISO Commercial General Liability Declaration Page ((Sample))
Source: ISO Commercial General Liability Coverage Form CG 00 0110 01. Includes copyrighted material of Insurance Services Office, Inc., with its
permission.
The policy clarifies the limits of insurance shown in the declarations and the applicable rules. The gen-
eral aggregate limit is the most that the insurer pays for the sum of
< medical expenses under Coverage C, plus
< damages under Coverage A, except damages because of “bodily injury” or “property damage”
included in the “products-completed operations hazard,” plus
< damages under Coverage B
The limits are paid regardless of the number of insureds, claims made, or suits brought, or persons or
organizations making claims or bringing suits. The limits apply separately to each consecutive annual
period.
CGL Conditions
Like all other policies, the CGL includes an extensive conditions section, primarily outlining the duties
of the insured and insurer. Subrogation, other insurance, proper action in the event of loss, and similar
provisions are spelled out in the conditions section.
Definitions
Words used in insurance policies might not have the same interpretation as when they are used in oth-
er documents or conversations. To specify its intent, insurers define significant terms (remember that
insurance is a contract of adhesion, so ambiguities are read in the manner most favorable to the in-
sured). Some defined terms in the CGL have already been discussed, including “bodily injury,”
“property damage,” “personal injury,” “advertising injury,” and “occurrence.” In total, twenty-two
272 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
terms are defined in the CGL. Like the rest of the policy, a full interpretation of coverage requires read-
ing and analyzing these definitions. The problems that arise out of interpretation of the CGL policy
wording is discussed in the box “Liability Limits: One Event or Two?”
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
In this section you studied the commercial general liability component of the CPP and the umbrella liability
option:
< The CGL format is similar to the BPP and BIC; it consists of the declaration form, coverage form, and any
endorsements.
< Five sections make up the CGL: coverages, who is an insured, limits of insurance, conditions, and
definitions.
< Coverages are available on either an occurrence or a claims-made basis for bodily injury and
property damage, personal and advertising injury, and medical payments, each subject to many
exclusions.
< The insureds can be an individual, a partnership/joint venture, limited liability company, an other
organization, or a trust.
< The limits of insurance provide clarification for limits shown in declarations and applicable rules
as follows: paid regardless of number of insureds, claims made, suits brought, or persons/
organizations making claims or bringing suits.
< Conditions outlines the duties of the insured and insurer.
< Definitions describes any term of policy in quotation marks.
< The standard limits for CGL may be inadequate for many businesses.
< The umbrella liability policy provides excess coverage above and beyond underlying insurance.
< The umbrella policy has the same coverages as the CGL except medical expense.
CHAPTER 12 MULTIRISK MANAGEMENT CONTRACTS: BUSINESS 273
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. Provide an example of expenses that would be covered under each of the three CGL coverages.
2. What responsibility does a CGL insurer have with regard to litigation expenses for a lawsuit that, if
successfully pursued by the plaintiff, would result in payment of damages under the terms of the policy?
3. How does personal injury differ from bodily injury?
4. Who needs an umbrella liability policy? Why?
5. Assume that the Baker-Leetch Pet Store has a CGL with a $1,000,000 aggregate limit. The policy
commences July 1, 2008, and ends June 30, 2009.
a. If claims-made, the retroactive date is July 1, 2007, and a one-year extended reporting period
applies. Under both occurrence and claims-made scenarios, would the following losses be
covered? The pet shop sold a diseased gerbil in August 2007. The gerbil ultimately infected the
owner’s twenty cats and dogs (kept for breeding purposes), who all died. The owner filed a
lawsuit against Baker-Leetch in September 2008. What if the lawsuit were filed in September
2009? September 2010?
b. The pet shop provided dog training in July 2008 and guaranteed the results of the training. In
December 2008, one of the trained dogs attacked a mail carrier, causing severe injuries. The mail
carrier immediately sued Baker-Leetch.
c. The pet store sold an inoculated rare and expensive cat in October 2008. The cat contracted a
disease in October 2009 that would not have occurred if the animal truly had been properly
inoculated. The owners sued in December 2009.
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
What about the business liability exposures not covered by the CGL? Space limitations prohibit dis-
cussing all of them, but several merit some attention: automobile, professional liability, and workers’
compensation. Workers’ compensation is discussed in more detail in Chapter 14.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
In this section you studied business liability exposures not covered by the CGL:
< In a proprietorship, if the only vehicles used are private passenger automobiles, the personal auto policy is
available; if the business uses other types of vehicles, other forms of automobile insurance must be
purchased.
< Most professionals insure professional liability exposure with malpractice insurance, errors and omissions
insurance, or directors and officers insurance (D&O).
< The Employment-Related Practices Liability Program covers liability for injury to employees because of
employment-related offenses and provides legal defense for the insured; injury may result from
discrimination that results in refusal to hire, failure to promote, termination, demotion, discipline, or
defamation.
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
because of Koehn’s use of toxins. (Consider the variation that an explosion emitted the
toxins rather than normal business operations.)
d. Koehn’s Mighty Mate Slicing Machine must be recalled because of a product defect. The
recall causes massive losses.
e. Based on information in this chapter, which parts of any of these losses are covered by
Koehn’s CGL? Explain your answer.
7. Provide a detailed rationale for excluding pollution, auto accidents, and liquor liability in the
CGL.
8. What is a BOP? What does it cover?
9. The Goldman Cat House is a pet store catering to the needs of felines. The store is a sole
proprietorship, taking in revenues of approximately $1,700,000 annually. Products available
include kittens, cat food, cat toys, cages, collars, cat litter and litter boxes, and manuals on cat
care. One manual was written by the store owner, who also makes up his own concoction for cat
litter. All other goods are purchased from national wholesalers. Two part-time and two full-time
employees work for Goldman. Sometimes the employees deliver goods to Goldman customers.
a. Identify some of Goldman Cat House’s liability exposures.
b. Would Goldman be best advised to purchase an occurrence-based or claims-made
liability policy?
c. What liability loss-control techniques would you recommend for Goldman?
CHAPTER 12 MULTIRISK MANAGEMENT CONTRACTS: BUSINESS 277
evaluate risk attitudes and risk behavior. Chapter 3 concentrated on risk management and methods for identifying,
measuring, and managing risks. In this chapter we elaborate further on the management of risk, placing greater
emphasis on the opportunities that risk represents. We emphasize prudent opportunities rather than actions
motivated by greed. When trying to identify the main causes of the 2008–2009 credit crisis, the lack of risk
management and prudent behavior emerge as key factors. However, even companies that were not part of the
debacle are paying the price, as the whole economy suffers a lack of credit and consumers’ entrenchment.
Consumers are less inclined to buy something that they don’t consider a necessity. As such, even firms with
prudent and well-organized risk management are currently seeing huge devaluation of their stocks.[1]
In many corporations, the head of the ERM effort is the chief risk officer or CRO. In other cases, the whole
executive team handles the risk management decision with specific coordinators. Many large corporations adopted
a system called Six Sigma, which is a business strategy widely adopted by many corporations to improve processes
and efficiency. Within this model of operation they embedded enterprise risk management. The ERM function at
Textron follows the latter model. Textron’s stock fell from $72 in January 2008 to $15 in December 2008. Let’s recall
that ERM includes every aspect of risks within the corporation, including labor negotiation risks, innovation risks,
lack-of-foresight risks, ignoring market condition risks, managing self-interest and greed risks, and so forth. Take the
case of the three U.S. auto manufacturers—GM, Chrysler, and Ford. Their holistic risks include not only insuring
buildings and automobiles or worker’s compensation. They must look at the complete picture of how to ensure
survival in a competitive and technologically innovative world. The following is a brief examination of the risk
factors that contributed to the near-bankrupt condition of the U.S. automakers: [2]
< Lack of foresight in innovation of fuel-efficient automobiles with endurance and sustainability of value.
< Too much emphasis on the demand for the moment rather than on smart projections of potential
catastrophes impacting fuel prices, like hurricanes Katrina, Wilma, and Ike.
< They did not account for an increase in the worldwide demand for use of fuel.
< Inability to compete in terms of quality control and manufacturing costs because of the labor unions’ high
wage demands. Shutting down individual initiatives and smart thinking. Everything was negotiated rather
< Allowing top management to stagnate into luxury and overspending, such as the personal planes in which
< The credit crisis of 2008 escalated the demise; it compounded the already mismanaged industry that didn’t
Had risk management been a top priority for the automobile companies, perhaps they would face a different
attitude as they approach U.S. taxpayers for their bailouts. ERM needs to be part of the mind-set of every company
stakeholder. When one arm of the company is pulling for its own gains without consideration of the total value it
delivers to stakeholders, the result, no doubt, will be disastrous. The players need to dance together under the
paradigm that every action might have the potential to lead to catastrophic results. The risk of each action needs to
1. Links
3. Risk management and the firm’s financial statement—opportunities within the ERM
1. LINKS
While Chapter 3 enumerated all risks, we emphasized the loss part more acutely, since avoiding losses
represents the essence of risk management. But, with the advent of ERM, the risks that represent op-
portunities for gain are clearly just as important. The question is always “How do we evaluate activities
in terms of losses and gains within the firm’s main goal of value maximization?” Therefore, we are go-
ing to look at maps that examine both sides—both gains and losses as they appear in Figure 13.1. We
operate on the negative and positive sides of the ERM map and we look into opportunity risks. We ex-
pand our puzzle to incorporate the firm’s goals. We introduce more sophisticated tools to ensure that
you are equipped to work with all elements of risk management for firms to sustain themselves.
Let us emphasize that, in light of the financial crisis of 2008–2009, ERM is a needed mind-set for all
disciplines. The tools are just what ERM-oriented managers can pull out of their tool kits. For example,
we provide an example for the life insurance industry as a key to understanding the links. We provide a
more complete picture of ERM in Figure 13.2.
282 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
FIGURE 13.2 Links between the Holistic Risk Picture and Conventional Risk and ERM Tools
Part C illustrates the interaction between parts A and B.
Source: Etti G. Baranoff and Thomas W. Sager, “Integrated Risk Management in Life Insurance Companies,” a $10,000 award-winning paper,
International Insurance Society Seminar, Chicago, July 2006 and in special edition of the Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance Issues and Practice.
CHAPTER 13 THE EVOLUTION OF RISK MANAGEMENT: ENTERPRISE RISK MANAGEMENT 283
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
< In this section you will learn how the ERM function integrates well into the firm’s main theoret-
ical and actual goal: to maximize value. We show a hypothetical example of ERM adding value
to a firm.
< We also discuss the ambiguities regarding the firm goals.
As you saw in Chapter 3, risk management functions represent an integrated function within the or-
chief risk officer (CRO)
ganization. In Figure 3.2, we map every risk. While the enterprise risk management (ERM) function
compiles the information, every function should identify risks and examine risk management tools. Part of the executive team
Finance departments may take the lead, but engineering, legal, product development, and asset man- responsible for all risk
elements in the organization.
agement teams also have input. The individual concerned with the organization’s ERM strategy is often
given the position chief risk officer (CRO). The CRO is usually part of the corporation’s executive
team and is responsible for all risk elements—pure and opportunity risks.
In this section, we illustrate in simple terms how the function integrates well into the firm’s goal to
maximize value. In terms of publicly traded corporations, maximizing value translates to maximizing
the company’s stock value. Even nonpublicly traded firms share the same goal. With nonpublicly
traded firms, the market isn’t available to explicitly recognize the company’s true value. Therefore,
people may interpret the term “firm’s value” differently with public versus nonpublic companies. In-
stead of the simple stock value, nonpublic firms may well create value using inputs such as revenues,
costs, or sources of financing (debt of equity). While “cash-rich” companies have greater value, they
may not optimally use their money to invest in growth and future income. External variables, such as
the 2008–2009 credit crisis, may well affect firm value, as can the weather, investors’ attitudes, and the
like. In 2008 and 2009, even strong companies felt the effects from the credit crisis. Textron and other
well-run companies saw their values plummet.
The inputs for a model that determines value allow us to examine how each input functions in the stockholders’ wealth
context of all the other variables.[3] Once we get an appropriate model, we can determine firms’ values
Value of equity held by the
and use these values to reach rational decisions. Traditionally, the drive for the firm to maximize value owners of a company plus
referred to the drive to maximize stockholders’ wealth. In other words, the literature referred to the income in the form of
maximization of the value of the firm’s shares (its market value, or the price of the stock times the dividends.
number of shares traded, for a publicly traded firm). This approach replaces the traditional concept of
market value
profits maximization, or expected profit maximization, enabling us to introduce risky elements and
statistical models into the decision-making process. We just have to decipher the particular model by For a public firm, the price of
the stock times the number
which we wish to calculate the firm’s value and to enumerate the many factors (including risk variables
of shares traded.
from the enterprise risk map) that may affect firm value. Actual market value should reflect all these
elements and includes all the information available to the market. This is the efficient-markets
hypothesis.
Recently, many developed countries have seen a tendency to change the rules of corporate gov- brand equity
ernance. Traditionally, many people believed that a firm should serve only its shareholders. However,
The value created by a
most people now believe that firms must satisfy the needs of all the stakeholders—including employees
company with a good
and their families, the public at large, customers, creditors, the government, and others. A company is a reputation and good
“good citizen” if it contributes to improving its communities and the environment. In some countries, products.
corporate laws have changed to include these goals. This newer definition of corporate goals and values
translates into a modified valuation formula/model that shows the firm responding to stakeholders’
needs as well as shareholder profits. These newly considered values are the hidden “good will” values
that are necessary in a company’s risk management. We assume that a firm’s market value reflects the
combined impact of all parameters and the considerations of all other stakeholders (employees, cus-
tomers, creditors, etc.) A firm’s brand equity entails the value created by a company with a good
reputation and good products. You may also hear the term a company’s “franchise value,” which is an
alternative term for the same thing. It reflects positive corporate responsibility image.
a gallon of gas, alternatives have emerged globally. At the time of writing this textbook, the cost of gas
had dropped significantly to as low as $1.50 per gallon at the pump, but the memory of the high prices,
along with the major financial crisis, is a major incentive to production of alternative energy sources
such as wind and sun. Fuel cost contributed in large part to the trouble that the U.S. automakers faced
in December because they had continued to produce large gas-guzzlers such as sport-utility vehicles
(SUVs) with minimal production of alternative gas-efficient cars like the Toyota Prius and Yaris, the
Ford Fusion hybrid, and the Chevrolet Avio. With the U.S. government bailout of the U.S. automobile
industry in December 2008 came a string of demands to modernize and to innovate with electric cars.
Further, the government made it clear that Detroit must produce competitive products already offered
by the other large automakers such as Toyota and Honda (which offered both its Accord and its Civic
in hybrid form).[4] Chevrolet will offer a plug-in car called the Volt in the spring of 2010 with a range of
more than 80 mpg on a single charge. Chrysler and Ford plan to follow with their own hybrids by 2012.
sustainability
World population growth and fast growth among emerging economies have led us to believer that
our environment has suffered immense and irrevocable damage.[5] Its resources have been depleted; its
The capacity to maintain a
certain process or state.
atmosphere, land, and water quickly polluted; and its water, forests, and energy sources destroyed. The
2005 United Nations Millennium Ecosystem report from 2005 provides a glimpse into our ecosystem’s
fast destruction. From a risk management point of view, these risks can destroy our universe, so their
management is essential to sustainability. Sustainability, in a broad sense, is the capacity to maintain
a certain process or state. It is now most frequently used in connection with biological and human sys-
tems. In an ecological context, sustainability can be defined as the ability of an ecosystem to maintain
ecological processes and functions.[6] Some risk management textbooks regard the risk management
for sustainability as the first priority, since doing business is irrelevant if we are destroying our planet
and undoing all the man-made achievements.
To reflect these considerations in practical decision making, we have to further adjust the defini-
tion and measurement of business goals. To be sensible, the firm must add a long-term perspective to
its goals to include sustainable value maximization.
We assume that the value of the firm is ten times the value of the profit,[9] or $1,000 in this very simple
example (10 × $100).[10] Now, assume that the firm considers a new risk management policy in which
$40 will be spent to improve safety (or insurance premiums). If all other factors are held constant, then
the firm’s profits will decrease, and the firm’s value will also decrease. In other words, in the simplistic
model of certainty, any additional expense would reduce the firm’s value and managers would, there-
fore, regard the situation as undesirable. It seems that in general, almost all risk management activities
would be undesirable, since they reduce the hypothetical firm’s value. However, this analysis ignores
some effects and, therefore, leads to incorrect conclusions. In reality, the risk manager takes an action
that may improve the state of the firm in many directions. Recall our demonstration of the safety belts
example that we introduced Chapter 3. Customers may increase their purchases from this firm, based
on their desire to trade with a more secure company, as its chances of surviving sudden difficulties im-
prove. Many also believe that, as the firm gains relief from its fears of risks, the company can improve
long-term and continuous service. Employees would feel better working for a more secure company
and could be willing to settle for lower salaries. In addition, bondholders (creditors) will profit from in-
creased security measures and thus would demand lower interest rates on the loans they provide (this
is the main effect of a high credit rating). Thus, risk management activity may affect a variety of para-
meters and change the expected profit (or cash flow) in a more complex way. We present the state of
this hypothetical firm as follows:
CHAPTER 13 THE EVOLUTION OF RISK MANAGEMENT: ENTERPRISE RISK MANAGEMENT 285
The profit (or expected profit) of the company has risen. If the owners continue to demand a tenfold
multiplication factor, then the firm’s value increases from $1,000 to $1,250. The increase is a direct res-
ult of the new risk management policy, despite the introduction of the additional risk management or
insurance costs. Note that the firm’s value has increased because other stakeholders (besides the own-
ers) have enjoyed a change of attitude toward the firm. The main stakeholders affected include the
credit suppliers in the capital market, the labor market and the product customers’ market. This did
not happen as a result of improving the security of the stockholders but as a result of other parties be-
nefiting from the firm’s new policy.
In fact, the situation could be even more interesting, if, in addition, the owners would be interested
in a more secure firm and would be willing to settle for a higher multiplier (which translates into lower
rate of return to the owners).[11] For example, if the new multiplier is eleven, the value of the firm
would go up to $1,375 (125 × 11), relative to the original value of $1,000, which was based on a multi-
plier of ten.
This oversimplified example sheds a light on the practical complexity of measuring the risk man-
ager’s performance, according to the modern approach. Top managers couldn’t evaluate the risk man-
ager’s performance without taking into account all the interactions between all the parties involved. In
reality, a precise analysis of this type is complicated, and risk managers would have a hard time estim-
ating if their policies are the correct ones. Let us stress that this analysis is extremely difficult if we use
only standard accounting tools, which are not sensitive enough to the possible interactions (e.g., stand-
ard accounting does not measure the fine changes that take place—such as the incremental effect of the
new risk management policy on the sales, the salaries, or the creditors’ satisfaction). We described this
innovative approach in hope that the student will understand the nature of the problem and perhaps
develop accounting tools that will present them with practical value.
Risk managers may not always clearly define their goals, because the firm’s goals are not always
clearly defined, especially for nonprofit organizations. Executives’ complex personal considerations,
management coalitions, company procedures, past decisions, hopes, and expectations enter into the
mix of parameters defining the firm’s goals. These types of considerations can encourage risk managers
to take conservative action. For example, risk managers may buy too much insurance for risks that the
firm could reasonably retain. This could result from holding the risk manager personally responsible
for uninsured losses. Thus, it’s very important not to create a conflict between the risk managers’ in-
terests and the firm’s interests. For example, the very people charged with monitoring mortgage issu-
ance risk, the mortgage underwriters and mortgage bankers, had a financial incentive (commissions) to
issue the loans regardless of the intrinsic risks. The resulting subprime mortgage crisis ensued because
of the conflict of interest between mortgage underwriters and mortgage bankers. This situation created
the starting point for the 2008–2009 financial crisis.
Risk managers must ascertain—before the damage occurs—that an arrangement will provide equi-
librium between resources needed and existing resources. The idea is to secure continuity despite
losses. As such, the risk manager’ job is to evaluate the firm’s ability or capacity to sustain (absorb)
damages. This job requires in-depth knowledge of the firm’s financial resources, such as credit lines, as-
sets, and insurance arrangements. With this information risk managers can compare alternative meth-
ods for handling the risks. We describe these alternative methods in the next section.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
< In this section you studied the interrelationship between firms’ goals to maximize value and the
contributions of the enterprise risk management function to such goals.
< We used a hypothetical income statement of a company.
< We also discussed the challenges in achieving firms’ goals under stakeholders’ many conflicting objectives.
286 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. Discuss the different firm goals that companies seek to fulfill in the late 2000s.
2. How does the risk management function contribute to firm goals?
3. Find a company’s income statement and show how the enterprise risk management functions contribute
at least two actions to increase the firm’s value.
4. How might firm stakeholders’ goals conflict? How might such conflicting goals affect value maximization
objectives?
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
< In this section you will learn the tasks of the enterprise risk managers (ERM) function as it
relates to the balance sheet of the firm annual statement.
< The ERM function manages and ensures sustainability by preventing losses and providing op-
portunities within the risk matrix.
< Using hypothetical balance sheets, the student learns the actual ERM functions of both finan-
cial and nonfinancial firms.
< Our exploration of financial firms uncovers some of the causes of the 2008–2009 financial crisis.
The enterprise risk manager or CRO must understand the risks inherent in both sides of the balance
balance sheet
sheet of the firm’s financial statements. A balance sheet provides a snapshot of a firm’s assets and li-
Document that provides a abilities. We show a balance sheet for a nonfinancial firm in Table 13.3. Table 13.5 then shows a bal-
snapshot of a firm’s assets
and liabilities.
ance sheet for an insurance company. Firms must produce annual financial reports including their bal-
ance sheets and income statements. Together, we call income statements and balance sheets financial
financial statements statements. While we focused in the section above on a simplified hypothetical income statement,
Income statements and now we focus on the assets and liabilities as they appear at a certain point. With this ammunition at
balance sheets. hand, we will be able to explain why financial institutions created so many problems during the
2008–2009 credit crisis. You will be able to explain AIG’s major problems and why the government
ended up bailing it out, along with many other financial institutions. The question that you will be able
to answer is, “What side of the balance sheet did AIG fail to manage appropriately?”
TABLE 13.3 Hypothetical Retail and Wholesaler Fashion Apparel Balance Sheet—(Risks and ERM)
Assets Liabilities and Owners’ Equity
Cash (loss of use risks) $8,000 Liabilities
Accounts Receivable (customers quality, $28,000 Notes Payable (cash flow, foreign exchange $50,000
foreign exchange and interest rate risks) and interest rate risks)
Accounts Payable and the mortgage on the $90,000
building (real estate crisis, cash flow, and
interest rate risks)
Buildings (asset risk) $100,000 Total liabilities $140,000
Tools, furniture, inventory, and equipment $27,000 Owners’ equity
(asset risk and opportunity asset risk in
store design)
Capital Stock $17,000
Retained Earnings $6,000
Total owners’ equity $23,000
Total $163,000 Total $163,000
Based on Table 13.3, we can list some areas for which enterprise risk managers (ERMs) need to involve
themselves for risk mitigation. Note, these loss risks do not. As part of the executive team, enterprise
risk managers regard all activities, including any involvement in opportunity risks that carry the poten-
tial of gains as discussed in Chapter 1.
Examples of ERM activities generated from the assets and the liabilities on the balance sheet are as
follows:
< Building risk: The ERM or CRO has to keep all company buildings safe and operational. Most, if capital structure
not all, companies carry insurance on all real property. We will discuss the reasons later in the A firm’s choice between debt
text. However, this represents only part of the CRO’s activities. The risk management manual and equity.
should give directions for how to take care of weather-related potential damages, or losses from
fires or other perils. Furthermore, the risk manager should be involved in any discussions of how
to convert some building parts into income–producing opportunities. This will entail carefully
assessing potential cash flow streams from reliable and careful tenants, not only from their
capacity to pay potential, but also from their capacity to keep losses at an absolute minimum. The
CRO or ERM takes on the capital budgeting function and computes net present values with the
appropriate risk factors, as shown in Chapter 3 with the example of the safety belts. They need to
include some risk factors to measure tenant quality in terms of both paying the rent and
maintaining the properties properly.
< Accounts Receivables and Notes Due: ERMs and CROs must create procedures to ensure that the
accounts receivables can be collected and remain in good standing. This is key to
sustainability—the ability to maintain expected cash flows. In addition, since the Fashion
Apparel’s customers are from other countries, the decision of what currency to use is very
important. As far as currency risk is concerned, the risk officer must negotiate with the suppliers
and designers to set a mutually beneficial currency. This mutually beneficial currency will provide
a very important means to pay the firm’s suppliers and global designers. The risk manager can
use currency derivatives to hedge/mitigate the currency risk. Also, if the company uses credit to
maintain inventory for the long term, the ERM procedures should include ways to handle interest
rate risk on both sides. Such interest rate risk would affect both receivables and payments to
vendors, designers, and suppliers. To ensure liquidity, many companies create interest-bearing
credit lines from banks—as long as the interest rates are in line with what can be collected in the
accounts receivable. The firm has to borrow money to create the cash flows to pay salaries and
buy new inventory. At the same time, the firm receives interest from clients. These transactions
create a need for interest-rate management while it is receiving interest from clients, there needs
to be interest risk management, such as using swaps, which is explained in detail with an example
in the next section of this chapter.
< If used correctly, the swap derivative can act as insurance to mitigate interest rate risk. The
interest rate used for borrowing and lending must make sense in terms of the management of
accounts receivable and notes due on the liabilities side of the balance sheet. See Figure 13.1
showing the gains and losses that can occur because of interest rate and currency risks. They can
also provide opportunities if handled with appropriate risk management. Note that the ability to
obtain lines of credit from banks and suppliers and extend credit to customers is an integral part
of the working of the cash flow of the firm. Indeed the credit crisis of 2008–2009 occurred in part
288 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
because banks and other creditors lost confidence in the counterparty’s ability to pay, and the
credit markets “froze.” This led to insolvencies, declines in stock value, and a general recession.
< Tools, furniture, and inventory: ERMs must take account of the traffic flow in the show room
because they will want to establish sustainability and opportunities to make money. They must
ensure that halls provide safety designs as well as fashion statements and innovative and creative
designs to enhance visibility of the merchandise. Thus, while the risk manager is involved in
avoiding or reducing losses, he/she is also involved in the opportunities. For example, it may be
risky to hang some of the merchandise from the ceilings with wind tunnels that accentuate the
flow of the fabrics, but it may also increase sales dramatically if the right effects are achieved.
CROs must manage the opportunity risk (the chance to make money) with the appropriate risk
factors as they compute the capital budget.
< Accounts Payable including the Mortgage on the Buildings → Capital Structure: Until the real
estate crisis of 2008, real estate investments were stable. However, the CRO, working with other
managers, must decide whether to purchase large assets with debt or equity from investors. The
financing method is very important and it is regarded as the capital structure of the firm—the
choice between debt and equity. In this company, the Apparel Designer, the building was
purchased with a large mortgage (debt). The mortgage amount due is not subject to reduction
unless paid. But, the buildings can decline in value, and at the same time the company’s net worth
can be in jeopardy, with potentially catastrophic consequences. If our hypothetical example was a
publicly traded company, it would have to show at the end of each year the true value of
buildings—the market value. Under this scenario, with so much debt and so little owner’s equity,
the balance sheet can show the firm as insolvent. The CRO or risk manager must address the
company’s capital structure issue and point out the risks of taking large mortgages on buildings,
since the properties may lose their value. The capital structure decision creates a need for
managers to choose between financing property with debt versus equity. This tradeoff is a tricky
one to negotiate. If the firm uses equity, it may be underinvested. If it uses debt, it runs the risk of
insolvency. For example, we know that before the 2008 financial crisis, many firms used too
much debt, leading to sustainability issues and liquidation, such as Circuit City.[12]
Capital structure decisions as well as the nature of debt and its covenants (the details of the contracts
covenants
and promises between the debt contract parties), accounts receivables, and notes have been under the
The details of the contracts
domain of the finance or treasury department of companies with a new breed of financial risk man-
and promises between the
debt contract parties. agers. These risk managers are responsible for managing the risk of the investments and assets of the
firms using tools such as Value at Risk (VaR; discussed in Chapter 2) and capital markets instruments
financial risk managers such as derivatives as explained in Chapter 2 and will be detailed in the next section of this chapter.
Managers responsible for Currently, the trend is to move financial risk management into the firm-wide enterprise risk
managing the risk of the management.
investments and assets of a
firm.
CHAPTER 13 THE EVOLUTION OF RISK MANAGEMENT: ENTERPRISE RISK MANAGEMENT 289
TABLE 13.5 A Hypothetical Balance Sheet of a Hypothetical Life Insurance Firm with Its Asset asset allocation
Allocation Mix (in Millions of Dollars)—Risks and ERM The mix of assets held by an
insurer.
Assets Liabilities and Capital and Surplus
Bonds: risks of junk bonds and $1,800 Loans and advances $10 liability accounts
nonperforming, mortgage-backed
securities. Reserves held on balance
sheets to cover future claims
Stocks: risks of the market 990 Life insurance and annuities reserves [risk of catastrophes 950 and other obligations, such as
fluctuations and miscalculations by actuaries (longevity risk) and lack of
taxes and premium reserves.
underwriting
Mortgages: risk of nonperforming 260 Pension fund reserves: risk of inability to keep the promises 1,200 capital and surplus
mortgages, no liquidity of the guarantees The equivalent of equity on
Real Estate: risks of real estate 50 Taxes payable 25 the balance sheet of any
collapse and lack of liquidity firm—the net worth of the
firm, or assets minus liabilities.
Policy Loans: risk of inability of 110 Miscellaneous liabilities 650
policyholders to pay
Miscellaneous 120 Total Liabilities 2,835
Capital and Surplus $495
Total 3,330 Total $3,330
The hypothetical life insurer in Table 13.5 represents a typical insurer in the United States with a larger
percentage of investment in bonds and mortgages and less investment in stocks. The ERM joins the ex-
ecutive team and regards all activities, including firm undertakings in opportunity and financial risks.
290 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
Therefore, the risk manager works also as a financial risk manager on the side of the insurer’s asset al-
location and capital structure questions. Examples of ERM activities generated from the assets and liab-
ilities on the balance sheet are as follows:
actuaries < Risks from the liabilities: The liabilities comprise mostly reserves for claims on the products sold
Individuals who specialize in by the life insurer. The products here are life and annuities (this insurance company does not sell
forecasting the losses and health insurance). Most of the reserves are for these products. The reserves are computed by
developing the losses’ actuaries, who specialize in forecasting the losses and developing the losses’ potential future
potential future impact on impact on the insurers. Actuaries use mortality tables and life expectancy tables to estimate the
the insurers. future losses that the insurer must pay. Mortality tables indicate the percent of expected deaths
mortality tables for each age group. Life expectancy shows the length of life expected for people born in each
Tables that indicate the year. Chapter 1 delves into this topic in detail. Usually, life insurance firms maintain a high level
percent of expected deaths of expertise in selling products to people and categorizing them in similar risk levels. Insurance
for each age group. underwriters develop specialized expertise to ensure that the insurer does not sell the products
too cheaply for the risks that the insurer accepts. As such, the enterprise risk manager depends on
life expectancy
the actuarial and underwriting expertise to ensure the liabilities side of the business is well
Measure of the length of life managed. If the reserve calculations miss the mark, the insurer can become insolvent very quickly
expected for people born in
and lose the capital and surplus, which is its net worth.[13]
each year.
< Risks from the asset mix: The enterprise risk manager or CRO should ensure that the insurer’s
investment portfolio or asset mix can perform and sustain its value. Our hypothetical life insurer
posted $1,800 million in bonds. The mix of these bonds is critical, especially during the recent
2008–2009 global crisis (described in Chapter 1). The amount of mortgage-backed securities
(MBS) within the bonds is very critical, especially if these MBS are nonperforming and lose their
value. As it turns out, the balance sheet we provided above represents a time before the credit
crisis of 2008. This hypothetical insurer held 10 percent of its bonds in MBS and half of them
turned into nonperforming assets by the end of 2008. This translates into $90 million of lost
assets value in 2008. In addition, the stock market collapse took its toll and the 2008 market value
of the stocks decreased by 30.33 percent. Investment professionals worked with a CRO to ensure
a much lower decrease than the market indexes. They ensured that the stock portfolio was more
conservative. If we assume that all other liabilities and assets did not suffer any additional loss, the
capital and surplus of this hypothetical insurer will be almost wiped out at the end of 2008.[14]
$495 − 90 − 330 = $75 worth of capital and surplus
As an insurer, the firm faces an outcome to the ERM function, since underwriting is a critical compon-
due diligence
ent for the insurer’s sustainability. Here, the balance sheet would show that the insurer invested in
The process of examining mortgage-backed securities (MBS), not doing its underwriting work itself. The insurers allowed the in-
every action and items in the vestment professionals to invest in financial instruments that did not underwrite the mortgage holders
financial statement of
companies to ensure the data
prudently. If the CRO was in charge completely, he would have known how to apply the expertise of
reflect true value. the liabilities side into the expertise of the assets side and would have demanded clear due diligence in-
to the nature of MBS. Warren Buffet, the owner of insurance companies, said he did not trust MBS and
did not invest in such instruments in his successful and thriving businesses. Due diligence examines
every action and items in the financial statement of companies to ensure the data reflect true value.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y S
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. Find the balance sheet of a company such as Best Buy and analyze all the risk and ERM from the assets
side and from the liabilities side. Create a list of actions for the ERM function.
2. Find the balance sheet of Bank of America from 2006 or 2007 and analyze all the risk and ERM from the
assets side and from the liabilities side. Create a list of actions for the ERM function.
3. Introduce the 2008–2009 credit crisis to both companies in questions 1 and 2. Explain the impact on the
net worth of these companies. What actions you would suggest to incorporate in the ERM function?
L E A R N I N G O B J E C T I V E S
< In this section you will learn how the ERM function can incorporate the capital markets’ instru-
ments, such as derivatives.
< You also learn though a case how swaps can help mitigate the interest rate risk of a bank.
Enterprise risk management has emerged from the following steps of maturation:
< Risk management using insurance as discussed briefly in Chapter 3 and will be the topic of the
rest of the book
< Explosive growth in technology and communications
< Development of quantitative techniques and models to measure risk (shown in Chapter 2)
< Evolution of the financial markets and financial technology into hedging of risks
These mechanisms combine to create a direct connection between the firm’s overall appetite for risk, as
set in company objectives, and choosing appropriate corporate-level for solutions in mitigating risks.
Forward/Future Purchase
Forwards and futures are similar in that they are agreements that obligate the owner of the instrument
forwards
to buy or sell an asset for a specified price at a specified time in the future. Forwards are traded in the
over-the-counter market, and contract characteristics can be tailored to meet specific customer needs. Financial securities traded in
the over-the-counter market
Farmers and grain elevator operators also use forwards to lock in a price for their corn or soybeans or whose characteristics can be
wheat. They may choose to lock in the basis, which is the amount of money above and beyond the fu- tailored to meet specific
tures price. Alternatively, if they like (believe that the prices are at their highest likely levels) the futures’ customer needs.
price levels, they can lock in the entire price. Food and beverage companies use forwards to lock in
basis
their costs for grains and fruits and vegetables. Quaker Oats, for example, locks in the prices on corn
and oats using forward contracts with growers. Anheuser Busch depends upon forwards to lock in the The amount of money above
price of hops, rice, and other grains used to make beer. Dole fruit companies use forwards to price out and beyond the futures price.
pineapples, raspberries, grapes, and other fruits.
292 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
futures
Futures, on the other hand, trade on an exchange with standardized contract specifications. For-
wards and futures prices derive from the spot, or cash market, which is “today’s” price for a particular
Financial securities that trade asset. An example of a spot contract would be your agreement to purchase a meal at a restaurant. The
on an exchange and that
have standardized contract
spot market is the quoted price on today’s menu. A futures or forwards market would be the price you
specifications. would have to pay if you wanted the same meal one year from today. Getting back to our cereal manu-
facturer, Frosty O’s can either go to the spot market on an ongoing basis or use the forwards/futures
market to contract to buy wheat in the future at an agreed-upon price. Buying in the spot market cre-
ates exposure to later price fluctuation. Buying in the forwards/futures market allows the manufacturer
to guarantee future delivery of the wheat at a locked-in price. Hence, this strategy is known as a “lock it
in” defense. Southwest Airlines’ strategy to buy oil futures during the fuel crisis of 2007–2008 allowed
them to be the only profitable airline. On the other side, Continental Airline is suffering from buying
aviation fuel futures when the price of oil subsequently declined dramatically. Thus, the use of futures
and forwards can create value or losses, depending upon the timing of its implementation.
Swaps
swaps
Swaps are agreements to exchange or transfer expected future variable-price purchases of a commod-
ity or foreign exchange contract for a fixed contractual price today. In effect, Frosty O’s buys wheat and
Agreements to exchange or swaps its expected “floating” price exposure for wheat at different times in the future for a fixed rate
transfer expected future
variable-price purchases of a
cost. For example, if Frosty O’s normally buys wheat on the first of each month, the company will have
commodity or foreign to pay whatever the spot price of wheat is on that day. Frosty O’s is exposed to market price fluctu-
exchange contract for a fixed ations for each of the twelve months over a year’s time period. It can enter into a transaction to pay a
contractual price today. fixed monthly rate over a year’s time period instead of whatever the floating spot rate may be each
month. The net effect of the swap transaction is to receive the necessary wheat allotment each month
while paying a fixed, predetermined rate. The swap rate quote would be fixed using the spot market
and the one-year forward market for wheat. Thus Frosty O’s eliminates any adverse price exposure by
switching the “floating” price exposure for an agreed-upon fixed price. Swaps are used in the same
manner to exchange floating interest rate liabilities for fixed-interest rate liabilities. Hence, this strategy
is known as a “switch out of it” defense. We will show an elaborate swaps example at the end of this
section.
Options
Agreements that give the right (but not the obligation) to buy or sell an underlying asset at a specified
options
price at a specified time in the future are known as options. Frosty O’s can purchase an option to buy
Agreements that give the the wheat it needs for production at a given strike price. The strike price (also called exercise price) is
right (but not the obligation)
to buy or sell an underlying
the specified price set in the option contract. In this fashion, Frosty O’s can place a ceiling on the price
asset at a specified price at a it will pay for the needed wheat for production in future time periods. Until the maturity date of the
specified time in the future. option passes, option holders can exercise their rights to buy wheat at the strike price. If the future spot
price of wheat rises above the strike price, Frosty O’s will execute its option to purchase the wheat at
the lower strike price. If the future price of wheat falls below the strike price, the company will not ex-
ercise its option and will instead purchase wheat directly in the spot market. This differentiates the op-
tion contract from the futures contract. An option is the right to buy or sell, whereas a futures/forward
contract is an obligation to buy of sell. The option buyer pays the cost of the option to buy wheat at the
strike price—also known as the option premium. A call option grants the right to buy at the strike
price. A put option grants the right to sell at the strike price. A call option acts like insurance to provide
an upper limit on the cost of a commodity. A put option acts like insurance to protect a floor selling
price for wheat. Hence, option strategies are known as “cap” and “floor” defenses.[15]
Individuals and companies alike use derivative instruments to hedge against their exposure to un-
predictable loss due to price fluctuations. The increasing availability of different derivative products has
armed enterprise risk managers (ERM) with new risk management tool solutions. An importer of raw
materials can hedge against changes in the exchange rate of the U.S. dollar relative to foreign curren-
cies. An energy company can hedge using weather derivatives to protect against adverse or extreme
weather conditions. And a bank can hedge its portfolio against interest rate risk. All of these risk expos-
ures interrupt corporate cash flow and affect earnings, capital, and the bottom line, which is the value
of the firm. These solutions, however, create new risk exposures. Over-the-counter market-traded de-
rivatives, which feature no exchange acting as counterparty to the trade, expose a company to credit
risk in that the counter party to the contract may not live up to its side of the obligation.
the last worst-case scenarios. Past fears of multiple noncorrelated catastrophic events occurring in a rel-
atively short period of time are on the top of agendas of catastrophe risk modelers and all constituen-
cies responsible for national disaster management. The affordability of coverage, along with reinsurers’
credit quality concerns players who have lost large chunks of capital and surplus or equity to those dis-
asters led to the first foray into using the capital markets as a reinsurance alternative.[16]
Securitization
Packaging and transferring the insurance risks to the capital markets through the issuance of a financial
securitization
security is termed securitization.[17] The risks that have been underwritten are pooled together into a
bundle, which is then considered an asset and the underwriter then sells its shares; hence, the risk is Packaging and transferring
the insurance risks to the
transferred from the insurers to the capital markets. Securitization made a significant difference in the capital markets through the
way insurance risk is traded—by making it a commodity and taking it to the capital markets in addi- issuance of a financial
tion to or instead of to the insurance/reinsurance market. Various insurance companies’ risks for simil- security.
ar exposures in diversified locations are combined in one package that is sold to investors (who may
also include insurers). Securitized catastrophe instruments can help a firm or an individual to diversify counterparty risk
risk exposures when reinsurance is limited or not available. Because global capital markets are so vast, Risk of loss from failure of a
they offer a promising means of funding protection for even the largest potential catastrophes. Capital counterparty, or second
market solutions also allow the industry (insurers and reinsurers) to reduce credit risk exposure, also party, in a derivatives contract
to perform as agreed or
known as counterparty risk. This is the risk of loss from failure of a counterparty, or second party, in contracted.
a derivatives contract to perform as agreed or contracted. Capital market solutions also diversify fund-
ing sources by spreading the risk across a broad spectrum of capital market investors. Securitization in- insurance-linked securities
struments are also called insurance-linked securities (ISLs). They include catastrophe bonds, cata- General term for
strophe risk exchange swaps, insurance-related derivatives/options, catastrophe equity puts (Cat-E- securitization instruments.
Puts), contingent surplus notes, collateralized debt obligations (CDOs),[18] and weather derivatives.
Catastrophe bonds, or CAT bonds, seek to protect the insurance industry from catastrophic catastrophe bonds
events. The bonds pay interest and return principal to investors the way other debt securities do—as
Bonds that seek to protect
long as the issuer does not experience losses above an agreed-upon limit. Insurers can come to the cap- the insurance industry from
ital market to issue bonds that are tied to a single peril, or even to a portfolio or basket of risks. Embed- catastrophic events.
ded in each issue is a risk trigger that, in the event of catastrophic loss, allows for forgiveness of interest
and/or principal repayment.
have a loss, the bonds will pay, but you still have the exposure. The question is whether you’ll be able to float
another bond issue to cover it the next time something happens. Reinsurers are expected to stick around and
still write coverage after a loss, but can the same be said with CAT bond investors?” Apparently, the answer is
“yes,” as evidenced from the substantial growth of this risk capital from an estimated $4.04 billion in 2004 to
approximately $6 billion in 2005. The biggest fear of the CAT bonds owners in the aftermath of Katrina did not
materialize. The insured losses from Katrina did not exceed the agreed level.
Sources: Andrew Osterland, “The CATs Are out of the Bag,” BusinessWeek, January 26, 1998; Douglas McLeod, “Cat Bonds to Grow: Increasing Frequency
of Losses Will Contribute: S&P,” Business Insurance, July 12 1999, 2; Mike Hanley, “Cat Bond Market Almost There,” International Risk Management, 8,
no. 1 (2001); Sam Friedman, “There’s More than One Way to Skin a Cat,” National Underwriter, Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits Management
Edition, May 8, 2000; Mark E. Ruquet “CAT Bonds Grew 17 Percent In ‘04” National Underwriter Online News Service, April 1, 2005; Richard Beales and
Jennifer Hughes, “Katrina Misses Cat Bond Holders,” Financial Times, August 31, 2005 at http://news.ft.com/cms/s/
59e21066-1a66-11da-b7f5-00000e2511c8.html.
An example of a CAT bond is the issue by Oriental Land Company Ltd., owner and operator of Tokyo
Disneyland. Oriental Land used CAT bonds to finance one facility providing earthquake coverage and
the other to provide standby financing to continue a $4 billion expansion of the theme park. Each facil-
ity raised $100 million via the bond market to cover property risk exposure and subsequent indirect
business interruption loss in case of catastrophic loss from an earthquake. The trigger event was for an
earthquake, regardless of whether the event caused any direct physical damage to the park.[19] For more
about how CAT bonds provide protection, see “The CAT Bond Story” in this chapter.
catastrophe equity puts With catastrophe equity puts (Cat-E-Puts), the insurer has the option to sell equity (e.g., pre-
(Cat-E-Puts) ferred shares) at predetermined prices, contingent upon the catastrophic event. Contingent surplus
Financial instrument that notes are options to borrow money in case of a specific event. Collateralized debt obligations
gives an insurer the option to (CDOs) are securities backed by a pool of diversified assets; these are referred to as collateralized bond
sell equity (e.g., preferred obligations (CBOs) when the underlying assets are bonds and as collateralized loan obligations (CLOs)
shares) at predetermined
when the underlying assets are bank loans.[20] Weather derivatives are derivative contracts that pay
prices, contingent upon the
catastrophic event. based on weather-related events. All are examples of financial market instruments that have been used
to transfer risk and to provide risk-financing vehicles.[21]
contingent surplus notes Investors’ advantages in insurance-linked securities are diversification, as these instruments allow
Options to borrow money in noninsurance investors to participate in insurance-related transactions and above-average rates of re-
case of a specific event. turn. Advantages to the issuers of such instruments include greater capacity and access to the capital
collateralized debt
markets. Insurance-linked securities provide issuers with more flexibility and less reliance on rein-
obligations (CDOs) surers. The presence of new instruments stabilizes reinsurance pricing and provides higher levels of
risk transfer with cutting-edge understanding for both insurance and capital markets.
Securities backed by a pool of
diversified assets.
We have shown that enterprise risk management (ERM) for a corporation is indeed complex. Full
enterprise-wide risk management entails folding financial risk management into the CRO’s department
weather derivatives responsibilities. A chief risk officer’s role is multifaceted. Today, risk managers develop goals to widen
Derivative contracts that pay the understanding of risk management so that employees take into account risk considerations in their
based on weather-related day-to-day operations. Risk awareness has become imperative to the overall health of the organization.
events. Sound practices must incorporate the advancements on the technology front so that companies can
compete in the global environment. Viewing all integrated segments of risk from across the enterprise
in a holistic manner facilitates a global competitive advantage.
History
In the early years of U.S. banking history, banks seemed to have the easiest job in the corporate world.
All a bank manager had to do was receive deposits in the form of checking, savings, and deposit ac-
counts (bank liabilities), and provide mortgage and other lending services (bank assets). Throughout
the twentieth century, the banking industry prospered. For most of the post–World War II era the
upward-sloping yield curve meant that interest rates on traditional thirty-year residential mortgage
CHAPTER 13 THE EVOLUTION OF RISK MANAGEMENT: ENTERPRISE RISK MANAGEMENT 295
loans exceeded rates on shorter-term savings and time deposits.[23] The positive net margin between
the two rates accounted for banks’ prosperity. All of this ended abruptly when the Federal Reserve
changed its monetary policy in October 1979 to one of targeting bank reserves instead of interest rates.
Figure 13.3 and Figure 13.4 provide a historical perspective of interest rates.
Source: http://www.Economagic.com. Economagic includes the original data source: U.S. Government, Federal Reserve Board of Governors historical
monthly interest rate series.
Source: http://www.Economagic.com. Economagic includes the original data source: U.S. Government, Federal Reserve Board of Governors historical
monthly interest rate series.
Figure 13.3 and Figure 13.4 graphically present interest rate risk exposure that banks face. The notice-
able change is the absolute pickup in interest rate volatility from 1979 forward. As Figure 13.4 shows,
three-month T-bill interest rates reached above 16 percent in the early 1980s. Yet many banks’ assets
were locked into low-interest, long-term loans, mostly thirty-year mortgages. The financial crisis that
followed the rapid rise in interest rates (on both short- and long-term liabilities) was catastrophic in
proportion; many banks failed by positioning their loan portfolios incorrectly for the change in interest
rates. Locked-in long-term mortgage loan rates provided insufficient cash inflows to meet the higher
cash outflows required on deposits. Those that survived had to make major changes in their risk
296 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
management style. Later we will introduce how a specific bank, Hometown Bank, manages its interest
rate exposure using derivatives.
“Modern banks employ credit-scoring techniques to ensure that they are making good lending de-
cisions, use analytical models to monitor the performance of their loan portfolios, and implement fin-
ancial instruments to transfer out those credit risks with which they are not comfortable.”[24] Bankers
learned a costly lesson in the 1980s by not being adequately prepared for a changing interest rate envir-
onment. Risk management must be enterprise-wide and inclusive of all components of risk. Homet-
own Bank is a surviving bank, with lofty goals for the future. The current focus for CEO John Allen has
three components:
1. Review the primary elements of Hometown’s financial risks:
< Interest rate risk—those risks associated with changes in interest rates
< Market risk—risk of loss associated with changes in market price or value
< Credit risk—risk of loss through customer default
2. Review Hometown’s nonfinancial, or operational, risks: those risks associated with the operating
processes or systems in running a bank
3. Monitor the success of risk mitigation techniques the bank employs
Asset growth has occurred both internally and externally with the acquisition of community banks and
branches in Hometown’s market. Market domain expanded to include the capital region (the city of
Richmond and surrounding counties), the Tidewater region, the Shenandoah Valley region, and the
northern Virginia markets. In March 2002, Hometown Bank opened its twenty-fifth branch, in Virgin-
ia Beach, Virginia. With total assets of approximately $785 million (as of December 2001), Hometown
ranks as the eighth largest commercial bank in the state of Virginia. The network of branches offers a
wide range of lending and deposit services to business, government, and consumer clients. The use of
these deposits funds both the loan and investment portfolio of the bank. Principal sources of revenue
are interest and fees on loans and investments and maintenance fees for servicing deposit accounts.
Principal expenses include interest paid on deposits and other borrowings and operating expenses.
Corporate goals include achieving superior performance and profitability, gaining strategic market
share, and providing superior client service. Hometown has achieved its fifth consecutive year of record
earnings. Table 13.7 shows Hometown’s consolidated financial statements from 1999 to 2001.
CHAPTER 13 THE EVOLUTION OF RISK MANAGEMENT: ENTERPRISE RISK MANAGEMENT 297
TABLE 13.7 Hometown Bancorp and Subsidiaries Financial Statements (in Thousands)
2001 2000 1999
Consolidated Balance Sheet
Interest-earning assets
Money market investments $62,800 $49,600 $39,100
Investment securities 65,500 51,700 40,800
Loans 649,300 513,000 405,000
Allowance for loan losses (11,300) (7,600) (6,000)
Premises, furniture, & equipment 14,900 11,700 10,000
Other real estate 3,800 3,000 2,500
Total assets $785,000 $621,400 $491,400
Interest-bearing liabilities
Deposits $467,500 $369,300 $292,000
Other short-term borrowings 123,000 97,000 76,700
non-interest borrowings 117,000 92,400 73,000
Long-term debt 12,900 10,000 8,200
Total liabilities $720,400 $568,700 $449,900
Shareholders’ equity 64,600 $52,700 41,500
Total liabilities and shareholders equity $785,000 $621,400 $491,400
Thus, when assets grow more than liabilities, shareholder value also increases. Hometown Bank’s as-
sets, as noted on its consolidated balance sheet in Table 13.7, primarily consist of loans; at year-end
2001, $649 million of Hometown’s $785 million total assets were in the form of loans (see Table 13.8
for loan portfolio composition). Hometown obtains funding for these loans from its deposit base. Note
that for Hometown Bank, as for all banks, deposit accounts are recorded as liabilities. Hometown Bank
has an outstanding obligation to its deposit customers to give the money back. For Hometown, depos-
its make up $467.5 million, or 65 percent, of total outstanding liabilities. The mismatch between depos-
its and loans is each element’s time frame. Hometown’s main asset category, retail mortgage loans, has
long-term maturities, while its main liabilities are demand deposits and short-term CDs, which have
immediate or short-term maturities.
TABLE 13.8 Loan Portfolio Composition, Hometown Bancorp (in Thousands)
2001 Amount ($) % 2000 Amount ($) % 1999 Amount ($) %
Construction and land development
Residential 32,465 5 30,780 6 28,350 7%
Commercial 32,465 5 25,650 5 20,250 5
Other 12,986 2 20,520 4 16,200 4
Mortgage
Residential 331,143 51 241,110 47 182,250 45
Commercial 110,381 17 82,080 16 81,000 20
Commercial and industrial 32,465 5 41,040 8 24,300 6
Consumer 97,395 15 71,820 14 52,650 13
Total Loans Receivable 649,300 100 513,000 100 405,000 100
Hometown’s net cash outflows represent payments of interest on deposits. Because of the deposits’
short-term maturities, these interest payments are subject to frequent changes. Demand depositors’ in-
terest rates can change frequently, even daily, to reflect current interest rates. Short-term CDs are also
subject to changes in current interest rates because the interest rate paid to customers changes at each
maturity date to reflect the current market. If bank customers are not happy with the new rate offered
by the bank, they may choose not to reinvest their CD. Interest rate risk for Hometown Bank arises
from its business of lending long-term, with locked-in interest rates, while growing their loan portfolio
with short-term borrowings like CDs, with fluctuating interest rates. This risk has increased dramatic-
ally because of the increase in interest rate volatility. During the period of January 2001 through Octo-
ber 2002, three-month treasury bills traded in a range from 6.5 percent to 1.54 percent. (Refer to Figure
13.3). During periods of inverted yield curves (where longer-term investments have lower interest rates
than short-term investments), a bank’s traditional strategy of providing long-term loans using deposits
is a money-losing strategy. Note the normal yield curve and inverted yield curve inset below in Figure
13.5.
When interest rates are inverted, cash outflows associated with interest payments
FIGURE 13.5 Yield Curves to depositors will exceed cash inflows from borrowers such as mortgage holders. For
example, a home buyer with a thirty-year mortgage loan at 6 percent on $100,000 will
continue to make principal and interest payments to Hometown at $597.65 per month.
Interest cash flow received by Hometown is calculated at the 6 percent stated rate on
the $100,000 loan. If short-term interest rates move higher, for example to 10 percent,
Hometown will have interest cash outflows at 10 percent with interest cash inflows at
only 6 percent. How will Hometown Bank deal with this type of interest rate risk?
Swaps as a Tool
An interest rate swap is an agreement between two parties to exchange cash flows at
specified future times. Banks use interest rate swaps primarily to convert floating-rate
liabilities (remember, customers will demand current market interest rates on their de-
posits—these are the floating rates) into fixed-rate liabilities. Exchanging variable cash
flows for fixed cash flows is called a “plain vanilla” swap. Hometown can use a swap as a
tool to reduce interest rate risk.
CHAPTER 13 THE EVOLUTION OF RISK MANAGEMENT: ENTERPRISE RISK MANAGEMENT 299
European banks are the opposite of U.S. banks. European bank customers demand floating rate loans
tied to LIBOR (London Interbank Offer Rate); their loans are primarily variable rate and their deposit
base is fixed-rate time deposits. If two banks, one U.S. and one European, can agree to an exchange of
their liabilities the result is the following:
TABLE 13.10 Objective of Mitigating Interest Rate Risks
U.S. Bank European Bank
Assets Liabilities Assets Liabilities
Fixed Fixed Floating Floating
The swap creates a match of interest-rate-sensitive cash inflows and outflows: fixed rate assets and liab-
ilities for the U.S. bank and floating rate assets and liabilities for the European bank as shown in Table
13.10. The following steps show how Hometown Bank employs the financial instrument of a swap with
SwissBank for $100 million of their mortgage loans as a risk management tool.
In our simplified example, Hometown agrees to swap with SwissBank cash flows equal to an
agreed-upon fixed rate of 3 percent on $100 million, a portion of their total assets. The term is set for
ten years. At the same time, SwissBank agrees to pay Hometown cash flows equal to LIBOR an indexed
short-term floating rate of interest on the same $100 million. Remember, the contract is an agreement
to exchange, or swap, interest payments only. The amount is determined by the desired amount of as-
sets the two parties wish to hedge against interest rate risk. They agree to do this because, as explained
above, it better aligns each bank’s risk. They agree to swap to minimize interest-rate risk exposure. For
Hometown Bank, when interest rates rise, the dollars they receive on the swap increase. This creates a
gain on the swap that offsets the loss or supplements the smaller margins are available to the bank be-
cause of interest rate moves. Keep in mind that the interest margin may have been profitable at the
time of the original transaction; however, higher interest rates have increased cash outflows of interest
paid to depositors.
TABLE 13.11 Swap Cash Flow
Hometown Bank Pays 5 percent fixed rate to SwissBank
SwissBank pays LIBOR to Hometown Bank
In our example in Table 13.11, we show what happens if interest rates increase. Over the sample four
years shown, short-term interest rates move up from 2.50 percent to 4.50 percent. If Hometown Bank
was not hedged with the interest rate swap, their interest expenses would increase as their deposit base
would be requiring higher interest cash outflows. With the swap, Hometown Bank can offset the higher
300 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
cash outflows on their liabilities (higher interest payments to depositors) with the excess cash payments
received on the swap. The swap mitigates the risk of increasing interest rates.
Why, you might ask, would SwissBank agree to the swap? Remember, SwissBank has floating rate
loans as the majority of their asset base. As interest rates rise, their cash inflows increase. This offsets
their increasing cash flows promised to Hometown Bank. The risk of loss for SwissBank comes into
play when interest rates decline. If interest rates were to decline below the fixed rate of 3 percent, Swis-
sBank would benefit from the swap.
K E Y T A K E A W A Y
< In this section you learned about the use capital markets to mitigate risks and the many financial
instruments that are used as derivatives to hedge against risks.
D I S C U S S I O N Q U E S T I O N S
1. What financial instrument might a jeweler use to cap his price for gold, the main raw material used in
jewelry production?
2. If an insurance company invests in the stock market, what type of instrument would the insurer use to
mitigate the risk of stock price fluctuations?
3. What are the benefits of securitization in the insurance/reinsurance industry?
4. It has been said that the most important thing in the world is to know what is most important now. What
do you think is the most important risk for you now? What do you think will be the most important risk
you will face twenty-five years from now?
5. Explain securitization and provide examples of insurance-linked securities.
6. Explain how swaps work to mitigate the interest rate risk. Give an example.
CHAPTER 13 THE EVOLUTION OF RISK MANAGEMENT: ENTERPRISE RISK MANAGEMENT 301
11. This happens if the corporate cost of capital decreases to about 9 percent from 10
ENDNOTES percent.
12. Circuit City announced its liquidation in the middle of January 2009 after they could
not find a buyer to salvage the company that specialized in electronics.
1. See explanation at http://www.Wikiperdia.org. see also “Executive Suite: Textron CEO 13. Insurers have a special accounting system called statutory accounting. Only insurers
Zeroes in on Six Sigma,” USA Today, updated January 28, 2008. that are publicly traded are required to show the market value of their assets in a
separate accounting system, called GAAP accounting (Generally Accepted Account-
2. Paul Ingrassia, “How Detroit Drove into a Ditch: The Financial Crisis Has Brought the ing Procedures). The assets and liabilities shown in Table 13.5 are based on the stat-
U.S. Auto Industry to a Breaking Point, but the Trouble Began Long Ago,” Wall Street utory accounting and the assets are booked at book value, rather than market value,
Journal, October 25, 2008. except for the stocks. The differences between the two accounting systems are bey-
ond the scope of this textbook. Nevertheless, the most important differences have to
3. See references to Capital versus Risks studies such as Etti G. Baranoff and Thomas W.
do with accrued liabilities and mark-to-market values of the assets. Statutory ac-
Sager, “The Impact of Mortgage-backed Securities on Capital Requirements of Life In-
surers in the Financial Crisis of 2007–2008,” Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance Issues counting does not require market values of bonds.
and Practice, The International Association for the Study of Insurance Economics
1018–5895/08, http://www.palgrave-journals.com/gpp; Etti G. Baranoff, Tom W. 14. This was reflected in the stock market with insurers such as Hartford Life, Genworth
Life, and AIG life insurance, for example. This decline, without a decline in the liabilit-
Sager, and Savas Papadopoulos, “Capital and Risk Revisited: A Structural Equation ies, lowered the capital amount of these insurers.
Model Approach for Life Insurers,” Journal of Risk and Insurance, 74, no. 3 (2007):
653–81; Etti G. Baranoff and Thomas W. Sager, “The Interrelationship among Organiz- 15. James T. Gleason, The New Management Imperative in Finance Risk (Princeton, NJ:
ational and Distribution Forms and Capital and Asset Risk Structures in the Life Insur- Bloomberg Press, 2000), Chapter 3.
ance Industry,” Journal of Risk and Insurance 70, no. 3 (2003): 375; Etti G. Baranoff and
Thomas W. Sager, “The Relationship between Asset Risk, Product Risk, and Capital in 16. Michael Himick et al., Securitized Insurance Risk: Strategic Opportunities for Insurers and
the Life Insurance Industry,” Journal of Banking and Finance 26, no. 6 (2002): 1181–97. Investors (Chicago: Glenlake Publishing Co., Ltd., 1998), 49–59.
4. See references to Capital versus Risks studies such as Etti G. Baranoff and Thomas W. 17. David Na, “Risk Securitization 101, 2000, CAS Special Interest Seminar” (Bermuda:
Sager, “The Impact of Mortgage-backed Securities on Capital Requirements of Life In- Deloitte & Touche), http://www.casact.org/coneduc/specsem/catastrophe/2000/
surers in the Financial Crisis of 2007–2008,” Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance Issues handouts/na.ppt.
and Practice, The International Association for the Study of Insurance Economics
1018–5895/08, http://www.palgrave-journals.com/gpp; Etti G. Baranoff, Tom W. 18. A word of caution: AIG and its CDS without appropriate capitalization and reserves.
Sager, and Savas Papadopoulos, “Capital and Risk Revisited: A Structural Equation The rating of credit rating agencies provided the security rather than true funds.
Model Approach for Life Insurers,” Journal of Risk and Insurance, 74, no. 3 (2007): Thus, when used inappropriately, the use of such instruments can take down giant
653–81; Etti G. Baranoff and Thomas W. Sager, “The Interrelationship among Organiz- corporations as is the case of AIG during the 2008 to 2009 crisis.
ational and Distribution Forms and Capital and Asset Risk Structures in the Life Insur- 19. Sam Friedman, “There’s More Than One Way to Skin a Cat,” National Underwriter,
ance Industry,” Journal of Risk and Insurance 70, no. 3 (2003): 375; Etti G. Baranoff and Property & Casualty/Risk & Benefits, May 8, 2000.
Thomas W. Sager, “The Relationship between Asset Risk, Product Risk, and Capital in
the Life Insurance Industry,” Journal of Banking and Finance 26, no. 6 (2002): 1181–97. 20. Definition from Frank J. Fabozzi and Laurie S. Goodman, eds., Investing in Collateral-
ized Debt Obligations (Wiley, 2001).
5. See environmental issues at http://environment.about.com/b/2009/01/20/
obama-launches-new-white-house-web-site-environment-near-the-top-of-his-agenda 21. A comprehensive report by Guy Carpenter appears in “The Evolving Market for Cata-
.htm, http://environment.about.com/b/2009/01/12/ strophic Event Risk,” August 1998, http://www.guycarp.com/publications/white/
billions-of-people-face-food-shortages-due-to-global-warming.htm, or evolving/evolv24.html.
http://environment.about.com/b/2009/01/20/
obamas-first-100-days-an-environmental-agenda-for-obamas-first-100-days.htm. 22. Written by Denise Togger, printed with permission of the author. Denise Williams
Togger earned her Bachelor of Science degree in economics in 1991 and her Master
6. http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Sustainability. of Science in finance in 2002 from Virginia Commonwealth University. In fulfilling the
MS degree requirements, she completed an independent study in finance focusing
7. Capital budgeting is a major topic in financial management. The present value of a on enterprise risk management tools. Text and case material presented draws from
stream of projected income is compared to the initial outlay in order to make the de- curriculum, research, and her eighteen years experience in the investment securities
cision whether to undertake the project. We discuss Net Present Value (NPV) in industry. Most recently Denise served as a member of the risk management commit-
Chapter 3 for the decision to adopt safety belts. For more methods, the student is in- tee of BB&T Capital Markets as senior vice president and fixed-income preferred
vited to examine financial management textbooks. trader. BB&T Capital Markets is the capital markets division of BB&T Corporation, the
nation’s fourteenth largest financial holding company. It was featured as part of Case
8. This example follows Doherty’s 1985 Corporate Risk Management.
4 in the original “Risk Management and Insurance” Textbook by Etti Baranoff, 2003,
9. This assumes an interest rate for the cash flow of 10 percent. The value of the firm is Wiley and Sons.
the value of the perpetuity at 10 percent which yields a factor of ten.
23. Anthony Saunders, Chapter 1 Financial Institutions Management: A Modern Perspect-
10. This concept follows the net income (NI) approach, which was shown to have many ive, 3rd ed. (New York: McGraw-Hill Higher Education, 2000), ch. 1.
drawbacks relative to the Net Operating Income (NOI) approach. See the famous
Miller-Modigliani theorems in the financial literature of 1950 and 1960. 24. Sumit Paul-Choudhury, “Real Options,” Risk Management Magazine, September 2001,
38.
302 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
CHAP TER 14
Risks Related to the Job:
Workers’ Compensation and
Unemployment
Compensation
Workers’ compensation is a state-mandated coverage that is exclusively related to the workplace. Unemployment
compensation is also a mandated program required of employers. Both are considered social insurance programs,
as is Social Security. Social Security is featured in [MISSING REF: #baranoff-ch18] as a foundation program for
employee benefits (covered in [MISSING REF: #baranoff-ch19] through [MISSING REF: #baranoff-ch22]). Social
insurance programs are required coverages as a matter of law. The programs are based only on the connection to
the labor force, not on need. Both workers’ compensation and unemployment compensation are part of the risk
management of businesses in the United States. The use of workers’ compensation as part of an integrated risk
Workers’ compensation was one of the coverages that helped the families who lost their breadwinners in the
attacks of September 11, 2001. New York City and the state of New York suffered their largest-ever loss of human
lives. Because most of the loss of life occurred while the employees were at work, those injured received medical
care, rehabilitation, and disability income under the New York workers’ compensation system, and families of the
deceased received survivors’ benefits. The huge payouts raised the question of what would happen to workers’
compensation rates. The National Council on Compensation Insurance (NCCI) predicted a grim outlook then, but
by 2005, conditions improved as frequency of losses declined and the industry’s reserves increased.[1] The workers’
compensation line has maintained this strong reserve position and has been helped by a continual downward
trend in loss frequency. Consequently, the industry reported a combined ratio of 93 percent in 2006 and projects a
99 percent combined ratio for 2007. This indicates positive underwriting results. However, medical claims severity
Workers’ compensation is considered a social insurance program. Another social insurance program is the
unemployment compensation offered in all the states. This chapter includes a brief explanation of this program as
well. To better understand how workers’ compensation and unemployment compensation work, this chapter
1. Links
5. Unemployment compensation
FIGURE 14.1 Changes in the Distribution of Medical versus Indemnity Claims in Workers’
Compensation*
* 2007p: Preliminary based on data valued as of December 31, 2007; 1987, 1997: Based on data through December
31, 2006, developed to ultimate; based on the states where NCCI provides rate-making services, excludes the
effects of deductible policies
Source: Dennis C. Mealy, FCAS, MAAA, National Council on Compensation Insurance (NCCI), Inc. Chief Actuary, “State of the Line” Annul Issues
Symposium (AIS), May 8, 2008, Accessed March 28, 2009, https://www.ncci.com/documents/AIS-2008-SOL-Complete.pdf. © 2008 NCCI Holdings,
Inc. Reproduced with permission.
1. LINKS
At this point in our study, we look at the coverage employers provide for you and your family in case
you are hurt on the job (workers’ compensation) or lose your job involuntarily (unemployment com-
pensation). As noted above, these coverages are mandatory in most states. Workers’ compensation is
not mandatory in New Jersey and Texas (although most employers in these states provide it anyway).
In later chapters, you will see the employer-provided group life, health, disability, and pensions as part
of noncash compensation programs. These coverages complete important parts of your holistic risk
management. You know that, at least for work-related injury, you have protection, and that if you are
laid off, limited unemployment compensation is available to you for six months. These coverages are
paid completely by the employer; the rates for workers’ compensation are based on your occupational
classification.
In some cases, the employer does not purchase workers’ compensation coverage from a private in-
surer but buys it from a state’s monopolistic fund or self-insures the coverage. For unemployment
compensation, the coverage, in most cases, is provided by the states.[2] Regardless of the method of ob-
taining the coverage, you are assured by statutes to receive the benefits.
As with the coverages discussed in [MISSING REF: #baranoff-ch13] to Chapter 12, external mar-
ket conditions are a very important indication of the cost of coverage to your employer. When rates in-
crease dramatically, many employers will opt to self-insure and use a third-party administrator (TPA)
to manage the claims. In workers’ compensation, loss control and safety engineering are important
parts of the risk management process. One of the causes of loss is ergonomics, particularly as related to
computers. See the box “Should Ergonomic Standards Be Mandatory?” for a discussion. You would like
to minimize your injury at work, and your employer is obligated under federal and state laws to secure
a safe workplace for you.
Thus, in your pursuit of a holistic risk management program, workers’ compensation coverage is
an important piece of the puzzle that completes your risk mitigation. The coverages you receive are
only for work-related injuries. What happens if you are injured away from work? This will be discussed
in later chapters. One trend is integrated benefits, in which the employer integrates the disability and
CHAPTER 14 RISKS RELATED TO THE JOB: WORKERS’ COMPENSATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT COMPENSATION 305
medical coverages of workers’ compensation with voluntary health and disability insurance. Integrated
benefits are part of the effort to provide twenty-four-hour coverage regardless of whether an injury oc-
curred at work or away from work. Currently, nonwork-related injuries are covered for medical pro-
cedures by the employer-provided health insurance and for loss of income by group disability insur-
ance. Integrating the benefits is assumed to prevent double dipping (receiving benefits under workers’
compensation and also under health insurance or disability insurance) and to ensure security of cover-
age regardless of being at work or not. (See the box “Integrated Benefits: The Twenty-Four-Hour
Coverage Concept.”) Health and disability coverages are provided voluntarily by your employer, and it
is your responsibility to seek individual coverages when the pieces that are offered are insufficient to
complete your holistic risk management. Figure 14.2 shows how your holistic risk pieces relate to the
risk management parts available under workers’ compensation and unemployment compensation.
FIGURE 14.2 Links between Holistic Risk Pieces and Workers’ Compensation and Unemployment
Compensation
306 RISK MANAGEMENT FOR ENTERPRISES AND INDIVIDUALS
2. Exceptions are taxing governmental entities, such as the school districts in Texas,
ENDNOTES that may be allowed to self-insure unemployment compensation. They have a pool
administered by the Texas Association of School Boards.
1. Dennis C. Mealy, FCAS, MAAA, Chief Actuary, NCCI, Inc., “State of the Line,” May 8,
2008; Orlando, Florida, 2008; NCCI Holdings, Inc.