Hw1 2 Solutions
Hw1 2 Solutions
Hw1 2 Solutions
Solutions to Homework #1
0.1
A2.9
0.2
A2.25
For each problem, we form the Lagrangian function, write down the first-order conditions,
and solve for the optimal values.
(d) Objective function: f (x1 , x2 ) = x1 + x2 . Constraint: g(x1 , x2 ) = x41 + x42 1 = 0.
s.t. x41 + x42 1 = 0
max x1 + x2
x1 ,x2
x1
x3
= 31 x1 = x2
x2
x2
Plugging into constraint,
1
x41 + x41 = 1 x1 = 2 4 , x2 = 2 4 , = 2 2
The maximized value of the objective function is:
3
x1 + x2 = 2 4
x1 ,x2 ,x3
s.t. x1 + x2 + x3 1 = 0
0.3
1
432
A2.33
x1 ...xn
subject to
g 1 (x1 , ..., xn ) a1 = 0
g 3 (x1 , ..., xn ) a2 = 0
..
.
g m (x1 , ..., xn ) am = 0
Denote the jth constraint as
Gj (x1 , ..., xn , a1 , ...am ) = g j (x1 , ..., xn ) aj = 0
The Lagrangian is
L(x1 , ..., xn , 1 , ..., m ) = f (x1 , ..., xn )
m
X
i=1
X Gi
f
i
aj
aj
i=1
Since aj does not enter into f (), the first term is 0. Each
i = j. Therefore,
0.4
V (a1 ,...aj )
aj
Gi
aj
term is 0 if i 6= j, and -1 if
= j .
1.3
(a) For a binary relation > to be complete, for all x1 , x2 in X, one or both of these must
be true: x1 > x2 , x2 > x1 . We assume the preference relation % is complete, therefore
x1 % x2 is true, x2 % x1 is true, or both are true.
Suppose is complete. Then at least one of these is true: x x, x x. However, both
are false, so cannot be complete.
Suppose is complete, and consider x1 , x2 such that x1 x2 . Then at least one of these
is true: x1 x2 , x2 x1 . However, both are false, so cannot be complete.
(b) By the completeness of %, x1 % x2 is true, x2 % x1 is true, or both are.
Suppose both are true. Then x1 x2 .
Suppose x1 % x2 is true and x2 % x1 is false. Then x1 x2 .
Suppose x1 % x2 is false and x2 % x1 is true. Then x2 x1 .
Since these are the only three possibilities, exactly one must hold.
0.5
1.5
0.6
1.8
One possible set of indifference curves is shown above. The upper level sets are convex, but not
strictly convex, therefore these preferences are quasiconcave, but not strictly quasiconcave.
0.7
1.12
0.8
1.20
p 1 x1 + p 2 x2 y = 0
s.t.
L(x1 , x2 , ) = Ax1 x1
+ (p1 x1 + p2 x2 y)
2
4
L
= Ax1
x21 p1 = 0
1
x1
L
= A(1 )x1 x
2 p2 = 0
x2
L
= p 1 x1 + p 2 x2 y = 0
Combining
L
x1
and
L
x2 ,
we get
p1
p1 1
x2
=
x2 =
x1
1 x1
p2
p2
0.9
p1 1
y (1 )y
x1 = y x1 =
,x =
p2
p1 2
p2
1.21
p1 x1 + p2 x2 y = 0
s.t.
=
p1 = 0
x1
x1
L
=
p2 = 0
x2
x2
L
= p 1 x1 + p 2 x2 y = 0
Combining
L
x1
and
L
x2 ,
we get
x2
p1
=
1 x1
p2
which is the same as in problem 1.20. Therefore, the generated Marshallian demand will be
the same.
0.10
1.27
u
a
x1
a
The optimal solution(s) will depend on the slope of the budget line, pp12 .
If pp12 < a1 , the optimal solution will be the corner solution at (0, y/p2 ).
If pp21 = a1 , all points on the upper half of the indifference curve are optimal.
If a > pp21 > a1 , the only optimal solution is the point on the 45-degree line,
y
( p1 +p
, y ).
2 p1 +p2
If a = pp21 , all points in the lower half of the indifference curve are optimal.
If a < pp21 , the optimal solution will be the corner solution at (y/p1 , 0).
0.11
1.33
Suppose we have the indirect utility function v(p, y) which is the maximized value of some
utility function u(x). We apply the positive, monotonic transform f () to get f (v(p, y)). If
we can show that this is the maximized value of some utility function v(x), and that v()
represents the same preferences as u() (i.e. given (p, y), the solutions for maximizing u(x)
and v(x) are the same), then we are done.
Suppose that v() is the result of applying f () to u(): v(x) = f (u(x)). We know that applying
a positive, monotonic transform to a utility function gives us another utility function that
represents the same preferences (see Theorem 1.2 in Chapter 1). The last thing we need to
show is that f (v(p, y)) is the indirect utility function of f (u(x)), that is, for any (p, y),
max f (u(x)) = f (v(p, y)) = f max u(x)
x
This is true because f () is monotonic: f (a) f (b) iff a b. Therefore, we have proven the
statement.