Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

11th Circuit Opinion

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 304

[PUBLISH]

IN THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS

FOR THE ELEVENTH CIRCUIT FILED


________________________ U.S. COURT OF APPEALS
ELEVENTH CIRCUIT
Nos. 11-11021 & 11-11067 AUG 12, 2011
JOHN LEY
________________________ CLERK

D.C. Docket No. 3:10-cv-00091-RV-EMT

STATE OF FLORIDA, by and through Attorney General, STATE OF SOUTH


CAROLINA, by and through Attorney General, STATE OF NEBRASKA, by and
through Attorney General, STATE OF TEXAS, by and through Attorney General,
STATE OF UTAH, by and through Attorney General, et. al.,

Plaintiffs - Appellees - Cross-Appellants,

versus

UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF HEALTH AND HUMAN SERVICES,


SECRETARY OF THE UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF HEALTH AND
HUMAN SERVICES, UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF THE TREASURY,
SECRETARY OF THE UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF TREASURY,
UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF LABOR, SECRETARY OF THE
UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF LABOR,

Defendants - Appellants - Cross-Appellees.


________________________

Appeals from the United States District Court


for the Northern District of Florida
________________________

(August 12, 2011)


Before DUBINA, Chief Judge, and HULL and MARCUS, Circuit Judges.

DUBINA, Chief Judge, and HULL, Circuit Judge:1

Soon after Congress passed the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act,

Pub. L. No. 111-148, 124 Stat. 119 (2010), amended by Health Care and

Education Reconciliation Act of 2010 (HCERA), Pub. L. No. 111-152, 124 Stat.

1029 (2010) (the Act), the plaintiffs brought this action challenging the Acts

constitutionality. The plaintiffs are 26 states, private individuals Mary Brown and

Kaj Ahlburg, and the National Federation of Independent Business (NFIB)

(collectively the plaintiffs).2 The defendants are the federal Health and Human

Services (HHS), Treasury, and Labor Departments and their Secretaries

(collectively the government).

The district court granted summary judgment (1) to the government on the

state plaintiffs claim that the Acts expansion of Medicaid is unconstitutional and

(2) to the plaintiffs on their claim that the Acts individual mandatethat

1
This opinion was written jointly by Judges Dubina and Hull. Cf. Waters v. Thomas, 46
F.3d 1506, 1509 (11th Cir. 1995) (authored by Anderson and Carnes, J.J.) (citing Peek v. Kemp,
784 F.2d 1479 (11th Cir.) (en banc) (authored by Vance and Anderson, J.J.), cert. denied, 479
U.S. 939, 107 S. Ct. 421 (1986)).
2
The 26 state plaintiffs are Alabama, Alaska, Arizona, Colorado, Florida, Georgia, Idaho,
Indiana, Iowa, Kansas, Louisiana, Maine, Michigan, Mississippi, Nebraska, Nevada, North
Dakota, Ohio, Pennsylvania, South Carolina, South Dakota, Texas, Utah, Washington,
Wisconsin, and Wyoming.

2
individuals purchase and continuously maintain health insurance from private

companies3is unconstitutional. The district court concluded that the individual

mandate exceeded congressional authority under Article I of the Constitution

because it was not enacted pursuant to Congresss tax power and it exceeded

Congresss power under the Commerce Clause and the Necessary and Proper

Clause. The district court also concluded that the individual mandate provision

was not severable from the rest of the Act and declared the entire Act invalid.

The government appeals the district courts ruling that the individual

mandate is unconstitutional and its severability holding. The state plaintiffs cross-

appeal the district courts ruling on their Medicaid expansion claim. For the

reasons that follow, we affirm in part and reverse in part.4

INTRODUCTION

Legal issues concerning the constitutionality of a legislative act present

important but difficult questions for the courts. Here, that importance and

3
As explained later, unless the person is covered by a government-funded health program,
such as Medicare, Medicaid, and others, the mandate is to purchase insurance from a private
insurer.
4
We review the district courts grant of summary judgment de novo. Sammys of Mobile,
Ltd. v. City of Mobile, 140 F.3d 993, 995 (11th Cir. 1998). We review de novo a constitutional
challenge to a statute. United States v. Cunningham, 607 F.3d 1264, 1266 (11th Cir.), cert.
denied, 131 S. Ct. 482 (2010).

3
difficulty are heightened because (1) the Act itself is 975 pages in the format

published in the Public Laws;5 (2) the district court, agreeing with the plaintiffs,

held all of the Act was unconstitutional; and (3) on appeal, the government argues

all of the Act is constitutional.

We, as all federal courts, must begin with a presumption of constitutionality,

meaning that we invalidate a congressional enactment only upon a plain showing

that Congress has exceeded its constitutional bounds. United States v. Morrison,

529 U.S. 598, 607, 120 S. Ct. 1740, 1748 (2000).

As an initial matter, to know whether a legislative act is constitutional

requires knowing what is in the Act. Accordingly, our task is to figure out what

this sweeping and comprehensive Act actually says and does. To do that, we

outline the congressional findings that identify the problems the Act addresses,

and the Acts legislative response and overall structure, encompassing nine Titles

and hundreds of laws on a diverse array of subjects. Next, we set forth in greater

depth the contents of the Acts five components most relevant to this appeal: the

insurance industry reforms, the new state-run Exchanges, the individual mandate,

5
Pub. L. No. 111-148, 124 Stat. 119 (2010), Pub. L. No. 111-152, 124 Stat. 1029 (2010).
Some of the sections of the Act have not yet been codified in the U.S. Code, and for those
sections we cite to the future U.S. Code provision, along with the effective date if applicable.

4
the employer penalties, and the Medicaid expansion.

After that, we analyze the constitutionality of the Medicaid expansion and

explain why we conclude that the Acts Medicaid expansion is constitutional.

We then review the Supreme Courts decisions on Congresss commerce

power, discuss the individual mandatewhich requires Americans to purchase an

expensive product from a private insurance company from birth to deathand

explicate how Congress exceeded its commerce power in enacting its individual

mandate. We next outline why Congresss tax power does not provide an

alternative constitutional basis for upholding this unprecedented individual

mandate. Lastly, because of the Supreme Courts strong presumption of

severability and as a matter of judicial restraint, we conclude that the individual

mandate is severable from the remainder of the Act. Our opinion is organized as

follows:

I. STANDING

II. THE ACT

A. Congressional Findings
B. Overall Structure of Nine Titles
C. Terms and Definitions
D. Health Insurance Reforms
E. Health Benefit Exchanges
F. Individual Mandate

5
G. Employer Penalty
H. Medicaid Expansion

III. CONSTITUTIONALITY OF MEDICAID EXPANSION

A. History of the Medicaid Program


B. Congresss Power under the Spending Clause

IV. SUPREME COURTS COMMERCE CLAUSE DECISIONS

V. CONSTITUTIONALITY OF INDIVIDUAL MANDATE UNDER


THE COMMERCE POWER

A. First Principles
B. Dichotomies and Nomenclature
C. Unprecedented Nature of the Individual Mandate
D. Wickard and Aggregation
E. Broad Scope of Congresss Regulation
F. Governments Proposed Limiting Principles
G. Congressional Findings
H. Areas of Traditional State Concern
I. Essential to a Larger Regulatory Scheme
J. Conclusion

VI. CONSTITUTIONALITY OF INDIVIDUAL MANDATE UNDER


THE TAX POWER

A. Repeated Use of the Term Penalty in the Individual Mandate


B. Designation of Numerous Other Provisions in the Act as Taxes
C. Legislative History of the Individual Mandate

VII. SEVERABILITY

I. STANDING

As a threshold matter, we consider the governments challenge to the

6
plaintiffs standing to bring this lawsuit. Article III of the Constitution limits the

jurisdiction of federal courts to cases and controversies. Socialist Workers

Party v. Leahy, 145 F.3d 1240, 1244 (11th Cir. 1998) (citations omitted). As we

have explained:

The case-or-controversy constraint, in turn, imposes a dual limitation on


federal courts commonly referred to as justiciability. Basically,
justiciability doctrine seeks to prevent the federal courts from
encroaching on the powers of the other branches of government and to
ensure that the courts consider only those matters that are presented in
an adversarial context. Because the judiciary is unelected and
unrepresentative, the Article III case-or-controversy limitation, as
embodied in justiciability doctrine, presents an important restriction on
the power of the federal courts.

Id. (citations omitted). Indeed, there are three strands of justiciability

doctrinestanding, ripeness, and mootnessthat go to the heart of the Article III

case or controversy requirement. Harrell v. The Fla. Bar, 608 F.3d 1241, 1247

(11th Cir. 2010) (quotation marks and alterations omitted).

As for the first strand, [i]t is by now axiomatic that a plaintiff must have

standing to invoke the jurisdiction of the federal courts. KH Outdoor, LLC v. City

of Trussville, 458 F.3d 1261, 1266 (11th Cir. 2006). In essence the question of

standing is whether the litigant is entitled to have the court decide the merits of the

dispute or of particular issues. Primera Iglesia Bautista Hispana of Boca Raton,

7
Inc. v. Broward Cnty., 450 F.3d 1295, 1304 (11th Cir. 2006) (quotation marks

omitted). To demonstrate standing, a plaintiff must show that (1) he has suffered,

or imminently will suffer, an injury-in-fact; (2) the injury is fairly traceable to [the

statute]; and (3) a favorable judgment is likely to redress the injury. Harrell, 608

F.3d at 1253; see also Lujan v. Defenders of Wildlife, 504 U.S. 555, 56061, 112

S. Ct. 2130, 2136 (1992). The plaintiff bears the burden of establishing each of

these elements. Elend v. Basham, 471 F.3d 1199, 1206 (11th Cir. 2006). And

standing must be established for each claim a plaintiff raises. See Harrell, 608

F.3d at 125354. We review standing determinations de novo. Bochese v. Town

of Ponce Inlet, 405 F.3d 964, 975 (11th Cir. 2005).

In fact, [s]tanding is a threshold jurisdictional question which must be

addressed prior to and independent of the merits of a partys claims. Id. at 974

(quotation marks and alteration omitted). And we are obliged to consider

questions of standing regardless of whether the parties have raised them. Id. at

975.

Notably, the government does not contest the standing of the individual

plaintiffs or of the NFIB to challenge the individual mandate. In fact, the

government expressly concedes that one of the individual plaintiffsMary

8
Brownhas standing to challenge the individual mandate. See Governments

Opening Br. at 6 n.1 (Defendants do not dispute that plaintiff Browns challenge

to the minimum coverage provision is justiciable.). Nor does the government

dispute the state plaintiffs standing to challenge the Medicaid provisions.

The only question raised by the government is whether the state plaintiffs

have standing to challenge the individual mandate. The government claims that the

state plaintiffs do not have standing because they are impermissibly suing the

government as parens patriaeor as representatives of their citizensin

violation of the rule articulated in Massachusetts v. Mellon, 262 U.S. 447, 48586,

43 S. Ct. 597, 600 (1923).6 The state plaintiffs respond that they are not in

violation of the Mellon rule, but rather have standing to challenge the individual

mandate for three independent reasons: first, because the increased enrollment in

Medicaid spurred by the individual mandate will cost the states millions of dollars

in additional Medicaid funding; second, because they are injured by other

provisions of the Actsuch as the Medicaid expansionfrom which the

individual mandate cannot be severed; and finally, because the individual mandate

6
In Mellon, the Supreme Court held that states cannot sue the federal government in a
representative capacity to protect their citizens from the operation of an allegedly
unconstitutional federal law. 262 U.S. at 48586, 43 S. Ct. at 600. This has come to be known as
the Mellon rule.

9
intrudes upon their sovereign interest in enacting and enforcing state statutes that

shield their citizens from the requirement to purchase health insurance. States

Opening Br. at 6769.

Although the question of the state plaintiffs standing to challenge the

individual mandate is an interesting and difficult one, in the posture of this case, it

is purely academic and one we need not confront today. The law is abundantly

clear that so long as at least one plaintiff has standing to raise each claimas is

the case herewe need not address whether the remaining plaintiffs have

standing. See, e.g., Watt v. Energy Action Educ. Found., 454 U.S. 151, 160, 102 S.

Ct. 205, 212 (1981) (Because we find California has standing, we do not consider

the standing of the other plaintiffs.); Vill. of Arlington Heights v. Metro. Hous.

Dev. Corp., 429 U.S. 252, 264 & n.9, 97 S. Ct. 555, 562 & n.9 (1977) (Because

of the presence of this plaintiff, we need not consider whether the other individual

and corporate plaintiffs have standing to maintain suit.); ACLU of Fla., Inc. v.

Miami-Dade Cnty. Sch. Bd., 557 F.3d 1177, 1195 (11th Cir. 2009) (Because

Balzli has standing to raise those claims, we need not decide whether either of the

organizational plaintiffs also has standing to do so.); Jackson v. Okaloosa Cnty.,

21 F.3d 1531, 1536 (11th Cir. 1994) (In order for this court to have jurisdiction

10
over the claims before us, at least one named plaintiff must have standing for each

of the claims.); Mountain States Legal Found. v. Glickman, 92 F.3d 1228, 1232

(D.C. Cir. 1996) (For each claim, if constitutional and prudential standing can be

shown for at least one plaintiff, we need not consider the standing of the other

plaintiffs to raise that claim.). Because it is beyond dispute that at least one

plaintiff has standing to raise each claim herethe individual plaintiffs and the

NFIB have standing to challenge the individual mandate, and the state plaintiffs

undeniably have standing to challenge the Medicaid provisionsthis case is

justiciable, and we are permitted, indeed we are obliged, to address the merits of

each. Accordingly, we turn to the constitutionality of the Act.

II. THE ACT

A. Congressional Findings

The congressional findings for the Act, including those relating to the

individual mandate, are contained in two pages, now codified in 42 U.S.C.

18091(a)(1)(3). Approximately 50 million people are uninsured.7 The

7
U.S. Census Bureau, P60-238, Income, Poverty, and Health Insurance Coverage in the
United States: 2009 23 tbl.8 (2010) (Census Report), available at
http://www.census.gov/prod/2010pubs/p60-238.pdf. Although the congressional findings do not
state the precise number of the uninsured, the parties use the 50 million figure, so we will too.
Copies of the Internet materials cited in this opinion are on file in the Clerks Office. See
11th Cir. R. 36, I.O.P. 10.

11
congressional findings focus on these uninsureds, health insurance, and health

care. Id.

1. The Uninsured and Cost-Shifting Problems

The congressional findings state that some individuals make an economic

and financial decision to forego health insurance coverage and attempt to self-

insure, which increases financial risks to households and medical providers. Id.

18091(a)(2)(A). In its findings, Congress determined that the decision by the

uninsured to forego insurance results in a cost-shifting scenario. Id.

18091(a)(2)(F).

Congresss findings identify a multi-step process that starts with

consumption of health care: (1) some uninsured persons consume health care; (2)

some fail to pay the full costs; (3) in turn the unpaid costs of that health care$43

billion in 2008are shifted to and spread among medical providers; (4) thereafter

medical providers, by imposing higher charges, spread and shift the unpaid costs

to private insurance companies; (5) then private insurance companies raise

premiums for health policies and shift and spread the unpaid costs to already-

insured persons; and (6) consequently already-insured persons suffer higher

premiums. Id. 18091(a)(2). Also, some uninsured persons continue not to buy

coverage because of higher premiums. Id.

12
The findings state that this cost-shifting scenario increases family premiums

on average by $1,000 per year. Id. 18091(a)(2)(F). Although not in the findings,

the data show the cost-shifting increases individual premiums on average by

$368410 per year.8 The cost-shifting represents roughly 8% of average

premiums.9

In its findings, Congress also points out that national health care spending in

2009 was approximately $2.5 trillion, or 17.6% of the national economy.10 Id.

18091(a)(2)(B). Thus, the $43 billion in shifted costs represents about 1.7% of

total health care expenditures. Of that $2.5 trillion in national health care spending

in 2009, federal, state, and local governments paid $1.1 trillion, or 44%.11

8
Uncompensated care costs translate into a surcharge of $368 for individual premiums
and a surcharge of $1017 for family premiums in 2008. See Families USA, Hidden Health Tax:
Americans Pay a Premium 7 (2009), available at http://familiesusa2.org/assets/pdfs/hidden-
health-tax.pdf (cited by both the plaintiffs and the government).
9
[A] hidden tax on health insurance accounts for roughly 8% of the average health
insurance premium and [t]his cost-shift added, on average, $1,100 to each family premium in
2009 and about $410 to an individual premium. Br. of Amici Curiae Am. Assn of People with
Disabilities, et al., in Support of the Government at 15 (citing Ben Furnas & Peter Harbage, Ctr.
for Am. Progress Action Fund, The Cost Shift from the Uninsured 12 (2009), available at
http://www.americanprogressaction.org/issues/2009/03/pdf/cost_shift.pdf (calculations based on
a 2005 analysis by Families USA)).
10
See Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services (CMS), National Health Expenditure
Web Tables tbls.1, 5, 11, available at
http://www.cms.gov/NationalHealthExpendData/downloads/tables.pdf (derived from
calculations).
11
See CMS, National Health Expenditure Web Tables, supra note 10, at tbl.5. The
governments health care spending in 2009 included $503 billion for Medicare and $374 billion
for Medicaid and the Childrens Health Insurance Program (CHIP).
13
Private insurers still paid for 32% of health care spending in 2009,12 id.,

through: (1) primarily private employer-based insurance plans, or (2) the private

individual insurance market. The private employer-based health system covers 176

million Americans. Id. 18091(a)(2)(D). The private individual insurance market

covers 24.7 million people.13 Undisputedly, [h]ealth insurance and health care

services are a significant part of the national economy. Id. 18091(a)(2)(B).

2. $90 Billion Private Underwriting Costs Problem

Congress also recognized that many of the uninsured desire insurance but

have been denied coverage or cannot afford it. Its findings emphasize the barriers

created by private insurers underwriting practices and related administrative

costs. Id. 18091(a)(2)(J). Private insurers want healthy insureds and try to

protect themselves against unhealthy entrants through medical underwriting,

especially in the individual market. As a result of medical underwriting, many

uninsured Americansranging from 9 million to 12.6 millionvoluntarily sought

Projected Medicare spending is $723.1 billion in 2016 and $891.4 billion in 2019. CMS,
Natl Health Expenditure Projections 20092019 tbl.2, available at
http://www.cms.gov/National HealthExpendData/Downloads/NHEProjections2009to2019.pdf.
With the Acts Medicaid expansion and other factors, projected Medicaid and CHIP
spending is $737.5 billion in 2016 and $896.2 billion in 2019. Id.
12
See CMS, National Health Expenditure Web Tables, supra note 10, at tbl.3 (derived
from calculations).
13
See Census Report, supra note 7, at 2225 & 23 tbl.8 (derived from calculations).
14
health coverage in the individual market but were denied coverage, charged a

higher premium, or offered only limited coverage that excludes a preexisting

condition.14

In its findings, Congress determined that the [a]dministrative costs for

private health insurance were $90 billion in 2006, comprising 26 to 30 percent

of premiums in the current individual and small group markets. Id. The findings

state that Congress seeks to create health insurance markets that do not require

underwriting and eliminate its associated administrative costs. Id. The Act

requires private insurers to allow all applicants to enroll. 42 U.S.C. 300gg-1(a).

Congress stated that the Act, by eliminating underwriting costs, will lower health

insurance premiums. Id.

3. Congresss Solutions

Given the 50 million uninsured, $43 billion in uncompensated costs, and

$90 billion in underwriting costs, Congress determined these problems affect the

national economy and interstate commerce. Id. 18091(a)(2). The congressional

14
HHS, Coverage Denied: How the Current Health Insurance System Leaves Millions
Behind, http://www.healthreform.gov/reports/denied_coverage/index.html (citing
Commonwealth Fund Biennial Health Insurance Survey, 2007); Sara R. Collins, et al., The
Commonwealth Fund, Help on the Horizon: How the Recession Has Left Millions of Workers
Without Health Insurance, and How Health Reform Will Bring Relief xi (2011), available at
http://www.commonwealthfund.org/~/media/Files/Surveys/2011/1486_Collins_
help_on_the_horizon_2010_biennial_survey_report_FINAL_31611.pdf.
15
findings identify what the Act regulates: (1) the health insurance market, (2)

how and when health care is paid for, and (3) when health insurance is

purchased. Id. 18091(a)(2)(A), (H). The findings also state that the Acts

reforms will significantly reduce the number of the uninsured and will lower

health insurance premiums. Id. 18091(a)(2)(F).

To reduce the number of the uninsured, the Act employs five main tools: (1)

comprehensive insurance industry reforms which alter private insurers

underwriting practices, guarantee issuance of coverage, overhaul their health

insurance products, and restrict their premium pricing structure; (2) creation of

state-run Health Benefit Exchanges as new marketplaces through which

individuals, families, and small employers, now pooled together, can

competitively purchase the new insurance products and obtain federal tax credits

and subsidies to do so; (3) a mandate that individuals must purchase and

continuously maintain health insurance or pay annual penalties; (4) penalties on

private employers who do not offer at least some type of health plan to their

employees; and (5) the expansion of Medicaid eligibility and subsidies.

The Acts Medicaid expansion alone will cover 9 million of the 50 million

uninsured by 2014 and 16 million by 2016.15 The Acts health insurance reforms

15
CBOs Analysis of the Major Health Care Legislation Enacted in March 2010: Before
the Subcomm. on Health of the H. Comm. on Energy & Commerce 112th Cong. 18 tbl.3 (2011)
16
remove private insurers barriers to coverage and restrict their pricing to make

coverage accessible to the 9 to 12 million uninsured who were denied coverage or

had their preexisting conditions excluded.16 The Acts new Exchanges, with

significant federal tax credits and subsidies, are predicted to make insurance

available to 9 million in 2014 and 22 million by 2016.17

Congresss findings state that the Acts multiple provisions, combined

together:18

(1) will add millions of new consumers to the health insurance market and

will increase the number and share of Americans who are insured;

(2) will reduce the number of the uninsured, will broaden the health

insurance risk pool to include additional healthy individuals, will increase

economies of scale, and will significantly reduce insurance companies

administrative costs, all of which will lower health insurance premiums;

(3) will build upon and strengthen the private employer-based health

insurance system, which already covers 176,000,000 Americans; and

(Statement of Douglas Elmendorf, Director, Cong. Budget Office) [hereinafter CBO, Analysis],
available at http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/121xx/doc12119/03-30-HealthCareLegislation.pdf.
16
See HHS, Coverage Denied, and Collins, supra note 14.
17
CBO, Analysis, supra note 15, at tbl.3.
18
The congressional findings refer six times to the individual mandate requirement,
together with the other provisions of this Act. 42 U.S.C. 18091(a)(2)(C), (E), (F), (G), (I), (J).
17
(4) will achieve near-universal coverage of the uninsured.

Id. 18091(a)(2).

Although the congressional findings summarily refer to the uninsured, the

parties briefs and the 52 amici briefs contain, and indeed rely on, additional data

about the uninsured. Before turning to the Act, we review that data.19

4. Data about the Uninsured and Uncompensated Care

So who are the uninsured? As to health care usage, the uninsured do not fall

into a single category. Many of the uninsured do not seek health care each year. Of

course, many do. In 2007, 57% of the 40 million uninsured that year used some

medical services; in 2008, 56% of the 41 million uninsured that year used some

medical services.20

As to medical services, 50% of uninsured people had routine checkups in

the past two years; 68% of uninsured people had routine checkups in the past five

19
There has been no evidentiary objection by any party to the data and studies cited in the
parties briefs or in any of the amici briefs. In fact, at times the parties cite the same data.
20
HHS, Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality, Medical Expenditure Panel Survey,
Household Component Summary Tables (MEPS Summary Tables), Table 1: Total Health
ServicesMedian and Mean Expenses per Person with Expense and Distribution of Expenses by
Source of Payment: United States, 2007 & 2008, available at
http://www.meps.ahrq.gov/mepsweb/data_stats/quick_tables.jsp (follow Household Component
summary tables hyperlink; then select 2007 or 2008 for year and follow the search
hyperlink; then follow the hyperlink next to Table 1").
The Medical Expenditure Panel Survey (MEPS) is a set of large-scale surveys of
families and individuals, their medical providers (including doctors, hospitals, and pharmacies),
and employers across the United States. It is conducted under the auspices of HHS.
18
years.21 In 2008, the uninsured made more than 20 million visits to emergency

rooms,22 and 2.1 million were hospitalized.23 The medical care used by each

uninsured person cost about $2,000 on average in 2007, and $1,870 on average in

2008.24

When the uninsured do seek health care, what happens? Some pay in full.

Some partially pay. Some pay nothing. Data show the uninsured paid on average

37% of their health care costs out of pocket in 2007, and 46.01% in 2008,25 while

21
June E. ONeill & Dave M. ONeill, Who Are the Uninsured? An Analysis of Americas
Uninsured Population, Their Characteristics and Their Health, EMP T POLICIES INSTITUTE , 21
tbl.9 (2009), available at http://epionline.org/studies/oneill_06-2009.pdf.
22
Br. of Amici Curiae Am. Hosp. Assn et al. in Support of the Government at 11 (citing
Press Release, HHS, New Data Say Uninsured Account for Nearly One-Fifth of Emergency
Room Visits (Jul. 15, 2009), available at http://www.hhs.gov/news/press/2009pres/
07/20090715b.html).
23
In 2008, U.S. hospitals reported more than 2.1 million hospitalizations of the uninsured.
Office of the Assistant Secy for Planning and Evaluation, HHS, The Value of Health Insurance:
Few of the Uninsured Have Adequate Resources to Pay Potential Hospital Bills 5 (2011),
available at http://aspe.hhs.gov/health/reports/2011/valueofinsurance/rb.shtml.
24
MEPS Summary Tables, supra note 20. An Economic Scholars amici brief, filed in
support of the government, states: The medical care used by each uninsured person costs about
$2000 per year, on average. Br. of Amici Curiae Economists in Support of the Government at
16 (citing Agency for Health Care Quality and Research, Medical Expenditure Panel Survey,
Summary Data Tables, Table 1" (see MEPS Summary Tables, supra note 20); Jack Hadley, et
al., Covering the Uninsured in 2008: Current Costs, Sources of Payment, and Incremental
Costs, 27(5) HEALTH AFFAIRS W399-415 (2008)).
In contrast, this same amici brief points out: In 2007, the average person used $6,186 in
personal health care services. Id. at 11 (citing Center for Medicare and Medicaid Services,
National Health Expenditure Accounts); see CMS, National Expenditure Web Tables, supra
note 10, at tbl.1.
25
See MEPS Summary Tables, supra note 20.
19
third parties pay another 26% on their behalf.26 Not surprisingly, the poorer

uninsured, on average, consume more health care for which they do not pay.27

Even in households at or above the median income level ($41,214) in 2000, the

uninsured paid, on average, less than half their medical care costs.28

It is also undisputed that people are uninsured for a wide variety of reasons.

The uninsured are spread across different income brackets:

(1) less than $25,000: 15.5 million uninsured, or about 31%;

(2) $25,000 to $49,999: 15.3 million uninsured, or about 30%;

(3) $50,000 to $74,999: 9.4 million uninsured, or about 18%;

(4) $75,000 or more: 10.6 million uninsured, or about 21%.29

As the data show, many of the uninsured have low to moderate incomes and

simply cannot afford insurance. Some of the uninsured can afford insurance and

tried to obtain it, but were denied coverage based on health status.30 Some are

26
See Families USA, Hidden Health Tax, supra note 8, at 2 (cited by both the plaintiffs
and the government).
27
Bradley Herring, The Effect of the Availability of Charity Care to the Uninsured on the
Demand for Private Health Insurance, 24 J. HEALTH ECON . 225, 22931 (2005).
28
Herring, supra note 27, at 231 ([T]he median income for all household[s] in the U.S. is
roughly 300% of poverty, and the poverty threshold was US$13,738 for a family of three in
2000.); see id. at 230 tbl.1.
29
See Census Report, supra note 7, at 23 tbl.8.
30
See HHS, Coverage Denied, and Collins, supra note 14.
20
voluntarily uninsured and self-finance because they can pay for their medical care

or have modest medical care needs. Some may not have considered the issue.

There is no one reason why people are uninsured. It is also not surprising,

therefore, that Congress has attacked the uninsured problem through multiple

reforms and numerous avenues in the Act that we outline later.

Given these identified problems, congressional findings, and data as

background, we now turn to Congresss legislative response in the Act.

B. Overall Structure of Nine Titles

The sweeping and comprehensive nature of the Act is evident from its nine

Titles:

I. Quality, Affordable Health Care for All Americans

II. Role of Public Programs

III. Improving the Quality and Efficiency of Health Care

IV. Prevention of Chronic Disease and Improving Public Health

V. Health Care Workforce

VI. Transparency and Program Integrity

VII. Improving Access to Innovative Medical Therapies

VIII. Community Living Assistance Services and Supports

21
IX. Revenue Provisions31

The Acts provisions are spread throughout many statutes and different titles in the

United States Code. As our Appendix A demonstrates, the Acts nine Titles

contain hundreds of new laws about hundreds of different areas of health

insurance and health care. Appendix A details most parts of the Act with section

numbers. Here, we merely list the broad subject matter in each Title.

Title I contains these four components mentioned earlier: (1) the insurance

industry reforms; (2) the new state-run Exchanges; (3) the individual mandate; and

(4) the employer penalty. Act 10011568. Title II shifts the Acts focus to

publicly-funded programs designed to provide health care for the uninsured, such

as Medicaid, CHIP, and initiatives under the Indian Health Care Improvement Act.

Id. 20012955. Title II contains the Medicaid expansion at issue here. Title IIs

provisions also create, or expand, other publicly-funded programs. Id.

Title III primarily addresses Medicare. Id. 30013602. Title IV

concentrates on prevention of illness. Id. 40014402. Title V seeks to increase

the supply of health care workers through education loans, training grants, and

other programs. Id. 50015701.

Title VI creates new transparency and anti-fraud requirements for physician-

31
There is also a tenth Title dedicated to amendments to these nine Titles.
22
owned hospitals participating in Medicare and for nursing facilities participating

in Medicare or Medicaid. Id. 60016801. Title VI includes the Elder Justice

Act, designed to eliminate elder abuse, neglect, and exploitation. Id.

Title VII extends and expands certain drug discounts in health care facilities

serving low-income patients. Id. 70017103. Title VIII establishes a national,

voluntary long-term care insurance program for purchasing community living

assistance services and support by persons with functional limitations. Id.

80018002. Title IX contains revenue provisions. Id. 90019023.

We include Appendix A because it documents (1) the breadth and scope of

the Act; (2) the multitudinous reforms enacted to reduce the number of the

uninsured; (3) the large number and diverse array of new, or expanded, federally-

funded programs, grants, studies, commissions, and councils in the Act; (4) the

extensive new federal requirements and regulations on myriad subjects; and (5)

how many of the Acts provisions on their face operate separately and

independently.

We now examine in depth the five parts of the Act largely designed to

reduce the number of the uninsured. Because of the Acts comprehensive and

complex regulatory scheme, it is critical to examine what the Act actually does and

does not do. We start with some terms and definitions.

23
C. Terms and Definitions

The Act regulates three aspects of health insurance: (1) markets, the

outlets where consumers may purchase insurance products; (2) plans, the

insurance products themselves; and (3) benefits, the health care services or items

covered under an insurance plan.

1. Markets

Given its focus on making health insurance available to the uninsured, the

Act recognizes and regulates four markets for health insurance products: (1) the

individual market; (2) the small group market; (3) the large group market;

and (4) the new Exchanges, to be created and run by each state.

The term individual market means the market for health insurance

coverage offered to individuals other than in connection with a group health plan.

42 U.S.C. 300gg-91(e)(1)(A), 18024(a)(2).

The term group market means the health insurance market under which

individuals obtain health insurance coverage (directly or through any arrangement)

on behalf of themselves (and their dependents) through a group health plan

maintained by an employer. Id. 18024(a)(1).

Within the group market, the Act distinguishes between the large group

market and the small group market. The term large group market refers to the

24
market under which individuals purchase coverage through a group plan of a

large employer. Id. 300gg-91(e)(3), 18024(a)(3). A large employer is an

employer with over 100 employees. Id. 300gg-91(e)(2), 18024(b)(1).

The term small group market refers to the market under which individuals

purchase coverage through a group plan of a small employer, or an employer

with no more than 100 employees. Id. 300gg-91(e)(4), (5), 18024(a)(3), (b)(2).

The term Exchanges refers to the health benefit exchanges that each state

must create and operate.32 Id. 18031(b). Companies (profit and nonprofit)

participating in the Exchanges will offer insurance for purchase by individuals and

employees of small employers. See id.; id. 18042. The uninsured can obtain

significant federal tax credits and subsidies through the Exchanges. See 26 U.S.C.

36B; 42 U.S.C. 18071. In 2017, the states will have the option to open the

Exchanges to large employers. 42 U.S.C. 18032(f)(2)(B).

2. Essential Health Benefits Package Term

Two key terms in the Act are: (1) essential health benefits package and (2)

minimum essential coverage. Although they sound similar, each has a different

meaning.

32
The Act allows a state to opt out of creating and operating an Exchange, in which case
the federal government (or a nonprofit contractor) will establish the Exchange. 42 U.S.C.
18041(c).
25
The term essential health benefits package refers to the comprehensive

benefits package that must be provided by plans in the individual and small group

markets by 2014. Id. 300gg-6(a) (effective Jan. 1, 2014); id. 18022(a). The Act

does not impose the essential health benefits package on plans offered by large

group employers to their employees.

An essential health benefits package must: (1) provide coverage for the

essential health benefits described in 18022(b); (2) limit the insureds cost-

sharing, as provided in 18022(c); and (3) provide either the bronze, silver, gold,

or platinum level of coverage described in 18022(d). Id. 18022(a).

The Act leaves it to HHS to define the term essential health benefits. Id.

18022(b). However, that definition of essential health benefits must include at

least these ten services:

(A) Ambulatory patient services.


(B) Emergency services.
(C) Hospitalization.
(D) Maternity and newborn care.
(E) Mental health and substance use disorder services, including
behavioral health treatment.
(F) Prescription drugs.
(G) Rehabilitative and habilitative services and devices.
(H) Laboratory services.
(I) Preventive and wellness services and chronic disease management.
(J) Pediatric services, including oral and vision care.

26
Id. 18022(b)(1).33 The bronze, silver, gold, and platinum levels of coverage

reflect the levels of cost-sharing (or actuarial value of benefits) in a plan and do

not represent the level or type of services. Id. 18022(d)(1)(2). For example, a

bronze plan covers 60% of the benefits costs, and the insured pays 40% out of

pocket; a platinum plan covers 90%, with the insured paying 10%. Id.

18022(d)(1)(A), (D).

3. Individual Mandates Minimum Essential Coverage Term

The Act uses a wholly different termminimum essential coveragein

connection with the individual mandate. Minimum essential coverage is the type

of plan needed to satisfy the individual mandate. A wide variety of health plans

are considered minimum essential coverage: (1) government-sponsored

programs, (2) eligible employer-sponsored health plans, (3) individual market

health plans, (4) grandfathered health plans, and (5) health plans that qualify for,

and are offered in, a state-run Exchange. 26 U.S.C. 5000A(a), (f)(1).

Many of these plan types will satisfy the mandate even if they do not have

the essential health benefits package and regardless of the level of benefits or

33
In defining essential health benefits, HHS must ensure that the scope of essential
health benefits is equal to the scope of benefits provided under a typical employer plan. 42
U.S.C. 18022(b)(2). HHS must take additional elements into consideration, such as balance
among the categories of benefits, discrimination based on age or disability, and the needs of
diverse segments of the population. Id. 18022(b)(4).
27
coverage. The requirement of the essential health benefits package is directly

tied to some of the insurance product reforms, but not the individual mandate.

We turn to the Acts first component: the insurance reforms.

D. Health Insurance Reforms

To reduce the number of the uninsured, the Act heavily regulates private

insurers and reforms their health insurance products. We list examples of the

major reforms.

1. Guaranteed Issue. Insurers must permit every employer or individual

who applies in the individual or group markets to enroll. 42 U.S.C. 300gg-1(a)

(effective Jan. 1, 2014). However, insurers may restrict enrollment in coverage

described [in subsection (a)] to open or special enrollment periods.34 Id. 300gg-

1(b)(1) (effective Jan. 1, 2014).

2. Guaranteed renewability. Insurers in the individual and group markets

must renew or continue coverage at the individual or plan sponsors option in the

absence of certain exceptions, such as premium nonpayment, fraud, or the

34
The Act directs HHS to promulgate regulations with respect to enrollment periods. 42
U.S.C. 300gg-1(b)(3) (effective Jan. 1, 2014). Insurers must establish special enrollment
periods for qualifying events. Id. 300gg-1(b)(2). Qualifying events include, for example:
(1) [t]he death of the covered employee; (2) [t]he termination (other than by reason of such
employees gross misconduct), or reduction of hours, of the covered employees employment;
and (3) [t]he divorce or legal separation of the covered employee from the employees spouse.
29 U.S.C. 1163.
28
insurers discontinuation of coverage in the relevant market. Id. 300gg-2(b).

3. Waiting periods. Under group health plans, insurers may impose waiting

periods of up to 90 days before a potential enrollee is eligible to be covered under

the plan. Id. 300gg-7 (effective Jan. 1, 2014), 300gg-3(b)(4). The Act places no

limits on insurers waiting periods for applications in the individual market.

4. Elimination of preexisting conditions limitations. Insurers may no

longer deny or limit coverage due to an individuals preexisting medical

conditions. The Act prohibits preexisting condition exclusions for children under

19 within six months of the Acts enactment, and eliminates preexisting condition

exclusions for adults beginning in 2014.35 Id. 300gg-3.

5. Prohibition on health status eligibility rules. Insurers may not establish

eligibility rules based on any of the health status-related factors listed in the Act.36

35
For dates effective as to children and then adults, see Pub. L. No. 111-148, Title I,
1255 (formerly 1253), 124 Stat. 162 (2010) (renumbered 1255 and amended, Pub. L. No.
111-148, Title X, 10103(e), (f)(1), 124 Stat. 895 (2010), and codified in note to 42 U.S.C.
300gg-3).
36
Health status-related factors include:
(1) Health status.
(2) Medical condition (including both physical and mental illnesses).
(3) Claims experience.
(4) Receipt of health care.
(5) Medical history.
(6) Genetic information.
(7) Evidence of insurability (including conditions arising out of acts of domestic
violence).
(8) Disability.
(9) Any other health status-related factor determined appropriate by the [HHS]
29
Id. 300gg-4 (effective Jan. 1, 2014).

6. Community rating. In the individual and small group markets and the

Exchanges, insurers may vary premium rates only based on (1) whether the plan

covers an individual or a family; (2) rating area; (3) age (limited to a 3to1

ratio); and (4) tobacco use (limited to a 1.5to1 ratio). Id. 300gg(a)(1). Each

state must establish one or more rating areas subject to HHS review. Id.

300gg(a)(2)(B). This rule prevents insurers from varying premiums within a

geographic area based on gender, health status, or other factors.

7. Essential health benefits package. The individual and small group

market plans must contain comprehensive coverage known as the essential health

benefits package, defined above. Id. 300gg-6(a) (effective Jan. 1, 2014),

18022(a). The Act does not impose this requirement on large group market plans.37

8. Preventive service coverage. Insurers must provide coverage for certain

enumerated preventive health services without any deductibles, copays, or other

cost-sharing requirements. Id. 300gg-13(a).

Secretary.
42 U.S.C. 300gg-4(a) (effective Jan. 1, 2014).
37
Rather, the large group market is subject to only a few coverage-reform requirements
that apply broadly to either all insurance plans or group health plans in particular. See Amy
Monahan & Daniel Schwarcz, Will Employers Undermine Health Care Reform by Dumping Sick
Employees?, 97 VA . L. REV . 125, 147 (2011).
30
9. Dependent coverage. Insurers must allow dependent children to remain

on their parents policies until age 26. Id. 300gg-14(a).

10. Elimination of annual and lifetime limits. Insurers may no longer

establish lifetime dollar limits on essential health benefits. Id. 300gg-

11(a)(1)(A), (b). Insurers may retain annual dollar limits on essential health

benefits until 2014.38 Id. 300gg-11(a).

11. Limits on cost-sharing by insureds. Cost-sharing39 includes out-of-

pocket deductibles, coinsurance, copayments, or similar charges and qualified

medical expenses.40 Id. 18022(c)(3)(A). Annual cost-sharing limits apply to

group health plans, health plans sold in the individual market, and qualified health

plans offered through an Exchange.41 Id. 300gg-6(b) (effective Jan. 1, 2014),

18022(a), (c).

38
HHS shall determine what restricted annual limits are permitted on the dollar value of
essential health benefits until 2014. 42 U.S.C. 300gg-11(a)(1), (2). Subsection (a) shall not be
construed to prevent a group health plan or health insurance coverage from placing annual or
lifetime per beneficiary limits on specific covered benefits that are not essential health
benefits . . . . Id. 300gg-11(b).
39
Cost-sharing does not include premiums, balance billing amounts for non-network
providers, or spending for non-covered services. 42 U.S.C. 18022(c)(3)(B).
40
Qualified medical expense is defined in 26 U.S.C. 223(d)(2).
41
Annual limits on cost-sharing are equal to the current limits on out-of-pocket spending
for high-deductible health plans under the Internal Revenue Code (for 2011, $5,950 for self-only
coverage and $11,900 for family coverage), adjusted after 2014 by a premium adjustment
percentage. 42 U.S.C. 300gg-6(b) (effective Jan. 1, 2014), 18022(c)(1); 26 U.S.C.
223(c)(2)(A)(ii), (g); I.R.S. Pub. 969 (2010), at 3.
31
12. Deductibles. Deductibles for any plans offered in the small group

market are capped at $2,000 for plans covering single individuals and $4,000 for

any other plan, adjusted after 2014. Id. 300gg-6(b) (effective Jan. 1, 2014),

18022(c)(2). The deductible limits do not apply to individual plans or large group

plans. See id.

13. Medical loss ratio. Insurers must maintain certain ratios of premium

revenue spent on the insureds medical care versus overhead expenses. Id.

300gg-18(a), (b)(1). In the large group market, insurers must spend 85% of their

premium revenue on patient care and no more than 15% on overhead. Id. 300gg-

18(a), (b)(1)(A)(i). In the individual and small group markets, insurers must spend

80% of their revenue on patient care and no more than 20% on overhead. Id.

300gg-18(a), (b)(1)(A)(ii). This medical-loss ratio requirement applies to all

plans (including grandfathered plans). Id. 300gg-18(a), (b)(1). Insurers must

report to HHS their ratio of incurred claims to earned premiums. Id. 300gg-

18(a).

14. Premium increases. HHS, along with all states, shall annually review

unreasonable increases in premiums beginning in 2010. Id. 300gg-94(a)(1).

Issuers must justify any unreasonable premium increase. Id. 300gg-94(a)(2).

15. Prohibition on coverage rescissions. Insurers may not rescind

32
coverage except for fraud or intentional misrepresentation of material fact. Id.

300gg-12.

16. Single risk pool. Insurers must consider all individual-market enrollees

in their health plans (except enrollees in grandfathered plans) to be members of a

single risk pool (whether enrolled privately or through an Exchange). Id.

18032(c)(1). Small group market enrollees must be considered in the same risk

pool. Id. 18032(c)(2).

17. Temporary high risk pool program. To cover many of the uninsured

immediately, the Act directs HHS to establish a temporary high risk health

insurance pool program to offer coverage to uninsured individuals with

preexisting conditions until the prohibition on preexisting condition exclusions for

adults becomes effective in 2014. Id. 18001(a). The premiums for persons with a

preexisting condition remain what a healthy person would pay. Id.

18001(c)(2)(C), 300gg(a)(1). The Act allocates $5 billion to HHS to cover this

high-risk pool. When this temporary program ends in 2014, such individuals will

be transferred to coverage through an Exchange. Id. 18001(a)(d), (g).

18. State regulation maintained. States will license insurers and enforce

both federal and state insurance laws. Id. 18021(a)(1)(C). The Act provides for

the continued operation of state regulatory authority, even with respect to

33
interstate health care choice compacts, which enable qualified health plans to be

offered in more than one state.42 Id. 18053(a).

In addition to reforming health insurance products, the Act requires the

creation of Exchanges where the uninsured can buy the new products. We examine

this second component of the Act, also designed to make insurance more

accessible and affordable and thus reduce the number of the uninsured.

E. Health Benefit Exchanges

1. Establishment of State-Run Exchanges

By January 1, 2014, all states must establish American Health Benefit

Exchanges and Small Business Health Options Program Exchanges, which are

insurance marketplaces where individuals, families, and small employers can shop

for the Acts new insurance products. Id. 18031(b). Consumers can compare

prices and buy coverage from one of the Exchanges issuers. Id. 18031(b), (c).

Exchanges centralize information and facilitate the use of the Acts significant

federal tax credits and other subsidies to purchase health insurance. See 26 U.S.C.

42
Health care choice compacts allow qualified health plans to be offered in the individual
markets of multiple states, yet such plans will only be subject to the laws and regulations of the
State in which the plan was written or issued. 42 U.S.C. 18053(a)(1)(A). The issuer of such
qualified health plans offered through health care choice compacts would continue to be subject
to market conduct, unfair trade practices, network adequacy, and consumer protection standards
. . . of the State in which the purchaser resides and would be required to be licensed in each
State in which it offers the plan under the compact. Id. 18053(a)(1)(B)(i)(ii).
34
36B; 42 U.S.C. 18031, 18071, 1808183. States may create and run the

Exchanges through a governmental or nonprofit entity. 42 U.S.C. 18031(d)(1).

States may establish regional, interstate, or subsidiary Exchanges. Id.

18031(f). The federal government will provide funding until January 1, 2015 to

establish Exchanges. Id. 18031(a). Insurers may offer their products inside or

outside these Exchanges, or both. Id. 18032(d).

Importantly, the Exchanges draw upon the states significant experience

regulating the health insurance industry. See id. 18041. The Act allows states

some flexibility in operations and enforcement, though states must either (1)

directly adopt the federal requirements set forth by HHS, or (2) adopt state

regulations that effectively implement the federal standards, as determined by

HHS. Id. 18041(b). In a subsection entitled, No interference with State

regulatory authority, the Act provides that [n]othing in this chapter shall be

construed to preempt any State law that does not prevent the application of the

provisions of this chapter. Id. 18041(d).

2. Qualified Individuals and Employers in the Exchanges

The Act provides that qualified individuals and qualified employers

may purchase insurance through the Exchanges. Id. 18031(d)(2). Although

35
qualified individuals is broadly defined,43 qualified employers are initially

limited to small employers, but in 2017, states may allow large employers to

participate in their Exchanges. Id. 18032(f)(2)(A), (B). Qualified employers can

purchase group plans in or out of Exchanges. Id. 18032(d)(1).

3. Qualified Health Plans in the Exchanges

The Act prescribes the types of plans available in the Exchanges, known as

qualified health plans. Id. 18031(d)(2)(B)(i). A qualified health plan is a

health plan that: (1) is certified as a qualified health plan in each Exchange

through which the plan is offered; (2) provides an essential health benefits

package; and (3) is offered by an issuer that (a) is licensed and in good standing

in each state where it offers coverage, and (b) complies with HHS regulations and

any requirements of the Exchange. Id. 18021(a)(1). The issuer must agree, inter

alia, to offer at least one plan in the silver level and one in the gold level in

each Exchange in which it participates, as described in 18022(d). Id.

18021(a)(1)(C). The issuer must charge the same premium rate regardless of

43
A qualified individual is a legal resident who (1) seeks to enroll in a qualified health
plan in the individual market through the Exchange, and (2) resides in the state that established
the Exchange. 42 U.S.C. 18032(f)(1), (3). Prisoners and illegal aliens may not purchase
insurance through Exchanges. Id. 18032(f)(1)(B), (3).
36
whether a plan is offered in an Exchange or directly.44 Id.

4. Essential Health Benefits Package and Catastrophic Plans

The essential health benefits package is required of all qualified health

plans sold in the Exchanges. Id. 18021(a)(1)(B). States may require that a

qualified health plan offered in that state cover benefits in addition to essential

health benefits, but the state must defray the costs of additional coverage through

payments directly to patients or insurers. Id. 18031(d)(3)(B).

One significant exception to the essential health benefits package

requirement is the catastrophic plan in the individual market only. In and outside

the Exchanges, insurers may offer catastrophic plans which provide no benefits

until a certain level of out-of-pocket costs$5,950 for self-only coverage and

$11,900 for family coverage in 2011are incurred. Id. 18022(e); see id.

18022(c)(1), (e)(1)(B)(i); 26 U.S.C. 223(c)(2)(A)(ii), (g); I.R.S. Pub. 969

(2010), at 3. The level of out-of-pocket costs is equal to the current limits on out-

of-pocket spending for high deductible health plans adjusted after 2014. 42 U.S.C.

18022(e), (c)(1).

44
HHS establishes the criteria for certification of insurance plans as qualified health
plans and develops a rating system to rate qualified health plans offered through an Exchange
in each benefits level on the basis of the relative quality and price. 42 U.S.C. 18031(c)(1), (3).
States must rate each health plan offered in an Exchange (in accordance with federal standards)
and certify health plans as qualified health plans. See id. 18031(e).
37
This catastrophic plan exception applies only if the plan: (1) is sold in the

individual market; (2) restricts enrollment to those under age 30 or certain persons

exempted from the individual mandate; (3) provides the essential health benefits

coverage after the out-of-pocket level is met; and (4) provides coverage for at least

three primary care visits. Id. 18022(e)(1), (2).

5. Federal Premium Tax Credit

To reduce the number of the uninsured, the Act also establishes

considerable federal tax credits for individuals and families (1) with household

incomes between 1 and 4 times the federal poverty level; (2) who do not receive

health insurance through an employer; and (3) who purchase health insurance

through an Exchange.45 26 U.S.C. 36B(a), (b), (c)(1)(A)(C).

To receive the credit, eligible individuals must enroll in a plan offered

45
Specifically, the amount of the federal tax credit for a given month is an amount equal
to the lesser of (1) the monthly premiums for the qualified health plan or plans, offered in the
individual market through an Exchange, that cover the taxpayer and the members of the
taxpayers household, or (2) the excess of: (a) the monthly premium the taxpayer would be
charged for the second lowest-cost silver plan over (b) 1/12 of the taxpayers yearly household
income multiplied by the applicable percentage, a percentage which ranges from 2.0% to 9.5%,
depending on income. 26 U.S.C. 36B(b)(3)(A)(C).
An example helps translate. For a family of four with an income of $33,075 per year,
assuming that the premium in the second lowest-cost silver plan covering the family is $4,500
per year ($375 per month), the federal tax credit would be $3,177 per year ($264.75 per month).
See Families USA, Lower Taxes, Lower Premiums: The New Health Insurance Tax Credit 8
(2010), available at http://www.familiesusa.org/assets/pdfs/health-reform/Premium-Tax-
Credits.pdf. Without the federal tax credit, the family pays $375 per month; with the credit, the
family pays $110.25 per month, or a total of $1,323, instead of the full $4,500 premium. Id. The
federal tax credit provides a major incentive for the uninsured (in the individual market) to
purchase insurance from a private insurer but through the Exchange.
38
through an Exchange and report their income to the Exchange. 42 U.S.C.

18081(b). If the individuals income level qualifies, the Treasury pays the

premium tax credit amount directly to the individuals insurance plan issuer. Id.

18082(c)(2)(A). The individual pays only the dollar difference between the

premium tax credit and the total premium charged. Id. 18082(c)(2)(B). The

credit amount is tied to the cost of the second-cheapest plan in the silver level

offered through an Exchange where the individual resides, though the credit may

be used for any plan purchased through an Exchange.46 See 26 U.S.C. 36B(b)(2).

6. Federal Cost-Sharing Subsidies

The Act also provides a variety of federal cost-sharing subsidies to reduce

the out-of-pocket expenses for individuals who (1) enroll in a qualified health plan

46
Commentators have explained the operation of the tax credit for households between
one and four times the federal poverty level as follows:
For taxable years after 2013, certain low- and moderate-income individuals who
purchase insurance under a health insurance exchange that the states are required to
create will receive a refundable credit that subsidizes their purchase of that insurance.
. . . According to the Social Security Administration, the current poverty level for a
single individual is $10,830; thus a single individual can have household income of
as much as $43,320 and still qualify to have his insurance cost subsidized by the
government. For a family of four, the current poverty level is $22,050; such a family
can have household income as large as $88,200 and still qualify for a subsidy.
Douglas A. Kahn & Jeffrey H. Kahn, Free Rider: A Justification for Mandatory Medical
Insurance Under Health Care Reform, 109 MICH . L. REV . FIRST IMPRESSIONS 78, 83 (2011).
HHS has since raised the poverty level for 2011 to $22,350 for a family of four and
$10,890 for a single individual. 76 Fed. Reg. 3637, 3638 (Jan. 20, 2011). Thus, a single
individual can have a household income of as much as $43,560 and still be eligible for a federal
tax credit. A family of four can have a household income of as much as $89,400 and still be
eligible for a federal tax credit. See 42 U.S.C. 18071(b).
39
sold through an Exchange in the silver level of coverage, and (2) have a household

income between 1 and 4 times the federal poverty level. 42 U.S.C. 18071.

As noted earlier, the Exchanges, with significant federal tax credits and

subsidies, are predicted to make insurance available to 9 million in 2014 and 22

million by 2016.47 We now turn to the Acts third component: the individual

mandate.

F. Individual Mandate

The individual mandate and its penalty are housed entirely in the Internal

Revenue Code, in subtitle D, labeled Miscellaneous Excise Taxes. 26 U.S.C.

5000A et seq. The Act mandates that, after 2013, all applicable individuals (1)

shall maintain minimum essential coverage for themselves and their dependents,

or (2) pay a monetary penalty. Id. 5000A(a)(b). Taxpayers must include the

penalty on their annual federal tax return. Id. 5000A(b)(2). Married taxpayers

filing a joint return are jointly liable for any penalty. Id. 5000A(b)(3)(B).

47
CBO, Analysis, supra note 15, at 18 tbl.3. The CBO predicts that by 2019, 24 million
will be insured through the Exchanges, with at least four-fifths receiving federal subsidies to
substantially reduce the cost of purchasing health insurance coverage, on average $6,460 per
person. Id. at 2, 1819 tbl.3.
The CBO estimates that this 9 million increase in 2014 will be partially offset by a 3
million decrease in individual-market coverage outside the Exchanges. Id. The number obtaining
coverage in the individual market outside the Exchanges is projected to decrease because the Act
incentivizes individualsthrough premium tax credits, subsidies, and otherwiseto purchase
policies through the Exchanges. Similarly, the 22 million increase in Exchange-based coverage in
2016 will be partially offset by a 5 million decrease in those covered by individual-market
policies obtained outside the Exchanges. Id.
40
1. Minimum Essential Coverage

At first glance, the term minimum essential coverage, as used in the

Internal Revenue Code, sounds like it refers to a base level of benefits or services.

However, the Act uses a different termthe essential health benefits package in

Title 42to describe health care benefits and services. 42 U.S.C. 300gg-6(a)

(effective Jan. 1, 2014). In contrast, minimum essential coverage refers to a

broad array of plan types that will satisfy the individual mandate. 26 U.S.C.

5000A(f)(1).

An individual can satisfy the mandates minimum essential coverage

requirement through: (1) any government-funded health plan such as Medicare

Part A, Medicaid, TRICARE, or CHIP; (2) any eligible employer-sponsored

plan; (3) any health plan in the individual market; (4) any grandfathered health

plan; or (5) as a catch-all, such other health benefits coverage that is recognized

by HHS in coordination with the Treasury. Id. The mandate provisions in 5000A

do not specify what benefits must be in that plan. The listed plans, in many

instances, satisfy the mandate regardless of the level of benefits or coverage.

2. Government-Sponsored Programs

For example, a variety of government-sponsored programs will satisfy the

individual mandate. For individuals 65 or over, enrolling in Medicare Part A will

41
suffice. Id. 5000A(f)(1)(A)(i). Individuals and families may satisfy the mandate

by enrolling in Medicaid, if eligible. Id. 5000A(f)(1)(A)(ii). Qualifying children

under age 19 can satisfy the mandate by enrolling in CHIP. Id.

5000A(f)(1)(A)(iii). Government-sponsored programs for veterans, active and

former military personnel and their families, active Peace Corps volunteers, and

active and retired civilian Defense Department personnel and their dependents

satisfy the mandate. Id. 5000A(f)(1)(A)(iv), (v), (vi).

3. Eligible Employer-Sponsored Plans

Individuals may also satisfy the mandate by purchasing coverage through

any eligible employer-sponsored plan. Id. 5000A(f)(1)(B). An eligible

employer-sponsored plan is a group health plan or group health insurance

coverage offered by an employer to the employee, which is defined broadly as:

(1) a governmental plan established by the federal, state, or local government for

its employees; (2) any other plan or coverage offered in the small or large group

market within a State; or (3) a grandfathered health plan offered in a group

market. Id. 5000A(f)(2). Health plans of large employers satisfy the individual

mandate whatever the nature of the benefits offered to the employee.48

48
Because of these looser restrictions, some commentators have found it surprising that
employer-sponsored coverage qualifies as minimum essential coverage under the Act. See
Monahan & Schwarcz, supra note 37, at 157 (Surprisingly, . . . [the Act] appears to define
employer-provided coverage as automatically constituting minimum essential coverage for
42
Whether a self-insured health plan of large employers satisfies the

mandate is another story.49 The mandates 5000A(f)(2) refers to plans in the

small or large group market. Id. 5000A(f)(2). A self-insured health plan, by

definition, is not sold or offered in a market. It is thus not clear whether large

employers self-insured plans will constitute eligible employer-sponsored plans

in 5000A(f)(2) and thereby satisfy the mandate. It may be that HHS will later

recognize self-insured plans under the other coverage or grandfathered plan

categories in the mandates 5000A(f)(2).

4. Plans in the Individual Market

Individuals can also satisfy the mandate by purchasing insurance in the

individual market through Exchanges or directly from issuers. Id.

5000A(f)(1)(C). The Act imposes the essential health benefits package

requirement on plans sold in the individual and small group markets. 42 U.S.C.

300gg-6 (effective Jan. 1, 2014). However, in the individual market, insurers can

offer catastrophic plans to persons under age 30 or certain persons exempted from

the mandate. Id. 18022(e).

individuals, despite the minimal requirements applicable to such plans.).


49
The Act defines an applicable self-insured health plan to include self-insured plans
providing health care coverage where any portion of such coverage is provided other than
through an insurance policy. 26 U.S.C. 4376(c).
43
5. Grandfathered Plans

An already-insured individual can fulfill the individual mandate by being

covered by any grandfathered health plan, 26 U.S.C. 5000A(f)(1)(D), which is

any group health plan or health insurance coverage in which an individual was

enrolled on March 23, 2010.50 42 U.S.C. 18011(a)(1), (e).

While not subject to many of the Acts product reforms, grandfathered plans

must comply with some provisions, among them the extension of dependent

coverage until age 26, the medical-loss ratio requirements, and the prohibitions on

(1) preexisting condition exclusions, (2) lifetime limits on coverage, (3) excessive

waiting periods, and (4) unfair rescissions of coverage. Id. 18011(a)(2)(4), (e).

Under the interim final regulations issued by HHS, plans will lose their

grandfathered status if they choose to significantly (1) cut or eliminate benefits;

(2) increase copayments, deductibles, or out-of-pocket costs for their enrollees; (3)

decrease the share of premiums employers contribute for workers in group plans;

50
The Act also allows the enrollment of family members and newly hired employees in
grandfathered plans without losing the plans grandfathered status. 42 U.S.C. 18011(b), (c).
Under the interim final regulations issued by HHS, [a] group health plan or group health
insurance coverage does not cease to be grandfathered health plan coverage merely because one
or more (or even all) individuals enrolled on March 23, 2010 cease to be covered, provided that
the plan has continuously covered someone since March 23, 2010 (not necessarily the same
person, but at all times at least one person). 45 C.F.R. 147.140(a)(1)(i).
44
or (4) decrease annual limits.51 45 C.F.R. 147.140(g).

6. Other Coverage Recognized by HHS

The individual mandate even provides a catch-all that leaves open the door

to other health coverage. The minimum essential coverage requirement may be

met by any other coverage that HHS, in coordination with the Treasury, recognizes

for purposes of meeting this requirement. 26 U.S.C. 5000A(f)(1)(E).

7. Exemptions and Exceptions to Individual Mandate

The individual mandate, however, does not apply to eight broad categories

of persons, either by virtue of an exemption from the mandate or an exception to

the mandates penalty. The Act carves out these three exemptions from the

individual mandate: (1) persons with religious exemptions; (2) aliens not legally

present in the country; and (3) incarcerated persons. Id. 5000A(d).

The Act also excepts five additional categories of persons from the

individual mandate penalty: (1) individuals whose required annual premium

contribution exceeds 8% of their household income for the taxable year;52 (2)

51
See also HealthReform.gov, Fact Sheet: Keeping the Health Plan You Have: The
Affordable Care Act and Grandfathered Health Plans,
http://www.healthreform.gov/newsroom/keeping_the_health_plan_you_have.html; Families
USA, Grandfathered Plans under the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act (2010),
available at http://www.familiesusa.org/assets/pdfs/health-reform/Grandfathered-Plans.pdf.
52
The required contribution for coverage means, generally, the amount required to
maintain coverage either in an employer-sponsored health plan or in a bronze-level plan offered
on an Exchange. See 26 U.S.C. 5000A(e)(1)(A).
45
individuals whose household income for the taxable year is below the federal

income tax filing threshold in 26 U.S.C. 6012(a)(1); (3) members of Indian

tribes; (4) individuals whose gaps in health insurance coverage last less than three

months; and (5) as a catch-all, individuals who, as determined by HHS, have

suffered a hardship regarding their ability to obtain coverage under a qualified

health plan. Id. 5000A(e).

8. Calculation of Individual Mandate Penalty

If an applicable individual fails to purchase an insurance plan in one of the

many ways allowed, the individual must pay a penalty. Id. 5000A(b)(1). The

annual penalty will be either: (1) a flat dollar amount, or (2) a percentage of the

individuals income if higher than the flat rate. Id. 5000A(c)(1). However, the

percentage-of-income figure is capped at the national average premium amount for

bronze-level plans in the Exchanges.53 Id.

The flat dollar penalty amount, which sets the floor, is equal to $95 in 2014,

$325 in 2015, and $695 in 2016. Id. 5000A(c)(2)(A), (c)(3)(A)(C). Beyond

2016, it remains $695, except for inflation adjustments.54 Id. 5000A(c)(3)(D).

53
If the individual fails to fulfill the mandate requirement for only certain months as
opposed to a full year, the penalty for each month of no coverage is equal to one-twelfth of the
greater of these figures. 26 U.S.C. 5000A(c)(2)(3).
54
The flat dollar amount applies to each individual and dependent in the taxpayers
household without minimum essential coverage, but will not exceed three times the flat dollar
amount (even if more than three persons are in the household). 26 U.S.C. 5000A(c)(2)(A). A
46
The percentage-of-income number that will apply, if higher than the flat

dollar amount, is a set percentage of the taxpayers income that is in excess of the

tax-filing threshold (defined in 26 U.S.C. 6012(a)(1)).55 Id. 5000A(c)(2). In

any event, the total penalty for the taxable year cannot exceed the national average

premium of a bronze-level qualified health plan. Id. 5000A(c)(1).

9. Collection of Individual Mandate Penalty

An individual who fails to pay the penalty is not subject to criminal or

additional civil penalties. Id. 5000A(g)(2)(A), (B). The IRSs authority to use

liens or levies does not apply to the penalty. Id. 5000A(g)(2)(B). No interest

accrues on the penalty. The Act contains no enforcement mechanism. See id. All

the IRS, practically speaking, can do is offset any tax refund owed to the

uninsured taxpayer.56

We now review the Acts fourth component aimed at reducing the number

of the uninsured: the employer penalty.

G. Employer Penalty

familys flat dollar penalty in 2016 would not exceed $2,085 ($695 multiplied by 3).
55
The percentage by which the taxpayers household income exceeds the filing threshold
is phased in over three years: 1% in 2014, 2% in 2015, and 2.5% in 2016 and thereafter. 26
U.S.C. 5000A(c)(2)(B)(i)(iii).
56
Of course, the government can always file a civil lawsuit, but the cost of that suit would
exceed the modest penalty amount.
47
The Act imposes a penalty, also housed in the Internal Revenue Code, on

certain employers if they do not offer coverage, or offer inadequate coverage, to

their employees. Id. 4980H(a), (b). The penalty applies to employers with an

average of at least 50 full-time employees. Id. 4980H(a), (b), (c)(2). The

employer must pay a penalty if the employer: (1) does not offer its full-time

employees the opportunity to enroll in minimum essential coverage under an

eligible employer-sponsored plan as defined in 5000(A)(f)(2); or (2) offers

minimum essential coverage (i) that is unaffordable, or (ii) that consists of a

plan whose share of the total cost of benefits is less than 60% (i.e., does not

provide minimum value); and (3) at least one full-time employee purchases a

qualified health plan through an Exchange and is allowed a premium tax credit or

a subsidy. Id. 4980H(a), (c).

The employer penalty is tied to an employers failure to offer minimum

essential coverage. Id. 4980H(a), (b). Recall that minimum essential coverage

is not the same thing as the essential health benefits package. Thus, a large

employer may avoid the penalty so long as it offers any plan in the large group

market in the state, and the plan is affordable and provides minimum value.

Id. 4980H(b)(1), (c)(3).

A small employers plan, however, must include an essential health

48
benefits package and also be affordable and provide minimum value. 42

U.S.C. 300gg-6(a) (effective Jan. 1, 2014), 18022(a)(1)(3). The Act also

provides tax incentives for certain small employers (up to 25 employees) to

purchase health insurance for their workers. 26 U.S.C. 45R.

1. Calculation of Penalty Amount

The penalty amount depends on whether the employee went to the

Exchange because the employers plan (1) was not minimum essential coverage

or (2) was either unaffordable or did not provide minimum value. The penalty

translates to $2,000 to $3,000 per employee annually. Id. 4980H.

An employer that does not offer minimum essential coverage to all full-

time employees faces a tax penalty of $166.67 per month (one-twelfth of $2,000)

for each of its full-time employees, until the employer offers such coverage

(subject to an exemption for the first 30 full-time employees). Id. 4980H(a),

(c)(1), (c)(2)(D). This particular penalty applies for as long as at least one

employee, eligible for a premium tax credit or a subsidy, enrolls in a qualified

health plan through an Exchange. Id.

In the unaffordable coverage57 or no minimum value scenarios, the

57
Employer-sponsored coverage that is not affordable is defined as coverage where the
employees required annual contribution to the premium is more than 9.5% of the employees
household income (as defined for purposes of the premium tax credits in the Exchanges). 26
U.S.C. 36B(c)(2)(C)(i). This percentage of the employees income is indexed to the per capita
49
employer faces a tax penalty of $250 per month (one-twelfth of $3,000) for each

employee who (1) turns down the employer-sponsored plan; (2) purchases a

qualified health plan in an Exchange; and (3) is eligible for a federal premium tax

credit or subsidy in an Exchange.58 Id. 4980H(b)(1).

2. Automatic Enrollment

An automatic enrollment requirement applies to employers who (1) have

more than 200 employees and (2) elect to offer coverage to their employees. Id.

218a. Such employers must automatically enroll new and current full-time

employees, who do not opt out, in one of the employers plans. Id. The maximum

90-day waiting period rule applies, however. Id.; 42 U.S.C. 300gg-7 (effective

Jan. 1, 2014).

3. Temporary Reinsurance Program for Employers Early Retirees

To reduce the number of the uninsured, the Act provides for immediate

coverage for even retired employees 55 years and older who are not yet eligible for

growth in premiums for the insurance market as determined by HHS. Id. 36B(c)(2)(C)(iv).
Note that the definition of unaffordable for the purposes of obtaining a federal tax credit or
subsidy is not the same standard that is used to determine whether an individual is exempt from
the individual mandate because that individual cannot afford coverage. Compare id.
36B(c)(2)(C)(i), with id. 5000A(e)(1).
58
The employers penalty, in this instance, does not exceed the maximum penalty for
offering no coverage at all. The penalty for any month is capped at an amount equal to the
number of full-time employees during the month multiplied by one-twelfth of $2,000, or $166.67
(subject to the exemption for the first 30 full-time employees). See 26 U.S.C. 4980H(b)(2), (c).
50
Medicare. A federal temporary reinsurance program will reimburse former

employers who allow their early retirees and the retirees dependents and spouses

to participate in their employment-based plans. The federal government will

reimburse a portion of the plans cost.59 42 U.S.C. 18002(a)(1), (a)(2)(C).

We turn to the Acts fifth component: the Medicaid expansion, which alone

will cover millions of the uninsured.

H. Medicaid Expansion

The Act expands Medicaid eligibility and subsidies by amending 42 U.S.C.

1396a, the section of the Medicaid Act outlining what states must offer in their

coverage plans. The Act imposes these substantive requirements on the states

plans, starting in 2014, unless otherwise noted:

(1) States will be required to cover adults under age 65 (who are not

pregnant and not already covered) with incomes up to 133% of the federal poverty

level (FPL). Id. 1396a(a)(10)(A)(i)(VIII). This is a significant change, because

previously the Medicaid Act did not set a baseline income level for mandatory

eligibility. Thus, many states currently do not provide Medicaid to childless adults

59
The plan shall submit claims for reimbursement to HHS, and HHS shall reimburse the
plan for 80% of the costs of claims in excess of $15,000 but not greater than $90,000. 42 U.S.C.
18002(c)(2). The reimbursements will be available until January 1, 2014. Id. 18002(a)(1).
This federally-subsidized temporary program closes the gap between now and 2014, when the
Exchanges, with their federal tax credits and subsidies, become operational.
51
and cover parents only at much lower income levels.

(2) States will be required to provide Medicaid to all children whose

families earn up to 133% of the FPL, including children currently covered through

separate CHIP programs. Id. 1396a(a)(10)(A)(i)(VII), 1396a(l)(1)(D),

1396a(l)(2)(C). States currently must provide Medicaid to children under age 6

with family income up to 133% of the FPL and children ages 6 through 18 with

family income up to 100% of the FPL. Id. 1396a(a)(10)(A)(i)(IV), (VI), (VII),

1396a(l)(1)(B)(D), 1396a(l)(2)(A)(C).

(3) States are required to at least maintain existing Medicaid eligibility

levels for adults and children (that were in place as of March 23, 2010) until a

states Exchange is fully operational. Id. 1396a(gg)(1). Whereas states

previously had the option to raise or lower their eligibility levels, states cannot

institute more restrictive eligibility standards until the new policies take place. Id.

(4) Children under age 26 who were receiving Medicaid but were aged

out of foster care will be newly eligible to continue receiving Medicaid. Id.

1396a(a)(10)(A)(i)(IX) (effective Jan. 1, 2014).

(5) The new law will increase Medicaid payments for primary care services

provided by primary care doctors to 100% of the Medicare payment rates for 2013

and 2014. Id. 1396a(a)(13)(C). States will receive 100% federal funding for the

52
cost of the increasing payment rates for 2013 and 2014.60 Id. 1396d(dd).

Having covered the Acts five major components, we examine the two

components challenged as unconstitutional: (1) the Medicaid expansion and (2)

the individual mandate.

III. CONSTITUTIONALITY OF MEDICAID EXPANSION

The state plaintiffs challenge the district courts grant of summary judgment

in favor of the government on the state plaintiffs claim that the Acts expansion of

the Medicaid program, enacted pursuant to the Spending Clause, is unduly

coercive under South Dakota v. Dole, 483 U.S. 203, 211, 107 S. Ct. 2793, 2798

(1987). For the reasons given below, we conclude that it is not.

A. History of the Medicaid Program

Medicaid is a long-standing partnership between the national and state

sovereigns that has been in place for nearly half a century. In 1965, Congress

enacted the Medicaid Act, 42 U.S.C. 1396 et seq., as Title XIX of the Social

Security Act. Moore ex rel. Moore v. Reese, 637 F.3d 1220, 1232 (11th Cir.

2011); see also Harris v. McRae, 448 U.S. 297, 301, 100 S. Ct. 2671, 2680 (1980).

Medicaid is a jointly financed federal-state cooperative program, designed to help

states furnish medical treatment to their needy citizens. Reese, 637 F.3d at 1232.

60
See also Julie Stone, et al., Cong. Research Serv., R41210, Medicaid and the State
Childrens Health Insurance Program (CHIP) Provisions in the PPACA 24 (2010).
53
The Medicaid Act prescribes substantive requirements governing the scope of

each states program. Curtis v. Taylor, 625 F.2d 645, 649 (5th Cir. 1980).61

Section 1396a provides that a State plan for medical assistance must meet

various guidelines, including the provision of certain categories of care and

services. Reese, 637 F.3d at 1232 (citing 42 U.S.C. 1396a). Some of these

categories are discretionary, while others are mandatory for participating states.

Id. (citing 42 U.S.C. 1396a(a)(10)).

Under the Act, the Medicaid program serves as a cornerstone for expanded

health care coverage. As explained above in Section II(H), the Act expands

Medicaid eligibility and provides significant Medicaid subsidies to the

impoverished. As a result of the Acts Medicaid expansion, an estimated 9 million

of the 50 million uninsured will be covered for health care by 2014 (and 16

million by 2016 and 17 million by 2021).62

The federal government will pay 100% of the fees associated with the

increased Medicaid eligibility and subsidies beginning in 2014 and until 2016;

that percentage will then drop gradually each year until reaching 90% in 2020. 42

61
In Bonner v. City of Prichard, 661 F.2d 1206, 1209 (11th Cir. 1981) (en banc), this
Court adopted as binding precedent all decisions of the former Fifth Circuit issued before the
close of business on September 30, 1981.
62
CBO, Analysis, supra note 15, at 18 tbl.3.
54
U.S.C. 1396d(y)(1). The federal government will not cover administrative

expenses associated with implementing the new Medicaid policies. See id. Under

42 U.S.C. 1396c, a state whose plan does not comply with the requirements

under 1396a will be notified by HHS of its noncompliance, and further

payments will not be made to the State (or, in [HHSs] discretion . . . payments

will be limited to categories under or parts of the State plan not affected by such

failure), until [HHS] is satisfied that there will no longer be any such failure to

comply. Id. 1396c.

B. Congresss Power under the Spending Clause

The Spending Clause provides that Congress shall have Power . . . to pay

the Debts and provide for the common Defence and general Welfare of the United

States. U.S. CONST. art. I, 8, cl. 1. The Spending Clause permits Congress to

fix the terms on which it shall disburse federal money to the States. Pennhurst

State Sch. & Hosp. v. Halderman, 451 U.S. 1, 17, 101 S. Ct. 1531, 1539 (1981).

[L]egislation enacted pursuant to the spending power is much in the nature of a

contract: in return for federal funds, the States agree to comply with federally

imposed conditions. Id. at 17, 101 S. Ct. at 1540.

There are four primary restrictions on legislation enacted pursuant to the

Spending Clause. First, the exercise of the spending power must be in pursuit of

55
the general welfare. See Helvering v. Davis, 301 U.S. 619, 640, 57 S. Ct. 904, 908

(1937). Second, the conditions on the receipt of federal funds must be reasonably

related to the legislations stated goal. Dole, 483 U.S. at 207, 107 S. Ct. at 2796.

Third, Congresss intent to condition funds on a particular action must be

unambiguous and must enable the states to knowingly exercise their choice

whether to participate. Pennhurst, 451 U.S. at 17, 101 S. Ct. at 1540. Finally, the

federal legislation cannot induce the States to engage in activities that would

themselves be unconstitutional. Dole, 483 U.S. at 210, 107 S. Ct. at 2798. The

state plaintiffs do not contend the Acts Medicaid expansion violates any of these

restrictions.63

Rather, the state plaintiffs argue that the Medicaid expansion violates an

additional limitation on the use of the spending power to encourage state

legislation, one that derives not from the spending power alone, but also from the

63
The state plaintiffs suggest that the conditions imposed here violated the second Dole
restriction because they have no reasonable relationship to the size of the federal inducement.
States Opening Br. at 48, 53. In so arguing, the plaintiffs misinterpret Dole. The Supreme Court
made clear that the required relationship is between the conditions imposed and the federal
interest in particular national projects or programs, Dole, 483 U.S. at 207, 107 S. Ct. at 2796
(quotation marks omitted)that is, the purpose of federal spending. New York v. United
States, 505 U.S. 144, 167, 122 S. Ct. 2408, 2423 (1992). The state plaintiffs mistakenly assert
that the required relationship is between the conditions imposed and the size of the federal
inducement. States Opening Br. at 53. The condition Congress imposes here on the receipt of
federal fundsrequiring Medicaid coverage of certain newly eligible individualsis undeniably
related to the purpose of the Medicaid Act, which is to provid[e] federal financial assistance to
States that choose to reimburse certain costs of medical treatment for needy persons. McRae,
448 U.S. at 301, 100 S. Ct. at 2680.
56
Tenth Amendments reservation of certain powers to the states. U.S. CONST.

amend. X; see Charles C. Steward Mach. Co. v. Davis, 301 U.S. 548, 585, 57 S.

Ct. 883, 890 (1937); West Virginia v. HHS, 289 F.3d 281, 28687 (4th Cir. 2002).

Congress may not employ the spending power in such a way as to coerce the

states into compliance with the federal objective. See Dole, 483 U.S. at 211, 107 S.

Ct. at 2798; Steward Mach., 301 U.S. at 58991, 57 S. Ct. at 89293; cf. Coll. Sav.

Bank v. Fla. Prepaid Postsecondary Educ. Expense Bd., 527 U.S. 666, 687, 119 S.

Ct. 2219, 2231 (1999) (holding that a states waiver of its sovereign immunity is

not voluntary where Congress has made it a condition of the states participation

in an otherwise lawful activity). This restriction is different from the restrictions

stemming from the spending power because it addresses whether the legislation,

while perhaps an appropriate use of the spending power, goes beyond the

Spending Clause by forcing the states to participate in a federal program. Cf.

Printz v. United States, 521 U.S. 898, 117 S. Ct. 2365 (1997) (holding that

Congress may not enact a law pursuant to one of its enumerated powers and then

compel state officers to execute those federal laws); see also Steward Mach., 301

U.S. at 585, 57 S. Ct. at 890. That is, the coercion test asks whether the federal

scheme removes state choice and compels the state to act because the state, in fact,

has no other option.

57
The coercion doctrine was first discussed at length by the Supreme Court in

Charles C. Steward Machine Co. v. Davis. In that case, a corporation challenged

the imposition of an employment tax under the newly enacted Social Security Act.

Addressing the corporations argument that the federal government improperly

coerced states into participation in the Social Security program, the Supreme Court

stated:

The difficulty with the petitioners contention is that it confuses motive


with coercion. Every tax is in some measure regulatory. To some extent
it interposes an economic impediment to the activity taxed as compared
with others not taxed. In like manner every rebate from a tax when
conditioned upon conduct is in some measure a temptation. But to hold
that motive or temptation is equivalent to coercion is to plunge the law
in endless difficulties. The outcome of such a doctrine is the acceptance
of a philosophical determinism by which choice becomes impossible.
Till now the law has been guided by a robust common sense which
assumes the freedom of the will as a working hypothesis in the solution
of its problems. . . . Nothing in the case suggests the exertion of a power
akin to undue influence, if we assume that such a concept can ever be
applied with fitness to the relations between state and nation. Even on
that assumption the location of the point at which pressure turns into
compulsion, and ceases to be inducement, would be a question of
degree, at times, perhaps, of fact.

301 U.S. at 58990, 57 S. Ct. at 892 (quotation marks and citation omitted)

(emphasis added).

This discussion of the coercion doctrine was later revived by the Supreme

Court in South Dakota v. Dole. In Dole, the state of South Dakota challenged 23

U.S.C. 158, which directed the Secretary of Transportation to withhold a

58
percentage of federal highway funds otherwise allocable to the states if states

failed to maintain a minimum drinking-age requirement of 21 years. 483 U.S. at

205, 107 S. Ct. at 2795. The Court noted that Congress may attach conditions on

the receipt of federal funds to meet certain policy objectives, including those that

Congress could not otherwise meet through direct regulation. Id. at 20607, 107 S.

Ct. at 279596. After analyzing whether the minimum drinking-age condition met

the four restrictions on the Spending Clause discussed above, the Court noted,

Our decisions have recognized that in some circumstances the financial

inducement offered by Congress might be so coercive as to pass the point at which

pressure turns into compulsion. Id. at 211, 107 S. Ct. at 2798 (quoting Steward

Mach., 301 U.S. at 590, 57 S. Ct. at 892). It further opined:

When we consider, for a moment, that all South Dakota would


lose if she adheres to her chosen course as to a suitable minimum
drinking age is 5% of the funds otherwise obtainable under specified
highway grant programs, the argument as to coercion is shown to be
more rhetoric than fact. . . .
Here Congress has offered relatively mild encouragement to the
States to enact higher minimum drinking ages than they would otherwise
choose. But the enactment of such laws remains the prerogative of the
States not merely in theory but in fact.

Id. (emphasis added). Thus, the Court once again recognized the coercion

doctrine, but found no violation.

The limited case law on the doctrine of coercion and the fact that the

59
Supreme Court has never devised a test to apply it has left many circuits with the

conclusion that the doctrine, twice recognized by the Supreme Court, is not a

viable defense to Spending Clause legislation. See, e.g., Pace v. Bogalusa City

Sch. Bd., 403 F.3d 272, 278 (5th Cir. 2005) (en banc) (It goes without saying that,

because states have the independent power to lay and collect taxes, they retain the

ability to avoid the imposition of unwanted federal regulation simply by rejecting

federal funds.); A.W. v. Jersey City Pub. Schs., 341 F.3d 234, 24344 (3d Cir.

2003) (noting that the states freedom to tax makes it difficult to find a federal law

coercive, even when that law threatens to withhold all federal funding in a

particular area); Kansas v. United States, 214 F.3d 1196, 120102 (10th Cir. 2000)

(The cursory statements in Steward Machine and Dole mark the extent of the

Supreme Courts discussion of a coercion theory. The Court has never employed

the theory to invalidate a funding condition, and federal courts have been similarly

reluctant to use it. (footnote omitted)); id. at 1202 (observing that the theory is

unclear, suspect, and has little precedent to support its application); California v.

United States, 104 F.3d 1086, 1092 (9th Cir. 1997) (noting in a Medicaid

expansion case that to the extent that there is any viability left in the coercion

theory, it is not reflected in the facts of this record); Nevada v. Skinner, 884 F.2d

445, 448 (9th Cir. 1989) (The difficulty if not the impropriety of making judicial

60
judgments regarding a states financial capabilities renders the coercion theory

highly suspect as a method for resolving disputes between federal and state

governments.); Oklahoma v. Schweiker, 655 F.2d 401, 414 (D.C. Cir. 1981)

(The courts are not suited to evaluating whether the states are faced here with an

offer they cannot refuse or merely a hard choice. . . . We therefore follow the lead

of other courts that have explicitly declined to enter this thicket when similar

funding conditions have been at issue.) (pre-Dole); N.H. Dept of Empt Sec. v.

Marshall, 616 F.2d 240, 246 (1st Cir. 1980) (Petitioners argue, however, that this

option of the state to refuse to participate in the program is illusory, since the

severe financial consequences that would follow such refusal negate any real

choice. . . . We do not agree that the carrot has become a club because rewards for

conforming have increased. It is not the size of the stakes that controls, but the

rules of the game.) (pre-Dole).

Even in those circuits that do recognize the coercion doctrine, it has had

little success. See West Virginia v. HHS, 289 F.3d at 290, 29495 (rejecting a

coercion doctrine challenge to previous Medicaid Act amendments on the ground

that the Secretary may choose to withhold only some funds); Jim C. v. United

States, 235 F.3d 1079, 108182 (8th Cir. 2000) (en banc) (holding that loss of all

federal education funds, in that case amounting to 12% of the states education

61
budget, was politically painful but not coercive). Indeed, our review of the

relevant case law indicates that no court has ever struck down a law such as this

one as unduly coercive.

There are two cases in which the Supreme Court has struck down a statute

because it violated the Tenth Amendments prohibition on commandeering state

legislators and executive officials to perform the federal governments work.

While not Spending Clause cases, these cases do give us an understanding of

when a law may be considered so coercive as to violate the Tenth Amendment. In

New York v. United States, the Court struck down as unduly coercive a portion of

the Low-Level Radioactive Waste Policy Amendments Act that required states to

take title to waste created within the state, noting that Congress has ample

opportunity to create incentives for states to act the way that Congress desires. 505

U.S. 144, 17677, 112 S. Ct. 2408, 242829 (1992); see also Printz, 521 U.S. 898,

117 S. Ct. 2365 (holding, in accord with New York, that Congress cannot compel

states to enact or administer federal regulatory programs).64 It is clear from these

64
The Supreme Court has also briefly discussed coercion in another context. In Florida
Prepaid, the Court held that federal courts lack jurisdiction over a Lanham Act suit against a
state, despite a law purporting to abrogate the states sovereign immunity under the Lanham Act.
527 U.S. at 691, 119 S. Ct. at 2233. While the holding rested on Eleventh Amendment immunity
grounds, Justice Scalia noted: [W]e think where the constitutionally guaranteed protection of
the States sovereign immunity is involved, the point of coercion is automatically passedand
the voluntariness of waiver destroyedwhen what is attached to the refusal to waive is the
exclusion of the State from otherwise lawful activity. Id. at 687, 119 S. Ct. at 2231.
62
two cases that Congress cannot directly compel a state to act, nor can Congress

hinge the states right to regulate in an area that the state has a constitutional right

to regulate on the states participation in a federal program. Either act is clearly

unconstitutionally coercive.

If anything can be said of the coercion doctrine in the Spending Clause

context, however, it is that it is an amorphous one, honest in theory but

complicated in application. But this does not mean that we can cast aside our duty

to apply it; indeed, it is a mystery to us why so many of our sister circuits have

done so. To say that the coercion doctrine is not viable or does not exist is to

ignore Supreme Court precedent, an exercise this Court will not do. As the district

court noted, The reluctance of some circuits to deal with this issue because of the

potential legal and factual complexities is not entitled to a great deal of weight,

because courts deal every day with the difficult complexities of applying

Constitutional principles set forth and defined by the Supreme Court. Florida ex

rel. McCollum v. HHS, 716 F. Supp. 2d 1120, 1160 (N.D. Fla. 2010).65 If the

government is correct that Congress should be able to place any and all conditions

65
In Florida ex rel. McCollum v. HHS, 716 F. Supp. 2d 1120 (N.D. Fla. 2010), the district
court granted in part and denied in part the governments motion to dismiss. In Florida ex rel.
Bondi v. HHS, No. 3:10-CV-91-RV/EMT, __ F. Supp. 2d __, 2011 WL 285683 (N.D. Fla. Jan.
31, 2011), the district court ruled that (1) the Medicaid expansion did not exceed Congresss
Spending Clause powers and (2) the individual mandate is beyond Congresss commerce powers
and is inseverable from the rest of the Act.
63
it wants on the money it gives to the states, then the Supreme Court must be the

one to say it.

For now, we find it a reasonable conclusion that Dole instructs that the

Tenth Amendment places certain limitations on congressional spending; namely,

that Congress cannot place restrictions so burdensome and threaten the loss of

funds so great and important to the states integral function as a statefunds that

the state has come to rely on heavily as part of its everyday service to its

citizensas to compel the state to participate in the optional legislation. This is

the point where pressure turns into compulsion. Dole, 483 U.S. at 211, 107 S.

Ct. at 2798 (quoting Steward Mach., 301 U.S. at 590, 57 S. Ct. at 892).

And so it is not without serious thought and some hesitation that we

conclude that the Acts expansion of Medicaid is not unduly coercive under Dole

and Steward Machine. There are several factors, which, for us, are determinative.

First, the Medicaid-participating states were warned from the beginning of the

Medicaid program that Congress reserved the right to make changes to the

program. See 42 U.S.C. 1304 (The right to alter, amend, or repeal any provision

of this chapter is hereby reserved to the Congress.); McRae, 448 U.S. at 301, 100

S. Ct. at 2680 (noting [a]lthough participation in the Medicaid program is entirely

optional, once a State elects to participate, it must comply with the requirements

64
that Congress sees fit to impose). Indeed, Congress has made numerous

amendments to the program since its inception in 1965. 42 U.S.C. 1396a Note

(listing amendments).66 In each of these previous amendments, the states were

given the option to comply with the changes, or lose all or part of their funding. Id.

1396c. None of these amendments has been struck down as unduly coercive.

Second, the federal government will bear nearly all of the costs associated

with the expansion. The states will only have to pay incidental administrative costs

associated with the expansion until 2016; after which, they will bear an increasing

percentage of the cost, capping at 10% in 2020.67 Id. 1396d(y)(1). If states bear

little of the cost of expansion, the idea that states are being coerced into spending

66
The government discusses the various Medicaid expansions at length:
Congress has amended the Medicaid Act many times since its inception, and,
between 1966 and 2000, Medicaid enrollment increased from four million to 33
million recipients. Klemm, Medicaid Spending: A Brief History, 22 Health Care Fin.
Rev. 106 (Fall 2000). For example, in 1972, Congress required participating states
to extend Medicaid to recipients of Supplemental Security Income, thereby
significantly expanding Medicaid enrollment. Social Security Act Amendments of
1972, Pub. L. No. 92-603, 86 Stat. 1329 (1972). In 1989, Congress again expanded
enrollment by requiring states to extend Medicaid to pregnant women and children
under age six who meet certain income limits. Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act
of 1989, Pub. L. No. 101-239, 103 Stat. 2106 (1989).
Governments Reply Br. at 4647.
67
At oral argument, the state plaintiffs expressed a concern that Medicaid costs would be
even larger because the individual mandate would greatly increase the number of persons in
Medicaid who are currently eligible but for one reason or another do not choose to participate.
This argument is not persuasive, however, as to whether the expansions themselves are coercive,
because the increase in enrollment would still occur if the mandate were upheld, even if the
Medicaid expansions were struck down.
65
money in an ever-growing program seems to us to be more rhetoric than fact.

Dole, 483 U.S. at 211, 107 S. Ct. at 2798.

Third, states have plenty of noticenearly four years from the date the bill

was signed into lawto decide whether they will continue to participate in

Medicaid by adopting the expansions or not. This gives states the opportunity to

develop new budgets (indeed, Congress allocated the cost of the entire expansion

to the federal government initially, with the cost slowly shifting to the states over a

period of six years) to deal with the expansion, or to develop a replacement

program in their own states if they decide to do so. Fourth, like our sister circuits,

we cannot ignore the fact that the states have the power to tax and raise revenue,

and therefore can create and fund programs of their own if they do not like

Congresss terms. See Pace, 403 F.3d at 278; Jersey City Pub. Schs., 341 F.3d at

24344.

Finally, we note that while the state plaintiffs vociferously argue that states

who choose not to participate in the expansion will lose all of their Medicaid

funding, nothing in the Medicaid Act states that this is a foregone conclusion.

Indeed, the Medicaid Act provides HHS with the discretion to withhold all or

merely a portion of funding from a noncompliant state. 42 U.S.C. 1396c; see

also West Virginia v. HHS, 289 F.3d at 29192; Dole, 483 U.S. at 211, 107 S. Ct.

66
at 2798 (finding no coercion when all South Dakota would lose if she adheres to

her chosen course as to a suitable minimum drinking age is 5% of the funds

otherwise obtainable under specified highway grant programs).

Taken together, these factors convince us that the Medicaid-participating

states have a real choicenot just in theory but in factto participate in the Acts

Medicaid expansion. See Dole, 483 U.S. at 211, 107 S. Ct. at 2798. Where an

entity has a real choice, there can be no coercion. See Steward Mach., 301 U.S. at

590, 57 S. Ct. at 892 (noting that in the absence of undue influence, the law has

been guided by a robust common sense which assumes the freedom of the will as a

working hypothesis in the solution of its problems).

Accordingly, the district courts grant of summary judgment to the

government on the Medicaid expansion issue is affirmed.

We now turn to the constitutionality of the Acts fourth component: the

individual mandate. We begin with the relevant constitutional clauses and

Supreme Court precedent.

IV. SUPREME COURTS COMMERCE CLAUSE DECISIONS

Two constitutional provisions govern our analysis of whether Congress

acted within its commerce authority in enacting the individual mandate: the

Commerce Clause and the Necessary and Proper Clause. U.S. CONST. art. I, 8,

67
cls. 3, 18.

Seven words in the Commerce Clause[t]o regulate Commerce . . . among

the several States, id. art. I, 8, cl. 3have spawned a 200-year debate over the

permissible scope of this enumerated power. For many years, the Supreme Court

described Congresss commerce power as regulating trafficthe buying and

selling, or the interchange of commoditiesand intercourse among states,

including transportation. See Gibbons v. Ogden, 22 U.S. (9 Wheat.) 1, 18990

(1824). Under this early understanding of the Clause, Congress could not reach

commerce that was strictly internal to a state. See id. at 19495 (The enumeration

presupposes something not enumerated; and that something, if we regard the

language or the subject of the sentence, must be the exclusively internal commerce

of a State.).

Ultimately, in recognition of a modern and integrated national economy and

society, the New Deal decisions of the Supreme Court charted an expansive

doctrinal path. See, e.g., United States v. Darby, 312 U.S. 100, 61 S. Ct. 451

(1941); NLRB v. Jones & Laughlin Steel Corp., 301 U.S. 1, 57 S. Ct. 615 (1937).

These Supreme Court decisions adopted a broad view of the Commerce Clause, in

tandem with the Necessary and Proper Clause, and permitted Congress to regulate

purely local, intrastate economic activities that substantially affect interstate

68
commerce. The substantial effects doctrine, along with the related aggregation

doctrine, expanded the reach of Congresss commerce power exponentially.

Nonetheless, the Supreme Court has staunchly maintained that the commerce

power contains outer limits which are necessary to preserve the federal-state

balance in the Constitution.

We therefore review the principal Commerce Clause precedents that inform

our analysis of the difficult question before us. Although extensive, this survey is

necessary to understanding the rudiments of the Supreme Courts existing

Commerce Clause doctrines that we, as an inferior Article III court, must apply.

A. Wickard v. Filburn

One of the early substantial effects decisions is Wickard v. Filburn, 317

U.S. 111, 63 S. Ct. 82 (1942), where the Supreme Court held that Congresss

wheat production quotas were constitutional as applied to a plaintiff farmers

home-grown and home-consumed wheat. The Agricultural Adjustment Act of

1938 (AAA) sought to control the volume of wheat in interstate and foreign

commerce by placing acreage limits on farmers. Id. at 115, 63 S. Ct. at 84. This

scheme was intended to prevent wheat surpluses and shortages, attendant price

instability, and obstructions to commerce. Id.

Plaintiff Filburn operated a small farm raising wheat. Id. at 114, 63 S. Ct. at

69
84. Filburn sold some of this wheat crop, allocated a portion as feed for livestock

and poultry on his farm, used another portion as flour for home consumption, and

preserved the remainder for future seedings. Id. Although his AAA allotment was

only 11.1 acres, Filburn sowed and harvested 23 acres of wheat11.9 excess

acres that the Supreme Court treated as home-consumed wheat.68 Id. at 11415, 63

S. Ct. at 84. This violation subjected him to a penalty of 49 cents a bushel.69 Id.

Filburn sued, claiming that Congresss acreage quotas on his home-consumed

wheat exceeded its commerce power because the regulated activities were local in

nature and their effects upon interstate commerce were indirect. Id. at 119, 63 S.

Ct. at 86.

The Supreme Court examined the factors of home-consumed wheat that

impinged on interstate commercefactors which could potentially frustrate

Congresss regulatory scheme if not controlled. The Court declared that home-

consumed wheat constitutes the most variable factor in the disappearance of the

wheat crop, since [c]onsumption on the farm where grown appears to vary in an

amount greater than 20 per cent of average production. Id. at 127, 63 S. Ct. at 90.

68
See also Gonzales v. Raich, 545 U.S. 1, 20, 125 S. Ct. 2195, 2207 (2005) (noting that
Wickard Court treated Filburns wheat as home-consumed, not part of commercial farming
operation).
69
These penalties were levied regardless of whether any part of the wheat either within
or without the quota, is sold or intended to be sold. Wickard, 317 U.S. at 119, 63 S. Ct. at 86.
70
Filburns home-consumed wheat therefore compete[d] with wheat sold in

commerce, since it supplies a need of the man who grew it which would

otherwise be reflected by purchases in the open market. Id. at 128, 63 S. Ct. at 91.

The Wickard Court recognized that the power to regulate commerce

includes the power to regulate the prices at which commodities in that commerce

are dealt in and practices affecting such prices and it can hardly be denied that a

factor of such volume and variability as home-consumed wheat would have a

substantial influence on price and market conditions. Id. at 128, 63 S. Ct. at

9091. Therefore, the objectives of the AAA acreage quotasto increase the

market price of wheat and to that end to limit the volume thereof that could affect

the market constituted appropriate regulatory goals. Id.

Despite the fact that Congresss commerce power has been held to have

great latitude, id. at 120, 63 S. Ct. at 86, the Supreme Court recognized the

novelty of its decision, remarking that there is no decision of this Court that such

activities may be regulated where no part of the product is intended for interstate

commerce or intermingled with the subjects thereof. Id. at 120, 63 S. Ct. at

8687. However, the Wickard Court concluded that even if [Filburns] activity be

local and though it may not be regarded as commerce, it may still, whatever its

nature, be reached by Congress if it exerts a substantial economic effect on

71
interstate commerce and this irrespective of whether such effect is what might at

some earlier time have been defined as direct or indirect. Id. at 125, 63 S. Ct.

at 89. The Court declared that questions of the power of Congress are not to be

decided by reference to any formula which would give controlling force to

nomenclature such as production and indirect and foreclose consideration of

the actual effects of the activity in question upon interstate commerce. Id. at 120,

63 S. Ct. at 87; see also id. at 12324, 63 S. Ct. at 88 (stating that the relevance

of the economic effects in the application of the Commerce Clause . . . has made

the mechanical application of legal formulas no longer feasible).

Even though Filburns own contribution to wheat demand may be trivial by

itself, this was not enough to remove him from the scope of federal regulation

where, as here, his contribution, taken together with that of many others similarly

situated, is far from trivial. Id. at 12728, 63 S. Ct. at 90. Since Filburns home-

grown wheat slackened demand for market-based wheat and placed downward

pressures on price, Congress may properly have considered that wheat consumed

on the farm where grown if wholly outside the scheme of regulation would have a

substantial effect in defeating and obstructing its purpose to stimulate trade therein

at increased prices. Id. at 12829, 63 S. Ct. at 91.

The Supreme Court noted that restricting Filburns acreage could have the

72
effect of forcing Filburn to buy wheat in the market: It is said, however, that this

Act, forcing some farmers into the market to buy what they could provide for

themselves, is an unfair promotion of the markets and prices of specializing wheat

growers. Id. at 129, 63 S. Ct. at 91. Rejecting this, the Supreme Court stated, It

is of the essence of regulation that it lays a restraining hand on the self-interest of

the regulated and that advantages from the regulation commonly fall to others. Id.

B. United States v. South-Eastern Underwriters Association

Although not concerning the substantial effects doctrine, the 1944 case

United States v. South-Eastern Underwriters Association, 322 U.S. 533, 64 S. Ct.

1162 (1944), is important to our analysis, as it marked the Supreme Courts first

recognition that the insurance business is commerceand where it is conducted

across state borders, it constitutes interstate commerce capable of being regulated

by Congress.70 Id. at 553, 64 S. Ct. at 1173. The Supreme Court emphasized the

interstate character of insurance business practices, which resulted in a

70
Prior to 1944, the Supreme Court consistently upheld the power of the states to regulate
insurance. During those early years, Congress had not regulated insurance, but the states had. The
operative question concerned whether Congresss power to regulate interstate commerce
deprived states of the power to regulate the insurance business themselves. Since Congress had
not sought to regulate insurance, an invalidation of the states statutes would entail that insurance
companies could operate without any regulation. The earlier Supreme Court decisions held that
insurance is not commerce, thereby skirting any constitutional problem arising from the
Constitutions grant of power to Congress to regulate interstate commerce. See Paul v. Virginia,
75 U.S. (8 Wall.) 168 (1868); see also N.Y. Life Ins. Co. v. Deer Lodge Cnty., 231 U.S. 495, 34
S. Ct. 167 (1913); Hooper v. California, 155 U.S. 648, 15 S. Ct. 207 (1895).
73
continuous and indivisible stream of intercourse among the states composed of

collections of premiums, payments of policy obligations, and the countless

documents and communications which are essential to the negotiation and

execution of policy contracts. Id. at 541, 64 S. Ct. at 1167. The defendants

insurances policies covered not only all kinds of fixed local properties, but also

. . . movable goods of all types carried in interstate and foreign commerce by every

media of transportation. Id. at 542, 64 S. Ct. at 1168.

The South-Eastern Underwriters Court rejected the notion that, if any

components of the insurance business constitute interstate commerce, the states

may not exercise regulatory control over the industry. Id. at 548, 64 S. Ct. at 1171.

Nevertheless, the Court pronounced that [n]o commercial enterprise of any kind

which conducts its activities across state lines has been held to be wholly beyond

the regulatory power of Congress under the Commerce Clause. We cannot make

an exception of the business of insurance. Id. at 553, 64 S. Ct. at 1173.

C. Heart of Atlanta Motel v. United States

In another landmark Commerce Clause case, Heart of Atlanta Motel v.

United States, 379 U.S. 241, 85 S. Ct. 348 (1964), the Supreme Court held that

Congress acted within its commerce authority in enacting Title II of the Civil

Rights Act of 1964, which prohibited discrimination in public accommodations.

74
The plaintiff owned and operated a 216-room motel whose guests were primarily

out-of-state visitors. Id. at 243, 85 S. Ct. at 35051. The motel refused to rent

rooms to black patrons. Id. at 243, 85 S. Ct. at 351.

The Supreme Court detailed the overwhelming evidence that

discrimination by hotels and motels impedes interstate travel. Id. at 253, 85 S. Ct.

at 355. The Court noted that it had long been settled that transportation of

persons in interstate commerce is within Congresss regulatory power, regardless

of whether the transportation is commercial in character. Id. at 256, 85 S. Ct. at

357. Additionally, Supreme Court precedents confirmed that the power of

Congress to promote interstate commerce also includes the power to regulate the

local incidents thereof . . . which might have a substantial and harmful effect upon

that commerce. Id. at 258, 85 S. Ct. at 358. Thus, Congress mayas it

hasprohibit racial discrimination by motels serving travelers, however local

their operations may appear. Id.

The Heart of Atlanta Motel Court acknowledged that Congress could have

pursued other methods to eliminate the obstructions it found in interstate

commerce caused by racial discrimination, but the means employed in removing

such obstructions are within the sound and exclusive discretion of the Congress

and are subject only to one caveatthat the means chosen by it must be

75
reasonably adapted to the end permitted by the Constitution. Id. at 26162, 85 S.

Ct. at 360. The means chosen by Congress in Title II clearly met this standard.71

D. United States v. Lopez

For the next thirty years, the Supreme Court applied an expansive

interpretation of Congresss commerce power and upheld a wide variety of

statutes. See, e.g., Preseault v. ICC, 494 U.S. 1, 110 S. Ct. 914 (1990) (upholding

statute amending National Trails System Act in facial challenge); Hodel v. Va.

Surface Mining & Reclamation Assn, 452 U.S. 264, 101 S. Ct. 2352 (1981)

(sustaining Surface Mining Control and Reclamation Act in facial challenge);

Perez v. United States, 402 U.S. 146, 91 S. Ct. 1357 (1971) (sustaining Title II of

Consumer Credit Protection Act in as-applied challenge); Maryland v. Wirtz, 392

U.S. 183, 88 S. Ct. 2017 (1968) (upholding validity of amendments to Fair Labor

Standards Act of 1938 in facial challenge), overruled on other grounds, Natl

League of Cities v. Usery, 426 U.S. 833, 96 S. Ct. 2465 (1976), overruled by

Garcia v. San Antonio Metro. Transit Auth., 469 U.S. 528, 105 S. Ct. 1005 (1985).

These cases reflect a practical need to allow federal regulation of a growing and

unified national economy.

71
In Katzenbach v. McClung, 379 U.S. 294, 85 S. Ct. 377 (1964), a companion case, the
Court also upheld Title IIs prohibition on discrimination in restaurants serving food to interstate
travelers or serving food that had moved in interstate commerce.
76
In 1995, the Supreme Court decided United States v. Lopez, 514 U.S. 549,

115 S. Ct. 1624 (1995), the first Supreme Court decision since the 1930s to rule

that Congress had exceeded its commerce power. Lopez concerned the Gun-Free

School Zones Act of 1990, which made it a federal offense for any individual

knowingly to possess a firearm at a place that the individual knows, or has

reasonable cause to believe, is a school zone. 18 U.S.C. 922(q)(1)(A) (1993).

The defendant Alfonso Lopez, a twelfth-grade student, was convicted of carrying

a concealed handgun to his Texas school. Lopez, 514 U.S. at 551, 115 S. Ct. at

1626.

In a 54 opinion, the Lopez Court invalidated 922(q). The Lopez Court

first observed that the Constitution created a federal government of enumerated,

delegated, and thus limited powers. Id. at 552, 115 S. Ct. at 1626. Although the

Supreme Courts New Deal precedents expanded Congresss commerce power, the

Lopez Court recognized that this power is subject to outer limits. Id. at 557, 115

S. Ct. at 1628. The Lopez Court then enumerated the three broad categories of

activity that Congress may regulate under its commerce power: (1) the use of the

channels of interstate commerce; (2) the instrumentalities of interstate

commerce, or persons or things in interstate commerce, even though the threat

may come only from intrastate activities; and (3) those activities that

77
substantially affect interstate commerce.72 Id. at 55859, 115 S. Ct. at 162930.

After determining that 922(q) could be sustained only under this third category,

the Lopez Court identified four factors influencing its analysis of whether gun

possession in school zones substantially affects interstate commerce.

First, the Lopez Court differentiated between economic and non-economic

activity, stressing how prior cases utilizing the substantial effects test to reach

intrastate conduct had all involved economic activity. The Supreme Court stated

that Section 922(q) is a criminal statute that by its terms has nothing to do with

commerce or any sort of economic enterprise and was not an essential part of a

larger regulation of economic activity, in which the regulatory scheme could be

undercut unless the intrastate activity were regulated. Id. at 561, 115 S. Ct. at

163031. The Court opined that [e]ven Wickard, which is perhaps the most far

reaching example of Commerce Clause authority over intrastate activity, involved

economic activity in a way that the possession of a gun in a school zone does not.

Id. at 560, 115 S. Ct. at 1630 (emphasis added). The Lopez Court acknowledged

that a determination whether an intrastate activity is commercial or

noncommercial may in some cases result in legal uncertainty, yet so long as

[Congresss] enumerated powers are interpreted as having judicially enforceable

72
The third Lopez prong is the broadest expression of Congress commerce power.
United States v. Ballinger, 395 F.3d 1218, 1226 (11th Cir. 2005) (en banc).
78
outer limits, congressional legislation under the Commerce Clause always will

engender legal uncertainty. Id. at 566, 115 S. Ct. at 1633.

Second, the Lopez Court found it significant that 922(q) did not contain a

jurisdictional element to ensure, through case-by-case inquiry, that the firearm

possession in question affects interstate commerce. Id. at 561, 115 S. Ct. at 1631.

Instead, the Act penalized mere possession and lacked any requirement that

there be an explicit connection with or effect on interstate commerce.73 Id. at

562, 115 S. Ct. at 1631.

Third, the Court noted that Congress provided no legislative findings

demonstrating the purported nexus between gun possession around schools and its

effects on interstate commerce. Id. at 56263, 115 S. Ct. at 163132.

Fourth, the Lopez Court examined the actual relationship between gun

possession in a school zone and its effects on interstate commerce. The

government posited three effects: (1) violent crime, even when purely local,

generates substantial costs that are spread to the wider populace through

73
In this respect, the Lopez Court contrasted the Gun-Free School Zones Act of 1990 with
the firearm possession statute at issue in United States v. Bass, 404 U.S. 336, 92 S. Ct. 515
(1971). In Bass, the Supreme Court construed legislation making it a federal crime for a felon to
receiv[e], posses[s], or transpor[t] in commerce or affecting commerce . . . any firearm. Lopez,
514 U.S. at 56162, 115 S. Ct. at 1631 (emphasis added) (quoting former 18 U.S.C. 1202(a)).
The Lopez Court stated that [u]nlike the statute in Bass, 922(q) has no express jurisdictional
element which might limit its reach to a discrete set of firearm possessions that additionally have
an explicit connection with or effect on interstate commerce. Id. at 562, 115 S. Ct. at 1631.
79
insurance; (2) individuals are deterred from traveling to areas beset by violent

crime; and (3) guns in schools imperil the learning environment, which in turn

adversely impacts national productivity. Id. at 56364, 115 S. Ct. at 1632.

The Lopez Court declared that the governments arguments yielded no

limiting principles. For example, under the governments proffered costs of

crime theory, Congress could regulate not only all violent crime, but all

activities that might lead to violent crime, regardless of how tenuously they relate

to interstate commerce. Id. at 564, 115 S. Ct. at 1632. Likewise, the national

productivity rationale afforded no bounds, either. If Congress could employ its

Commerce Clause authority to regulate activities that adversely affect the

learning environment, then, a fortiori, it also can regulate the educational process

directly. Id. at 566, 115 S. Ct. at 1633. Indeed, Congress could regulate any

activity that it found was related to the economic productivity of individual

citizens, including marriage, divorce, and child custody. Id. at 564, 115 S. Ct.

at 1632.

The Supreme Court pronounced that these links were too attenuated to

conclude that the regulated activity substantially affects interstate commerce:

[I]f we were to accept the Governments arguments, we are hard pressed to posit

any activity by an individual that Congress is without power to regulate. Id. To

80
uphold the Governments contentions, the Supreme Court continued, we would

have to pile inference upon inference in a manner that would bid fair to convert

congressional authority under the Commerce Clause to a general police power of

the sort retained by the States. Id. at 567, 115 S. Ct. at 1634.

Lastly, the Lopez Court acknowledged that some of the Supreme Courts

precedents gave great deference to congressional action but refused to expand

the broad language of these precedents any further, since [t]o do so would

require us to conclude that the Constitutions enumeration of powers does not

presuppose something not enumerated. Id. Such judicial abdication would

dissolve the distinction between what is truly national and what is truly local

and subvert constitutional notions of federalism. Id. at 56768, 115 S. Ct. at 1634.

Although both joined the majority opinion in full, two justices wrote

separately and echoed the majoritys emphasis on the significance of the federal-

state balance in the structure of the Constitution, and the need for judicial

intervention when Congress has tipped the scales too far. See id. at 56883, 115

S. Ct. at 163442 (Kennedy, J., concurring);74 id. at 584602, 115 S. Ct. at

74
In a concurring opinion, Justice Kennedy explained why he joined the Lopez majority
opinion in full and what he characterized as its necessary though limited holding. 514 U.S. at
568, 115 S. Ct. at 1634 (Kennedy, J., concurring). Justice Kennedy noted the imprecision of
content-based boundaries used without more to define the limits of the Commerce Clause,
referring to earlier dichotomies that distinguished between manufacturing and commerce,
direct and indirect effects, and other formalistic categories. Id. at 574, 115 S. Ct. at 1637. He
stressed that the Supreme Court is often called upon to resolve questions of constitutional law
81
164251 (Thomas, J., concurring).75

E. United States v. Morrison

In another 54 decision, the Supreme Court in United States v. Morrison,

529 U.S. 598, 120 S. Ct. 1740 (2000), reapplied the Lopez principles and

invalidated a section of the Violence Against Women Act of 1994 (VAWA), 42

U.S.C. 13981, which provided a federal civil remedy for victims of gender-

motivated violence.76

In enacting the VAWA, Congress made specific findings about the

relationship between gender-motivated violence and its substantial effects on

interstate commerce. Congress declared its objectives were to protect victims of

gender motivated violence and to promote public safety, health, and activities

not susceptible to the mechanical application of bright and clear lines. Id. at 579, 115 S. Ct. at
1640.
Justice Kennedy found that 922(q) upsets the federal balance to a degree that renders it
an unconstitutional assertion of the commerce power, and our intervention is required. Id. at
580, 115 S. Ct. at 1640. Much like the majority opinion, Justice Kennedy emphasized the far-
reaching implications of the governments position: In a sense any conduct in this
interdependent world of ours has an ultimate commercial origin or consequence, but we have not
yet said the commerce power may reach so far. If Congress attempts that extension, then at the
least we must inquire whether the exercise of national power seeks to intrude upon an area of
traditional state concern. Id. Such an interference was present in Lopez, as it is well established
that education is a traditional concern of the States. Id. Justice Kennedy added that courts have a
duty to recognize meaningful limits on the commerce power of Congress. Id.
75
See discussion of Justice Thomass concurring opinion infra note 78.
76
The VAWA provided that a person who commits a crime of violence motivated by
gender . . . shall be liable to the party injured, in an action for the recovery of compensatory and
punitive damages, injunctive and declaratory relief, and such other relief as a court may deem
appropriate. 42 U.S.C. 13981(c).
82
affecting interstate commerce.77 Id. 13981(a).

The Morrison Court observed that since the New Deal case of Jones &

Laughlin Steel, Congress has had considerably greater latitude in regulating

conduct and transactions under the Commerce Clause than our previous case law

permitted. Morrison, 529 U.S. at 608, 120 S. Ct. at 1748. Lopez clarified,

however, that Congress regulatory authority is not without effective bounds. Id.

The Supreme Court stated that a fair reading of Lopez shows that the

noneconomic, criminal nature of the conduct at issue was central to our decision in

that case. Id. at 610, 120 S. Ct. at 1750. The Morrison Court pointed out that

[g]ender-motivated crimes of violence are not, in any sense of the phrase,

economic activity. Id. at 613, 120 S. Ct. at 1751. While we need not adopt a

categorical rule against aggregating the effects of any noneconomic activity in

order to decide these cases, the Supreme Court reiterated that our cases have

upheld Commerce Clause regulation of intrastate activity only where that activity

is economic in nature. Id.

The Supreme Court next noted that 13981 contained no jurisdictional

77
The Morrison plaintiff was a college student allegedly raped by two football players.
529 U.S. at 602, 120 S. Ct. at 174546. The plaintiff filed suit in federal court under 13981(c).
Id. at 604, 120 S. Ct. at 1746. The defendants motion to dismiss argued that Congress lacked
authority to enact the VAWAs federal civil remedy provision under either the Commerce Clause
or 5 of the Fourteenth Amendment. Id. at 604, 120 S. Ct. at 174647.
83
element. It commented that another provision of the VAWA, which similarly

provided a federal remedy for gender-motivated crime, did contain a jurisdictional

hook. Id. at 613 n.5, 120 S. Ct. at 1752 n.5 (discussing 18 U.S.C. 2261(a)(1),

which at the time applied only to an individual who travels across a State line or

enters or leaves Indian country).

Unlike 922(q) in Lopez, 13981 was supported by numerous findings

regarding the serious impact that gender-motivated violence has on victims and

their families. Id. at 614, 120 S. Ct. at 1752. Nonetheless, the Morrison Court

stated that congressional findings were not dispositive, echoing Lopezs statement

that [s]imply because Congress may conclude that a particular activity

substantially affects interstate commerce does not necessarily make it so. Id.

(alteration in original) (quoting Lopez, 514 U.S. at 557 n.2, 115 S. Ct. at 1624 n.2).

The Morrison Court determined that Congress findings are substantially

weakened by the fact that they rely so heavily on a method of reasoning that we

have already rejected as unworkable if we are to maintain the Constitutions

enumeration of powers. Id. at 615, 120 S. Ct. at 1752. The congressional findings

in Morrison asserted that gender-motivated violence deterred potential victims

from interstate travel and employment in interstate business, decreased national

productivity, and increased medical costs. Id. According to the Morrison Court,

84
[t]he reasoning that petitioners advance seeks to follow the but-for causal chain

from the initial occurrence of violent crime (the suppression of which has always

been the prime object of the States police power) to every attenuated effect upon

interstate commerce. Id. The logical entailment of this but-for causal chain of

reasoning would allow Congress to regulate any crime as long as the nationwide,

aggregated impact of that crime has substantial effects on employment,

production, transit, or consumption. Id. at 615, 120 S. Ct. at 175253. Such

arguments suggested no stopping point, and Congress could thereby exercise

powers traditionally reposed in the states.78 Id. at 61516, 120 S. Ct. at 1753.

F. Gonzales v. Raich

Next came Gonzales v. Raich, 545 U.S. 1, 125 S. Ct. 2195 (2005), where the

Supreme Court, in a 63 vote, concluded that Congress acted within its commerce

power in prohibiting the plaintiffs wholly intrastate production and possession of

marijuana, even though California state law approved the drugs use for medical

78
Although joining the majority opinion in full in both Lopez and Morrison, Justice
Thomas wrote separately in both cases to reject the substantial effects doctrine. In Morrison,
Justice Thomas wrote only to express my view that the very notion of a substantial effects test
under the Commerce Clause is inconsistent with the original understanding of Congress powers
and with this Courts early Commerce Clause cases. 529 U.S. at 627, 120 S. Ct. at 1759
(Thomas, J., concurring). Characterizing the substantial effects test as a rootless and malleable
standard, Justice Thomas remarked that the Supreme Courts present Commerce Clause
jurisprudence had encouraged the federal government to operate under the misguided belief that
the Clause has virtually no limits. Id. Unless the Supreme Court reversed its course,we will
continue to see Congress appropriating state police powers under the guise of regulating
commerce. Id.
85
purposes. The legislation at issue was the Controlled Substances Act (CSA), 21

U.S.C. 801 et seq., in which Congress sought to conquer drug abuse and to

control the legitimate and illegitimate traffic in controlled substances and

prevent the diversion of drugs from legitimate to illicit channels. Raich, 545

U.S. at 1213, 125 S. Ct. at 2203. Congress consequently devised a closed

regulatory system making it unlawful to manufacture, distribute, dispense, or

possess any controlled substance except in a manner authorized by the CSA. Id.

at 13, 125 S. Ct. at 2203. Under the CSA, marijuana is classified as a Schedule I

drug, meaning that the manufacture, distribution, or possession of marijuana

constitutes a criminal offense. Id. at 14, 125 S. Ct. at 2204.

In 1996, California voters passed Proposition 215, which exempted from

criminal prosecution physicians who recommend marijuana to a patient for

medical purposes, as well as patients and primary caregivers who possess and

cultivate marijuana for doctor-approved medical purposes.79 Id. at 56, 125 S. Ct.

at 2199. The two California plaintiffs, Angel Raich and Diane Monson, suffered

from serious medical conditions and used marijuana as medication for several

years, as recommended by their physicians. Id. at 67, 125 S. Ct. at 21992200.

Monson cultivated her own marijuana, while Raich relied upon two caregivers to

79
Proposition 215 is codified as the Compassionate Use Act of 1996, CAL. HEALTH &
SAFETY CODE 11362.5.
86
provide her with locally grown marijuana at no cost. Id. at 7, 125 S. Ct. at 2200.

After federal agents seized and destroyed Monsons cannabis plants, the

Raich plaintiffs sued. Id. They acknowledged that the CSA was within Congresss

commerce authority and did not contend that any section of the CSA was

unconstitutional. Id. at 15, 125 S. Ct. at 2204. Instead, they argued solely that the

CSA was unconstitutional as applied to their manufacture, possession, and

consumption of cannabis for personal medical use. Id. at 78, 125 S. Ct. at 2200.

In rejecting the plaintiffs quite limited as-applied challenge, the Raich

Court stated that its case law firmly establishes Congress power to regulate

purely local activities that are part of an economic class of activities that have a

substantial effect on interstate commerce. Id. at 15, 17, 125 S. Ct. at 220405.

The Supreme Court emphasized that, in assessing Congresss commerce power, its

review was a modest one: We need not determine whether respondents

activities, taken in the aggregate, substantially affect interstate commerce in fact,

but only whether a rational basis exists for so concluding. Id. at 22, 125 S. Ct. at

2208. The Raich Court commented that [w]hen Congress decides that the total

incidence of a practice poses a threat to a national market, it may regulate the

entire class, and it need not legislate with scientific exactitude. Id. at 17, 125 S.

Ct. at 2206 (quotation marks omitted). [W]e have reiterated, the Supreme Court

87
continued, that when a general regulatory statute bears a substantial relation to

commerce, the de minimis character of individual instances arising under that

statute is of no consequence. Id. (quotation marks omitted) (quoting Lopez, 514

U.S. at 558, 115 S. Ct. at 1629).

The Supreme Court found similar regulatory concerns underlying both the

CSA in Raich and the AAA wheat provisions in Wickard. Just as rising market

prices could draw wheat grown for home consumption into the interstate market

and depress prices, a parallel concern making it appropriate to include marijuana

grown for home consumption in the CSA is the likelihood that the high demand in

the interstate market will draw such marijuana into that market. Id. at 19, 125 S.

Ct. at 2207. In both cases, there was a threat of unwanted commodity diversion

that could disrupt Congresss regulatory control over interstate commerce. Id.

According to the Raich Court, Wickard established that Congress can

regulate purely intrastate activity that is not itself commercial, in that it is not

produced for sale, if it concludes that failure to regulate that class of activity

would undercut the regulation of the interstate market in that commodity. Id. at

18, 125 S. Ct. at 2206. Characterizing the similarities between the plaintiffs case

and Wickard as striking, the Raich Court explained that [i]n both cases, the

regulation is squarely within Congress commerce power because production of

88
the commodity meant for home consumption, be it wheat or marijuana, has a

substantial effect on supply and demand in the national market for that

commodity. Id. at 1819, 125 S. Ct. at 220607.

The Raich Court opined that the failure to regulate intrastate production and

possession of marijuana would leave a gaping hole in the CSAs regulatory

scheme: CSA enforcement would be frustrated by the difficulty in distinguishing

between locally cultivated marijuana and out-of-state marijuana, and the marijuana

authorized by state law could be diverted into illicit channels. Id. at 22, 125 S.

Ct. at 2209. The Raich Court rejected the notion that California had surgically

excised a discrete activity that is hermetically sealed off from the larger interstate

marijuana market. Id. at 30, 125 S. Ct. at 2213. Accordingly, even though the

CSA ensnares some purely intrastate activity, the Raich Court refuse[d] to

excise individual components of that larger scheme. Id. Instead, congressional

judgment that an exemption for such a significant segment of the total market

would undermine the orderly enforcement of the entire regulatory scheme is

entitled to a strong presumption of validity. Id. at 28, 125 S. Ct. at 2212.

The Raich Court concluded that the statutory challenges in Lopez and

Morrison were markedly different from the plaintiffs statutory challenge to the

CSA. Id. at 23, 125 S. Ct. at 2209. Whereas the Raich plaintiffs sought to excise

89
individual applications of a concededly valid statutory scheme, the Supreme

Court noted that in both Lopez and Morrison, the parties asserted that a particular

statute or provision fell outside Congress commerce power in its entirety. Id.

The Raich Court considered this distinction between facial and as-applied

challenges pivotal because [w]here the class of activities is regulated and that

class is within the reach of federal power, the courts have no power to excise, as

trivial, individual instances of the class. Id. (alteration in original) (quoting Perez,

402 U.S. at 154, 91 S. Ct. at 1361). Additionally, since the CSA was a lengthy

and detailed statute creating a comprehensive framework, its statutory scheme

was at the opposite end of the regulatory spectrum from the statutes in Lopez

and Morrison. Id. at 24, 125 S. Ct. at 2210.

Once again central to the Courts analysis was whether the regulated

activities were economic or noneconomic. The Raich Court defined [e]conomics

as referring to the production, distribution, and consumption of commodities. Id.

at 2526, 125 S. Ct. at 2211 (quoting WEBSTERS THIRD NEW INTL DICTIONARY

720 (1966)). In contrast to the activities regulated in Lopez and Morrison, the

Raich Court concluded that the activities regulated by the CSA are

quintessentially economic. Id. at 25, 125 S. Ct. at 2211. Indeed, the activities

engaged in by the plaintiffs themselves fit the Courts definition of economic,

90
since they involved the production, distribution, and consumption of marijuana.

Concurring in only the Raich judgment, Justice Scalia commented that

under his understanding of the commerce power, the authority to enact laws

necessary and proper for the regulation of interstate commerce is not limited to

laws governing intrastate activities that substantially affect interstate commerce.

Where necessary to make a regulation of interstate commerce effective, Congress

may regulate even those intrastate activities that do not themselves substantially

affect interstate commerce. Id. at 3435, 125 S. Ct. at 2216 (Scalia, J.,

concurring).

Justice Scalia cited two general circumstances in which the regulation of

intrastate activities may be necessary to and proper for the regulation of interstate

commerce. Id. at 35, 125 S. Ct. at 2216. First, the commerce power permits

Congress not only to devise rules for the governance of commerce between States

but also to facilitate interstate commerce by eliminating potential obstructions, and

to restrict it by eliminating potential stimulants. Id. at 35, 125 S. Ct. at 2216. Yet,

[t]his principle is not without limitation, as the cases of Lopez and Morrison

made clear. Id. at 3536, 125 S. Ct. at 221617. Second, Justice Scalia submitted

that Congress may regulate even noneconomic local activity if that regulation is a

necessary part of a more general regulation of interstate commerce. Id. at 37, 125

91
S. Ct. at 2217. The relevant question then becomes whether the means chosen

are reasonably adapted to the attainment of a legitimate end under the commerce

power. Id.

In addition to relying on these Commerce Clause cases, both parties and the

district court conducted a separate analysis of the Necessary and Proper Clauses

implications for the Act. We review some foundational principles relating to that

Clause, focusing our attention on United States v. Comstock, 560 U.S. __, 130 S.

Ct. 1949 (2010).

G. Necessary and Proper Clause: United States v. Comstock

Congress has the power [t]o make all Laws which shall be necessary and

proper for carrying into Execution its enumerated power. U.S. CONST. art. I, 8,

cl. 18. The Necessary and Proper Clause is intimately tied to the enumerated

power it effectuates. The Supreme Court has recognized that the Necessary and

Proper Clause is not the delegation of a new and independent power, but simply

provision for making effective the powers theretofore mentioned. Kansas v.

Colorado, 206 U.S. 46, 88, 27 S. Ct. 655, 663 (1907). It is merely a declaration,

for the removal of all uncertainty, that the means of carrying into execution those

[powers] otherwise granted are included in the grant. Kinsella v. United States,

361 U.S. 234, 247, 80 S. Ct. 297, 304 (1960) (alterations in original) (quoting VI

92
WRITINGS OF JAMES MADISON 383 (Gaillard Hunt ed., 1906)). It reaffirms that

Congress has the incidental powers necessary to carry its enumerated powers into

effect.

The Supreme Courts most definitive statement of the Necessary and Proper

Clauses function remains Chief Justice Marshalls articulation in McCulloch v.

Maryland: Let the end be legitimate, let it be within the scope of the constitution,

and all means which are appropriate, which are plainly adapted to that end, which

are not prohibited, but consist with the letter and spirit of the constitution, are

constitutional. 17 U.S. (4 Wheat.) 316, 421 (1819). Thus, when legislating within

its enumerated powers, Congress has broad authority: the Necessary and Proper

Clause makes clear that the Constitutions grants of specific federal legislative

authority are accompanied by broad power to enact laws that are convenient, or

useful or conducive to the authoritys beneficial exercise. Comstock, 560 U.S.

at __, 130 S. Ct. at 1956 (quoting McCulloch, 17 U.S. at 413, 418).

As it relates to the commerce power, the Supreme Court has essentially

bound up the Necessary and Proper Clause with its substantial effects analysis.80

80
For instance, the Court formulated the question in Raich as whether the power vested
in Congress by Article I, 8, of the Constitution to make all Laws which shall be necessary and
proper for carrying into Execution its authority to regulate Commerce with foreign Nations, and
among the several States includes the power [asserted]. 545 U.S. at 5, 125 S. Ct. at 219899
(alteration omitted). Although the Wickard Court did not expressly invoke the Necessary and
Proper Clause, the Raich Court clearly assumed as much. See id. at 22, 125 S. Ct. at 2209.
93
As Justice Scalia noted in Raich, Congresss regulatory authority over intrastate

activities that are not themselves part of interstate commerce (including activities

that have a substantial effect on interstate commerce) derives from the Necessary

and Proper Clause. 545 U.S. at 34, 125 S. Ct. at 2216 (Scalia, J., concurring).

Comstock represents the Supreme Courts most recent, detailed application

of Necessary and Proper Clause doctrine. In Comstock, the Supreme Court held

that Congress acted pursuant to its Article I powers in enacting a federal civil-

commitment statute, 18 U.S.C. 4248, that authorized the Department of Justice

to detain mentally ill, sexually dangerous prisoners beyond the term of their

sentences. The majority opinion enumerated five considerations that supported

the statutes constitutional validity: (1) the breadth of the Necessary and Proper

Clause, (2) the long history of federal involvement in this arena, (3) the sound

reasons for the statutes enactment in light of the Governments custodial interest

in safeguarding the public from dangers posed by those in federal custody, (4) the

statutes accommodation of state interests, and (5) the statutes narrow scope.

Comstock, 560 U.S. at __, 130 S. Ct. at 1965.

On the breadth of the Necessary and Proper Clause, the Comstock Court

noted that (1) the federal government is a government of enumerated powers, but

(2) is also vested with ample means for the execution of those powers. Id.

94
(quoting McCulloch, 17 U.S. at 408). The Supreme Court must determine whether

a federal statute constitutes a means that is rationally related to the

implementation of a constitutionally enumerated power. Id. [T]he relevant

inquiry is simply whether the means chosen are reasonably adapted to the

attainment of a legitimate end under the commerce power or under other powers

that the Constitution grants Congress the authority to implement. Id. at __, 130 S.

Ct. at 1957 (quotation marks omitted) (quoting Raich, 545 U.S. at 37, 125 S. Ct. at

2217 (Scalia, J., concurring)).

Turning to the second factorthe history of federal involvementthe

Supreme Court recognized that, beginning in 1855, persons charged with or

convicted of federal offenses could be confined to a federal mental institution for

the duration of their sentences. Id. at __, 130 S. Ct. at 1959. Since 1949, Congress

had also authorized the postsentence detention of federal prisoners who suffer

from a mental illness and who are thereby dangerous. Id. at __, 130 S. Ct. at

1961. The Supreme Court observed that [a]side from its specific focus on

sexually dangerous persons, 4248 is similar to the provisions first enacted in

1949" and therefore represented a modest addition to a longstanding federal

statutory framework, which has been in place since 1855. Id.

As to the third factorreasons for enactment in light of the governments

95
interestthe Supreme Court concluded that Congress reasonably extended its

longstanding civil-commitment system to cover mentally ill and sexually

dangerous persons who are already in federal custody, even if doing so detains

them beyond the termination of their criminal sentence. Id. The federal

government: (1) is the custodian of its prisoners and (2) has the power to protect

the public from the threats posed by the prisoners in its charge. Id.

Turning to the fourth factoraccommodation of state intereststhe

Comstock Court ruled that 4248 properly accounts for state interests. Id. at __,

130 S. Ct. at 1962. The Supreme Court found persuasive that the statute required

the Attorney General (1) to allow (and indeed encourage) the state in which the

prisoner was domiciled or tried to take custody and (2) to immediately release the

prisoner if the state seeks to assert authority over him.81 Id.

On the fifth and final factorthe statutes narrow scopethe Comstock

Court found the statute not too sweeping in its scope and the link between

4248 and an enumerated Article I power not too attenuated. Id. at __, 130 S.

Ct. at 1963. The Supreme Court concluded that Lopezs admonition that courts

81
The Attorney General must make all reasonable efforts to cause the state in which the
prisoner is domiciled or tried to assume responsibility for his custody, care, and treatment.
Comstock, 560 U.S. at __, 130 S. Ct. at 1954 (quoting 18 U.S.C. 4248(d)). If the state consents,
the prisoner will be released to the appropriate official in that state. Id. at __, 130 S. Ct. at
195455. If the state declines to take custody, the Attorney General will place the person for
treatment in a suitable facility until the state assumes the role or until the person no longer poses
a sexually dangerous threat. Id. at __, 130 S. Ct. at 1955 (quoting 18 U.S.C. 4248(d)).
96
should not pile inference upon inference did not present any problems with

respect to the civil-commitment statute. Id. (quoting Lopez, 514 U.S. at 567, 115

S. Ct. at 1634). Specifically, the Comstock Court discerned that the same

enumerated power that justifies the creation of a federal criminal statute, and that

justifies the additional implied federal powers that the dissent considers legitimate,

justifies civil commitment under 4248 as well. Id. at __, 130 S. Ct. at 1964. The

Supreme Court rejected the notion that Congresss authority can be no more than

one step removed from a specifically enumerated power. Id. at __, 130 S. Ct. at

1963.

Lastly, the Supreme Court emphasized that 4248 had been applied to

only a small fraction of federal prisoners. Id. at __, 130 S. Ct. at 1964 (citing

evidence that 105 individuals have been subject to 4248 out of over 188,000

federal inmates). The Supreme Court concluded that 4248 is a reasonably

adapted and narrowly tailored means of pursuing the Governments legitimate

interest as a federal custodian in the responsible administration of its prison

system and thus did not endow Congress with a general police power. Id. at __,

130 S. Ct. at 1965.

Although concurring in the judgment, Justice Kennedy and Justice Alito82

82
Justice Alito wrote separately to express concern[] about the breadth of the Courts
language, and the ambiguity of the standard that the Court applies. 560 U.S. at __, 130 S. Ct. at
97
did not join the Courts majority opinion. Because Justice Kennedys concurring

opinion focuses on Commerce Clause and federalism issues, we provide extended

treatment of it here.

Justice Kennedys primary disagreement with the majority concerned its

application of a means-ends rationality test. He advised that [t]he terms

rationally related and rational basis must be employed with care, particularly if

either is to be used as a stand-alone test. Id. at __, 130 S. Ct. at 1966 (Kennedy,

J., concurring). Justice Kennedy observed that the phrase rational basis is

typically employed in Due Process Clause contexts, where the Court adopts a very

deferential review of congressional acts. Id. Under the Lee Optical test applied in

such due process settings, the Court merely asks whether it might be thought that

the particular legislative measure was a rational way to correct an evil. Id.

(quoting Williamson v. Lee Optical of Okla., Inc., 348 U.S. 483, 48788, 75 S. Ct.

461, 464 (1955)). By contrast, Justice Kennedy asserted, under the Necessary and

1968 (Alito, J., concurring) (citation omitted). Justice Alito stressed that the Necessary and
Proper Clause does not give Congress carte blanche. Id. at __, 130 S. Ct. at 1970. While the
word necessary need not connote that the means employed by Congress be absolutely
necessary or indispensable, the term requires an appropriate link between a power
conferred by the Constitution and the law enacted by Congress. Id. It is the Supreme Courts
duty, he declared, to enforce compliance with that limitation. Id. Like Justice Kennedy, Justice
Alito suggested that the Necessary and Proper Clause context of the case did not warrant an
analysis in which it is merely possible for a court to think of a rational basis on which Congress
might have perceived an attenuated link between the powers underlying the federal criminal
statutes and the challenged civil commitment provision. Id. In Comstock, by contrast, the
government had demonstrated a substantial link to Congress constitutional powers. Id.
98
Proper Clause, application of a rational basis test should be at least as exacting as

it has been in the Commerce Clause cases, if not more so. Id.

The Commerce Clause precedents of Raich, Lopez, and Hodel require a

tangible link to commerce, not a mere conceivable rational relation, as in Lee

Optical. Id. at __, 130 S. Ct. at 1967. The rational basis referred to in the

Commerce Clause context is a demonstrated link in fact, based on empirical

demonstration. Id. Justice Kennedy reiterated Lopezs admonition that [s]imply

because Congress may conclude that a particular activity substantially affects

interstate commerce does not necessarily make it so. Id. (quoting Lopez, 514

U.S. at 557 n.2, 115 S. Ct. at 1629 n.2). In this regard, [w]hen the inquiry is

whether a federal law has sufficient links to an enumerated power to be within the

scope of federal authority, the analysis depends not on the number of links in the

congressional-power chain but on the strength of the chain. Id. at __, 130 S. Ct. at

1966.

In summary, these landmark Supreme Court decisionsWickard, South-

Eastern Underwriters, Heart of Atlanta Motel, Lopez, Morrison, Raich, and

Comstocktogether set forth the governing principles and analytical framework

we must apply to the commerce power issues presented here.

V. CONSTITUTIONALITY OF INDIVIDUAL MANDATE


UNDER THE COMMERCE POWER
99
With a firm understanding of the Acts provisions, the congressional

findings, and the Supreme Courts Commerce Clause precedents, we turn to the

central question at hand: whether the individual mandate is beyond the

constitutional power granted to Congress under the Commerce Clause and

Necessary and Proper Clause.

In this Section, we begin with first principles. We then examine the subject

matter the individual mandate seeks to regulate, and whether it can be readily

categorized under the classes of activity the Supreme Court has previously

identified. We follow with a discussion of the unprecedented nature of the

individual mandate. Next, we analyze whether the individual mandate is a valid

exercise of Congresss power to regulate activities that substantially affect

interstate commerce. In this regard, we appraise whether the governments

argument furnishes judicially enforceable limiting principles and address the

individual mandates far-reaching implications for our federalist structure. Lastly,

we consider the governments alternative argument that the individual mandate is

an essential part of a larger regulation of economic activity.

We conclude that the individual mandate exceeds Congresss commerce

power.

A. First Principles

100
As the Supreme Court has observed, The judicial authority to determine the

constitutionality of laws, in cases and controversies, is based on the premise that

the powers of the legislature are defined and limited; and that those limits may

not be mistaken, or forgotten, the constitution is written. City of Boerne v.

Flores, 521 U.S. 507, 516, 117 S. Ct. 2157, 2162 (1997) (quoting Marbury v.

Madison, 5 U.S. (1 Cranch) 137, 176 (1803)). The judiciary is called upon not

only to interpret the laws, but at times to enforce the Constitutions limits on the

power of Congress, even when that power is used to address an intractable

problem.

In enforcing these limits, we recognize that the Constitution established a

federal government that is acknowledged by all to be one of enumerated

powers. Comstock, 560 U.S. at __, 130 S. Ct. at 1956 (quoting McCulloch, 17

U.S. at 405). In describing this constitutional structure, the Supreme Court has

emphasized James Madisons exposition in The Federalist No. 45: The powers

delegated by the proposed Constitution to the federal government are few and

defined. Those which are to remain in the State governments are numerous and

indefinite. Gregory v. Ashcroft, 501 U.S. 452, 458, 111 S. Ct. 2395, 2399 (1991)

(quoting THE FEDERALIST NO. 45, at 29293 (James Madison) (Clinton Rossiter

ed., 1961)); see also Lopez, 514 U.S. at 552, 115 S. Ct. at 1626 (quoting same). In

101
that same essay, Madison noted that the commerce power was one such

enumerated power: The regulation of commerce, it is true, is a new power; but

that seems to be an addition which few oppose, and from which no apprehensions

are entertained. THE FEDERALIST NO. 45, at 289 (James Madison) (E.H. Scott ed.,

1898). The commerce power has since come to dominate federal legislation.

The power to regulate commerce is the power to prescribe the rule by

which commerce is to be governed. Gibbons, 22 U.S. at 196. As the Supreme

Court instructs us, The power of Congress in this field is broad and sweeping;

where it keeps within its sphere and violates no express constitutional limitation it

has been the rule of this Court, going back almost to the founding days of the

Republic, not to interfere. Katzenbach v. McClung, 379 U.S. 294, 305, 85 S. Ct.

377, 384 (1964). In fact, if the object of congressional legislation falls within the

sphere contemplated by the Commerce Clause, [t]hat power is plenary and may

be exerted to protect interstate commerce no matter what the source of the dangers

which threaten it. Jones & Laughlin Steel Corp., 301 U.S. at 37, 57 S. Ct. at 624

(citation and quotation marks omitted).

It is because of the breadth and depth of this power that even when the

Supreme Court has blessed Congresss most expansive invocations of the

Commerce Clause, it has done so with a word of warning: Undoubtedly the scope

102
of this power must be considered in the light of our dual system of government

and may not be extended so as to embrace effects upon interstate commerce so

indirect and remote that to embrace them, in view of our complex society, would

effectually obliterate the distinction between what is national and what is local and

create a completely centralized government. Id. It is this dualistic nature of the

Commerce Clause powernecessarily broad yet potentially dangerous to the

fundamental structure of our governmentthat has led the Court to adopt a

flexible approach to its application, one that is often difficult to apply. As Chief

Justice Hughes noted,

Whatever terminology is used, the criterion is necessarily one of degree


and must be so defined. This does not satisfy those [who] seek for
mathematical or rigid formulas. But such formulas are not provided by
the great concepts of the Constitution such as interstate commerce,
due process, equal protection. In maintaining the balance of the
constitutional grants and limitations, it is inevitable that we should
define their applications in the gradual process of inclusion and
exclusion.

Santa Cruz Fruit Packing Co. v. NLRB., 303 U.S. 453, 467, 58 S. Ct. 656, 660

(1938); see also Lopez, 514 U.S. at 566, 115 S. Ct. at 1633 (But, so long as

Congress authority is limited to those powers enumerated in the Constitution, and

so long as those enumerated powers are interpreted as having judicially

enforceable outer limits, congressional legislation under the Commerce Clause

always will engender legal uncertainty.).

103
Thus, it is not surprising that Lopez begins not with categories or substantial

effects tests, but rather first principles, reaffirming the constitutionally

mandated division of authority [that] was adopted by the Framers to ensure

protection of our fundamental liberties. 514 U.S. at 553, 115 S. Ct. at 1626

(citing Gregory, 501 U.S. at 458, 111 S. Ct. at 2400). While the substantial growth

and development of Congresss power under the Commerce Clause has been well-

documented, the Court has often reiterated that the power therein granted remains

subject to outer limits. Id. at 557, 115 S. Ct. at 1628. When Congress oversteps

those outer limits, the Constitution requires judicial engagement, not judicial

abdication.

The Supreme Court has placed two broad limitations on congressional

power under the Commerce Clause. First, Congresss regulation must

accommodate the Constitutions federalist structure and preserve a distinction

between what is truly national and what is truly local. Id. at 56768, 115 S. Ct. at

1634. Second, the Court has repeatedly warned that courts may not interpret the

Commerce Clause in a way that would grant to Congress a general police power,

which the Founders denied the National Government and reposed in the States.

Morrison, 529 U.S. at 618, 120 S. Ct. at 1754; see also Lopez, 514 U.S. at 584,

115 S. Ct. at 1642 (Thomas, J., concurring) ([W]e always have rejected readings

104
of the Commerce Clause and the scope of federal power that would permit

Congress to exercise a police power; our cases are quite clear that there are real

limits to federal power.).

Therefore, in determining if a congressional action is within the limits of the

Commerce Clause, we must look not only to the action itself but also its

implications for our constitutional structure. See Lopez, 514 U.S. at 56368, 115

S. Ct. at 163234. While these structural limitations are often discussed in terms of

federalism, their ultimate goal is the protection of individual liberty. See Bond v.

United States, 564 U.S. __, __, 131 S. Ct. 2355, 2363 (2011) (Federalism secures

the freedom of the individual.); New York v. United States, 505 U.S. at 181, 112

S. Ct. at 2431 (The Constitution does not protect the sovereignty of States for the

benefit of the States or state governments as abstract political entities . . . . To the

contrary, the Constitution divides authority between federal and state governments

for the protection of individuals.).

With this at stake, we examine whether Congress legislated within its

constitutional boundaries in enacting the individual mandate.83 We begin this

analysis with a presumption of constitutionality, meaning that we invalidate a

83
As a preliminary matter, we note that the parties appear to agree that if the individual
mandate is to be sustained, it must be under the third category of activities that Congress may
regulate under its commerce power: i.e., those activities that substantially affect interstate
commerce. Lopez, 514 U.S. at 559, 115 S. Ct. at 1630.
105
congressional enactment only upon a plain showing that Congress has exceeded its

constitutional bounds. Morrison, 529 U.S. at 607, 120 S. Ct. at 1748.

B. Dichotomies and Nomenclature

The parties contend that the answer to the question of the individual

mandates constitutionality is straightforward. The government emphasizes that

Congress intended to regulate the health insurance and health care markets to

ameliorate the cost-shifting problem created by individuals who forego insurance

yet at some time in the future seek health care for which they cannot pay. 42

U.S.C. 18091(a)(1)(A), (H). One of the tools Congress employed to solve that

problem is an economic mandate requiring Americans to purchase and

continuously maintain health insurance. The government argues that the individual

mandate is constitutional because it regulates quintessentially economic activity

related to an industry of near universal participation, whereas the regulations in

Lopez and Morrison touched on criminal conduct, which is not in any sense of

the phrase, economic activity. Morrison, 529 U.S. at 613, 120 S. Ct. at 1751. The

government submits that Congress has mandated only how Americans finance

their inevitable health care needs.

The plaintiffs respond that the plain text of the Constitution and Supreme

Court precedent support the conclusion that activity is a prerequisite to valid

106
congressional regulation under the commerce power. The plaintiffs stress that

Congresss authority is to regulate commerce, not to compel individuals to enter

into commerce so that the federal government may regulate them. The plaintiffs

point out that by choosing not to purchase insurance, the uninsured are outside the

stream of commerce. Indeed, the nature of the conduct is marked by the absence of

a commercial transaction. Since they are not engaged in commerce, or activities

associated with commerce, they cannot be regulated pursuant to the Commerce

Clause. The plaintiffs emphasize that, in 220 years of constitutional history,

Congress has never exercised its commerce power in this manner.

Whereas the parties and many commentators have focused on this

distinction between activity and inactivity, we find it useful only to a point.

Beginning with the plain language of the text, the Commerce Clause gives

Congress the power to regulate Commerce. U.S. CONST. art. I, 8, cl. 3. The

power to regulate commerce, of course, presupposes that something exists to

regulate. In its first comprehensive discussion of the Commerce Clause, the

Supreme Court in Gibbons attempted to define commerce, stating, Commerce,

undoubtedly, is traffic, but it is something more: it is intercourse. It describes the

commercial intercourse between nations, and parts of nations, in all its branches,

and is regulated by prescribing rules for carrying on that intercourse. Gibbons,

107
22 U.S. at 18990 (emphasis added). The nature of Chief Justice Marshalls

formulation presaged the Supreme Courts tendency to describe commerce in very

general terms, since an attempt to formulate a precise and all-encompassing

definition would prove impractical.

However, the Supreme Court has always described the commerce power as

operating on already existing or ongoing activity. The Gibbons Court stated, If

Congress has the power to regulate it, that power must be exercised whenever the

subject exists. If it exists within the States, if a foreign voyage may commence or

terminate at a port within a State, then the power of Congress may be exercised

within a State. Id. at 195 (emphasis added). In its recent cases, the Supreme Court

has continued to articulate Congresss commerce authority in terms of activity.

In Lopez, the Court identified three broad categories of activity that Congress

may regulate under its commerce power and concluded that possession of a gun

in a local school zone is in no sense an economic activity. 514 U.S. at 558, 567,

115 S. Ct. at 1629, 1634 (emphasis added); see also Raich, 545 U.S. at 26, 125 S.

Ct. at 2211 ([T]he CSA is a statute that directly regulates economic, commercial

activity. (emphasis added)); Morrison, 529 U.S. at 611, 120 S. Ct. at 1750

(Lopezs review of Commerce Clause case law demonstrates that in those cases

where we have sustained federal regulation of intrastate activity based upon the

108
activitys substantial effects on interstate commerce, the activity in question has

been some sort of economic endeavor. (emphasis added)).

As our extensive discussion of the Supreme Courts precedent reveals,

Commerce Clause cases run the gamut of possible regulation. But the diverse fact

patterns of Wickard, South-Eastern Underwriters, Heart of Atlanta Motel, Lopez,

Morrison, and Raich share at least one commonality: they all involved attempts by

Congress to regulate preexisting, freely chosen classes of activities.

Nevertheless, we are not persuaded that the formalistic dichotomy of

activity and inactivity provides a workable or persuasive enough answer in this

case. Although the Supreme Courts Commerce Clause cases frequently speak in

activity-laden terms, the Court has never expressly held that activity is a

precondition for Congresss ability to regulate commerceperhaps, in part,

because it has never been faced with the type of regulation at issue here.

We therefore must refine our understanding of the nature of the individual

mandate and the subject matter it seeks to regulate. The uninsured have made a

decision, either consciously or by default, to direct their financial resources to

some other item or need than health insurance. Congress described the activity it

sought to regulate as economic and financial decisions about how and when

health care is paid for, and when health insurance is purchased. 42 U.S.C.

109
18091(a)(2)(A) (emphasis added). It deemed such decisions as activity that is

commercial and economic in nature. Id. Congress linked the individual mandate

to this decision: In the absence of th[is] requirement, some individuals would

make an economic and financial decision to forego health insurance coverage and

attempt to self-insure . . . . Id.

That Congress casts the individual mandate as regulating economic activity

is not surprising. In Morrison, the Supreme Court acknowledged that thus far in

our Nations history our cases have upheld Commerce Clause regulation of

intrastate activity only where that activity is economic in nature. 529 U.S. at 613,

120 S. Ct. at 1751. Raich confirmed the continued viability of this distinction

between economic and noneconomic activity in assessing Congresss commerce

authority. See 545 U.S. at 2526, 125 S. Ct. at 221011.

The parties here disagree about where the individual mandate falls within

this economic versus noneconomic activity framework. On one hand, a decision

not to purchase insurance and to self-insure for health care is a financial decision

that has more of an economic patina than the gun possession in Lopez or the

gender-motivated violence in Morrison. But whether such an economic decision

constitutes economic activity as previously conceptualized by the Supreme Court

is not so clear, nor do we find this sort of categorical thinking particularly helpful

110
in assessing the constitutionality of such an unprecedented congressional action.

After all, in choosing not to purchase health insurance, the individuals regulated

by the individual mandate are hardly involved in the production, distribution, and

consumption of commodities, which was the broad definition of economics

provided by the Raich Court.84 545 U.S. at 25, 125 S. Ct. at 2211 (citation and

quotation marks omitted). Rather, to the extent the uninsured can be said to be

active, their activity consists of the absence of such behavior, at least with

respect to health insurance.85 Simply put, the individual mandate cannot be neatly

classified under either the economic activity or noneconomic activity

headings.

This confirms the wisdom in the conclusion that the Courts attempts

throughout history to define by semantic or formalistic categories those activities

that were commerce and those that were not are doomed to fail. Lopez, 514 U.S.

at 569, 115 S. Ct. at 1635 (Kennedy, J., concurring). Compare United States v.

84
The fact that conduct may be said to have economic effects does not, by that fact alone,
render the conduct economic activity, at least as defined by the Supreme Court. Lopez and
Morrison make this observation apparent. Even the fact that conduct in some way relates to
commerce does not, by itself, convert that conduct into economic activity. Indeed, the regulated
activity in Lopez (firearm possession) directly related to an article of commerce (the firearm
being possessed). The Supreme Court has emphasized that the relevant inquiry is the link
between the regulated activity and its effects on interstate commerce.
85
The government correctly notes that many of the uninsured do actively consume health
care, even though they are not participants in the health insurance market. We address this point
at length later.
111
E.C. Knight Co., 156 U.S. 1, 13, 15 S. Ct. 249, 254 (1895) (approving

manufacturing-commerce dichotomy), with Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 221

U.S. 1, 6869, 31 S. Ct. 502, 519 (1911) (declaring manufacturing-commerce

dichotomy unsound). See also Lopez, 514 U.S. at 572, 115 S. Ct. at 1636

(Kennedy, J., concurring) (noting the Courts recognition of the importance of a

practical conception of the commerce power); Wickard, 317 U.S. at 120, 63 S. Ct.

at 87 (stating that questions of the power of Congress are not to be decided by

reference to any formula which would give controlling force to nomenclature such

as production and indirect); Swift & Co. v. United States, 196 U.S. 375, 398,

25 S. Ct. 276, 280 (1905) (observing that commerce among the states is not a

technical legal conception, but a practical one, drawn from the course of

business). Yet, confusing though these dichotomies and doctrinal vacillations

have been, they appear animated by one overarching goal: to provide courts with

meaningful, judicially administrable limiting principles by which to assess

Congresss exercise of its Commerce Clause power.

Properly formulated, we perceive the question before us to be whether the

federal government can issue a mandate that Americans purchase and maintain

health insurance from a private company for the entirety of their lives.86 These

86
Whether one describes the regulated individuals decision as the financing of health
care, self-insurance, or risk retention, the congressional mandate is to acquire and continuously
112
types of purchasing decisions are legion. Every day, Americans decide what

products to buy, where to invest or save, and how to pay for future contingencies

such as their retirement, their childrens education, and their health care. The

government contends that embedded in the Commerce Clause is the power to

override these ordinary decisions and redirect those funds to other purposes.

Under this theory, because Americans have money to spend and must inevitably

make decisions on where to spend it, the Commerce Clause gives Congress the

power to direct and compel an individuals spending in order to further its

overarching regulatory goals, such as reducing the number of uninsureds and the

amount of uncompensated health care.

In answering whether the federal government may exercise this asserted

power to issue a mandate for Americans to purchase health insurance from private

companies, we next examine a number of issues: (1) the unprecedented nature of

the individual mandate; (2) whether Congresss exercise of its commerce authority

affords sufficient and meaningful limiting principles; and (3) the far-reaching

implications for our federalist structure.

C. Unprecedented Nature of the Individual Mandate

Both parties have cited extensively to previous Supreme Court opinions

maintain health coverage. And unless the person is covered by a government-financed health
program, the mandate is to purchase insurance from a private insurer.
113
defining the scope of the Commerce Clause. Economic mandates such as the one

contained in the Act are so unprecedented, however, that the government has been

unable, either in its briefs or at oral argument, to point this Court to Supreme

Court precedent that addresses their constitutionality. Nor does our independent

review reveal such a precedent.

The Supreme Court has sustained Congresss authority to regulate

steamboat traffic, Gibbons, 22 U.S. 1; trafficking of lottery tickets across state

lines, The Lottery Case, 188 U.S. 321, 23 S. Ct. 321 (1903); and carrying a woman

across state lines for immoral purposes, Hoke v. United States, 227 U.S. 308,

320, 33 S. Ct. 281, 283 (1913). Through the Commerce Clause, Congress may

prevent the interstate transportation of liquor, United States v. Simpson, 252 U.S.

465, 40 S. Ct. 364 (1920); punish an automobile thief who crosses state lines,

Brooks v. United States, 267 U.S. 432, 45 S. Ct. 345 (1925); and prevent diseased

herds of cattle from bringing their contagion from Georgia to Florida, Thornton v.

United States, 271 U.S. 414, 46 S. Ct. 585 (1926).

In the modern era, the Commerce Clause has been used to regulate labor

practices, Jones & Laughlin Steel Corp., 301 U.S. 1, 57 S. Ct. 615; impose

minimum working conditions, Darby, 312 U.S. 100, 61 S. Ct. 451; limit the

production of wheat for home consumption, Wickard, 317 U.S. 111, 63 S. Ct. 82;

114
regulate the terms of insurance contracts, South-Eastern Underwriters, 322 U.S.

533, 64 S. Ct. 1162; prevent discrimination in hotel accommodations, Heart of

Atlanta Motel, 379 U.S. 241, 85 S. Ct. 348, and restaurant services, Katzenbach,

379 U.S. 294, 85 S. Ct. 377; and prevent the home production of marijuana for

medical purposes, Raich, 545 U.S. 1, 125 S. Ct. 2195. What the Court has never

done is interpret the Commerce Clause to allow Congress to dictate the financial

decisions of Americans through an economic mandate.

Both the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) and the Congressional

Research Service (CRS) have commented on the unprecedented nature of the

individual mandate. When the idea of an individual mandate to purchase health

insurance was first floated in 1994, the CBO stated that a mandate requiring all

individuals to purchase health insurance would be an unprecedented form of

federal action. SPEC. STUDIES DIV., CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, THE BUDGETARY

TREATMENT OF AN INDIVIDUAL MANDATE TO BUY HEALTH INSURANCE 1 (1994)

[hereinafter CBO MANDATE MEMO]. The CBO observed that Congress has never

required people to buy any good or service as a condition of lawful residence in

the United States, noting that mandates typically apply to people as parties to

economic transactions, rather than as members of society. Id. at 12. Meanwhile,

in reviewing the present legislation in 2009, the CRS warned:

115
Despite the breadth of powers that have been exercised under the
Commerce Clause, it is unclear whether the clause would provide a solid
constitutional foundation for legislation containing a requirement to
have health insurance. Whether such a requirement would be
constitutional under the Commerce Clause is perhaps the most
challenging question posed by such a proposal, as it is a novel issue
whether Congress may use this clause to require an individual to
purchase a good or a service.

JENNIFER STAMAN & CYNTHIA BROUGHER, CONG. RESEARCH SERV., R. 40725,

REQUIRING INDIVIDUALS TO OBTAIN HEALTH INSURANCE: A CONSTITUTIONAL

ANALYSIS 3 (2009).

The fact that Congress has never before exercised this supposed authority is

telling. As the Supreme Court has noted, the utter lack of statutes imposing

obligations on the States executive (notwithstanding the attractiveness of that

course to Congress), suggests an assumed absence of such power. Printz, 521

U.S. at 90708, 117 S. Ct. at 2371; see also Va. Office for Prot. & Advocacy v.

Stewart, 563 U.S. __, __, 131 S. Ct. 1632, 1641 (2011) (Lack of historical

precedent can indicate a constitutional infirmity.); Alden v. Maine, 527 U.S. 706,

74344, 119 S. Ct. 2240, 2261 (1999). Few powers, if any, could be more

attractive to Congress than compelling the purchase of certain products. Yet even

if we focus on the modern era, when congressional power under the Commerce

Clause has been at its height, Congress still has not asserted this authority. Even in

the face of a Great Depression, a World War, a Cold War, recessions, oil shocks,

116
inflation, and unemployment, Congress never sought to require the purchase of

wheat or war bonds, force a higher savings rate or greater consumption of

American goods, or require every American to purchase a more fuel efficient

vehicle.87 See Printz, 521 U.S. at 905, 117 S. Ct. at 2370 ([I]f . . . earlier

Congresses avoided use of this highly attractive power, we would have reason to

believe that the power was thought not to exist.).

Traditionally, Congress has sought to encourage commercial activity it

favors while discouraging what it does not. This is instructive. Not only have prior

congressional actions not asserted the power now claimed, they contain some

indication of precisely the opposite assumption. Id. at 910, 117 S. Ct. at 2372.

Instead of requiring action, Congress has sought to encourage it. The instances of

such encouragement are ubiquitous, but the example of flood insurance provides a

particularly relevant illustration of how the individual mandate departs from

conventional exercises of congressional power.

In passing the National Flood Insurance Act of 1968, Congress recognized

that from time to time flood disasters have created personal hardships and

economic distress which have required unforeseen disaster relief measures and

have placed an increasing burden on the Nations resources. 42 U.S.C.

87
Compare the lack of legislation compelling activity to the long history of Congress
forbidding activity.
117
4001(a)(1). Despite considerable expenditures on public programs designed to

prevent floods, those programs had not been sufficient to protect adequately

against growing exposure to future flood losses. Id. 4001(a)(2). In response to

this problem, however, Congress did not require everyone who owns a house in a

flood plain to purchase flood insurance. In fact, Congress did not even require

anyone who chooses to build a new house in a flood plain to buy insurance.

Rather, Congress created a series of incentives designed to encourage voluntary

purchase of flood insurance. These incentives included requiring flood insurance

before the home owner could receive federal financial assistance or federally

regulated loans. See id. 4012a(a), (b)(1).

Without an individual mandate, the flood insurance program has largely

been a failure. See Bryant J. Spann, Note, Going Down for the Third Time:

Senator Kerrys Reform Bill Could Save the Drowning National Flood Insurance

Program, 28 GA. L. REV. 593, 597 (1994) (One of the most astounding facts to

surface from the Midwestern flood of 1993 was that so few homeowners eligible

for flood insurance actually had it. Of the states impacted by the flood, Illinois had

the highest percentage of eligible households covered, with 8.7%.). One key

reason for this low participation is not surprising. Disaster relief, as a political

issue, is almost invincible. No politician wants to be on record as opposing

118
disaster relief, particularly for his or her own constituents. Id. at 602. People

living in a flood plain know that even if they do not have insurance, they can count

on the virtually guaranteed availability of federal funds.88 Nevertheless, despite the

unpredictability of flooding, the inevitability that floods will strike flood plains,

and the cost shifting inherent in uninsured property owners seeking disaster relief

funds, Congress has never taken the obvious and expedient step of invoking the

power the government now argues it has and forcing all property owners in flood

plains to purchase insurance.89

Contrast flood insurance with the very few instances of activity in which

Congress has compelled Americans to engage solely as a consequence of being

citizens living in the United States. Given the attractiveness of the power to

compel behavior in order to solve important problems, we find it illuminating that

Americans have, historically, been subject only to a limited set of personal

mandates: serving on juries, registering for the draft, filing tax returns, and

responding to the census. These mandates are in the nature of duties owed to the

government attendant to citizenship, and they contain clear foundations in the

88
Compare this with the Emergency Medical Treatment and Active Labor Act
(EMTALA), 42 U.S.C. 1395dd, which ensures public access to emergency medical services
without regard to ones ability to pay.
89
The contrast with the individual mandate is even more stark when we consider that
property owners in flood plains have actually entered the housing market.
119
constitutional text.90 Additionally, all these mandates involve a citizen directly

interacting with the government, whereas the individual mandate requires an

individual to enter into a compulsory contract with a private company. In these

respects, the individual mandate is a sharp departure from all prior exercises of

federal power.

The draft is an excellent example of this sort of duty, particularly as it is one

upon which the Supreme Court has spoken. In the Selective Draft Law Cases, the

Supreme Court reviewed challenges to the draft instituted in 1917 upon the entry

of the United States into World War I. 245 U.S. 366, 38 S. Ct. 159 (1918). The

Court rejected these challenges on several grounds, primarily based on the long

history of the draft both in the United States and other nations. Id. at 37987, 38 S.

Ct. at 16264. But it also pointed to the relationship between citizens and

government: It may not be doubted that the very [c]onception of a just

government and its duty to the citizen includes the reciprocal obligation of the

citizen to render military service in case of need and the right to compel it. Id. at

378, 38 S. Ct. at 161.

90
See, e.g., U.S. CONST . art. I, 2 ([An] Enumeration shall be made within three Years
after the first Meeting of the Congress of the United States, and within every subsequent Term of
ten Years, in such Manner as they shall by Law direct.); id. art. I, 8, cl. 1 (The Congress shall
have Power To lay and collect Taxes); id. art. I, 8, cl. 12 (providing Congress with power [t]o
raise and support Armies); id. art. III, 2 (The Trial of all Crimes, except in Cases of
Impeachment, shall be by Jury.).
120
It is striking by comparison how very different this economic mandate is

from the draft. First, it does not represent the solution to a duty owed to the

government as a condition of citizenship. Moreover, unlike the draft, it has no

basis in the history of our nation, much less a long and storied one. Until Congress

passed the Act, the power to regulate commerce had not included the authority to

issue an economic mandate. Now Congress seeks not only the power to reach a

new class of activityfinancial decisions whose effects are felt some time in the

futurebut it wishes to do so through a heretofore untested power: an economic

mandate.

Having established the unprecedented nature of the individual mandate and

the lack of any Supreme Court case addressing this issue, we are left to apply some

basic Commerce Clause principles derived largely from Wickard, Lopez,

Morrison, and Raich.

D. Wickard and Aggregation

It is not surprising that Wickard, which the Lopez Court considered

perhaps the most far reaching example of Commerce Clause authority over

intrastate activity,91 514 U.S. at 560, 115 S. Ct. at 1630, provides perhaps the best

perspective on an economic mandate. Congresss restrictions on Roscoe Filburns

91
Some have argued that Raich now represents the high-water mark of Congresss
commerce authority. We discuss Raich in more detail below.
121
wheat acreage potentially forced him to purchase wheat on the open market. In

doing so, Congress was able to artificially inflate the price of wheat by

simultaneously decreasing supply and increasing demand. But Wickard is striking

not for its similarity to our present case, but in how different it is. Although

Wickard represents the zenith of Congresss powers under the Commerce Clause,

the wheat regulation therein is remarkably less intrusive than the individual

mandate.

Despite the fact that Filburn was a commercial farmer92 and thus far more

amenable to Congresss commerce power than an ordinary citizen, the legislative

act did not require him to purchase more wheat. Instead, Filburn had any number

of other options open to him. He could have decided to make do with the amount

of wheat he was allowed to grow. He could have redirected his efforts to

agricultural endeavors that required less wheat. He could have even ceased part of

his farming operations. The wheat-acreage regulation imposed by Congress, even

though it lies at the outer bounds of the commerce power, was a limitationnot a

mandateand left Filburn with a choice. The Acts economic mandate to purchase

92
In enacting the Agricultural Adjustment Act at issue in Wickard, Congress apparently
sought to avoid reaching subsistence farmers whose production did not leave surplus for sale.
Thus, it exempted small farms from the quota. See Wickard, 317 U.S. at 130 n.30, 63 S. Ct. at 92
n.30. In other words, Congresss regulation only applied to suppliers operating in the stream of
commerce, even though some of those market suppliers also consumed a portion of wheat at
home.
122
insurance, on the contrary, leaves no choice and is more far-reaching.

Although this distinction appears, at first blush, to implicate liberty

concerns not at issue on appeal,93 in truth it strikes at the heart of whether

Congress has acted within its enumerated power. Individuals subjected to this

economic mandate have not made a voluntary choice to enter the stream of

commerce, but instead are having that choice imposed upon them by the federal

government. This suggests that they are removed from the traditional subjects of

Congresss commerce authority, in the same manner that the regulated actors in

Lopez and Morrison were removed from the traditional subjects of Congresss

commerce authority by virtue of the noneconomic cast of their activity.

This departure from commerce power norms is made all the more salient

when we consider principles of aggregation, the chief addition of Wickard to the

Commerce Clause canon. Aggregation may suffice to bring otherwise non-

regulable, trivial instances of intrastate activity within Congresss reach if the

cumulative effect of this class of activity (i.e., the intrastate activity taken

together with that of many others similarly situated) substantially affects

interstate commerce. Wickard, 317 U.S. at 12728, 63 S. Ct. at 90. Aggregation is

93
Among other counts, the district court dismissed the plaintiffs substantive due process
challenge under the Fifth Amendment. Florida v. HHS, 716 F. Supp. 2d at 116162. That ruling
is not on appeal.

123
a doctrine that allows Congress to apply an otherwise valid regulation to a class of

intrastate activity it might not be able to reach in isolation.94

In Morrison and Lopez, the Supreme Court declined to apply aggregation to

the noneconomic activity at issue, reasoning that in every case where we have

sustained federal regulation under the aggregation principle in [Wickard], the

regulated activity was of an apparent commercial character. Morrison, 529 U.S.

at 611 n.4, 120 S. Ct. at 1750 n.4. The Court thereby resisted additional

expansion of the substantial effects and aggregation doctrines. Lopez, 514 U.S. at

567, 115 S. Ct. at 1634.

The question before us is whether Congress may regulate individuals

outside the stream of commerce, on the theory that those economic and financial

decisions to avoid commerce themselves substantially affect interstate commerce.

Applying aggregation principles to an individuals decision not to purchase a

product would expand the substantial effects doctrine to one of unlimited scope.

Given the economic reality of our national marketplace, any persons decision not

to purchase a good would, when aggregated, substantially affect interstate

94
Although not made explicit in Wickard, the courts have come to recognize aggregation
as flowing from Congresss powers to enact laws necessary and proper to effectuate its power
under the Commerce Clause. See, e.g., Raich, 545 U.S. at 22, 125 S. Ct. at 2209; id. at 34, 125 S.
Ct. at 2216 (Scalia, J., concurring); Katzenbach, 379 U.S. at 301302, 85 S. Ct. at 382.
124
commerce in that good.95 From a doctrinal standpoint, we see no way to cabin the

governments theory only to decisions not to purchase health insurance. If an

individuals mere decision not to purchase insurance were subject to Wickards

aggregation principle, we are unable to conceive of any product whose purchase

Congress could not mandate under this line of argument.96 Although any decision

not to purchase a good or service entails commercial consequences, this does not

warrant the facile conclusion that Congress may therefore regulate these decisions

pursuant to the Commerce Clause. See id. at 580, 115 S. Ct. at 1640 (Kennedy, J.,

concurring) (In a sense any conduct in this interdependent world of ours has an

ultimate commercial origin or consequence, but we have not yet said the

commerce power may reach so far.).

Thus, even assuming that decisions not to buy insurance substantially affect

interstate commerce, that fact alone hardly renders them a suitable subject for

95
Perhaps we can conceive of a purely intrastate good that is wholly insulated from the
interstate market and, therefore, whose purchase Congress may not mandate even under the
governments sweeping extension of Wickards aggregation principle. To the extent such
hypothetical goods exist, their number is vanishingly small.
96
The CBO suggested the possibility of this perilous course when it warned that an
individual mandate to buy health insurance could open the door to a mandate-issuing
government taking control of virtually any resource allocation decision that would otherwise be
left to the private sector . . . . In the extreme, a command economy, in which the President and
the Congress dictated how much each individual and family spent on all goods and services,
could be instituted without any change in total federal receipts or outlays. CBO MANDATE
MEMO , supra p.115, at 9.
125
regulation. See, e.g., Morrison, 529 U.S. at 617, 120 S. Ct. at 1754 (We

accordingly reject the argument that Congress may regulate noneconomic, violent

criminal conduct based solely on that conducts aggregate effect on interstate

commerce. (emphasis added)). Instead, what matters is the regulated subject

matters connection to interstate commerce. That nexus is lacking here. It is

immaterial whether we perceive Congress to be regulating inactivity or a financial

decision to forego insurance. Under any framing, the regulated conduct is defined

by the absence of both commerce or even the the production, distribution, and

consumption of commoditiesthe broad definition of economics in Raich. 545

U.S. at 25, 125 S. Ct. at 2211. To connect this conduct to interstate commerce

would require a but-for causal chain that the Supreme Court has rejected, as it

would allow Congress to regulate anything. Morrison, 529 U.S. at 615, 120 S. Ct.

at 1752.

E. Broad Scope of Congresss Regulation

The scope of Congresss regulation also affects the constitutional inquiry.

Indisputably, the health insurance and health care industries involve, and

substantially affect, interstate commerce, and Congress can regulate broadly in

both those realms. Nonetheless, Congress, in exercising its commerce authority,

must be careful not to sweep too broadly by including within the ambit of its

126
regulation activities that bear an insufficient nexus with interstate commerce. See

Morrison, 529 U.S. at 613 & n.5, 120 S. Ct. at 175152 & n.5 (distinguishing

invalidated statute from analogous statute requiring explicit interstate nexus);

Lopez, 514 U.S. at 56162, 115 S. Ct. at 1631 (same).

In this regard, the individual mandates attempt to reduce the number of the

uninsured and correct the cost-shifting problem is woefully overinclusive. The

language of the mandate is not tied to those who do not pay for a portion of their

health care (i.e., the cost-shifters). It is not even tied to those who consume health

care. Rather, the language of the mandate is unlimited, and covers even those who

do not enter the health care market at all. Although overinclusiveness may not be

fatal for constitutional purposes, the Supreme Court has indicated that it is a factor

to be added to the constitutional equation.

For example, in Lopez the vast majority of the regulated behavior (firearm

possession) did possess an interstate character.97 However, the Supreme Court

97
A staggering proportion of the firearms in America have been transported across state
lines, and thus the possessions at issue in Lopez likely did have a sufficient nexus to interstate
commerceand thus, were within Congresss regulatory authority. In the wake of Lopez, many
defendants challenged their prosecutions under the felons-with-firearms statute18 U.S.C.
1202(a), later recodified as 18 U.S.C. 922(g)that the Supreme Court distinguished from
922(q) by virtue of its jurisdictional element. In one such case, the governments own expert
witness testified that 95% of the firearms in the United States were transported across state lines.
See Brent E. Newton, Felons, Firearms, and Federalism: Reconsidering Scarborough in Light of
Lopez, 3 J. APP . PRAC. & PROCESS 671, 68182 & n.53 (2001).
Instructively, Congress took its cue from the Supreme Court after Lopez and amended the
Gun-Free School Zones Act to require an explicit interstate nexus on an individualized basis.
127
ultimately found this fact insufficient to save the statute. Rather, the Supreme

Court commented that an interstate-tying element in the statute itself would

ensure, through case-by-case inquiry, that the [activity] in question affects

interstate commerce.98 Lopez, 514 U.S. at 561, 115 S. Ct. at 1631.

Here, the decision to forego insurance similarly lacks an established

interstate tie or any case-by-case inquiry. See id. Aside from the categories of

exempted individuals, the individual mandate is applied across-the-board without

regard to whether the regulated individuals receive, or have ever received,

uncompensated careor, indeed, seek any care at all, either now or in the future.99

Thus, the Act contains no language which might limit its reach to a discrete set of

[activities] that additionally have an explicit connection with or effect on interstate

commerce. See id. at 562, 115 S. Ct. at 1631.

The individual mandate sweeps too broadly in another way. Because the

Specifically, Congress added a jurisdictional element to ensure that the charged individuals
particular firearm had moved in interstate or foreign commerce (or otherwise affected such
commerce). See 18 U.S.C. 922(q)(2)(A) (It shall be unlawful for any individual knowingly to
possess a firearm that has moved in or that otherwise affects interstate or foreign commerce at a
place that the individual knows, or has reasonable cause to believe, is a school zone. (emphasis
added)).
98
The Lopez Court never stated that such an element was required, and nor do we.
However, it is clearly a relevant constitutional factor that the Supreme Court instructs us to
consider. The governments argument ignores it completely.
99
Although health care consumption is pervasive, the plaintiffs correctly note that
participation in the market for health care is far less inevitable than participation in markets for
basic necessities like food or clothing.
128
Supreme Courts prior Commerce Clause cases all deal with already-existing

activitynot the mere possibility of future activity (in this case, health care

consumption) that could implicate interstate commercethe Court never had to

address any temporal aspects of congressional regulation. However, the premise of

the governments positionthat most people will, at some point in the future,

consume health carereveals that the individual mandate is even further removed

from traditional exercises of Congresss commerce power.100

It is true that Congress may, in some instances, regulate individuals who are

consuming health care but not themselves causing the cost-shifting problem. Cf.

Raich, 545 U.S. at 17, 125 S. Ct. at 2206 (We have never required Congress to

legislate with scientific exactitude.); id. at 22, 125 S. Ct. at 2209 (That the

regulation ensnares some purely intrastate activity is of no moment.). As the

plaintiffs acknowledged at oral argument, when the uninsured actually enter the

100
The dissent attempts to sidestep the temporal leap problem by citing Consolidated
Edison Co. v. NLRB for the proposition that Congress may take reasonable preventive
measures to avoid future disruptions to interstate commerce. 305 U.S. 197, 222, 59 S. Ct. 206,
213 (1938). Consolidated Edison, of course, is wholly inapposite to this case, since Congress was
regulating the labor practices of utility companies (1) fully engaged in the stream of commerce
and (2) presently supplying economic services to instrumentalities of interstate commerce, such
as railroads and steamships. Id. at 22022, 59 S. Ct. at 213. Even so, the dissents argument
proves far too much. After all, by the dissents reasoning, Congress could clearly reach the gun
possession at issue in Lopez, since firearms are (1) objects of everyday commercial transactions
and (2) are daily used to disrupt interstate commerce. See Lopez, 514 U.S. at 60203, 115 S. Ct.
at 1651 (Stevens, J., dissenting) (Guns are both articles of commerce and articles that can be
used to restrain commerce. Their possession is the consequence, either directly or indirectly, of
commercial activity.). Indeed, Antonio Lopez himself was paid $40 to traffic the gun for which
he was charged under 922(q). United States v. Lopez, 2 F.3d 1342, 1345 (5th Cir. 1995).
129
stream of commerce and consume health care, Congress may regulate their activity

at the point of consumption.

But the individual mandate does not regulate behavior at the point of

consumption. Indeed, the language of the individual mandate does not truly

regulate how and when health care is paid for. 42 U.S.C. 18091(a)(2)(A). It

does not even require those who consume health care to pay for it with insurance

when doing so. Instead, the language of the individual mandate in fact regulates a

related, but different, subject matter: when health insurance is purchased. Id. If

an individuals participation in the health care market is uncertain, their

participation in the insurance market is even more so.

In sum, the individual mandate is breathtaking in its expansive scope. It

regulates those who have not entered the health care market at all. It regulates

those who have entered the health care market, but have not entered the insurance

market (and have no intention of doing so). It is overinclusive in when it regulates:

it conflates those who presently consume health care with those who will not

consume health care for many years into the future. The governments position

amounts to an argument that the mere fact of an individuals existence

substantially affects interstate commerce, and therefore Congress may regulate

them at every point of their life. This theory affords no limiting principles in

130
which to confine Congresss enumerated power.

F. Governments Proposed Limiting Principles

We pause to consider the implications of the Governments arguments.

Lopez, 514 U.S. at 564, 115 S. Ct. at 1632. The government clearly appreciates the

far-reaching implications of the individual mandate. The government has struggled

to avoid the conclusion that Congress may order Americans other economic

decisions through the use of economic mandates. At oral argument, the

governments counsel specifically disclaimed the argument that Congress could

compel a person to purchase insurance solely on the basis of his financial decision

to spend his money elsewhere. Rather, the government seems to view an economic

mandate as an emergency tool of sorts, for use in extreme and unique situations

and only to the extent the underlying regulated conduct meets a number of fact-

based criteria.

The government submits that health care and health insurance are factually

unique and not susceptible of replication due to: (1) the inevitability of health care

need; (2) the unpredictability of need; (3) the high costs of health care; (4) the

federal requirement that hospitals treat, until stabilized, individuals with

emergency medical conditions, regardless of their ability to pay;101 (5) and

101
See EMTALA, 42 U.S.C. 1395dd. In this regard, the plaintiffs point out that the
governments contention amounts to a bootstrapping argument. Under the governments theory,
131
associated cost-shifting.

The first problem with the governments proposed limiting factors is their

lack of constitutional relevance.102 These five factual criteria comprising the

governments uniqueness argument are not limiting principles rooted in any

constitutional understanding of the commerce power. Rather, they are ad hoc

factors thatfortuitouslyhappen to apply to the health insurance and health care

industries. They speak more to the complexity of the problem being regulated than

the regulated decisions relation to interstate commerce. They are not limiting

principles, but limiting circumstances.

Apparently recognizing that these factors appear in many subjects worthy of

regulation, the government acknowledged at oral argument that the mere presence

of many of these factors is not sufficient. Presented with three examples of

Congress can enlarge its own powers under the Commerce Clause by legislating a market
externality into existence, and then claiming an extra-constitutional fix is required.
102
The Supreme Court has rejected similar calls for a reprieve from Commerce Clause
restraints based upon the ostensible uniqueness or gravity of the problem being regulated. For
instance, Justice Breyers dissent in Lopez attempted to deflect the majoritys focus on limiting
principlesspecifically, its statement that upholding 922(q) would enable the federal
government to regulate any activity that it found was related to the economic productivity of
individual citizens, 514 U.S. at 564, 115 S. Ct. at 1632by arguing that 922(q) is aimed at
curbing a particularly acute threat and that guns and education are incompatible in a special
way. Id. at 624, 115 S. Ct. at 1661 (Breyer, J., dissenting) (emphasis added). The dissent further
opined that gun possession in schools embodied the rare case . . . [when] a statute strikes at
conduct that (when considered in the abstract) seems so removed from commerce, but which
(practically speaking) has so significant an impact upon commerce. Id. at 624, 115 S. Ct. at
1662 (emphasis added). The majority dismissed these suggested limitations, however,
characterizing them as devoid of substance. Id. at 564, 115 S. Ct. at 1632 (majority opinion).
132
industries characterized by some or all of these market deficiencieselder care,

other types of insurance, and the energy marketthe government argued that an

economic mandate in these three settings is distinguishable.

However, virtually all forms of insurance entail decisions about timing and

planning for unpredictable events with high associated costsinsurance

protecting against loss of life, disability from employment, business interruption,

theft, flood, tornado, and other natural disasters, long-term nursing care

requirements, and burial costs. Under the governments proposed limiting

principles, there is no reason why Congress could not similarly compel Americans

to insure against any number of unforeseeable but serious risks.103 High costs and

cost-shifting in premiums are simply not limited to hospital care, but occur when

individuals are disabled, cannot work, experience an accident, need nursing care,

die, and myriad other insurance-related contingencies.

This gives rise to a second fatal problem with the governments proposed

limits: administrability. We are at a loss as to how such fact-based criteria can

serve as the sort of judicially enforceable limitations on the commerce power

103
The government essentially argues that anyone creates a cost-shifting risk by virtue of
being alive, since they may one day be injured or sick and seek care that they do not pay for.
Therefore, Congress can compel the purchase of health insurance, from birth to death, to protect
against such risks. This expansive theory could justify the compelled purchase of innumerable
forms of insurance, however. To give but one example, Congress could undoubtedly require
every American to purchase liability insurance, lest the consequences of their negligence or
inattention lead to unfunded costs (medical and otherwise) passed on to others in the future.
133
that the Supreme Court has repeatedly emphasized as necessary to that enumerated

power. Lopez, 514 U.S. at 566, 115 S. Ct. at 1633; see also Morrison, 529 U.S. at

608 n.3, 120 S. Ct. at 1749 n.3 (rejecting dissents remarkable theory that the

commerce power is without judicially enforceable boundaries). We are loath to

invalidate an act of Congress, and do so only after extensive circumspection. But

the role that the Court would take were we to adopt the position of the government

is far more troublesome. Were we to adopt the limiting principles proffered by

the government, courts would sit in judgment over every economic mandate issued

by Congress, determining whether the level of participation in the underlying

market, the amount of cost-shifting, the unpredictability of need, or the strength of

the moral imperative were enough to justify the mandate.

But the commerce power does not admit such limitations; rather it is

complete in itself, may be exercised to its utmost extent, and acknowledges no

limitations, other than are prescribed in the constitution. Gibbons, 22 U.S. at 196.

If Congress may compel individuals to purchase health insurance from a private

company, it may similarly compel the purchase of other products from private

industry, regardless of the unique conditions the government cites as warrant for

Congresss regulation here. See Governments Opening Br. at 19.

Moreover, the governments insistence that we defer to Congresss fact

134
findings underscores the lack of any judicially enforceable stopping point to the

governments uniqueness argument. Presumably, a future Congress similarly

would be able to articulate a unique problem requiring a legislative fix that

entailed compelling Americans to purchase a certain product from a private

company. The government apparently seeks to set the terms of the limiting

principles courts should apply, and then asks that we defer to Congresss judgment

about whether those conditions have been met. The Supreme Court has firmly

rejected such calls for judicial abdication in the Commerce Clause realm. See

Lopez, 514 U.S. at 557 n.2, 115 S. Ct. at 1629 n.2 ([W]hether particular

operations affect interstate commerce sufficiently to come under the constitutional

power of Congress to regulate them is ultimately a judicial rather than a legislative

question, and can be settled finally only by this Court. (quoting Heart of Atlanta

Motel, 379 U.S. at 273, 85 S. Ct. at 366 (Black, J., concurring))).

At root, the governments uniqueness argument relies upon a convenient

sleight of hand to deflect attention from the central issue in the case: what is the

nature of the conduct being regulated by the individual mandate, and may

Congress reach it? Because an individuals decision to forego purchasing a

product is so incongruent with the activities previously reached by Congresss

commerce power, the government attempts to limit the individual mandates far-

135
reaching implications. Accordingly, the government adroitly and narrowly re-

defines the regulated activity as the uninsureds health care consumption and

attendant cost-shifting, or the timing and method of payment for such

consumption.104

The governments reluctance to define the conduct being regulated as the

decision to forego insurance is understandable. After all, if the decision to forego

purchasing a product is deemed economic activity (merely because it is

inevitable that an individual in the future will consume in a related market), then

decisions not to purchase a product would be subject to the sweeping doctrine of

aggregation, and such no-purchase decisions of all Americans would fall within

the federal commerce power. Consequently, the government could no longer fall

back on uniqueness as a limiting factor, since Congress could enact purchase

mandates no matter how pedestrian the relevant product market.

As an inferior court, we may not craft new dichotomiesuniqueness

versus non-uniqueness, or cost-shifting versus non-cost-shiftingnot

recognized by Supreme Court doctrine. To do so would require us to fabricate out

104
The dissent adopts the governments position. See Dissenting Op. at 227 (describing
the relevant conduct targeted by Congress as the uncompensated consumption of health care
services by the uninsured); id. at 235 (stating that many of the[] uninsured currently consume
health care services for which they cannot or do not pay and [t]his is, in every real and
meaningful sense, classic economic activity); id. at 214 (In other words, the individual mandate
is the means Congress adopted to regulate the timing and method of individuals payment for the
consumption of health care services.).
136
of whole cloth a five-factor test that lacks any antecedent in the Supreme Courts

Commerce Clause jurisprudence. Thus, not only do the uniqueness factors lack

judicial administrability, present Commerce Clause doctrine prohibits inferior

courts, like us, from applying them anyway.

Ultimately, the governments struggle to articulate cognizable, judicially

administrable limiting principles only reiterates the conclusion we reach today:

there are none.

G. Congressional Findings

This brings us to the congressional findings. See 42 U.S.C.

18091(a)(1)(3). We look to congressional findings to help us evaluate the

legislative judgment that the activity in question substantially affected interstate

commerce. Lopez, 514 U.S. at 549, 115 S. Ct. at 1632.

Here, tracking the language of Supreme Court decisions, the congressional

findings begin with the statement that the individual insurance mandate is

commercial and economic in nature and substantially affects interstate

commerce. 42 U.S.C. 18091(a)(1). Of course, the relevant inquiry is not

whether the regulation itself substantially affects interstate commerce but rather

whether the underlying activity being regulated substantially affects interstate

commerce.

137
Later on, the findings do ground the individual mandate in Congresss effort

to address this multi-step cost-shifting scenario: (1) some uninsureds consume

health care; (2) in turn, some of them do not pay their full medical costs and

instead shift them to medical providers; (3) medical providers thereafter shift these

costs to private insurers; and (4) private insurers then shift them to insureds

through higher premiums.105 Id. 18091(a)(2). The average annual premium

increase is $1,000 for insured families, id., and $400 for individuals.106 The

findings state that the mandate will reduce the number of the uninsured and the

$43 billion cost-shifting and thereby lower health insurance premiums.107 Id.

18091(a)(2)(F).

Of course, the existence of congressional findings is not sufficient, by

itself, to sustain the constitutionality of Commerce Clause legislation. Morrison,

105
The parties and amici use the shorthand terms cost-shifting, cost-shifters, or free-
riders to describe these problems.
106
See Families USA, supra note 8.
107
Experts debate whether the Act will accomplish its premium-lowering objective.
According to even the CBO, Under PPACA and the Reconciliation Act, premiums for health
insurance in the individual market will be somewhat higher than they would otherwise be . . .
mostly because the average insurance policy in that market will cover a larger share of enrollees
costs for health care and provide a slightly wider range of benefits. CONG . BUDGET OFFICE , AN
ANALYSIS OF HEALTH INSURANCE PREMIUMS UNDER THE PATIENT PROTECTION AND
AFFORDABLE CARE ACT 8 (2009).
The CBO estimates the Act will cause costs for health insurance in the individual market
to rise by 27% to 30% over current levels in 2016, due to the broadened coverage achieved by the
insurance market reforms. Id. at 6. For the purpose of our analysis, however, we accept the
congressional finding that cost-shifters lead to higher premiums.
138
529 U.S. at 614, 120 S. Ct. at 1752. Rather, the Supreme Court has insisted that

courts examine congressional findings regarding substantial effects. See Lopez,

514 U.S. at 557 n.2, 115 S. Ct. at 1629 n.2 ([S]imply because Congress may

conclude that a particular activity substantially affects interstate commerce does

not necessarily make it so. (quoting Hodel, 452 U.S. at 311, 101 S. Ct. at 2391

(Rehnquist, J., concurring))).

As a preliminary matter, we recount what the record reveals regarding the

cost-shifting effects of the uninsured. To the extent the data show anything, the

data demonstrate that the cost-shifters are largely persons who either (1) are

exempted from the mandate, (2) are excepted from the mandate penalty, or (3) are

now covered by the Acts Medicaid expansion.

For example, illegal aliens and other nonresidents are cost-shifters ($8.1

billion, or 18.9% of the $43 billion),108 but they are exempted from the individual

mandate entirely. 26 U.S.C. 5000A(d)(3). Low-income persons are the largest

segment of cost-shifters ($15 billion, or 34.8% of the $43 billion),109 but they are

covered by the Acts Medicaid expansion or excepted from the mandate penalty.

108
See Br. of Amici Curiae Economists in Support of Plaintiffs at 11 & app. A
(summarizing their calculations based on the MEPS data set).
109
See Br. of Amici Curiae Economists in Support of Plaintiffs at 11 & app. A
(summarizing their calculations based on the MEPS data set).
139
Id. 5000A(e)(1), (2) (excepting individuals (1) whose premium contribution

exceeds 8% of household income or (2) whose household income is below the

specified income tax filing threshold). Previously, the uninsured with preexisting

health conditions sought, but were denied, coverage and ended up in the past cost-

shifting pool ($8.7 billion, or 20.1%).110 However, the Acts insurance reforms

now guarantee them coverage and move them out of the future cost-shifting pool.

Already-insured persons who do not pay their out-of-pocket costs (such as co-

payments and deductibles) are cost-shifters ($3.3 billion, or 7.6%),111 but they are

already covered by insurance without the mandate. In addition, the cost-shifter

uninsureds who cannot pay the average $2,000 medical bill also cannot pay the

average $4,500 premium,112 yielding another disconnect.

In reality, the primary persons regulated by the individual mandate are not

cost-shifters but healthy individuals who forego purchasing insurance. The Act

110
See Br. of Amici Curiae Economists in Support of Plaintiffs at 11 & app. A
(summarizing their calculations based on the MEPS data set).
111
See Br. of Amici Curiae Economists in Support of Plaintiffs at 11 & app. A
(summarizing their calculations based on the MEPS data set).
112
As noted earlier, the uninsureds average medical care costs were $2,000 in 2007 and
$1,870 in 2008. Some uninsureds incur a larger expense, some a smaller expense, and some no
expense at all. We use the average cited in the Brief of the Amici Curiae Economists in Support
of the Government, at 16, which is based on the MEPS tables. The CBO estimates that in 2016
the annual premium for a bronze level plan, even in the Exchanges, will average $4,5005,000
for individuals and $12,00012,500 for a family policy. Letter from Douglas Elmendorf,
Director, Cong. Budget Office, to Olympia Snowe, U.S. Senator (Jan. 11, 2010), available at
http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/108xx/doc10884/01-11-Premiums_for_Bronze_Plan.pdf.
140
confirms as much. To help private insurers, the congressional findings

acknowledge that the individual mandate seeks to broaden the health insurance

risk pool to include healthy individuals, to minimize adverse selection,113 to

increase the size of purchasing pools, and to promote economies of scale. 42

U.S.C. 18091(a)(2)(I), (J). The individual mandate forces healthy and voluntarily

uninsured individuals to purchase insurance from private insurers and pay

premiums now in order to subsidize the private insurers costs in covering more

unhealthy individuals under the Acts reforms. Congress sought to mitigate its

reforms regulatory costs on private insurers114 by compelling healthy Americans

outside the insurance market to enter the private insurance market and buy the

insurers products. This starkly evinces how the Act is forcing market entry by

those outside the market.

Nevertheless, we need not, and do not, rely on the factual disparity between

the persons regulated by the individual mandate and the cost-shifting problem.

113
Distinguished economists have filed helpful briefs on both sides of the case. While
they disagree on some things, they agree about the theory of adverse selection. They agree some
relatively healthy people refrain from, or opt out of, buying health insurance more often than
people who are unhealthy or sick seek insurance. This results in a smaller and less healthy pool
of insured persons for private insurance companies. Br. of Amici Curiae Economists in Support
of the Government at 1718; Br. of Amici Curiae Economists in Support of Plaintiffs at 1316.
114
As explained above, the Act requires private insurers (1) to cover the unhealthy and (2)
to price that coverage, not on actuarial risks or basic economic pricing decisions, but on
community-rated premiums without regard to health status. 42 U.S.C. 300gg-1(a).
141
After all, courts need not determine whether respondents activities, taken in the

aggregate, substantially affect interstate commerce in fact, but only whether a

rational basis exists for so concluding.115 Raich, 545 U.S. at 22, 125 S. Ct. at

2208 (emphasis added). The government would have this be the end of the

constitutional inquiry.

But the government skips important analytical steps. Rational basis review

is not triggered by the mere fact of Congresss invocation of Article I power;

rather, the Supreme Court has applied rational basis review to a more specific

question under the Commerce Clause: whether Congress has a rational basis for

concluding that the regulated activities, when taken in the aggregate,

substantially affect interstate commerce.116 Id. (emphasis added). As discussed in

subsection D, supra, courts must initially assess whether the subject matter

115
Notably, the Lopez Court recognized the same rational basis level of review as
Raich. See Lopez, 514 U.S. at 557, 115 S. Ct. at 1629 (stating that, since the New Deal, the
Supreme Court has undertaken to decide whether a rational basis existed for concluding that a
regulated activity sufficiently affected interstate commerce). Raich did not adopt a more
deferential review of congressional legislation than prior cases, as the Supreme Court itself
acknowledged. See 545 U.S. at 22, 125 S. Ct. at 2208 (collecting cases).
116
Every case the Raich Court cited for rational basis review is a substantial effects case.
See 545 U.S. at 22, 125 S. Ct. at 2208 (citing Lopez, 514 U.S. at 557, 115 S. Ct. 1624; Hodel,
452 U.S. at 27680, 101 S. Ct. 2352; Perez, 402 U.S. at 15556, 91 S. Ct. 1357; Katzenbach,
379 U.S. at 299301, 85 S. Ct. 377; Heart of Atlanta Motel, 379 U.S. at 25253, 85 S. Ct. 348).
In such contexts, courts will accord significant deference to Congresss assessment of whether an
activitys cumulative effect on interstate commerce is substantial or some lesser quantum. This
is an altogether separate question from (1) whether a regulated activity is amenable to
aggregation analysis at all and (2) the extent of the inferential leap needed to connect the
regulated activity to the effects on interstate commerce.
142
targeted by the regulation is suitable for aggregation in the first place. Relatedly,

courts, in the rational basis inquiry, must also examine whether the link between

the regulated activity and interstate commerce is too attenuated, lest there be no

discernible stopping point to Congresss commerce power.117 See Lopez, 514 U.S.

at 56268, 115 S. Ct. at 163034.

The wholesale deference the government would have us apply here cannot

be squared with the Supreme Courts decisions in Morrison and Lopez. Here,

Congress findings are substantially weakened by the fact that they rely so

heavily on a method of reasoning that [courts] have already rejected as

unworkable if we are to maintain the Constitutions enumeration of powers.

Morrison, 529 U.S. at 615, 120 S. Ct. at 1752. It is highly instructive that the

Lopez and Morrison Courts rejected a similar cost-shifting theory now

propounded by the government. In examining the actual relationship between gun

117
Compare Raich, 545 U.S. at 22, 125 S. Ct. at 2209 ([W]e have no difficulty
concluding that Congress had a rational basis for believing that failure to regulate the intrastate
manufacture and possession of marijuana would leave a gaping hole in the CSA.), Heart of
Atlanta Motel, 379 U.S. at 253, 85 S. Ct. at 355 (referring to overwhelming evidence that
discrimination by hotels and motels impedes interstate travel), and Wickard, 317 U.S. at 128, 63
S. Ct. at 91 ([A] factor of such volume and variability as home-consumed wheat would have a
substantial influence on price and market conditions.), with Morrison, 529 U.S. at 615, 120 S.
Ct. at 1752 (rejecting the governments invitation to follow the but-for causal chain from the
initial occurrence of violent crime . . . to every attenuated effect upon interstate commerce), and
Lopez, 514 U.S. at 564, 115 S. Ct. at 1632 ([I]f we were to accept the Governments arguments,
we are hard pressed to posit any activity by an individual that Congress is without power to
regulate.).
143
possession and interstate commerce, the Lopez Court refused to accept what it

referred to as the governments cost of crime theory. 514 U.S. at 564, 115 S. Ct.

at 1632. It did so despite the governments argument that the costs of violent

crime are substantial, and, through the mechanism of insurance, those costs are

spread throughout the population. Id. at 56364, 115 S. Ct. at 1632 (emphasis

added).

Similarly, in Morrison the Supreme Court considered a stockpile118 of

congressional findings attesting to the link between domestic violence and medical

costs frequently borne by third parties. See, e.g., 529 U.S. at 62936, 120 S. Ct at

176064 (Souter, J., dissenting); see also id. at 632, 120 S. Ct. at 1762 (Over 1

million women in the United States seek medical assistance each year for injuries

sustained [from] their husbands or other partners. (quoting S. Rep. No. 101-545,

at 37 (1990))); id. ([E]stimates suggest that we spend $5 to $10 billion a year on

health care, criminal justice, and other social costs of domestic violence.

(quoting S. Rep. No. 103-138, at 41 (1993))).

In Morrison, the Supreme Court also recounted Congresss express finding

118
In Morrison, [t]he congressional findings that accompanied VAWA were so
voluminous that they were removed from the text of the statute and placed in a conference report
to avoid cluttering the United States Code. Melissa Irr, Note, United States v. Morrison; An
Analysis of the Diminished Effect of Congressional Findings in Commerce Clause Jurisprudence
and a Criticism of the Abandonment of the Rational Basis Test, 62 U. PITT . L. REV . 815, 824
(2001).
144
that gender-motivated violence substantially affected interstate commerce by

deterring potential victims from traveling interstate, from engaging in employment

in interstate business, and from transacting with business, and in places involved

in interstate commerce; . . . by diminishing national productivity, increasing

medical and other costs, and decreasing the supply of and the demand for

interstate products. Id. at 615, 120 S. Ct. at 1752 (majority opinion) (emphasis

added) (quoting H.R. Conf. Rep. No. 103-711, at 385 (1994)). The Morrison

Court did not dispute the above figures about medical costs, but instead

considered them largely extraneous to the threshold question of whether the

subject matter of the regulation had a sufficient nexus to interstate commerce. See

id. at 617, 120 S. Ct. at 1754.

In both Lopez and Morrison, the Supreme Court determined that the

governments cost-shifting argument provided too attenuated a link to Congresss

commerce power. Under such a cost-shifting theory, it is difficult to perceive any

limitation on federal power, even in areas such as criminal law enforcement or

education where States historically have been sovereign. Lopez, 514 U.S. at 564,

115 S. Ct. at 1632.

For example, we harbor few doubts that an individuals decisions about

marriage, divorce, and child custody, if aggregated, would have substantial

145
effects on interstate commerce. See id. at 564, 115 S. Ct. at 1632. Yet, the mere

fact of an activitys substantial effects on interstate commerce does not thereby

render that activity an appropriate subject for Congresss plenary commerce

authority. Such a holding would require the Supreme Court to overturn Lopez and

Morrison.

We see no reason why the inferential leaps in this case are any less

attenuated than those in Lopez and Morrison. The cost-shifting accompanying the

criminal acts of violence at issue in Lopez and Morrisonhospital bills borne by

third parties, property damage and insurance consequences, law enforcement

expenditures and incarceration costsis at least as apparent as the multi-step cost-

shifting scenario associated with the medically uninsured. Meanwhile, in all three

cases, the regulated conduct giving rise to the cost-shifting is divorced from a

commercial transaction or the production, distribution, and consumption of

commodities. Raich, 545 U.S. at 26, 125 S. Ct. at 2211.

At best, we can say that the uninsured may, at some point in the

unforeseeable future, create that cost-shifting consequence. Yet this readily leads

to a scenario where we must pile inference upon inference to sustain Congresss

legislation, a practice the Supreme Court admonishes us to avoid. See Lopez, 514

U.S. at 567, 115 S. Ct. at 1634. If anything, the temporal aspects present here, but

146
not in Lopez or Morrison, render the regulated activity even further remote.119

We next explain how the individual mandate impairs important federalism

concerns.

H. Areas of Traditional State Concern

Before examining the states traditional role in regulating insurance and

health care, we fully recognize that Congress has the power under the Commerce

Clause to regulate broadly in those arenas. In fact, Congress has legislated

expansively and constitutionally in the fields of insurance and health care. See,

e.g., Health Insurance Portability and Accountability Act of 1996 (HIPAA),

Pub. L. No. 104-191, 110 Stat. 1936 (1996); Consolidated Omnibus Budget

Reconciliation Act of 1985 (COBRA), Pub. L. No. 99-272, 100 Stat. 82 (1986);

Employee Retirement Income Security Act of 1974 (ERISA), Pub. L. 93-406, 88

Stat. 829 (1974); Social Security Amendments of 1965, Pub. L. No. 89-97, 79 Stat.

119
The dissent identifies an economic effectcost-shiftingand essentially defines that
as the activity being regulated. But the dissents conflation of activity and effect is sheer question
begging. It is no wonder, then, that the dissent makes the breathtaking assertion that there is not
even a single inferential step needed to link the regulated activity here to an impact on
commerce. As the dissent frames the issue, there is no lack of nexus between the regulated
activity and its effects on interstate commerce because they are one and the same!
To the extent the dissent describes the conduct being regulated as the uncompensated
consumption of health care services, the language of the mandate refers only to insurance and
contains no reference to health care services, much less how health care services are consumed or
paid for. The dissent can find no inferential leap because it has assumed away the very problem
in this case, effectively treating the mandate as operating at the point of consumption. Under the
dissents re-framing of the issue, the VAWAs civil-remedy provision in Morrison could be
regarded as regulating the consumption of health care services, because such consumption
inevitably and empirically flows from gender-motivated violence.
147
286 (1965) (establishing Medicare and Medicaid); Federal Food, Drug, and

Cosmetic Act, Pub. L. No. 75-717, 52 Stat. 1040 (1938). It is clear that Congress

has enacted comprehensive legislation regarding health insurance and health care.

The Act is another such example. Yet, the narrow constitutional question here is

whether one provision 5000Ain that massive regulation goes too far.

For the individual mandate to be sustained, it must be enacted pursuant to a

valid exercise of Article I power. It simply will not suffice to say that, because

Congress has regulated broadly in a field, it may regulate in any fashion it pleases.

The Constitution supplies Congress with various tools to effectuate its legislative

power, but it also denies others. In assessing Congresss exercise of power, courts

recognize that the structural limits embedded in the Constitution are of equal

dignity to the express prohibitionsand may even be a more prevalent source of

limitation. See, e.g., Comstock, 560 U.S. at __, 130 S. Ct. at 1968 (Kennedy, J.,

concurring) (rejecting notion that the Constitutions express prohibitions are

the only, or even the principal, constraints on the exercise of congressional

power (emphasis added)).120

120
The Supreme Court reminds us that the federal structure serves to grant and delimit
the prerogatives and responsibilities of the States and the National Government vis--vis one
another and action that exceeds the National Governments enumerated powers undermines the
sovereign interests of States. Bond, 564 U.S. at __, __, 131 S. Ct. at 2364, 2366; see also
Gregory, 501 U.S. at 458, 111 S. Ct. at 2399 (This federalist structure of joint sovereigns
preserves to the people numerous advantages. It assures a decentralized government that will be
more sensitive to the diverse needs of a heterogenous society; it increases opportunity for citizen
148
The Supreme Courts Commerce Clause jurisprudence emphasizes that, in

assessing the constitutionality of Congresss exercise of its commerce authority, a

relevant factor is whether a particular federal regulation trenches on an area of

traditional state concern. See Morrison, 529 U.S. at 611, 613, 61516, 120 S. Ct.

at 175051, 1753; Lopez, 514 U.S. at 561 n.3, 56468, 115 S. Ct. at 1631 n.3,

163234. The Supreme Court has expressed concern that Congress might use the

Commerce Clause to completely obliterate the Constitutions distinction between

national and local authority. Morrison, 529 U.S. at 615, 120 S. Ct. at 1752; see

also Raich, 545 U.S. at 3536, 125 S. Ct. at 221617 (Scalia, J., concurring);

Lopez, 514 U.S. at 557, 56768, 115 S. Ct. at 162829, 1634; id. at 577, 115 S. Ct.

at 163839 (Kennedy, J., concurring) (stating that if Congress were to assume

control over areas of traditional state concern, the boundaries between the

spheres of federal and state authority would blur and political responsibility would

become illusory. The resultant inability to hold either branch of the government

answerable to the citizens is more dangerous even than devolving too much

authority to the remote central power (citation omitted)). Coupled with this

consideration, the Supreme Court recognizes that the Constitution withhold[s]

involvement in democratic processes; it allows for more innovation and experimentation in


government; and it makes government more responsive by putting the States in competition for a
mobile citizenry.).
149
from Congress a plenary police power. Lopez, 514 U.S. at 566, 115 S. Ct. at

1633; see also Morrison, 529 U.S. at 61819, 120 S. Ct. at 1754; cf. Comstock,

560 U.S. at __, 130 S. Ct. at 1964; id. at __, 130 S. Ct. at 1967 (Kennedy, J.,

concurring) (stating that the police power belongs to the States and the States

alone).

In addition, whether the regulated subject matter is an area of traditional

state concern impacts three of the five Comstock factors pertinent to a Necessary

and Proper Clause analysis: (1) whether there is a long history of federal

involvement in this arena, (2) whether the statute accommodates or supplants state

interests, and (3) the statutes narrow scope. 560 U.S. at __, 130 S. Ct. at 1965.

With these principles in mind, we examine whether insurance and health

care qualify as areas of traditional state concern. Prior to the Supreme Courts

1944 decision in South-Eastern Underwriters, the States enjoyed a virtually

exclusive domain over the insurance industry. St. Paul Fire & Marine Ins. Co. v.

Barry, 438 U.S. 531, 539, 98 S. Ct. 2923, 2928 (1978). Thus, South-Eastern

Underwriters was widely perceived as a threat to state power to tax and regulate

the insurance industry. United States Dept of Treasury v. Fabe, 508 U.S. 491,

499500, 113 S. Ct. 2202, 2207 (1993); see also Cantor v. Detroit Edison Co.,

428 U.S. 579, 608 n.4, 96 S. Ct. 3110, 3126 n.4 (1976) (Blackmun, J., concurring)

150
(Congress expressed concern [was that the result in South-Eastern

Underwriters] would greatly impair or nullify the regulation of insurance by the

States, bringing to a halt their experimentation and investigation in the area.).

To allay those fears, Congress moved quickly to restore the supremacy of the

States in the realm of insurance regulation. Fabe, 508 U.S. at 500, 113 S. Ct. at

2207 (emphasis added).

In 1945, a year after South-Eastern Underwriters, Congress passed the

McCarran-Ferguson Act, 59 Stat. 33, ch. 20, 15 U.S.C. 10111015.121 The

McCarran-Ferguson Act preserved state regulatory control over insurance, which

was largely considered by Congress to be a local matter. W. & S. Life Ins. Co. v.

State Bd. of Equalization, 451 U.S. 648, 653, 101 S. Ct. 2070, 2075 (1981)

(quoting H.R. Rep. No. 143, at 2 (1945)). The passage of the McCarran-Ferguson

Act signaled Congresss recognition of the states historical role in regulating

insurance within their boundariesand its unwillingness to supplant their vital

function as a source of experimentation. Prudential Ins. Co. v. Benjamin, 328 U.S.

408, 429, 66 S. Ct. 1142, 1155 (1946) (Obviously Congress purpose [in passing

121
The McCarran-Ferguson Act states: (1) [t]he business of insurance, and every person
engaged therein, shall be subject to the laws of the several States which relate to the regulation or
taxation of such business, 15 U.S.C. 1012(a), and (2) [n]o Act of Congress shall be construed
to invalidate, impair, or supersede any law enacted by any State for the purpose of regulating the
business of insurance, or which imposes a fee or tax upon such business, unless such Act
specifically relates to the business of insurance, id. 1012(b).
151
the McCarran-Ferguson Act] was broadly to give support to the existing and

future state systems for regulating and taxing the business of insurance.); see also

Ne. Bancorp, Inc. v. Bd. of Governors of Fed. Reserve Sys., 472 U.S. 159, 179,

105 S. Ct. 2545, 2556 (1985) (OConnor, J., concurring) (The business of

insurance is also of uniquely local concern . . . . [and] historically ha[s] been

regulated by the States in recognition of the critical part [it] play[s] in securing the

financial well-being of local citizens and businesses. (citations omitted)). Our

Circuit has reached a similar conclusion. Blue Cross & Blue Shield v. Nielsen, 116

F.3d 1406, 1413 (11th Cir. 1997) (Adjustment of the rights and interests of

insurers, health care providers, and insureds is a subject matter that falls squarely

within the zone of traditional state regulatory concerns.).

Thus, insurance qualifies as an area of traditional state regulation. This

recognition counsels caution, and supplies reviewing courts with even greater

cause for doubt when faced with an unprecedented economic mandate of dubious

constitutional status. Cf. Lopez, 514 U.S. at 583, 115 S. Ct. at 1641 (Kennedy, J.,

concurring) (The statute now before us forecloses the States from experimenting

and exercising their own judgment in an area to which States lay claim by right of

history and expertise, and it does so by regulating an activity beyond the realm of

commerce in the ordinary and usual sense of that term.).

152
The health care industry also falls within the sphere of traditional state

regulation. A states role in safeguarding the health of its citizens is a

quintessential component of its sovereign powers. The Supreme Court has

declared that the structure and limitations of federalism . . . allow the States great

latitude under their police powers to legislate as to the protection of the lives,

limbs, health, comfort, and quiet of all persons. Gonzales v. Oregon, 546 U.S.

243, 270, 126 S. Ct. 904, 923 (2006) (quotation marks and citation omitted).

Numerous Supreme Court decisions have identified the regulation of health

matters as a core facet of a states police powers. See, e.g., Hill v. Colorado, 530

U.S. 703, 715, 120 S. Ct. 2480, 2489 (2000) (It is a traditional exercise of the

States police powers to protect the health and safety of their citizens. (quotation

marks and citation omitted)); Barnes v. Glen Theatre, Inc., 501 U.S. 560, 569, 111

S. Ct. 2456, 2462 (1991) (The traditional police power of the States is defined as

the authority to provide for the public health, safety, and morals.); Head v. N.M.

Bd. of Examrs in Optometry, 374 U.S. 424, 428, 83 S. Ct. 1759, 1762 (1963)

([T]he statute here involved is a measure directly addressed to protection of the

public health, and the statute thus falls within the most traditional concept of what

is compendiously known as the police power.); Barsky v. Bd. of Regents, 347

U.S. 442, 449, 74 S. Ct. 650, 654 (1954) (It is elemental that a state has broad

153
power to establish and enforce standards of conduct within its borders relative to

the health of everyone there. It is a vital part of a states police power.); Jacobson

v. Massachusetts, 197 U.S. 11, 25, 25 S. Ct. 358, 360 (1905) (According to

settled principles, the police power of a state must be held to embrace, at least,

such reasonable regulations established directly by legislative enactment as will

protect the public health and the public safety.); see also Raich, 545 U.S. at 42,

125 S. Ct. at 2221 (OConnor, J., dissenting) (This case exemplifies the role of

States as laboratories. The States core police powers have always included

authority to define criminal law and to protect the health, safety, and welfare of

their citizens.).122

Although the states and the federal government both play indispensable

roles in regulating matters of health, modern Supreme Court precedents have

confirmed the view that the health of a states citizens is predominantly a state-

based concern: the regulation of health and safety matters is primarily, and

historically, a matter of local concern. Hillsborough Cnty. v. Automated Med.

Labs., Inc., 471 U.S. 707, 719, 105 S. Ct. 2371, 2378 (1985). The Supreme Court

122
Gibbons, which represents one of the Supreme Courts earliest articulations of the
states reserved police powers, also provides insight into the traditionally local nature of health
laws. In Gibbons, Chief Justice Marshall remarked that [i]nspection laws, quarantine laws,
health laws of every description, as well as laws for regulating the internal commerce of a State
together form a portion of that immense mass of legislation, which embraces every thing within
the territory of a State, not surrendered to the general government: all which can be most
advantageously exercised by the States themselves. 22 U.S. at 203 (emphasis added).
154
similarly has stated that the narrower category of health care is an area of

traditional state concern. See, e.g., Rush Prudential HMO, Inc. v. Moran, 536 U.S.

355, 387, 122 S. Ct. 2151, 2171 (2002) (referring to the field of health care as

a subject of traditional state regulation (quoting Pegram v. Herdrich, 530 U.S.

211, 237, 120 S. Ct. 2143, 2158 (2000))); N.Y. State Conf. of Blue Cross & Blue

Shield Plans v. Travelers Ins. Co., 514 U.S. 645, 661, 115 S. Ct. 1671, 1680

(1995) ([G]eneral health care regulation . . . historically has been a matter of local

concern.).

Here, it is undisputed that the individual mandate supersedes a multitude of

the states policy choices in these key areas of traditional state concern.

Congresss encroachment upon these areas of traditional state concern is yet

another factor that weighs in the plaintiffs favor, and strengthens the inference

that the individual mandate exceeds constitutional boundaries. The inference is

particularly compelling here, where Congress has used an economic mandate to

compel Americans to purchase and continuously maintain insurance from a private

company.

We recognize the argument that, if states can issue economic mandates,

Congress should be able to do so as well. Yes, some states have exercised their

general police power to require their citizens to buy certain productsmost

155
pertinently, for our purposes, health insurance itself.123 But if anything, this gives

us greater constitutional concern, not less. Indeed, if the federal government

possesses the asserted power to compel individuals to purchase insurance from a

private company forever, it may impose such a mandate on individuals in states

that have elected not to employ their police power in this manner.124 After all, if

and when Congress actually operates within its enumerated commerce power,

Congress, by virtue of the Supremacy Clause, may ultimately supplant the states.

When this occurs, a state is no longer permitted to tailor its policymaking goals to

the specific needs of its citizenry. This is precisely why it is critical that courts

preserve constitutional boundaries and ensure that Congress only operates within

the proper scope of its enumerated commerce power.

In sum, the fact that Congress has enacted this insurance mandate in an area

of traditional state concern is a factor that strengthens the inference of a

123
See, e.g., MASS. GEN . LAWS ch. 111M 2 (Massachusetts law requiring residents 18
years and older to obtain and maintain creditable coverage so long as it is deemed affordable);
N.J. STAT . ANN . 26:15-2 (New Jersey law requiring residents 18 years and younger to obtain
and maintain health care coverage that provides hospital and medical benefits).
124
Some states have even passed legislation providing that their citizens may not be
required to obtain or maintain health insurance. See, e.g., Utah Code Ann. 63M-1-2505.5; Va.
Code Ann. 38.2-3430.1:1; see also ARIZ. CONST . Art. XXVII, 2 (A law or rule shall not
compel, directly or indirectly, any person, employer or health care provider to participate in any
health care system.). The American Legislative Exchange Council, a nonprofit membership
association of state legislators, filed a helpful amicus brief documenting the diverse array of
policies implemented by states to provide their citizens with health coverage. See Br. of Amicus
Curiae American Legislative Exchange Council in Support of Plaintiffs at 2128.
156
constitutional violation. When this federalism factor is added to the numerous

indicia of constitutional infirmity delineated above, we must conclude that the

individual mandate cannot be sustained as a valid exercise of Congresss power to

regulate activities that substantially affect interstate commerce.

We do not reach this conclusion lightly, and we recognize that [d]ue

respect for the decisions of a coordinate branch of Government demands that we

invalidate a congressional enactment only upon a plain showing that Congress has

exceeded its constitutional bounds. Morrison, 529 U.S. at 607, 120 S. Ct. at

1748. But we believe a compelling showing has been made here, and the federal

balance is too essential a part of our constitutional structure and plays too vital a

role in securing freedom for us to admit inability to intervene when one or the

other level of Government has tipped the scales too far. Lopez, 514 U.S. at 578,

115 S. Ct. at 1639 (Kennedy, J., concurring) (citations omitted).

I. Essential to a Larger Regulatory Scheme

We lastly consider the governments separate contention that the individual

mandate is a necessary and proper exercise of Congresss commerce power

because it is essential to Congresss broader regulation of the insurance and health

care markets.

The governments argument derives from a Commerce Clause doctrine of

157
recent vintage. In 1995, the Lopez Court commented that the Gun-Free School

Zones Act was not an essential part of a larger regulation of economic activity, in

which the regulatory scheme could be undercut unless the intrastate activity were

regulated. Id. at 561, 115 S. Ct. at 1631 (majority opinion). Ten years later in

Raich, although plainly operating within the economic-noneconomic rubric

adopted in Lopez and Morrison, the Supreme Court adverted to the essential part

of a larger regulation of economic activity language in Lopez as a further reason

to sustain Congresss action.125 However, several features of the individual

mandate materially distinguish this case from Raich and demonstrate why the

governments essential to a broader regulation of commerce argument fails here.

First, the Supreme Court has implied that the larger regulatory scheme

doctrine primarily implicates as-applied challenges as opposed to the facial

challenge at issue here. For instance, the Supreme Court has employed the larger

regulatory scheme doctrine when a plaintiff asserts that, although Congresss

statute is a permissible regulation within its commerce power, the statute cannot

be validly applied to his particular intrastate activity. Raich, 545 U.S. at 15, 2324,

125
In a concurring opinion, Justice Scalia stated that Congress may regulate even
noneconomic local activity if that regulation is a necessary part of a more general regulation of
interstate commerce. Raich, 545 U.S. at 37, 125 S. Ct. at 2217 (Scalia, J., concurring) (emphasis
added). As noted earlier, however, the majority opinion in Raich described the regulated activity
as the production, distribution, and consumption of commodities and thus quintessentially
economic. Id. at 26, 125 S. Ct. at 2211 (majority opinion).
158
125 S. Ct. at 2204, 220910. In such an instance, the Supreme Court may

determine that the failure to reach a plaintiffs intrastate activities would

undermine Congresss efforts to police the interstate market. Id. at 28, 125 S. Ct. at

2212. However, the Supreme Court has to date never sustained a statute on the

basis of the larger regulatory scheme doctrine in a facial challenge, where

plaintiffs contend that the entire class of activity is outside the reach of

congressional power.126

On this facial versus as-applied point, the Raich Court declared that the

statutory challenges at issue in [Lopez and Morrison] were markedly different

from the challenge respondents pursue in the case at hand. Here, respondents ask

us to excise individual applications of a concededly valid statutory scheme. In

contrast, in both Lopez and Morrison, the parties asserted that a particular statute

or provision fell outside Congress commerce power in its entirety. Id. at 23, 125

S. Ct. at 2209. The Court deemed this facial versus as-applied distinction

pivotal, as we have often reiterated that [w]here the class of activities is

126
Although the Lopez Court was the first to recognize the larger regulatory scheme
doctrine, it is arguable whether they actually applied it, in any real sense, in that case. Rather, the
Supreme Court summarily stated that 922(q) did not implicate that doctrine at all and cannot,
therefore, be sustained under our cases upholding regulations of activities that arise out of or are
connected with a commercial transaction, which viewed in the aggregate, substantially affects
interstate commerce. Lopez, 514 U.S. at 561, 115 S. Ct. at 1631. Here, it would strain credulity
to suggest that the plaintiffs conduct arises out of or is connected with a commercial
transaction, since the very nature of their conduct is marked by the absence of a commercial
transaction.
159
regulated and that class is within the reach of federal power, the courts have no

power to excise, as trivial, individual instances of the class. Id. (quoting Perez,

402 U.S. at 154, 91 S. Ct. at 1361). The plaintiffs here, of course, are not asking

for courts to excise, as trivial, individual instances of a classrather, the plaintiffs

contend the mandate to purchase insurance from a private company falls outside of

Congresss commerce power in its entirety.

But even accepting that this larger regulatory scheme doctrine fully applies

in facial challenges, the governments argument still fails here. To see why, we

discuss how the Supreme Court utilized the doctrine in the as-applied setting of

Raich, the only instance in which a statute has been sustained by the larger

regulatory scheme doctrine. The Supreme Court in Raich observed that, in

enacting the CSA, Congress devised a closed regulatory system making it

unlawful to manufacture, distribute, dispense, or possess any controlled substance

except in a manner authorized by the CSA. Id. at 13, 125 S. Ct. at 2203 (emphasis

added). By classifying marijuana as a Schedule I drug, Congress sought to

eliminate all interstate traffic in the commodity. The Supreme Court concluded

that the diversion of homegrown marijuana tends to frustrate the federal interest

in eliminating commercial transactions in the interstate market in their entirety.

Id. at 19, 125 S. Ct. at 2207 (emphasis added).

160
Additionally, the fungible nature of the commodityi.e., the inability to

distinguish intrastate marijuana from interstate marijuanaalso undermined

Congresss ability to enforce its concededly valid total CSA ban on commercial

transactions in the interstate market. The Raich Court stated that [g]iven the

enforcement difficulties that attend distinguishing between marijuana cultivated

locally and marijuana grown elsewhere, and concerns about diversion into illicit

channels, we have no difficulty concluding that Congress had a rational basis for

believing that failure to regulate the intrastate manufacture and possession of

marijuana would leave a gaping hole in the CSA.127 Id. at 22, 125 S. Ct. at 2209

(citation omitted) (emphasis added). Consequently, the Raich Court determined

that Congresss regulation was justified by the possibility that the plaintiffs

127
The gaping hole identified by the Supreme Court was thrown into sharp relief by the
Raich plaintiffs lack of limiting principles. If Congress could not reach intrastate marijuana used
for medical purposes, the Raich Court reasoned that it must also be true that intrastate marijuana
used for recreational purposes could not be regulated either. 545 U.S. at 28, 125 S. Ct. at 2212.
And if Congress could not reach intrastate marijuana authorized by state law, neither could it
reach intrastate marijuana unauthorized by state law. Id. Moreover, if Congress could not reach
intrastate marijuana when it is authorized by state law, then Congresss ability to police the
interstate marijuana market would be wholly contingent on state decisions about whether or not
to authorize marijuana use. Congress would effectively be at the mercy of states, even though
state action cannot circumscribe Congress plenary commerce power. Id. at 29, 125 S. Ct. at
2213. It is easy to see how the Raich plaintiffs arguments threatened to completely undermine
the CSAs regulation of the interstate marijuana market, not to mention turn the Supremacy
Clause on its head. Id. at 29 n.38, 125 S. Ct. at 2213 n.38.
This stands in marked contrast with the case before us, where neither state law nor the
plaintiffs uninsured status undermine the ability of Congress to enforce its regulation of
interstate commerce. Even without the mandate, the integrity of all other statutory provisions is
maintained, and Congresss ability to enforce the Act is in no way jeopardized.
161
intrastate activities could frustrate or impede a validly enacted congressional

statute regulating interstate commerce.

In this case, the government contends that the individual mandate is

essential to its broader regulation of the insurance market. For example, the

government submits that Congresss insurance industry reformsspecifically, its

community-rating and guaranteed-issue reformswill encourage individuals to

delay purchasing private insurance until an acute medical need arises. Therefore,

the government argues that unless the individual mandate forces individuals into

the private insurance pool before they get sick or injured, Congresss insurance

industry reforms will be unsustainable by the private insurance companies. The

government emphasizes that the congressional findings state that the individual

mandate is essential to creating effective health insurance markets in which

improved health insurance products that are guaranteed issue and do not exclude

coverage of pre-existing conditions can be sold. 42 U.S.C. 18091(a)(2)(I).

We first note the truism that the mere placement of a particular regulation in

a broader regulatory scheme does not, ipso facto, somehow render that regulation

essential to that scheme. It would be nonsensical to suggest that, in announcing its

larger regulatory scheme doctrine, the Supreme Court gave Congress carte

blanche to enact unconstitutional regulations so long as such enactments were part

162
of a broader, comprehensive regulatory scheme. We do not construe the Supreme

Courts larger regulatory scheme doctrine as a magic words test, where

Congresss statement that a regulation is essential thereby immunizes its

enactment from constitutional inquiry. Such a reading would eviscerate the

Constitutions enumeration of powers and vest Congress with a general police

power.

Ultimately, we conclude that the Supreme Courts larger regulatory

scheme doctrine embodies an observation put forth in the New Deal case of Jones

& Laughlin Steel Corp.: Although activities may be intrastate in character when

separately considered, if they have such a close and substantial relation to

interstate commerce that their control is essential or appropriate to protect that

commerce from burdens and obstructions, Congress cannot be denied the power to

exercise that control. 301 U.S. at 37, 57 S. Ct. at 624 (emphasis added). Justice

Scalias concurring opinion in Raich suggests a similar interpretation. There, he

stated that the larger regulatory scheme statement in Lopez referred to those

cases permitting the regulation of intrastate activities which in a substantial way

interfere with or obstruct the exercise of the granted power. Raich, 545 U.S. at

36, 125 S. Ct. at 2217 (Scalia, J., concurring) (emphasis added) (quoting United

States v. Wrightwood Dairy Co., 315 U.S. 110, 119, 62 S. Ct. 523, 526 (1942)). In

163
other words, the Necessary and Proper Clause enables Congress in some instances

to reach intrastate activities that markedly burden or obstruct Congresss ability to

regulate interstate commerce.

In Raich, the plaintiffs intrastate activitiesgrowing and consuming

marijuanaobstructed and burdened Congresss total CSA ban on interstate

marijuana traffic, both because the fungible nature of marijuana frustrated

Congresss ability to police the interstate market and because evidence indicated

that intrastate marijuana is often diverted into the interstate market. Yet it is

evident that the conduct regulated by the individual mandatean individuals

decision not to purchase health insurance and the concomitant absence of a

commercial transactionin no way burdens or obstructs Congresss ability to

enforce its regulation of the insurance industry. Congresss statutory reforms of

health insurance productssuch as guaranteed issue and community ratingdo

not reference or make their implementation in any way dependent on the

individual mandate.

The individual mandate does not remove an obstacle to Congresss

regulation of insurance companies. An individuals uninsured status in no way

interferes with Congresss ability to regulate insurance companies. The uninsured

and the individual mandate also do not prevent insurance companies regulatory

164
compliance with the Acts insurance reforms. At best, the individual mandate is

designed not to enable the execution of the Acts regulations, but to counteract the

significant regulatory costs on insurance companies and adverse consequences

stemming from the fully executed reforms. That may be a relevant political

consideration, but it does not convert an unconstitutional regulation (of an

individuals decision to forego purchasing an expensive product) into a

constitutional means to ameliorate adverse cost consequences on private insurance

companies engendered by Congresss broader regulatory reform of their health

insurance products.128

The governments assertion that the individual mandate is essential to

Congresss broader economic regulation is further undermined by components of

the Act itself. In Raich, Congress devised a closed regulatory system, id. at 13,

125 S. Ct. at 2203, designed to eliminate all interstate marijuana traffic. Here, by

contrast, Congress itself carved out eight broad exemptions and exceptions to the

individual mandate (and its penalty) that impair its scope and functionality. See 26

128
The government argues that Congress has broad authority to select the means by which
it enforces its comprehensive regulatory scheme. But this hardly entails that Congress may
choose any and all means whatsoever. Indeed, Congress might have employed other
unconstitutional means to render its community-rating and guaranteed-issue reforms more
effective. For example, it might order unreasonable searches and seizures of corporate
documents to ensure that insurance companies were not discriminating against applicants with
preexisting conditions. Surely this action would not cease being a Fourth Amendment violation
merely because it is deemed essential to a broader regulatory scheme.
165
U.S.C. 5000A(d)(e). Even if the individual mandate remained intact, the

adverse selection problem identified by Congress would persist not only with

respect to these eight broad exemptions, but also with respect to those healthy

persons who choose to pay the mandate penalty. Those who pay the penalty one

year instead of purchasing insurance may still get sick the next year and then

decide to purchase insurance, for which they could not be denied.

Additionally, Congress has hamstrung its own efforts to ensure compliance

with the mandate by opting for toothless enforcement mechanisms. Eschewing the

IRSs traditional enforcement tools, the Act waives all criminal penalties for

noncompliance and prevents the IRS from using liens or levies to collect the

penalty. Id. 5000A(g)(2). Thus, to the extent the uninsureds ability to delay

insurance purchases would leave a gaping hole in Congresss efforts to reform

the insurance market, Congress has seen fit to bore the hole itself.

J. Conclusion

For these reasons, we conclude that the individual mandate contained in the

Act exceeds Congresss enumerated commerce power. This conclusion is limited

in scope. The power that Congress has wielded via the Commerce Clause for the

life of this country remains undiminished. Congress may regulate commercial

actors. It may forbid certain commercial activity. It may enact hundreds of new

166
laws and federally-funded programs, as it has elected to do in this massive 975-

page Act. But what Congress cannot do under the Commerce Clause is mandate

that individuals enter into contracts with private insurance companies for the

purchase of an expensive product from the time they are born until the time they

die.

It cannot be denied that the individual mandate is an unprecedented exercise

of congressional power. As the CBO observed, Congress has never required

people to buy any good or service as a condition of lawful residence in the United

States. CBO MANDATE MEMO, supra p.115, at 1. Never before has Congress

sought to regulate commerce by compelling non-market participants to enter into

commerce so that Congress may regulate them. The statutory language of the

mandate is not tied to health care consumptionpast, present, or in the future.

Rather, the mandate is to buy insurance now and forever. The individual mandate

does not wait for market entry.

Because the Commerce Clause is an enumerated power, the Supreme

Courts decisions all emphasize the need for judicially enforceable limitations on

its exercise. The individual mandate embodies no such limitations, at least none

recognized by extant Commerce Clause doctrine. If an individuals decision not to

purchase an expensive product is subject to the sweeping doctrine of aggregation,

167
then that purchase decision will almost always substantially affect interstate

commerce. The governments five factual elements of uniqueness, proposed as

constitutional limiting principles, are nowhere to be found in Supreme Court

precedent. Rather, they are ad hoc, devoid of constitutional substance, incapable

of judicial administrationand, consequently, illusory. The governments fact-

based criteria would lead to expansive involvement by the courts in congressional

legislation, requiring us to sit in judgment over when the situation is serious

enough to justify an economic mandate.

This lack of limiting principles also implicates two overarching

considerations within the Supreme Courts Commerce Clause jurisprudence: (1)

preserving the federal-state balance and (2) withholding from Congress a general

police power. Morrison, 529 U.S. at 61719, 120 S. Ct. at 1754; Lopez, 514 U.S.

at 56668, 115 S. Ct. at 163334; Jones & Laughlin Steel Corp., 301 U.S. at 30,

57 S. Ct. at 621. These concerns undergird the Constitutions dual sovereignty

structure, ensuring that the federal government remains a government of

enumerated powers.

As demonstrated at length throughout our opinion, Congress has broad

power to deal with the problems of the uninsured, and it wielded that power

pervasively in this comprehensive and sweeping Act. As to the individual mandate

168
provision, however, Congress exceeded its enumerated commerce power. The

structure of the Constitution interposes obstacles by design, in order to prevent the

arrogation of power by one branch or one sovereign. See Gregory, 501 U.S. at

458, 111 S. Ct. at 2400 (Just as the separation and independence of the coordinate

branches of the Federal Government serve to prevent the accumulation of

excessive power in any one branch, a healthy balance of power between the States

and the Federal Government will reduce the risk of tyranny and abuse from either

front.). We cannot ignore these structural limits on the Commerce Clause because

of the seriousness and intractability of the problem Congress sought to resolve in

the Act.

The Supreme Court has often found itself forced to strike down

congressional enactments even when the law is designed to address particularly

difficult and universally acknowledged problems. For instance, in Clinton v. City

of New York, 524 U.S. 417, 118 S. Ct. 2091 (1998), the Supreme Court addressed

a problem of Congresss own creationdeficit spending. The Line Item Veto Act

was of first importance, for it seems undeniable the Act will tend to restrain

persistent excessive spending. Id. at 449, 118 S. Ct. at 2108 (Kennedy, J.,

concurring). The problem the act addressed was momentous: A nation cannot

plunder its own treasury without putting its Constitution and its survival in peril.

169
Id.

Nevertheless, the Supreme Court invalidated the Line Item Veto Act,

recognizing that the Constitution establishes restraints on the power of Congress

to act, even in regards to the mechanism by which it withholds or allocates

funding. The fact that constitutional tools sometimes prove insufficient[] cannot

validate an otherwise unconstitutional device because [t]he Constitutions

structure requires a stability which transcends the convenience of the moment. Id.

at 453, 118 S. Ct. at 2110; see also New York v. United States, 505 U.S. at 178,

112 S. Ct. at 2429 (noting that [n]o matter how powerful the federal interest

involved, the Constitution simply does not give Congress the authority to

supersede its constitutionally imposed boundaries); INS v. Chadha, 462 U.S. 919,

95859, 103 S. Ct. 2764, 2788 (1983) (In purely practical terms, it is obviously

easier for action to be taken by one House without submission to the President; but

it is crystal clear from the records of the Convention, contemporaneous writings

and debates, that the Framers ranked other values higher than efficiency.).

In the same way, the difficulties posed by the insurance market and health

care cannot justify extra-constitutional legislation. See Printz, 521 U.S. at 935, 117

S. Ct. at 2385 (It matters not whether policymaking is involved, and no

case-by-case weighing of the burdens or benefits is necessary; such [federal]

170
commands are fundamentally incompatible with our constitutional system of dual

sovereignty.).

The federal governments assertion of power, under the Commerce Clause,

to issue an economic mandate for Americans to purchase insurance from a private

company for the entire duration of their lives is unprecedented, lacks cognizable

limits, and imperils our federalist structure. We recognize that [t]hese are not

precise formulations, and in the nature of things they cannot be. Lopez, 514 U.S.

at 567, 115 S. Ct. at 1634. That an economic mandate to purchase insurance from

a private company is an expedient solution to pressing public needs is not

sufficient. As the Supreme Court counseled in New York v. United States,

The result may appear formalistic in a given case to partisans of the


measure at issue, because such measures are typically the product of the
eras perceived necessity. But the Constitution protects us from our own
best intentions: It divides power among sovereigns and among branches
of government precisely so that we may resist the temptation to
concentrate power in one location as an expedient solution to the crisis
of the day.

505 U.S. at 187, 112 S. Ct. at 2434. Although courts must give due consideration

to the policy choices of the political branches, the judiciary owes its ultimate

deference to the Constitution.129

129
We are at a loss as to why the dissent spends a considerable portion of its opinion on
the Fifth and Tenth Amendments. As mentioned earlier, the district court dismissed the
plaintiffs Fifth Amendment claim. Florida v. HHS, 716 F. Supp. 2d at 116162. That ruling is
not on appeal.
171
VI. CONSTITUTIONALITY OF INDIVIDUAL MANDATE UNDER THE
TAX POWER

The government claims in the alternative that the individual mandate is a tax

validly enacted pursuant to the Taxing and Spending Clause. The Clause provides

in relevant part that Congress shall have Power To lay and collect Taxes, Duties,

Imposts and Excises, to pay the Debts and provide for the common Defence and

general Welfare of the United States. U.S. CONST. art. 1, 8, cl. 1. The

government claims that the taxing power is comprehensive and plenary, and the

fact that the individual mandate also has a concededly regulatory purpose is

irrelevant, because a tax does not cease to be valid merely because it regulates,

discourages, or even definitely deters the activities taxed. Governments

Opening Br. at 50 (quoting United States v. Sanchez, 340 U.S. 42, 44, 71 S. Ct.

108, 110 (1950)). The government claims that as long as a statute is productive of

Furthermore, the plaintiffs briefs on appeal raise no free-standing Tenth Amendment


claim as to the individual mandate. Although the state plaintiffs brief makes a single passing
reference to the Tenth Amendment in the introduction, see States Opening Br. at 3, the fact
remains that the Tenth Amendment is not once cited or argued in the state plaintiffs individual
mandate discussion. See States Opening Br. at 1947. The private plaintiffs brief also makes a
single passing reference to the Tenth Amendment, but only in relation to how principles of
federalism inform a Necessary and Proper Clause analysis. See Private Plaintiffs Br. at 46.
Accordingly, we cannot consider a free-standing Tenth Amendment claim. See, e.g.,
Tanner Adver. Grp., L.L.C. v. Fayette Cnty., 451 F.3d 777, 785 (11th Cir. 2006) (The law is by
now well settled in this Circuit that a legal claim or argument that has not been briefed before the
court is deemed abandoned and its merits will not be addressed. (quoting Access Now, Inc. v.
Sw. Airlines Co., 385 F.3d 1324, 1330 (11th Cir. 2004)) (brackets omitted)); United States v.
Jernigan, 341 F.3d 1273, 1283 n.8 (11th Cir. 2003) (finding issue waived, despite four passing
references in Appellants brief, because a party seeking to raise a claim or issue on appeal must
plainly and prominently so indicate).
172
some revenue, Congress may enact it under its taxing power. Id. (quoting

Sonzinsky v. United States, 300 U.S. 506, 514, 57 S. Ct. 554, 556 (1937)).

Furthermore, the government contends our review is limited because the

constitutional restraints on taxing are few and [t]he remedy for excessive

taxation is in the hands of Congress, not the courts. United States v. Kahriger,

345 U.S. 22, 28, 73 S. Ct. 510, 513 (1953), overruled on other grounds by

Marchetti v. United States, 390 U.S. 39, 88 S. Ct. 697 (1968); see also Kahriger,

345 U.S. at 31, 73 S. Ct. at 515 (Unless there are provisions, extraneous to any

tax need, courts are without authority to limit the exercise of the taxing power.).

Like every other court that has addressed this claim, we remain unpersuaded.

It is not surprising to us that all of the federal courts, which have otherwise

reached sharply divergent conclusions on the constitutionality of the individual

mandate, have spoken on this issue with clarion uniformity. Beginning with the

district court in this case, all have found, without exception, that the individual

mandate operates as a regulatory penalty, not a tax. Florida v. HHS, 716 F. Supp.

2d at 114344 (I conclude that the individual mandate penalty is not a tax. It is

(as the Act itself says) a penalty.); U.S. Citizens Assn v. Sebelius, 754 F. Supp.

2d 903, 909 (N.D. Ohio 2010) (concluding that the individual mandate is a

penalty, agree[ing] with the thoughtful and careful analysis of Judge Vinson);

173
Liberty Univ., Inc. v. Geithner, 753 F. Supp. 2d 611, 629 (W.D. Va. 2010) (After

considering the prevailing case law, I conclude that the better characterization of

the exactions imposed under the Act for violations of the employer and individual

coverage provisions is that of regulatory penalties, not taxes.); Virginia v.

Sebelius, 728 F. Supp. 2d 768, 78288 (E.D. Va. 2010) (concluding that the

individual mandate is, in form and substance, a penalty as opposed to a tax);

Goudy-Bachman v. HHS, 764 F. Supp. 2d 684, 695 (M.D. Pa. 2011) (The court

finds that the individual mandate itself is not a tax . . . .); Mead v. Holder, 766 F.

Supp. 2d 16, 41 (D.D.C. 2011) ([T]he Court concludes that Congress did not

intend [the individual mandate] to operate as a tax, and therefore Defendants

cannot rely on the General Welfare Clause as authority for its enactment.).

For good reason. The breadth of the taxing power, well noted by the

government and its amici, fails to resolve the question we face: whether the

individual mandate is a tax in the first place. The plain language of the statute and

well-settled principles of statutory construction overwhelmingly establish that the

individual mandate is not a tax, but rather a penalty. The legislative history of the

Act further supports this conclusion. And as the Supreme Court has repeatedly

recognized, there is a firm distinction between a tax and a penalty. See, e.g.,

United States. v. La Franca, 282 U.S. 568, 572, 51 S. Ct. 278, 280 (1931) (The

174
two words are not interchangeable one for the other.).

The government would have us ignore all of this and instead hold that any

provision found in the Internal Revenue Code that will produce revenue may be

characterized as a tax. This we are unwilling to do.

A. Repeated Use of the Term Penalty in the Individual Mandate

As in any case involving statutory construction, we begin with the plain

language of the statute. Hemispherx Biopharma, Inc. v. Johannesburg Consol.

Invs., 553 F.3d 1351, 1362 (11th Cir. 2008) (citing Consumer Prod. Safety

Commn v. GTE Sylvania, Inc., 447 U.S. 102, 108, 100 S. Ct. 2051, 2056 (1980)).

The plain language of the individual mandate is clear that the individual mandate

is not a tax, but rather, as the statute itself repeatedly states, a penalty imposed

on an individual for failing to maintain a minimum level of health insurance

coverage in any month beginning in 2014. Title 26 U.S.C. 5000A(a) requires

[a]n applicable individual to ensure that the individual . . . is covered under

minimum essential coverage. 26 U.S.C. 5000A(a). In order to enforce this

requirement, Congress stated that [i]f a taxpayer who is an applicable individual

. . . fails to meet the requirement of subsection (a) for 1 or more months, then . . .

there is hereby imposed on the taxpayer a penalty with respect to such failures.

Id. 5000A(b)(1) (emphasis added).

175
Nor could we construe Congresss choice of language as a careless one-time

invocation of the word penalty, because the remainder of the relevant provisions

in 5000A uses the same term over and over again, without exception and without

ever describing the penalty as a tax. See, e.g., id. 5000A(b)(3)(B) (individual

with respect to whom a penalty is imposed by this section who files joint tax

return shall [along with individuals spouse] be jointly liable for such penalty

(emphasis added)); id. 5000A(c)(1) (describing [t]he amount of the penalty

imposed by this section on any taxpayer for any taxable year (emphasis added));

id. 5000A(c)(2) (describing the monthly penalty amount with respect to any

taxpayer (emphasis added)); id. 5000A(g)(1) (The penalty provided by this

section shall be paid upon notice and demand by the Secretary . . . . (emphasis

added)); id. 5000A(g)(2)(A) (providing that taxpayer shall not be subject to any

criminal prosecution or penalty for failure to timely pay any penalty imposed by

this section (emphasis added)); id. 5000A(g)(2)(B) (providing that the Secretary

shall not file notice of lien or levy on any property of a taxpayer by reason of

any failure to pay the penalty imposed by this section (emphasis added)).

Thus, the text of the individual mandate unambiguously provides that it

imposes a penalty. The penalty encourages compliance with the Acts requirement

to obtain minimum essential coverage by imposing a monetary sanction on

176
conduct that violates that requirement. The text is not unclear and was carefully

selected to denote a specific meaning. As the Supreme Court most recently

recognized in United States v. Reorganized CF & I Fabricators of Utah, Inc., 518

U.S. 213, 116 S. Ct. 2106 (1996), [a] tax is an enforced contribution to provide

for the support of government; a penalty . . . is an exaction imposed by statute as

punishment for an unlawful act. Id. at 224, 116 S. Ct. at 2113 (quoting La

Franca, 282 U.S. at 572, 51 S. Ct. at 280). The Court further expounded upon La

Franca: We take La Francas statement of the distinction [between a tax and

penalty] to be sufficient for the decision of this case; if the concept of penalty

means anything, it means punishment for an unlawful act or omission. . . . Id.; see

also Dept of Revenue of Mont. v. Kurth Ranch, 511 U.S. 767, 77980, 114 S. Ct.

1937, 1946 (1994) (Whereas fines, penalties, and forfeitures are readily

characterized as sanctions, taxes are typically different because they are usually

motivated by revenue-raising, rather than punitive, purposes.). It is clear that the

terms tax and penalty are not interchangeable one for the other . . . . and if an

exaction be clearly a penalty it cannot be converted into a tax by the simple

expedient of calling it such. La Franca, 282 U.S. at 572, 51 S. Ct. at 280.

B. Designation of Numerous Other Provisions in the Act as Taxes

We add the truism that Congress knows full well how to enact a tax when it

177
chooses to do so. And the Act contains several provisions that are unmistakably

taxes. The point is amply made by simply looking at four different provisions: (1)

an Excise Tax on Medical Device Manufacturers, 26 U.S.C. 4191(a) (There is

hereby imposed on the sale of any taxable medical device by the manufacturer,

producer, or importer a tax equal to 2.3 percent of the price for which so sold.

(emphasis added)); (2) an Excise Tax on High Cost Employer-Sponsored Health

Coverage, id. 4980I(a)(1)(2) (if an employee receives excess benefit, as

defined in the statute, from employer-sponsored health coverage, there is hereby

imposed a tax equal to 40 percent of the excess benefit (emphasis added)); (3) an

Additional Hospital Insurance Tax for High-Income Taxpayers, amending id.

3101(b) (as part of Federal Insurance Contributions Act, providing that there is

hereby imposed on the income of every individual a tax equal to 1.45 percent of the

wages . . . received by him with respect to employment (emphasis added));130 and

(4) an Excise Tax on Indoor Tanning Services, id. 5000B(a) (There is hereby

imposed on any indoor tanning service a tax equal to 10 percent of the amount paid

for such service . . . whether paid by insurance or otherwise (emphasis added)).

130
Indeed, this provision, which takes effect in 2013, is a 0.9% flat tax increase on an
individuals wages, applicable to those earning annual wages over $200,000 ($250,000 in the
case of a jointly-filed return, or $125,000 in the case of a married taxpayer filing a separate tax
return). Act 9015(a)(1), 10906(a), (c); HCERA, Pub. L. No. 111-152, 1402(b)(1)(A), (3),
124 Stat. 1029, 1063 (2010), to be codified in 26 U.S.C. 3101(b) (effective Jan. 1, 2013).
178
It is an unremarkable matter of statutory construction that we presume

Congress did not indiscriminately use the term tax in some provisions but not in

others. See Duncan v. Walker, 533 U.S. 167, 173, 121 S. Ct. 2120, 2125 (2001) (It

is well settled that where Congress includes particular language in one section of a

statute but omits it in another section of the same Act, it is generally presumed that

Congress acts intentionally and purposely in the disparate inclusion or exclusion.

(quotation marks and alteration omitted)). We have little difficulty concluding that

Congress intended 5000A to operate as a penalty.

The very nature of congressional findings about the individual mandate

further amplifies that Congress designed and intended to design a penalty for the

failure to comply and not a tax. The source of the power, asserted by Congress, to

create the mandate is directly pegged to the Commerce Clause. See, e.g., 42 U.S.C.

18091(a)(1) (The individual responsibility requirement provided for in this

section . . . is commercial and economic in nature, and substantially affects

interstate commerce . . . .); id. 18091(a)(2)(B) (Health insurance and health care

services are a significant part of the national economy. . . . Private health insurance

spending . . . pays for medical supplies, drugs, and equipment that are shipped in

interstate commerce. Since most health insurance is sold by national or regional

health insurance companies, health insurance is sold in interstate commerce and

179
claims payments flow through interstate commerce.).

Indeed, the findings make clear that the goal of the individual mandate is not

to raise revenue for the public fisc, but rather to, among other things, reduce the

number of the uninsured and to create what Congress perceived to be effective

health insurance markets that make health insurance more widely available. Id.

18091(a)(2)(C)(I); see also id. 18091(a)(2)(J) (The requirement is essential to

creating effective health insurance markets that do not require underwriting and

eliminate its associated administrative costs.).

The argument that Congress need not employ the label of tax or expressly

invoke the Taxing and Spending Clause in order to enact a valid tax is surely true,

insofar as it goes. See Woods v. Cloyd W. Miller Co., 333 U.S. 138, 144, 68 S. Ct.

421, 424 (1948) ([T]he constitutionality of action taken by Congress does not

depend on recitals of the power which it undertakes to exercise.). The problem

with the claim, however, is not that Congress simply failed to use the term tax, or

declined to invoke the Taxing and Spending Clause when explaining the

constitutional basis for enacting the individual mandate. Rather, Congress

repeatedly told us that the individual mandate is a penalty and expressly invoked

its Commerce Clause power as the foundation for the mandate. The two are not the

same thing. Ultimately, we are hard pressed to construe the statute in a manner that

180
would require us to ignore the plain text of the statute, the words repeatedly

employed by Congress, well-settled principles of statutory construction, and well-

settled law emphasizing the substantive distinction between a tax and a penalty.

C. Legislative History of the Individual Mandate

Even if the text were unclearalthough it is notand we were to resort to

an examination of the legislative history, we would still find more of the same

thing: Congress intended to impose a penalty for the failure to maintain health

insurance.

Prior to the passage of the Act, earlier bills in both houses of Congress

proposed an individual mandate accompanied by a tax, as the district court noted.

See Florida v. HHS, 716 F. Supp. 2d at 1134. Thus, for example, Section 401 of the

Americas Affordable Choices Act of 2009, H.R. 3200, 111th Cong. (2009),

which was introduced in the House of Representatives on July 14, 2009, provided

that there is hereby imposed a tax on any individual who does not meet the

requirements of [maintaining minimum health insurance coverage] at any time

during the taxable year. A later version of the House bill, the Affordable Health

Care for America Act, H.R. 3962, 111th Cong. 501 (2009), passed the House of

Representatives on November 7, 2009, and similarly referred to the individual

mandates enforcement mechanism as a tax. On the Senate side, the Americas

181
Healthy Future Act, a precursor to the Act, also used the term tax. See S. 1796,

111th Cong. 1301 (2009) (If an applicable individual fails to [maintain

minimum health insurance coverage] there is hereby imposed a tax. . . .).

Notably, however, the final version of the Act abandoned the term tax in

favor of the term penalty. This is no mere semantic distinction, as [f]ew

principles of statutory construction are more compelling than the proposition that

Congress does not intend sub silentio to enact statutory language that it has earlier

discarded in favor of other language. INS v. Cardoza-Fonseca, 480 U.S. 421,

44243, 107 S. Ct. 1207, 1218 (1987) (emphasis added) (quotation marks omitted).

The government relies on different pieces of the legislative history,

particularly the statements of individual legislators, speaking both for and against

the Act, who at various times referred to the individual mandate as a tax. See

Governments Opening Br. at 54 (citing 156 Cong. Rec. H1854, H1882 (daily ed.

Mar. 21, 2010) (statement of Rep. Miller); 156 Cong. Rec. H1824, H1826 (daily

ed. Mar. 21, 2010) (statement of Rep. Slaughter); 155 Cong. Rec. S13,751,

S13,753 (daily ed. Dec. 22, 2009) (statement of Sen. Leahy); 155 Cong. Rec.

S13,558, S13,58182 (daily ed. Dec. 20, 2009) (statement of Sen. Baucus); 155

Cong. Rec. S12,768 (daily ed. Dec. 9, 2009) (statement of Sen. Grassley)). These

assorted statements of individual legislators are of precious little value, because

182
they are in conflict with the plain text of the statute and with more reliable

indicators of congressional intent. See Huff v. DeKalb Cnty., Ga., 516 F.3d 1273,

1280 (11th Cir. 2008) (The best evidence of [legislative] purpose is the statutory

text adopted by both Houses of Congress and submitted to the President. Where

that contains a phrase that is unambiguousthat has a clearly accepted meaning in

both legislative and judicial practicewe do not permit it to be expanded or

contracted by the statements of individual legislators or committees during the

course of the enactment process. (alteration in original) (quoting W. Va. Univ.

Hosps., Inc. v. Casey, 499 U.S. 83, 9899, 111 S. Ct. 1138, 1147 (1991))).

The government argues nevertheless that the individual mandate is still a

tax in both administration and effect. Governments Opening Br. at 54. It claims

that in passing on the constitutionality of a tax law, we should be concerned

only with its practical operation, not its definition or the precise form of descriptive

words which may be applied to it. Id. (quoting Nelson v. Sears, Roebuck & Co.,

312 U.S. 359, 363, 61 S. Ct. 586, 588 (1941)). That the individual mandate will

produce some revenue and will be enforced by the Internal Revenue Service is

enough, they say, to transmute the individual mandates penalty provision into a

tax.

We remain unpersuaded. Even on the governments own terms, the

183
individual mandate does not in practical operation act as a tax. See Nelson, 312

U.S. at 363, 61 S. Ct. at 588. The government specifically claims that the individual

mandate has the character of a tax because it will produce revenue. This

argumentwhich relies on undisputed projections by the CBO that the individual

mandate will generate some four to five billion dollars in annual revenue by the

end of this decade131does little to address the distinction between a penalty and a

tax. This is because [c]riminal fines, civil penalties, civil forfeitures, and taxes all

share certain features: They generate government revenues, impose fiscal burdens

on individuals, and deter certain behavior. Kurth Ranch, 511 U.S. at 778, 114 S.

Ct. at 1945. The Supreme Court has thus recognized, as indeed we must, that in our

world of less than perfect compliance, penalties generate revenue just as surely as

taxes.

Nor does the amount of projected revenue that will be collected under the

individual mandatea significant sum, to be surerender the mandate a tax. The

Supreme Court has never understood the amount of revenue generated by a

statutory provision to have definitional value. In Sonzinsky, the Court considered a

converse of the situation we face here, where a provision imposing a $200 annual

131
CBO, Payments of Penalties for Being Uninsured Under the Patient Protection and
Affordable Care Act 3 (rev. Apr. 30, 2010) [hereinafter CBO, Payments], available at
http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/113xx/doc11379/Individual_Mandate_ Penalties-04-30.pdf.
184
license tax on firearms dealers was challenged as not a true tax, but a penalty

imposed for the purpose of suppressing traffic in a certain noxious type of

firearms. 300 U.S. at 51112, 57 S. Ct. at 55455. The tax was productive of

some revenue, but not much. Id. at 514 & n.1, 57 S. Ct. at 556 & n.1 (observing

that 27 dealers paid the tax in 1934, and 22 paid in 1935). That did not stop the

Supreme Court from upholding the provision as a tax. The Supreme Court later

interpreted Sonzinsky as standing for the proposition that a tax does not cease to

be valid merely because it regulates, discourages, or even definitely deters the

activities taxed, and that proposition applies even though the revenue obtained is

obviously negligible. Sanchez, 340 U.S. at 44, 71 S. Ct. at 110 (emphasis added).

While the government views these cases as supportive of its argument,

because they demonstrate the breadth of Congresss taxing power, the cases merely

hold that an Act of Congress which on its face purports to be an exercise of the

taxing power is not any the less so because the tax is burdensome or tends to

restrict or suppress the thing taxed. Sonzinsky, 300 U.S. at 513, 57 S. Ct. at 556

(emphasis added). Thus, once Congress has expressly and unmistakably indicated

that a provision is a tax, courts will not [i]nquir[e] into the hidden motives which

may move Congress to exercise a power constitutionally conferred upon it. Id. at

51314; 57 S. Ct. at 556. But that is not this case. Here we confront a statute that is

185
not on its face a tax, but rather a penalty. Whats more, the district court correctly

noted that the government lacks any case precedent squarely on point. Florida v.

HHS, 716 F. Supp. 2d at 1140.

Even ignoring Congresss deliberate choice of the term penalty, the

individual mandate on its face imposes a monetary sanction on an individual who

fails to meet the requirement to maintain minimum essential coverage. 26

U.S.C. 5000A(b)(1). As we see it, such an exaction appears in every important

respect to be punishment for an unlawful act or omission, which defines the very

concept of penalty. CF & I Fabricators, 518 U.S. at 224, 116 S. Ct. at 2113; see

also Virginia v. Sebelius, 728 F. Supp. 2d at 786 (The only revenue generated

under the [individual mandate] is incidental to a citizens failure to obey the law by

requiring the minimum level of insurance coverage. The resulting revenue is

extraneous to any tax need. (quoting Kahriger, 345 U.S. at 31, 73 S. Ct. at 515)).

The government also suggests that the individual mandate operates as a tax

because it is housed in the Internal Revenue Code and is collected through

taxpayers annual returns. It is true that the individual mandate is located under the

section of the Code titled Miscellaneous Excise Taxes. Yet the Code itself makes

clear that Congresss choice of where to place a provision in the Internal Revenue

Code has no interpretive value: No inference, implication, or presumption of

186
legislative construction shall be drawn or made by reason of the location or

grouping of any particular section or provision or portion of this title. . . . 26

U.S.C. 7806(b); see also Florida v. HHS, 716 F. Supp. 2d at 1137 (citing same).

More significantly, not every provision in the Internal Revenue Code is a

tax. Indeed, Congress placed in Chapter 68 of the Internal Revenue Code a panoply

of civil penalties, running the gamut from broadly applicable (filing frivolous tax

returns132 or making unreasonable erroneous claims for a tax refund or credit133) to

highly industry-specific (tampering with or failing to maintain security

requirements for mechanical dye injection systems,134 or selling or reselling

adulterated diesel fuel that violates environmental standards135). In addition, the

mandates penalty is not treated like a tax because, as noted above, the IRS may not

132
See 26 U.S.C. 6702(a) (imposing penalty of $5,000" on person who files what
purports to be a return of a tax imposed by this title which either lacks information on which
the substantial correctness of the self-assessment may be judged or contains information that
on its face indicates that the self-assessment is substantially incorrect).
133
See 26 U.S.C. 6676(a) (If a claim for refund or credit with respect to income tax . . .
is made for an excessive amount, unless it is shown that the claim for such excessive amount has
a reasonable basis, the person making such claim shall be liable for a penalty in an amount equal
to 20 percent of the excessive amount.).
134
See 26 U.S.C. 6715A(a)(1) (If any person tampers with a mechanical dye injection
system used to indelibly dye fuel . . . such person shall pay a penalty in addition to the tax (if
any).). The penalty is the greater of $25,000 or $10 for each gallon of fuel involved. Id.
6715A(b)(1).
135
See 26 U.S.C. 6720A (imposing penalty of $10,000" for each violation, in addition
to the tax on such [fuel]).
187
place liens, or levy or initiate criminal prosecution or impose any interest or

criminal sanctions. All the IRS, practically speaking, may do is to offset the penalty

against a tax refund. 26 U.S.C. 5000A(g)(2)(A)(B).

Although it is irrelevant for our purposes precisely where in the Internal

Revenue Code Congress decided to place the individual mandate, id. 7806(b), we

observe that other chapters of the Internal Revenue Code include penalty

provisions as well. See, e.g., id. 5761(a) (imposing a penalty of $1,000" on any

personprimarily manufacturers, importers, and retailerswho willfully fails to

comply with a variety of statutory duties and taxes under Chapter 52 of the Internal

Revenue Code related to tobacco products and cigarettes). And Chapter 75 of the

Internal Revenue Code sets forth criminal penalties, which permit courts to impose

substantial fines. Id. 7206 (providing that those who commit tax fraud in a variety

of ways shall be guilty of a felony and, upon conviction thereof, shall be fined not

more than $100,000 ($500,000 in the case of a corporation), or imprisoned not

more than 3 years, or both, together with the costs of prosecution). While the

entire list of penalties in the Internal Revenue Code is far too long to exhaust here,

it is apparent that the placement of the individual mandate in the Internal Revenue

Code is far from sufficient to convert the individual mandate into a tax and has

limited value, if any at all, in determining whether the individual mandate is a tax

188
or a penalty.

After careful review of the statute, we conclude that the individual mandate

is a civil regulatory penalty and not a tax. As a regulatory penalty, the individual

mandate must therefore find justification in a different enumerated power. See

Sunshine Anthracite Coal Co. v. Adkins, 310 U.S. 381, 393, 60 S. Ct. 907, 912

(1940) (Congress may impose penalties in aid of the exercise of any of its

enumerated powers.); Virginia v. Sebelius, 728 F. Supp. 2d at 788; Florida v.

HHS, 716 F. Supp. 2d at 114344.

The individual mandate as written cannot be supported by the tax power.

VII. SEVERABILITY

We now turn to whether the individual mandate, found in 26 U.S.C.

5000A, can be severed from the remainder of the 975-page Act.

A. Governing Principles

In analyzing this question, we start with the settled premise that severability

is fundamentally rooted in a respect for separation of powers and notions of judicial

restraint. See Ayotte v. Planned Parenthood of N. New Eng., 546 U.S. 320, 32930,

126 S. Ct. 961, 96768 (2006). Courts must strive to salvage acts of Congress by

severing any constitutionally infirm provisions while leaving the remainder

intact. Id. at 329, 126 S. Ct. at 96768. [T]he presumption is in favor of

189
severability. Regan v. Time, Inc., 468 U.S. 641, 653, 104 S. Ct. 3262, 3269

(1984).

In the overwhelming majority of cases, the Supreme Court has opted to sever

the constitutionally defective provision from the remainder of the statute. See, e.g.,

Free Enter. Fund v. Pub. Co. Accounting Oversight Bd., 561 U.S. __, __, 130 S. Ct.

3138, 316162 (2010) (holding tenure provision severable from Sarbanes-Oxley

Act); New York v. United States, 505 U.S. at 186187, 112 S. Ct. at 2434 (holding

take-title provision severable from Low-Level Radioactive Waste Policy

Amendments Act of 1985); Alaska Airlines, Inc. v. Brock, 480 U.S. 678, 68497,

107 S. Ct. 1476, 147986 (1987) (holding legislative veto provision severable from

Airline Deregulation Act of 1978); Chadha, 462 U.S. at 93135, 103 S. Ct. at

277476 (holding legislative veto provision severable from Immigration and

Nationality Act); Buckley v. Valeo, 424 U.S. 1, 10809, 96 S. Ct. 612, 677 (1976)

(holding campaign expenditure limits severable from public financing provisions in

Federal Election Campaign Act of 1971).136

Indeed, in the Commerce Clause context, the Supreme Court struck down an

136
The paucity of case law supporting the plaintiffs severability position is underscored
by the lack of citation to any modern case where the Supreme Court found a legislative act
inseverable. Indeed, the most recent such case cited by the plaintiffs was decided over 75 years
ago, before modern severability law had even been established. See Private Plaintiffs Br. at
5962 (citing R.R. Ret. Bd. v. Alton R. Co., 295 U.S. 330, 55 S. Ct. 758 (1935); Williams v.
Standard Oil Co., 278 U.S. 235, 49 S. Ct. 115 (1929); Pollock v. Farmers Loan & Trust Co.,
158 U.S. 601, 15 S. Ct. 912 (1895), superseded by U.S. CONST . amend. XVI).
190
important provision of a statute and left the remainder of the statute intact. In

Morrison, the Court invalidated only one provisionthe civil remedies provision

for victims of gender-based violence. Morrison, 529 U.S. at 605, 627, 120 S. Ct. at

1747, 1759. The Supreme Court did not invalidate the entire VAWAor the

omnibus Violent Crime Control and Law Enforcement Act of 1994, of which it was

parteven though the text of the two bills did not contain a severability clause.

As these cases amply demonstrate, the Supreme Court has declined to

invalidate more of a statute than is absolutely necessary. Rather, when confronting

a constitutional flaw in a statute, we try to limit the solution to the problem.

Ayotte, 546 U.S. at 328, 126 S. Ct. at 967. Because [a] ruling of

unconstitutionality frustrates the intent of the elected representatives of the

people, courts should act cautiously and refrain from invalidating more of the

statute than is necessary. Regan, 468 U.S. at 652, 104 S. Ct. at 3269.

The Supreme Courts test for severability is well-established: Unless it is

evident that the Legislature would not have enacted those provisions which are

within its power, independently of that which is not, the invalid part may be

dropped if what is left is fully operative as a law. Alaska Airlines, 480 U.S. at 684,

107 S. Ct. at 1480 (quotation marks omitted) (emphasis added). As the Supreme

Court remarked in Chadha, divining legislative intent in the absence of a

191
severability or non-severability clause can be an elusive enterprise. 462 U.S. at

932, 103 S. Ct. at 2774.

B. Wholesale Invalidation

Applying these principles, we conclude that the district court erred in its

decision to invalidate the entire Act. Excising the individual mandate from the Act

does not prevent the remaining provisions from being fully operative as a law. As

our exhaustive review of the Acts myriad provisions in Appendix A demonstrates,

the lions share of the Act has nothing to do with private insurance, much less the

mandate that individuals buy insurance. While such wholly unrelated provisions

are too numerous to bear repeating, representative examples include provisions

establishing reasonable break time for nursing mothers, 29 U.S.C. 207(r);

epidemiology-laboratory capacity grants, 42 U.S.C. 300hh-31; an HHS study on

urban Medicare-dependent hospitals, id. 1395ww note; restoration of funding for

abstinence education, id. 710; and an excise tax on indoor tanning salons, 26

U.S.C. 5000B.

In invalidating the entire Act, the district court placed undue emphasis on the

Acts lack of a severability clause. See Florida ex rel. Bondi v. HHS, No. 3:10-CV-

91-RV/EMT, __ F. Supp. 2d __, 2011 WL 285683, at *3536 (N.D. Fla. Jan. 31,

2011). Supreme Court precedent confirms that the ultimate determination of

192
severability will rarely turn on the presence or absence of such a clause. United

States v. Jackson, 390 U.S. 570, 585 n.27, 88 S. Ct. 1209, 1218 n.27 (1968).

Rather, Congress silence is just thatsilenceand does not raise a presumption

against severability. Alaska Airlines, 480 U.S. at 686, 107 S. Ct. at 1481.

Nevertheless, the district court emphasized that an early version of

Congresss health reform bill did contain a severability clause. Congresss failure

to include such a clause in the final bill, the district court reasoned, can be viewed

as strong evidence that Congress recognized the Act could not operate as intended

without the individual mandate. Florida v. HHS, 2011 WL 285683, at *36. The

district court pushes this inference too far.

First, both the Senate and House legislative drafting manuals state that, in

light of Supreme Court precedent in favor of severability, severability clauses are

unnecessary unless they specifically state that all or some portions of a statute

should not be severed. See Office of Legislative Counsel, U.S. Senate, Legislative

Drafting Manual, 131 (Feb. 1997) (providing that a severability clause is

unnecessary but distinguishing a nonseverability clause, which provides that if

a specific portion of an Act is declared invalid, the whole Act or some portion of

the Act shall be invalid); Office of Legislative Counsel, U.S. House of

Representatives, House Legislative Counsels Manual on Drafting Style, 328

193
(Nov. 1995) (stating that a severability clause is unnecessary unless it provides in

detail which related provisions are to fall, and which are not to fall, if a specified

key provision is held invalid).

Second, the clause present in one early version of the Act was a general

severability clause, not a non-severability clause. See H.R. Rep. No 111-299, pt. 3,

at 17 155 (2009), reprinted in 2010 U.S.C.C.A.N. 474, 537 (If any provision of

this Act . . . is held to be unconstitutional, the remainder of the provisions of this

Act . . . shall not be affected.). Thus, according to Congresss own drafting

manuals, the severability clause was unnecessary, and its removal should not be

read as any indicator of legislative intent against severability. Rather, the removal

of the severability clause, in short, has no probative impact on the severability

question before us.

In light of the stand-alone nature of hundreds of the Acts provisions and

their manifest lack of connection to the individual mandate, the plaintiffs have not

met the heavy burden needed to rebut the presumption of severability. We therefore

conclude that the district court erred in its wholesale invalidation of the Act.

C. Severability of Individual Mandate from Two Insurance Reforms

The severability inquiry is not so summarily answered, however, with

194
respect to two of the private insurance industry reforms.137 The two reforms are:

guaranteed issue, 42 U.S.C. 300gg-1 (effective Jan. 1, 2014); and the prohibition

on preexisting condition exclusions, id. 300gg-3.

Our pause over the severability of these two reforms is due to the fact that

the congressional findings speak in broad, general terms except in one place that

states, as noted earlier, that the individual mandate is essential to creating

effective health insurance markets in which improved health insurance products

that are guaranteed issue and do not exclude coverage of pre-existing conditions

can be sold. Id. 18091(a)(2)(I). The findings in that paragraph add that if there

were no mandate, many individuals would wait to purchase health insurance until

they needed care.138 Id.

As discussed earlier, a significant number of the uninsured with preexisting

conditions voluntarily tried to buy insurance but were denied coverage or had those

137
For ease of discussion, we refer to those two provisions collectively as the two
reforms.
138
Section 18091(a)(2)(I) provides, in its entirety:
Under sections 2704 and 2705 of the Public Health Service Act (as added by section
1201 of this Act) [to be codified in 42 U.S.C. 300gg-3, 300gg-4], if there were no
requirement, many individuals would wait to purchase health insurance until they
needed care. By significantly increasing health insurance coverage, the requirement,
together with the other provisions of this Act, will minimize this adverse selection
and broaden the health insurance risk pool to include healthy individuals, which will
lower health insurance premiums. The requirement is essential to creating effective
health insurance markets in which improved health insurance products that are
guaranteed issue and do not exclude coverage of pre-existing conditions can be sold.
42 U.S.C. 18091(a)(2)(I).
195
conditions excluded, resulting in uncompensated health care consumption and cost-

shifting. Congress also found that insurers $90 billion in underwriting costs in

identifying unhealthy entrants represented 26% to 30% of premium costs. Id.

18091(a)(2)(J). The two reforms reduce the number of the uninsured and

underwriting costs by guaranteeing issue and prohibiting preexisting condition

exclusions. To benefit consumers, Congress has improved health insurance

products and required insurers to cover consumers who need their products the

most.

It is not uncommon that government regulations beneficial to consumers

impose additional costs on the industry regulated. These two reforms obviously

have significant negative effects on the business costs of insurers because they

require insurers to accept unhealthy entrants, raising insurers costs. The individual

mandate, in part, seeks to mitigate the reforms costs on insurers by requiring the

healthy to buy insurance and pay premiums to insurers to subsidize the insurers

costs in covering the unhealthy. Further, if there were no mandate, the argument

goes, the healthy people can wait until they are sick to obtain insurance, knowing

they could not then be turned away.139

139
When a medical need arises, individuals cannot literally purchase insurance on the way
to the hospital. Rather, the Act permits insurers to restrict enrollment to a specific open or special
enrollment period. 42 U.S.C. 300gg-1(b) (effective Jan. 1, 2014). Individuals therefore must
wait for an enrollment period. And once an individual applies for insurance, the Act allows up to
196
In this regard, our severability concern is not over whether the two reforms

can fully operate as a law. They can. Rather, our severability concern is only

whether it is evident that Congress would not have enacted the two insurance

reforms without the individual mandate. Alaska Airlines, 480 U.S. at 684, 107 S.

Ct. at 1480.

At the outset, we note that Congress could easily have included in the Act a

non-severability clause stating that the individual mandate should not be severed

from the two reforms. Under the legislative drafting manuals, the one instance in

which a severability clause is important is where it provides in detail which

related provisions are to fall, and which are not to fall, if a specified key provision

is held invalid. Office of Legislative Counsel, U.S. House of Representatives,

House Legislative Counsels Manual on Drafting Style, 328; accord Office of

Legislative Counsel, U.S. Senate, Legislative Drafting Manual, 131. Congress

did not include any such non-severability clause in the Act, however.

It is also telling that none of the insurance reforms, including even

guaranteed issue and coverage of preexisting conditions, contain any cross-

reference to the individual mandate or make their implementation dependent on the

mandates continued existence. See United States v. Booker, 543 U.S. 220, 260,

a 90-day waiting period for group coverage eligibility. Id. 300gg-7 (effective Jan. 1, 2014). We
can find no limit in the Act on the waiting period insurers can have in the individual market.
197
125 S. Ct. 738, 765 (2005) (stating that 18 U.S.C. 3742(e) contains critical

cross-references to the (now-excised) 3553(b)(1) and consequently must be

severed and excised for similar reasons); Alaska Airlines, 480 U.S. at 68889, 107

S. Ct. at 1482 (Congress did not link specifically the operation of the first-hire

provisions to the issuance of regulations.). Indeed, 300gg-3's prohibition on

preexisting condition exclusions was implemented in 2010 with respect to enrollees

under 19, despite the individual mandate not taking effect until 2014. This is a far

cry from cases where the Supreme Court has ruled provisions inseverable because

it would require courts to engage in quasi-legislative functions in order to preserve

the provisions. See, e.g., Randall v. Sorrell, 548 U.S. 230, 262, 126 S. Ct. 2479,

2500 (2006) (declining to sever Vermonts campaign finance contribution limits

because doing so would require [the Court] to write words into the statute); see

also Free Enter. Fund, 561 U.S. at __, 130 S. Ct. at 3162 (cautioning courts against

blue-pencil[ing]).

[T]he remedial question we must ask is which alternative adheres more

closely to Congress original objective in passing the Act: (1) the Act without the

individual mandate but otherwise intact; or (2) the Act without the individual

mandate and also without these two insurance reforms. See Booker, 543 U.S. at

263, 125 S. Ct. at 76667.

198
As discussed earlier, a basic objective of the Act is to make health insurance

coverage accessible and thereby to reduce the number of uninsured persons. See,

e.g., 42 U.S.C. 18091(a)(2) (stating the Act will increase the number and share

of Americans who are insured and significantly reduc[e] the number of the

uninsured). Undoubtedly, the two reforms seek to achieve those objectives. All

other things being equal, then, a version of the Act that contains these two reforms

would hew more closely to Congresss likely intent than one that lacks them.

But without the individual mandate, not all things are equal. We must

therefore look to the consequences of the individual mandates absence on the two

reforms. See Booker, 543 U.S. at 260, 125 S. Ct. at 765 (considering whether

excision of one part of statute would pose a critical problem); Regan, 468 U.S. at

653, 104 S. Ct. at 3269 (asking whether the policies Congress sought to advance

by enacting 504 can be effectuated even though the purpose requirement is

unenforceable). In doing so, several factors loom large.

First, the Act retains many other provisions that help to accomplish some of

the same objectives as the individual mandate. See Booker, 543 U.S. at 264, 125 S.

Ct. at 767 (The system remaining after excision, while lacking the mandatory

features that Congress enacted, retains other features that help to further these

objectives.); New York v. United States, 505 U.S. at 186, 112 S. Ct. at 2434

199
(Common sense suggests that where Congress has enacted a statutory scheme for

an obvious purpose, and where Congress has included a series of provisions

operating as incentives to achieve that purpose, the invalidation of one of the

incentives should not ordinarily cause Congress overall intent to be frustrated.).

For example, Congress included other provisions in the Act, apart from and

independent of the individual mandate, that also serve to reduce the number of the

uninsured by encouraging or facilitating persons (including the healthy) to

purchase insurance coverage. These include: (1) the extensive health insurance

reforms; (2) the new Exchanges; (3) federal premium tax credits, 26 U.S.C. 36B;

(4) federal cost-sharing subsidies, 42 U.S.C. 18071; (5) the requirement that

Exchanges establish an Internet website to provide consumers with information on

insurers plans, id. 18031(d)(4)(D); (6) the requirement that employers offer

insurance or pay a penalty, 26 U.S.C. 4980H; and (7) the requirement that certain

large employers automatically enroll new and current employees in an employer-

sponsored plan unless the employee opts out, 29 U.S.C. 218A, just to name a few.

Second, the individual mandate has a comparatively limited field of

operation vis--vis the number of the uninsured. In Alaska Airlines, the Supreme

Court found that the unconstitutional legislative veto provision of the Airline

Deregulation Act (permitting Congress to veto the Labor Secretarys implementing

200
regulations) was severable because, among other things, the statute left little of

substance to be subject to a veto. 480 U.S. at 687, 107 S. Ct. at 1481. The

Supreme Court noted the ancillary nature of the Labor Secretarys obligations

and the limited substantive discretion afforded the Secretary.140 Id. at 688, 107 S.

Ct. at 1482. Thus, the limited field of operation of an unconstitutional statutory

provision furnishes evidence that Congress likely would have enacted the statute

without it. Cf. Booker, 543 U.S. at 249, 125 S. Ct. at 759 (considering whether the

scheme that Congress created would be so transform[ed] . . . that Congress likely

would not have intended the Act as so modified to stand).

Here, as explained above, the operation of the individual mandate is limited

by its three exemptions, its five exceptions to the penalty, and its stripping the IRS

of tax liens, interests, or penalties and leaving virtually no enforcement mechanism.

Even with the mandate, a healthy individual can pay a penalty and wait until

becoming sick to purchase insurance.

Further, the individual mandates operation and effectiveness are limited by

140
The Supreme Court stated:
With this subsidiary role allotted to the Secretary, the veto provision could affect only
the relatively insignificant actions he might take in connection with the duty-to-hire
program. There is thus little reason to believe that Congress contemplated the
possibility of vetoing any of these actions and one can infer that Congress would
have been satisfied with the duty-to-hire provisions even without preserving the
opportunity to veto the DOLs regulations.
Alaska Airlines, 480 U.S. at 688, 107 S. Ct. at 1482 (footnote omitted).
201
the fact that, although the individual mandate requires individuals to obtain

insurance coverage, the mandate itself does not require them to obtain the

essential health benefits package or, indeed, any particular level of benefits at all.

Although the chosen term minimum essential coverage appears to suggest

otherwise, when the lofty veneer of the term is stripped away, one finds that the

actual coverage the individual mandate deems essential is nothing more than

coverage essential to satisfying the individual mandate.

The multiple features of the individual mandate all serve to weaken the

mandates practical influence on the two insurance product reforms.141 They also

weaken our ability to say that Congress considered the individual mandates

existence to be a sine qua non for passage of these two reforms. There is tension, at

least, in the proposition that a mandate engineered to be so porous and toothless is

such a linchpin of the Acts insurance product reforms that they were clearly not

intended to exist in its absence.

We are not unmindful of Congresss findings about the individual mandate.

But in the end, they do not tip the scale away from the presumption of severability.

As observed above, the findings in 18091(a)(2) track the language of the

141
Studies by the CBO bear this out. Even with the individual mandate, the CBO
estimates that in 2016, there will still be more than 21 million non-elderly persons who remain
uninsured, the majority of whom will not be subject to the penalty. See CBO, Payments, supra
note 131, at 1.
202
Supreme Courts Commerce Clause decisions. But the severability inquiry is

separate, and very different, from the constitutional analysis. The congressional

language respecting Congresss constitutional authority does not govern, and is not

particularly relevant to, the different question of severability (which focuses on

whether Congress would have enacted the Acts other insurance market reforms

without the individual mandate).

An example makes the point. Section 18091(a)(2)(H) of the same

congressional findings provides:

Under the Employee Retirement Income Security Act of 1974 (29 U.S.C.
1001 et seq.), the Public Health Service Act (42 U.S.C. 201 et seq.), and
this Act, the Federal Government has a significant role in regulating
health insurance. The requirement is an essential part of this larger
regulation of economic activity, and the absence of the requirement
would undercut Federal regulation of the health insurance market.

42 U.S.C. 18091(a)(2)(H). By its text, 18091(a)(2)(H) states that the individual

mandate is essential to this larger regulation of economic activitythat is,

regulating health insurance, which it does through ERISA and the Public Health

Service Act. If applied to severability, this would mean that Congress intended the

individual mandate to be essential to, and thus inseverable from, ERISA (enacted

in 1974) and the entire Public Health Service Act (or at least all parts of those

statutes that regulate health insurance). This is an absurd result for which no party

203
argues.142

These congressional findings do not address the one question that is relevant

to our severability analysis: whether Congress would not have enacted the two

reforms but for the individual mandate. Just because the invalidation of the

individual mandate may render these provisions less desirable, it does not

ineluctably follow that Congress would find the two reforms so undesirable

without the mandate as to prefer not enacting them at all. The fact that one

provision may have an impact on another provision is not enough to warrant the

inference that the provisions are inseverable. This is particularly true here because

the reforms of health insurance help consumers who need it the most.

In light of all these factors, we are not persuaded that it is evident (as

opposed to possible or reasonable) that Congress would not have enacted the two

reforms in the absence of the individual mandate.143 In so concluding, we are

142
A second illustration of the danger in relying too much on these statements in isolation
is that the same congressional findings also statenot once, but six timesthat the individual
mandate operates together with the other provisions of this Act to reduce the number of the
uninsured, lower health insurance premiums, improve financial security for families, minimize
adverse selection, and reduce administrative costs. See 42 U.S.C. 18091(a)(2)(C), (E), (F), (G),
(I), (J) (emphasis added). Congress itself states that all the provisions of the Act operate together
to achieve its goals. On this reasoning, the entire Act would be invalidated along with the
individual mandate. As discussed above, this conclusion is invalid.
143
While we discuss the two reforms specifically, our conclusionthat the individual
mandate is severableis the same as to the other insurance product reforms, such as community
rating and discrimination based on health status.
204
mindful of our duty to refrain from invalidating more of the statute than is

necessary.144 Regan, 468 U.S. at 652, 104 S. Ct. at 3269; see also Booker, 543

U.S. at 25859, 125 S. Ct. at 764 ([W]e must retain those portions of the Act that

are (1) constitutionally valid, (2) capable of functioning independently, and (3)

consistent with Congress basic objectives in enacting the statute. (quotation

marks and citations omitted)). And where it is not evident Congress would not have

enacted a constitutional provision without one that is unconstitutional, we must

allow any furtherand perhaps even necessaryalterations of the Act to be

rendered by Congress as part of that branchs legislative and political prerogative.

See Free Enter. Fund, 561 U.S. at __, 130 S. Ct. at 3162 ([S]uch editorial

freedomfar more extensive than our holding todaybelongs to the Legislature,

not the Judiciary. Congress of course remains free to pursue any of these options

going forward.). We therefore sever the individual mandate from the remaining

sections of the Act.

VIII. CONCLUSION

144
We acknowledge that the government, in arguing for the individual mandates
constitutionality, stated summarily that the individual mandate cannot be severed from the Acts
guaranteed issue and community rating provisions because the individual mandate is integral to
those sections that . . . provide that insurers must extend coverage and set premiums without
regard to pre-existing medical conditions. Governments Reply Br. at 58. But as explained
above, whether a statutory provision is integral or essential to other provisions for
Commerce Clause analytical purposes is a question distinct from severability. And in any event,
the touchstone of severability analysis is legislative intent, not arguments made during litigation.
205
We first conclude that the Acts Medicaid expansion is constitutional.

Existing Supreme Court precedent does not establish that Congresss inducements

are unconstitutionally coercive, especially when the federal government will bear

nearly all the costs of the programs amplified enrollments.

Next, the individual mandate was enacted as a regulatory penalty, not a

revenue-raising tax, and cannot be sustained as an exercise of Congresss power

under the Taxing and Spending Clause. The mandate is denominated as a penalty in

the Act itself, and the legislative history and relevant case law confirm this reading

of its function.

Further, the individual mandate exceeds Congresss enumerated commerce

power and is unconstitutional. This economic mandate represents a wholly novel

and potentially unbounded assertion of congressional authority: the ability to

compel Americans to purchase an expensive health insurance product they have

elected not to buy, and to make them re-purchase that insurance product every

month for their entire lives. We have not found any generally applicable, judicially

enforceable limiting principle that would permit us to uphold the mandate without

obliterating the boundaries inherent in the system of enumerated congressional

powers. Uniqueness is not a constitutional principle in any antecedent Supreme

Court decision. The individual mandate also finds no refuge in the aggregation

206
doctrine, for decisions to abstain from the purchase of a product or service,

whatever their cumulative effect, lack a sufficient nexus to commerce.145

The individual mandate, however, can be severed from the remainder of the

Acts myriad reforms. The presumption of severability is rooted in notions of

judicial restraint and respect for the separation of powers in our constitutional

system. The Acts other provisions remain legally operative after the mandates

excision, and the high burden needed under Supreme Court precedent to rebut the

presumption of severability has not been met.

Accordingly, we affirm in part and reverse in part the judgment of the district

court.

AFFIRMED in part and REVERSED in part.

145
Our respected dissenting colleague says that the majority: (1) has ignored the broad
power of Congress; (2) has ignored the Supreme Courts expansive reading of the Commerce
Clause; (3) presume[s] to sit as a superlegislature; (4) misapprehends the role of a reviewing
court; and (5) ignores that as nonelected judicial officers, we are not afforded the opportunity
to rewrite statutes we dont like. See Dissenting Op. at 208209, 243. We do not respond to
these contentions, especially given (1) our extensive and exceedingly careful review of the Act,
Supreme Court precedent, and the parties arguments, and (2) our holding that the Act, despite
significant challenges to this massive and sweeping federal regulation and spending, falls within
the ambit and prerogative of Congresss broad commerce power, except for one section,
5000A. We do, however, refuse to abdicate our constitutional duty when Congress has acted
beyond its enumerated Commerce Clause power in mandating that Americans, from cradle to
grave, purchase an insurance product from a private company.
207
MARCUS, Circuit Judge, concurring in part and dissenting in part1:

Today this Court strikes down as unconstitutional a central piece of a

comprehensive economic regulatory scheme enacted by Congress. The majority

concludes that Congress does not have the commerce power to require uninsured

Americans to obtain health insurance or otherwise pay a financial penalty. The

majority does so even though the individual mandate was designed and intended to

regulate quintessentially economic conduct in order to ameliorate two large,

national problems: first, the substantial cost shifting that occurs when uninsured

individuals consume health care services -- as virtually all of them will, and many

do each year -- for which they cannot pay; and, second, the unavailability of health

insurance for those who need it most -- those with pre-existing conditions and

lengthy medical histories.

In the process of striking down the mandate, the majority has ignored many

years of Commerce Clause doctrine developed by the Supreme Court. It has

ignored the broad power of Congress, in the words of Chief Justice Marshall, to

prescribe the rule by which commerce is to be governed. Gibbons v. Ogden, 22

U.S. (9 Wheat.) 1, 196 (1824). It has ignored the undeniable fact that Congress

commerce power has grown exponentially over the past two centuries, and is now

1
I concur only in Parts I (standing), III (Medicaid expansion), and VI (taxing
power) of the majority opinion.
208
generally accepted as having afforded Congress the authority to create rules

regulating large areas of our national economy. It has ignored the Supreme Courts

expansive reading of the Commerce Clause that has provided the very foundation

on which Congress already extensively regulates both health insurance and health

care services. And it has ignored the long-accepted instruction that we review the

constitutionality of an exercise of commerce power not through the lens of formal,

categorical distinctions, but rather through a pragmatic one, recognizing, as Justice

Holmes put it over one hundred years ago, that commerce among the states is not

a technical legal conception, but a practical one, drawn from the course of

business. Swift & Co. v. United States, 196 U.S. 375, 398 (1905).

The approach taken by the majority has also disregarded the powerful

admonitions that acts of Congress are to be examined with a heavy presumption of

constitutionality, that the task at hand must be approached with caution, restraint,

and great humility, and that we may not lightly conclude that an act of Congress

exceeds its enumerated powers. The circumspection this task requires is

underscored by recognizing, in the words of Justice Kennedy, the long and difficult

history of the judicial struggle to interpret the Commerce Clause during the

transition from the economic system the Founders knew to the single, national

market still emergent in our own era. United States v. Lopez, 514 U.S. 549, 568

209
(1995) (Kennedy, J., concurring).

The plaintiffs and, indeed, the majority have conceded, as they must, that

Congress has the commerce power to impose precisely the same mandate

compelling the same class of uninsured individuals to obtain the same kind of

insurance, or otherwise pay a penalty, as a necessary condition to receiving health

care services, at the time the uninsured seek these services. Nevertheless, the

plaintiffs argue that Congress cannot do now what it plainly can do later. In other

words, Congress must wait until each component transaction underlying the cost-

shifting problem occurs, causing huge increases in costs both for those who have

health care insurance and for health care providers, before it may constitutionally

act. I can find nothing in logic or law that so circumscribes Congress commerce

power and yields so anomalous a result.

Although it is surely true that there is no Supreme Court decision squarely on

point dictating the result that the individual mandate is within the commerce power

of Congress, the rationale embodied in the Courts Commerce Clause decisions

over more than 75 years makes clear that this legislation falls within Congress

interstate commerce power. These decisions instruct us to ask whether the target of

the regulation is economic in nature and whether Congress had a rational basis to

conclude that the regulated conduct has a substantial effect on interstate commerce.

210
It cannot be denied that Congress has promulgated a rule by which to

comprehensively regulate the timing and means of payment for the virtually

inevitable consumption of health care services. Nor can it be denied that the

consumption of health care services by the uninsured has a very substantial impact

on interstate commerce -- the shifting of substantial costs from those who do not

pay to those who do and to the providers who offer care. I therefore respectfully

dissent from the majoritys opinion insofar as it strikes down the individual

mandate.

I.

A.

A considerable portion of the American population -- estimated at 50 million

-- lacks any form of health care insurance.2 The individual mandate was designed

2
In 2009, the total number of uninsured was estimated at 50.7 million, or about
16.7% of the total population. U.S. Census Bureau, U.S. Dept of Commerce, Income,
Poverty, and Health Insurance Coverage in the United States: 2009, at 23 tbl.8 (2010),
available at http://www.census.gov/prod/2010pubs/p60-238.pdf. Whats more, the
population of uninsured is not confined to those with low incomes. The Census Bureau
found that the estimated income brackets for the uninsured are as follows:

(1) less than $25,000: 15.5 million uninsured, about 26.6% of the total
population in this income bracket;
(2) $25,000 to $49,999: 15.3 million, about 21.4%;
(3) $50,000 to $74,999: 9.4 million, about 16.0%;
(4) $75,000 or more: 10.6 million, about 9.1%.

Id.
211
to ameliorate twin problems related to the uninsured as a class: (1) huge cost

shifting from the uninsured, who often dont pay for their health care services, to

those with health insurance and to health care providers; and (2) the inability of

many uninsured individuals to obtain much-needed health insurance coverage

because they are effectively blacklisted on account of their pre-existing conditions

or medical histories. Congress sought to address these problems by requiring non-

exempted individuals to pay a penalty, or shared responsibility payment, on their

tax returns for any month, beginning in 2014, in which they fail to maintain

minimum essential coverage. 26 U.S.C. 5000A(a)-(b). And while remaining

uninsured is not an option under the Act (at least to avoid paying a penalty),

individuals are offered a variety of choices when it comes to satisfying the

individual mandates minimum essential coverage requirement. Many insurance

plans will satisfy the individual mandate. These plans fall into five general

categories, some of which are further divided into subcategories: (1) government-

sponsored programs; (2) eligible employer-sponsored plans; (3) plans purchased on

the individual market; (4) grandfathered health plans; or (5) any other coverage

recognized by the Secretary of Health and Human Services (HHS) in

coordination with the Secretary of the Treasury. Id. 5000A(f)(1).

As for the first problem Congress sought to address, it is undeniable that,

212
despite lacking health insurance, the uninsured are still substantial participants in

the market for health care services. And when the uninsured do seek medical care,

they often fail to pay all or even most of their costs. On average -- and these

figures are not disputed -- the uninsured pay only 37% of their health care costs out

of pocket, while third parties pay another 26% on their behalf.3 The remaining

costs are uncompensated -- they are borne by health care providers and are passed

on in the form of increased premiums to individuals who already participate in the

insurance market.

Congress findings reflect its determination that this problem -- the

uncompensated consumption of health care services by the uninsured -- has

national economic consequences that require a national solution through

comprehensive federal regulation. See 42 U.S.C. 18091. As part of the empirical

foundation for the individual mandate, Congress quantified the costs associated

with the free-riding and cost-shifting problems that result from the provision of

uncompensated health care to the uninsured:

3
These figures come from a study cited by both the plaintiffs and the government:
Families USA, Hidden Health Tax: Americans Pay a Premium 2 (2009) [hereinafter
Hidden Health Tax], available at http://familiesusa2.org/assets/pdfs/hidden-health-
tax.pdf. And again, the problem of uncompensated care is not confined to those of
limited means. Even in households at or above the median income, people without health
insurance pay, on average, less than half the cost of the medical care they consume. See
Bradley Herring, The Effect of the Availability of Charity Care to the Uninsured on the
Demand for Private Health Insurance, 24 J. Health Econ. 225, 229-31 (2005).
213
The cost of providing uncompensated care to the uninsured was
$43,000,000,000 [$43 billion] in 2008. To pay for this cost, health
care providers pass on the cost to private insurers, which pass on the
cost to families. This cost-shifting increases family premiums by on
average over $1,000 a year. By significantly reducing the number of
the uninsured, the [individual mandate], together with the other
provisions of this Act, will lower health insurance premiums.

Id. 18091(a)(2)(F) (emphases added).

The Act thus seeks to regulate the payment for health care consumption

through the mechanism of health insurance. As Congress found, the individual

mandate regulates activity that is commercial and economic in nature: economic

and financial decisions about how and when health care is paid for, and when

health insurance is purchased. Id. 18091(a)(2)(A) (emphasis added). In other

words, the individual mandate is the means Congress adopted to regulate the timing

and method of individuals payment for the consumption of health care services.

As for the second problem of millions of uninsured individuals being unable

to obtain health insurance, Congress sought to dramatically reform the health

insurance market by regulating the insurers themselves. The Act bars insurers from

using many of the tools they had previously employed to protect themselves against

the large costs imposed by high-risk individuals. Thus, insurers may no longer

deny coverage or charge higher premiums because of an individuals pre-existing

conditions or medical history. Id. 300gg(a)(1), 300gg-3(a), 300gg-4(a); Act


214
2702(a) (to be codified at 42 U.S.C. 300gg-1(a)). Under the community rating

provision, insurers may only vary premiums based on (i) whether the plan covers

an individual or a family, (ii) rating area, (iii) age, and (iv) tobacco use. 42 U.S.C.

300gg(a)(1). And under the guaranteed issue provisions, insurers must accept

every employer or individual who applies for coverage through the individual or

group markets. Act 2702(a) (to be codified at 42 U.S.C. 300gg-1(a)). Notably,

insurers may no longer offer plans that limit or exclude benefits for individuals

pre-existing conditions, 42 U.S.C. 300gg-3(a), nor may they refuse to cover

individuals on the basis of (i) health status, (ii) medical condition (including both

physical and mental illnesses), (iii) claims experience, (iv) receipt of health care,

(v) medical history, (vi) genetic information, (vii) evidence of insurability

(including conditions arising out of acts of domestic violence), (viii) disability, or

(ix) any other health status factor recognized by the Secretary of HHS, id. 300gg-

4(a).

Congress determined that the individual mandate was essential to the

effective implementation of the Acts insurer regulations -- that is, to creating

effective health insurance markets in which improved health insurance products

that are guaranteed issue and do not exclude coverage of pre-existing conditions

can be sold. Id. 18091(a)(2)(I). Congress further found that waiting until the

215
uninsured actually consume health care services before regulating them would

effectively be a day late and a dollar short. See id. ([I]f there were no [individual

mandate], many individuals would wait to purchase health insurance until they

needed care.); Liberty Univ., Inc. v. Geithner, 753 F. Supp. 2d 611, 634-35 (W.D.

Va. 2010) (As Congress stated in its findings, the individual coverage provision is

essential to th[e] larger regulatory scheme because without it, individuals would

postpone [acquiring] health insurance until they need substantial care, at which

point the Act would obligate insurers to cover them at the same cost as everyone

else. This would increase the cost of health insurance and decrease the number of

insured individuals -- precisely the harms that Congress sought to address . . . .);

Govt Br. at 19 (citing testimony before Congress that a health insurance market

could never survive or even form if people could buy their insurance on the way to

the hospital (internal quotation marks omitted)).

Congress also made findings supporting the proposition that the markets for

health insurance and health care services are deeply and inextricably bound

together and indicated clearly that it sought to regulate across them both. Congress

understood that health insurance and health care consumption are linked as a

factual matter. Health insurance is the means by which most of our national health

care costs are paid for; in 2009, private and government insurance financed

216
approximately 75% of health care spending. Govt Br. at 9 (citing non-disputed

data from the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services (CMS)). Moreover,

Congress expressly connected the increased participation in the health insurance

market that it expected to result from the individual mandate with increasing the

supply of, and demand for, health care services. 42 U.S.C. 18091(a)(2)(C). On

a more basic level, Congress also understood that [h]ealth insurance is not bought

for its own sake; it is bought to pay for medical expenses. Govt Br. at 39 (citing

M. Moshe Porat et al., Market Insurance Versus Self Insurance: The Tax-

Differential Treatment and Its Social Cost, 58 J. Risk & Ins. 657, 668 (1991);

Martin S. Feldstein, The Welfare Loss of Excess Health Insurance, 81 J. Pol. Econ.

251, 253 (1973) [hereinafter Welfare Loss] (Health insurance is purchased not as

a final consumption good but as a means of paying for the future stochastic

purchases of health services.)); see also Brief for Econ. Scholars as Amici Curiae

Supporting the Government (Govt Econ. Br.) at 12 (Medical care is the set of

services that make one healthier, or prevent deterioration in health. Health

insurance is a mechanism for spreading the costs of that medical care across people

or over time, from a period when the cost would be overwhelming to periods when

costs are more manageable.).

B.

217
1.

Congress commerce power to regulate is, as Chief Justice Marshall taught

us almost two hundred years ago, the power to prescribe the rule by which

commerce is to be governed. This power, like all others vested in Congress, is

complete in itself, may be exercised to its utmost extent, and acknowledges no

limitations, other than are prescribed in the constitution. Gibbons, 22 U.S. at 196.

It is precisely this power to prescribe rules governing commerce that Congress

lawfully exercised in enacting the individual mandate.

It is clear that Congress rule-making power extends to both the health

insurance and health care markets, areas of commerce that Congress has long

regulated and regulated heavily. First, the parties all agree (as they must) that

Congress commerce power lawfully extends to the regulation of insurance in

general, as the Supreme Court concluded more than 60 years ago in United States

v. South-Eastern Underwriters Assn, 322 U.S. 533, 552-53 (1944). Indeed,

Congress expressly relied on this proposition in enacting the individual mandate.

See 42 U.S.C. 18091(a)(3) (citing South-Eastern Underwriters as a basis for

Congress authority to regulate insurance under the Commerce Clause).4

4
In response to South-Eastern Underwriters, Congress enacted the McCarran-
Ferguson Act, which provides that state laws regulating insurance will not be
invalidate[d], impair[ed], or supersede[d] by federal law, unless the federal law
specifically relates to the business of insurance. 15 U.S.C. 1012(b). But this
218
Second, in light of Congress undeniable power under the Commerce Clause

to regulate the business of insurance generally, it follows -- and again there is no

dispute -- that Congress may also regulate health insurance in particular, which is,

after all, a subset of the insurance market. See Charles Fried, Written Testimony

Before the Senate Judiciary Committee Hearing on The Constitutionality of the

Affordable Care Act 1 (Feb. 2, 2011), available at

http://judiciary.senate.gov/pdf/11-02-02%20Fried%20Testimony.pdf. In fact,

Congress has extensively exercised its commerce power to regulate the health

insurance market for many years, long before the Act was passed. For example,

Congress enacted the Employee Retirement Income Security Act of 1974

(ERISA), Pub. L. No. 93-406, 88 Stat. 829 (1974), which is a massive piece of

legislation regulating the operation of employee benefit plans, including retirement

plans, pension plans, and employer-provided health insurance plans. Congress

enactment in no way affects or diminishes the Courts clear holding in South-Eastern


Underwriters that Congress may, concurrently with the states, regulate the business of
insurance under the Commerce Clause. Whats more, Congress has hardly abdicated its
role in regulating the insurance business. See Humana Inc. v. Forsyth, 525 U.S. 299, 311,
314 (1999) (holding that federal RICO statute -- which is itself grounded in the
Commerce Clause -- may be applied to insurers because it is not precluded by the
McCarran-Ferguson Act); id. at 308 (We reject any suggestion that Congress intended to
cede the field of insurance regulation to the States . . . .). Rather, the McCarran-
Ferguson Act sought to protect state regulation primarily against inadvertent federal
intrusion -- say, through enactment of a federal statute that describes an affected activity
in broad, general terms, of which the insurance business happens to constitute one part.
Barnett Bank of Marion Cnty., N.A. v. Nelson, 517 U.S. 25, 39 (1996).
219
expressly pegged the broad scope of ERISAs coverage to its Commerce Clause

power. 29 U.S.C. 1001(b) (It is hereby declared to be the policy of this chapter

to protect interstate commerce . . . .); see also id. 1003(a). Among other things,

the regulatory provisions in Title I of ERISA, 29 U.S.C. 1001 et seq., set forth

uniform minimum standards to ensure that employee benefit plans are established

and maintained in a fair and financially sound manner. U.S. Dept of Labor,

Health Benefits, Retirement Standards, and Workers Compensation: Employee

Benefit Plans, http://www.dol.gov/compliance/guide/erisa.htm (last visited Aug.

10, 2011). Title I of ERISA governs most private sector employee benefit plans,

with the most significant exceptions being plans established or maintained by

government entities or churches. Id.; see also Williams v. Wright, 927 F.2d 1540,

1545 (11th Cir. 1991) (concluding that ERISA regulates even plans covering only

a single employee).

Congressional efforts to regulate health insurance did not end with ERISA.

Congress passed the Consolidated Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1985

(COBRA), Pub. L. No. 99-272, 100 Stat. 82 (1986), which contains a wide

variety of provisions relating to health care and health insurance. As for health

insurance, the most significant reforms were amendments to ERISA, which added

continuation coverage provisions that allow employees to continue receiving

220
employer-sponsored health insurance for a period following the end of their

employment in order to prevent gaps in health insurance coverage. 29 U.S.C.

1161, 1162. And in the Health Insurance Portability and Accountability Act of

1996 (HIPAA), Pub. L. No. 104-191, 110 Stat. 1936 (1996), Congress amended

the Public Health Service Act to add insurance portability provisions that prohibit

group health plans -- including ERISA plans -- from discriminating against

individual participants and beneficiaries based on health status, that require

insurers to offer coverage to small businesses, and that limit pre-existing condition

exclusions. See 29 U.S.C. 1181-1183.

Under its commerce power, Congress has also repeatedly regulated the

content of private health insurers policies. See, e.g., Mental Health Parity Act of

1996, Pub. L. No. 104-204, 702, 110 Stat. 2874, 2944 (1996) (regulating limits

on mental health benefits); Newborns and Mothers Health Protection Act of 1996,

Pub. L. No. 104-204, 603, 110 Stat. 2874, 2935 (1996) (requiring maternity

coverage to provide at least a 48-hour hospital stay); Womens Health and Cancer

Rights Act of 1998, Pub. L. No. 105-277, 902, 112 Stat. 2681, 2681-436 (1998)

(requiring certain plans to offer benefits related to mastectomies); Paul Wellstone

and Pete Domenici Mental Health Parity and Addiction Equity Act of 2008, Pub. L.

No. 110-343, 512, 122 Stat. 3765, 3881 (2008) (providing for parity between

221
mental health/substance abuse disorder benefits and medical/surgical benefits).

Third, it is equally clear that Congress power under the Commerce Clause

likewise extends to the regulation of the provision and consumption of health care

services. Indeed, for many years, Congress has substantially regulated both health

care providers and the commodities that those providers may use. As far back as

1946, Congress enacted the Hospital Survey and Construction Act (also known as

the Hill-Burton Act), Pub. L. No. 79-725, 60 Stat. 1040 (1946), which

appropriated funds for the construction of new hospitals in the post-World War II

economy. The Hill-Burton Act required hospitals receiving federal construction or

renovation funds to provide care to all persons residing in the territorial area and

to provide a reasonable volume of free care to indigent patients. See 42 U.S.C.

291c(e).

The requirement that hospitals provide free care was strengthened and

broadened, when, as part of COBRA, Congress enacted the Emergency Medical

Treatment and Active Labor Act (EMTALA). COBRA, Pub. L. No. 99-272,

9121, 100 Stat. 82, 164 (1986). EMTALA requires all hospitals that receive

Medicare funds to screen and stabilize, if possible, any patient who comes in with

an emergency medical condition. 42 U.S.C. 1395dd(a)-(b); see also Roberts v.

Galen of Va., Inc., 525 U.S. 249, 250-51 (1999) (per curiam). EMTALA also

222
restricts the ability of hospitals to transfer a patient until he is stable or a medical

determination is made that transfer is necessary. 42 U.S.C. 1395dd(c).

EMTALAs provisions are backed by both civil fines and a private cause of action

for those harmed by a hospitals failure to comply. Id. 1395dd(d).

Congress has also regulated health care providers (and, as mentioned, health

care insurers) through HIPAA. The definition of health care provider under

HIPAA is extraordinarily broad, covering any person or organization who

furnishes, bills, or is paid for health care in the normal course of business. 45

C.F.R. 160.103. And in 2009, Congress expanded HIPAAs coverage even

further to include business associates of health care providers and health insurers.

See Health Information Technology for Economic and Clinical Health Act, Pub. L.

No. 111-5, 13401, 13404, 123 Stat. 115, 260, 264 (2009); 45 C.F.R. 160.103.

In addition to the insurance portability provisions, HIPAA includes a number of

privacy provisions that govern[] the use and disclosure of protected health

information by health care providers and health insurers, Sneed v. Pan Am. Hosp.,

370 F. Appx 47, 50 (11th Cir. 2010) (per curiam) (unpublished), as well as protect

the privacy of employees health information against inquiries by their employers.

HIPAA even regulates what information health care providers may communicate to

one another. See generally 45 C.F.R. 164.102-164.534; 42 U.S.C. 1320d-2.

223
HIPAA also requires health care providers to follow several administrative

requirements, including the development of physical and technical privacy

safeguards and employee training. See 45 C.F.R. 164.308, 164.310, 164.312.

Fourth, Congress has extensively regulated under its commerce power the

commodities used in the health care services market, most notably drugs and

medical devices. For example, in the Food, Drug, and Cosmetics Act, Congress

delegated to the Food and Drug Administration the authority to screen and approve

drugs and medical devices for use in commerce, and to regulate their continued use

once approved. See, e.g., 21 U.S.C. 351, 352, 355(a), 360c, 360e, 360j(e).

Fifth, the majority and all the parties also agree that Congress commerce

power extends to the regulation of the price to be paid for the consumption of

health care services. Medicare is the most pervasive example. Since 1983, the

Medicare program has set the fees it pays to hospitals through a prospective

payment system that assigns a fixed amount to each service provided rather than

reimbursing hospitals for their actual costs. See United States v. Whiteside, 285

F.3d 1345, 1346 (11th Cir. 2002). In 1989, Congress also set a federally

determined fee schedule for Medicare payments to physicians. Omnibus Budget

Reconciliation Act of 1989, Pub. L. No. 101-239, 6102, 103 Stat. 2106, 2169

(1989). In this way, Congress directly sets the prices for health care services paid

224
for under Medicare.5

Beyond Congress already substantial regulation of the price of health care

services through Medicare and Medicaid, under controlling precedent Congress

may lawfully regulate prices for all manner of health care consumption, however

wise or unwise that regulation may be. In fact, the Supreme Court has said that

Congress may regulate or even fix prices in interstate markets, either directly or by

engaging in the stimulation of commerce through regulation. Wickard v.

Filburn, 317 U.S. 111, 128 (1942) (It is well established . . . that the power to

regulate commerce includes the power to regulate the prices at which commodities

in that commerce are dealt in and practices affecting such prices.); accord

Gonzales v. Raich, 545 U.S. 1, 18-19 (2005); see also Sunshine Anthracite Coal

Co. v. Adkins, 310 U.S. 381, 394 (1940) (holding that Congress could not only

regulate price, but could also attach other conditions to the flow of a commodity

5
While Medicaid prices are not as directly regulated at the federal level, Congress
has legislated in a number of ways that affect the prices to be paid to health care providers
and others under the Medicaid program. Most notable is the Medicaid Drug Rebate
Program, created by the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1990. The program
provides that, if drug companies want their products to be covered by Medicaid, they
must provide detailed price information to, and enter into a national rebate agreement
with, the Secretary of HHS. 42 U.S.C. 1396r-8. Congress has thus regulated
prescription drug prices under Medicaid by requiring drug companies to provide
discounts to states -- in the form of rebates -- for their Medicaid drug purchases. See
generally Iowa Dept of Human Servs. v. Ctrs. for Medicare & Medicaid Servs., 576 F.3d
885, 886-87 (8th Cir. 2009).
225
in interstate [commerce]); id. (To regulate the price for . . . transactions is to

regulate commerce itself, and not alone its antecedent conditions or its ultimate

consequences. (quoting Carter v. Carter Coal Co., 298 U.S. 238, 326 (1936)

(Cardozo, J., dissenting in part and concurring in the judgment in part))).

Sixth, and perhaps most significantly, Congress commerce power includes

the power to prescribe rules cutting across the two linked markets of health

insurance and health care services. Both the congressional intent to link the two

and the empirical relation between the purchase of health insurance and the

consumption of health care services are clear. Accordingly, in determining

whether Congress has lawfully exercised its commerce power, courts must examine

the entire transaction, of which [the] contract [for insurance] is but a part, in order

to determine whether there may be a chain of events which becomes interstate

commerce. South-Eastern Underwriters, 322 U.S. at 547. I am hard pressed to

see how the relevant chain of events here does not include the substantial

consumption of health care services by the uninsured.

2.

The plaintiffs assert, nevertheless, that in enacting the individual mandate

Congress was limited to regulating a single industry at a single point in time -- in

other words, it could only look at the health insurance market standing alone. In

226
the plaintiffs view, Congress could not mandate the purchase of insurance as a

means of ameliorating a national problem arising in the related but distinct market

for health care services. The majority appears to have adopted this view,

concluding that the relevant conduct targeted by Congress is not the

uncompensated consumption of health care services by the uninsured, but rather

only the decision to forego health insurance. Maj. Op. at 126, 136. This approach

is wooden, formalistic, and myopic. The plaintiffs and the majority would view the

uninsured in a freeze-framed still, captured, like a photograph, in a single moment

in time. They contend that Congress cannot constitutionally regulate the uninsured

as a class at that single moment, because at that moment any particular uninsured

individual may be healthy, may be sitting in his living room, or may be doing

nothing at all. The only way the plaintiffs and the majority can round even the first

base of their argument against the mandate is by excluding from Congress

purview, for no principled reason that I can discern, the cost-shifting problems that

arise in the health care services market.

This blinkered approach cannot readily be squared with the well-settled

principle that, in reviewing whether Congress has acted within its enumerated

powers, courts must look at the nature of the problem Congress sought to address,

based on economic and practical realities. See Swift & Co., 196 U.S. at 398

227
([C]ommerce among the states is not a technical legal conception, but a practical

one, drawn from the course of business.); Wickard, 317 U.S. at 123-24

([R]ecognition of the relevance of the economic effects in the application of the

Commerce Clause . . . has made the mechanical application of legal formulas no

longer feasible.); NLRB v. Jones & Laughlin Steel Corp., 301 U.S. 1, 41-42

(1937) (observing that interstate commerce itself is a practical conception); N.

Am. Co. v. SEC, 327 U.S. 686, 705 (1946) (Congress is not bound by technical

legal conceptions. Commerce itself is an intensely practical matter. To deal with it

effectively, Congress must be able to act in terms of economic and financial

realities. (citation omitted)); Lopez, 514 U.S. at 571, 574 (Kennedy, J.,

concurring) (favoring a pragmatic approach to Congress commerce power

grounded in broad principles of economic practicality and a practical conception

of commercial regulation); Raich, 545 U.S. at 25 n.35. When the individual

mandate is viewed through a more pragmatic and less stilted lens, it is clear that

Congress has addressed a substantial economic problem: the uninsured get sick or

injured, seek health care services they cannot afford, and shift these unpaid costs

onto others.

Moreover, despite their contention that Congress is limited to regulating in a

single industry, the plaintiffs nevertheless concede that Congress may use its rule-

228
making power to regulate the market for health insurance as a vehicle or means to

address the cost-shifting problems arising in the market for health care services.

They have conceded, both in their briefs and at oral argument, that Congress may

constitutionally regulate the consumption of health care services by the uninsured

at the time they actually seek medical care. The plaintiffs acknowledge -- as does

the majority -- that Congress may constitutionally require the uninsured to obtain

health care insurance on the hospital doorstep, or that Congress may otherwise

impose a penalty on those who attempt to consume health care services without

insurance. States Br. at 31-32 (Supreme Court precedent allows Congress to

regulate [the practice of consuming health care services without insurance] -- for

example, by imposing restrictions or penalties on individuals who attempt to

consume health care services without insurance.); Maj. Op. at 129-30 ([W]hen

the uninsured actually enter the stream of commerce and consume health care,

Congress may regulate their activity at the point of consumption.); see also

Florida ex rel. Bondi v. U.S. Dept of Health & Human Servs., No. 3:10-cv-91-

RV/EMT, 2011 WL 285683, at *26 (N.D. Fla. Jan. 31, 2011) (Congress plainly

has the power to regulate [the uninsured] . . . at the time that they initially seek

229
medical care[], a fact with which the plaintiffs agree.).6 Thus, all of the parties

agree that, at the time of health care consumption, Congress may lawfully cut

across a distinct market and impose a financial penalty designed to compel the

uninsured to obtain health insurance. And Congress may do so even where the

uninsured would otherwise voluntarily choose to finance the consumption of health

care services out of pocket, without buying insurance.

If the plaintiffs had argued that Congress cannot constitutionally force

anyone to buy health insurance at any time as a means of paying for health care,

they at least would have evinced the virtue of consistency. But instead, the

plaintiffs concession undermines their claim that Congress has exceeded its rule-

making power by regulating in one industry to address a problem found in another,

at least where the two industries are so closely bound together. After all, even at

the point of consuming health care services, individuals may wish to remain

inactive in the health insurance market. But the plaintiffs and the majority

6
At oral argument, counsel for the state plaintiffs was explicitly asked whether, at
the point of health care consumption, Congress could compel an individual who doesnt
have health insurance to either pay a penalty or obtain insurance at that time, to which
counsel responded that [i]n the health care market, at the time of consumption, yes.
And at the district court hearing on the governments motion to dismiss, counsel for the
plaintiffs made a similar concession. In response to the district courts question, Well,
the government could impose this penalty at the point of service at the doctors office or
the hospital and say, if you do not have insurance, you are subject to a penalty?, counsel
for the plaintiffs responded, I believe the government would be able to do it, Your
Honor. RE 334-35.
230
concede that Congress may nevertheless compel individuals at that point to

purchase a private insurance product.

Despite this concession, the plaintiffs contend that the regulation of

commerce necessarily presupposes a pre-existing voluntary activity to be regulated.

The plaintiffs activity/inactivity dichotomy, however, is nowhere to be found in

the text of the Commerce Clause, nor in the jurisprudence surrounding it. The

language of the Commerce Clause itself draws no distinction between activity and

inactivity. The seven operative words speak broadly about Congress power [t]o

regulate Commerce . . . among the several States. U.S. Const. art. I, 8, cl. 3.

The power to regulate is the power to prescribe the rule by which commerce is to

be governed. Gibbons, 22 U.S. at 196. And while the power of Congress is

limited to specific objects, it is plenary as to those objects. Id. at 197. Creating

an artificial doctrinal distinction between activity and inactivity is thus novel and

unprecedented, resembling the categorical limits on Congress commerce power

the Supreme Court swept away long ago.

The plaintiffs claim, nevertheless, that the individual mandate exceeds

Congress commerce power because it improperly conscripts uninsured individuals

-- who are presently inactive in the health insurance market -- to unwillingly enter

the stream of commerce to purchase health insurance they would not otherwise

231
choose to buy. The plaintiffs and the majority would have Congress wait at the

waters edge until the uninsured literally enter the emergency room. In other

words, they say, Congress may not legislate prophylactically, but instead must wait

until the cost-shifting problem has boiled over, causing huge increases in costs for

those who have health care insurance (through increased premiums), and for those

who provide health care services.

At bottom, the plaintiffs argument seems to boil down only to a temporal

question: can Congress, under the Commerce Clause, regulate how and when

health care services are paid for by requiring individuals -- virtually all of whom

will consume health care services and most of whom have done so already -- to pay

now for those services through the mechanism of health insurance? As I see it, the

answer to whether Congress can make this temporal jump under its Commerce

Clause power is yes.

There is no doctrinal basis for requiring Congress to wait until the cost-

shifting problem materializes for each uninsured person before it may regulate the

uninsured as a class. The majoritys imposition of a strict temporal requirement

that congressional regulation only apply to individuals who first engage in specific

market transactions in the health care services market is at war with the idea that

Congress may adopt reasonable preventive measures to avoid future disruptions

232
of interstate commerce. Consol. Edison Co. v. NLRB, 305 U.S. 197, 222 (1938)

([I]t cannot be maintained that the exertion of federal power must await the

disruption of [interstate or foreign] commerce.); see also Katzenbach v. McClung,

379 U.S. 294, 301 (1964) (quoting same, and noting that Congress was not

required to await the total dislocation of commerce); Stevens v. United States, 440

F.2d 144, 152 (6th Cir. 1971) (It is not necessary for Congress to await the total

dislocation of commerce before it may provide reasonable preventive measures for

the protection of commerce. (citing Katzenbach, 379 U.S. at 301)), limited on

other grounds by United States v. Bass, 404 U.S. 336 (1971); NLRB v. Sunshine

Mining Co., 110 F.2d 780, 784 (9th Cir. 1940). In Consolidated Edison, the

Supreme Court explained that, through the National Labor Relations Act -- which

regulates labor practices -- Congress did not attempt to deal with particular

instances in which interstate commerce was disrupted, concluding that Congress

did not need to wait until labor practices actually disrupted interstate commerce

before it could regulate.7 305 U.S. at 222. In other words, Congress may lawfully

7
The majority opinion misapprehends this point. See Maj. Op. at 129 n.100.
Consolidated Edison is cited along with Katzenbach to make this simple point: Congress
need not wait until an economic problem has erupted and the national economy is
disrupted before it may act prophylactically, under its commerce power, to address an
obvious and apparent economic problem. That Consolidated Edison specifically involved
the regulation of labor practices or that Katzenbach (along with Heart of Atlanta)
specifically involved the regulation of innkeepers and restaurateurs is beside the point.
This principle of Commerce Clause jurisprudence is general, and it remains binding law.
233
regulate present conduct to prevent future disruptions of interstate commerce from

occurring.

Whats more, and even more basic, here the disruption of interstate

commerce is already occurring. The majority inexplicably claims that the

individual mandate regulates the mere possibility of future activity, Maj. Op. at

129, but as we speak, the uninsured are consuming health care services in large

numbers and shifting costs onto others. By ignoring the close relationship between

the health insurance and health care services markets, the plaintiffs and the

majority seek to avoid the hard fact that the uninsured as a class are actively

consuming substantial quantities of health care services now -- not just next week,

next month, or next year. The uninsured make more than 20 million visits to

emergency rooms each year; 68% of the uninsured had routine checkups in the past

five years; and 50% had one in the past two years.8 See U.S. Dept of HHS, New

Data Say Uninsured Account for Nearly One-Fifth of Emergency Room Visits

(July 15, 2009), available at

http://www.hhs.gov/news/press/2009pres/07/20090715b.html; June E. ONeill &

8
The plaintiffs do not contest the validity of these data. Indeed, at oral argument,
counsel for the state plaintiffs conceded that these visits to the emergency room constitute
economic activity that Congress may lawfully regulate.
234
Dave M. ONeill, Empt Policies Inst., Who Are the Uninsured? An Analysis of

Americas Uninsured Population, Their Characteristics and Their Health 20-21 &

tbl.9 (2009), available at http://epionline.org/studies/oneill_06-2009.pdf; see also

Hidden Health Tax, supra, at 2 (observing that the uninsured consumed $116

billion worth of health care services in 2008); Govt Econ. Br. at 10 (57 percent of

the 40 million people uninsured in all of 2007 used medical services that year.

(emphasis added)); NFIB Br. at 5 (citing same 57% statistic). In addition, there

were more than two million hospitalizations -- not just emergency room visits, but

actual admissions to a hospital -- of the uninsured in 2008 alone. U.S. Dept of

HHS, ASPE Research Brief, The Value of Health Insurance: Few of the Uninsured

Have Adequate Resources To Pay Potential Hospital Bills 5 (2011), available at

http://aspe.hhs.gov/health/reports/2011/valueofinsurance/rb.pdf.

In light of these undisputed figures, there can be little question that

substantial numbers of uninsured Americans are currently active participants in the

health care services market, and that many of these uninsured currently consume

health care services for which they cannot or do not pay. This is, in every real and

meaningful sense, classic economic activity, which, as Congress findings tell us,

has a profound effect on commerce. See Thomas More Law Ctr. v. Obama, -- F.3d

--, 2011 WL 2556039, at *24 (6th Cir. June 29, 2011) (Sutton, J., concurring) (No

235
matter how you slice the relevant market -- as obtaining health care, as paying for

health care, as insuring for health care -- all of these activities affect interstate

commerce, in a substantial way.).9 Once the artificial barrier drawn between the

health insurance and health care services markets breaks down, the plaintiffs

inactivity argument collapses. And there can be no doubt that Congress rationally

linked the two markets. Its very findings accompanying the mandate detail at

length the impact that going uninsured has on the broader availability of health

insurance and on the costs associated with the consumption of health care services.

See 42 U.S.C. 18091(a)(2). I observe again that [h]ealth insurance is purchased

not as a final consumption good but as a means of paying for the future stochastic

purchase of health care services. Welfare Loss, supra, at 253. And virtually all of

us will have the misfortune of having to consume health care services at some

unknown point for some unknown malady and at some uncertain price. Each of us

remains susceptible to sudden and unpredictable injury. No one can opt out of

illness, disability, and death. These, we all must accept, are facts of life. Thus,

9
Contrary to the majoritys assertion, see Maj. Op. at 147 n.119, the conduct
being regulated by Congress is the consumption of health care services by the uninsured.
And it is the very act of consuming health care services by those who do not pay for them
that has the natural and probable effect of shifting costs to those who do -- what occurs
when I consume a good, and leave you with the bill. In every real sense, the conduct
being regulated is analytically and conceptually distinct from its effects on interstate
commerce.
236
even if I were to accept the plaintiffs distinction between activity and inactivity,

the facts undermine the distinction here. The inevitable consumption of health care

services by the uninsured is sufficient activity to subject them to congressional

regulation.

3.

The plaintiffs and the majority also object to the mandate on different

grounds -- that it is overinclusive insofar as it applies to: those who do not enter

the health care market at all (non-consumers), and those who consume health

care services but pay for their services in full and thus do not shift costs (non-cost-

shifters). Maj. Op. at 127.

The majority understates the point when it acknowledges that

overinclusiveness may not be fatal for constitutional purposes. Id. Indeed, the

Supreme Court has made it abundantly clear that Congress is not required to

legislate with scientific exactitude. Raich, 545 U.S. at 17. Rather, [w]hen

Congress decides that the total incidence of a practice poses a threat to a national

market, it may regulate the entire class. Id. (emphases added) (internal quotation

marks omitted). As Justice Holmes put it in Westfall v. United States, 274 U.S.

256 (1927), when it is necessary in order to prevent an evil to make the law

embrace more than the precise thing to be prevented [Congress] may do so. Id. at

237
259. There is simply no requirement under the Commerce Clause that Congress

choose the least restrictive means at its disposal to accomplish its legitimate

objectives. Nor is there a requirement that Congress target only those uninsured

individuals who will consume health care services at a particular point in time or

just those who will be unable to pay for the health care services they consume.

Congress concluded that the total incidence of health care consumption by the

uninsured threatened the national health insurance and health care services

markets. It was free to regulate the entire class of the uninsured.10

Moreover, even if I were to accept the notion that Congress, in regulating

commerce, was obliged to somehow draw the class more narrowly, the subclass of

10
The Court in Raich specifically approved of Congress legislating across a
broad class when enforcement difficulties would attend drawing the class more
narrowly. Raich, 545 U.S. at 22. The Court said, [g]iven the enforcement difficulties
that attend distinguishing between marijuana cultivated locally and marijuana grown
elsewhere, and concerns about diversion into illicit channels, we have no difficulty
concluding that Congress had a rational basis for believing that failure to regulate the
intrastate manufacture and possession of marijuana would leave a gaping hole in the
CSA. Id. (citation and footnote omitted). When it may be difficult to distinguish
between categories of conduct, especially when the categories are fluid, Congress may
enlarge the regulated class. Here, too, Congress may broadly regulate uninsured
individuals because it may be difficult to distinguish between cost-shifters and non-cost-
shifters. And the categories are fluid -- a non-consumer or non-cost-shifter today may
become a cost-shifter tomorrow, especially if a catastrophic injury befalls him.
Moreover, the majority concedes that Congress may regulate all of the uninsured -- cost-
shifters and non-cost-shifters alike -- at the point of consumption. See Maj. Op. at 129-
30. Thus, by the majoritys own lights, Congress inclusion of non-cost-shifters within
the mandates reach does not create a constitutional infirmity.
238
non-consumers -- those individuals who will never enter the health care services

market at all -- is surely minuscule. The plaintiffs emphasize that it is not strictly

true that everyone will participate in the health care services market. States Br. at

30. But the only elaboration the plaintiffs offer on this point is that some

individuals will not participate because of religious scruples or the vaguely-put

individual circumstances. Id. As for the first, it does not get the plaintiffs very

far, because religious groups that opt out of the health care services or health

insurance markets may also seek exemption from the individual mandate. 26

U.S.C. 5000A(d)(2). And as for individual circumstances, presumably what

the plaintiffs mean is that a few individuals either will fortuitously avoid ill health

altogether, or -- more likely -- will fail to consume health care services due to an

immediately fatal accident or the like. I am unable to draw a relevant constitutional

distinction between the virtual inevitability of health care consumption and the

absolute, 100% inevitability of health care consumption. There is less of a chance

that an individual will go through his entire life without ever consuming health care

services than there is that he will win the Irish Sweepstakes at the very moment he

is struck by lightning. Nor are there more than a minuscule number of Americans

who could afford to take on the financial risk of a personal medical catastrophe out

of their own pockets. Yet, on the basis of these slight mathematical possibilities

239
would the majority bring down the individual mandate and all that may fall with it.

Congress has wide regulatory latitude to address the extent of financial risk-

taking in the health care services market, Govt Reply Br. at 15, which in its view

is a threat to a national market, Raich, 545 U.S. at 17. The fact that an

exceedingly small set of individuals may go their whole lives without consuming

health care services or can afford to go it alone poses no obstacle to Congress

ability under the Commerce Clause to regulate the uninsured as a class.

Similarly, a group of economists who filed an amicus brief in support of the

plaintiffs object to the individual mandate by disputing the substantiality of the

cost-shifting impact the mandate seeks to address. First, they claim that the

individual mandate targets the young and healthy and that the annual costs of

uncompensated care for those individuals is much less than $43 billion. See Brief

for Economists as Amici Curiae Supporting the Plaintiffs (Plaintiffs Econ. Br.) at

3, 10, 13. The point is unpersuasive, because it conflates the scope of the

individual mandate with its relative benefits for different population groups. The

individual mandate applies to all non-exempted individuals, 26 U.S.C. 5000A(a),

and while the young and healthy may benefit less than other groups from having

health insurance, [i]t is of the essence of regulation that it lays a restraining hand

on the selfinterest of the regulated and that advantages from the regulation

240
commonly fall to others, Wickard, 317 U.S. at 129. Balancing different groups

competing economic interests is not a constitutional concern for the courts to

calibrate, but rather is wisely left under our system to resolution by the Congress

under its more flexible and responsible legislative process. Id. Moreover, the

argument that the mandate targets the young and healthy and that, therefore, this

Court should only look at the economic impact on interstate commerce of those

individuals is not even consistent with the plaintiffs own suggestion that the

individual mandate regulates everyone at every moment of their lives, from cradle

to grave. States Br. at 29.

The economists also suggest that even if we look at the $43 billion figure as

a whole, that amount is less than 1.8% of overall annual health care spending

(which Congress found was $2.5 trillion, or 17.6% of the national economy, in

2009, 42 U.S.C. 18091(a)(2)(B)), and, therefore, the alleged cost-shifting

problem is relatively modest and fails to justify the individual mandate. Plaintiffs

Econ. Br. at 9-10. The argument is unconvincing. It would be novel indeed to

examine whether a problem substantially affects interstate commerce by

comparing the economic impact of the problem to the total size of the regulated

market. The argument would also lead to the perverse conclusion that Congress

has less regulatory power the larger the national market at issue. But in any event,

241
there can be no doubt that $43 billion is a substantial amount by any accounting.

Even the economists (as well as the district court) recognize that the amount is not

insignificant. Plaintiffs Econ. Br. at 10; accord Florida, 2011 WL 285683, at *26

(noting that $43 billion is clearly a large amount of money). In this connection, I

am reminded of the comment often attributed to the late Illinois Senator Everett

McKinley Dirksen: A billion here, a billion there, and pretty soon youre talking

about real money.

Relying heavily on the economists brief, the majority goes even further and

subjects Congress findings to an analysis that looks startlingly like strict scrutiny

review. The majority engages in a breakdown of who among the uninsured are

responsible for the $43 billion, presumably in order to show that the mandate will

not be the most efficacious means of ameliorating the cost-shifting problem. See

Maj. Op. at 139-41. For instance, the majority claims that low-income individuals

and illegal aliens (or other nonresidents) together are responsible for around half of

the total cost shifting, yet are exempted from either the mandate or its penalty. Id.

at 139-40. But even on the majoritys own terms, a substantial number of cost-

shifters are not exempted from the mandate or its penalty, and there was nothing

irrational about Congress decision to subject to the mandate those individuals who

could reasonably afford health insurance in the first place.

242
More fundamentally, however, as I see it, the majoritys searching inquiry

throughout its opinion into whether the individual mandate fully solves the

problems Congress aimed to solve, or whether there may have been more

efficacious ways to do so, probes far beyond the proper scope of a courts

Commerce Clause review. The majority suggests any number of changes to the

legislation that would, it claims, improve it. Thus, for example, the majority offers

that Congress should have legislated with a finer scalpel by inserting some element

in the statute calling for a case-by-case inquiry of each regulated individuals

conduct. Id. at 128 (internal quotation marks omitted). And the majority would

have the IRS enforce the mandate more aggressively. See id. at 166; id. at 202

(describing the mandate as porous and toothless).

Quite simply, the majority would presume to sit as a superlegislature,

offering ways in which Congress could have legislated more efficaciously or more

narrowly. This approach ignores the wide regulatory latitude afforded to Congress,

under its Commerce Clause power, to address what in its view are substantial

problems, and it misapprehends the role of a reviewing court. As nonelected

judicial officers, we are not afforded the opportunity to rewrite statutes we dont

like, or to craft a legislative response more sharply than the legislative branch of

government has chosen. What we are obliged to do is to determine whether the

243
congressional enactment falls within the boundaries of Art. 1, 8, cl. 3. In

examining the constitutionality of legislation grounded in Congress commerce

power, [w]e need not determine whether [the regulated] activities, taken in the

aggregate, substantially affect interstate commerce in fact. Raich, 545 U.S. at 22

(emphasis added). Rather, all we need to do -- indeed, all we are permitted to do --

is determine whether a rational basis exists for so concluding. Id. The courts

are not called upon to judge the wisdom or efficacy of the challenged statutory

scheme. See, e.g., id. at 9 (The question before us, however, is not whether it is

wise to enforce the statute in these circumstances.); Wickard, 317 U.S. at 129

(And with the wisdom, workability, or fairness[] of the plan of regulation we have

nothing to do.). As Justice Cardozo put it, [w]hether wisdom or unwisdom

resides in the scheme of [the statute at issue], it is not for us to say. The answer to

such inquiries must come from Congress, not the courts. Helvering v. Davis, 301

U.S. 619, 644 (1937); see also Thomas More Law Ctr., 2011 WL 2556039, at *33

(Sutton, J., concurring) (Time assuredly will bring to light the policy strengths and

weaknesses of using the individual mandate as part of this national legislation,

allowing the peoples political representatives, rather than their judges, to have the

primary say over its utility. (emphasis added)).

The majority says, nevertheless, that we are compelled to approach the

244
individual mandate with caution and with greater cause for doubt, Maj. Op. at

152, because insurance and health care are areas of traditional state concern, id.

at 150. While it is true that insurance and health care are, generally speaking, areas

of traditional state regulation, this observation in no way undermines Congress

commerce power to regulate concurrently in these areas. The sheer size of the

programs Congress has created underscores the extensiveness of its regulation of

the health insurance and health care industries. In 2010, 47.5 million people were

covered by Medicare . . . . 2011 Annual Report of the Boards of Trustees of the

Federal Hospital Insurance and Federal Supplementary Medical Insurance Trust

Funds 4 (2011), available at http://www.cms.gov/ReportsTrustFunds/downloads/

tr2011.pdf. Medicaid is similarly massive. As of December 2008, approximately

44.8 million people were covered by Medicaid. The Kaiser Commission on

Medicaid and the Uninsured, Medicaid Enrollment in 50 States 1 (2010), available

at http://www.kff.org/medicaid/upload/7606-05.pdf. And as the government points

out, Medicare and Medicaid accounted for roughly $750 billion of federal spending

in 2009 alone. Govt Br. at 10. It would surely come as a great shock to Congress,

or, for that matter, to the 47.5 million people covered by Medicare, the 44.8 million

people covered by Medicaid, and the overwhelming number of employers, health

insurers, and health care providers regulated by ERISA, COBRA, and HIPAA, to

245
learn that, because the health care industry also falls within the sphere of

traditional state regulation, Maj. Op. at 153, Congress was somehow skating on

thin constitutional ice when it enacted these laws.

4.

In the course of its opinion, the majority also attaches great significance to

the unprecedented nature of the legislation before us. It is surely true that, as the

district court concluded, the individual mandate is a novel exercise of Congress

Commerce Clause power. Florida, 2011 WL 285683, at *20-21. But the mere fact

of its novelty does not yield its unconstitutionality. See Garcia v. Vanguard Car

Rental USA, Inc., 540 F.3d 1242, 1252 (11th Cir. 2008) (upholding, under the

Commerce and Necessary and Proper Clauses, the constitutionality of the Graves

Amendment, 49 U.S.C. 30106, even though it was a novel statute employing

the relatively novel theory that the rental car market should be protected by

deregulating it). Every new proposal is in some way unprecedented before it is

tried. And to draw the line against any new congressional enactment simply

because of its novelty ignores the lessons found in the Supreme Courts Commerce

Clause cases. For example, in Wickard the Court squarely recognized that the case

presented an unprecedented expansion of the Commerce Clause power before then

embracing that expansion. 317 U.S. at 120 (Even today, when this power has

246
been held to have great latitude, there is no decision of this Court that such

activities [local activities such as production, manufacturing, and mining] may be

regulated where no part of the product is intended for interstate commerce or

intermingled with the subjects thereof.). The truth is that any ruling this Court

issues on the individual mandates constitutionality is necessarily a departure from

existing case law because the legislation and the issues presented are new. That the

Supreme Court has never before upheld a regulation of this kind can hardly be

decisive; it has never rejected one either.

Indeed, when measured against the kinds of sweeping changes we have seen

in the past, the individual mandate is far from a cataclysmic expansion of

Congress commerce power. Even the briefest examination of the growth of

Congress commerce power over the past 75 years makes the point. Facing the

practical realities of an emergent, highly integrated national economy, the Supreme

Court abandoned the categorical and formalistic distinctions that it had erected

initially, in favor of a pragmatic view of commerce drawn from the course of

business. The Court had previously held that broad categories of economic life,

such as agriculture, insurance, labor, manufacturing, mining, and production were

antecedent to commerce itself, which was once viewed as being limited to the

movement of the fruits of those antecedent activities in and among the states. But a

247
more pragmatic view began to take hold by the mid-1930s. The Courts earlier

restrictive view of commerce did not survive the New Deal-era cases, where the

Supreme Court swiftly brought all of these categories within the lawful ambit of

Congress commerce power. See, e.g., Jones & Laughlin Steel, 301 U.S. at 40 (It

is thus apparent that the fact that the employees here concerned were engaged in

production is not determinative. The question remains as to the effect upon

interstate commerce of the labor practice involved.); United States v. Darby, 312

U.S. 100, 115-17 (1941) ([W]e conclude that the prohibition of the shipment

interstate of goods produced under the forbidden substandard labor conditions is

within the constitutional authority of Congress.); Wickard, 317 U.S. at 124-25

(Whether the subject of the regulation in question was production,

consumption, or marketing [of wheat] is . . . not material for purposes of

deciding the question of federal power before us. . . . [E]ven if appellees activity

be local and though it may not be regarded as commerce, it may still, whatever its

nature, be reached by Congress if it exerts a substantial economic effect on

interstate commerce . . . .); South-Eastern Underwriters, 322 U.S. at 553 (No

commercial enterprise of any kind which conducts its activities across state lines

has been held to be wholly beyond the regulatory power of Congress under the

Commerce Clause. We cannot make an exception of the business of insurance.).

248
The Court did not stop there. It expanded the scope of Congress commerce

power from the regulation of the intercourse of goods moving across borders to

the regulation of wholly intrastate conduct that substantially affected interstate

commerce. See Darby, 312 U.S. at 119-20 & n.3. Indeed, Wickard involved a

jump arguably far greater than the one we face today. In order to regulate price,

Congress could penalize conduct -- Filburns growing wheat above a fixed quota

for his own personal consumption -- absent any indicia that Filburn would ever

enter into the interstate wheat market. Justice Jackson, writing for the Court,

recognized this as a novel exercise of the commerce power. Wickard, 317 U.S. at

120. The Court held that Congress could nonetheless regulate the price of wheat

by restricting its production, even on a small farm where it was grown purely for

personal consumption. And, according to the Court, if the regulation had the

natural and probable effect of forcing some farmers into the market to buy what

they could provide for themselves absent the regulation, so be it. Id. at 129

(emphasis added).

In Wickard, the Court expanded Congress commerce power further still,

concluding that the impact or effect on interstate commerce is not measured case by

case, or person by person, but rather in an aggregated way. Id. at 127-28. That

Filburns own contribution to the demand for wheat may be trivial by itself is not

249
enough to remove him from the scope of federal regulation where, as here, his

contribution, taken together with that of many others similarly situated, is far from

trivial. Id. (emphasis added); see also Darby, 312 U.S. at 123 ([Congress]

recognized that in present day industry, competition by a small part may affect the

whole and that the total effect of the competition of many small producers may be

great.); NLRB v. Fainblatt, 306 U.S. 601, 606 (1939) (The power of Congress to

regulate interstate commerce is plenary and extends to all such commerce be it

great or small.). Building upon earlier inklings of an aggregation principle found

in Darby and Fainblatt, the Court firmly established that Congress may regulate

classes of local activities that, only in the aggregate, have a substantial effect on

interstate commerce.11

In a pair of notable civil rights cases, Heart of Atlanta Motel, Inc. v. United

States, 379 U.S. 241 (1964), and Katzenbach, 379 U.S. 294, the Supreme Court

continued to read the Commerce Clause in an expansive way. The Court upheld

nondiscrimination legislation, grounded in the Commerce Clause, that required

11
The majority attempts to skirt the breadth of the aggregation principle by
claiming that an individuals mere decision not to purchase insurance is not subject to
aggregation. Maj. Op. at 125. But again, the majority has shot at the wrong target.
Congress is regulating the uninsureds uncompensated consumption of health care
services. And under Wickard and Raich, we are instructed to measure the effect on
interstate commerce not case-by-case or person-by-person, but rather in the aggregate and
taken as a whole.
250
hoteliers and restaurateurs to enter into economic transactions with racial

minorities (indeed, with individuals of any race, color, religion, or national origin)

on the same terms as any other patrons (or exit their respective businesses

altogether). The Court underscored that the power of Congress to promote

interstate commerce also includes the power to regulate the local incidents thereof,

including local activities in both the States of origin and destination, which might

have a substantial and harmful effect upon that commerce. Heart of Atlanta, 379

U.S. at 258. The Court concluded that, having entered the stream of commerce,

these sellers could be forced by Congress to engage in economic transactions into

which they would not otherwise enter.

The plaintiffs are quick to point out, however, that the Commerce Clause has

not simply expanded unabated. In rejecting the constitutionality of the individual

mandate, the plaintiffs and the majority rely heavily upon Lopez, 514 U.S. 549, and

United States v. Morrison, 529 U.S. 598 (2000), the only two Supreme Court cases

in the past 75 years to hold that an act of Congress exceeded its commerce power.

Neither Lopez, where the Court struck down a statute criminalizing the possession

of a firearm within 1000 feet of a school, nor Morrison, where the Court struck

down a statute creating a federal civil remedy for victims of gender-motivated

felonious acts of violence, answers the question we face today.

251
Indeed, in Raich, 545 U.S. 1, decided five years after Morrison, the Supreme

Court reaffirmed the vitality of Wickard, and specifically applied its holding in a

challenge to the constitutionality of the Controlled Substances Act (CSA). The

Court emphatically distinguished Lopez and Morrison, observing that the statutes

at issue in those cases were singular prohibitions regulating wholly noneconomic

criminal behavior. The CSA, on the other hand, was characterized as a lengthy

and detailed statute creating a comprehensive framework for regulating the

production, distribution, and possession of five classes of controlled substances.

Raich, 545 U.S. at 24. The Court found that, [u]nlike those at issue in Lopez and

Morrison, the activities regulated by the CSA are quintessentially economic. Id.

at 25.

Thus, much as in Raich, while Lopez and Morrison remind us that there are

discernible limits on Congress commerce power, the limits drawn in those two

cases are of limited help in this one. As a panel of this Circuit recently stated,

Raich makes clear that when a statute regulates economic or commercial activity,

Lopez and Morrison are inapposite. Garcia, 540 F.3d at 1252. Indeed, when we

are not . . . dealing with a single-subject statute whose single subject is itself

non-economic (e.g., possession of a gun in a school zone or gender-motivated

violence), Morrison and Lopez have little applicability and instead Raich guides

252
our analysis. United States v. Maxwell (Maxwell II), 446 F.3d 1210, 1216 n.6

(11th Cir. 2006); see also United States v. Paige, 604 F.3d 1268, 1273 (11th Cir.

2010) (per curiam). Lopez and Morrison each involved an effort to regulate

noneconomic activity (criminal conduct); in neither instance did Congress seek to

broadly regulate an entire industry; and, unlike in this case, the criminal conduct

regulated in those cases was only linked to interstate commerce in a highly

attenuated fashion that required piling inference upon inference. Whatever

problems there may be with the constitutionality of the individual mandate, they

cannot be found in Lopez or Morrison. See Part II.A, infra.

The historical growth of Congress commerce power powerfully suggests

that, contrary to the arguments advanced by the plaintiffs, upholding the individual

mandate would be far from a cosmic expansion of the boundaries of the Commerce

Clause. These past expansions have not been random, accidental, or in any way

contrary to first principles or an original understanding of the Constitution. As the

Supreme Court has observed, [t]he Federal Government undertakes activities

today that would have been unimaginable to the Framers. United States v.

Comstock, -- U.S. --, 130 S. Ct. 1949, 1965 (2010) (quoting New York v. United

States, 505 U.S. 144, 157 (1992)). Indeed, the Framers purposely drafted a

Constitution capable of such resilience through time. Id.; see also McCulloch v.

253
Maryland, 17 U.S. (4 Wheat.) 316, 415 (1819) (describing the Constitution as a

document intended to endure for ages to come, and consequently, to be adapted to

the various crises of human affairs).

The long and short of it is that Congress has promulgated a rule (the

individual mandate) by which to comprehensively regulate the timing and means of

payment for the virtually inevitable consumption of health care services, and to

thereby regulate commerce. The individual mandate was enacted as part of a broad

scheme to regulate health insurance and health care services, industries already

heavily regulated by Congress. Congress made express legislative findings

detailing the economic problems it saw, and how the mandate would ameliorate

those problems. And the substantial impact on interstate commerce cannot be

denied. Article 1, 8, cl. 3 requires no more than this.

C.

The individual mandate is also a valid means under the Necessary and Proper

Clause to further the regulatory end of the Acts insurance reforms. It has been long

recognized that Congress has the power to pass laws or regulations necessary and

proper to carrying out [its] commerce clause power. United States v. Ambert, 561

F.3d 1202, 1211 (11th Cir. 2009). Under the Necessary and Proper Clause, Congress

is empowered [t]o make all Laws which shall be necessary and proper for carrying

254
into Execution the foregoing [Art. 1, 8] Powers. U.S. Const. art. 1, 8, cl. 18.

Both the Supreme Court and this Circuit have said that in determining whether the

Necessary and Proper Clause grants Congress the legislative authority to enact a

particular federal statute, we look to see whether the statute constitutes a means that

is rationally related to the implementation of a constitutionally enumerated power.

Comstock, 130 S. Ct. at 1956 (emphasis added); United States v. Belfast, 611 F.3d

783, 804 (11th Cir. 2010).

The constitutionality of the end -- that is, the Acts insurer regulations -- is

both clear and unchallenged, as even the district court recognized. Florida, 2011 WL

285683, at *32 ([T]he end of regulating the health care insurance industry (including

preventing insurers from excluding or charging higher rates to people with pre-

existing conditions) is clearly legitimate and within the scope of the constitution.

(internal quotation marks omitted)). Once it has identified a legitimate and

constitutional end, Congress has an expansive choice of means. As Chief Justice

Marshall enduringly articulated [i]n language that has come to define the scope of the

Necessary and Proper Clause, Comstock, 130 S. Ct. at 1956:

Let the end be legitimate, let it be within the scope of the constitution,
and all means which are appropriate, which are plainly adapted to that
end, which are not prohibited, but consist with the letter and spirit of the
constitution, are constitutional.

255
McCulloch, 17 U.S. at 421. In addition, Chief Justice Marshall broadly defined the

term necessary. It does not mean absolutely necessary, but rather only

convenient, or useful or conducive to the beneficial exercise of one or more of

Congress enumerated powers. Comstock, 130 S. Ct. at 1956 (quoting McCulloch, 17

U.S. at 413, 414, 418).

It is clear under this expansive definition of necessary, the validity of which

was recently reaffirmed by the Supreme Court in Comstock, that requiring the

purchase of health insurance is convenient, useful, or conducive to effectively

implementing the Acts insurer regulations. As the states that tried to effectuate

guaranteed issue and community rating reforms without some form of individual

mandate attest, trying to do the former without the latter simply does not work. See,

e.g., Brief for Am. Assn of People with Disabilities et al. as Amici Curiae Supporting

the Government at 5-6 (Kentucky, Maine, New Hampshire, New Jersey, New York,

Vermont, and Washington enacted legislation that required insurers to guarantee issue

to all consumers in the individual market, but did not have a minimum coverage

provision. . . . All seven states suffered from sky-rocketing insurance premium costs,

reductions in individuals with coverage, and reductions in insurance products and

providers. (footnote omitted)); Brief for Governor of Wash. as Amicus Curiae

Supporting the Government at 2 (Washington knows firsthand the necessity of

256
universal coverage because of the problems it experienced when it eliminated barriers

to insurance coverage, like preexisting condition restrictions, without also imposing

a minimum coverage requirement.); Brief for Law Professors as Amici Curiae

Supporting the Government at 17 ([A]fter Kentucky enacted reform, all but two

insurers (one State-run) abandoned the State.).12 In this light, the individual mandate

is necessary to the end of regulating insurers underwriting practices without

running insurers out of business entirely -- a point the district court recognized.

Florida, 2011 WL 285683, at *33 (The defendants have asserted again and again that

the individual mandate is absolutely necessary and essential for the Act to operate

as it was intended by Congress. I accept that it is.).

The plaintiffs also claim that the individual mandate exceeds Congress power

because it is not proper -- that is, because it is inconsistent with the letter and the

spirit of the constitution. McCulloch, 17 U.S. at 421. I have little doubt that the

individual mandate is also proper. It violates no other provision of the

12
During a hearing before the House Ways and Means Committee, an economist
stated that imposition of community-rated premiums and guaranteed issue on a market of
competing private health insurers will inexorably drive that market into extinction, unless
these two features are coupled with . . . a mandate on individual[s] to be insured. Health
Reform in the 21st Century: Insurance Market Reforms: Hearing Before the H. Comm. on
Ways and Means, 111th Cong. 13 (2009) (statement of Dr. Uwe Reinhardt, Professor,
Princeton University). In other words, without a mandate, these two insurer reforms
would result in adverse selection, increased premiums, decreased enrollment, and fleeing
insurers -- in short, the insurance market would implode. See id. at 13 n.4.
257
Constitution.13 Cf. Comstock, 130 S. Ct. at 1957 ([T]he present statutes validity

under provisions of the Constitution other than the Necessary and Proper Clause is an

issue that is not before us. . . . [Therefore], the relevant inquiry is simply whether the

means chosen are reasonably adapted to the attainment of a legitimate end under the

commerce power . . . . (internal quotation marks omitted)). And the mandate is

undoubtedly rationally related to the end of effectuating the Acts guaranteed issue

and community rating reforms. Id. at 1956; Belfast, 611 F.3d at 804. The mandate

arguably renders the insurer regulations practically and economically feasible.

Congress found that without the mandate, many individuals would wait to purchase

health insurance until they needed care, 42 U.S.C. 18091(a)(2)(I) -- that is, until

they were sick, which would impose enormous costs on insurers and drive them out

of the market. And having observed the failed experience of those states that tried to

enact insurer reforms without an individual mandate, Congress rationally concluded

that one way to prevent this problem was to require that non-exempted individuals

enter the insurance risk pool. The Necessary and Proper Clause requires nothing

more.

II.

13
I address the plaintiffs suggestions that the individual mandate violates the
Fifth or Tenth Amendments in Part II.B, infra.
258
More fundamentally, the plaintiffs have offered two arguments that, they say,

undermine the governments position that Congress commerce power can justify

prescribing a rule that compels an individual to buy health insurance. First, they argue

that if Congress has the constitutional authority to enact the individual mandate, then

there is virtually no limit on its authority, and Art. 1, 8, cl. 3 of the Constitution

(whether standing alone or in concert with the Necessary and Proper Clause) would

be transformed into a grant of general police power. Second, they offer, although

largely implicitly, that the individual mandate really infringes upon notions of

individual liberty and popular sovereignty found either in the Fifth or Tenth

Amendments to the Constitution. I take up each argument in turn.

A.

1.

Perhaps at the heart of the plaintiffs objection to the mandate -- adopted by the

majority opinion in conclusion, if not in reasoning14 -- is the notion that allowing the

14
The majority comes perilously close to abandoning the central foundation -- the
dichotomy between activity and inactivity -- on which the plaintiffs and the district court
rely for their position that upholding the individual mandate would convert the Commerce
Clause into an unlimited general police power. See Maj. Op. at 109 ([W]e are not
persuaded that the formalistic dichotomy of activity and inactivity provides a workable or
persuasive enough answer in this case.). As I understand the position taken by the
plaintiffs and the district court, it is this: if the Commerce Clause affords Congress the
power to conscript the unwilling uninsured to enter the stream of commerce and buy
insurance, then Congress could also conscript any American to buy any private product at
a time and under circumstances not of his own choosing. In other words, the plaintiffs
259
individual mandate to stand will convert Congress commerce power into a plenary

federal police power, admitting of no limits and knowing of no bounds. The parade

of horribles said to follow ineluctably from upholding the individual mandate includes

the federal governments ability to compel us to purchase and consume broccoli, buy

General Motors vehicles, and exercise three times a week. However, acknowledging

the constitutionality of the individual mandate portends no such impending doom.

At the outset, there is always a danger in evaluating the constitutionality of

legislation actually before us solely on the basis of conjecture about what the future

may hold. The plaintiffs heavy reliance on floodgate fears and a parade of

dreadfuls calls to mind wise counsel: Judges and lawyers live on the slippery slope

of analogies; they are not supposed to ski it to the bottom. Buckley v. Am.

Constitutional Law Found., Inc., 525 U.S. 182, 194 n.16 (1999) (quoting Robert Bork,

The Tempting of America: The Political Seduction of the Law 169 (1990)). Federal

courts may only be called on to resolve ripe controversies, and it is difficult and

say, the individual mandate extends the Commerce Clause beyond its outer limits
precisely because it allows the government to conscript the inactive and unwilling.
Without drawing the distinction between activity and inactivity, I am at a loss to
understand the argument that sustaining the individual mandate would transmute the
limited power contained in Art. 1, 8, cl. 3 of the Constitution into an unlimited general
police power. For reasons that remain inexplicable to me, the majority opinion seems to
suggest that the individual mandate is a bridge too far -- in the words of the district
court -- not because it conscripts the inactive, but rather for some inchoate reason stated at
the highest order of abstraction.
260
hazardous for courts to prejudge the next case or the one after that in a vacuum, devoid

of a factually developed record sharpened in the crucible of the adversarial process.

See Baker v. Carr, 369 U.S. 186, 204 (1962) ([C]oncrete adverseness . . . sharpens

the presentation of issues upon which the court so largely depends for illumination of

difficult constitutional questions[.]). As courts of limited jurisdiction, we ought not

lose sight of the legislation before us, viewed in the context of the discrete issues and

facts presented. I have little doubt that the federal courts will be fully capable of

addressing future problems raised in future cases in the fullness of time.

But a more basic answer is this: upholding the individual mandate leaves fully

intact all of the existing limitations drawn around Congress Commerce Clause power.

To begin with, Congress is limited by the constitutional text and Supreme Court

doctrine largely to prescribing rules regulating economic behavior that has a

substantial effect on interstate commerce. These powerful limits afford no problem

in this case, because Congress has undeniably prescribed a rule (the individual

mandate) to regulate economic behavior (consumption of health care services by the

uninsured) that has a powerful impact on how, when, and by whom payment is made

for health care services. Indeed, the conduct regulated by the Act is even more

quintessentially economic in nature than the cultivation, possession, and personal

use of controlled substances, see Raich, 545 U.S. at 25, or the cultivation of wheat for

261
personal consumption, see Wickard, 317 U.S. at 119.

In Lopez and Morrison, the Supreme Court began to flesh out some of the outer

limits surrounding Art. I, 8, cl. 3. Chief Justice Rehnquist, writing for the Court in

both instances, posited a series of significant considerations, none of which pose any

problem in this case. See Morrison, 529 U.S. at 609-12. First, he observed that the

regulated conduct at issue in Lopez and Morrison was plainly of a noneconomic nature

-- again, the possession of a handgun within 1000 feet of a school in Lopez, and

gender-motivated felonious acts of violence in Morrison. See id. at 610 ([A] fair

reading of Lopez shows that the noneconomic, criminal nature of the conduct at issue

was central to our decision in that case.). Here, in sharp contrast, Congress has

prescribed a rule governing purely economic behavior. As Ive noted already, the Act

addresses an economic problem of enormous dimension -- $43 billion of annual cost

shifting from the uninsured to insured individuals and health care providers, 42 U.S.C.

18091(a)(2)(F) -- by prescribing an economic rule governing the timing and method

of payment for health care services. In short, the first problem identified in Lopez and

Morrison -- that the statutes reached purely intrastate, noneconomic behavior -- is not

found in this case, and thus the mandate does not, at least for this reason, penetrate

beyond the outer limits of Congress Commerce Clause power.

A second powerful consideration identified by the Court in both Lopez and

262
Morrison was that the nexus between the criminal conduct regulated by the legislation

and its impact -- even if taken in the aggregate -- on interstate commerce was remote

and wholly attenuated, and on its own terms provided no limiting principle

surrounding the exercise of Congress commerce power. In both Lopez and Morrison,

the government relied on a lengthy inferential chain of causal reasoning in order to

show that the criminal conduct regulated had a substantial effect on interstate

commerce. In Lopez -- where Congress had made no factual findings regarding the

effects upon interstate commerce of gun possession in a school zone -- the government

had to argue, among other things, that the possession of firearms near schools had the

natural effect of disrupting the educational process, and that this disruption, over time,

would in turn lower the economic productivity of our citizens, causing an adverse

effect on the national economy. See Lopez, 514 U.S. at 563-64. Its no surprise, then,

that the Court found the critical link to interstate commerce wanting, and concluded

that if this chain of reasoning were an acceptable means of bridging the gap between

the regulated conduct and commerce, precious little would fall outside the ambit of

Congress commerce power. Id. at 564. By the same token, in Morrison, the Court

found wanting Congress chain of reasoning -- that felonious acts of violence against

women would, inter alia, cause lost hours in the workplace and drive up hospital costs

and insurance premiums, which in turn would have an adverse effect on the national

263
economy. See Morrison, 529 U.S. at 615. The problem remained the same as in

Lopez, even though in Morrison, Congress had sought to draw the causal inferences

itself through express factual findings. Again, the causal reasoning that was required

to link the regulated criminal conduct to interstate commerce was lengthy and

attenuated. And again, the very method of reasoning offered by Congress afforded no

limitations on its commerce power. Id. at 615-16.

In this case, no such complex and attenuated causal story is necessary to locate

the regulated conducts nexus with interstate commerce. Here, the substantial effect

on commerce occurs directly and immediately when the uninsured consume health

care services in large numbers, do not pay for them in full or maybe even at all, and

thereby shift powerful economic costs onto insured individuals and health care

providers (as Congress found they do). The nexus between the regulated conduct and

interstate commerce could not be more direct. I am at a loss to find even a single

inferential leap[], Maj. Op. at 146, required to link them. Moreover, Congress

unambiguously and in considerable detail drew the connection between the regulated

conduct and its substantial effect on interstate commerce through extensive findings

of fact. See 42 U.S.C. 18091. Contrary to the majoritys claim, here there is no need

to pile inference upon inference, Lopez, 514 U.S. at 567, to draw the critical nexus,

and, therefore, we face no unlimited exercise of congressional power for that reason.

264
Moreover, in sharp contrast to Lopez and Morrison, we are confronted today

with a comprehensive economic statute, not a one-off, criminal prohibition. See

Raich, 545 U.S. at 23-24 (drawing a sharp distinction between brief, single-subject

statute[s] divorced from a larger regulatory scheme and lengthy and detailed

statute[s] creating a comprehensive framework for regulating an entire market). The

individual mandate is an essential part of a larger regulation of economic activity,

without which the regulatory scheme would be undercut, Lopez, 514 U.S. at 561,

and the Supreme Court has endorsed the constitutionality of such comprehensive,

economic regulatory schemes, Raich, 545 U.S. at 24-25; see also Hodel v. Indiana,

452 U.S. 314, 329 n.17 (1981) (A complex regulatory program such as established

by the [Surface Mining] Act can survive a Commerce Clause challenge without a

showing that every single facet of the program is independently and directly related

to a valid congressional goal. It is enough that the challenged provisions are an

integral part of the regulatory program and that the regulatory scheme when

considered as a whole satisfies this test.); Raich, 545 U.S. at 36 (Scalia, J., concurring

in the judgment) (Though the conduct in Lopez was not economic, the Court

nevertheless recognized that it could be regulated as an essential part of a larger

regulation of economic activity, in which the regulatory scheme could be undercut

unless the intrastate activity were regulated. (quoting Lopez, 514 U.S. at 561)). And,

265
according to Eleventh Circuit precedent, where Congress comprehensively regulates

economic activity, it may constitutionally regulate intrastate activity, whether

economic or not, so long as the inability to do so would undermine Congresss ability

to implement effectively the overlying economic regulatory scheme. Maxwell II, 446

F.3d at 1215 (footnote omitted).

The majority, in an effort to distance itself from this precedent, suggests that,

because Raich involved an as-applied challenge, the inquiry into whether challenged

legislation is an essential part of a larger regulation of economic activity is only

appropriate in as-applied challenges, as opposed to facial ones. Maj. Op. at 158-60.

In other words, the majority seems to be saying that, because the Supreme Court has

to date never sustained a statute on the basis of the larger regulatory scheme doctrine

in a facial challenge, id. at 159, it is irrelevant to the question of the individual

mandates constitutionality that the mandate is an essential part of a larger economic

regulatory scheme. There is no doctrinal basis for this view. In Lopez itself, the Court

applied this principle in the context of a facial challenge. In Raich, the Court plainly

recognized that, unlike the challenge it faced, the challenges to the constitutionality

of the Gun-Free School Zones Act in Lopez, and, for that matter, to Title III of the

Violence Against Women Act in Morrison, were facial challenges. Justice Stevens,

writing for the majority in Raich, said: Here, respondents ask us to excise individual

266
applications of a concededly valid statutory scheme. In contrast, in both Lopez and

Morrison, the parties asserted that a particular statute or provision fell outside

Congress commerce power in its entirety, the very definition of a facial challenge.

Raich, 545 U.S. at 23 (emphasis added). Indeed, Justice Thomas, dissenting, likewise

expressly recognized that [i]n Lopez and Morrison, the parties asserted facial

challenges. Id. at 71 (Thomas, J., dissenting). And of course in Lopez, the Court, for

the first time, applied this very doctrine, explaining that even though the Gun-Free

School Zones Act targeted purely local, noneconomic behavior, the Court could have

upheld it nonetheless if it had been an essential part of a larger regulation of

economic activity, in which the regulatory scheme could be undercut unless the

intrastate activity were regulated. Lopez, 514 U.S. at 561. Moreover, a panel of this

Court has recently explained in binding precedent that what distinguished Raich from

Morrison and Lopez . . . was the comprehensiveness of the economic component of

the regulation, Maxwell II, 446 F.3d at 1214 -- not whether the challenge was facial

or as-applied.

Furthermore, the majoritys view that the individual mandate is not an essential

part of the Acts concededly economic regulatory scheme, see Maj. Op. at 162-66,

cannot be squared with the economic realities of the health insurance business or the

legislative realities of the Act. Nor can this view be squared with the contrary

267
judgment reached by Congress on this very point. Thus, for example, the majority

appears to simply cast aside Congress finding that the individual mandate is essential

to creating effective health insurance markets in which improved health insurance

products that are guaranteed issue and do not exclude coverage of pre-existing

conditions can be sold. 42 U.S.C. 18091(a)(2)(I). In Maxwell II, we explained that

courts have only a limited role in second-guessing Congress judgments about

whether leaving a class of conduct outside of federal control would undercut[]

Congresss unquestioned authority to regulate the broader interstate market. 446

F.3d at 1215 (internal quotation marks omitted). Faced with evidence that the

insurance industry would collapse if the Acts guaranteed issue and community rating

provisions were implemented without the individual mandate, Congress had more than

a rational basis for concluding, Raich, 545 U.S. at 19, that the individual mandate

was essential to the success of the Acts concededly valid and quintessentially

economic insurer reforms.15 In short, the real and substantial limits on the commerce

15
Although the majority seems to take comfort in only striking down the
individual mandate, see Maj. Op. at 207 n.145, all of the parties have agreed that the
individual mandate is so essential to the principal insurer reforms that, at least for
severability purposes, the guaranteed issue and community rating provisions necessarily
rise and fall with the individual mandate, Govt Reply Br. at 58 (As plaintiffs note, the
federal government acknowledged below [and continues to acknowledge] that the
guaranteed-issue and community-rating provisions due to take effect in 2014 . . . cannot
be severed from the minimum coverage requirement. The requirement is integral to those
sections that go into effect along with it in 2014 and provide that insurers must extend
coverage and set premiums without regard to pre-existing medical conditions . . . .);
268
power set forth by the Supreme Court in Lopez and Morrison would be left wholly

intact if we were to uphold the individual mandate.

Because the impact on interstate commerce of the conduct that Congress sought

to regulate through the individual mandate is so clear and immediate, this case is

readily distinguishable from many of the plaintiffs suggested hypothetical horribles,

which suffer from the inference-piling reasoning condemned in Lopez and Morrison.

Thus, for example, in arguing that Congress could force us to purchase broccoli, the

plaintiffs necessarily reason as follows: everyone is a participant in the food market;

if people buy more broccoli, they will eat more broccoli; eating more broccoli will, in

the long run, improve peoples health; this, in turn, will improve overall worker

productivity, thus affecting our national economy. Such reasoning violates the

cautionary note that under the Governments national productivity reasoning,

Congress could regulate any activity that it found was related to the economic

productivity of individual citizens . . . . Thus, if we were to accept the Governments

arguments, we are hard pressed to posit any activity by an individual that Congress is

without power to regulate. Lopez, 514 U.S. at 564. By contrast, the economic

States Br. at 63 (stating that the individual mandate cannot be severed from the core,
interrelated health insurance reforms); NFIB Br. at 60-61 (stating that the mandate and
the principal insurer provisions truly are the heart of the Act, and highlighting the
governments concession that the mandate and the insurer reforms must stand or fall
together (internal quotation marks omitted)).
269
problem that Congress sought to address through the individual mandate does not

depend on any remote or long-term effects on economic productivity stemming from

individuals health care choices; indeed, the mandate does not compel individuals to

seek health care at all, much less any particular form of it. Instead, Congress rationally

found that the uninsureds inevitable, substantial, and often uncompensated

consumption of health care services -- of any form -- in and of itself substantially

affects the national economy.

2.

Moreover, this case does not open the floodgates to an unbounded Commerce

Clause power because the particular factual circumstances are truly unique, and not

susceptible to replication elsewhere. This factual uniqueness would render any

holding in this case limited. I add the unremarkable observation that the holding of

every case is bounded by the peculiar fact pattern arising therein. See Licciardello v.

Lovelady, 544 F.3d 1280, 1288 n.8 (11th Cir. 2008) (Our holding, as always, is

limited to the facts before us.); see also United States v. Hunter, 172 F.3d 1307, 1310

(11th Cir. 1999) (Carnes, J., concurring) (The holdings of a prior decision can reach

only as far as the facts and circumstances presented to the Court in the case which

produced that decision.).

The health care services market is characterized by five relevant factors, which,

270
when taken in concert, uniquely converge to create a truly sui generis problem: (1) the

unavoidable need that virtually all of us have to consume medical care; (2) the

unpredictability of that need; (3) the high costs associated with the consumption of

health care services; (4) the inability of providers to refuse to provide care in

emergency situations; and, largely as a result of the previous four factors, (5) the very

significant cost shifting that underlies the way medical care is paid for in this country.

Govt Econ. Br. at 1.

These are not just five fortuitous descriptors of the health care market, elevated

to artificial constitutional significance. Over the last 75 years the Supreme Court has

emphatically and repeatedly counseled a pragmatic approach to Commerce Clause

analysis, grounded in a practical conception of commercial regulation, drawn from

the course of business. Swift & Co., 196 U.S. at 398; accord Raich, 545 U.S. at 25

n.35; Lopez, 514 U.S. at 571, 574 (Kennedy, J., concurring); Wickard, 317 U.S. at

123-24; Jones & Laughlin Steel, 301 U.S. at 41-42. Legislation enacted pursuant to

Congress Commerce Clause power cannot be evaluated in a vacuum, but only in light

of the peculiar problems Congress sought to address, what Congress chose to regulate,

how Congress chose to regulate, and the connection between the regulated conduct

and the problem Congress sought to resolve. Courts must always engage in the hard

work of identify[ing] objective markers for confining the analysis in Commerce

271
Clause cases. Raich, 545 U.S. at 47 (OConnor, J., dissenting). Far from being ad

hoc and illusory, Maj. Op. at 168, these factual criteria are relevant descriptors,

drawn from the course of business, of the economic realities Congress confronted.

They are, therefore, precisely what the Court has instructed us to consider in the

Commerce Clause analysis. And given these unique characteristics of the health care

market and the peculiar way these characteristics converge, the individual mandate

was part of a practical solution to the cost-shifting problem Congress sought to

address.

The first and most basic of these factors is that no individual can opt out of the

health care services market, and thus virtually everyone will consume health care

services. Individual participation in the health care services market is properly,

therefore, a question of when and how individuals will consume and pay for such

services, not whether they will consume them. The plaintiffs are correct that there are

other markets that, if defined broadly enough, no one may opt out of, such as the

markets for food, transportation, and shelter. But the hypothetical mandates -- that

Congress can force individuals to buy broccoli, GM cars, or homes -- do not follow.

Neither those markets nor their hypothetical mandates resemble the market and

mandate here.

In the first place, unlike the needs for food, transportation, and shelter -- which

272
are always present and have largely predictable costs -- illness and injury are wholly

unpredictable. Individuals who never intend to consume health care, unlike those who

never intend to purchase GM cars or broccoli or a home, will nonetheless do so

because of accidents, illnesses, and all the vagaries to which ones health is subject.

Indeed, the economists concluded that even the most sophisticated methods of

predicting medical spending can explain only 25-35% of the variation in the costs

incurred by different individuals; the vast bulk of [medical] spending needs cannot

be forecast in advance. Govt Econ. Br. at 10-11.

In addition, while the costs associated with obtaining food, transportation, and

shelter are susceptible to budgeting, this is not the case for health care, which can be

so expensive that most everyone must have some access to funds beyond their own

resources in order to afford them. Id. at 11-12 (explaining that unpredicted medical

costs can eclipse the financial assets of all but the very well-to-do); see also Govt

Reply Br. at 15 (The frequency, timing and magnitude of a given individuals

demand for health care are unknowable. (quoting Jennifer Prah Ruger, The Moral

Foundations of Health Insurance, 100 Q.J. Med. 53, 54-55 (2007))). Moreover, there

are lower cost alternatives to purchasing a house or a car, such as renting an

apartment, leasing an automobile, or relying on public transportation. There are no

realistic alternatives or less expensive substitutes for treating cancer, a heart attack,

273
or a stroke, or for performing a needed organ transplant or hip replacement. Even

routine medical procedures, such as MRIs, CT scans, colonoscopies, mammograms,

and childbirth, cost more than many Americans can afford. Govt Econ. Br. at 11.

This is not to say that individuals may not budget and plan as best they can for their

health care costs, as many surely do, but the combination of uncertain timing,

unpredictable malady, and potentially astronomical cost can nonetheless leave

individuals wholly unable to pay for the health care services they consume. Indeed,

Congress found that 62 percent of all personal bankruptcies are caused in part by

medical expenses. 42 U.S.C. 18091(a)(2)(G).

Largely because of these first three factors -- that health care costs are

inevitable, unpredictable, and often staggeringly high -- the health care services

market, unlike other markets, is paid for predominantly through the mechanism of

insurance.16 Govt Br. at 9 (citing CMS data that payments by private and government

insurers comprise 75% of national health care spending). Insurance is thus already

intimately linked to the health care services market. People do not similarly insure

16
The unpredictability and wide variation in health care costs demonstrate why
the majoritys comparison of average health care costs to the average insurance premium
misses the point. Maj. Op. at 140. Individuals pay $4500 in insurance premiums not to
avoid the $2000 average annual medical bill, but to avoid the extreme medical bill.
Indeed, the whole point of insurance is to make spending more regular and predictable.
Comparing the average medical bill with the average insurance premium is hollow --
insurance is purchased for the very reason that one cannot count on receiving the
average medical bill every year.
274
against the risk that they will need food or shelter, because these needs are apparent

and predictable, and people can reliably budget for them. Although the purchase of

a car or a home may often be too expensive for many individuals to afford out of

pocket, it would be fanciful indeed to suggest that individuals would insure against the

sudden and unpredictable purchase of a home or automobile. The plaintiffs admit that

[r]egulations are plainly adapted if they invoke the ordinary means of execution.

NFIB Br. at 42 (quoting McCulloch, 17 U.S. at 409, 421). Insurance is the ordinary

means of paying for health care services. Thus, a mandate to purchase insurance is

more appropriately suited to address the problems of non-payment and cost shifting

in the health care services market than it would be to address problems in other

markets that do not similarly rely on insurance as the primary method of payment.

The fourth important factor distinguishing the health care market from all other

markets -- and peculiarly contributing to the cost shifting that Congress sought to

address through the mandate -- is the fact that individuals may consume health care

services without regard to their ability to pay and often without ever paying for them.

Unlike any other sellers in any other marketplace, nearly all hospitals are required by

law to provide emergency services to anyone, regardless of ability to pay. See

EMTALA, 42 U.S.C. 1395dd. If an individual shows up at the emergency room

doorstep with a broken neck from an automobile accident or bleeding from a gunshot

275
wound, or if an individual suffers a heart attack or a stroke, hospitals will not turn him

away. Even aside from the federal obligation imposed by EMTALA, by my count, at

least ten of the plaintiff states have statutes on the books requiring hospitals with

emergency rooms to provide emergency treatment to those in need of it, regardless of

ability to pay.17 Still other plaintiff states have state court judicial rulings imposing

similar requirements.18 And even absent any legal duty, many hospitals provide free

or deeply discounted care as part of their charitable mission, even when the patients

need does not rise to the level of an emergency. See Thornton v. Sw. Detroit Hosp.,

895 F.2d 1131, 1132 (6th Cir. 1990) (observing in the application of EMTALA that

American hospitals have a long tradition of giving emergency medical aid to anyone

17
See Fla. Stat. Ann. 395.1041(1); Idaho Code Ann. 39-1391b; La. Rev. Stat.
Ann. 40:2113.4(A); Nev. Rev. Stat. Ann. 439B.410(1); 35 Pa. Stat. Ann. 449.8(a);
S.C. Code Ann. 44-7-260(E); Tex. Health & Safety Code Ann. 311.022(a); Utah Code
Ann. 26-8a-501(1); Wash. Rev. Code 70.170.060(2); Wis. Stat. Ann. 256.30(2); see
also Govt Br. at 35 (citing testimony before Congress in 1986 that at least 22 states had
enacted statutes or issued regulations requiring provision of emergency medical services
regardless of ability to pay, and observing that state court rulings impose a common law
duty on doctors and hospitals to provide emergency care).
18
See, e.g., Thompson v. Sun City Cmty. Hosp., Inc., 688 P.2d 605, 610 (Ariz.
1984) ([A]s a matter of public policy, licensed hospitals in this state are required to
accept and render emergency care to all patients who present themselves in need of such
care. . . . This standard of care has, in effect, been set by statute and regulation embodying
a public policy which requires private hospitals to provide emergency care that is
medically indicated without consideration of the economic circumstances of the patient
in need of such care.); Walling v. Allstate Ins. Co., 455 N.W.2d 736, 738 (Mich. Ct.
App. 1990) ([L]iability on the part of a private hospital may be based upon the refusal of
service to a patient in a case of unmistakable medical emergency.).
276
in need who appeared on the emergency room doorstep). One expert from the

Heritage Foundation persuasively illustrated this distinction between health care and

other markets when recommending in 1989 that the government impose a mandate to

obtain adequate [health] insurance:

If a young man wrecks his Porsche and has not had the foresight to
obtain insurance, we may commiserate but society feels no obligation to
repair his car. But health care is different. If a man is struck down by a
heart attack in the street, Americans will care for him whether or not he
has insurance. If we find that he has spent his money on other things
rather than insurance, we may be angry but we will not deny him services
-- even if that means more prudent citizens end up paying the tab.

Stuart M. Butler, Heritage Found., The Heritage Lectures 218: Assuring Affordable

Health Care for All Americans 6 (1989);19 see also Govt Br. at 37.

This obligation of health care providers to provide free medical care creates

market imperfections that fall under a variety of labels: an externality (a situation

where one persons actions or inactions affect[] others), a free-rider problem (where

people buy [or consume] a good and leave the costs to others), or a Samaritans

19
The Heritage Foundation has filed an amicus brief in support of the plaintiffs
making clear that this excerpt does not reflect the policy of the Heritage Foundation or
even the current beliefs of the speaker; both strongly dispute the efficacy and the
constitutionality of the individual mandate. Brief for Heritage Found. as Amicus Curiae
Supporting the Plaintiffs at 5-6. I do not doubt the sincerity of this position, and use this
statement not to imply that the Heritage Foundation has blessed the individual mandate
but rather only for the statements own value as a persuasively articulated description of
an important distinction between health insurance, health care, and other markets.
277
dilemma (where people choose not to be prepared for emergencies, knowing that

others will care for them if needed). Govt Econ. Br. at 14-15. Individuals who

decline to purchase health insurance are not held to the full economic consequence of

that choice, as society does not refuse medical care to a patient in need, even when its

cost far exceeds the individuals ability to pay. The ability of health care market

participants to demand services without paying for them bolsters Congress rational

conclusion that the individual mandate -- which helps to assure payment for services

in advance -- is peculiarly suited to addressing a unique economic problem in the

health care market.20

Finally, the four factors described above converge to cause a fifth unique factor

of the health care market: the substantial cost shifting from the uninsured to current

20
Contrary to the plaintiffs suggestion, it is not problematic that Congress own
legislation -- EMTALA -- may have contributed to the very market conditions that it
sought to address in the Act. Significantly, EMTALA predated the individual mandate by
over two decades, and was enacted for reasons wholly unrelated to the mandate.
Moreover, EMTALA did not create a new federal obligation out of whole cloth and then
impose it on health care providers; rather, it supplemented numerous state laws and
overarching social judgments that the sick and injured should be cared for regardless of
ability to pay. Nor should we be concerned that Congress might similarly enact
legislation requiring companies to give away cars, food, or housing, and then accompany
that legislation with a mandate prescribing the pre-purchase of a mechanism for financing
those items. Not only is it wholly unrealistic that Congress would require companies to
give away free cars or housing (even if it could do so) simply so that it could then impose
an insurance requirement on those items, but cars and houses are also products not
already predominantly financed through insurance. An insurance mandate thus would not
be a well-suited means to regulate payment in those markets.
278
participants in the health insurance market and to health care providers. This cost

shifting does not occur in other markets, even those in which we all participate, such

as transportation, food, or housing. When an individual purchases a home or a car, the

purchaser pays all of the cost (whether upfront or over time through a loan or

mortgage). My neighbor will not help cover my costs of purchasing a home by paying

a higher price for his own house. And I will not pay more for my car, simply because

my neighbor cannot afford to buy one for himself. The costs in those markets are

borne by the individual purchaser alone. Again, in sharp contrast, the uninsured shift

substantial costs to the insured and to health care providers, because the uninsured in

the aggregate consume health care services in large numbers and yet bear only a small

fraction of the costs for the services they consume. The parties agree that the

uninsured fail to pay for 63% of the health care services they receive, and some 37%

(amounting to $43 billion) of all health care costs incurred by the uninsured are

uncompensated entirely. States Br. at 30-31; Govt Reply Br. at 8-9, 11. Congress

found that this uncompensated care increases the average insured familys annual

insurance premiums by $1000. 42 U.S.C. 18091(a)(2)(F). This cost-shifting

phenomenon simply does not occur in other industries.21 Even under the majoritys

21
Perhaps the closest analog to the individual mandate is a requirement that
individuals buy other types of insurance. The district court rejected the governments
contention that the failure to buy health insurance is a financing decision by reasoning
that this is essentially true of any and all forms of insurance. Florida, 2011 WL
279
characterization of the regulated conduct as a decision not to purchase health

insurance, Maj. Op. at 164, deciding to self-insure in the health care market, unlike

all other financial decisions of Americans, id. at 115, is a decision to pay for your

care if you can afford it or to shift costs onto society if you cant.

In sum, the particular problems riddling the health care industry that Congress

sought to address, together with the unique factors that characterize the health care

market and its peculiar interconnectedness with the health insurance market, all led

Congress to enact the individual mandate as an appropriate means of ameliorating two

large national problems. Although these economic factors are not precise

formulations, and in the nature of things they cannot be[,] . . . [I] think they point the

way to a correct decision of this case. Lopez, 514 U.S. at 567; see also id. at 579

(Kennedy, J., concurring) ([A]s the branch whose distinctive duty it is to declare

what the law is, we are often called upon to resolve questions of constitutional law

not susceptible to the mechanical application of bright and clear lines. (citation

omitted) (quoting Marbury v. Madison, 5 U.S. (1 Cranch) 137, 177 (1803))).

Upholding the mandate under the particular circumstances of this case would do little

285683, at *28; see also Maj. Op. at 133. But of the examples suggested by the district
court -- supplemental income, credit, mortgage guaranty, business interruption, or
disability insurance -- none insures against risks or costs that are inevitable, or that will
otherwise be subsidized by those with insurance, unlike the relationship between health
insurance and health care services.
280
to pave the way for future congressional mandates that address wholly distinct

problems that may arise in powerfully different contexts. While the individual

mandate is indeed novel, I cannot accept the charge that it is a bridge too far. The

individual mandate, viewed in light of the larger economic regulatory scheme of the

Act as a whole and the truly unique and interrelated nature of both markets, is a

legitimate exercise of Congress power under Art. I, 8, cl. 3 of the Constitution and

is not prone to the slippery slope of hypothetical horrors leading to an unlimited

federal Commerce Clause power.

B.

Finally, implicit in the plaintiffs Commerce Clause challenge, and providing

the subtext to much of the majoritys opinion, is the deeply rooted fear that the federal

government is infringing upon the individuals right to be left alone -- a fear that is

intertwined with a visceral aversion to the governments making us do something we

do not want to do (in this case, buy a product we do not wish to purchase). The

plaintiffs say that Congress cannot compel unwilling individuals to engage in a private

commercial transaction or otherwise pay a penalty. The difficulty, however, is in

finding firm constitutional footing for the objection. The plaintiffs suggest that the

claim derives, if anywhere, from either of two constitutional provisions: the Fifth

Amendments Due Process Clause or the Tenth Amendment. If derived from the Fifth

281
Amendment, the objection, fairly stated, is that the mandate violates individual liberty,

as protected by the substantive component of the Due Process Clause. In the

alternative, if derived from the Tenth Amendment, the objection is that the individual

mandate infringes on the powers, or rights, retained by the people.

At the trial court, the plaintiffs squarely raised a Fifth Amendment substantive

due process challenge to the individual mandate, which the district court flatly

rejected. Florida ex rel. McCollum v. U.S. Dept of Health & Human Servs., 716 F.

Supp. 2d 1120, 1161-62 (N.D. Fla. 2010). And while the plaintiffs also challenged the

individual mandate on Tenth Amendment grounds, the district court addressed this

challenge only implicitly in ruling that the mandate exceeded Congress commerce

power. Florida, 2011 WL 285683, at *33.

On appeal, the plaintiffs have expressly disclaimed any substantive due process

challenge to the individual mandate, although they appear still to advance a Tenth

Amendment challenge. Nevertheless, it is clear that individual liberty concerns lurk

just beneath the surface, inflecting the plaintiffs argument throughout, although

largely dressed up in Commerce Clause and Necessary and Proper Clause terms. For

example, the state plaintiffs go so far as to say that the individual mandate is one of

the Acts principal threats to individual liberty, States Br. at 16, and that upholding

it would sound the death knell for our constitutional structure and individual

282
liberties, id. at 19. Similarly, the private plaintiffs claim that the individual mandate

exemplifies the threat to individual liberty when Congress exceeds its enumerated

powers and attempts to wield a plenary police power. NFIB Br. at 7. Sounding

almost entirely in economic substantive due process, the private plaintiffs also assert

that [a]mong the most longstanding and fundamental rights of Americans is their

freedom from being forced to give their property to, or contract with, other private

parties. Id. at 47. Thus, to the extent the plaintiffs individual liberty-based

challenge to the individual mandate derives from the Fifth and Tenth Amendments,

I address each constitutional source in turn.

The Fifth Amendment provides that [n]o person shall . . . be deprived of life,

liberty, or property, without due process of law. U.S. Const. amend. V. Although the

Due Process Clause has both a procedural and a substantive component, only its

substantive aspect is implicated here. The substantive component [of the Due

Process Clause] protects fundamental rights that are so implicit in the concept of

ordered liberty that neither liberty nor justice would exist if they were sacrificed.

Doe v. Moore, 410 F.3d 1337, 1342 (11th Cir. 2005) (internal quotation marks

omitted). This narrow band of fundamental rights is largely protected from

governmental action, regardless of the procedures employed. Id. at 1343. And any

law, whether federal or state, that infringes upon these rights will undergo strict

283
scrutiny review, which means that the law must be narrowly tailored to serve a

compelling state interest. Id. (quoting Reno v. Flores, 507 U.S. 292, 302 (1993)).

Today, substantive due process protects only a small class of fundamental rights,

including the rights to marry, to have children, to direct the education and upbringing

of ones children, to marital privacy, to use contraception, to bodily integrity, and to

abortion, Washington v. Glucksberg, 521 U.S. 702, 720 (1997) (citations omitted) --

a list the Supreme Court has been very reluctant to expand, Moore, 410 F.3d at

1343.

In a bygone period known as the Lochner era,22 however, substantive due

process was more broadly interpreted as also encompassing and protecting the right,

liberty, or freedom of contract. See, e.g., Adkins v. Childrens Hosp. of D.C., 261 U.S.

525, 545 (1923); Adair v. United States, 208 U.S. 161, 174-75 (1908). Through this

interpretation of the Due Process Clause, the Supreme Court struck down many federal

and state laws that sought to regulate business and industrial conditions. See, e.g.,

Adkins, 261 U.S. 525 (striking down a federal law fixing minimum wages for women

and children in the District of Columbia); Jay Burns Baking Co. v. Bryan, 264 U.S.

504 (1924) (striking down a Nebraska law regulating the weight of loaves of bread for

22
The name refers, of course, to Lochner v. New York, 198 U.S. 45 (1905), where
the Supreme Court struck down a New York law setting maximum hours for bakery
employees on the ground that it violated the right of contract, as protected by the
Fourteenth Amendments Due Process Clause.
284
sale).

However, the Supreme Court has long since abandoned the sweeping protection

of economic rights through substantive due process. See, e.g., Ferguson v. Skrupa,

372 U.S. 726, 730 (1963) (The doctrine that prevailed in Lochner . . . and like cases --

that due process authorizes courts to hold laws unconstitutional when they believe the

legislature has acted unwisely -- has long since been discarded.); Williamson v. Lee

Optical of Okla., Inc., 348 U.S. 483, 488 (1955) (The day is gone when this Court

uses the Due Process Clause of the Fourteenth Amendment to strike down state laws,

regulatory of business and industrial conditions, because they may be unwise,

improvident, or out of harmony with a particular school of thought.); West Coast

Hotel Co. v. Parrish, 300 U.S. 379, 391 (1937). Today, economic regulations are

presumed constitutional, Usery v. Turner Elkhorn Mining Co., 428 U.S. 1, 15 (1976),

and are subject only to rational basis review, Vesta Fire Ins. Corp. v. Florida, 141 F.3d

1427, 1430 n.5 (11th Cir. 1998).

In substantive due process cases, binding precedent requires that we carefully

formulat[e] the alleged fundamental right, Glucksberg, 521 U.S. at 722, which must

be defined in reference to the scope of the [statute at issue], Williams v. Atty Gen.

of Ala., 378 F.3d 1232, 1241 (11th Cir. 2004). In light of the individual mandates

scope, the carefully formulated right would be the right of non-exempted individuals

285
to refuse to maintain a minimum level of health insurance. And this right -- whether

cast as the freedom to contract, the right to remain uninsured, or, in the words of one

commentator, the right to force a society to pay for your medical care by taking a free

ride on the system23 -- cannot be characterized as a fundamental one receiving

heightened protection under the Due Process Clause. The present state of our

jurisprudence does not recognize any such right as a fundamental one, deeply

rooted in this Nations history and tradition, and implicit in the concept of ordered

liberty, such that neither liberty nor justice would exist if [it] were sacrificed.

Williams, 378 F.3d at 1239 (quoting Glucksberg, 521 U.S. at 720-21).

Since the individual liberty interest asserted by the plaintiffs is not a

fundamental right, we are obliged to apply rational basis review, which only asks

whether the mandate is rationally related to a legitimate government interest. TRM,

Inc. v. United States, 52 F.3d 941, 945 (11th Cir. 1995). Under rational basis review,

legislation must be sustained if there is any conceivable basis for the legislature to

believe that the means they have selected will tend to accomplish the desired end.

Id. at 945-46 (internal quotation marks omitted); see also Williams v. Morgan, 478

F.3d 1316, 1320 (11th Cir. 2007) (A statute is constitutional under rational basis

23
See Is the Obama Health Care Reform Constitutional? Fried, Tribe and Barnett
Debate the Affordable Care Act, Harvard Law School (Mar. 28, 2011),
http://www.law.harvard.edu/news/spotlight/constitutional-law/is-obama-health-care-refor
m-constitutional.html.
286
scrutiny so long as there is any reasonably conceivable state of facts that could

provide a rational basis for the [statute]. (alteration in original) (quoting FCC v.

Beach Commcns, Inc., 508 U.S. 307, 313 (1993))).

Here, Congress rationally found that the individual mandate would address the

powerful economic problems associated with cost shifting from the uninsured to the

insured and to health care providers, and with the inability of millions of uninsured

individuals to obtain health insurance. Thus, to the extent the plaintiffs individual

liberty concerns are rooted in the Fifth Amendments Due Process Clause, they must

fail.

The plaintiffs more provocative argument is found in the Tenth Amendment,

which provides that [t]he powers not delegated to the United States by the

Constitution, nor prohibited by it to the States, are reserved to the States respectively,

or to the people. U.S. Const. amend. X. The plaintiffs do not explicitly flesh out how

the mandate violates the Tenth Amendment. The state plaintiffs cite the Tenth

Amendment generally, claiming that [i]f this Court were to uphold [the individual

mandate and the Acts Medicaid expansion], there would remain little if any power

reserved to the States . . . or to the people. States Br. at 3 (alteration in original)

287
(quoting U.S. Const. amend. X).24 And the private plaintiffs suggest that the portion

of the amendment reserving undelegated power to the people provides the basis for

their individual liberty claim. See NFIB Br. at 46 (reciting the Tenth Amendments

admonition that the non-enumerated powers are reserved to the States respectively,

or to the people. (quoting U.S. Const. amend. X) (emphasis in original)); see also

Brief for Cato Institute as Amicus Curiae Supporting the Plaintiffs at 24 ([T]he text

of the Tenth Amendment protects not just state sovereignty, but also popular

sovereignty.).

The Supreme Court, however, has said precious little about the tail end of the

Tenth Amendment that reserves power to the people. Indeed, no case, either from the

Supreme Court or from any lower federal court, has ever invoked this portion of the

amendment to strike down an act of Congress. Instead, the Supreme Courts Tenth

Amendment cases have grappled almost exclusively with the balance of power

between the federal government and the states.25

24
Indeed, when asked at oral argument if the Tenth Amendment had been
abandoned on appeal, counsel for the states reiterated that the Tenth Amendment is still
very much in this case, and that this is both an individual rights case and a Commerce
Clause enumerated rights case.
25
In Bond v. United States, -- U.S. --, 131 S. Ct. 2355 (2011), the Supreme Court
recently held that an individual has prudential standing to assert injury from
governmental action taken in excess of the authority that federalism defines. Id. at 2363-
64. In other words, Carol Anne Bond had standing to raise federalism-based arguments
in challenging the constitutionality of the criminal statute under which she was indicted,
288
In these cases, the Supreme Court has interpreted the Tenth Amendments

reservation of power to the states to mean that the federal government may not

commandeer[] the legislative processes of the States by directly compelling them to

enact and enforce a federal regulatory program. New York, 505 U.S. at 176 (quoting

Hodel v. Va. Surface Mining & Reclamation Assn, 452 U.S. 264, 288 (1981)); see

also Printz v. United States, 521 U.S. 898, 935 (1997) (The Federal Government may

neither issue directives requiring the States to address particular problems, nor

command the States officers, or those of their political subdivisions, to administer or

enforce a federal regulatory program.). The Court has thus held that federal laws

compelling state governments to enact legislation providing for the disposal of

radioactive waste, New York, 505 U.S. at 149, and compelling state agents to conduct

background checks on prospective handgun purchasers, Printz, 521 U.S. at 902,

violate the Tenth Amendment. In so holding, the Supreme Court has explained that

the limits the Tenth Amendment imposes on Congress power come not from the

amendments text, but rather from the principle of federalism, or dual sovereignty, that

the Tenth Amendment embodies. See New York, 505 U.S. at 156-57.

But because of the utter lack of Supreme Court (or any other court) precedent,

18 U.S.C. 229 (which prohibits the knowing development, acquisition, possession, or


use of chemical weapons). Id. at 2360. It remains true, however, that the Court has never
used the people prong of the Tenth Amendment to invalidate an act of Congress.
289
the amendments people prong provides little, if any, support here. It may be that

in time the law will come to breathe practical life into the Tenth Amendments

reservation of power to the people, but that day has not yet arrived.

Setting aside the lack of any precedent on point, a Tenth Amendment challenge

to the individual mandate fails for an additional, and critical, reason: when a federal

law is properly within Congress delegated power to enact, the Tenth Amendment

poses no limit on the exercise of that power. See, e.g., New York, 505 U.S. at 156 (If

a power is delegated to Congress in the Constitution, the Tenth Amendment expressly

disclaims any reservation of that power to the States . . . .); Midrash Sephardi, Inc.

v. Town of Surfside, 366 F.3d 1214, 1242 (11th Cir. 2004) (Because [the Religious

Land Use and Institutionalized Persons Act] is a proper exercise of Congresss power

under 5 of the Fourteenth Amendment, there is no violation of the Tenth

Amendment.); United States v. Williams, 121 F.3d 615, 620 (11th Cir. 1997) ([T]he

[Child Support Recovery Act] is a valid exercise of Congresss power under the

Commerce Clause, and Congresss valid exercise of authority delegated to it under

the Constitution does not violate the Tenth Amendment. (quoting Cheffer v. Reno,

55 F.3d 1517, 1519 (11th Cir. 1995))); N. Ala. Express, Inc. v. ICC, 971 F.2d 661, 666

(11th Cir. 1992) (Because the Tenth Amendment reserves only those powers not

already delegated to the federal government, the Tenth Amendment has been violated

290
only if [the federal law at issue] goes beyond the limits of Congress power under the

Commerce Clause.). Since the individual mandate falls within Congress commerce

power, its enactment is a proper exercise of a power delegated to the United States

by the Constitution. U.S. Const. amend. X. The Tenth Amendment, therefore, has

no independent role to play. In short, the plaintiffs individual liberty claims find little

support in the Constitution -- whether pegged to the Fifth Amendments Due Process

Clause or to the Tenth Amendments reservation of power to the people.

At bottom, Congress rationally concluded that the uninsureds consumption of

health care services, in the aggregate, shifts enormous costs onto others and thus

substantially affects interstate commerce. The individual mandate directly and

unambiguously addresses this cost-shifting problem by regulating the timing and

means of payment for the consumption of these services. Congress also fairly

determined that the mandate is an essential part of the Acts comprehensive regulation

of the health insurance market. I would, therefore, uphold the mandate as

constitutional, and I respectfully dissent on this critical point.

291
APPENDIX A: OVERALL STRUCTURE OF ACTS NINE TITLES

The Acts nine Titles are:

I. Quality, Affordable Health Care for All Americans

II. Role of Public Programs

III. Improving the Quality and Efficiency of Health Care

IV. Prevention of Chronic Disease and Improving Public Health

V. Health Care Workforce

VI. Transparency and Program Integrity

VII. Improving Access to Innovative Medical Therapies

VIII. Community Living Assistance Services and Supports

IX. Revenue Provisions1

We outline here the structure and many of the key provisions in these nine

Titles.

Title I reforms the business and underwriting practices of insurance companies

and overhauls their health insurance products. Title I requires that private insurers

change their practices and products and offer new and better health insurance policies

for consumers. Title Is hefty insurance reforms include: (1) elimination of preexisting

1
There is also a tenth Title dedicated to amendments to these nine Titles. Although the
amendments are actually located in Title X, we list the substance of the amendments under the
Title being amended.
i
conditions exclusions for children immediately, Act 1201, 1255 (as re-numbered

by 10103(f)), 10103(e));2 (2) elimination of preexisting conditions for adults in

2014, 1201, 1255 (as re-numbered by 10103(f)); (3) elimination of annual and

lifetime limits on benefits, 1001, 10101(a); (4) required coverage for preventive

services, 1001; (5) immediate extension of dependent coverage up to age 26, 1001;

(6) imposition of a cap on insurers administrative costs in relation to their claims-

payments (the medical loss ratio), 1001, 10101(f); (7) prohibition on excessive

waiting periods to obtain coverage, 1251, 10103(b); (8) guaranteed issue of

coverage and guaranteed renewability in 2014, 1201, 1255 (as re-numbered by

10103(f)(1)); (9) prohibition on rescission except on limited grounds, 1001; (10)

prohibition of coverage denial based on health status, medical condition, claims

experience, genetic information, or other health-related factors, 1201; (11)

community-rated premiums, 1201; (12) prohibition of discrimination based on

salary, 1001, 10101(d); (13) development and utilization of uniform explanation

of coverage documents and standardized definitions, 1001; (14) coverage appeals

process, 1001, 10101(g); and (15) insurance offerings for persons who retire before

age 65, 1102.

2
In this Appendix, we provide citations to the sections of the Act. Our opinions in-depth
discussion of the contents of specific provisions, however, cites to the sections of the U.S. Code
where each provision is now, or will be, codified.
ii
In addition to requiring insurers to offer new, improved health insurance

products, Title I creates new state-run marketplaces for consumers to buy those new

products, accompanied by federal tax credits and subsidies. Title I establishes state-

administered Health Benefit Exchanges where both individuals and small groups can,

and are encouraged to, purchase health insurance plans through non-profits and private

insurers. 13011421, 1010410105. The Exchanges allow individuals, families,

and small businesses to pool resources together and obtain premium prices

competitive with those of large employer group plans. 1311. The Exchange

provisions include: (1) state flexibility to establish basic health programs for low-

income individuals not eligible for Medicaid, 1331; (2) transitional reinsurance

program for sellers of insurance in the individual and small group markets in each

state, 1341; (3) establishment of a temporary risk corridor program for plans in

individual and small group markets, 1342; (4) refundable premium-assistance tax

credit and reduced cost-sharing for individuals enrolled in qualified health plans,

140102; (5) tax credits for small businesses employee health insurance expenses,

1421; and (6) streamlining of enrollment procedures through the Exchanges,

Medicaid, CHIP, and health subsidy programs, 1413.

Title I next addresses employers. Title I imposes penalties on certain employers

if they do not offer any, or an adequate, health insurance plan to their employees.

iii
1513. Title I contains provisions regarding automatic enrollment for employees

of large corporations, reporting requirements, informing employees of coverage

options, and offering of Exchange-participating health plans through cafeteria plans.

15111515. Miscellaneous Title I provisions include transparency in government,

equity for certain eligible survivors, health information technology enrollment

standards and protocols, and prohibition against discrimination on refusal to furnish

services or goods used to facilitate assisted suicide. 1552, 1553, 1556, 1561.

Title I contains the individual mandate, which requires individual taxpayers

either to purchase health insurance or pay a monetary penalty with their federal tax

return. 1501. Title I includes three exemptions from the mandate and five exceptions

to the penalty, which together exclude many uninsured persons from the individual

mandate. 1501.

Title II shifts the Acts focus to publicly-funded programs such as Medicaid,

CHIP, and initiatives under the Indian Health Care Improvement Act. As to Medicaid,

Title IIs provisions: (1) expand Medicaid eligibility to 133% of the federal poverty

level, 2001; (2) provide Medicaid coverage for former foster children, 2004; (3)

rescind the Medicaid Improvement Fund, 2007; (4) permit hospitals to make

presumptive eligibility determinations for all Medicaid-eligible populations, 2202;

(5) extend Medicaid coverage to freestanding birth center services and concurrent care

iv
to children, 230102; (6) require premium assistance to Medicaid recipients for

employer-sponsored coverage, 2003; (7) provide a state eligibility option for

Medicaid family planning services, 2303; (8) create a Community First Choice

Option for Medicaid, 2401; (9) remove barriers to providing home- and community-

based services through Medicaid, 2402; (10) reauthorize Medicaid programs aimed

at moving beneficiaries out of institutions and into their own homes or other

community settings, 2403; and (11) protect Medicaid recipients of home- and

community-based services against spousal impoverishment, 2404.

As to CHIP, Title II provides enhanced federal support and funding. 2101.

The Act: (1) reauthorizes CHIP through September 2015, 10203; and (2) from

October 2015 through September 2019, increases state matching rates for CHIP by 23

percentage points, up to a 100% cap, 2101. Title II requires states to maintain CHIP

eligibility through September 2019. 2101.

Title II also amends and extends the Indian Health Care Improvement Act

(IHCIA). 10221. The Acts IHCIA amendments, inter alia: (1) make the IHCIAs

provisions permanent; (2) expand programs to address diseases, such as diabetes, that

are prevalent among the Indian population; (3) provide funding and technical

assistance for tribal epidemiology centers; (4) establish behavioral health initiatives,

especially as to Indian youth suicide prevention; and (5) authorize long-term care and

v
home- and community-based care for the Indian health system. 10221; see S.1790,

111th Cong. (2009).

Title IIs provisions also create, or expand, other new publicly-funded programs

that: (1) establish a pregnancy assistance fund for pregnant and parenting teens and

women, 10212; (2) fund expansion of State Aging and Disability Resource Centers,

2405; (3) fund maternal, infant, and early childhood home visiting programs in order

to reduce infant and maternal mortality, 2951; (4) provide for support, education,

and research for postpartum depression, 2952; (5) support personal responsibility

education, 2953; (6) restore funding for abstinence education, 2954; and (7)

require inclusion of information about the importance of foster-care children

designating a health care power of attorney for them as part of their transition planning

for aging out of either foster care or other programs, 2955.

Title III primarily addresses Medicare. Title III establishes new Medicare

programs, including: (1) a value-based purchasing program for hospitals that links

Medicare payments to quality performance on common, high-cost conditions, 3001;

(2) a Center for Medicare & Medicaid Innovation to research and develop innovative

payment and delivery arrangements, 3021; (3) an Independent Payment Advisory

Board to present to Congress proposals to reduce Medicare costs and improve quality,

3403, 10320(b); and (4) a new program to develop community health teams

vi
supporting medical homes to increase access to community-based, coordinated care,

3502, 10321. Title III revises the Medicare Part D prescription drug program and

reduces the so-called donut hole coverage gap in that program.3 3301. Title III

extends a floor on geographic adjustments to the Medicare fee schedule to increase

provider fees in rural areas. 3102.

Other sundry Medicare provisions in Title III include: (1) quality reporting for

long-term care hospitals, inpatient rehabilitation hospitals, and hospice programs,

3004; (2) permitting physician assistants to order post-hospital extended care

services, 3108; (3) exemption of certain pharmacies from accreditation requirements,

3109; (4) payment for bone density tests, 3111; (5) extensions of outpatient hold-

harmless provisions, the Rural Community Hospital demonstration project, and the

Medicare-dependent hospital program, 3121, 312324; (6) payment adjustments

for home health care, 3131; (7) hospice reform, 3132; (8) revision of payment for

power-driven wheelchairs, 3136; (9) payment for biosimilar biological products,

3139; (10) an HHS study on urban Medicare-dependent hospitals, 3142; (11)

Medicare Part C benefit protection and simplification amendments, 3202; and (12)

3
The Medicare Part D donut hole is the gap in prescription drug coverage, where
beneficiaries prescription drug expenses exceed the initial coverage limit but do not yet reach
the catastrophic coverage threshold, meaning beneficiaries must pay 100% of those prescription
drug costs. See 42 U.S.C. 1395w-102(b)(3)(A), (b)(4) (2009). In 2006, the donut hole extended
to yearly prescription drug expenses between $2,250 and $3,600, with values for later years
adjusted by an annual percentage increase. See id.
vii
an increase in premium amount for high-income Medicare Part D beneficiaries,

3308. Title III also includes new federal grants for (1) improving womens health,

3509; (2) health care delivery system research, 3501; and (3) medication

management services in treatment of chronic diseases, 3503.

Title IV concentrates on prevention. Title IV creates the National Prevention,

Health Promotion, and Public Health Council, and authorizes $15 billion for a new

Prevention and Public Health Fund to support initiatives from smoking cessation to

fighting obesity. 4001, 4002. Title IV authorizes new publicly-funded programs for

(1) an oral healthcare prevention education campaign, 4102; (2) Medicare coverage

for annual wellness visits, 4103; and (3) the operation and development of school-

based health clinics, 4101. Title IV also: (1) waives Medicare coinsurance

requirements and deductibles for most preventive services, 4104; and (2) provides

states with an enhanced funds-match if the state Medicaid program covers certain

clinical preventive services and adult immunizations, 4106. Title IV further provides

for: (1) Medicaid coverage of comprehensive tobacco cessation services for pregnant

women, 4107; (2) community transformation grants, 4201; (3) nutrition labeling

of standard menu items at chain restaurants, 4205; (4) reasonable break time for

nursing mothers and a place, other than a bathroom, which may be used, 4207; (5)

research on optimization of public health services delivery, 4301; (6) CDC and

viii
employer-based wellness programs, 4303; (7) advancing research and treatment for

pain care management, 4305; (8) epidemiology-laboratory capacity grants, 4304;

and (9) funding for childhood obesity demonstration projects, 4306.

Title V seeks to increase the supply of health care workers through education

loans, training grants, and other spending. Title V: (1) modifies the federal student

loan program, 5201; (2) increases the nursing student loan program, 5202; and (3)

establishes a loan repayment program for pediatric subspecialists, juvenile mental

health providers, and public health workers who practice in underserved areas, 5203.

Title V also provides for: (1) state health care workforce development grants, 5102;

(2) a national health care workforce commission, 5101; (3) nurse-managed health

clinics, 5208; (4) workforce diversity grants, 5404; (5) training in general,

pediatric, and public health dentistry, 5303; (6) mental and behavioral health

education and training grants, 5306; (7) advanced nursing education grants, 5309;

(8) grants to promote the community health workforce, 5313; (9) spending for

Federally Qualified Health Centers, 5601; and (10) reauthorization of the Wakefield

Emergency Medical Services for Children program, 5603. Title V addresses: (1) the

distribution of additional residency positions, 5503; and (2) rules for counting

resident time for didactic and scholarly activities and in non-provider settings,

550405.

ix
Title VI creates new transparency and anti-fraud requirements for physician-

owned hospitals participating in Medicare and for nursing facilities under Medicare

or Medicaid. Title VI authorizes the HHS Secretary to (1) reduce civil monetary

penalties for facilities that self-report and correct deficiencies, 6111; and (2)

establish a nationwide background-check program for employees of certain long-term

support and service facilities, 6201. Title VI also provides: (1) screening of

providers and suppliers participating in Medicare, Medicaid, and CHIP, 6401; and

(2) new penalties for false statements on applications or contracts to participate in a

federal health care program, 6408.

Title VI also includes the Elder Justice Act, designed to prevent and eliminate

elder abuse, neglect, and exploitation. 6703. Other Title VI provisions include: (1)

dementia and abuse prevention training, 6121; (2) patient-centered outcomes

research funded by a $2 fee on accident or health insurance policies, 6301; (3)

federal coordinating counsel for comparative effectiveness research, 6302; (4)

enhanced Medicare and Medicaid program integrity provisions, 6402; (5)

elimination of duplication between the Healthcare Integrity and Protection Data Bank

and the National Practitioner Data Bank, 6403; (6) reduction of maximum period for

submission of Medicare claims to not more than 12 months, 6404; (7) requirement

for physicians to provide documentation on referrals to programs at high risk of waste

x
and abuse, 6406; (8) requirement of face-to-face encounter before physicians may

certify eligibility for home health services or durable medical equipment under

Medicare, 6407; (9) prohibition on Medicaid payments to institutions or entities

outside the United States, 6505; (10) enablement of the Department of Labor to issue

administrative summary cease-and-desist orders and summary seizure orders against

plans in financially hazardous condition, 6605; and (11) mandatory state use of the

national correct coding initiative, 6507.

Title VII extends and expands the drug discounts through the 340B program.4

7101. Title VII establishes a process for FDA licensing of biological products shown

to be biosimilar or interchangeable with a licensed biological product. 7002.

Title VIII establishes a national voluntary long-term care insurance program for

purchasing community living assistance services and support by persons with

functional limitations. 8002.

Title IX includes: (1) an excise tax on high-premium employer-sponsored health

plans, 9001; (2) an increase in taxes on distributions from individuals health savings

accounts, 9004; (3) increases in the employee portion of the FICA hospital insurance

4
Section 340B of the Public Health Service Act, 42 U.S.C. 256b, establishes a program
whereby HHS enters into contracts with manufacturers of certain outpatient drugs under which
the manufacturers provide those drugs at discounted prices to covered entities generally,
certain enumerated types of federally funded health care facilities serving low-income patients.
Id.; see generally Univ. Med. Ctr. of S. Nev. v. Shalala, 173 F.3d 438, 439 (D.C. Cir. 1999).
xi
tax for employees with wages over certain threshold amounts, 9015; (4) an

additional tax of 3.8% on investment income above certain thresholds to fund

Medicare, 9001, 10901; HCERA 1402; (5) a $2,500 limitation on individuals

health flexible spending accounts under cafeteria plans, 9005; (6) imposition of an

annual fee on manufacturers and importers of branded prescription drugs, 9008; (7)

elimination of the tax deduction for expenses allocable to the Medicare Part D subsidy,

9012; (8) a decrease in the itemized tax deduction for medical expenses, 9013; and

(9) an excise tax on indoor tanning services, 10907. Title IX also provides for: (1)

inclusion of the cost of employer-sponsored health coverage on W-2 forms, 9002;

(2) expansion of information-reporting requirements, 9006; (3) additional

requirements for hospitals to receive charitable designation and tax status, 9007;

(4) a study and report on the effect of the Acts new fees on drug manufacturers and

insurers on veterans health care, 9011; (5) prohibition on health insurers deducting

employee compensation over $500,000, 9014; (6) tax credit for companies with

fewer than 250 employees that are engaged in research on qualifying therapeutic

discoveries, 9023; and (7) establishment of simple cafeteria plans for small

businesses, 9022. Title IX assesses an annual fee on health insurance companies,

which is apportioned among insurers based on a ratio designed to reflect each insurers

share of the net premiums written in the United States health care market. 9010,

xii
10905; HCERA 1406.

xiii

You might also like