World Socialism 51
World Socialism 51
World Socialism 51
56 articles, 2006—2010
Second edition (Fall 2009): Six articles have been added to the first edition,
bringing the total to 46.
I would like to add another recommended site, that of the World
Socialist Party of the United States (of which I am a member) at
www.wspus.org
Third edition (Spring 2010): Five more pieces (four new and one that I had
mislaid) bring the total to 51.
Contents
Asteroid wars
War in Georgia
Section 1
In his famous novel The Grapes of Wrath (Chapter 25), John Steinbeck
miles to take the fruit, but this could not be. How would they buy
oranges if they could drive out and pick them up? And men with
needing the fruit – and kerosene sprayed over the golden mountains.
Burn coffee for fuel in the ships... Dump potatoes in the rivers
and place guards along the banks to keep the hungry people from
fishing them out [with nets]. Slaughter the pigs and bury them...
the sewers. 25 million acres of crops (the area of a square with sides 200
The current depression is the deepest since that of the 1930s, and its
end is not yet in sight. As real wages continue to fall and austerity measures
bite harder, more and more goods will remain unsold. Falling prices and
Steinbeck.
collapse in wholesale prices, were leaving huge tracts to rot in the fields.
Most of these farmers did not allow people in to pick fruit for themselves.
They were afraid that cucumbers and other new crops they were planting
Not only the strawberries went to waste but also the water used to
Bulldozing houses. There have been reports from around the United
States of the destruction of houses, many of them newly built. Most
foreclosed houses can no longer be sold at auction, even for prices as low as
$500. They end up in the hands of banks that see no medium-term prospect
of reselling them and conclude that the cheapest solution is to tear them
down. This happens not only to individual houses but often to whole streets.
complex in California rather than spend the few hundred thousand dollars
Slashing clothes and shoes. In early January 2010, The New York
Times ran a story about two major retail chains, H&M and Wal-Mart,
throwing out unsold clothes in trash bags. First they are made unwearable:
employees are told to slash garments, slice holes in shoes, cut sleeves off
now are.
thing. Their logic was that if they donated it [to charity] people would try to
bring it back to exchange for other merchandise.”
Martha: “Yeah, I used to work at a store where they would rip the bed
sheets, blankets and pillow cases if they couldn’t sell them, then throw them
away... I thought it was dumb. I wanted to take it and donate it, but they
Nat: “I used to work for H&M and hated to cut the clothing [that] I
knew we could have given away to those who needed it. We destroyed
Maryliz: “This just makes me sick. How terrible, especially right now
with people freezing to death. They could have been saved if they had
wouldn’t let the food be donated! Some blather about how that would
devalue the brand, because people would just go to that shelter to eat the
The vintage
Steinbeck finishes Chapter 25 with the passage that gives his book its
title:
“In the eyes of the hungry there is a growing wrath. In the souls of the
people the grapes of wrath are filling and growing heavy, growing heavy for
the vintage.”
There is ample cause for wrath. But wrath is not enough. The
managers who got Maggie so angry have to act as they do. (Otherwise they
won’t remain managers.) The things that Maggie and the others naively see
as use values they have to view solely as potential exchange values. They
loss. The idea of giving people what they need, simply because they need it,
will come into its own once we reorganize society on a different, human
basis.
August 2010
You must have heard the song by Woody Guthrie that begins: “This land is
your land, this land is my land.”
So who does own the land? Over 95 percent of the privately held land
in the United States is owned by just 3 percent of the population. These are
the people who own the land, the industry, the technology — all the means
of life on which we depend. This land is their land.
Apparently Woody Guthrie did know whose land this really is. One
verse of the original song went:
This was one of two verses that were later suppressed, turning a protest
against private property into yet another piece of patriotic drivel.
A brotherhood of Man.
WSPUS website, November 21, 2005
Each year half a million people in India and other tropical countries catch
visceral leishmaniasis, also known as black fever. Infected by the bite of a
sand fly, they rapidly weaken and lose weight before dying with painfully
swollen livers and spleens.
A safe and effective treatment for black fever was found long ago: the
antibiotic paromomycin (cure rate 95%). But the firm that developed it --
Pharmacia, a precursor of Pfizer – shelved it in the 1960s for lack of a
"viable market." What that means is that the people who need it cannot
afford to pay for it. It is simply not profitable for pharmaceutical companies
to fight diseases that afflict the poor. Less than 1% of the new drugs
developed in 1975–99 were for tropical diseases (Joel Bakan, The
Corporation, p. 49).
Lack of effective demand is not the only thing that makes many useful
drugs unprofitable. In general, a capitalist firm can only make big profits by
selling drugs on which it has a patent – that is, an exclusive right to make,
use, and sell a new product for a certain period (in Britain and the US it is 20
or even 25 years). Firms are not interested in making drugs that cannot be
patented, and indeed will go to great lengths to suppress them.
Cancer provides a striking example. The established treatments for
cancer — surgery, radiation, and chemotherapy — are destructive, usually
ineffective, and weaken the body’s natural resistance. Many alternative
therapies that are demonstrably safer and more effective are denounced as
“quackery” and often banned under pressure from those with a vested
interest in the established treatments. One is amygdalin (laetrile), a
carbohydrate that occurs in some 1,200 plants throughout the world. Another
is the simple off-the-shelf chemical hydrazine sulfate (Ralph W. Moss, The
Cancer Industry, Ch. 8, 10). It is precisely the wide availability of such
substances that makes them unpatentable and therefore unprofitable.
Capitalism has been widely celebrated for its capacity for rapid
technological advance. Thus Marx in the Communist Manifesto of 1848:
“The bourgeoisie cannot exist without constantly revolutionizing the
instruments of production.” A century later Joseph Schumpeter declared that
“creative destruction” is “the essential fact about capitalism” (Capitalism,
Socialism and Democracy, 1942). And surely this fact has never been truer
than it is today, in the age of microelectronics and bioengineering?
The technological dynamism of capitalism is undeniable, especially in
comparison with earlier historical formations. This, however, is only half the
story. The functioning of capitalism also entails the shelving or suppression
of many useful inventions. One common cause of neglect is the limited
purchasing power of those who stand to benefit from some discovery, as in
the case of drugs to treat tropical diseases. Another key factor behind the
non-use of inventions is the patents system.
A patent is a legally protected exclusive right to use a new product or
process, valid for a fixed period of time (typically 20—25 years). Patent
rights supposedly belong to “inventors” and promote technological advance
by giving inventors a substantial material interest in the results of their work.
It’s a dubious rationale because most inventors are members of the working
class and the patents on their inventions, like the windfall profits from them,
belong not to them but to their employers. If they’re lucky they might get a
small bonus. They go on inventing things because it gives them satisfaction.
That’s human nature.
Nevertheless, the patents system does encourage companies to employ
research scientists and engineers and in some cases to exploit patented
inventions or license other companies to exploit them. In many other cases,
however, a particular invention is viewed primarily as a threat to profits
from the sale of an existing product, demand for which it would undercut. It
will then seem more profitable not to make the new product while using the
patent to prevent anyone else from making it. According to various studies,
anywhere from 40% to 90% of patents are never used or licensed.
But what if the patent on the unwelcome invention is already owned
by a competitor who plans to exploit it? Even in this situation there is often
some action that can be taken to ward off the threat. Firms interested in
developing new technologies tend to be financially weak and vulnerable.
They may be threatened, paid not to use their patents, or simply taken over,
patents and all. The permutations are endless. There are many ways to skin a
cat, as they say.
Let’s consider a few examples. They are taken from articles by Kurt
Saunders, an expert on business law at California State University, and
Linda Levine, an engineer at Carnegie Mellon University. (The articles are
available at http://www.mttlr.org/voleleven/saunders.pdf and
http://jolt.law.harvard.edu/articles/pdf/v15/15HarvJLTech389.pdf)
* * *
* * *
There are two divergent tendencies in patent law. On the one hand,
patents are recognized as a form of property. An owner of property has the
right to use that property or not at his or her discretion, and this applies to
patents as it does, say, to land. On the other hand, legislators created patent
law for the purpose of promoting technological advance in the public
interest, so should the courts not try to discourage its misuse for the opposite
purpose? Legal reformers like Saunders and Levine advocate changes to
patent law that will strengthen the “public interest” tendency and impede the
suppression of useful inventions.
The provisions of patent law do matter. The law already places certain
restrictions on the rights of patent owners; otherwise inventions would be
suppressed even more thoroughly. So legal reform might have a beneficial
effect. But, as in other areas of industrial regulation, companies will find
means of complying with the letter of any new requirements while thwarting
their spirit. Let us suppose that the owner of a new patent is required to put it
to use within a fairly short time interval or otherwise forfeits the patent (and
Saunders and Levine do not suggest anything nearly as drastic). Could he
not start production of the new product while “sabotaging” it to make sure
sales of the old product would not be affected? For instance, the new product
could be produced on a small scale and in deliberately slipshod fashion, sold
at a very high price with hardly any advertising, and so on.
How much does it really matter if an invention has to wait a few
decades before it is widely applied? Not very much, perhaps, if it’s a new
kind of camera or photocopier. The delay is harder to tolerate if it’s an
effective treatment for a previously incurable disease. And, with global
warming upon us, new sources of environmentally harmless energy and new
devices to raise energy efficiency are a matter of life and death for the
planet. We can’t afford to wait until capitalists finally find it profitable to
make the switch to new technologies. It is high time to put knowledge and
human creativity at the direct disposal of the community.
February 2007
August 2006
April 2007
Even the corporate executives who organize the evil deeds are not
doing evil as a free and deliberate choice. They are required by law to do
whatever is necessary to maximize profits for their shareholders. They
could, of course, give up their positions and join the working class, but you
can understand why so few of them would want to do that! The
shareholders, in turn, do not feel obliged to concern themselves with the
morality of the businesses that provide their dividends. Everywhere we look
we find moral ambiguity. Evil is certainly being done, but no one is clearly
to blame – only the social arrangement that we refer to as a system.
Some of us are lucky enough to come by paid work that allows us the
luxury of a relatively clean conscience. Some are not so lucky. The
appropriate target of our indignation is the system that places people in such
excruciating dilemmas, penalises altruistic impulses, rewards ruthless
egoism and inexorably turns “good guys” (or potential “good guys”) into
“bad guys.” It is only by understanding and changing the system that we can
build a way of life in which heeding the voice of our conscience will not
jeopardise our livelihood and the wellbeing of our families.
August 2007
I can’t trace the original author, but it seems to be a popular motto among
rich “philanthropists”. It has been attributed, in slightly variant wordings, to
steel magnate Andrew Carnegie, oil tycoon J. Paul Getty, New York
“socialite” Brooke Astor, Clint W. Murchison (chairman of Tecon
Corporation) and Kenneth Langone (founder of The Home Depot).
Two questions spring to mind.
First, if these people so hate the smell of manure, why do they keep
piling it up? After all, they are free to stop at any time.
Second, what do they want all that money for anyway? Surely a few
hundred million should suffice to buy all the luxuries anyone could want? So
why chase after the billions?
An addiction to extravagance. One answer is offered by Eric
Schoenberg of Columbia Business School (on the site of Forbes magazine).
Driving your first Rolls Royce is a fantastic experience, he explains, but as
you get used to it you no longer enjoy it so much. So you have to look for
new experiences, which for some reason are always more and more
expensive.
Presumably, an obsession with money spoils the enjoyment of
anything that does not cost a lot of it. The result is an addiction to
extravagance that reinforces the drive to make more money.
And yet the worship of wealth need not wholly exclude other social
values. Many people feel that just being rich is not sufficiently glorious in
itself: in addition, one should “do good”. As a result, some wealthy
individuals wish also to be “great humanitarians and philanthropists”.
There is actually a special business that makes money by selling
“philanthropic” fame. For a fixed sum you can have a concert hall, museum,
hospital, college or whatever named after you (or a relative of yours). For
example, Brown University named its Institute of International Studies,
where I used to work, in honour of Tom Watson of IBM in exchange for $25
million.
The publicity given to large “philanthropic” donations suggests that in
certain circles kudos may now depend on how much money you give as well
as how much you have. It is like the potlatch among the Kwakiutl of western
Canada, where the wealthy gain kudos by making generous gifts.
Guilt feelings?
Very little aid ever reaches the poor, let alone the poorest of the poor.
This is partly due to the practical difficulty that the poorest areas also have
the poorest infrastructure (roads, storage facilities, etc.). But mainly it is
because those who are supposed to distribute the aid sell most of it and
pocket the proceeds.
In some cases, aid goes directly to the rich. Schwartz describes an
“orphanage” run by an American reverend where the “orphans” have parents
who could easily afford to provide for them. The place is really an elite
boarding school. Meanwhile, naïve churchgoers back in the States, most of
them ordinary working people, fork out to support the “poor orphans” they
have “adopted”, send them gifts, and even pay for their college education.
The poor in rich countries give charity to the rich in poor countries.
Schwartz’ most important finding is this. When the flow of food aid
into Haiti increases, the overall result is that malnutrition becomes more
widespread, not less. Why? The great majority of Haitians are small farmers,
dependent on selling food to meet their non-food needs. Typically, natural
disaster prompts the decision to send food aid, but by the time it arrives the
emergency is over and the country may well be right in the middle of a
bumper harvest. The effect is to drive prices down further, causing enormous
misery throughout the rural areas.
It seems commonsense. If you see hungry people on TV, so you give
money to buy and send them food. But capitalism has a perverse logic of its
own that has nothing to do with commonsense. Reactions that ignore that
logic are liable to do more harm than good.
Some experts and charities – notably, Oxfam – advocate aid in the
form of cash transfers. Then food for distribution can be bought locally
instead of imported, strengthening rather than undermining the local peasant
economy. Local supply would also be quicker and easier to organise.
Nevertheless, most aid agencies, and especially those like CARE that
are dependent on Western governments, keep on shipping in food. They
even require their national affiliates to cover operating expenses by selling
part of the food received locally (“monetised food”).
Do they know?
March 2010
Section 2
WORKING TO SURVIVE
Futurologists, Alvin Toffler being the best known, used to herald the
imminent arrival of the "post-industrial society" – an arcadia in which
automation has almost done away with work and our main problem will be
how to cope with an excess of leisure. Indeed, labour productivity has risen
steadily and at an accelerating rate throughout the last century, except for a
blip in the period 1975--85, when labour productivity in the US (though not
in Western Europe) fell slightly. But it is only in a rational (i.e., socialist)
society, where the means of life serve the community as a whole, that higher
productivity will equal less work.
It is not widely recognized that since the 1970s working hours have
tended to rise. There appear to be only two books about recent trends in
working time: Juliet B. Schor, The Overworked American: The Unexpected
Decline of Leisure (BasicBooks, 1992) and Pietro Basso, Modern Times,
Ancient Hours. Working Lives in the Twenty-First Century (translated from
Italian by Giacomo Donis; Verso, 2003). Schor is concerned with the U.S.
and has a reformist approach, while Basso attempts a Marxian analysis and
focuses more on Europe.
Today's young wage and salary workers work longer hours than their
parents and grandparents did at the same age. There is less time not only for
relaxation, hobbies, self-education, and political activity, but even for
parenting, family life, sleep, socializing, and sex – much to the detriment of
our quality of life and physical and emotional health.
It isn't just a matter of the number of hours per day, week, or year.
Working time has been "rationalized" as well as increased. That means
greater intensity of effort and reduced opportunity for rest, social interaction,
and even going to the toilet during the workday (zero "dead time," also
known as the Toyota system). It means "variable" or "flexible" schedules –
flexible for the boss, not the worker – with more night and weekend work to
keep costly machinery in nonstop operation. Many couples now meet only to
hand over the kids as they change shifts. And while some are mercilessly
overworked, others are thrown out of work altogether, all in the name of
profitability.
Working time has gone through some dramatic ups and downs in the
course of history. Chattel slaves, of course, were forced to work long hours,
though not always as long as wage slaves in the early days of capitalism,
when 14 or even 16-hour days and 7-day weeks (i.e., 5,000 hours a year or
more) were imposed on children and adults alike. Medieval peasants, by
contrast, had led a more leisurely life. Thanks largely to the numerous
holidays of the church calendar, according to four studies of Britain in the
13th to 16th centuries they typically worked 2,000 hours a year or less. The
working hours of "primitive" tribal people also tend to be relatively short.
Capitalist "progress" put paid to such idleness.
In the mid-19th century working hours stood at about 3,500 hours a
year (according to studies of Britain in 1840 and the U.S. in 1850). In
England the Ten Hours Bill (May 1, 1848) brought the work week down to
60 hours in the countryside (where the Sabbath was enforced) and 70 hours
in the cities (where it was not). For decade after decade the working class
movement struggled for the 8-hour day, but it was not achieved until after
World War One. Children were finally taken out of the mines and factories
and put in school. Eventually the weekend and annual vacation came
(though not for all). By the late 1940s the typical work year in most
"developed" countries was down below 2,000 hours – just about where it
had been in the Middle Ages.
After this the story varies somewhat from country to country. In
France and Germany, where the trade unions fought for "work sharing" and
the 35-hour week, the postwar decades saw a further modest decline in
working hours. Paid vacations are much longer in these countries than in the
U.S. and Japan. In the U.S. working hours were stable in the 1950s and
1960s, only to start rising again in the 1970s: the average work week
increased by almost three hours between 1973 and 1997. In Britain the rise
in hours appears to have levelled off in recent years. According to the U.K.
Labour Force Survey, the proportion of employed persons usually working
over 45 hours a week rose from 21% in 1991 to 24% in 1997 and then fell to
19% in 2003.
American activists make a great deal of the contrast between the U.S.
and Europe and point to Europe as a model for the U.S. to emulate.
However, the same processes are underway in Europe, and indeed
throughout the world, even though they are more advanced in the U.S. and
Japan. (And in China the 11 or 12-hour day is standard.) Only certain groups
of European production workers ever won the 35-hour week. For example,
German metalworkers and typographers won an agreement for the 35-hour
week in 1984, though it did not come into force until 1995. In exchange they
had to accept intensified work regimes and "flexible" hours, including
weekend work. Moreover, the employers have since launched a largely
successful counteroffensive against reduced working hours.
Why are working hours rising and what can we do about it?
Some commentators blame "consumerism" and the "work and spend
cycle". No doubt there are those who overwork, often in two full-time jobs,
for the sake of conspicuous consumption – "to keep up with the Joneses".
But the usual pattern is probably for people to work more in an effort to
preserve their accustomed standard of living despite another trend of the last
quarter century: the decline in real wages. Many overwork to save for their
children's education or for retirement, although the overwork makes it much
less likely that they'll survive to enjoy their "nest egg". And many have to
overwork just to make ends meet or under pressure from their employers
(e.g., compulsory overtime). Managers are especially vulnerable to such
pressure: thanks to the cell phone, they can be called upon at any time and
are thereby deprived of any guaranteed non-working time.
One important part of the explanation must be that it is cheaper for
employers to hire a small number of employees to work long hours than it
would be to divide up the available work among a larger number of
employees. Many labour-related costs – training, administration, fringe
benefits – depend on the number of employees, not total employee-hours. So
"downsizing" is always an appealing way of quickly improving a firm's
profitability and competitive position. Long hours also have the advantage
of making workers more dependent on a specific employer and therefore
easier to control.
So could reforms change the incentive structure for both employers
and employees in favour of shorter hours? Suggestions include improving
the status of part-time work, abolishing higher rates for overtime, and
banning compulsory overtime. Tax incentives could be devised for
spreading available work more thinly. In principle such changes might have
a certain effect. But if capitalists were to come under strong pressure from a
reformist government in one country to shorten hours, they would surely
move their assets elsewhere, as they already do to escape unwelcome
regulation of other kinds.
Historical evidence does point to a clear relationship between working
time and the willingness of workers and their organizations to fight for its
reduction. Reduced hours have never flowed automatically from increased
productivity. They have been won though long and intense struggle. And in
today's world the struggle has to be waged on a global scale – not for the
"right to work" but for the right to live, which includes the right to leisure.
Or, to borrow the title of a classic pamphlet by Marx's son-in-law Paul
Lafargue, the right to be lazy.
May 2006
We socialists like to refer to wage labor as “wage slavery” and call workers
“wage-slaves”. Non-socialists may assume that we use these expressions as
figures of speech, for rhetorical effect. No, we use them literally. They
reflect our view of capitalist society.
Socialists use the word “slavery” in a broad sense, to encompass both
chattel slavery and wage slavery as alternative ways of exploiting labor. We
are aware of the differences between them, but we also want to draw
attention to their common purpose. Capitalist language conceals this
common purpose by equating chattel slavery with slavery as such and by
conflating wage labor with free labor. Socialists regard labor as free only
where the laborers themselves individually or collectively own and control
the means by which they labor (land, tools, machinery, etc.).
Why chattel slavery was abandoned
It may be objected that wage workers are not slaves because they have
the legal right to leave a particular employer, even if in practice they may be
reluctant to use that right out of fear of not finding another job.
All that this proves, however, is that the wage worker is not the slave
of any particular employer. According to Marx, the owner of the wage-slave
is not the individual capitalist but the capitalist class – “capital as a whole”.
Yes, you can leave one employer, but only in order to look for a new one.
What you cannot do, lacking as you do all other access to the means of life,
is escape from the thrall of employers as a class – that is, cease to be a wage-
slave.
Intermediate forms
It doesn’t apply to me
If you are fortunately situated, you may feel that my argument doesn’t
apply to you. Your boss or manager treats you well, you do not suffer insult
or assault, you are satisfied with your working conditions, and the work
itself may even give you satisfaction. You at least are not a wage-slave.
Or so you imagine. Some chattel slaves – in particular, the personal
servants of kind masters and mistresses -- also had the good fortune to be
treated well. But they had no guarantee that their good fortune would
continue. They might be sold to or inherited by a cruel new master following
the old master’s death, departure or bankruptcy. You too may suddenly find
yourself with a nasty new boss or manager. The matter is out of your hands,
precisely because you are only a wage-slave.
If you are a technical specialist, a scientist or analyst of some kind,
you may even say: “What sort of slave can I be? I am not ordered about all
the time. On the contrary. I was hired for my expertise and I am expected to
think for myself, solve problems and offer suggestions. True, I can’t make
important decisions by myself, but my bosses are always willing to listen to
me. And they are always polite to me.”
You are deluding yourself. I know because I have been in a similar
situation and deluded myself. Your bosses listen to you before they come to
a decision. Once they make a decision, they expect you to accept it. But
suppose you once forget yourself (which means -- forget your place) and
continue to argue against a decision that has already been made. Then you
are in for a rude shock!
What makes your delusion possible is that you have grown
accustomed to analyze problems from your employer’s point of view. You
are every bit as alienated from your own thinking as the assembly line
worker is from his or her physical movements. And if a process that you
think up is patented, do you imagine that the patent will belong to you?
May 2010
May 2006
Labour in hell: mining sulphur in Indonesia
* * *
* * *
Why, in our high-tech age, does a horrible job like sulphur mining
have to be done by such primitive means, by the hard labour of “human
donkeys”? Surely it could be mechanized? I see no technical barrier. A
socialist society, to the extent that it needed to mine sulphur at all, would
certainly mechanize the process.
One idea that springs to mind is to use specialized robots. A major
advantage of robots is that they can be designed to function in environments
hostile to human beings, such as the surface of another planet. And being
inside a volcanic crater is rather like being on another planet. In both cases
the atmosphere is unsuitable for human respiration. In fact, there are thought
to be “solphatara-like environments” on Mars.
Probably sulphur could be extracted from volcanoes perfectly well by
much less sophisticated mechanical means. It would suffice to extend the
pipes over (or, if necessary, through) the crater wall and empty them into
sealed tanks mounted on trucks. Possibly some pumping would be required.
The engineers installing the system would be properly equipped with
protective clothing and oxygen cylinders. Such an investment is evidently
considered unprofitable. That reflects the low value – close to zero – that the
profit system places on the health, welfare and lives of the poor.
Despite its enormous and growing potential, the scope for applying
technology within capitalism is limited. A key constraint is the availability
of cheap labour, which reduces the savings from mechanization below the
level of its costs. When operations are transferred to regions where labour
costs are lower, the result is likely to be regression to more primitive
technologies.
One striking example is shipbreaking – the dismantling of
decommissioned vessels to recover the steel. In the 1970s this was a highly
mechanized industrial operation carried out at European docks. Ships are
now broken at “graveyards” on beaches in countries such as India, Pakistan,
Bangladesh and Turkey, where workers labour with rudimentary tools,
wearing little or no protective gear despite exposure to toxic fumes, gas
explosions and fires, asbestos dust and falling pieces of metal.
* * *
March 2008
We all know that tobacco harms those who smoke it. Few are aware of the
damage it does to those who pick and process it.
The “children’s organisation” Plan International recently issued a
report about children in Malawi, some as young as five, who toil up to
twelve hours in the tobacco fields for an average daily wage of 11 p. (Hard
Work, Long Hours and Little Pay: Research with Children Working on
Tobacco Farms in Malawi).
The finding that has attracted most attention is that these children are
being poisoned by the nicotine “juice” they absorb through the skin – and
also ingest, as they have no chance to wash hands before eating. Many of the
ailments that plague them -- headaches, abdominal and chest pain, nausea,
breathlessness, dizziness – are symptoms of Green Tobacco Sickness.
But much of their suffering has nothing to do with nicotine. All have
blisters on their hands. All have pains – in the shoulders, neck, back, knees –
caused by overexertion of their immature muscles. About a third of the
children are coughing blood, which suggests TB.
Many of the children examined had been beaten, kicked or otherwise
physically abused by estate owners or supervisors. Many of the girls had
been raped by them. One boy had deep knee wounds as a result of being
made to walk across a stony field on his knees as punishment for “laziness”.
Who are these estate owners?
Commercial tobacco farming in Malawi began late in the 19th century,
when it was the British colony of Nyasaland. White settlers seized much of
the best arable land for plantations of tea, coffee, tung trees (for their oil,
used as a wood finisher) and – mostly -- tobacco. Even today the majority of
owners of large estates are descendants of the colonial settlers, although now
there are also black owners.
In 1948 some tung and tobacco plantations (estates) were taken over
by the Colonial Development Corporation, funded mainly by the British
Treasury. After Malawi gained formal independence in 1964, these came
under state ownership. Later they were reprivatised. Another recent change
is the direct acquisition of some estates by international tobacco companies.
The estates were established on land stolen from traditional peasant
communities. The process began in colonial times but continued even after
independence, under the Banda regime. Land theft impoverishes local
communities and compels those worst affected to offer themselves – or their
children! – to the estate owners as wage slaves.
Tobacco is also grown on many small family farms. Here too,
children work and suck in nicotine juice, alongside their parents.
Malawi’s tobacco market is dominated – through subsidiaries -- by
two international corporations, Universal Corporation and Alliance One
International. These corporations operate a cartel, refusing to compete and
colluding to keep tobacco purchase prices low. This in turn intensifies the
pressure on farm owners to minimise costs by exploiting cheap or free child
labour – a practice that the corporations hypocritically claim to oppose.
Representatives of the corporations sit on several committees that
advise the government of Malawi on economic policy. By this means they
ensure that their interests are served and block any initiatives to diversify the
economy and reduce the country’s dependence on tobacco.
The main reason why child labour is so prevalent in Malawian
agriculture is the poverty – in particular, land hunger -- of most of the rural
population. This reflects not any absolute shortage of land but rather the
highly skewed pattern of land ownership. Large tracts of land lie fallow on
the big estates.
Environmental degradation
Section 3
POLITICS IN VARIOUS
COUNTRIES
* * *
What makes the political positions of a candidate acceptable or
unacceptable to the media owners?
They would certainly judge any opposition to the capitalist system
unacceptable. But the limits are in fact much narrower than that. In order to
pass the test a candidate must not convey an “anti-corporate message” or
challenge any significant corporate interest. That means in effect that he or
she cannot advocate any serious reform.
I reached this conclusion by observing what happened to the most
“left-wing” of the Democratic Party candidates – Dennis Kucinich, the
Congressional Representative for Cleveland. Kucinich is not against
capitalism, though unlike the general run of American politicians he appears
to be independent of specific business interests. (As mayor of Cleveland he
resisted pressure to privatize the city’s public utility system.) Like Franklin
D. Roosevelt in the 1930s, with whose tradition he associates himself, he
aspires to “save capitalism from itself” by instituting long-overdue reforms.
He was the only candidate to stand for a “single-payer” system of healthcare
finance that would eliminate the parasitic health insurance companies.
Similarly, he was the only candidate to challenge the military-industrial
complex by calling for big cuts in “defence” spending. These reforms are
readily justified in capitalist terms, as essential to restore the
competitiveness of U.S. civilian industry.
The media did their best to ignore Kucinich, except to ridicule him as
a “kook” because, like Carter and Reagan, he says he once saw a UFO. The
networks excluded him from TV debates, even when that required changing
their own rules. (He sued NBC, but the courts upheld its right to exclude
him.) As a result most Americans were unaware of his candidacy, although
polls indicate that the policies he advocates enjoy wide support. In January
he withdrew from the race, but has managed to hold onto his seat in
congress.
* * *
April 2008
Does that mean that all American politicians are the same? That there
is no significant difference between Democrats and Republicans, “liberals”
and “conservatives”?
Not at all.
Different politicians rely on different sponsors. Each represents a
specific mix of big business interests. In general, for instance, Republicans
have closer connections with the oil corporations, Democrats with Wall
Street.
Different politicians also use different kinds of rhetoric and have
different approaches to government. Conservative Republicans ignore
popular grievances and try to distract people by exploiting their fears (of
“communism,” “socialism,” “radicalism,” terrorism, Islam, foreigners, etc.)
and by waving the U.S. flag. Democrats, especially liberal Democrats,
convey the impression that they understand and care deeply about the daily
troubles of ordinary people – perhaps even deeply enough to do something
about them (that’s where things start to get fuzzy). Some of them maintain
links with trade unions. For them too, however, business connections are
more important.
In April 2009, interviewers working for the Rasmussen agency asked 1,000
people: ‘Which is a better system – capitalism or socialism?’ 53% said
capitalism, 20% socialism, and 27% were not sure.
Although ‘capitalism’ came out the clear winner, commentators were
shocked that almost half the respondents failed to give the ‘correct’ response
on a matter so crucial to the dominant ideology.
The interviewers did not define ‘capitalism’ or ‘socialism’, so we are
left to guess what respondents understood by these words. No doubt most of
those who answered ‘socialism’ did not have a clear or accurate idea of what
it means. Nevertheless, socialists can take encouragement from the evident
ability of a sizeable proportion of people to resist indoctrination by the
corporate media, which never have anything good to say about any kind of
‘socialism’. Even the fact that so many Americans do not react negatively to
the S-word itself is significant: people who do not take fright at the word are
more likely to be open to consideration of the idea.
A clue to how Americans interpret ‘capitalism’ is found in another
Rasmussen poll (May 2009). Here people were asked: ‘Is a free market
economy the same as a capitalist economy?’ 35% replied yes, 38% no. This
result puzzled the hired ideologists of capital, who do equate the two
concepts and like to use ‘the free market’ as a euphemism for ‘capitalism’.
Yet another poll (December 2008) asked: ‘Which is better – a free
market economy or a government-managed economy?’ 70% preferred a
‘free market economy’ and only 15% a ‘government-managed economy’.
This implies that there is a substantial body of people (about 17%) who are
in favour of ‘the free market’ but against ‘capitalism’.
In the US ‘capitalism’ is widely associated with big business and ‘the
free market’ with small business. Hatred for big business commonly goes
along with admiration for small business. In the frequent polls that compare
the approval ratings of various occupational groups, small business owners
regularly come out on top, while corporate CEOs (together with politicians)
end up at the bottom.
Those who are ‘against capitalism but for the free market’ are,
perhaps, still influenced by the old populist idea of the good society as a
relatively egalitarian community of small independent producers – farmers,
fishermen, craftsmen, doctors, etc. This utopia has its roots in an idealised
image of early rural colonial society in New England and Pennsylvania,
before its transformation by industrial capitalism.
Why?
In American Fascists: The Christian Right and the War on America (Free
Press, 2006), Chris Hedges warns of the danger presented by the section of
the U.S. political spectrum usually known as the Christian right – a danger
Billy Graham, he points out, were concerned with saving souls not politics)
literal Word of God, that denounces all opponents as servants of Satan and
The dominionists are hostile to real science and deny global warming
even though they too used the Christian label. Dominionist symbols are
Comparing the new Christian fascists with the Ku Klux Klan, for
instance, we find that each focuses on a quite different set of enemies. They
renounce hatred for blacks, Catholics and Jews – the three bugbears of
Christians across racial lines, work with Catholics on issues such as abortion
and prayer in schools, and cultivate a close alliance of convenience with the
two groups. The main targets of their hostility are those they call “secular
fleecing their flocks, who pay a “tithe” of 10% of income in addition to other
Amway founder Richard DeVos and beer baron Joseph Coors. Finally, the
Bush Administration, with which they had close ties through the Council for
National Policy, enabled them to tap federal funds for “faith-based” social
service initiatives – an arrangement that Obama has left intact.
who support the dominionists care all that deeply about religious dogma.
Indeed, for the preachers themselves religion is, apart from anything
else, a highly lucrative business. Their opulent lifestyles suggest that they
divert a significant portion of the various cash flows into their own bank
instance, Jesus’ well-known remark about the camel who tried to pass
In his book Hedges describes how vulnerable people are recruited into
church offers an illusion of community and the victim snatches at the bait,
only later to discover, when escape has become very difficult, that he or she
offers no hope of a more communal way of life that might counter the
fascism.
(CPRF) in St. Petersburg, “sounds the tocsin to warn of the danger of the
Volobuyev explains that Russian fascists have been arguing for a long
time on their websites about “what to do with the CPRF.” Some said that
they should just put communists “up against the wall”, but others argued that
they should first join the CPRF and take over its structures. In recent years,
and losing legal status, “fascists and people inclined toward fascism
streamed into the CPRF.” There they found many party leaders “demoralised
by the collapse of the Soviet Union” and sympathetic to their cause. With
the help of these leaders, they “were able to create an unofficial fascist
faction inside the CPRF” (officially the party does not allow factions). They
The infiltrators would have been less successful had the ground not
been so well prepared for them. Ever since the CPRF was founded in 1993,
by Gennady Zyuganov. Until now, however, the party also had a place for
Mass expulsions
That is now changing. The fascist faction, acting through its allies in
the party leadership, is carrying out individual and mass expulsions with a
view to purging the CPRF of all opponents of Russian nationalism: “The
branches, such as the one to which Volobuyev belongs, have been targeted
branded as enemies of the Russian nation. Many party members are also
Volobuyev remarks, because with hardly any exceptions they have never
read Trotsky and have no idea what Trotskyism is, let alone neo-Trotskyism.
But the Russian nationalists know that Trotsky was the most prominent
opponent of Stalin, whom they count as one of their own. And they know
“Communist” oligarchs
The nationalists and fascists in the CPRF are allied with various party
figures – all of ethnic Russian origin, of course – who are also big
businessmen (“oligarchs” in current Russian parlance). One such figure is
and vodka tycoon Sergei Shtogrin, currently deputy chairman of the Duma
They believe that a “mistake” has been made and that “if they appeal to
members and even branch organizers still look to leaders for guidance and
initiative. They take pride in the awards they receive from the leaders and
are chastened by their reprimands – just like in the good old days of the
“Soviet” regime.
in other ways too. Arbitrary decisions can be made to expel members and
What next?
takeover of the CPRF, what are the likely consequences for Russian politics?
The CPRF will lose many of its local activists and depend increasingly on
expelled from the CPRF. These people do not share the same views except
socialism.
The fight against the system of racial segregation and white supremacy
called apartheid (“apartness” in Afrikaans) was one of the great liberal and
left-wing causes of my generation. It was a fight not only for political
democracy in South Africa but also for socio-economic reform. The
Freedom Charter, adopted by the African National Congress in 1955
(www.anc.org.za), called for “restoring national wealth to the people”
(understood as nationalization of the mines, banks and “monopoly
industry”), “re-dividing the land among those who work it to banish famine
and land hunger,” improved pay and working conditions, free healthcare,
universal literacy, and decent housing for all.
Apartheid as a political and legal system was dismantled in the early
1990s. South Africa’s capitalists did not on the whole object. Apartheid had
brought them immense profits from the exploitation of a cheap captive labor
force. But it had its drawbacks. By denying training and advancement to a
large majority of the workforce, it created a growing shortage of skilled
labor. Capitalists are often willing to accept a measure of social change,
provided that they can set its limits.
Although apartheid is gone, economically South Africa is still one of
the most unequal countries in the world. Almost all the land, mines and
industry remain in the same (mostly white) hands. Almost half the
population lives below subsistence level. Unemployment is widespread;
children scavenge on dumps and landfill sites from sunrise to sunset seven
days a week. Life expectancy is falling (a drop of 13 years since 1990) as
AIDS, drug-resistant TB and other diseases spread.
Even segregation still exists in practice. The wealthy take shelter in
“gated communities” from the violence pervading the shantytowns. As the
wealthy are no longer exclusively but only predominantly white, the proper
name for this is class rather than race segregation.
True, efforts have been made to improve living conditions. Close to
two million new homes have been built. Whether they count as “decent
housing” is another matter.) Water, telephone and electricity networks have
been expanded. But while millions were rehoused, millions were also
evicted for rent arrears. Nine million people were connected to the water
supply, but during the same period ten million were disconnected as the
price rose out of their reach.
* * *
How did the main reform goals of the Freedom Charter come to be
abandoned? Political journalist William Mervin Gumede tells the story in his
book Thabo Mbeki and the Battle for the Soul of the ANC (Cape Town:
Zebra Press 2005).
While political negotiations, conducted in the glare of publicity,
moved the ANC toward government office, parallel and almost unpublicized
economic negotiations, led on the ANC side by Thabo Mbeki (now
president), ensured that when the ANC did take office it would be unable to
act against white business interests. A new clause of the constitution made
all private property sacrosanct. Power over economic policy was ceded to an
“autonomous” central bank and international financial institutions.
“The ANC found itself caught in a web made of arcane rules and
regulations. As the web descended on the country only a few people even
noticed it was there, but when the new government tried to give its voters
the tangible benefits they expected the strands of the web tightened and [it]
discovered that its powers were tightly bound” (Klein, pp. 202-3).
The ANC hierarchy came under “relentless pressure” from local and
international business, the (business-controlled) media, foreign politicians,
the World Bank and IMF, etc. It was “an onslaught for which the ANC was
wholly unprepared” (Gumede, p. 72). This does not mean that crude
demands and threats played a crucial role. It was a process more of
seduction than intimidation, aimed at integrating a set of new partners into
the institutional structure and social milieu of the global capitalist class.
This meant providing opportunities for ANC officials to go into
business or train at American business schools and investment banks.
Leading figures were lavished with hospitality: “Harry Oppenheimer
[former chairman of Anglo American Corporation and De Beers
Consolidated Mines] was eager to entertain Mandela at his private estate,
while Anglovaal’s Clive Menell hosted him for Christmas (1990) at his
mansion… While separated from his wife, Mandela’s home for several
months was the palatial estate of insurance tycoon Douw Steyn… His
daughter Zinzi had a honeymoon partly financed by resort and casino king
Sol Kerzner, and Mandela spent Christmas 1993 in the Bahamas as a guest
of Heinz and Independent Newspapers chairman Sir Anthony O’Reilly”
(Gumede, p. 72).
It seems churlish to begrudge Mandela a little luxury after 27 years in
prison. But what were his benefactors’ motives?
However, the most effective form of capitalist influence was the
impersonal pressure of “the markets.” As Mandela told the ANC’s 1997
national conference: “The mobility of capital and the globalization of the
capital and other markets make it impossible for countries to decide national
economic policy without regard to the likely response of these markets”
(Klein, p. 207). And the markets punished the slightest sign of deviation
from the “Washington consensus” with capital flight and speculation against
the rand.
Mbeki was the first to grasp what was needed to win the markets’
confidence. Precisely in order to live down its “revolutionary” and “Marxist”
past, the ANC leaders had to prove themselves more Catholic than the pope.
“Just call me a Thatcherite” – quipped Mbeki as he unveiled his new “shock
therapy” program in 1996. South Africa could not afford the protectionist
measures with which Malaysia, for instance, warded off the Asian financial
crisis of 1997. Orthodoxy, however, was never rewarded with the hoped-for
flood of foreign investment. The markets are stern taskmasters: they demand
everything and promise nothing.
It is not altogether fair to say that Mandela or Mbeki “sold out.” They
simply saw no escape from the “web” spun by global capital. Indeed, at the
national level there is no escape. Reformers in other countries, such as the
Solidarity movement in Poland and Lula’s Workers’ Party in Brazil, have
gone through much the same experience on reaching office. Socialists have
long said that socialism cannot be established in a single country. Now we
also know that under conditions of globalization even a meaningful program
of reform cannot be implemented in a single country.
Capital is global. That is its trump card against any attempt to defy its
dictates that is confined within national boundaries. The resistance to capital
must also be organized on a global scale if it is to have any chance of
success.
March 2008
It's now 110 years since Theodor Herzl wrote Der Judenstaat (The State of
the Jews) and launched the Zionist movement, nearly 60 since the state he
envisaged came into being. Upset by the Dreyfus case (Dreyfus was a
French Jewish army officer framed as a spy for Germany), Herzl had
concluded that Jews would only be safe when they had a state of their own.
As they ran for the shelters during the war with Hezbullah, Israelis
may well have wondered whether there is any country in the world where
Jews are less safe. And although the Israeli government keeps emigration
statistics secret, it is estimated that since 2003 more Jews have been seeking
refuge by leaving Israel than by entering it. Thoughtful Israelis may also
wonder how much of the antisemitism in the world today is generated by
Israel itself through its mistreatment of Palestinians and Lebanese.
Zionists are always complaining about antisemitism, real or
imaginary. They use such complaints especially as a gambit to de-legitimise
criticism of Zionism and Israel. From the start, however, Zionist opposition
to anti-semitism has been superficial and selective, because Zionism is itself
closely connected to anti-semitism. Zionists need antisemitism like heroin
addicts need a fix.
That’s how it’s been from the start. Herzl realised that if his project
was to succeed he had to seek support wherever it might be found. And who
was more likely to back his movement than the antisemites? Not the most
extreme antisemites, who wanted to exterminate the Jews, but "moderate"
ones who would be content to get rid of them. And so Herzl set off for
Russia to sell his idea to the tsar's minister of police, Plehve, a notorious
antisemite widely regarded as responsible for the Kishinev pogrom of 1903.
An opportunistic alliance with another antisemitic ruler of Russia –
Stalin – was crucial to the establishment of the state of Israel. On Stalin's
instructions, Czechoslovakia provided arms and training that enabled the
fledgling Zionist armed forces in Palestine to win the war of independence
in 1947-48. Stalin's motive was to undermine the position of Britain in the
Middle East. For some years the Israeli government continued to rely on
Soviet military and diplomatic support, while keeping silent about the
persecution of Soviet Jews, then at its height. (For more on this episode, see
Arnold Krammer, The Forgotten Friendship: Israel and the Soviet Bloc,
1947-53, University of Illinois, 1974.)
In 1953 the Israeli-Soviet alliance finally broke down. Israel switched
to the other side of the Cold War, obtaining aid first from France and then
from the US. Alliance with "the West" also entailed maintaining good
relations with antisemitic regimes, notably in Latin America. Consider
Argentina: a disproportionate number of Jews were among those killed,
imprisoned and tortured by the military junta that ruled the country from
1976 to 1983. Given the "anti-democratic, anti-semitic and Nazi tendencies"
of the Argentine officer corps, we may assume that they were persecuted not
merely as political opponents but also as Jews. Meanwhile a stream of
Israeli generals passed through Buenos Aires, selling the junta arms. (See
http://www.jcpa.org/jpsr/jpsr-mualem-s04.htm and
http://www.thirdworldtraveler.com/Terrorism/Argentina_STATUS.html;
also Jacobo Timmerman's book Prisoner Without a Name, Cell Without a
Number.)
But it is not just a matter of Zionists and antisemites sometimes
having strategic or business interests in common. There are ideological
affinities. Zionists, like antisemites, are mostly racists and nationalists for
whom it is abnormal that an ethnic group should live dispersed as a minority
in various countries. It is therefore natural and only to be expected if the
majority reacts badly to such an anomaly. There is a strong tendency in
Zionism to agree that Jews have objectionable traits, which are to be
overcome as they turn themselves into a normal nation by settling in
Palestine "to rebuild the land and be rebuilt by it."
What if the Jews in a given country are well integrated, face no
significant antisemitism, and show no interest in being "normalized"?
Originally Zionism was conceived as a means of solving the problem of
antisemitism. From this point of view, where the problem does not exist
there is no need for the solution. However, ends and means were inverted
long ago, and Zionism became an end in itself, with antisemitism a condition
of its success. Antisemitism might still be regarded in principle as an evil,
but as a necessary evil. Often it was also said to be a lesser evil compared to
the threat of assimilation supposedly inherent in rising rates of intermarriage.
Against this background, it seems a trifle naive to ask why Israel's
ruling circles don't realise that by their own actions they are generating
antisemitism. They realise. But they make it a point not to give a damn what
the world thinks of them.
There is nothing unique about the affinity between Zionism and
antisemitism. Russian nationalism thrives on Russophobia (the denigration
of Russians), Irish nationalism on anti-Irish prejudice, Islamism on hatred of
Moslems, and so on. To escape the vicious circle, we must respond to ethnic
persecution not by promoting "our own" brand of nationalist or religious
politics, but by asserting our identity as human beings and citizens of the
future world cooperative commonwealth.
January 2007
* * *
Observers have called the Gaza Strip "the world's largest open-air
prison" (360 square kilometres), a cage, a concentration camp, now even a
death camp. But a more accurate term for it, as well as for certain areas
administered by the Palestinian Authority on the West Bank, is ghetto. As in
the Jewish ghettoes of Nazi-occupied or late medieval Europe (the first was
established in Venice in 1516), the inhabitants of the Palestinian ghettoes are
confined to closed areas but not directly governed by the dominant power.
They have their own semi-autonomous though dependent institutions. This
usage requires only expanding the concept to cover rural and mixed rural-
urban as well as urban ghettoes. Another parallel that many draw is with the
Bantustans of apartheid South Africa.
While officially Israel indignantly rejects the comparison with
apartheid, former Italian premier Massimo D'Alema revealed that Israeli PM
Sharon had stated at a private meeting that he took the Bantustans as his
model (www.informationclearinghouse.info/article19256.htm). There is no
conflict between the two parallels, as the Bantustan too may be regarded as a
form of ghetto.
Besides its basic political function of confining and controlling a
stigmatized group, a ghetto may perform economic functions. It may provide
capitalists with a captive and therefore cheap labour force. This used to be
an important function of the Palestinian ghettoes. But as 'closure' has
tightened they have lost this function. Palestinians have been replaced in
menial jobs by workers from Romania, Thailand, the Philippines, and West
Africa. The number of unemployed among Israelis has also increased (to
about 200,000). So Palestinian ghetto workers are increasingly superfluous
to the labour needs of Israel's capitalist economy. This gives even more
cause for concern about their fate.
One of the worst miseries inflicted on the hapless residents of the
Gaza Ghetto is sonic booming. The Israeli Air Force flies U.S. F-16 fighter
planes low and fast over the ghetto, generally every hour or two from
midnight to dawn, deliberately creating sonic booms. The noise and the
shockwaves prevent people sleeping, shake them up inside, make their
pulses race, ears ring and noses bleed, cause miscarriages, crack walls, and
smash windows. Children, especially, are terrified and traumatized: they
suffer panic and anxiety attacks, have trouble breathing, wet their beds, lose
appetite and concentration. Many are thrown off their beds, sometimes
resulting in broken limbs. The sonic booming began in October 2005, after
the Jewish settlements were evacuated from Gaza. Since then it has been
periodically suspended but always renewed. An anonymous IDF source
described its purpose as "trying to send a message, to break civilian support
for armed groups." And yet the first wave of booming was followed by the
victory of Hamas in the Palestine Legislative Council elections of January
2006. (The U.S. had ordered free elections, but neglected to give clear
instructions on who to vote for. In view of the harsh punishment for voting
incorrectly, that was most unfair.)
* * *
The image of Maoist China conveyed in the poster art and other propaganda
of the regime was that of a regimented and spartan but egalitarian society,
without hierarchical class distinctions. Curiously enough, anti-Maoist
propaganda conveyed a very similar image: several authors, for instance,
dehumanized the Chinese under Mao as “blue ants.” In accordance with its
egalitarian image, Maoism is commonly classified as a leftwing – indeed,
“extreme left” or “ultra-left” – ideology. The blatant inequalities of post-
Mao China have served only to enhance the image in retrospect.
And yet the image was always an illusion, a meticulously maintained
lie. The rich memoir literature that has become available since the “thaw” of
1978 begins to dispel the illusions and portray the realities of Maoist China.
And one of those realities turns out to be a class structure that differs in
detail but not in broad outline from that of the “old China.”
* * *
* * *
So China under Mao was, like China before Mao and China after
Mao, a class-divided society. And, as in any other class-divided society,
class struggle existed in various forms. However, the real class struggle
between the real classes that made up the society was obscured by
unrelenting official propaganda about an illusory “class struggle” (“Never
forget class struggle!”) that was actually something else entirely.
In Maoist China the authorities assigned every citizen an official
“class” label or political “hat.” A great deal depended on this label, from
political influence and social respect to work assignments and access to
medical care – not to mention the chance of ending up in a labour camp or
on an execution ground. Most labels referred not to current social position
but to the alleged former status of the person or of his or her parents and
grandparents in the old society. Thus, “poor and lower middle peasants”
(“red” categories), “upper middle peasants” (an intermediate category), and
“rich peasants” and “landlords” (“black” categories) were currently all
collective farmers. The harshest treatment (justified as “class struggle”) and
worst jobs were reserved for “landlords,” who became a hereditary caste of
pariahs like the Indian untouchables.
The real function of the labels was to measure the presumed degree of
loyalty to the regime. Party leaders in good standing, irrespective of family
background, belonged to the “red” category of “revolutionary cadre.” Both
prime minister Zhou Enlai and secret police chief Kang Sheng were sons of
big landlords and Mao’s own father was a small landlord, but that did not
count against them. Conversely, worker or poor peasant origin provided very
limited protection to those who challenged party policy: a “class” label
could be arbitrarily changed or the malcontent could be dumped in the catch-
all category of “bad element.”
So we must decode the official “class struggle” as a continuing
campaign to crush all actual and potential dissent. In official discourse
“proletariat” (working class) was a codeword for the regime (or whichever
faction controlled the regime at any given time). When workers in Shanghai
went on strike in 1966--67, they were accused of falling under the influence
of “class enemies wielding the weapon of economism.” In other words, they
were tools of the capitalist class striking against themselves!
* * *
June 2007
Section 4
POPULAR CULTURE
From this I infer that you might be let off smiling duty if a parent rather than
just an uncle has died. You might get a few days’ “family leave.” But when
you return your smile must be firmly back in place.
Besides show business, smiling is a condition of employment in all
service jobs involving contact with the public (and to a lesser extent in many
other jobs). A waiter, air steward, hotel receptionist or croupier, for example,
is expected to keep smiling, however irritating, rude or unpleasant a
customer may be to him or her. “I am just not as good at faking that smile as
I used to be,” bemoans one service worker. So why do we have to smile?
The song lyrics don’t really explain. Smiling is simply required by
fashion:
We are also told: “Smile and the world smiles with you.” In other words,
look unhappy and the world will give you the cold shoulder. I suppose it’s
true to some extent: I have enough troubles of my own, thank you, don’t
burden me with yours! But what does that say about our way of life?
One curious rationale for smiling is the “urban legend” that more
facial muscles are used in frowning than in smiling (exact figures vary).
Smiling saves effort. According to Dr. David H. Song, the claim is false: a
smile uses twelve muscles, a frown only eleven
(http://www.straightdope.com/columns/040116.html). In any case, isn’t
exercising as many different muscles as possible supposed to be good for
us?
If you take Dale Carnegie’s advice and “don’t criticize, condemn or
complain” about anyone or anything, then you will never develop a critique
of the social system or an aspiration to change it. Ultimately, I suspect, that
is what the smile propaganda is about. It serves the interests of those who do
not have much to complain about themselves but who are natural targets of
others’ complaints. That means: the most privileged and powerful section of
society.
August 2007
Section 5
INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS
The first article in this section is devoted to the issue of
globalisation. The other four articles examine how the
shifting pattern of international relations affects different
regions of the world – and outer space! The pattern changes,
but not the dynamic of great power rivalry – until we block it.
* * *
* * *
October 2008
Latin America:
The Changing Geopolitical Context
For close on 200 years the main geopolitical fact about Latin America has
been the overwhelming economic and political domination of the United
States—or, more precisely, of its ruling capitalist class. The wide range of
instruments used to enforce this domination has included frequent direct and
indirect military interventions. One source lists 55 such interventions since
1890.1 Another important instrument has been the foreign policy known as
the Monroe Doctrine, first proclaimed by the U.S. president of that name in
1823.
The gist of the Monroe Doctrine is that the U.S. regards Latin
America as its own exclusive sphere of influence and will not tolerate the
interference of “outside” powers in its affairs. The doctrine was initially
directed against the colonial claims of Spain and France. For most of the
twentieth century it was directed first against Germany and then against
Russia (the USSR). But does it still have any relevance now that Russia’s
ambitions are confined to regions nearer home?
In fact, as the Russian threat to U.S. hegemony in the Americas
receded the doctrine was overtly redirected against another Eurasian
challenger—Japan. On December 20, 1989, the U.S. bombed and invaded
Panama, ostensibly in order to arrest the country’s president, Manuel
Noriega, on drug trafficking charges. The real reason was that Noriega, who
had earlier been willing to serve as an agent of the CIA, had begun to act in
ways that the U.S. considered contrary to its interests.2
One example concerns the School of the Americas, where the U.S.
army trains military officers from all over Latin America as torturers and
assassins. The school had been based in Panama from 1946 to 1984, when it
was withdrawn from the country at the demand of Noriega’s predecessor,
Omar Torrijos.3 Noriega refused to accede to a request from the Reagan
administration to allow the school to return.
Noriega committed an even graver offence in U.S. eyes by entering
into negotiations with a Japanese consortium that the businessman Shigeo
Nagano had put together (with his government’s approval) for the purpose of
financing the construction of a new and better sea-level canal between the
Atlantic and Pacific Oceans or of a new land-based inter-oceanic
transportation system.4 The old Panama Canal, opened in 1914, has
inadequate capacity for the current volume of traffic and cannot
accommodate the largest of today’s seagoing vessels. It was, above all, the
Japanese threat to its control of a strategic transportation route in its
“backyard” that prompted the United States to intervene.
China’s economic penetration of Latin America has been even more
striking than that of Japan. As recently as 1995, for instance, China’s trade
with Brazil was a mere 6% of U.S. trade with Brazil; by 2005—6 it had
reached 39%. In the case of Argentina the corresponding rise was from 15%
to 70%.5 China is still some way behind but catching up fast. Chinese firms
are also investing on a large scale in some countries. Their Brazilian
investments include metals, consumer electronics, telecommunications
equipment, and space technology. China and Brazil are jointly developing
two satellites.
Judging by the whole history of capitalist great power rivalry, we can
expect that sooner or later the shifting pattern of economic relationships will
change the military power equation, with a progressive dilution of U.S.
domination over Latin America. Suppose that at some point in the future
Japanese capitalists and a new Panamanian government revive the scheme
for a new canal. But this time round, learning from experience, they press
the Japanese government—no longer, perhaps, shackled by the “peace
constitution”—to extend Panama military aid and a security guarantee.
Of course, no other state is likely to replace the U.S. as the clear
hegemon in the region. Like Africa and Central Asia today, Latin America
will be an arena in which a number of outside powers compete for influence.
As a declining global power, the U.S. will have to reconcile itself to the new
situation and finally bury the Monroe Doctrine.
For Latin American governments the new geopolitical context will
have certain advantages. They will have more room for maneuver and be
able to play off one outside power against another. Latin American workers,
however, will discover that their basic position remains unchanged despite
the new mix of nationalities among their employers.
Workers in some African countries have already learnt this lesson. In
Zambia, copper mines bought up by Chinese companies provided even
lower pay and even more hazardous working conditions than mines owned
by other foreign companies. Following an explosion in which 49 miners
died, five protestors were shot dead by police. The government temporarily
closed down one mine after men were forced to work underground without
boots or safety gear.6
Social protest in Latin America has traditionally targeted “Yanqui
imperialism,” just as social protest in Eastern Europe used to be aimed
against “Soviet imperialism.” Both are understandable responses to real
oppression—but also parochial and superficial responses. The source of the
oppression is capitalism itself, not the various national flags under which it
operates.
(http://www.scribd.com/doc/2781501/World-Socialist-Review-US-Latin-
America)
Notes
instances were the sponsorship of a (failed) military coup to overthrow President Chavez
2. On the background to the U.S. invasion, see Manuel Noriega and Peter Eisner, The
Hemisphere Institute for Security Cooperation. Torrijos died in a plane crash under
suspicious circumstances.
5. Comparing total value of imports and exports in 1995 and in 2005 and the first 9
* * *
* * *
The alarm with which the media have reacted to the Russian claim on
the Lomonosov Ridge is reminiscent of the Cold War, especially in the
context of other recent tensions between Russia and “the West.”
Nevertheless, it is misleading to talk about a new Cold War or, indeed, about
“the West.” We no longer live in a world of bipolar confrontation between
“East” and “West.” We now live in a multipolar world of fluid alliances
among a fairly large number of powers, some of them rising (e.g., China)
and others in decline (e.g., the U.S.). In certain ways the early twenty-first
century resembles the first half of the twentieth century much more closely
than it does the second.
Nothing illustrates the new-old pattern of multipolarity more clearly
than territorial disputes in the Arctic. Several important disputes do not
involve Russia at all. They are between the other Arctic states, all of which
are still formally allies, fellow members of NATO.
The potentially most serious disputes are, perhaps, those between
Canada and the United States. One concerns the offshore Canada/Alaska
boundary, which traverses an area thought to be rich in oil and gas. The
other dispute is over the straits that separate Canada’s Arctic islands from
one another and from the mainland. Last year the Canadian government
declared that it regarded these straits, which together make up the Northwest
Passage, as Canadian Internal Waters. The US government has made clear
that it still regards the straits as international waters by sending its navy to
patrol them.
Lord Palmerston is famous for his remark that “Britain has no
permanent allies, only permanent interests.” Evidently the same is true of
any capitalist state.
The behaviour of the Arctic states also debunks the widely held idea
that some states are inherently peace-loving and others inherently
militaristic. Many people think of Canada as being in the first category.
They might be perturbed to come across the following Guardian headline:
“Canada flexes its muscles in scramble for the Arctic”
(http://www.guardian.co.uk/environment/2007/jul/11/climatechange.climate
change).
September 2007
Over the last few centuries, one region of the planet after another has been
“opened up” to capitalist plunder. Often rival capitalist powers fought over
the spoils of conquest. In the nineteenth century they had the “scramble for
Africa.” In the twenty-first they are scrambling to control the resources of
the Arctic, which global warming and technological advance are making
accessible to exploitation.
Once the Arctic and Antarctic are brought fully under the sway of
capital, what next? Won’t that be the end of the story, the closing of the last
frontier? There remains space, to be sure. But won’t the costs of extracting
resources and transporting them to earth be prohibitive? So you might think.
In fact, the strategists of the six powers that now have active space
programs – the United States, Russia, the European Union, China, India, and
Japan – already have their sights on the commercial and military potential of
the cosmos.
On 22 October India launched the Chandrayaan-1 satellite, and on 11
November it entered moon orbit. One of its main tasks is to map deposits of
Helium-3 (He-3). This isotope, used together with deuterium (H-2), is the
optimal fuel for nuclear fusion: in particular, it minimises radioactive
emissions. It is very rare on earth – according to one estimate, only 30 kg is
available – because the solar wind that carries it is blocked by the earth’s
atmosphere and magnetic field. The dust and rocks in the moon’s surface
layer contain millions of tonnes of the stuff.
It has been calculated that a single shuttle flight bearing a load of 25
tonnes (currently valued at $100 billion) would meet energy demand in India
for several years or in the U.S. for one year, while three flights a year would
suffice for the world (Guardian, 21 October; Tribune, 23 October).
The main problem is extracting the He-3 as gas from the lunar soil.
This requires heating the soil to a temperature of 800º C. in furnaces or
towers, using solar power. (Silicon for solar cells is also abundant on the
moon.) To collect enough gas for one load, it would be necessary to process
360,000 tonnes of soil. Nevertheless, technologically this is believed to be
feasible; modern furnaces do actually process such huge quantities of
material. Some specialists question whether it would be economically
feasible to strip mine the moon in this way.
Despite uncertainties, Indian strategists hope that the Chandrayaan-1
satellite will enable India to “stake a priority claim” on He-3 resources when
lunar colonization begins (SkyNews). India’s main rivals in this field appear
to be the U.S., which has “re-energised” its moon program and plans to
establish a manned base by 2020, and also China.
Given the abundant supply of He-3 relative to foreseeable demand,
why should India need to compete with other space powers for preferential
access? Surely there is more than enough for everyone.
Yes, but some locations on the moon’s surface are much better for
mining than others. Finding the best locations is the main aim of satellite
exploration.
First, the nature of the terrain will obviously matter when building
bases and installations, whether operated by human workers or robots. It will
be a great advantage to have water (ice) available nearby.
Second, it will be least expensive to work in areas where deposits are
richest, where the smallest amount of soil has to be processed for each unit
of gas extracted.
Third, reliance on solar power for soil heating (and other purposes)
puts a premium on those parts of the lunar surface which are exposed to
sunlight for most of the time.
These are also the warmest regions (by lunar standards). An example
is the Shackleton Crater at the South Pole. India is especially interested in
this area, and it is also here that the U.S. wants to establish its base.
Certain places on the moon are already thought of as “strategic
locations.” Thus, the topography of Malapert Mountain makes it an ideal
spot for a radio relay station. Near the Shackleton Crater, it enhances the
strategic value of the crater area.
Considerations of this kind will become more important in the event
of the moon’s militarisation. This may happen as a result of competition for
land and resources on the moon itself. Or it may happen simply as an
extension of existing military preparations: lunar stations may serve as
reserve command centres for wars on earth.
Even if international agreements are reached to constrain the process
of militarisation and divide the lunar surface into zones belonging to the
various space powers, military threats may arise from “dual use”
technologies. Let us suppose, for instance, that instead of mining He-3 a
space power decides to generate electricity on the moon using solar cells and
transmit it on microwave beams to a receiving station on earth. The problem
– under capitalism – is that these same beams may equally well be used as
powerful weapons against earth targets.
There will also be potential conflict between the space powers and
other countries that for one reason or another are unable to compete in this
sphere. Like the club of nuclear weapons states, the space powers may
constitute themselves as an exclusive club and think up a rationale for joint
efforts to thwart “space power proliferation,” that is, to prevent other
countries from acquiring space capabilities. The two clubs will, of course,
largely overlap.
It is absurd and presumptuous for humanity to venture into the cosmos
while still divided into rival states and still dominated by primitive
mechanisms like capital accumulation. Even the first people in space, almost
half a century ago, could see that our planet is a single fragile system.
A world socialist community will have to decide which elements of
existing space programmes to retain and which to freeze or abandon.
National programmes that are retained will be merged into global
programmes, eliminating the wasteful duplication inherent in the
competition among space powers. Ambitious programs of purely scientific
interest may be deferred pending the solution of more urgent problems.
Attitudes in a socialist world toward reliance on space activities may
diverge quite widely. Some people may wish to enjoy the benefits of a
complex high-consumption lifestyle made possible by He-3 fuel for nuclear
fusion and other off-earth technologies. Others may prefer to avoid the
irreducible risks of a space-dependent strategy and solve earth’s problems
here on earth, at least to whatever extent this proves possible.
December 2008
Asteroid wars
Obama outlined plans for the U.S. space program. He rejected proposals to
for manned missions into deep space. The first destination will be “an
So perhaps I was wrong when I called the moon “the next capitalist
frontier” (MW, December 2008). Why is an asteroid landing being given top
priority?
Near-earth asteroids
Obama was certainly referring to one of the “near-earth asteroids”
(NEAs). These are asteroids that have been dislodged, usually by the
gravitational pull of Jupiter, from the main asteroid belt between Mars and
Jupiter into orbits that approach or intersect the orbit of the earth. About
fantastically rich in valuable metals and other minerals. In fact, many metals
now mined on earth originated in asteroids that rained down on our planet
Consider, for instance, the NEA known as 1986 DA. A mile and a half
in diameter, it is estimated to contain ten billion tons of iron, one billion tons
of nickel, 100,000 tons of platinum and over 10,000 tons of gold. The
platinum alone, at the current price of £35 per gram, is worth £3.5 trillion.
True, the price would fall rapidly once exploitation was underway, but at
the moon. Thanks to the very low gravity, a round trip to an NEA passing
nearby will require less energy than a round trip to the moon. Processing
might be carried out on site and only processed materials brought back to
earth. True, a way will have to be found to “tether” machinery to the asteroid
Window of opportunity
months when it is passing close enough to earth, for it may not return our
course. This might be done if one were on a collision course with earth. (The
resource-rich NEA could be “captured” – that is, transported into earth orbit,
shudder at the thought of the calamities that may descend on us from above
mining on earth, with its attendant ecological and work-related costs (costs
might well be an occasion for conflict between the U.S. and another space
stake.
With adequate profit, capital is very bold. A certain 10 per cent. will
ensure its employment anywhere; 20 per cent. certain will produce
eagerness; 50 per cent., positive audacity; 100 per cent. will make it
ready to trample on all human laws; 300 per cent., and there is not a
crime at which it will scruple, nor a risk it will not run, even to the
chance of its owner being hanged.
There is a treaty designed for this purpose (the Moon Treaty of 1979), but it
has never come into force because only a few states – not one of them a
space power – have ratified it. An attempt in 1980 to get the U.S. Senate to
than the risk of war over lunar resources. First, the moon is large enough to
asteroid may not be. Second, an NEA will have to be exploited while it is
within easy reach, so there will be little time for maneuvering, negotiations
asteroid may have the unintended consequence of the asteroid hitting the
earth.
May 2010
Antics in the South China Sea
The recent incidents in the middle of the South China Sea, in which a large
American ship was “harassed” by various Chinese boats, have a comical
aspect. The “harassment” seems to have been mostly a matter of
uncomfortably close approaches, flag waving, and beaming lights. The most
violent moment was when the Americans used fire hoses to drench the
sailors on a boat that had come too close, inducing them to strip to their
underwear.
These antics, however, may be the prelude to more serious conflict.
An armed clash between China and the U.S. is, perhaps, more likely to occur
in the South China Sea than in the context of a putative Chinese invasion of
Taiwan.
Many reports have described the American vessel, USNS Impeccable,
as a “survey ship” or “ocean surveillance ship.” This creates the misleading
impression that such ships exist for the purpose of oceanographic mapping
or scientific research.
In fact, although they are unarmed and have civilian crews, the
“survey ships” belong to the U.S. navy and their function is to collect
military intelligence. They are really spy ships.
The main job of the survey ship deployed in the South China Sea is to
track the Chinese submarines that patrol there, operating from a base at the
southern tip of Hainan Island. These are nuclear submarines carrying
intercontinental ballistic missiles – that is, they constitute China’s “nuclear
deterrent.” The tracking is done by means of underwater sonar arrays
attached to the ship by cables. There was some attempt by Chinese sailors to
sever the cables and set the arrays adrift.
It is true that USNS Impeccable, lacking armaments more powerful
than fire hoses, does not by itself pose a direct threat to the submarines. But
the data it collects could be passed on to another vessel equipped with anti-
submarine missiles. In other words, the spy ship is a key component of anti-
submarine warfare capability. It is therefore no surprise that the Chinese
government should want it to leave the area.
It is in large part with a view to securing a sanctuary for its nuclear
submarines that China asserts the right to control most of the South China
Sea, an area of some 2 million square kilometres – to turn it into a “Chinese
lake.” The legal case cooked up by its diplomats involves claiming the three
main archipelagos in the sea as Chinese territory and then demarcating an
Exclusive Economic Zone (EEZ) 200 miles (320 km.) wide around them as
well as Hainan Island and along the shore of the mainland.
Finally, China seeks to erase the distinction between territorial waters
and an EEZ. The UN Convention on the Law of the Sea (UNCLOS)
prohibits the presence of a spy ship in territorial waters, but not in an EEZ.
The U.S. position is that USNS Impeccable did not enter China’s territorial
waters – it was 75 miles (120 km.) off the coast of Hainan at the time of the
incidents – so its activity is perfectly legal.
Of course, it does not matter to us as socialists which side has the
better case in terms of international law. The whole world is the common
heritage of mankind, and we do not recognize the right of capitalist powers
to carve it up among themselves.
While the military issue is the direct cause of the current clash
between China and the U.S., as it was of a similar clash involving aircraft in
1991, there are also other major issues at stake.
First, rights in the South China Sea are crucial to control over vital
shipping lanes. The shortest route between the Indian and the Pacific Ocean
passes through the sea. This, for instance, is the route taken by tankers
transporting crude oil from the Gulf to East Asia. One rationale for the U.S.
presence is to keep the sea routes open: if China were allowed strategic
dominance it could close off the Malacca Strait, which connects the South
China Sea with the Indian Ocean.
There are also plenty of resources to fight about in and under the sea,
including valuable fishing grounds and still unexploited oil and gas fields.
This is the underlying reason why it is so difficult to unravel the complicated
tangle of territorial disputes over the sea and its islands among the six
coastal states: China, Vietnam, Malaysia, Brunei, Taiwan and the
Philippines. In 1974 and 1988 these disputes led to military clashes – in both
cases between China and Vietnam.
April 2009
Section 6
WAR AND PEACE
(mostly war)
* * *
November 2008
* * *
What is new is the emergence, within the broader human rights
movement, of a loosely organized network that campaigns for military
intervention wherever that seems to be the only effective means of halting or
preventing genocidal atrocities against some ethnic group. Currently, for
example, there is an international campaign for intervention in Darfur
(Sudan).
During the period when I was not a socialist, I was involved for a
while in one of the organizations that makes up this network: the Institute
for the Study of Genocide (ISG). My research, publicized through the ISG,
helped to bring the massacres of Bosnian Moslems by Serb militias to the
attention of the U.S. media and politicians – including, notably, Bill Clinton,
who at that time was campaigning for president. Later Clinton did intervene
militarily in Yugoslavia, though over Kosovo rather than Bosnia.
Unlike governments, anti-genocide activists like the ISG have quite
genuine humanitarian motives. They recall how “the world sat by” and
allowed the Armenian genocide and the Holocaust to proceed. (Though at
war with Nazi Germany, the Allied command turned down pleas to bomb
the railway lines leading to Auschwitz.) They are determined to establish
humanitarian considerations as an integral part of policy making, so that
“we” will not let such terrible things happen again.
Any decent person will sympathize with this line of thought. But there
is a problem with it. Let us shift our focus from the moral imperative of
effective action to the political forces capable of such action. Who is “the
world”? Who is “we”? The only “we” capable of intervening is governments
with their armed forces. But governments do not exist for humanitarian
purposes. They are therefore loathe to intervene for humanitarian reasons,
and it is close to impossible to compel them to do so.
From the point of view of governments, the existence of a public
movement for humanitarian intervention has both pros and cons. It is
irritating and embarrassing to have to face down emotional public demands
to intervene in places where no important “national interests” are at stake –
in Rwanda, for instance, or Darfur. On the other hand, when you are inclined
to intervene anyway for other, more “important” reasons it is extremely
convenient to have a public movement pressing for intervention. That makes
it much easier to drum up public support for war, and at the same time you
can enhance your democratic credentials by “responding to public opinion.”
In the case of Yugoslavia, the demand to intervene effectively over
Bosnia was resisted, but the campaign in which I participated prepared the
ground for intervention over Kosovo. The evidence now available suggests
that in Kosovo, in contrast to Bosnia, there was never any real danger of
genocide (as opposed to the usual ethnic cleansing). In Kosovo, however,
and again in contrast to Bosnia, significant interests were at stake, such as a
major oil pipeline and metal-mining complex.
It may appear to campaigners for humanitarian intervention that they
have a certain limited success. They “win some and lose some.” But if we
look more deeply into the real interests involved we see that their success is
largely illusory. It is by no means clear that their efforts have the net effect
of reducing the amount of suffering in the world. In fact, by supporting and
helping to legitimize brutal and devastating wars they may well increase the
total of suffering.
The epithet “useful idiots” (or “useful fools”) was used to pillory
Western pacifists who supposedly served the interests of the Soviet Union,
though without intending to do so and for the best of all possible motives.
Jean Bricmont borrows the expression for a different purpose, calling
campaigners for humanitarian intervention the “useful idiots” of Western
militarism and imperialism (Humanitarian Imperialism: Using Human
Rights to Sell War, NY: Monthly Review Press, 2006). Again, this is not
meant to cast any aspersions on their motives.
As socialists we would only question the stress on “Western.” In
principle such people could equally well serve as useful idiots for non-
Western (Russian, Chinese, Indian, etc.) militarism and imperialism, though
in practice they are active mostly in Western countries.
Calls for humanitarian intervention only make sense in terms of a
false conception of the nature and functions of government. They feed a
delusion that obscures the reality of our capitalist world, thereby making it
harder to overcome that reality.
August 2008
Who protests against nuclear weapons nowadays? People seem to have half-
forgotten them.
But they are still there, patiently lying in wait. In The Seventh
Decade: The New Shape of Nuclear Danger (NY: Henry Holt & Co., 2007),
Jonathan Schell even speaks of a “nuclear renaissance” in the new century.
True, there are fewer nukes than there used to be. The number of
active nuclear weapons has declined from a Cold War peak of some 65,000
to below 20,000. In another decade it may fall to 10,000. But this is scant
consolation, for several reasons:
* The 10,000 remaining nukes will still suffice to wipe out the human
race many times over. Even the use of 100 would cause disaster on an
unprecedented scale. Atmospheric scientists at UCLA and the University of
Colorado modeled the climatic effects of the use of 100 Hiroshima-type
bombs – just 0.03% of the explosive power of the global arsenal – in a
nuclear war between India and Pakistan. These countries have fought four
wars and now have about 75 nukes each. Direct fatalities would be
comparable with World War Two, while millions of tons of soot borne aloft
would devastate agriculture over vast expanses of Eurasia and North
America.
* * *
Schell calls for “action in concert by all the nations on Earth” (p. 217)
to abolish nuclear weapons, halt global warming, and tackle other urgent
global problems. His eloquence is moving, but his vision is only very briefly
sketched and lacks substance. True, he has some technical and
organizational proposals. Like IAEA director Mohammed ElBaradei, for
instance, he would revive the Baruch Plan put forward by Truman in 1946
and place all nuclear fuel production under the control of an international
agency. But he fails to consider what political, social and economic changes
might be necessary to create and sustain the international trust and
cooperation that he seeks.
Let us suppose, for the sake of argument, that nuclear disarmament
were somehow to be achieved within the existing conflict-based system.
Many states would still have the technological capacity to make nuclear
weapons again if they so decided. This is known as the “breakout” problem.
It is hard to imagine countries resisting this temptation when at war or even
under conditions of acute military confrontation. As we need not just to
achieve but maintain nuclear disarmament, we therefore also need to abolish
war in general, together with all weapons that can be used to threaten war. A
close reading of Schell suggests that he accepts this point, though he does
not spell it out.
But take the argument a step further. Wars arise out of conflicts over
the control of resources. Doesn’t this mean that an end has to be put to such
conflicts? And how can this be done without placing resources under the
control of a global community – that is, without establishing world
socialism?
Socialists are not against nuclear (or general) disarmament within
capitalism. We know that the world faces problems of the greatest urgency
and we know that the global social revolution is not an immediate prospect.
We have no wish to hold human survival hostage to the attainment of our
ideals. Please go ahead and prove us wrong by abolishing nuclear weapons
without abolishing capitalism. Nothing, apart from socialism itself, would
make us happier. The trouble is that we simply don’t understand how it can
be done. That is why we see no alternative to working for socialism.
February 2008
As an act of war, the al-Qaeda attack on the Pentagon and the World Trade
Centre was somewhat unusual, though not unprecedented, in three respects.
First, the method used was non-standard. Standard military practice is
to blow things and people up by dropping bombs or firing shells and
missiles on them. But flying planes right into the target has been done
before. Japanese kamikaze pilots used the technique against U.S. warships in
the Pacific during World War Two.
Second, al-Qaeda is a non-state actor. Such actors rarely have the
capacity to carry through such a complex and costly operation. Therefore al-
Qaeda must have had financial backing from wealthy sponsors - Osama bin
Laden himself comes from an extremely wealthy family - and the support, or
at least complicity, of one or more powerful states. In general, arranging
wars is a pastime for members of the capitalist class, though they get
hirelings to do the dirty work for them. Working people don't command the
necessary resources.
Finally, it is a little unusual for the U.S. to be on the receiving end of a
military assault from abroad. For a comparable attack on the continental
United States, you have to go back to 1814, when the British army entered
Washington and burned down the White House and the Capitol.
In other ways the attack was not unusual in the least. As an atrocity it
was par for the course. The death toll, initially estimated at 6,500, was later
revised downward to about 2,800. Atrocities on a similar or larger scale are
committed routinely by the U.S. in other countries.
To take just one example, 3--4,000 civilians were killed in the
invasion of Panama in December 1989. Even if we start the reckoning with
September 11, we find that the U.S. was quick to even the score. According
to an independent study, 3,767 Afghan civilians (hardly any of them
connected with al-Qaeda) had been killed inbombing raids by 6 December,
2001. This figure does not include the far more numerous indirect casualties
resulting from the creation of refugees and the disruption of food and other
supplies.
* * *
The attack should not have been a total surprise, a bolt out of the blue.
After all, it was merely the next step in a war that Osama bin Laden had
formally declared on the United States in August 1996. He had built up a
far-flung network of front companies, banks,"charities," and NGOs (e.g., the
World Union of Moslem Youth) to raise funds and recruit young fighters for
the war. He had already attacked American assets abroad, notably the
embassies in Kenya and Tanzania in August 1998, and there was ample
intelligence warning that a major attack on US soil was in the offing. So the
parallel with Pearl Harbor is pretty weak.
And yet September 11 clearly did come as a shock to Bush. That was
because the attack came from forces that the U.S., its sidekicks Britain and
Israel, and the Bush family in particular had long regarded as friends, allies
and partners. This explains why Bush ignored the warnings - just as Stalin
ignored warnings of impending attack by Nazi Germany in 1941 and felt
"betrayed" by Hitler when the attack came.
American, British, and Israeli ruling circles saw the main threats to
their economic and strategic interests in the Moslem world as coming from
"communists" and secular nationalists backed by the Soviet Union (e.g.
Nasser in Egypt, Ghaddafi in Libya, the PLO). When Khomeini's theocracy
took power, Iran was added to the list of enemies, together with associated
Shi'ite Islamist movements in other countries. Sunni Islamist movements,
however, were encouraged - largely on the principle that "the enemy of my
enemy is my friend," although also because they seemed more interested in
imposing ritual conformity on their own communities and in fighting
"communism" than in challenging the substantive interests of the "infidel"
powers.
The Islamists were also beneficiaries of the "neo-liberal" economic
policies of Western institutions. In Pakistan, for example, the secular state
schools collapsed in the1980s as a result of public spending cuts imposed by
the IMF. This left the Saudi-financed religious schools (madrassas) as the
only educational option available to boys who were not from wealthy
families. (Girls, needless to say, didn't even have that option.) It was from
these madrassas that the Taliban drew its recruits.
Moreover, relations with the leading Sunni Islamist power, Saudi
Arabia, were and still are vital to Britain and the US in economic terms. The
Saudi capitalist class, led by the royal family and influential families like the
bin Ladens, not only sells these countries' oil but uses much of the proceeds
to buy arms from them and invest in their economies.
There are close and long-established personal and business ties
between wealthy Saudis and British and American capitalists and politicians,
including the father of the current US president and several members of his
administration.
The Saudi—U.S. alliance also entailed close military cooperation,
above all in the fight against Soviet forces in Afghanistan. Osama bin Laden
went to Pakistan in 1979 as an official of the Saudi intelligence service to
finance, organize, and control the anti- Soviet Afghan resistance in
collaboration with the CIA. It was here that Osama, who had trained as an
engineer and economist with a view to taking part in the family business,
acquired his taste for war. Osama fell out with the Saudi royal family in
1991 when they allowed the US to set up military bases on the "holy" soil of
Arabia following Iraq's invasion of Kuwait.
But even in exile Osama received frequent visits from relatives, who
provided a channel of communication between him and the royal family. An
understanding appears to have been reached. Osama would abstain from
attacking targets inside Saudi Arabia and in return no action would be taken
against his Saudi supporters, who included various members of his own and
of other wealthy families (such as Khalid bin Mahfouz, the "banker of
terror") and even certain royal princes. And the Saudi authorities did protect
these people, refusing to provide U.S. intelligence agencies with any
information that might compromise them. So September 11 originated in a
"betrayal" by the Saudi capitalist class of their American friends, allies and
partners.
How can we account for such strange ingratitude to those to whom
they owe their vast riches? It probably has to do with the circumstances in
which the Saudi capitalist class came into being. They did not make
themselves into capitalists. It was done for them when oil was discovered in
Arabia (in 1938) and property rights in that oil were vested in the royal
house. The Saudi capitalists are a class of bedouin patriarchs turned rentiers,
who became capitalists by investing their revenue. So they retain to some
extent a pre-capitalist mentality and have a deeply ambivalent attitude to the
capitalist world in which they now operate.
* * *
Despite the shock effect, U.S. ruling circles did not necessarily regard
9/11 as an unalloyed evil. In his book The New Crusade, anti-war analyst
Rahul Mahajan draws attention to a document entitled Rebuilding America's
Defenses, issued in September 2000 by the Project for the New American
Century, a neo-conservative think tank with links to the Bush administration.
The authors call for increased military spending to preserve US "global pre-
eminence," but add that such a programme will be politically impossible
unless there is a "catastrophic and catalyzing event, like a new Pearl
Harbor."
The purposes for which the fear generated by the al-Qaeda attack was
exploited suggest that it filled this bill. The threat of "terrorism" has been
used to push through military programs ranging from anti-missile defence to
germ warfare. Thus, a vast lab is being built near Washington called the
National Biodefence Analysis and Countermeasures Center, where in
violation of the1972 biological and toxin weapons convention the most
lethal bacteria and viruses are to be stockpiled (Guardian Weekly, 4-10
August 2006). What a tempting target that will make for terrorists to
infiltrate or attack!
The "war on terrorism" unleashed in the aftermath of September 11,
against first Afghanistan and then Iraq, is not - so Mahajan argues - a war on
terrorism, just as the
"war on drugs" is not a war on drugs. Combating terrorism and drugs are
both low priorities, and the "wars" against them are covers for the pursuit of
higher-priority interests.
In Afghanistan the U.S. had turned against the Taliban (previously
welcomed as a force for "stability"), mainly because they were unwilling to
host oil and gas pipelines from Central Asia to Pakistan, and was looking for
a pretext to overthrow them. Capturing Osama was that pretext, for it was
obvious that the chaos of war would create ideal conditions for him to
escape.
Iraq was invaded to secure control over its oil and in the hope of
establishing a new strategic beachhead in the Middle East. Saddam had no
ties with Islamic terrorism, just as he had no nuclear weapons. To the likes
of Osama he was not even a genuine Moslem. Bush demanded of his experts
that they find ties between Iraq and terrorism; when they replied that there
were none, he pretended not to hear and reiterated his demand. In October
2001 Vice President Dick Cheney declared that the war on terrorism"may
never end -- at least, not in our lifetime" (Washington Post, 21 October,
2001). Am I alone in finding this suspicious? Ordinarily in a war it is
considered important for morale to hold out some prospect of victory,
however remote. Does Cheney want and need the "war" to go on forever?
* * *
September 2006
Preparations for a U.S. attack on Iran are well advanced. Planes probe the
country’s air defences. Commandos infiltrate Iran on sabotage and
reconnaissance missions. A new military base is built close to the Iraq/Iran
border at Badrah. The Fifth Fleet patrols in the Gulf and along Iran’s
southern coast.
Political preparations also continue. Accusations against Iran are
elaborated and repeated ad nauseam. Pressure is exerted (with variable
success) on other countries to assist in the war plans. Aid and
encouragement are given to separatists in ethnic-minority areas of Iran: Arab
Khuzestan in the southwest, “southern Azerbaijan” in the northwest.
Resolutions are pushed through at the U.N. Security Council and in the U.S.
Congress to create a “legal” justification for aggression.
Why are the dominant capitalist interests in the U.S. so bent on war
with Iran? The war propaganda provides a highly distorted and incomplete
picture of the real reasons.
* * *
An attack on Iran will be sold as the next stage, after Afghanistan and
Iraq, of the “war against terror.” What does this mean?
As with the attack on Iraq, the claim may be made, explicitly or
implicitly, that the Iranian regime is connected in some way with Al-Qaeda.
This time round the claim would be even more deceptive, as Iranian leaders
denounced 9/11 and helped the U.S. depose the Taliban in Afghanistan. The
terrorism charge is also based on the real Iranian support of Hizbollah in
Lebanon and Hamas in Palestine. This, however, means enlarging the
meaning of “terrorist” to cover any armed movement that opposes the
regional interests of the U.S. and its allies. Finally, the U.S. Congress has
passed a resolution – supported, incidentally, by leading Democratic
presidential contender Senator Hilary Clinton – declaring Iran’s
Revolutionary Guards (an elite section of its armed forces) a terrorist
organization. This justifies military action against them as part of the “war
against terror.”
Above all, the Bush administration claims that Iran is very close to
acquiring nuclear weapons and that a nuclear-armed Iran would be an
unprecedented threat to world peace. The same claim was used to justify the
attack on Iraq. No nuclear weapons capability was discovered after the
invasion, but the claim had served its purpose. Iran is enriching uranium for
a civilian nuclear power program under IAEA supervision, but there is no
evidence that its leaders seek nuclear weapons and it will not be in a position
to produce them for several (perhaps ten) years. This is a consensus view of
specialists not only at the IAEA but also at the CIA and Pentagon.
Nevertheless, Iran is a rising power with ambitions of exerting
influence in a region crowded with nuclear powers (Israel, Pakistan, India,
Russia and China, not to mention the U.S. nuclear presence). As such it is
very likely to acquire nuclear weapons at some point. It might be willing to
barter the nuclear weapons option for international recognition of its status
as a regional power, but that is precisely what the U.S. and its allies are
unwilling to grant.
While the risk of accident or miscalculation does increase with the
number of nuclear powers, there is no serious reason to suppose that Iran
would be more dangerous than any other state with nuclear weapons. All
nuclear states are prepared to resort to nuclear weapons under certain
circumstances.
“Nuclear non-proliferation” started as an international agreement to
confine nuclear weapons to the members of a small exclusive club. It has
now come to mean “disarmament wars” to deny nuclear weapons status
selectively to regimes considered hostile to U.S. interests (listen to an
interview with Jonathan Schell on www.therealnews.com). The U.S. seeks
to prevent Iran from going nuclear because it would shift the balance of
power in the Middle East, making American nuclear capabilities less
intimidating and depriving Israel of its regional nuclear monopoly.
* * *
While the U.S. does want to prevent Iran from eventually acquiring
nuclear weapons, this does not explain the urgency of the preparations for
war. The key factor is control over resources, in particular oil and natural
gas. The U.S. seeks to restore and maintain control over the hydrocarbon
resources of the Middle East, a region that contains 55% of the world’s oil
and 40% of its gas.
The occupation of Iraq marks an important step toward this goal. The
petroleum law that the U.S. is imposing on Iraq will give foreign companies
direct control of its oilfields through “production sharing agreements”. Iran,
which alone accounts for 10% of world oil and 16% of world gas, is the
main remaining obstacle to regional domination.
Control over oil has various aspects. One is control over price –
gaining the leverage to ensure the continued flow of cheap oil to the
American economy. Another is control over who buys the oil. The country
that buys the most oil from Iran is now China, a situation that upsets those in
the U.S. who view China as a major rival and future adversary. Arguably,
however, the most important issue is which currency is used to price and sell
oil.
As the position of the dollar in relation to other currencies weakens,
the dollar is ceasing to function as the world’s main reserve currency.
Countries are shifting their foreign exchange reserves away from dollar
assets toward assets denominated in other currencies, especially the euro.
Dollar assets now constitute only 20% of Iran’s reserves.
Similarly, oil producers increasingly prefer not to receive dollars for
their oil. In late 2006 China began paying for Iranian oil in euros, while in
September 2007 Japan’s Nippon Oil agreed to pay for Iranian oil in yen.
Continuation of this trend will flood the U.S. economy with petrodollars,
fuelling inflation and further weakening the dollar. It is feared that the result
will be a deep recession.
Occupying oil-producing countries may seem like an obvious way to
buck the trend, although the effect is bound to be temporary. In 2000 Iraq
began selling oil for euros; subsequently it converted its reserves to euros.
Since the U.S. invasion it has gone back to using dollars. This may be an
important motive for attacking Iran too.
* * *
January 2008
Last month 100 U.S. veterans of the wars in Iraq and Afghanistan held
hearings in Washington to describe their experience. Named Winter Soldier
after a similar meeting of Vietnam veterans in 1971, the event was ignored
by the major corporate media outlets. In contrast to Vietnam, media
coverage of these wars is sanitized. Viewers see no scenes of carnage, hear
no cries of pain. No publicity accompanies the coffins on their return.
On the internet, however, there is uncensored testimony, including
videos and personal blogs (e.g.: ivaw.org, indybay.org, therealnews.com,
5yearstoomany.org, aliveinbaghdad.org). These are the sources on which I
draw here.
Let’s start with the army recruiter who inveigles the naïve youngster
into the inferno. A sinister figure? Or just another victim? After all, he didn’t
seek transfer to the Recruitment Command. Now he has to make his quota or
else endure constant humiliation, weekends in “corrective retraining” and
the threat of the sack. So he works himself to exhaustion, answers the kids’
questions with lies, and recruits anyone he can, whether or not they meet
official standards of health, education or “moral character” (i.e., no criminal
record).
Few now join for “patriotic” reasons. Most are bribed with the
promise of financial benefits, often payment of college fees. Many foreign
residents sign up as a way of becoming U.S. citizens. Over 100 have been
awarded citizenship posthumously.
A few weeks of basic training and the new teenage soldier, who has
probably never been abroad or even in another region of the U.S., suddenly
finds himself in a strange, uncomfortable and disorienting environment. He
does not understand the language, nor can he decipher the Arabic script. He
has been taught to fear every haji -- the term used to dehumanize Iraqis – as
a possible enemy. He starts to kill and goes on killing, usually with the
connivance of his superiors, often with their open encouragement. He kills in
blind fear, or on orders, or even out of boredom. Most likely he feels no
shame: his mates take souvenir photos of him standing by his “trophies.”
It is not necessarily only Iraqis who he kills. When Marines find their
forward movement blocked, one blogger tells us, they “start using their
training ‘to destroy the enemy’ on civilians or other Marines.” Violence and
degradation pervade relations not just between the military and Iraqi
civilians but also within the military. Soldiers are abused and humiliated by
officers. Rape is commonplace.
It is hard to see what purpose all this violence can possibly serve. The
U.S. government would like to suppress all resistance to the occupation and
stabilize a client regime that can be trusted to keep Iraq open to plunder by
Western (mainly U.S.) corporations. But the more people are killed the more
of their relatives and friends will take up arms to avenge them. Various
militias temporarily ally themselves with the occupation forces in order to
eliminate their rivals, but later they too will fight the Americans (as well as
one another). And the persisting “instability” and destruction of resources
make Iraq less appealing to corporate investors.
So the chances are that the U.S. will cut losses and give up, although
the process will no doubt drag on for years. Otherwise the fighting will
continue until the whole population is dead or has fled the country. In that
case there will be no one left to run the puppet government or work for the
corporations. Of course, the chore of administration could be dumped on the
UN and workers brought in from abroad.
Amid the bloody mayhem, measures are still taken to preserve the
sanctity of property – or at least of American property. One soldier tells of
being sent with others to guard a military contractor’s truck that has broken
down on the highway. After hours of warding off hungry Iraqis who want to
take the food stored inside, they received the order to destroy the truck
together with its contents. On another occasion they were ordered to destroy
an ambulance.
When capitalists are forced by circumstances to abandon their
property, they evidently prefer to have it destroyed rather than permit its use
to satisfy the needs of desperate people. That is the true face of our real,
class enemy.
The cost of this futile war to American society can hardly be compared with
the damage inflicted on a devastated and shattered Iraq. It is quite substantial
nonetheless. As always, the working class pays by far the highest price for
their masters’ insane adventures.
Over 4,000 U.S. soldiers have been killed in Iraq so far. This may
seem quite modest in view of the 50,000 killed in Vietnam. However, the
number killed is a misleading indicator of the amount of suffering. Due to
medical advances, the ratio of wounded to killed, which was 3:1 in Vietnam,
is 7:1 in Iraq. Many soldiers who in previous wars would have died of severe
brain injury, loss of limbs or extensive third-degree burns have been “saved”
– not restored to health, but salvaged to live out the rest of their lives in pain
and discomfort.
Even more numerous are the psychological casualties. Apart from
those who serve in office jobs and rarely if ever leave the Green Zone (the
specially secured part of Baghdad where the U.S. embassy and military
headquarters are located), there can be few who return from Iraq free of
psychological trauma -- “post-traumatic stress disorder” as the psychiatrists
call it. (Over 100,000 are seeking treatment, but there must be many more
who do not seek treatment – and, indeed, it is doubtful whether any effective
treatment exists.)
Many veterans feel unbearable guilt for what they have done,
although it is those who sent them who are mainly responsible. So it is not
uncommon for a young soldier to return home “safe and sound” only to hang
himself the next day. Besides suicide, the veterans are prone to alcoholism
and depression, homicide and domestic violence.
And there are so many of these brutalized and traumatized veterans!
While “only” about 175,000 troops are deployed at any one time (currently
158,000 in Iraq and 18,000 in Afghanistan), at least 1,400,000 soldiers have
fought at some time in one or both of these wars. The damage to the social
fabric is therefore enormous -- in the same way that the social fabric in
Russia, for instance, has been torn by its wars in Afghanistan and Chechnya.
And a new war against Iran is still on the cards. Nor can we exclude a
U.S. military intervention against pro-Taliban forces in northwestern
Pakistan.
May 2008
War in Georgia
Level 1. The struggle within Georgia for control over territory, waged
by ethnically based mini-states (Georgian, Abkhaz, Osset).
* * *
* * *
September 2008
Although the peace accord of 2003 ended five years of war in other parts of
the Democratic Republic of the Congo, fighting has continued intermittently
in the eastern Kivu region. The latest bout began on October 25, when the
rebel forces of Laurent Nkunda resumed their offensive, accompanied by the
usual atrocities against civilians, burning villages, and floods of starving
refugees.
What is this war about?
At first sight, it looks like spillover from the Hutu-Tutsi conflict in
neighbouring Rwanda. General Nkunda, a Congolese Tutsi and Christian
fundamentalist, says he is protecting his people from the Interahamwe, the
Hutu militia that perpetrated the Rwandan genocide of 1994 and later fled
over the border. He is backed by troops of the current Tutsi government of
Rwanda, which the Interahamwe seeks to overthrow.
This version is a smokescreen. Nkunda has shown much less interest
in pursuing the Interahamwe than in seizing control of Kivu’s rich mineral
resources – partly on behalf of Rwandan business interests, partly perhaps
for his own enrichment. He exploits the memory of genocide to mobilize the
Tutsis in his support and win foreign sympathy, much as Israel exploits the
memory of the Holocaust for its purposes. Control over resources is also the
main concern of the Congo government in Kinshasa and its armed forces.
The most valuable minerals in the Kivu region are two metallic ores
called cassiterite and coltan. These contain substances whose special
properties are ideally suited to various high-tech applications. Niobium
alloys are used in jet and rocket engines because they remain stable at very
high temperatures, while tantalum and tin oxide are used in making
electronic circuitry for devices ranging from computers to DVD players and
MRI scanners. In particular, the rapidly rising demand for mobile phones has
pushed up the price of coltan, fuelling the fight to control and mine its
deposits. So we could call the war in eastern Congo “the mobile phone war.”
On both sides, part of the proceeds from selling resources (through
chains of middlemen) on the world market goes to finance military
operations, which in turn secure access to the resources. This is an example
of the “war as business” model, which arises in this case from the weakness
of state institutions in Central Africa.
* * *
January 2009
The phrase “opium wars” usually refers to the British military assaults of
1839-42 and 1856-60 that forced the Chinese emperor to allow British
merchants to sell his subjects opium. The opium was grown in India, where
the tax revenue from its sale maintained the colonial administration.
In 1839, imperial commissioner Lin Zexu wrote to Queen Victoria:
“By what right do the barbarians use the poisonous drug to injure the
Chinese people? Although they may not intend to do us harm, in coveting
profit to an extreme they have no regard for injuring others. Let us ask,
where is your conscience?”
He never received an answer.
It was not only the Chinese who suffered at the hands of the profit-
coveting barbarians. They found it just as profitable to poison “their own
people.” Britain imported 200,000 pounds of opium from India in 1840. It
was consumed, quite legally, mostly mixed with alcohol in a flavoured
concoction called laudanum, as an all-purpose painkiller, tranquilliser and
sleeping potion. Society ladies used it to acquire the then-fashionable pallid
complexion associated with tuberculosis, while the neglected and
undernourished babies of the working class were dosed with it to keep them
quiet while their mothers toiled long hours in the mills.
Nowadays trading in opium is illegal. That, of course, does not
prevent its large-scale production, sale and consumption, mostly as heroin. It
merely raises prices and makes the business even more lucrative, though
some “drug lords” perhaps envy the respectability enjoyed by their Victorian
predecessors – and by pushers of currently legal poisons.
* * *
March 2009
According to Israeli propaganda, it was the only way to stop rocket attacks
on Israel from Gaza. Some are sceptical about this version of events. The
truce negotiated with Hamas last June held for four months, they say, and
could probably have been maintained and extended were it not for Israel’s
military incursion on 4 November and its continuing siege of Gaza.
There is some evidence to suggest that the operation was a “war of
choice,” planned well in advance for the purpose of destroying Hamas in
Gaza. Israeli military historian Zeev Maoz has traced a long history of Israel
using provocative measures to trigger reactions in order to create a pretext
for military action (Defending the Holy Land: A Critical Analysis of Israel’s
Security and Foreign Policy, University of Michigan Press, 2006).
In a previous article I drew the distinction between “resource wars”
that are fought directly for control over specific resources and “strategic
wars” that reflect a long-term power struggle between rival capitalist states.
To take recent examples, the “mobile phone war” in eastern Congo was a
resource war while the war in Georgia was a strategic war.
The factors underlying this war have to do both with resources and
with strategic rivalry. Israel and the Palestinian factions are manoeuvring for
control over offshore gas deposits. But there is also a strategic dimension
that cannot be understood adequately at the local level.
Hamas is an integral part of the Islamist forces in the Moslem world.
It arose as an offshoot of Egypt’s Moslem Brotherhood, which now poses
the main threat to the U.S.-oriented Mubarak regime. That is a big reason
why this regime, like Jordan and the Palestine Authority, more or less
openly support Israel’s assault on Hamas.
Hamas also depends heavily on support from Iran. Like Hezbollah in
Lebanon and Iran’s clients in Iraq, it serves as a vehicle of Iran’s effort to
establish itself as the leading power in the Middle East. This helps to explain
the strength of U.S. and European support for Israel in this war. So there is
some basis to Israel’s claim that it is fighting on behalf of an international
“anti-extremist” – that is, anti-Islamist and anti-Iran – coalition.
As always, the physical war is combined with a propaganda war. The
message is drummed into people that “we” have no choice but to defend
ourselves against an enemy bent on genocide. In the Western media the
word “terrorist” routinely precedes any reference to Hamas. Of course, both
sides are terrorist in the sense of targeting civilians. Israel uses terror on a
much larger scale than Hamas, though that is solely because it has much
greater military capacity.
In principle, either side could have avoided the war by submitting to
the other side’s political demands. It was a war of choice on both sides.
Hamas could probably have saved “their people” from the fury of the Israeli
war machine by ceding power in Gaza to the Palestine Authority. I make this
point not to diminish Israel’s direct responsibility for its atrocities, but rather
to highlight how little all the Palestinian as well as Israeli leaders really care
about ordinary people.
* * *
In demonizing Hamas the pro-Israel propagandists face a little
problem. Earlier they themselves reluctantly granted Hamas a certain
legitimacy in connection with its victory in the January 2006 elections to the
Palestinian Legislative Council. Now they just say that Hamas seized power
in a coup and delete any mention of the elections. In fact, it was the U.S. that
insisted on the elections, perhaps not anticipating the outcome.
Capitalism as a system is inherently undemocratic, because it
concentrates real power in the hands of a small ruling and owning class. In
general, elections may be welcomed as introducing a small element of
democracy into this undemocratic system. People in Gaza, however, have
been subjected to starvation, bombing, and other forms of harsh punishment
in effect for having voted for candidates that the sponsors of the elections
did not want. Under the circumstances, these elections were a nasty trick that
had little to do with democracy.
It appears that Obama will make another attempt to revive the “peace
process,” which is supposed to lead to a Palestinian state alongside Israel.
But unless he is willing to put Israel under very strong pressure to withdraw
from all the territory occupied in 1967, such a state will amount to little
more than a string of ghettoes or, to use the official term, “cantons”. A two-
state solution on these terms would have to be imposed by force, and it is
doubtful whether the Palestine Authority is up to the job.
Yet another failure of the “peace process” could strengthen the
growing trend in Palestinian opinion to accept the reality of Israel’s control
over the whole of what used to be Palestine and demand citizenship rights
within a single secular state. This would be equivalent to the ending of
apartheid in South Africa but would not solve the problems faced by the
majority of the population. Not that the emergence of such a secular state is
easy to envisage at present in view of the prevalence of ethnic-supremacist,
sectarian and even racist outlooks in both Jewish-Israeli and Palestinian
society.
February 2009
The immediate purpose of Israel’s state piracy and mass kidnapping in the
of the Gaza Strip that was imposed in 2007 to induce the Gazans to
overthrow the Hamas administration they had just elected. Of course, the
political effect of the blockade, which caused enormous suffering (see MW,
over Gaza’s borders, airspace and territorial waters. This control was not
2005. Keeping Gaza and the West Bank isolated from direct contact with the
Some sections of the Israeli ruling class are prepared to accept a peace
business unrestricted access to Arab export markets and cheap labour. The
– above all, the military-industrial complex and the settlers’ lobby. The
state or (like Jewish Home) committed to Greater Israel and thus opposed to
danger that peace might be imposed emerged when the United States, on
which Israel is now totally dependent, elected a president who believes that
American strategic interests at the regional and global level demand urgent
Why so violent?
The Israeli navy could have maintained the blockade and its control of
Gazan waters simply by blocking the path of the aid ships until they gave up
and went away. This method had worked well in the past. By massacring a
makers – Israel has created a PR disaster for itself. It has strained relations
with countries around the world and alienated its main regional ally, Turkey.
Part of the explanation may be that key members of the Israeli cabinet
(defence minister Ehud Barak) or simply thugs (foreign minister and former
may have been exactly what the Israeli government sought to achieve. And
that will serve even better to thwart Obama and ward off the threat of peace.
Offshore gas
There is another aspect to the issue of control over Gazan waters –
(PA) signed a 25-year agreement with British Gas and the Athens-based but
explore for oil and gas off the Gazan coast. Two wells were drilled in 2000
and, sure enough, a major gas field was found, not very far from the spot
where the Free Gaza flotilla was attacked. (Some offshore oil was also
found.) Rights to the proceeds were assigned: 60% to British Gas, 30% to
CCC, and only 10% to the PA. Nevertheless, the discovery enhanced
Palestinian sovereignty over the gas field and declared that Israel would
never buy gas from the PA. The consortium made plans to pump the gas to
Egypt instead. But all plans were scuppered in 2006 when Hamas replaced
the PA in Gaza. Israel then tried to take over the negotiations, but British
Gas decided to put the whole risky project on hold. Presumably both Israel
and the PA still hope that eventually the gas will be theirs.
What next?
Israeli state piracy did not have the desired intimidating effect. More
attempts to run the blockade followed. Iran and Turkey have offered naval
escorts for future flotillas. Conceivably this will broaden the war, though it
is more likely that the US will force Israel to abandon the siege. This is
likely to trigger the collapse of the current Israeli government and greatly
zones of control. The seeds of future war will remain. Yet as socialists we
will welcome even a fragile peace that temporarily halts the horrors of
workers, whatever their ethnic origin. It is always they who suffer the brunt
suppress democratic rights on both sides. Peace will create better conditions
NON-MILITARY
GLOBAL THREATS
The articles in this section are about two of the major non-
military threats that our planet and species face – global
warming and trans-species pathogens. I realise that both of
these problems merit much more extensive analysis.
Global warming:
is it (or will it soon be) too late?
On 28 February, a sizeable chunk (400 sq. km.) of the Antarctic ice sheet
toppled into the sea. This was just the latest sign that the planet is heating up
more rapidly than the quasi-official forecasts of the Intergovernmental Panel
on Climate Change (IPCC) have led us to expect.
Why does reality outpace prediction?
For one thing, scientists are trained to be cautious. Most are reluctant
to “speculate” – meaning to think a possibility through to its logical end
result. They are especially reticent when addressing a broad public. Those
who occupy positions in or close to government are under pressure to avoid
“alarmism” and be “politically realistic.” To preserve a modicum of
influence on the ruling class they must maintain an impression of
respectable complacency.
It is, of course, extremely difficult to form an adequate understanding
of such a complex interactive system as the global climate. Scientists rely on
computerised forecasting models to simulate such systems. But such models
can only incorporate factors that are already well understood and not subject
to excessive uncertainty. There is an inevitable lag, often a lengthy one,
between the discovery of a new danger or feedback mechanism and its
adequate representation in the models.
For instance, the usual prediction for rise in sea level by 2100 is a
little under one metre. We can cope with that, surely! But the only factor that
it takes into account is thermal expansion, which is fairly easy to calculate.
The big rise that will inundate coastal cities and vast lowland areas is that
which will follow collapse of the Arctic and Antarctic ice sheets, but no one
knows when it will occur.
Standard mathematical models are designed to analyse continuous,
relatively gradual change. The greatest dangers, however, are posed by
abrupt changes that give further sudden impetus to climate change. The
collapse of ice sheets is one example. Another likely near-term event of this
kind is a conflagration, sparked by increasingly hot and dry summertime
conditions, that destroys much or even most of the remaining Amazonian
rainforest, turning an important carbon sink into yet another carbon emitter.
Probably less imminent but even more terrifying is the prospect of the
release into the atmosphere of massive amounts of methane as a result of the
breakdown of frozen gas-ice compounds in the permafrost as it melts and on
the ocean floor as it warms up. Methane is by far the most powerful of the
greenhouse gases. It is also poisonous to life, at least as we know it.
These dangers explain why some scientists fear that global warming
may reach a “tipping point” beyond which it will become irreversible – that
is, beyond all hope of effective human counteraction. Within a few
generations, “runaway” climate change would then generate extreme
conditions that human beings will be unable to withstand.
This fear is fuelled by our knowledge of the geological record, which
contains abundant evidence of past climatic disasters in which numerous
species became extinct. It seems that when the biosphere of our planet is
jolted out of its not very stable equilibrium – whether by collision with a
meteorite or asteroid, by a supervolcanic eruption or by the insanity of
capitalist production and consumption – it is susceptible to catastrophic
climatic upheaval.
* * *
May 2009
Mystery of the pig/bird/human flu virus
“Swine flu” is really a misleading term for the current pandemic, inasmuch
as no single species serves as host of preference for the new virus. It does
not need to mutate as it jumps from pig to human and back again. This is a
fully trans-species disease.
According to the findings of Canada’s National Microbiology Lab, the
genome of the new virus is a strange composite of eight segments from four
old viruses, associated with two distinct varieties of swine flu (North
American and Eurasian), a North American avian flu and a human flu (the
H3N2 strain last seen in 1993). New Scientist calls it “an unusually
mongrelised mix of genetic sequences.”
It is widely assumed that the virus evolved in a pig. Suspicion has
come to rest on a huge fly-infested lake of pig shit on the site of a pig factory
– calling these places “farms” creates quite the wrong impression – in the
central Mexican province of Veracruz. The pig factory (one of 16 in the
province) is owned by Granjas Carroll, which is itself half-owned by the
U.S. pork and beef conglomerate, Smithfield Farms. The idea that this
particular factory is the source of the outbreak is based on the fact that a
young boy living nearby is the earliest known case of infection with the
virus.
This explanation is certainly plausible. Pigs are susceptible to most if
not all of the main virus families, so different kinds of virus can easily
accumulate inside the cells of their tissues and exchange genetic material.
Pigs are therefore ideal incubators for the evolution and spead of viruses,
especially when their immune systems are weakened by being crammed
together in the filthy pens provided by profit-seeking agribusiness. Over the
years, many experts have predicted that the outcome would be pandemics of
new diseases.
Nevertheless, the evidence for this version seems far from conclusive.
There may well be earlier cases elsewhere that have not been traced.
Smithfield systematically obstructs all investigation into its operations, but
that proves nothing: no doubt there are many things that they want to hide.
So other possibilities cannot be ruled out. It is unwarranted to assume
that the virus must have originated in Mexico because conditions there are
more unhygienic than in the U.S. The pig factories in Veracruz and those in
North Carolina are owned by the same firms and run in the same way.
According to Online Journal, a “top UN scientist” believes that the
virus was released, accidentally or deliberately, from a biological weapons
lab, inasmuch as certain features of its highly unusual structure are
suggestive of genetic engineering. A possible source is the U.S. Army
Medical Institute of Infectious Diseases at Fort Detrick, Maryland. It was
from here, for instance, that someone spread anthrax germs in 2001.
* * *
When the pandemic first hit the headlines, scientists did not yet even
understand the nature of the new virus and it was impossible to assess the
severity of the danger. That did not deter some politicians and officials from
reassuring the public and others from voicing the most alarming predictions.
To a large extent, the mixed responses can be explained in terms of
divergent commercial and other interests. The reassurance is designed to
avert panic and unrest, safeguard sales and exports of U.S. and Mexican
pork, protect the tourist industry and maintain business confidence. The
alarmism serves the interests, above all, of the big pharmaceutical
companies that produce anti-flu drugs and vaccines.
Mass vaccination is not always an effective measure against
pathogens susceptible to rapid mutation. Moreover, the vaccine itself may be
contaminated with viruses. Thus, last December a lab of Baxter International
in Austria distributed vaccines contaminated with live avian flu virus to 18
countries. The same company has now been commissioned by the World
Health Organization to develop an experimental vaccine for the new flu.
Whatever the outcome of the current pandemic, it is safe to say that it
will not be the last. On the one hand, meat factories and biological weapons
labs continue to generate new pathogens. On the other hand, these pathogens
are increasingly drug-resistant due to the indiscriminate use of antibiotics
and other malpractices. It is only a matter of time before we find ourselves
helpless in face of some new and much more fatal trans-species virus or
bacterium.
* * *
Eliminating the profit motive will remove the major obstacle to the
prevention of trans-species pandemics. Those responsible for food
production will be able to give proper weight to environmental and public
health considerations.
However, this may not suffice if socialist society were to commit
itself to providing a meat-rich diet for most of the population. (Some people,
of course, will not want such a diet.) Disease control may well require the
abandonment of animal factories and a return to a more traditional type of
farming. This is likely to reduce the supply of meat, although it will also
enhance its taste and nutritional value.
Besides change in patterns of production and consumption, a shift
away from reliance on air travel would help slow down the spread of new
diseases and allow more time for research and countermeasures. (It would
also reduce greenhouse gas emissions.) Work schedules might be
coordinated in such a way as to give people the time they need to use and
enjoy slower means of travel, interspersed as desired with participation in
the life of local communities, including farming.
June 2009
Section 8
HISTORICAL REFLECTIONS
Some 10,000 years ago – quite recently in the four million years of human
evolution – communities began to rely less on hunting, fishing, and foraging
for food and settled down to plant crops and rear livestock. This change,
known as the Neolithic (New Stone Age) Revolution, opened the way to
landed property, city life, patriarchy, slavery, imperial conquest, and all the
other delights of "civilization" – that is, class society. It has generally been
seen as a great step forward for humanity. This was the view was taken
Marx, who believed that the development of class society would eventually
lead to a return to communal life at a higher technological level.
And yet we inherit a myth that mourns the pre-Neolithic life as a
paradise lost. The Bible tells us that God drove Adam from the Garden of
Eden to till the accursed ground ("it shall bring forth thorns and thistles for
you") and eat bread in the sweat of his face. As for Eve, she was to bear
children in sorrow and be ruled over by her husband (Genesis 3: 17--19, 23).
If only they had played their cards right!
So what was life really like for our prehistoric ancestors? There are
two kinds of evidence. We can learn quite a lot about the material aspects of
their existence –what they ate, what tools they used, how often they moved
camp, how healthy they were – from the archeological record, although its
interpretation is sometimes open to dispute. We can also use information
collected in modern times about people still living by hunting and gathering,
such as Australian aborigines and South African bushmen, making due
allowance for change in environmental conditions. Thus, many
contemporary Stone Age groups have been pushed out into "marginal" semi-
desert environments. In prehistoric times people lived under a wide range of
natural conditions, often much more favorable to human life than the
Kalahari or the Australian outback.
Even in these marginal environments, however, surviving hunters
and gatherers live quite an easy life, working on average just two to four
hours a day. Many daylight hours are spent socializing, dancing or napping.
(See Marshall Sahlins, Stone Age Economics, Tavistock Publications, 1974.)
Their diet is adequate in quantity, varied, and nutritious. For instance, the
Kalahari bushmen eat over a hundred varieties of plant, including fruits,
berries, nuts, gums, roots and bulbs, leafy greens, beans, and melons.
Archeological evidence suggests that our Stone Age ancestors were also
generally well fed and healthy. Late Paleolithic skeletons from Greece and
Turkey show an average height of 5' 9" for men and 5' 5" for women, as
compared to 5' 3" and 5' 0" for skeletons from a later agricultural period
(3,000 BCE).
At least until very recently, agriculture involved much more work
than hunting and gathering. Moreover, as God warned Adam, it was more
exhausting work than the activities it replaced. Farmers have typically
depended heavily on one or two species of grain or tuber (wheat, maize, rice,
potatoes). If the crop failed they starved: recall the potato blight that caused
the great Irish famine. As well as being less reliable, their food supply was
poorer in nutritional quality, with more carbohydrates and less protein and
vitamins.
Farming was also bad for people's health. Dense settlement
facilitated the transmission of disease and made it more difficult to dispose
of human waste away from the living area. The clearing of woodland for
habitation and cultivation created attractive habitats for mosquitoes.
Why then did our ancestors give up their customary way of life and
switch to agriculture? Mark Nathan Cohen (The Food Crisis in Prehistory,
Yale University Press, 1977) argues that for a long time they knew how to
plant, weed, and even irrigate crops, and, like many Amazonian groups
today, did so selectively on a small scale. Not only did they hunt, fish and
forage; they gardened too. But they chose not to farm until forced to do so
by the gradually rising pressure of population on resources. For all its
disadvantages, agriculture can yield more food per unit area, thereby
supporting a denser population.
Who would voluntarily exchange the excitement of the hunt and
easygoing companionship of the foraging expedition, let alone the creative
experimentation of rainforest gardening, for the monotonous, backbreaking
toil of tilling the soil?
The prehistoric development of gardening skills demonstrates that
technological progress did occur in "primitive" communities and, moreover,
that it tended to take more ecologically sustainable forms than it has in class
society. Thus the transition to agriculture did not mark the beginning of
technological progress.
The Neolithic Revolution may have been socially regressive in yet
another sense. Contemporary Stone Age groups are culturally open.
Intermarriage is common across the boundaries not only of local bands but
also of broader speech communities. Among bushmen, "individuals are free
to move from group to group, partake of local resources, and participate in
whatever cooperative social efforts occur wherever they are" (Cohen, p. 62).
The same will apply, we hope, in a future socialist society. In the view of
many though not all prehistorians, the wide geographical distribution of
identical sets of tools (e.g., the Acheulian tool complex) indicates a similar
cultural openness in the Stone Age. Only in the period immediately
preceding the shift to agriculture did Stone Age society fracture into closed
"tribal" groups.
It is not my argument that the Neolithic Revolution and the class
societies that emerged from it have been socially regressive in all respects.
Their cultural, scientific and technological achievements cannot be denied.
But as we contemplate the last few millennia, full of suffering, futility, and
moral and ecological degradation, we may well wonder whether the losses
outweigh the gains.
December 2006
The story goes like this. Everyone is basically equal. There is no ruling class
as we are all citizens in a “democracy.” We live not in capitalism (that
outmoded concept) but in a classless “market economy” where we are all
consumers, taxpayers and investors (if only through our pension schemes).
In some countries the camouflage is taken one step further: the social system
is officially defined to be not just democratic but actually socialist. Those
who insist on pointing out the reality behind the camouflage are labelled
“extremists,” denied access to the mass media and banished from respectable
society.
This camouflage is so familiar to us that it is easy to assume it has
always existed. In fact, it is quite a recent development in historical terms.
Pre-industrial ruling classes never thought of pretending that they did not
exist. On the contrary, they glorified or even deified themselves as
intrinsically superior beings. The Greek philosopher Aristotle, who for many
centuries was considered the fount of all wisdom, wrote that some people are
slaves and others masters in accordance with their natures. Feudal law
highlighted class by specifying in detail the dress appropriate to each class
and making it illegal for people to wear clothes inappropriate to their station
in life.
The situation started to change when the thinkers of the
Enlightenment (such as Voltaire, Rousseau, and Montesquieu) questioned
the doctrine of natural inequality as well as other received ideas. In 1789
revolutionaries overthrew the French monarchy and aristocracy in the name
of the Enlightenment ideals of liberty, equality and fraternity. But some of
them (Babeuf and his followers), disappointed that the revolution had failed
to achieve these ideals, wanted to go further and strike at the roots of
property itself. For the first time a ruling class felt the need for some
camouflage.
In Britain, the transition from feudalism to capitalism was
accompanied by less political upheaval, so the need for concealment was not
felt until later. Democracy was condemned as a dangerous extremist notion,
while the class structure continued to be sanctified by religion and custom.
Nineteenth-century economists like Ricardo and Adam Smith talked openly
about the division of society into classes. They were closer in this respect to
Marx than to their twentieth-century successors. Perhaps you also recall a
verse from the old hymn All Things Bright and Beautiful:
June 2007
January 2008
In late 1989 and early 1990, in the space of a few months, the “communist”
regimes in a string of East European countries fell from power. They were
soon followed by the “Soviet” regime in Russia itself, which collapsed in the
wake of a failed coup in August 1991.
Almost everywhere the change occurred more or less peacefully. This
seemed especially remarkable in light of the history of these regimes, which
in the past had made ruthless use of violence to suppress opposition. In
Russia three anti-coup protestors were killed while trying to halt and disable
a tank. There was one major case of violent transition -- Romania, where
Ceausescu’s dictatorship was overthrown in December 1989 at the cost of
about 1,100 dead and several thousand wounded.
In Poland and Hungary, the ruling parties had already agreed to give
up their power monopoly in 1988, when they entered negotiations with
opposition forces to plan the details of the transition. In East Germany,
Czechoslovakia and Bulgaria, they were not quite so willing to give way, but
nor were they willing to do what was necessary to retain power – that is,
crush the rising wave of popular protest by force.
A lack of will
Nomenklatura capitalism
In the East European countries another factor was at work. For sudden
and unexpected as the “velvet revolutions” may have appeared at the time,
the conditions that made them possible had developed gradually over the
previous decade or so.
Above all, Eastern Europe was no longer strictly within the sphere of
Soviet influence. Soviet troops were being withdrawn from the region. The
“Brezhnev doctrine”, which had justified military intervention in
Czechoslovakia in 1968, was dead. Hard-line East European leaders could
no longer count on economic or military backing from Moscow: Gorbachev
had made that clear to them. Lacking confidence in their own strength and
accustomed to dependence on the Kremlin, they were not likely to act
decisively on their own.
Moreover, a number of the East European countries (especially
Poland) were deeply in debt – to the tune of over $100 billion – to Western
creditors, making them vulnerable to Western pressure. Their economic ties
were increasingly with Western Europe rather than with the Soviet Union or
one another. Close economic ties had developed between East and West
Germany. Hungary was already seeking to join the EEC.
Thus, in terms of great power alignments, Eastern Europe in 1989 was
a “grey zone” between Moscow and Brussels, in the middle of a process of
reorientation from east to west. At some point this external shift was likely
to trigger a corresponding internal change from state to private capitalism.
Awareness of this reality weakened the resolve of “communist” leaders to
struggle against the tide.
Section 9
If we want to save the planet earth, to save life and humanity, we have a
duty to put an end to the capitalist system. Unless we put an end to the
capitalist system, it is impossible to imagine that there will be equality and
justice on this planet earth. This is why I believe that it is important to put
an end to the exploitation of human beings and to the pillage of natural
resources, to put an end to destructive wars for markets and raw materials,
to the plundering of energy, particularly fossil fuels, to the excessive
consumption of goods and to the accumulation of waste. The capitalist
system only allows us to heap up waste. I would like to propose that the
trillions of money earmarked for war should be channelled to make good the
damage to the environment, to make reparations to the earth.
June 2008
Socialist capitalists
April 2010
The word utopia, together with its derivatives utopian and utopianism, is a
familiar part of our political vocabulary. It originated as the title of a work
by the Tudor lawyer, statesman and writer Thomas More, first published in
Latin in 1516 as a traveller’s description of a remote island. Utopia is a pun:
it can be read either as ou-topos, Greek for ‘no place’, or as eu-topos, ‘good
place’ – that is, a good place (society) that exists in the imagination.
More invented the word, but the thing it represents is much older.
Plato in his Republic discussed the nature of the ideal city state. Medieval
serfs took solace in the imaginary ease and plenty of the Land of Cockaigne.
More’s utopia, however, is the first to embody a response to capitalist social
relations, which in the early 16th century were just emerging in England and
the Low Countries (in agriculture and textiles). As the first modern utopia, it
has a special place in the emergence of modern socialist thought.
More’s Utopia consists of two ‘books’. Book I is his account of how
he came to hear of Utopia. Book II describes the Utopians’ way of life –
their towns and farms, government, economy, travel, slaves, marriages,
military discipline, religions.
More presents his story as true fact. Henry VIII sends him to Flanders
as his ambassador to settle a dispute with Spain – and we know that this is
true (it was in 1515; the dispute concerned the wool trade). During a break in
the negotiations he meets his young friend Peter Giles, who introduces him
to an explorer, Raphael Hythloday, just back from a long voyage. There
follows a long conversation between More, Giles and Hythloday.
Giles and More urge Hythloday to put the vast knowledge acquired on
his travels to use by entering the service of a king. Hythloday refuses,
arguing that no courtier dare speak his mind or advocate wise and just
policies. This exchange is thought to reflect More’s misgivings about his
own career in royal service.
The conversation then turns to the situation in England. They discuss
the enclosure (now we call it privatisation) of common land to graze sheep,
the consequent pauperisation and uprooting of the peasantry (“your sheep
devour men”), the futile cruelty of hanging wretches who steal to survive,
and other social ills.
This leads them to the question of remedies. Hythloday declares that
the injustice, conflict and waste inherent in the power of money can be
overcome only by doing away with private property. More objects that this
would remove the incentive to work. (Sounds familiar?) Hythloday replies
that More would think otherwise had he been with him in Utopia.
Utopia is, indeed, a society without private property. Households
contribute to and draw freely on common stocks of goods. Money is used
only in dealings with foreign countries, while gold and jewels are regarded
as baubles for children and “fools” (i.e., the mentally retarded). In these
respects Utopia resembles socialism as we conceive of it.
In other respects, however, it does not. Decision-making procedures
are only partly democratic. A hierarchy of “magistrates” enforces draconian
regulations: travel, for instance, requires official permission. The main
penalty for serious transgressions is enslavement – not to individuals, of
course, but to the community. Thus, there is a class of slaves who do not
participate in common ownership but are themselves owned. Utopia is not a
classless society.
* * *
* * *
* * *
* * *
July 2009
* * *
April 2007
Free access to what?
Some problems of consumption in socialism
* * *
July 2007