Pareto Efficiency
Pareto Efficiency
Pareto Efficiency
Contents
1 Overview
3 Use in engineering
o 3.1 Formal representation
3.1.3 Computation
4 Criticisms
o 4.1 Sen
5 See also
6 Further reading
7 References
Overview
Use in engineering
Example of a Pareto frontier. The boxed points represent feasible choices, and smaller values are
preferred to larger ones. Point C is not on the Pareto Frontier because it is dominated by both
point A and point B. Points A and B are not strictly dominated by any other, and hence do lie on
the frontier.
The notion of Pareto efficiency is also useful in engineering. Given a set of choices and a way of
valuing them, the Pareto frontier or Pareto set or Pareto front is the set of choices that are
Pareto efficient. By restricting attention to the set of choices that are Pareto-efficient, a designer
can make tradeoffs within this set, rather than considering the full range of every parameter.
Formal representation
Pareto frontier
For a given system, the Pareto frontier or Pareto set is the set of parameterizations (allocations)
that are all Pareto efficient. Finding Pareto frontiers is particularly useful in engineering. By
yielding all of the potentially optimal solutions, a designer can make focused tradeoffs within
this constrained set of parameters, rather than needing to consider the full ranges of parameters.
The Pareto frontier, P(Y), may be more formally described as follows. Consider a system with
function
, where X is a compact set of feasible decisions in the metric space
and Y is the feasible set of criterion vectors in
, such that
.
We assume that the preferred directions of criteria values are known. A point
preferred to (strictly dominating) another point
frontier is thus written as:
, written as
is
. The Pareto
.
Relationship to marginal rate of substitution
An important fact about the Pareto frontier in economics is that at a Pareto efficient allocation,
the marginal rate of substitution is the same for all consumers. A formal statement can be derived
by considering a system with m consumers and n goods, and a utility function of each consumer
as
where
constraint is written
multipliers are used:
where
for j=1,...,n.
for i = 2,...,m and j=1,...,n,
is the marginal utility on f' of x (the partial derivative of f with respect to x).
Algorithms for computing the Pareto frontier of a finite set of alternatives have been studied in
computer science, power engineering,[4] sometimes referred to as the maximum vector problem
or the skyline query.[5][6]
Criticisms
Pareto efficiency does not require an equitable distribution of wealth. An economy in which the
wealthy hold the vast majority of resources can be Pareto efficient. This possibility is inherent in
the definition of Pareto efficiency; by requiring that an allocation leave no participant worse off,
Pareto efficiency tends to favor outcomes that do not depart radically from the status quo.
Sen
Amartya Sen has elaborated a mathematical basis for this criticism, pointing out that under
relatively plausible starting conditions, systems of social choice will converge to Pareto efficient,
but inequitable, distributions.[7] A simple example is the distribution of a pie among three people.
The most equitable distribution would assign one third to each person. However the assignment
of, say, a half section to each of two individuals and none to the third is also Pareto optimal
despite not being equitable, because none of the recipients is left worse off than before, and there
are many other such distributions. An example of a Pareto inefficient distribution of the pie
would be allocation of a quarter of the pie to each of the three, with the remainder discarded. The
origin of the pie is conceived as immaterial in these examples. In such cases, in which a
"windfall" that none of the potential distributees actually produced is to be allocated (e.g., land,
inherited wealth, a portion of the broadcast spectrum, or some other resource), the criterion of
Pareto efficiency does not determine a unique optimal allocation.
See also
Bayesian efficiency
Deadweight loss
Efficiency (economics)
Game theory
KaldorHicks efficiency
Multiobjective optimization
Nash equilibrium
Social Choice and Individual Values for the '(weak) Pareto principle'
Welfare economics