Dumping and Anti Dumping
Dumping and Anti Dumping
Dumping and Anti Dumping
This article is about the economics term. For industrial relations and social justice issue,
see Social dumping. For the tax avoidance term, see SUTA dumping.
In economics, "dumping" is a kind of predatory pricing, especially in the context
of international trade. It occurs when manufacturers export a product to another country at a
price either below the price charged in its home market or below its cost of production.
Overview[edit]
A standard technical definition of dumping is the act of charging a lower price for the like
goods in a foreign market than one charges for the same good in a domestic market for
consumption in the home market of the exporter. This is often referred to as selling at less
than "normal value" on the same level of trade in the ordinary course of trade. Under
the World Trade Organization (WTO) Agreement, dumping is condemned (but is not
prohibited) if it causes or threatens to cause material injury to a domestic industry in the
importing country.[1]
The term has a negative connotation, as advocates of competitive markets see "dumping" as
a form of protectionism. Furthermore, advocates for workers and laborers believe that
safeguarding businesses against predatory practices, such as dumping, help alleviate some
of the harsher consequences of such practices between economies at different stages of
development (see protectionism). The Bolkestein directive, for example, was accused in
Europe of being a form of "social dumping," as it favored competition between workers, as
exemplified by the Polish Plumber stereotype. While there are few examples of a national
scale dumping that succeeded in producing a national-level monopoly, there are several
examples of local 'dumping' that produced a monopoly in regional markets for certain
industries. Ron Chernow points to the example of regional oil monopolies in Titan : The Life
of John D. Rockefeller, Sr. where Rockefeller receives a message from Colonel Thompson
outlining an approved strategy where oil in one market, Cincinnati, would be sold at or below
cost to drive competition's profits down and force them to exit the market. In another area
where other independent businesses were already driven out, namely in Chicago, prices
would be increased by a quarter.[2]
Anti-dumping actions[edit]
Legal issues[edit]
If a company exports a product at a price that is lower than the price it normally charges in its
own home market, or sells at a price that does not meet its full cost of production, it is said to
be "dumping" the product. It is a sub part of the various forms of price discrimination and is
classified as third-degree price discrimination. Opinions differ as to whether or not such
practice constitutes unfair competition, but many governments take action against dumping
to protect domestic industry. The WTO agreement does not pass judgment. Its focus is on
how governments can or cannot react to dumpingit disciplines anti-dumping actions, and it
is often called the "anti-dumping agreement". (This focus only on the reaction to dumping
contrasts with the approach of the subsidies and countervailing measures agreement.)
The legal definitions are more precise, but broadly speaking, the WTO agreement allows
governments to act against dumping where there is genuine ("material") injury to the
competing domestic industry. To do so, the government has to show that dumping is taking
place, calculate the extent of dumping (how much lower the export price is compared to the
exporters home market price), and show that the dumping is causing injury or threatening to
cause injury.
European Union anti-dumping is under the purview of the European Council. It is governed
by European Council regulation 384/96. However, implementation of anti-dumping actions
(trade defence actions) is taken after voting by various committees with member state
representation.
The bureaucratic entity responsible for advising member states on anti-dumping actions is
the Directorate General Trade (DG Trade) in Brussels. Community industry can apply to
have an anti-dumping investigation begin. DG Trade first investigates the standing of the
complainants. If they are found to represent at least 25% of community industry, the
investigation will probably begin. The process is guided by quite specific guidance in the
regulations. The DG Trade will make a recommendation to a committee known as the AntiDumping Advisory Committee, on which each member state has one vote. Member states
abstaining will be treated as if they voted in favour of industrial protection, a voting system
which has come under considerable criticism.[4]
As is implied by the criterion for beginning an investigation, EU anti-dumping actions are
primarily considered part of a "trade defence" portfolio. Consumer interests and non-industry
related interests ("community interests") are not emphasized during an investigation. An
investigation typically looks for damage caused by dumping to community producers, and
the level of tariff set is based on the damage done to community producers by dumping.
If consensus is not found, the decision goes to the European Council.
If imposed, duties last for five years theoretically. In practice they last at least a year longer,
because expiry reviews are usually initiated at the end of the five years, and during the
review process the status quo is maintained.
An example of an Anti-dumping duty action taken by the European Union is that of the Antidumping duty imposed upon bicycle imports from China into the EU, which has recently be
continued at a rate of 48.5%.[5] The tax has also been extended to imports from Indonesia,
Malaysia, Sri Lanka and Tunisia.[6] However, some companies are excluded or have a
reduced rate.
Chinese economic situation[edit]
The dumping investigation essentially compares domestic prices of the accused dumping
nation with prices of the imported product on the European market. However, several rules
are applied to the data before the dumping margin is calculated. Most contentious is the
concept of "analogue market". Some exporting nations are not granted "market economy
status" by the EU: China is a prime example because its market status is considered "statesponsored capitalism". In such cases, the DG Trade is prevented from using domestic prices
as the fair measure of the domestic price. A particular export industry may also lose market
status if the DG Trade concludes that this industry receives government assistance. Other
tests applied include the application of international accounting standards and bankruptcy
laws.
The consequences of not being granted market economy status have a big impact on the
investigation. For example, if China is accused of dumping widgets, the basic approach is to
consider the price of widgets in China against the price of Chinese widgets in Europe. But
China does not have market economy status, so Chinese domestic prices can not be used
as the reference. Instead, the DG Trade must decide upon an analogue market: a market
which does have market economy status, and which is similar enough to China. Brazil and
Mexico have been used, but the United States is a popular analogue market. In this case,
the price of widgets in the United States is regarded as the substitute for the price of widgets
in China. This process of choosing an analogue market is subject to the influence of the
complainant, which has led to some criticism that it is an inherent bias in the process.
However, China has one of the world's cheapest labour costs. Criticisms have argued that it
is quite unreasonable to compare China's goods price to the United States as analogue.
China is now developing to a more free and open market, unlike its planned-economy in the
early 1960s, the market in China is more willing to embrace the global competition. It is thus
required to improve its market regulations and conquer the free trade barriers to improve the
situation and produce a properly judged pricing level to assess the "dumping" behaviour.
Agricultural support[edit]
European Union and Common Agricultural Policy[edit]
The Common Agricultural Policy of the European Union has often been accused of dumping
though significant reforms were made as part of the Agreement on Agriculture at theUruguay
round of GATT negotiations in 1992 and in subsequent incremental reforms, notably
the Luxembourg Agreement in 2003. Initially the CAP sought to increase European
agricultural production and provide support to European farmers through a process of market
intervention whereby a special fundthe European Agricultural Guidance and Guarantee
Fundwould buy up surplus agricultural produce if the price fell below a certain centrally
determined level (the intervention level). Through this measure European farmers were given
a "guaranteed" price for their produce when sold in the European community. In addition to
this internal measure a system of export reimbursements ensured that European products
sold outside of the European community would sell at or below world prices at no detriment
to the European producer. This policy was heavily criticised as distorting world trade and
since 1992 the policy has moved away from market intervention and towards direct
payments to farmers regardless of production (a process of "decoupling"). Furthermore, the
payments are generally dependent on the farmer fulfilling certain environmental or animal
welfare requirements so as to encourage responsible, sustainable farming in what is termed
"multifunctional" agricultural subsidiesthat is, the social, environmental and other benefits
from subsidies that do not include a simple increase in production.