The Lucknow Pact of 1916
The Lucknow Pact of 1916
The Lucknow Pact of 1916
The author would like to thank the staff at the Gokhale Institute of
Politics and Economics, and Suhas Palshikar for his suggestions
and comments.
Abhay Datar (abhaydatar@hotmail.com) is at the department of politics
and public administration, University of Pune.
Economic & Political Weekly
EPW
vol xlviI no 10
SPECIAL ARTICLE
paper argues that the pact was signed by the Congress leaders
in the expectation that the post-war reforms would take a
certain shape. However, the reforms as envisaged by the
Montagu-Chelmsford scheme were somewhat different. It is
this change, rather than bad faith or latent communalism, that
led the Congressmen to backpedal on their support to the
Lucknow Pact. Furthermore, this paper also argues that the
pact was a badly drafted agreement, with ambiguities and
omissions in key provisions which ultimately led to contrasting and contradictory interpretations.
In Historiography
vol xlviI no 10
EPW
SPECIAL ARTICLE
What the colonial rulers were planning to deliver was something different. On 20 August 1917, Edwin Montagu announced
in the House of Commons that the policy of the government
towards India in the future would be in the direction of gradual development of self-governing institutions with a view to
the progressive realisation of responsible government in
India (Report on Indian Constitutional Reforms 1918: 1). The
phrase responsible government obviously did not, and no
longer could mean, that the Government of India would continue
to be responsible only to the imperial government in London,
or that the provincial governments would be responsible only
to the Government of India. It naturally implied that the
government would be responsible, in what measure it was not
defined, to the people through their elected representatives in
the legislative assemblies. One study of the process of reforms
has interpreted this phrase even more expansively to mean
government by ministers who commanded a majority in the
legislature (Robb 1986: 77). Whatever might be the interpretation of this key phrase, one aspect was clear. The pattern
of relations between the executive and the legislature was
about to change, albeit only in the provinces and not at the
all-India level.
However, it was equally obvious that the British were not
going to hand over power to predominantly elected legislatures with an Indian majority. Yet the executive had to be
made responsible in some measure to the elected assemblies,
whose size and the proportion of elected members in which
was going to be increased in any case. The solution that
emerged was dyarchy, which had been discussed in detail in
the Montagu-Chelmsford Report (Report on Indian Constitutional Reforms 1918: 140). This meant that the powers allotted
to the provinces would be divided into two parts known as
transferred subjects and reserved subjects. The former
would be handed over to ministers appointed from amongst
the elected members of the legislatures. The latter would continue to be handled by members of the governors executive
councils who would continue to be appointed by the governor
and the legislature was to have no part in their appointment.
Though the Montagu-Chelmsford Report claimed that the
ministers would be responsible to their constituents and not to
the legislature (ibid: 142), this was clearly an illogical and illusory position, contrary to all practice of parliamentary government. It was clear that the ministers, if they were to continue
in office, must enjoy the confidence of the assembly. The Joint
Parliamentary Committee of the Government of India Bill,
1919, conceded this and agreed that the ministers should enjoy
the confidence of the house (Curtis 1920: 550). This idea of
Economic & Political Weekly
EPW
vol xlviI no 10
SPECIAL ARTICLE
vol xlviI no 10
EPW
SPECIAL ARTICLE
scale and such intentions could hardly have been kept a secret.
While it is true that many Congressmen were opposed to communal electorates as such, the very fact that they accepted the
pact shows that they had accepted them, albeit grudgingly.
Prior to the Montagu-Chelmsford Report, there is no evidence to
suggest that the Congress leaders planned to repudiate the pact.
A latent Hindu communalism can be a competing explanation. It is true that there were many Congressmen who could
be legitimately described as Hindu communalist or had
sympathies in that direction and that many Hindu Congress
leaders had to be coaxed of the need to approve of the pact
(Owen 1972; Robinson 2008). Equally true is that fact that
there was a considerable overlap between the leaders of the
Congress and the newly emergent Hindu Mahasabha (Gordon
1975: 145-203). But these leaders could have easily maintained
their opposition to the pact instead of declaring it before the
Southborough Committee. Indeed these leaders did not signal
their opposition prior to the Montagu-Chelmsford Report.
The old dividing line between extremists and moderates also
cannot explain the opposition.
If these two possible explanations are not persuasive, then
the only other plausible explanation is structural. The Congress
Note
1 Note justifying and supplementing the Congress-League Scheme of Reform with An
Introductory Representation To His Excellency, the Right Honourable Baron Chelmsford,
The Viceroy and Governor General of India
and The Right Honourable Edwin Samuel
Montagu, The Secretary of State for India
1917: 47-49.
References
Ambedkar, Dr B R (1946(1967)): Pakistan Or The
Partition of India (Bombay: Thackers & Co).
Chand, Tara (2005(1972)): History of the Freedom
Movement in India, Volume Three (New Delhi:
Publications Divisions, Government of India).
Pp viii + 318
ISBN 978-81-250-3953-2
2010
Rs 350
Available from
EPW
vol xlviI no 10
69