Options Trading Activity and Firm Valuation
Options Trading Activity and Firm Valuation
Options Trading Activity and Firm Valuation
by
July 5, 2007
Abstract
We study the effect of options trading volume on the value of the underlying firm
after controlling for other variables that may affect firm value. The volume of
options trading might have an effect on firm value because it helps to complete the
market (allocational efficiency) and because the options market impounds
information faster than the stock market (informational efficiency). We find that
firms with more options trading have higher values. This result holds for all sample
firms and for the subset of firms with positive options volume.
Contacts
Roll Schwartz Subrahmanyam
Voice: 1-310-825-6118 1-310-825-2873 1-310-825-5355
Fax: 1-310-206-8404 1-310-825-6384 1-310-206-5455
E-mail: Rroll@anderson.ucla.edu Eschwart@anderson.ucla.edu Asubrahm@anderson.ucla.edu
Address: Anderson School Anderson School Anderson School
UCLA UCLA UCLA
Los Angeles, CA 90095-1481 Los Angeles, CA 90095-1481 Los Angeles, CA 90095-1481
1
Options Trading Activity and Firm Valuation
Abstract
We study the effect of options trading volume on the value of the underlying firm
after controlling for other variables that may affect firm value. The volume of
options trading might have an effect on firm value because it helps to complete the
information faster than the stock market (informational efficiency). We find that
firms with more options trading have higher values. This result holds for all sample
firms and for the subset of firms with positive options volume.
2
1. Introduction
More than thirty years ago Ross (1976) argued that options written on existing assets can
covered by traded securities. In the absence of complete markets, simple options are
markets have experienced an exponential growth, both in the number of underlying assets
This paper provides empirical evidence about options activity and the market values of
traded companies. Our central arguments revolve around how options affect incentives
to trade on private information. If options help to complete the market, agents with
information about future contingencies should be able to trade more effectively on their
prefer to trade options rather than stock, because of increased opportunities for leverage
Supporting the preceding notions, Cao and Wei (2007) find evidence that information
asymmetry is greater for options than for the underlying stock, implying that agents with
information find the options market a more efficient venue for trading. This finding is
bolstered further by Easley, O’Hara, and Srinivas (1998) and Chakravarty, Gulen, and
Mayhew (2004) who find that options order flows contain information about the future
direction of the underlying stock price. Finally, the analysis of Admati and Pfleiderer
3
(1988) indicates that informed traders are more active when volume is greater. These
arguments together imply that informational efficiency would be greater in more actively
traded options.
prices reveal more information, then resources are allocated more efficiently, which
translates to higher firm valuations. A more direct argument is that greater informational
efficiency reduces the risk of investing in an asset because market prices reflect
information more precisely; which also would tend to make the asset more valuable. It
can thus be argued that, ceteris paribus, markets for claims in firms with higher options
trading volume should be more informationally efficient and thus valued more highly.
It is worth noting that the mere listing of an option does not necessarily imply a valuation
benefit of the type discussed above. If the options market has insufficient volume or
liquidity, the incremental valuation benefit from listing would be minor or even
immaterial because informed traders see no advantage to trading in options (Admati and
Pfleiderer, 1988). Any valuation benefit of options listing should depend on substantial
trading activity. To the best of our knowledge, the relation between options trading
For a large sample of firm during the 10-year period 1996 to 2005 we analyze the effect
of options trading volume on firm value after controlling for other variables that may also
affect firm value such as firm size, share turnover, return on assets, capital expenditures,
4
leverage and dividend payments. Following other studies (Lang and Stulz, 1992,
Allayannis and Weston, 2001, and Carter, Rogers, and Simkins, 2006) we use a measure
We find strong evidence that firms with more options trading have higher value. This
result is robust to the inclusion of all sample firms, or to the restricted set of firms with
The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 reviews the literature and describes our
hypotheses. Section 3 describes the data. Section 4 presents the main empirical results,
5
2. Literature Review and Economic Hypotheses
Our paper lies at the intersection of the literatures on derivatives pricing, market
microstructure, and corporate finance. Black and Scholes (1973) treat options as
securities that are redundant and can be replicated in continuous time by investments in
stocks and bonds. However, it is well-known that when markets are incomplete, options
cannot be replicated by simple securities such as stocks and bonds (see Ross, 1976,
Hakansson, 1982, and Detemple and Selden, 1991). Another branch of the literature
shows that options cannot be dynamically replicated with stocks and bonds when the
stochastic process for the underlying stock involves features such as stochastic
discontinuities (see, for example, Naik and Lee, 1990, and Pan and Liu, 2003).
If options are not redundant, then their introduction may allow agents to expand the set of
contingencies available through trading and thus may be associated with a positive price
effect on the underlying stock. Indeed, Conrad (1989) documents an upward effect on
stock prices following an options listing using an event study approach. However,
Sorescu (2000) argues that that Conrad’s (1989) results are specific to her chosen sample
period, and find different results for a more recent sample period. This indicates that
there is not yet consensus on the effects of options listing on stock prices.
We contend, however, that the valuation benefit of options should depend on trading
activity in options, not merely listing; i.e., there is a link between options volume and
6
informational efficiency. Previous literature, both theoretical and empirical, has argued
that options increase the amount of private information conveyed by prices (see Biais and
Hillion, 1994, Easley, O’Hara, and Srinivas, 1998, or Chakravarty, Gulen, and Mayhew,
2004). Such increases in informational efficiency may occur because informed agents
are able to cover more states when options markets are available.1 In the presence of
frictions, options may also allow informed agents to obtain leverage more readily.
Option listing does not automatically imply that informed agents can take better
advantage of their information. Indeed, as Kyle (1985) points out, agents with private
information need to camouflage their trades from other agents to be effective. Do new
markets always attract a large number of agents? Pagano (1989) sheds light on this
question by arguing that microstructure models have multiple equilibria where “liquidity
begets liquidity.” Thus, if agents conjecture that a new market will have no liquidity they
optimally desist from trading and this belief becomes self-fulfilling. On the other hand if
the conjecture is the opposite, then a market with active trading is sustainable. This line
of thinking indicates that different options markets may have varying degrees of thinness,
which also implies different degrees of informational efficiency, with greater option
What is the link between informational efficiency and firm valuation? A vast literature
examines this question. Fishman and Hagerty (1992), Khanna, Bradley, and Slezak
(1994), Dow and Gorton (1997), and Subrahmanyam and Titman (1999) all conclude that
1
Note that more informed trading affects the costs of liquidity trading. But the valuation effects of such
costs are limited because they are a zero sum transfer from liquidity to informed traders.
7
if prices convey more information, corporate resources are allocated more efficiently, and
this leads to greater firm valuation. Alternatively, one could also argue that greater
informational efficiency reduces the conditional risk of investing in a risky asset (Kyle,
All of the preceding arguments imply that options with greater trading activity would be
At the same time, it is worth noting other possible hypotheses. For example, if options
lead to increased price uncertainty due to more speculative trading by uninformed agents
(De Long, Shleifer, Summers, and Waldmann, 1990) then the valuation effect of options
could be negative. Our tests may thus be viewed as an effort to distinguish between these
competing hypotheses.
2
To see this consider the extreme case where informed agents have perfectly precise information and the
price reveals all of their information. In this case the conditional risk of investing in the asset is zero and it
is clearly worth more to invest more in this asset, ceteris paribus, relative to an asset where the price
reflects the information imprecisely.
8
3. Data
We collect data on options trading from Options Metrics. This database includes daily
trading volume for each individual put and call option traded on U.S. listed equities. We
calculate total annual options volume for each stock in the database and then match these
variables.3
Tobin’s q is computed as the sum of the market capitalization of the firm’s common
equity, the liquidation value of its preferred stock, and the book value of its debt divided
by the book value of the firm’s assets. Our control variables are as follows. A proxy for
the firm’s leverage, long-term debt to total assets, is intended to measure the likelihood of
distress. Profitability, measured by return on assets (ROA), is net income divided by the
book value of assets. This variable is intended to capture the notion that more profitable
firms may have more favorable investment opportunities, leading to higher valuations.
On the other hand, high ROA may also signal that the firm is in a mature phase, and has
constructed as capital expenditures divided by sales. Firms that invest more presumably
have higher growth opportunities that should translate to a higher q. A dummy variable
3
An annual observation interval is dictated by the necessity of using accounting data from the annual report.
9
for whether the firm pays a dividend proxies for capital constraints (firms that pay
dividends may have more free cash flow, which may potentially be used to overinvest in
marginal projects). All these controls have been used in previous literature, e.g.,
Allayannis and Weston (2001), Carter, Rogers, and Simkins (2006). In addition, we
include share turnover in the underlying stock to account for any spurious conclusions
Table 1 gives the number of firms in each sample year. The number of firms with non-
missing Compustat data ranges from more than 6300 in 1996 to about 4400 in 2005. The
decrease in is likely due to the tech bust, which was accompanied by financial distress,
bankruptcy and eventual delisting. The number of firms with positive options trading
volume increased modestly during this same period, from 1342 in 1996 to 1705 in 2004,
Any firm with no options volume data in Options Metrics for a particular year is assumed
to have an options volume of zero in that year. This suggests a natural bifurcation of
samples into one consisting of all firms, (with the majority having zero options volume),
Table 2 presents summary statistics (over all firms and years) for Tobin’s q, the control
variables, and options volume. Panel A, covers all firms while Panel B includes firms
with positive options volume. The mean value of q for the whole sample is about 1.9.
The mean value of return on assets is negative, presumably because small (tech) firms did
10
not perform well during this period. Panel B shows that firms with positive options
volume have a higher Tobin’s q, both mean and median. Such firms are also larger and
Table 3 presents correlations among the variables (again, pooled over firms and years.)
Again, Panel A is for the full sample while Panel B is for firms with positive options
volume. The correlation between Tobin’s q and options volume is positive for both
samples and reaches almost 18% for the subsample with positive options volume.
Options volume is strongly positively correlated with firm size as well as share turnover.
because stocks with high current income are in the “mature” phase of their life-cycle with
As a pre-amble to the main analysis, consider the subsample of firms with positive
options volume sorted into deciles by options volume each year. For each decile, we
calculate the average value of Tobin’s q across all years within our sample. The plot of
As can be seen, the valuation metric q monotonically increases with options volume,
supporting the positive correlation between q and options trading activity documented in
Table 3. In terms of magnitudes, q for the decile with the highest options volume is
11
about 140% higher than that for the lowest options volume decile, and an unreported test
The next section tests formally whether options volume has an incremental effect on q
12
4. Regression Results
We now examine the determinants of Tobin’s q. Since our arguments are cross-sectional
in nature, the initial approach is to run year-by-year cross-sectional regressions and then
test the significance of the time series mean of the cross-sectional coefficients. But the
potential problem, t-statistics are corrected according to the procedure of Newey and
West (1987).4 Results for the full sample of firms and for the subsample with positive
postulated in the previous section. ROA also is inversely related to q, indicating that high
ROA signals firm maturity and relative paucity of future growth options. On the other
hand, capital expenditures, presumably proxying for future growth opportunities, have a
Share turnover has a positive impact on valuation, consistent with the presence of a
liquidity premium in asset prices (Amihud and Mendelson, 1986). Size has a weak but
positive impact on Tobin’s q. In general, these results are consistent with the rationales
4
As suggested by Newey and West (1994), the lag-length equals the integer portion of 4(T/100}2/9, where
T is the number of observations.
13
The coefficient of options volume is positive and significant for both subsamples
indicating that options volume has an upward impact on firm valuation. For all firms, the
magnitude of the coefficient implies that a one standard deviation move in options
volume implies a 16% higher q relative to its mean value. The effect for the subsample
of firms with positive options value is much stronger: in this case, a one-standard
deviation move in options volume implies a q that is higher relative to its mean by 118%.
Thus, the effect of options trading on firm valuation is both statistically and economically
significant.
14
5. Robustness Checks
We perform various checks on our results, and in all of these additional tests, the central
Table 6 presents a panel regression that pools the time series and cross-sectional data.
The Parks (1967) procedure is used to control for serial correlation in the error terms.
The results are qualitatively similar to those in Tables 4 and 5. Thus q is negatively
associated with the dividend dummy and leverage, but positively associated with firm
The next issue we consider is endogeneity; specifically, whether high Tobin’s q causes
increased options trading, rather than the reverse. One could argue, albeit implausibly,
that high q firms may attract more attention and this may translate to greater options
volume. To address this issue, one needs an instrument for options volume that is
We propose that options volume may be related to the average absolute moneyness, the
relative difference between the stock’s market price and the option’s strike price. Since
prefer at-the-money options for their greater sensitivity. On the other hand, for someone
15
without volatility information, at-the-money options have the greatest exposure to
volatility risk and hence may be eschewed for this reason. Moreover, it could also be
the case that informed traders may be attracted to out of the money options because they
provide the maximum leverage, but uninformed traders may migrate to in the money
The preceding arguments provide a link between absolute moneyness and options
volume, but do not specify an unambiguous direction, which remains an empirical issue.
exchanges periodically list new options with strike prices close to the recent market price
of the underlying stock, so there should be no mechanical link between moneyness and
stock prices.
Given the preceding arguments, we calculate the annual average of the daily absolute
deviation of the exercise price of each option from the closing price of the underlying
Estimates of this regression appear in Table 7. (Note that this regression necessarily uses
5
Pan and Poteshman (2006) document that volume from customers of discount brokers is slightly higher in
out of the money options than other ones.
6
For option k on stock j for day t, the absolute deviation is |ln(pricej,t/strikek)|. This is averaged over all k
and t within a year for each stock j.
7
The even-moneyness variable is positively and significantly related to volume for the overall sample.
Paradoxically, this does not necessarily mean that volume tends to be higher in options that are away from
the money. It might also be induced if the options exchange lists a larger number of options, with different
exercise prices, on firms with more overall options trading. But regardless of the underlying reason, so
long as the instrument is well correlated with the explanatory variable (options volume) and does not
inherently depend on the dependent variable (Tobin’s q), the instrumental variable procedure is well-
specified.
16
only that subsample for which the options volume is strictly positive because the
instrument is undefined when no option is traded.) As can be seen, the coefficient for
options volume remains significant in this regression and its magnitude is close to that in
Table 5, suggesting that the main result is not due to reverse causality.
Next, from Table 2, it may be seen that the distribution of options volume is skewed
because the mean is quite different from the median. To address this, we perform a
robustness check using the logarithm of options volume (by definition, using only those
firms with positive levels of options trading activity). Results from this alternative
specification (the analog of Table 5) appear in Table 8. As can be seen, the coefficient
of options volume remains positive and strongly significant, while the other coefficients
To obtain a more complete picture of the effect of options trading on valuation, Table 9
reports the year-by-year regression coefficients that are used in computing the averages
reported in Table 8. In every year, the coefficient of options trading is positive and
strongly significant. This provides reassurance that the results are not driven by high
We also performed the analog of the panel regression presented in Table 6 (using the
Parks (1967) procedure) for the logarithm of options volume, and found the coefficient of
17
this coefficient is greater than that in Table 6. Thus, the results are qualitatively
logarithms of firm size and share turnover;8 the coefficient of options volume does not
change appreciably in these specifications. Using share volume instead of share turnover
and scaling options volume by shares outstanding also have little impact on the
deviation of daily returns) in the regression corresponding to Table 7. The concern is that
options trading activity proxies for stock riskiness which could potentially affect q.
However, the return volatility variable was not significant (its t-statistic was 1.32), which
indicates that perhaps some of the other variables, such as leverage, account for the effect
of stock riskiness on q. Even in the presence of return volatility, however, the options
volume variable remained significant with a coefficient of 0.094 and a t-statistic of 4.75.
information production, such as the extent of analyst following. We thus included the
number of analysts following a company (from I/B/ES). We did not find the role of
8
The other variables in the regression are not constrained to be strictly positive, thus precluding us from
taking their logarithms.
9
Another issue is whether options volume is simply proxying for stock price runup (stocks that have gone
up would attract options volume and past returns may also be related to q). It is debatable whether past
return should be included as an explanatory variable for q over and above profitability measures such as
ROA. We found, however that including the past year’s return in the equation for q did not alter the
significance of options volume (though the past return was marginally significant at the 10% level).
18
analysts to be significant in the analog of Table 5, whereas options volume remained
significant. Details of all of these additional robustness checks are available upon
request.
19
5. Conclusion
We find reliable evidence that the volume of options trading is associated with higher
firm valuations. This result is consistent with the dual notions that more options trading
allocation.
The key point of our paper is that the degree to which an option is traded, not its mere
consider whether this notion extends to other scenarios. For example, countries such as
India have futures contracts on individual stocks, and the effect of such contracts on
valuation could be ascertained. In addition, the impact of index options and futures on
market valuation seems like a worthwhile exercise. Such issues are left for future
research.
20
References
Admati, A., and P. Pfleiderer, 1988, A theory of intraday patterns: Volume and price
variability, Review of Financial Studies 1, 3-40.
Allayannis, G., and J. Weston, 2001, The use of foreign currency derivatives and firm
market value, Review of Financial Studies 14, 243-276.
Amihud, Yakov, and Haim Mendelson, 1986, Asset pricing and the bid-ask spread,
Journal of Financial Economics 17, 223-249.
Back, K., 1992, Asymmetric information and options, Review of Financial Studies 6,
435-472.
Biais, B., and P. Hillion, 1994, Insider and Liquidity Trading in Stock and Options
Markets, Review of Financial Studies 7, 743-780.
Black, F., and M. Scholes, 1973, The pricing of options and corporate liabilities,
Journal of Political Economy 81, 637-654.
Khanna, N., S. Slezak, and M. Bradley, 1994, Insider trading, outside search, and
resource allocation: why firms and society may disagree on insider trading restrictions,
Review of Financial Studies 7, 575-608.
Cao, M., and J. Wei, 2007, Commonality in liquidity: Evidence from the option
market, working paper, University of Toronto.
Carter, D., D. Rogers, and B. Simkins, 2006, Hedging and value in the U.S. airline
industry, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 18, 21-33.
Chakravarty, S., H. Gulen, and S. Mayhew, 2004, Informed Trading in Stock and Option
Markets, Journal of Finance 59, 1235–1258.
Conrad, J., 1989, The price effect of option introduction, Journal of Finance 44, 487-498.
De Long, B., A. Shleifer, L. Summers, and R. Waldmann, 1990, Noise trader risk in
financial markets, Journal of Political Economy 98, 703-738.
Detemple, J., and L. Selden, 1991, A general equilibrium analysis of option and stock
market interactions, International Economic Review 32, 279-303.
Dow, J., and G. Gorton, 1997, Stock market efficiency and economic efficiency: Is
there a connection?, Journal of Finance 52, 1087-1129.
21
Easley, D., M. O’Hara, and P. Srinivas, 1998, Option volume and stock prices: Evidence
on where informed traders trade, Journal of Finance 53 431-465.
Fishman, M., and K. Hagerty, 1992, Insider Trading and the Efficiency of Stock
Prices, RAND Journal of Economics 23, 106-122.
Hakansson, N., 1982, Changes in the financial market: Welfare and price effects and the
basic theorems of value conservation, Journal of Finance 37, 977-1004.
Lang, L., and R. Stulz, 1994, Tobin’s q, Corporate Diversification, and Firm
Performance, Journal of Political Economy 102, 1248-1280.
Naik, V., and M. Lee, 1990, General equilibrium pricing of options on the market
portfolio with discontinuous returns, Review of Financial Studies 3, 493-521.
Newey, W., and K. West, 1987, A simple positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and
autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix, Econometrica 55, 703-708.
Newey, W., and K. West, 1994, Automatic lag selection in covariance matrix
estimation, Review of Economic Studies 61, 631-653.
Pagano, M., 1989, Trading Volume and Asset Liquidity, Quarterly Journal of Economics
104, 255-274.
Pan, J., and J. Liu, 2003, Dynamic derivative strategies, Journal of Financial Economics
69, 401-430.
Pan, J., and A. Poteshman, 2006, The information in options volume for future stock
prices, Review of Financial Studies 19, 871-908.
Ross, S., 1976, Options and efficiency, Quarterly Journal of Economics 90, 75-89.
Sorescu, S., 2000, The effect of options on stock prices: 1973 to 1995, Journal of
Finance 55, 487–514.
Subrahmanyam, A., and S. Titman, 1999, The Going-Public Decision and the
Development of Financial Markets, Journal of Finance 54, 1045-1082.
22
Table 1
Number of firms with non-missing data.
This table contains the sample size of firms each year. The second column lists the total
number of firms with available data for the dependent variable (Tobin’s q) and the
control variables. The third column lists the number of firms with positive options
volume. Firms with no data on options trading activity are assumed to have options
volume of zero.
Positive
Year All firms options
volume
1996 6376 1342
1997 6441 1575
1998 6185 1717
1999 5970 1686
2000 5817 1638
2001 5336 1503
2002 5087 1597
2003 4862 1565
2004 4886 1705
2005 4396 1655
23
Table 2
Summary statistics
Tobin’s q is defined as the market capitalization of common stock plus liquidation value
of preferred shares plus book value of long-term debt divided by total assets, Optvol is
the annual options volume (in ten thousands of shares), Size is market capitalization (in
billions of dollars), Stkturn is the annual share turnover in the underlying stock, ROA is
the return on assets defined as net income divided by the book value of assets, CapX is
capital expenditures divided by sales, LTD is long-term debt divided by book value of
assets, and DivDum is an indicator variable for whether the firm pays a dividend.
Standard
Variable Mean Median
Deviation
Tobin’s q 1.930 1.157 3.378
Options volume 1842 0 23128
Size 2.157 0.1878 12.44
Share turnover 1.547 0.9500 3.405
ROA -0.0695 0.0253 0.573
CapX 0.6855 0.0402 33.13
LTD 0.1813 0.1104 0.2685
DivDum 0.3168 0 0.465
Standard
Variable Mean Median
Deviation
Tobin’s q 2.258 1.457 2.922
Options volume 6379 388.2 42706
Size 5.154 1.012 19.68
Share Turnover 2.242 1.602 2.455
ROA -0.0109 0.0399 0.2990
CapX 0.6269 0.0492 41.46
LTD 0.1850 0.1333 0.2105
DivDum 0.3883 0 0.4874
24
Table 3
Correlation matrix
Tobin’s q is defined as the market capitalization of common stock plus liquidation value
of preferred shares plus book value of long-term debt divided by total assets, Optvol is
the annual options volume (in ten thousands of shares), Size is market capitalization (in
billions of dollars), Stkturn is the annual share turnover in the underlying stock, ROA is
the return on assets defined as net income divided by the book value of assets, CapX is
capital expenditures divided by sales, LTD is long-term debt divided by book value of
assets, and DivDum is an indicator variable for whether the firm pays a dividend.
Options Share
Tobin’s q Size ROA CapX LTD
Volume turnover
Options volume 0.0899
Size 0.0609 0.4134
Share Turnover 0.0783 0.0691 -0.0084
ROA -0.1312 0.0156 0.0402 -0.0589
CapX 0.0081 0.0003 -0.0013 -0.0007 -0.0075
LTD -0.0470 -0.0149 -0.0091 -0.0453 -0.0760 0.0141
DivDum -0.0993 0.0149 0.1495 -0.1024 0.1489 -0.0118 0.0838
Options Share
Tobin’s q Size ROA CapX LTD
Volume turnover
Options volume 0.1778
Size 0.1038 0.4676
Share Turnover 0.1513 0.1376 -0.0788
ROA -0.0545 0.0266 0.0748 -0.0633
CapX 0.0028 0.0006 -0.0006 -0.0004 -0.0045
LTD -0.1273 -0.0383 -0.0330 -0.0975 -0.0716 0.0127
DivDum -0.1667 0.0049 0.1829 -0.2933 0.1838 -0.0104 0.0655
25
Table 4
Time-series coefficient averages and Newey-West corrected t-statistics for year-by-
year cross-sectional regressions from 1996 through 2005 for Tobin’s q as the
dependent variable, using the full sample of firms with available data.
Tobin’s q is defined as the market capitalization of common stock plus liquidation value
of preferred shares plus book value of long-term debt divided by total assets, Optvol is
the annual options volume (in ten thousands of shares), Size is market capitalization (in
billions of dollars), Stkturn is the annual share turnover in the underlying stock, ROA is
the return on assets defined as net income divided by the book value of assets, CapX is
capital expenditures divided by sales, LTD is long-term debt divided by book value of
assets, and DivDum is an indicator variable for whether the firm pays a dividend.
26
Table 5
Time-series coefficient averages and Newey-West corrected t-statistics for year-by-
year cross-sectional regressions from 1996 through 2005 for Tobin’s q as the
dependent variable, using only those firms with positive options volume.
Tobin’s q is defined as the market capitalization of common stock plus liquidation value
of preferred shares plus book value of long-term debt divided by total assets, Optvol is
the annual options volume (in ten thousands of shares), Size is market capitalization (in
billions of dollars), Stkturn is the annual share turnover in the underlying stock, ROA is
the return on assets defined as net income divided by the book value of assets, CapX is
capital expenditures divided by sales, LTD is long-term debt divided by book value of
assets, and DivDum is an indicator variable for whether the firm pays a dividend.
27
Table 6
Panel estimation for the period 1996 to 2005 for Tobin’s q as the dependent
variable.
Tobin’s q is defined as the market capitalization of common stock plus liquidation value
of preferred shares plus book value of long-term debt divided by total assets, Optvol is
the annual options volume (in ten thousands of shares), Size is market capitalization (in
billions of dollars), Stkturn is the annual share turnover in the underlying stock, ROA is
the return on assets defined as net income divided by the book value of assets, CapX is
capital expenditures divided by sales, LTD is long-term debt divided by book value of
assets, and DivDum is an indicator variable for whether the firm pays a dividend. The
Parks (1967) procedure is used to account for autocorrelation, using a balanced panel of
2290 firms present in every year of the sample.
Panel Estimates
Variable Coefficient t-statistic
Optvol 0.0460 3.06
Size 36.41 4.78
Stkturn 0.0616 7.26
ROA 0.1781 1.20
CapX*100 -11.48 -1.70
LTD -1.316 -16.80
Divdum -0.3618 -4.57
Number of firms: 2290
28
Table 7
Time-series coefficient averages and Newey-West corrected t-statistics for year-by-
year cross-sectional regressions from 1996 through 2005 for Tobin’s q as the
dependent variable, using only those firms with positive options volume and using
annual average absolute moneyness as an instrument for options volume.
Tobin’s q is defined as the market capitalization of common stock plus liquidation value
of preferred shares plus book value of long-term debt divided by total assets, IV(Optvol)
is the instrumental variable estimate of annual options volume (in ten thousands of
shares) using the average absolute deviations from even-moneyness as the instrument,
Size is market capitalization (in billions of dollars), Stkturn is the annual share turnover
in the underlying stock, ROA is the return on assets defined as net income divided by the
book value of assets, CapX is capital expenditures divided by sales, LTD is long-term
debt divided by book value of assets, and DivDum is an indicator variable for whether the
firm pays a dividend.
29
Table 8
Time-series coefficient averages and Newey-West corrected t-statistics for year-by-
year cross-sectional regressions from 1996 through 2005 for Tobin’s q as the
dependent variable, using the logarithm of options volume.
Tobin’s q is defined as the market capitalization of common stock plus liquidation value
of preferred shares plus book value of long-term debt divided by total assets, Optvol is
the annual options volume (in ten thousands of shares), Size is market capitalization (in
billions of dollars), Stkturn is the annual share turnover in the underlying stock, ROA is
the return on assets defined as net income divided by the book value of assets, CapX is
capital expenditures divided by sales, LTD is long-term debt divided by book value of
assets, and DivDum is an indicator variable for whether the firm pays a dividend.
30
Table 9
Year-by-year coefficients and t-statistics for annual cross-sectional regressions from
1996 through 2005 for Tobin’s q as the dependent variable, using the logarithm of
options volume.
Tobin’s q is defined as the market capitalization of common stock plus liquidation value
of preferred shares plus book value of long-term debt divided by total assets. The
explanatory variables are the natural logarithm of optvol, i.e., the annual options volume,
Size: market capitalization, Stkturn: the annual share turnover in the underlying stock,
ROA: the return on assets defined as net income divided by the book value of assets,
CapX: capital expenditures divided by sales, LTD: long-term debt divided by book value
of assets, and DivDum, which is an indicator variable for whether the firm pays a
dividend. Only the coefficients of ln(options volume) are reported.
31
4
3.5
2.5
Average Tobin's q
1.5
0.5
0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Options volume decile
Firms with positive options volume during 1996-2005 are sorted into ten deciles by
options volume. The mean value of Tobin’s q over all sample years within each decile is
depicted above.
32