The Neoclassical Revival Growth Gone: Peter J. Klenow and Andres Rodriguez-Clare
The Neoclassical Revival Growth Gone: Peter J. Klenow and Andres Rodriguez-Clare
The Neoclassical Revival Growth Gone: Peter J. Klenow and Andres Rodriguez-Clare
Klenowand AndresRodriguez-Clare
GRADUATE SCHOOL OF BUSINESS, UNIVERSITYOF CHICAGO
The
Neoclassical
in
Growth
Too
Far?
Revival
Economics:
Has
It
Gone
1. Introduction
Theories endogenizing a country's technology, such as Romer (1990) and
Grossman and Helpman (1991), arose from the desire to explain the
enormous disparity of levels and growth rates of per capita output across
countries. The belief was that differences in physical and human capital
intensity were not up to the quantitative task. This belief has been
shaken by a series of recent empirical studies. Mankiw, Romer, and Weil
(1992) estimate that the Solow model augmented to include human capital can explain 78% of the cross-country variance of output per capita in
1985. Alwyn Young (1994, 1995) finds that the East Asian growth miracles were fueled more by growth in labor and capital than by rising
productivity. And Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995) show that the augmented Solow model is consistent with the speed of convergence they
estimate across countries as well as across regions within the United
States, Japan, and a number of European countries.1
In our view these studies constitute a neoclassicalrevival.2They suggest
We are gratefulto Ben Bemanke, MarkBils, V. V. Chari, Chad Jones, Greg Mankiw,Ed
Prescott,David Romer,JulioRotemberg,JimSchmitz,Nancy Stokey,and Alwyn Youngfor
helpful comments.
1. Mankiw, Romer, and Weil, and Barroand Sala-i-Martindo not explain the source of
countrydifferencesin investmentrates. Chari,Kehoe, and McGrattan(1996)arguethat
distortionssuch as tax rates, bribes, risk of expropriation,and corruptioncontributeto
an effective tax rate which, if it varies in the right (stochastic)way acrosscountries,can
explain the levels and growth rates of income observedin the Summers-Heston(1991)
panel.
2. We are indebted to Alwyn Youngfor this phrase.
74 *KLENOW& RODRIGUEZ-CLARE
that the level and growth rate of productivity is roughly the same across
countries, so that differences in output levels and growth rates are
largely due to differences in physical and human capital. Romer (1993),
in contrast, argues that "idea gaps" are much more important than "object gaps." In terms of a simplified production function Y = AX, where A
is productivity and X encompasses physical and human capital, this
debate is over the relative importance of A and X.
This debate matters because the positive and normative implications of
the A view can differ dramatically from those of the X view. Technologybased models of A exhibit scale effects because of the nonrival nature of
technology creation and adoption. And they suggest that openness, perhaps though its effect on technology diffusion, can have first-order effects on living standards and growth rates (without requiring big differences in rates of return to capital). These implications of openness could
be positive in all countries, as in Rodriguez-Clare (1997), or positive in
some and negative in others, as in Stokey (1991) and Young (1991). These
implications are not shared by the basic neoclassical growth model,
which has the same technology everywhere.
In this paper we offer new evidence relevant to this debate on the
importance of productivity vs. physical and human capital in explaining
international differences in levels and growth rates of output. In Section
2 we reexamine Mankiw, Romer, and Weil's (hereafter MRW) methodology for estimating human capital. We update their data and add data on
primary and tertiary schooling which have become available since their
study. Because primary school attainment varies much less across countries than secondary school attainment does, the resulting estimates of
human capital vary much less across countries than the MRW estimates.
We also incorporate evidence suggesting that the production of human
capital is more labor-intensive and less physical capital-intensive than is
the production of other goods. This further narrows country differences
in estimated human capital stocks.
In Section 3 we incorporate evidence that pins down the human capital intensity of production and the relative importance of primary vs.
secondary schooling. We exploit information contained in Mincer regressions, commonly run in the labor literature, on the amount of human
capital gained from each year of schooling. For a cross section of workers, Mincer (1974) ran a regression of worker log wages on worker years
of schooling and experience. Such regressions have since been run for
many countries (see Bils and Klenow, 1996, for citations for 48 countries).
We combine this evidence with data on schooling attainment and estimates of school quality to produce measures of human capital for 98
countries. Using these Mincer-based estimates of human capital, we find
76 *KLENOW& RODRiGUEZ-CLARE
2. Reexamining
MRW
In this section we first describe and comment on MRW's methodology
for attributing differences in output to differences in productivity vs.
differences in capital intensity. We then update MRW's estimates and
make a series of modifications, such as incorporating primary school data
and a more labor-intensive technology for producing human capital.
MRW specify the production technology
Y = C + IK + IH = KaHI(AL)'- a-,
(1)
L =A
/ K a/(ia-)
H\/(1-a-)
Y.
= AX,
(2)
78 KLENOW& RODRIGUEZ-CLARE
then it is likely that higher schooling (i.e., higher H/Y) leads to a higher
level of A. Once we obtain estimates of A and X, below we will actually
use the decomposition of equation (2) to study this issue by looking at
the correlation between A and the capital-intensity variables K/Y and H/
Y. A hypothetical example will illustrate the usefulness of this approach.
Imagine that, using this decomposition, we find that almost all of the
international variation in levels of Y/L is accounted for by international
differences in A. But imagine that we also find a strong positive correlation between A and H/Y. This would be consistent with-but not necessarily proof for-the view that human capital explains differences in Y/L,
albeit indirectly through its effect on A (say through economywide technology adoption as in the model of Ciccone, 1994). On the other hand,
finding no correlation between A and H/Y would suggest that differences in schooling are not important in explaining international output
differences.
With these preliminaries out of the way, we now proceed to updating
and modifying MRW's estimates. For Y/L MRW use the SummersHeston GDP per capita in 1985. For K/Y for each country they use
K
K
Y
IK/Y
IKY
g+
+n
(3)
'"/Y .
_- IHIY
g+
+ n
(4)
(4)
*79
TheNeoclassical
Revivalin GrowthEconomics
MRW use the average 1960-1985 ratio of secondary-school students to
the working-age population (UNESCO yearbook) as an estimate of the
average investment rate in human capital:
IH
population 12-17
population 15-64
15-64
Lpopulation
dent (L)!
11. HHH = LHL,because the representative worker's human capital and labor components
are supplied jointly.
80 *KLENOW& RODRIGUEZ-CLARE
ful treatment of proprietors' income). But we have no cause for comfort
with p = 0.28. Studies such as Jorgenson (1995) and Young (1995) look at
compensation of workers in different education and experience categories, thereby bypassing the need to choose a single share going to human capital. In other words, the share going to labor input is 1 - a, and
workers with more education and experience receive larger subshares of
this 1 - a. We will do something similar in Section 3 below by looking at
Mincerian estimates of wage differences across workers with different
education and experience levels. For the rest of this section we keep f =
0.28, but we discuss at the end how the results are affected by considering higher values.
We now show how the MRW results are sensitive to several modifications that we deem necessary. We keep a = 0.30 and P = 0.28 for comparison purposes. Given that our modified estimates of X and A will be
correlated, there will not be a unique decomposition of the variance of
ln(Y/L) into the variance of ln(X) and the variance of ln(A).12 We think an
informative way of characterizing the data is to split the covariance term,
giving half to ln(X) and half to ln(A). This means we decompose the
variance of ln(Y/L) as follows:
var ln(Y/L)
var ln(Y/L)
cov(ln(Y/L),ln(Y/L))
var ln(Y/L)
cov(ln(Y/L),ln(X)) + cov(ln(Y/L),ln(A))
var ln(Y/L),
or
1=
_cov(ln(Y/L),ln(X))
var ln(Y/L)
cov(ln(Y/L),ln(A))
var ln(Y/L)
This decomposition is equivalent to looking at the coefficients from independently regressing ln(X) and ln(A), respectively, on ln(Y/L). Since
ln(X) + ln(A) = ln(Y/L) and OLS is a linear operator, the coefficients sum
to one. So our decomposition amounts to asking, "When we see 1%
higher Y/Lin one country relative to the mean of 98 countries, how much
higher is our conditional expectation of X and how much higher is our
conditional expectation of A?" The first row of Table 1 gives the answer
for MRWO,the original MRW measure. Since the covariance term is zero
by construction for MRWO, the breakdown is precisely their 78% ln(X)
and 22% ln(A).
12. Since MRW construct ln(X) by regressing In(Y/L) on ln(H/Y) and ln(K/Y) with ln(A) as
the residual, their ln(X) and ln(A) are orthogonal by construction, and the unique
variance decomposition is R2, 1 - R2.
Z= (
Z= X
Z=
.29
.27
.31
.29
.29
.49
.49
.47
.11
.04
.78
.76
.78
.40
.33
Z=A
.22
.24
.22
.60
.67
is to recognize that,
Our first modification of MRW's methodology
measures
of output do not
to
national
income
(1),
contrary
accounting
include the value of student time-an
important component of human
investment.13
To
see
how
capital
important this might be, we consider
the extreme case in which none of the human capital investment is
measured as part of total output. To do this we replace K/Y and H/Y in
equation (2) with Ky/Y and Hy/Y, since only Ky and Hy are used in the
production of Y when Y does not include human capital investment. It
turns out that the MRW measure of IH/Y,namely LHIL,is also appropriate
for Hy/Y when all human capital investment goes unmeasured. The same
is not true for physical capital intensity, for which we must use Ky/Y =
(KIY)(Ly/L). As shown by the MRW1 row of Table 1, this modification
results in a 76% ln(X) vs. 24% ln(A) breakdown, so this distinction does
not appear to be quantitatively important.
The MRW2 row of Table 1 reproduces the MRW1 row, only with updated data and a set of countries for which we have all the necessary
schooling attainment data for the remainder of this paper. Like MRW,
13. MRWcontend that this slippage between model and data is not quantitativelyimportant. Parenteand Prescott(1996)disagree,contendingthat unmeasuredhuman capital
investment must be implausiblylarge for the combined share of capital to be about
two-thirds. Parente, Rogerson, and Wright(1996)illustratethat unmeasuredinvestment would have to be 25-76%of GDP.We are in closeragreementwith MRW,since,
accordingto Kendrick(1976),about half of schoolinginvestmentconsists of education
expenditures(teachers,facilities)which areincludedin measuredoutput. Accordingto
the 1996 Digest of Education Statistics published by the U.S. Department of Education
(1996), education expenditures averaged 7% of GDP over 1960-1990. Back-of-theenvelope calculationssuggest unmeasuredinvestmentmight thereforebe only 13%of
GDP.
enrollment
rate
population
population
15-19
15-64 J
*83
TheNeoclassical
Revivalin GrowthEconomics
says, rather, that primary schooling does not vary anywhere near as
much with Y/L across countries as secondary schooling does. By focusing only on secondary schooling, one overstates the percentage variation
in human capital across countries and its covariance with output per
worker.
A further objection we have to the MRW measure of the human capital
stock is that, as shown in (1), its construction assumes the same technology for producing human capital as for producing consumption and
physical capital. Kendrick (1976) presents evidence that the technology
for producing human capital is more intensive in labor than is the technology for producing other goods. He estimates that about 50% of investment in human capital in the-United States represents the opportunity
cost of student time. The remaining 50% is composed of expenditures on
teachers (human capital) and facilities (physical capital). According to
the 1996 Digest of EducationStatistics, expenditures on teachers represent
about 80% of all expenditures. These figures suggest factor shares of
10%, 40%, and 50% for physical capital, human capital, and raw labor in
the production of human capital, as opposed to the 30%, 28%, and 42%
shares MRW use for the production of consumption goods and new
physical capital. If we let
IH = K --H
(ALH) ,
(5)
this evidence suggests 4) = 0.4 and A = 0.5. Combining (2), (4), and (5)
yields17
Hy
L/ L
n+g+8
\1/[1-K+A,I/(1-a-f3)]
/K)[1-4-
(1-fP)/(1-a-3)]/[1-
+A3/(1-a-)()]
Y~L^-JI~~~~~
~(6) U~
When the two sectors have the same factor intensity (4)= 3 and A = 1 a - 3), this reduces to Hy/Y = (LH/L)(n+g+8), which MRW used and we
used above. But with ) = 0.40 and A = 0.50 the powers in (6) are 1.07 on
the first fraction and -0.28 on the second. Because human capital production is more human capital-intensive than is the production of Y
(0)>,3), a large share of labor devoted to human capital accumulation has
a more than proportionate effect on Hy/Y. And because human capital
production is less physical capital-intensive than is the production of Y
(1 - 4 - A<a), a high rate of investment in physical capital raises Y more
17. Hy/Y = (Ly/L)(HIY) = (Ly/L)(IHIY)/(n+g+8) = [(Ly/L)/(n+g+8) (KH/Y)1'--A(HH/Y)t(ALH/
Y). The expression in the text can be obtained by substituting for A using (2) with Hy/Y
and Ky/Y and by using KHIY= (LH/Ly)(Ky/Y) and HH/Y = (LH/Ly)(Hy/Y) (ignoring
multiplicative constants).
84 *KLENOW& RODRiGUEZ-CLARE
than H, thereby reducing Hy/Y. As shown in the MRW4 row of Table 1,
using ) = 0.40 and A = 0.50 results in a split of 33% ln(X) vs. 67% ln(A).
Comparing MRW4 with MRW3, we see that lowering the capital intensity of human capital production modestly lowers the variation of Hy/Y
across countries.
As shown by comparing MRW0 with MRW4 in Table 1, the cumulative effect of these modifications is to remove the linchpin of the neoclassical revival: MRW's original (78%, 22%) decomposition has given way
to a (33%, 67%) decomposition. Can one restore MRW's results with a
higher 3?Doubling 3 from 0.28 to 0.56 yields a (51%, 49%) division. As
,3 rises toward 23, the decomposition approaches 60% vs. 40%. Thus a
sufficiently high 3 does generate results that, although not as dramatic
as those of MRW, still have the major part of international income
variation explained by differences in levels of physical and human capital per worker. But what is the right value for 3? Unfortunately, we
know of no independent estimates of "the" share of human capital.
Fortunately, in the next section we are able to exploit wage regressions
to measure human-capital stocks in a way that does not depend on the
value of 3. This regression evidence also appropriately weights primary
schooling attainment relative to secondary schooling attainment, rather
than lumping them together with equal weight as we have done in the
preceding.
3. UsingMincerRegressionEvidenceto EstimateHuman
CapitalStocks
In this section we exploit evidence from the labor literature on the wage
gains associated with more schooling and experience. For a cross section
of workers, Mincer (1974) ran a regression of worker log wages on
worker years of schooling and experience. He chose this specification
because it fit the data much better than, say, a regression of the level of
wages on the years of schooling and experience. To incorporate this
evidence into the technology for producing human capital, we abandon
the infinite-life construct in favor of a life cycle in which people first go to
school full time and then work full time. We specify the following technology for human capital:
h = (KH/LH)1 A(hT)(AeY/A)s)A,
(7)
TheNeoclassical
Revivalin GrowthEconomics
?85
students, and
leads to18
Hy
(/
\/[1-,+
hT is
A,3/(l-a-3)]
(Ky)[l-,-A(l-3)/(1-a-3a)]/[-1
+ A3/(1-a-f3)]
--^'M~~~~~(7)
<(8)
86 *KLENOW& RODRiGUEZ-CLARE
Table2 THEROLESOF A AND X IN 1985PROSPERITY
cov[ln(Y/L),In (Z)]/varln(Y/L)
Sourcea
Z
Z== X
Z =A
BK1
.29
.31
.60
.40
BK2
BK3
BK4
.23
.23
.23
.33
.31
.11
.56
.53
.34
.44
.47
.66
over 1960-1985. Unfortunately, direct estimates of the 1960 K/Y are not
available for most countries. We therefore set, for each country,
/K
IK_ IK/Y
J 196=g+8+n
with the investment rate IK/Y,the growth rate of YIL(g), and the population growth rate (n) equal to the country's averages over either 1960-1965,
1960-1970, or 1960-1985, and 8 either 0.03, 0.05, or 0.07. We also followed
a procedure akin to King and Levine (1994) where we set g in the denominator equal to a weighted average of own-country and world growth. The
results were not at all sensitive to which way we calculated the 1960 K/Y,
so we report the results with 1960 K/Ycalculated using 8 = 0.03 (as in Table
1) and the country's own averages over 1960-1970 for g and n. To construct the 1985 H/Y, we use Barro and Lee's (1993) data on average years of
schooling attained by the 25-64-year-old population in each country in
1985. We report the results of using this approach to obtain 1985 levels of
K/Y and H/Y in the BK2 row of Table 2. Conditional on 1% higher Y/L in
one country in 1985, we expect 0.56% higher X and 0.44% higher A in that
country. These results are not far from the (60%, 40%) breakdown in BK1
with the steady-state assumption for K/Y and H/Y.19
We now modify (7) to incorporate human capital acquired through
experience:
hs = (KH/LH) -- A(hT)4(Ae(ls+
Y2exp+y3exp2)/)
(9)
19. The close similarity between H/Y calculated in BK1 and in BK2, i.e. between school
attainment implied by enrollments and measures of years of schooling attained, suggests that differences in the duration of primary, secondary, and higher education from
our assumed 8, 4, and 4 years are not quantitatively meaningful.
where exp = (age - s - 6). The average experience level among workers
was estimated using United Nations (1994) data in combination with
Barro and Lee's schooling attainment data. For each country experience
was calculated as the population-weighted average of (age - s - 6) at
ages 27, 32, . . ., 62 for the groups 25-29,
30-34,
Surprisingly, we find that the correlation between average years of experience of 25-64-year-olds and ln(Y/L) in 1985 is -0.67. Richer countries
have older workforces, but slightly less experienced ones because they
spend more years in school. As above, y, = 0.095(1-a)//3. Bils and
Klenow (1996) report average estimated coefficients on exp and exp2
across 48 countries of 0.0495 and -0.0007. Based on these, we set 72 =
0.0495(1 -a)//3 and y3 = 0.0007(1 -a)c//. The consequence of adding experience can be seen in the BK3 row of Table 2. As compared to the (56%,
44%) split in BK2, the split in BK3 is (53%, 47%).
Underlying this breakdown of 53% ln(X) vs. 47% ln(A) is the supposition that the quality of schooling is much higher in richer countries. In
richer countries, students enjoy better facilities (higher KH/LH)and better
teachers (higher HHILH). From (9), the quality of schooling is
-h OAI .
quality of schooling = (KH/L-H)1
Using this formula, for BK3 the elasticity of quality with respect to a
country's Y/L is 0.95%.20This means a country with 1% higher Y/L has
0.95% higher quality education. Note that higher quality of this type
does not raise the percentage wage premium from education, but instead
raises the base (log) wage for anyone in the country receiving some
education. It should affect the intercept of the Mincer regression for a
country, but not the coefficient on schooling.
Is an educational quality elasticity of 0.95% reasonable? Is it plausible
that, like GDP per worker, the quality of education varies by a factor of
about 34 across countries in 1985? An independent estimate of the quality elasticity can be gleaned from the wages of U.S. immigrants.21 Using
1970 and 1980 census data on the U.S. earnings of immigrants from 41
countries, Borjas (1987) estimates country-of-origin-specific intercepts in
a Mincer regression of log wages on immigrant years of education and
experience. He finds that immigrants with 1% higher per capita income
in their country of origin exhibit a 0.116% higher wage intercept (stan20. Calculatedas cov[ln(quality),ln(Y/L)]/var
ln(Y/L).
21. Incidentally,the enormous pressure for migrationfrom poor to rich countriesis itself
consistent with substantialdifferencesin productivityacrosscountries.However, this
pressure could be entirely explained by higher physical capital-output ratios and
greaternonpecuniarybenefits of living in richercountries.
88 *KLENOW& RODRiGUEZ-CLARE
dard error 0.025). This implies a quality elasticity of only 0.12%, suggesting that the elasticity embedded in BK3 is very aggressive.22'23
Borjas's evidence suggests an alternative, namely that teachers and
class facilities affect school quality through the schooling coefficient y.
In this event we would expect to see higher Mincer schooling coefficients in richer countries. Bils and Klenow (1996) find the opposite: each
additional year of schooling brings roughly 10% higher wages in a
country where the average worker has 5 years of schooling, compared
to only about 5% higher wages in a country where the average worker
has 10 years of schooling. Perhaps 's are higher in richer countries, but
the effect on the education premium is more than offset by a lower
relative marginal product of human capital in richer countries. This
could arise because of imperfect substitutability of workers with different education levels combined with abundance of human capital in
richer countries. Indeed, the Cobb-Douglas technology in (1) implies
unit elasticity of substitution between human capital and raw labor and
therefore a falling education premium with a country's H/Y, holding y
constant.
It is interesting to explore the possibility that the Mincer coefficients
already capture the effect of education quality combined with imperfect
substitutability. This would correspond to the extreme case when teachers and class buildings affect only the /s, so that 4 = 0 and A = 1. It
would be ideal to do this exercise using Mincer coefficients for each
country, but unfortunately we do not have such data for all countries.
Here we use the average Mincer coefficient of 9.5% instead. (The reader
should note that, since the Mincer coefficient is actually declining with
income per worker, this biases the results against a large role for A.) As
we report in the BK4 row of Table 2, without Mincer-intercept-type
variations in school quality, human capital contributes much less to Y/L
variation. The (ln(X), ln(A)) division shifts from (53%, 47%) in BK3 to
(34%, 66%) in BK4.
How do we choose between BK3 and BK4? Recall that the school
22. Immigrantsmay be more able than the average person in their country of origin.
Borjas'sregression controls for observabledifferencesin immigrants'ability such as
age, years of schooling, and English proficiency.With regard to unobservables,the
estimate of education qualitydifferenceswould be biased downward if positive selection (in Borjas'sterminology)were greaterthe poorerthe countryof origin. As Borjas
notes, the opposite may be true, since income inequalitytends to be greaterin poorer
countries.
23. Furthercause for concern is the difficulty researcherssuch as Hanushek (1986)and
Heckman, Layne-Farrar,and Todd (1996)have encountered in correlatingschooling
outcomes with teacherinputs. A (virtuallycontrolled)experimentin Tennessee, however, found that the group of students placedin smallerK-3 classes performedsignificantlybetter on standardizedtests (Mosteller,1995).
*89
Revivalin GrowthEconomics
TheNeoclassical
quality elasticity implied by BK3 is 0.95%, whereas BK4 implies no variation in school quality (of the intercept type) across countries. The evidence from Borjas (1987) suggests that BK3's elasticity is much higher
than the truth; the zero elasticity in BK4 seems closer. But if BK3 comes
from data on the shares of capital and teachers in the U.S. education
sector, why might it deliver wrong results? There are three possibilities.
First is the reason we just gave, namely that these inputs affect the /s.
Second, it could be that human capital varies much less across education
sectors than across other sectors; i.e., international differences in human
capital may be smaller for teachers than for other workers. Finally, it
could be that productivity A is not as significant in the education sector
as it is in other sectors. In the extreme case when A does not enter the
education sector at all, we find that the parameter values 4 = 0.19 and A
= 0.81 generate a quality elasticity matching Borjas's 0.12. In this case
we find a (42%, 58%) breakdown, in between BK3 and BK4 but a little
closer to the latter.
We conclude that richer countries tend to have higher K/Y,higher H/Y,
and higher A, with a dominant role for A, a large role for K/Y, and a
modest-to-large role for H/Y. To us this says that theorizing about international output differences should center at least as much on differences in
productivity as on differences in physical or human capital intensity.
Figures 1 and 2 display ln(A) and ln(X) using MRWOand BK4, respectively.24 In the MRWOworld, research should focus on explaining why
ln(X) varies so much; in the BK4 world a greater priority is to understand
differences in ln(A).
In contrasting MRWOand BK4, it is instructive to look at the correlations among output per worker (Y/L), capital intensity (K/Y and H/Y),
and productivity (A). Table 3a shows the correlation matrix for the case
where HIY is measured according to MRWO;Table 3b does the same for
the case where H/Y is measured according to BK4. In both cases YIL,K/Y,
and H/Y are highly positively correlated with each other. The difference
arises in the correlation between these variables and A. In particular,
Table 3a shows no correlation between A and K/Y or between A and H/Y
(both by MRW construction), whereas the corresponding correlations
are quite positive in Table 3b. In thinking about a theory of endogenous
A, it is hard to imagine that policies discouraging K/Y and H/Y-such as
high tax rates-would not also discourge A. The positive BK4 correlations seem much easier to generate theoretically.
A possible reason for the 0.57 correlation between ln(A) and ln(H/Y) is
24. These figures display visually what we try to convey by splitting the covariance terms
in Tables 1 and 2.
90 *KLENOW& RODRiGUEZ-CLARE
Figure 1 1985LEVELS:MRWO
2.0
1.5 -
1.0 -
0.5
* t
* *
0.0 -
o
*0
* *~
v
-0.5
* *
* *
-1.0
-1.5
-2.0
-2.5
-2.5
....I
-2.0
-1.5
-1.0
-0.5
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
In(X)
that high H/Y, say due to generous education subsidies, facilitates technology adoption. Ciccone (1994) presents a model with this feature: the
larger the economy's stock of human capital, the more profitable it is for
a firm to spend the fixed costs of adopting a given technology, and
therefore the higher the economy's A relative to the world frontier. Note
that this story links an economy's A to an economy's HIY,not an individual worker's A to an individual worker's h. We stress that the Mincer
evidence deployed in this section should capture any link between the
schooling of an individual worker and the level of technology (e.g. equipment quality) that worker can use. This is because technology adoption
that is linked to the individual should show up in the private wage gain
to more education.
1.0 -
*
* **
* * *'
*
*2 - *
*,
*
0.5 -
* S*
**%
**
4,
0.0 -
C
-0.5
*
*
*~~~
-1.0
-1.5 -
-2.0
-2.0
** *
-1.5
-1.0
-0.5
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
In(X)
Table 3 CORRELATION MATRICES
a.
With MRWOmethodology
ln(Y/L)
ln(K/Y)
ln(H/Y)
ln(A)
b.
.77
.84
.47
ln(K/Y)
ln(H/Y)
ln(A)
.59
.60
.93
ln(KY)
ln(H/Y)
.67
.00
.00
ln(K/Y)
ln(H/Y)
.02
.28
.57
92 *KLENOW& RODRIGUEZ-CLARE
At this point several robustness checks are in order. We first look at the
potential importance of imperfect substitutability. For 45 countries in Bils
and Klenow's (1996) sample, Barro and Lee (1996) report percentages of
the 25-64-year-old population in seven educational attainment categories: none, some primary, completed primary only, some secondary, completed secondary only, some tertiary, and completed tertiary. We treat
"some" as half-completed, and assume the durations are 8, 4, and 4 years
for primary, secondary, and tertiary schooling. We assume the first three
categories are perfectly substitutable "primary equivalents," and that the
last four are perfectly substitutable "secondary equivalents":
Y = K(Hl-1/t
lla)
sec /
pnm Hl-1/1o)(1-a)/(1-
with
Hpnm=
E ALseY,
s=0,4,8
Hs, =
>
s=10,12,14,16
ALAey,
TheNeoclassical
Revivalin GrowthEconomics
?93
given by /3y/(l-a), matches the Mincer evidence discussed in Bils and
Klenow (1996). Thus changing 3 results in an offsetting adjustment in y
to preserve the equality 3y/(l-a) = 9.5%. In other words, there is no
doubling of the importance of human capital from doubling f to 0.56,
since the coefficient y must be halved at the same time. Indeed, there is
zero effect. The intuition is that the Mincer estimates pin down the
combined effect of translating schooling into human capital and translating human capital into output. Thus a larger elasticity of output with
respect to human capital requires a smaller elasticity of human capital
with respect to schooling in order to maintain consistency with the
Mincer regression evidence.
An objection to the Mincer evidence is that the coefficient on schooling
captures only private gains from schooling. Productive benefits of economywidehuman capital, as proposed by Lucas (1988), would be absorbed
in the Mincer intercept. Lucas (1990) argues that human capital externalities can explain the large differences in TFP that Krueger (1968) found
across 28 countries even after adjusting for human capital per worker
(measured much as in BK4). Leaving aside the nature of these externalities, it is illuminating to ask how big they have to be in order to
restore MRW's 78%-vs.-22% breakdown. For BK3, with its substantial
variation in education quality, we find that the social Mincer coefficient
on schooling would have to be 15.6%, as opposed to the 9.5% or so
typically found. For BK4, the social education premium would have to be
29%. Since the evidence on school quality favors BK4, it appears that
external benefits of schooling would need to be larger than the private
benefits! In any case, entertaining externalities leads to questions about
their exact nature and transmission. To us, this supports our call for more
research into the source of productivity differences across countries.
4. FromDevelopment
Accountingto GrowthAccounting
Whereas Tables 1 and 2 were concerned with development accounting
(King and Levine's felicitous 1994 phrase), Table 4 is about growth accounting. For Table 4 we constructed K/Yand H/Y for each country in 1960
so that we could compute 1960-1985 growth rates. We did this for BK2
through BK4 (one cannot do it under the steady-state assumptions used
for MRWs and for BK1). For H/Y we used Barroand Lee's (1993) schooling
stocks in 1960 and, when necessary to construct experience levels, the
United Nations (1994) population data for 1960. We estimated the 1960 Kl
Y's as described in the previous section, and the results here are not at all
sensitive to the various ways we tried to estimate 1960 K/Y's.
Table 4 presents the results of 1960-1985 growth accounting. When a
94 *KLENOW& RODRiGUEZ-CLARE
Table4 THEROLESOF A AND X IN 1960-1985GROWTH
cov[Aln(Y/L),A In (Z)]/varA ln(Y/L)
Source
BK2
BK3
BK4
Z=
YZ
.03
.03
.03
.12
.12
.06
Z=X
Z= A
.15
.14
.09
.85
.86
.91
is distinct
H/Ygrowth, and 1.03%from A growth. This average-world-growth
accounting
from the country-variation-in-growth-rates
accountingthat we focus on above. Unlikethe
*95
TheNeoclassical
Revivalin GrowthEconomics
Figure3 1960-1985GROWTHRATES:BK4
5%
4% -
2% -
:t
E 1%
e
'
#* *.*
*
0%-
.C
* A * .
*. **
2%-3% -
-5%
-5%
-4%
-3%
-2%
-1%
0%
In(X) growth
1%
2%
3%
4%
5%
rate
The Appendix contains 1985 levels and 1960-1985 growth rates of Y/L,
KIY,HIY, and A (the latter two for BK4). For ease of interpretation the
1985 level variables are given relative to the United States. Many countries surprisingly come out higher than the United States in our estimates for A. Perhaps we have been aggressive in our estimates of the
return to human capital (e.g. making no attempt to adjust for ability
bias), but we prefer to err on this side, given our conclusion that human
capital's importance has been seriously overstated in previous research.
As we mentioned at the beginning of Section 2, the fact that A is not
exogenous implies that the growth rate of A could be affected by the
growth rate of K/Y and H/Y. Increasing levels of capital intensity and
schooling could thus be responsible for high growth rates indirectly, by
allowing for a faster growth of A. To examine this possibility Table 5
shows the correlation matrix for the 1960-1985 growth rates of Y/L, K/Y,
96 *KLENOW& RODRIGUEZ-CLARE
Table5 CORRELATION
MATRIX(BK4GROWTHRATES)
A ln(Y/L)
A ln(K/Y)
A ln(H/Y)
Aln(A)
.04
.28
.87
A ln(K/Y)
-.50
-.42
A ln(H/Y)
.34
H/Y, and A according to BK4. The 0.34 correlation between the growth
rates of A and H/Y suggests that countries with high growth in A have
had unusually high growth rates of schooling. Thus it could be that high
growth in economywide schooling attainment powerfully boosts growth
through its effect on technology adoption. In contrast, the negative correlations between the growth rate of KIYand the growth rates of, respectively, H/Y and A are puzzling.28
An alternative way to think about the role of factor accumulation and
total productivity factor (TFP) growth in explaining differences in economic performance across countries is to look at what has happened to
the standard deviations of Y/L, KIY, H/Y, X, and A (as logarithms)
across time. Table 6 compares the standard deviations of these variables
in 1960 and 1985. As is well known, the standard deviation of the
logarithm of output per worker increased somewhat during this period
(i.e., o-divergence). We find that o-convergence occurred for K/Y, but
not for H/Y, X, and A. Thus the lack of a-convergence in Y/L does not
stem from, say, A-convergence combined with X-divergence.29
5. Do Young'sFindings ContradictOurs?
The debate over whether fast rates of growth in some countries stem
from accumulation of capital or from technology catch-up has been heavily influenced by the East Asian miracles. It was initially thought that
these countries had very high TFP growth rates, pointing to technology
catch-up as the heart of the story. Then came the careful work of Alwyn
Young showing that these countries grew mostly through input accumulation (Young, 1995), and that their TFP growth rates were not extraordinarily high (Young, 1994). Singapore, for instance, was shown to have
28. The negative correlation between the growth rates of A and K/Y could indicate an
overstatement of the contribution of K/Y to outut per worker. One reason for this may
be that public investment (which is part of the data on investment that we used to
generate K/Y) is less efficient than private investment in generating efficiency units of
capital. If this is true, then the role of A is even larger than shown in our results.
29. We also did our variance decomposition on the 1960 numbers and obtained exactly the
same breakdown (34% ln(X) vs. 66% ln(A)) for BK4 that we did for 1985 in Table 2.
*97
TheNeoclassical
Revivalin GrowthEconomics
Table6 STANDARDDEVIATIONS(BK4LEVELS)
Quantity
1960
1985
ln(Y/L)
ln(K/Y)
ln(H/Y)
ln(X)
ln(A)
0.95
0.73
0.28
0.46
0.71
1.01
0.55
0.28
0.44
0.72
98 *KLENOW& RODRiGUEZ-CLARE
Table7
a. AlwynYoung'sresults
Y Growth
Country
Hong Kong
Korea
Singapore
Taiwan
Country
Hong Kong
Korea
Singapore
Taiwan
TFPGrowth
7.3
10.3
8.7
9.4
2.3
1.7
0.2
2.6
Y/LGrowth
A Growth
4.7
4.9
4.2
4.8
3.7
2.5
0.3
3.5
Country
Hong Kong
Korea
Singapore
Taiwan
Young's
Ours
Whydifferent?
3.7
2.5
4.4
2.5
L data
O.K.
0.3
3.3
L data; K share
3.5
3.0
O.K.
tigers are not too far off from Young's numbers. Table 7b reports our BK4
1960-1985 A growth rates for the Asian tigers alongside Young's estimates. Our estimate for South Korea matches Young's (2.5%), and our
estimate for Taiwan actually falls below Young's (3.0% vs. his 3.5%). For
Hong Kong our estimate is higher (4.4% vs. 3.7%), and for Singapore
our estimate is much higher (3.3% vs. 0.3%). Young uses census data for
L rather than Summers-Heston data, and the census data show faster
growth of L for Hong Kong and Singapore.30 Faster growth of L translates into slower growth of Y/L and A (with growth in H/Y and K/Y
unaffected). This explains the entire difference in our estimates for Hong
Kong. For Singapore Young used a physical-capital share of 0.49, as
opposed to the 0.30 we used. Combined with the difference in L growth,
Young's higher capital share explains almost all of the gap in our Singapore estimates, since K/Y grew sharply there.
We close by stressing that our results share two important features
30. For 1966-1990,Young'sworker/populationratiosrose from0.38 to 0.49 for Hong Kong
and from 0.27 to 0.51 for Singapore.The comparableSummers-Heston figures were
0.54 to 0.65 and 0.34 to 0.48.
TheNeoclassical
Revivalin GrowthEconomics?99
with those of Young (1994, 1995). First, we find a very modest role for
growth in human capital per worker in explaining growth (Young's adjustments for labor quality are a few tenths of a percent per year). Second, we find that TFP growth accounts for most of the growth of output
per worker in Hong Kong, South Korea, and Taiwan. And we stress that
this relative importance of TFP growth for three of the four Asian tigers
generalizes to our sample of 98 countries: we find that roughly 90% of
country differences in YIL growth are attributable to differences in A
growth. Combining these growth results with our findings on levels, we
call for returning productivity differences to the center of theorizing
about international differences in output per worker.
Appendix.Data
Y/L= 1985RGDPWin Summers-Heston PWT5.6.
K/Y= 1985physical-capital-to-outputratio (see Section4 for K/Yused for BK2BK4).
H/Y = 1985human-capital-to-outputratio (see Section4 for H/Yused for BK4).
A = 1985level of productivity[see equation (2)]. Note: Levels are relativeto the
United States.
g(Z) = 1960-1985annual growth rate of series Z.
Y/L KIY H/Y
Algeria
Benin
Botswana
Cameroon
CentralAfr.R.
Congo
Gambia
Ghana
Guinea-Biss
Kenya
Lesotho
Liberia
Malawi
Mali
Mauritius
Mozambique
Niger
Rwanda
Senegal
South Africa
0.40
0.07
0.20
0.11
0.04
0.20
0.05
0.07
0.04
0.06
0.06
0.07
0.03
0.05
0.22
0.04
0.03
0.05
0.08
0.29
0.79
0.47
0.49
0.27
0.60
0.29
0.39
0.43
1.23
0.63
0.41
0.74
0.57
0.67
0.42
0.18
0.79
0.18
0.38
0.84
0.33
0.34
0.47
0.56
0.30
0.48
0.38
0.47
0.22
0.40
0.51
0.31
0.39
0.27
0.57
0.52
0.25
0.55
0.45
0.45
0.99
2.89
0.25
0.78
0.55
6.85
4.22
0.43
0.12
0.33
0.81
4.06
0.18
1.37
0.20
0.36
0.10
1.52
0.15
1.31
0.18
5.03
1.22
0.18
0.10
1.70
0.16
0.45
0.59
0.90
0.22 -1.18
0.10
0.79
0.23
1.89
0.27
0.87
0.57
1.82
0.71
1.37
2.20
1.16
-0.79
-1.81
4.32
-0.60
-0.01
-0.10
4.28
-0.82
1.87
-2.28
-1.09
2.98
1.82
1.70
-0.64
1.23
0.64
0.02
0.71
0.63
0.53
0.30
-0.70
1.51
0.34
1.03
-0.55
0.92
0.04
0.77
1.43
-0.39
-0.64
-0.02
0.62
0.12
1.96
-0.21
4.81
2.97
0.54
5.16
-1.25
-0.22
1.29
0.70
2.34
1.19
0.34
1.57
0.72
-3.05
-0.09
0.68
0.92
0.86
g(A)
(%)
0.41
0.08
0.12
0.81
0.17
0.14
0.12
0.26
2.96
2.08
2.60
3.22
0.06
0.42
-0.42
1.50
2.87
1.80
3.02
-0.94
0.96
4.19
-0.07
-0.96
0.35
0.05
0.28
1.35
0.17
-0.19
1.43
0.74
0.67
0.77
0.26
2.99
-0.74
-2.45
-1.32
1.70
0.77
0.85
0.58
0.51
0.51
0.40
0.39
0.46
0.39
0.53
0.47
0.62
0.66
1.00
0.51
0.42
0.40
0.53
0.51
0.53
0.37
0.58
0.54
0.48
0.49
0.70
1.05
0.64
0.55
0.48
0.62
0.22
0.38
0.28
1.29
0.47
0.60
1.55
1.00
0.64
0.35
0.77
0.47
0.68
0.58
0.17
0.50
0.47
0.43
1.07
2.39
1.88
1.17
2.16
0.95
1.32
0.96
1.41
0.34
2.33
0.56
3.00
1.65
1.30
1.11
2.11
2.73
0.44
2.10
3.07
-1.80
2.23
1.02
0.17
-0.43
1.55
0.64
1.68
2.33
1.94
1.24
2.23
0.21
1.23
1.27
2.35
1.45
1.57
0.56
1.38
0.57
0.32
0.73
0.33
0.78
1.58
2.10
1.45
1.34
2.46
0.46
0.94
0.50
0.33
0.53
0.47
-0.07
0.93
0.56
0.70
0.28
0.62
0.52
1.27
0.57
0.48
0.36
0.52
0.84
1.12
-0.18
0.09
1.05
0.87
0.82
0.97
0.80
-0.36
0.28
-0.79
0.12
-0.58
0.64
-0.91
0.95
-1.31
1.55
0.18
0.04
-0.25
1.38
2.26
-0.43
1.31
1.77
-2.82
0.67
-0.72
-1.36
-2.74
0.52
0.74
0.38
0.45
0.39
0.41
0.79
0.60
0.61
0.76
0.55
0.88
0.20
0.32
0.97
1.26
0.84
0.63
1.39
0.54
1.73
5.49
1.74
3.89
1.29
0.85
3.27
5.30
5.00
5.37
-1.11
0.53
-0.70
1.88
3.35
5.70
0.79
2.01
2.34
2.32
0.90
1.08
1.07
0.95
0.68
0.05
1.02
0.51
0.95
1.77
1.92
4.39
1.53
1.91
-1.55
-3.26
2.03
3.53
2.69
2.54
Y/L
K/Y
H/Y
Swaziland
Tanzania
Togo
Tunisia
Uganda
Zaire
Zambia
Zimbabwe
0.15
0.03
0.04
0.26
0.04
0.03
0.07
0.10
0.53
0.59
0.76
0.46
0.19
0.24
1.31
0.61
0.47
0.37
0.32
0.42
0.57
0.54
0.34
0.38
Barbados
Canada
Costa Rica
Dominican Rep.
El Salvador
Guatemala
Haiti
Honduras
Jamaica
Mexico
0.36
0.92
0.27
0.21
0.16
0.22
0.06
0.14
0.14
0.50
0.17
0.30
0.76
1.00
0.44
0.17
0.32
0.29
0.27
0.28
0.11
0.18
0.24
0.30
0.54
0.51
0.97
0.50
0.48
0.42
0.54
0.42
0.50
0.93
0.49
0.51
0.58
0.54
1.00
1.11
0.81
0.70
0.91
0.53
0.67
1.34
0.42
0.70
1.22
0.74
0.13
0.49
0.08
0.13
0.41
0.47
0.65
0.56
0.46
0.31
0.24
0.57
0.71
0.59
0.73
0.58
0.88
1.35
0.34
0.58
Nicaragua
Panama
Trinidad & Tobago
United States
Argentina
Bolivia
Brazil
Chile
Colombia
Ecuador
Guyana
Paraguay
Peru
Uruguay
Venezuela
Bangladesh
Hong Kong
India
Indonesia
Iran
Iraq
Israel
Japan
Jordan
Korea, Rep.
g(A)
(%)
Y/L
K/Y
H/Y
Malaysia
Myanmar
Nepal
Pakistan
Philippines
Singapore
Sri Lanka
Syria
Taiwan
Thailand
0.31
0.04
0.07
0.13
0.13
0.53
0.17
0.51
0.38
0.14
0.68
0.39
0.35
0.48
0.53
0.93
0.35
0.37
0.51
0.53
0.51
0.42
0.38
0.38
0.66
0.41
0.69
0.56
0.73
0.55
0.63
0.14
0.27
0.40
0.26
1.03
0.45
1.52
0.75
0.33
3.74
2.64
2.25
2.96
1.41
5.11
1.87
4.42
5.30
3.70
1.30
0.36
1.36
-0.31
2.18
2.40
0.63
0.97
1.76
0.87
1.21
0.46
0.09
0.76
0.76
0.16
0.84
1.35
1.52
0.62
2.00
2.08
1.21
2.68
-0.65
3.29
0.85
2.83
3.03
2.66
Austria
Belgium
Cyprus
Denmark
Finland
France
Germany, W.
Greece
Iceland
Ireland
0.71
0.81
0.41
0.71
0.70
0.80
0.81
0.48
0.69
0.57
0.80
0.46
0.85
0.85
0.34
0.63
0.78
0.88
0.21
0.68
0.34
1.53
1.43
1.11
1.49
1.80
1.47
1.85
1.25
1.10
1.07
1.51
0.95
1.28
1.49
1.21
1.28
1.54
2.03
0.79
1.23
1.52
0.45
0.64
0.54
0.73
0.60
0.45
0.53
0.50
0.59
0.62
0.43
0.56
0.61
0.73
0.34
0.42
0.65
0.55
0.37
0.64
0.48
0.88
0.84
0.58
0.66
0.65
1.04
0.79
0.65
0.91
0.75
1.04
0.70
0.98
0.79
0.60
0.93
0.77
0.80
0.48
0.79
0.41
3.20
2.59
4.12
1.91
2.87
2.79
2.69
4.60
2.46
3.31
3.60
4.71
2.05
2.80
3.40
3.80
1.69
1.57
3.19
1.77
3.97
0.74
0.63
0.49
0.58
0.15
1.16
0.51
1.41
-0.42
0.93
0.44
-1.08
0.68
0.18
0.93
1.91
0.57
1.03
1.23
0.21
1.44
1.42
0.73
1.33
0.26
0.97
1.02
0.30
0.94
1.20
0.47
0.85
1.18
1.45
2.35
0.83
0.71
0.77
0.86
0.41
0.38
1.25
1.72
1.65
2.88
1.32
2.11
1.29
2.12
2.97
1.95
2.33
2.72
4.69
0.59
1.10
2.18
1.96
0.77
0.26
2.04
1.37
2.11
0.86
0.29
0.77
0.10
1.33
0.68
1.25
1.08
0.74
0.61
0.94
0.26
0.85
0.53
0.68
0.23
1.63
1.03
0.81
1.59
0.46
0.25
0.38
2.77
0.48
0.86
1.01
-0.54
0.98
0.28
-0.14
-0.03
Italy
Malta
Netherlands
Norway
Portugal
Spain
Sweden
Switzerland
Turkey
United Kingdom
Yugoslavia
Australia
Fiji
New Zealand
Papua N. Guinea
REFERENCES
Comment 103
Mosteller,F (1995).The Tennessee study of class size in the early school grades.
TheFutureof Children5(2):113-127.
Parente, S., and E. C. Prescott. (1996).The barriersto riches. Philadelphia:University of Pennsylvania;Universityof Minnesota.Manuscript.
,R. Rogerson,and R. Wright.(1996).Homeworkin developmenteconomics: Household productionand the wealth of nations. Philadelphia:University
of Pennsylvania.Mimeo.
Pritchett,L. (1995).Where has all the educationgone? WorldBank.Mimeo.
Rodriguez-Clare,A. (1997).The role of tradein technology diffusion. University
of Chicago. Mimeo.
Romer, P. M. (1990). Endogenous technologicalchange. Journalof PoliticalEconomy98(5):S71-S102.
. (1993). Idea gaps and object gaps in economic development. Journalof
32(3):543-573.
MonetaryEconomics
Summers, R., and A. Heston. (1991). The Penn WorldTable(Mark5): An expanded set of internationalcomparisons, 1950-1988. QuarterlyJournalof Economics106(2):327-368.Mark5.6 (an update) is availableat nber.harvard.edu.
Stokey, N. L. (1991). Human capital, product quality, and growth. Quarterly
Journalof Economics
106(2):587-617.
United Nations. (1994). TheSex and Age Distributionof the WorldPopulations,the
1994Revision.New York:United Nations.
U.S. Departmentof Education.(1996).1996DigestofEducation
Statistics.Washington: U.S. GovernmentPrintingOffice.
Young, A. (1991). Learningby doing and the dynamic effects of international
trade. QuarterlyJournalof Economics
106(2):369-406.
. (1994). Lessons from the East Asian NICs: A contrarianview. European
Economic
Review38(3-4):964-973.
. (1995).The tyrannyof numbers:Confrontingthe statisticalrealitiesof the
east Asian growth experience. QuarterlyJournalof Economics
110(3):641-680.
Comment
N. GREGORYMANKIW
HarvardUniversity