Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

Comercio Mundial y DSustentable - ANadal

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 31

1

Redesigning the World's Trading


System for Sustainable Development
Alejandro Nadal (*)
Science, Technology and Development Program
El Colegio de Mxico

(*) The author wishes to acknowledge support from the John D. and Catherine T.
MacArthur Foundation for his research on alternative development strategies.

Redesigning the World's Trading System for


Sustainable Development
Alejandro Nadal
Science, Technology and Development Program
El Colegio de Mxico

Introduction
In a relatively short period of time, human activity has brought the world to the brink
of a major ecological disaster. One manifestation of this is a massive biotic crisis
(Elredge 1998; Myers and Knoll 2001; Wilson 1993). The other is the anthropogenic
impact on global average temperatures, with effects on rising oceans, disruption of
rainfall patterns, and extreme climate variability (Houghton et al 2001; McCarthy et
al 2001).
At the same time, social disparities and inequality mark the social and economic
landscape of the entire planet, both at the national and international levels (UNFPA
2002; GPM 2004). The powerful forces that have been leading the integration of the
world economy have also been at the origin of deep financial and economic crises.
To top everything, the world is now witness to more armed conflicts at the regional
level than in the past thirty years and world military expenditures have increased
dramatically (SIPRI 2004).
Economic performance in the past thirty years has been marked by slower growth
rates for the higher and middle income groups of countries, and only modest growth
rates for the lower income group of economies. Social disparities continue to exist,
and although there is some debate regarding trends today, the magnitude of these
disparities is still too big. It appears increasingly unlikely that the Millennium
Development Goal of halving the number of hungry people by 2015 will be met.
Even if there is a trend towards the reduction of these social disparities, and that is
a very big assumption, the evolution is taking place at a painstakingly slow rate. If
we take the environmental Kuznets curve as a heuristic device, we can confidently
say that most of the worlds developing countries are in the worst possible section of
the curve.1 Whatever the level of per capita income needed to start reducing
environmental deterioration, the vast majority of developing countries will remain at
the top of the parabola for a very long time given the very slow rates of growth of
per capita income or GDP. This is precisely the segment of the curve where
environmental degradation is at its highest levels. At current rates of per capita
1

The EKC is plagued by serious conceptual drawbacks. One illuminating critique is Tisdell (2000). It does not
deal with complex environmental systems, where one parameter worsens while others improve, and it does not
consider irreversible damages (such as species extinctions). In spite of its limitations, it is used by many
economists: Cole 1999; Grossman and Krueger 1995.

3
GDP, even in the best win-win scenarios, the developing world will remain in the
worst segment of the curve (as it approaches and the summit from the left and
continues towards the right and descending part of the curve) for a very long time,
at least sixty years. How will the environment endure this level of punishment?
On the other hand, the ecological footprint imposed by developed countries is still
unduly heavy. Although greenhouse gas emissions rates have been going steadily
down, the absolute level of emissions continues to increase. Energy efficiency is
also improving, with most developed countries having smaller rates of energy
consumption per unit of GDP. However, the absolute volume of most natural
resources used by developed countries continues to increase. And analyses of
material flows reveal the presence of a process of environmental cost-shifting or
environmental load displacement.2
During the past two decades, the world's multilateral organizations redefined the
architecture of the global economy. On one hand, financial and capital account
deregulation was promoted (in some cases imposed) in the 1980's. On the other
hand, trade liberalization was strengthened as a result of the Uruguay Round, a
long process of multilateral negotiations that led to the creation of the World Trade
Organization (WTO), successor to the General Agreements on tariffs and Trade
(GATT).
One of the dominant leitmotifs of this process was the relentless critique of public
sector intervention in anything remotely related to economic affairs. The private
sector and the allocation properties of the market system were systematically
presented as the best way to handle economic affairs. The drive towards greater
deregulation was accompanied by a thrust towards deeper privatization.
This was linked to the expansion of the original mandate of the GATT-WTO system
to integrate new areas into the multilateral trading system. These new areas went
from investment regulations to intellectual property rights, restricting the capacity of
governments to deal with critical issues of development policy and limiting the
availability and scope of policy instruments.
Today, the WTO is more than ten years old. It is at the crossroads of a critical
situation. On one side, there are countries and a trade-policy community that
demand more trade liberalization, at a faster rate and in more branches and sectors
of economic activity. On the other side, there is another group of countries and large
sectors of civil society demanding a slower pace for future negotiations. They also
demand a thorough assessment of what's working and what's wrong with the past
record of trade liberalization.
A look at the structure of world trade and the relative shares of different groups of
countries provides a sobering backdrop for the assessment of the accomplishments
of the WTO. Although exports from developing countries have increased, the
structure of world trade remains heavily lopsided. And there remain formidable tariff
and non-tariff barriers in developed countries preventing true market access for
developing countries exports. This reveals that the big winners of the globalization
la GATT-WTO have not been the worlds developing or poorest countries.
2

Muradian, R., Martin OConnor and J. Martinez Alier (2001); Muradian and Martinez Alier (2001a).

In addition, trade liberalization is clearly associated with greater trade deficits in


developing countries. Although it led to rapid growth of imports, if failed to keep a
higher growth rate for exports. Thus, UNCTAD studies find that average trade
deficits for all developing countries during the nineties were higher than those in the
seventies by three percentage points of GDP. At the same time, GDP growth rates
were lower by two percentage points (UNCTAD 2003). All of this has serious
negative implications for developing countries current accounts and indebtedness.
In addition, there is a disturbing trend towards divergence instead of convergence in
several critical domains. For example, in manufacturing industries the tendency is
for a higher concentration of total exports in a small number of countries. Lall (2003)
points out to this trend and explains it through the greater disparities among
countries in their ability to attract, master and improve on new technologies. These
are the drivers of dynamic competitiveness. The greater international disparity is not
a temporary adjustment to liberalization, and it will not correct itself automatically.
This paper takes a look at the reforms that are needed in the worlds trading system
in order to guarantee its contribution to the objectives of sustainable development.
This overarching goal is based on a combination of healthy environmental
stewardship and social responsibility. The first section presents a set of five themes
that are required as a backdrop for the general assessment of the trading system.
The second section discusses the relation between macroeconomic and trade
policies. Changes directed towards recovering a certain degree of autonomy for
monetary and fiscal policies are examined. The third section focuses on the Central
American countries, their macroeconomic indicators and a brief overview of how
their foreign trade patterns affect their natural resource base. The fourth section
examines the regulatory regime for agricultural trade and some of the fundamental
reforms needed in this area. The fifth section looks at international commodity
agreements, non-market access (NAMA), intellectual property and investment
rights, and the relation between trade and international environmental agreements
(IEAs). The final remarks include references to things that should not be done.

Perspectives for Reform


There are several aspects of the way we think about trade policies and trade flows
that need to be carefully revised. They condition the way we are able to analyze
whats going on and they are not perhaps the best point of reference. There are
also two principles that need closer scrutiny (SDT and PP).
The Myth of the Market
Any reflection on how economic, social and environmental affairs have been
managed or mismanaged in the past twenty years cannot fail to observe that this
period is dominated by the consolidation of the myth of the market. The notion of
the invisible hand as a process leading to efficient resource-allocation became the
paradigm of all economic policy considerations. It is probably the single most
powerful foundation of the one-size fits-all approach to economic policy favored by

5
the IMF and World Bank. And yet, when one asks for the evidence to back up this
contention, there is no reply.
A casual observer might note that the economic history of Western Europe and the
United States confirms the idea that free unabated markets bring along economic
prosperity. But, from the realm of economic history it is impossible to discern where
the market stops and other factors, such as state intervention, begin. Subsidies of
all types, as well as protectionism and strict regulations on capital and labor mobility
are inseparable from the operation of market forces over the past two hundred
years (Habbakuk 1962; Landes 1969; David 1975). The idea that the historic record
would reveal how the market brought about prosperity and welfare gains is
groundless. This, of course, does not mean that markets and prices are
unimportant. They are of great relevance, but they are not alone in explaining
prosperity in Europe or the United States.
Does theory show the market is the best system for resource allocation? Many
economists, those educated under the aegis of neoclassical economic theory, may
be tempted to reply that economic theory has demonstrated beyond reasonable
doubt that the market allocates resources efficiently. They might say that in a
position of general equilibrium, the allocation is Pareto-optimal. The problem is this
result depends on the condition of being in general equilibrium, and we still lack a
satisfactory theory of just how those equilibrium prices are attained in the first
place.3 Thus, there is no rational foundation for the belief that the market is the best
system for the allocation of resources.
Perhaps the most important implication of this is that the invisible hand is just a
metaphor, without robust empirical or theoretical underpinnings. The triumph of the
market ideology is in stark contrast with the scientific bankruptcy of general
equilibrium theory. From the perspective of applied economics and policymaking,
we must abandon this old idea and start thinking in new and more rigorous terms.
Protesters against deeper neoliberal globalization and more trade liberalization are
not mystical fanatics shrouded in obscurantism. And trade theory is not a scientific
truth that comes out in favor of free trade (as Bhagwati, 2000 pretends). Trade
theory is fatally hurt by the flaws of general equilibrium theory. And when we get to
the assumptions of the models of international trade theory, their simplicity is
misleading. Proofs of the basic theorems depend critically on the technical
assumptions, and whenever they need to be relaxed, the conclusions for theory and
policy are quite different (Ackerman 2004).
Debunking the mythology of free trade economics is an urgent task if we think
sustainability is a priority. Environmental economists and lawyers should examine
the implications of these shortcomings of economic theory. The market cannot
redress social inequalities, nor can it be the sole mechanism in charge of
environmental stewardship. It is vital to understand this if we want to improve our
performance in handling economic, social and environmental affairs.

The best references here are Fisher (1983), Sonnenschein (1973), Debreu (1974) and Mantel
(1973). An analytical review of this literature and of its implications can be found in Ackerman and
Nadal (2004).

6
The corollary of this is that the role of the State needs to be reconsidered. Recent
financial crises have not been provoked by irresponsible wrongdoings of
government, but by speculation and irresponsible exposure of agents from the
private sector. Thus, instead of chastising governments for their over-spending, for
example, we should look at the way in which private property rights help detonate
financial crises of great amplitude. At the macroeconomic level the role of the State
is critical in enforcing prudential supervision, implementing adequate riskmanagement practices and loan and investment policies for the banking and
financial sectors.
At the sector level, active State intervention is often important for industrial and
agricultural policies. In industry, policies are needed to generate dynamic
competitive advantages that are skill and technology driven. These are not
automatically transferred to the host country of foreign direct investments. An active
role for State agencies is often required to do the job. Developing countries normally
do not innovate at the technology frontier; they do need to engage in a protracted
effort to absorb new technologies, learn new networking and management
techniques before they can generate their own technology-base. These are things
that have been done in the developed world for over a century, and the market will
not do them automatically for developing countries as they engage in trade
liberalization.
Finally, there is a big difference in both objectives and nature between the agents
that sign the agreements within the WTO system (i.e., governments) and the agents
that actually perform trading operations (i.e., firms and corporations, sometimes
very large corporations). Today more than 66% of world trade takes place through
transnational corporations, and 40% of this takes place within companies (UNIDO
2003). If in the old days UNCTAD had a clear mandate to monitor markets and
patterns of market concentration, but developed countries destroyed this in the
1980s. Today here is a serious disconnect between the overarching WTO objective
of reducing or eliminating market distortions and the presence of intense market
power in most branches.
Market distortions are not always related to government subsidies but to market
concentration. Perhaps the single most important lacuna of all WTO agreements is
this lack of reference to market concentration, oligopolies and anti-trust enforcement
measures. Where collusion, unfair business practices and market concentration
have real impacts on international market prices, WTO has really nothing to offer.
Leaving these problems to the obscure workings of international commerce
arbitration boards is not the solution because their scope of competence does not
include mandatory anti-trust measures applicable to general cases. This is a real
problem that has not been addressed by WTO and is screaming for attention.
Vertical and horizontal integration in global commodity markets is a primary cause
of market distortion. Possible policy responses include an international review
mechanism on mergers and acquisitions (M&A) that involve transboundary
transactions. At a minimum, transparency requirements should be imposed on
transactions between agents that have more than 20% of a regional or global
market. Similarly, M&As and joint ventures involving cross-licensing and
capitalization of patent rights should receive better scrutiny. These operations can

7
be used to engage in serious business malpractices and unfair competition and can
significantly distort market operations.
Macroeconomic Policy and Trade
The last three decades have witnessed the separation of financial flows from
international trade. The clearest example of this pertains to short term transactions
in the worlds currency markets capital flows that are fifty times greater than trade
flows. Any assessment of the performance of the worlds trading system and its
relation to social and environmental sustainability needs to take into account the
evolution in the sphere of international monetary and financial relations.
In general, however, trade policy analysts have been focusing too narrowly on their
subject, without giving adequate consideration to the fact that trade liberalization is
part of a bigger macroeconomic policy package. Thus, they may have inadvertently
left outside of their scope of analysis the critical relationship between trade and
monetary and fiscal policies. The relation goes beyond the simple references to
exchange rate over or undervaluation, and involves the wider issues surrounding
finance, capital flows and the policy space in the context of capital account
deregulation.
UNCTAD has recently recognized the importance of reinforcing coherence
among policies and agents in the interface between the international
trading system and the international monetary and financial system
(UNCTAD 2004). But reforming the worlds trading system must go hand in hand
with changes in the role and operations of the IMF. The role, nature and mission of
the IMF must be clearly redefined: the world has changed, so the IMF must readapt. For one thing, it must stop imposing conditionality and seeking deeper and
faster financial liberalization. It must learn from the nature of financial crises today
and prevent bailouts that promote moral hazard. The IMF also must transform its
decision-making process and prepare to play a responsible lender of last resort role.
One of the most important aspects of the predominant views concerning
macroeconomic analysis and policymaking is the separation between macro
aggregates and the real sectors of the economy. Thus, we find a group of
economists that analyze economic aggregates without any consideration for real
sector variables. What happens in agriculture or industry, for example, is of no
importance as long as aggregate accounts remain balanced or stable. The same
applies to public or fiscal accounts, and to the balance of payments. Aggregate
balances are the only thing that matter, with the structure of the individual
components being totally irrelevant.
On the other side, we find a community of applied economists that concentrate on
the real sectors of the economy, natural resource management and environmental
economics. They know that interest and exchange rates matter for the natural
resource management and social welfare; they also know that the dynamics of
monetary and fiscal policies affect social inequality and the environment. But they
are normally not conversant with macroeconomic theory and thus prefer to ignore
that aspect of the problem.

8
Summarizing, the false dichotomy between monetary aggregates and real sector
variables needs to be abandoned. A new type of economic analysis, integrating
both dimensions, will be more policy-relevant. This implies redefining the contents
of macroeconomic policy for developing countries, in both its monetary and fiscal
components. And this is the more difficult part of the solution. Unless this is done,
there will be few benefits accruing to developing countries from reforms in the
trading system. This is of course the most difficult task, but it needs to be addressed
immediately. Below we return to this point to examine in greater detail how
macroeconomic policies that are relevant for trade flows can be redefined.
Special and Differential Treatment
Special and differential treatment (SDT) is based on the idea that fairness should be
an important guiding principle in international economic relations. It is also linked to
the recognition of existing international asymmetries as elements of great distortions
in the functioning of markets and generators of inefficiencies. In the context of WTO
it is linked to the idea that developing countries are not obligated to reciprocate in
full trade concessions made by developed countries because they need more time
to adjust to the economic forces unleashed by trade liberalization.
SDT is recognized by the original GATT in several of its articles, and these
principles were picked up in various rounds of multilateral negotiations and, finally ,
in several of the WTO agreements. The actual implementation of special and
differential treatment relies on various types of mechanisms: limited time
derogations; exceptions and preferences in disciplines; lower commitments in tariff
reductions; technical assistance commitments; etc.
In practice, however, SDT has really not provided the conditions needed by
developing countries to adjust. A few extra years in certain transition periods, or a
few tariff points below developed countries concessions, have not been able to
redress asymmetries that took decades or even centuries to crystallize. And
invariably, when the few extra years for adjustment go by, developed country trade
representatives demand immediate compliance with the commitments that have
been established. The lop-sided structure of world trade indicates that SDT has
been a failure to establish a leveled playing field.
At the same time, developed countries have failed to honor many of their critical
commitments and their non-binding pledges within the WTO system. So, as firm
obligations have been enforced on developing countries, the rich developed
countries have failed to deliver. The Uruguay Round is a lesson in failed promises
that cannot be forgotten when dealing with SDT in future negotiations.
Not only has SDT failed as a policy principle, it has been accompanied by a severe
contraction of the policy space of developing countries. As a result of structural
adjustment policies, several WTO agreements and some regional and bilateral
trade agreements, the array of industrial and agricultural policy instruments has
shrunk to the bare minimum. Policy instruments that were used by all developed
countries are thus out of reach, as if these countries had kicked the ladder that
enabled them to climb to levels of higher living standards. For example,
performance requirements are being curtailed by the agreement on Trade-Related

9
Aspects of Investment Measures (TRIMs), government procurement policies are
frowned upon and are now the target for destruction, direct government support
mechanisms are also forbidden in many cases because it is assumed they imply
unfair competition, etc.
The irony of this is that precisely at a point in time when economic theory
recognized asymmetric market configurations as the source of market failure, the
worlds trading system has essentially turned its back on the notion of special and
differential treatment (SDT) as the key guiding principle to eliminate asymmetries.
The first component of a new S&DT framework is recognition that developing
countries need more policy space. Under the principles of S&DT the worlds trading
system must open for developing countries the possibility of using all the industry
policy instruments that developed countries used at one point and that lateindustrializers also used. These are especially important for accessing dynamic
competitive advantages which are skill and technology based. Without these policy
instruments, developing countries run the risk of remaining forever in the lowproductivity trap of natural resource exporters. They cannot aspire to be able to
export goods in the high tech side of the industrial spectrum.
The second component is that financial assistance is essential to get to the level
playing field. Today we are far from the required levels of development aid. It is
sometimes argued that foreign direct investment (FDI) flows have picked up and
that they are preferable to aid. This is misleading because FDI is heavily
concentrated in a few developing countries, and because a significant portion of
total FDI is made up of mergers and acquisitions (M&A) of already existing
companies. It is estimated that up to 30% of total FDI is really M&A and therefore,
not an investment in new productive assets. Financial assistance is a different
instrument with a rationale of its own, oriented towards long term investments under
preferential conditions and should be part and parcel of trade agreements.
There are several successful instances where S&DT has been linked to financial
assistance and has played a very important role. Perhaps the most important one is
the European Union, where the accession of Spain, Portugal and Greece included a
series of financial support mechanisms that allowed these countries to invest in
several critical areas. Another example, in the context of an international
environmental agreement (IEA) is the Montreal Protocol where developing countries
were given not only longer time periods to adjust, but also received technical and
financial assistance to facilitate their compliance with the restrictions imposed on
ozone-depleting substances.
Although here is much talk about special and differential treatment these days,
there is not enough consideration to the principles we have mentioned here. No
new round of trade negotiations should take place without having S&DT at its core.
The need to make this principle operational is probably one of the most urgent
cross-cutting chores of the WTO system today.

Process and Production Methods

10

The debate about regulating processes and production methods (PPMs) is based
on the idea that any effort in this direction will lead to protectionism. Most
developing country governments are hostile to the notion of using environmentrelated PPMs within the WTO system. They argue that this leads to ecoprotectionism, not to adequate environmental defense. But the problem is not with
PPMs but with unilateral imposition of regulations and standards (Nadal 1994).
The 1998 Appellate Body decision on the US ban on shrimp imports when adequate
protection for sea turtles had not been used hints to a trend that is seen with distrust
by developing countries: if implies that if developed countries do use PPM-based
trade sanctions in an appropriate manner, they will be deemed to be GATT/WTO
consistent. This is of course unfortunate because issues that should be the object of
negotiations should not be left to the vagaries of dispute settlement and
adjudication.
To prevent this WTO members should start a program of consultations with
organizations such as UNEP in order to determine if and how PPM-based trade
restrictions can be used, and under what types of circumstances they can be
invoked. Defining criteria and accompanying disciplines should be the outcome of
multilateral negotiations and not unilateral imposition. This is the only manner in
which PPMs can be incorporated into the trade and environment agenda without
fears that it will lead to unjustified neo-protectionism.
Production processes that are liable to have global or transboundary effects, for
example, could be separated from those with purely domestic effects. The first
could be candidates for trade regulations and even restrictions under certain
circumstances and disciplines. But the most important point here is that all parties
should engage in a process of multilateral negotiations that would tackle three
important issues: sectors and products, disciplines and financial mechanisms to
assist developing countries. Special and differential treatment should be the
cornerstone of these negotiations.
The important precedent of the Montreal protocol is of critical relevance here. This
international environmental agreement is hailed as a success story and it is based
on a multilateral approach to regulations on PPMs. It could be argued that in fact
the Montreal Protocol dealt more with products (ozone-depleting substances) rather
than processes. But that distinction is a moot point here because that MEA was also
dealing with substances used in the production of certain products (refrigerating
devices, foams, aerosols, and certain pesticides using methyl bromide). The
regulatory regime of the Montreal protocol was based on the phasing out and
banning of certain inputs for production processes (refrigerants, foaming agents and
active agents in pesticides). This was done through multilateral negotiation and the
explicit recognition of asymmetries between members. Thus, developing countries
were given longer phasing out periods. In addition, a financial and technical support
mechanism was established to deal with this set of asymmetries.

Precautionary Principle

11

The precautionary principle (PP) is defined in the Rio Declaration as follows:


"Where there are threats of serious or irreversible damage, lack of full scientific
certainty shall not be used as a reason for postponing cost-effective measures to
prevent environmental degradation". The Cartagena protocol has a slightly different
formulation.
The PP recognizes the existence of critical ecological thresholds and seeks to
prevent breaching those thresholds. The cost of preventive anticipation should not
be unduly high and the onus probandi rests squarely with those that propose
change. The application of the PP requires weighing the risks of inaction with the
costs of preventive actions. It is an important and necessary guiding principle in the
relations between economic affairs and the environment.
PP is also a response to the commodification of science. Today more basic and
applied research is being funded by private companies and this raises serious
questions about the objectivity and independence of scientists. But the
precautionary principle has generated a major controversy due to fears that it might
serve neo-protectionism or that it can stifle technological innovations that could be
good for the environment.
Part of the problems arise from the ambiguities that surround the implementation of
the principle. Difficulties in determining where uncertainty and risks begin and where
reasonable doubt stops make the PP an awkward tool. If improperly managed, it
could lead to arbitrary and abusive decisions. For example, there are no easy
answers to the question of how to deal with exaggerated claims of hazard. And
although science by consensus does not necessarily lead to the best policy
advice, it seems that dialogue and ventilation of differing viewpoints is unavoidable
in the presence of disputes. The recent decision of the WTO to uphold the request
by the European Union to hear the opinion of scientists in its dispute with the United
States over genetically modified organisms is a good example of this. That case is a
decisive battleground in the war over GMOs, but it still remains to be seen how this
dialogue among scientists unfolds.
The problem with this principle is not in its uncertainty, as has been claimed by
many of its critics. After all, uncertainty and ambiguity is inscribed all over the WTO
system. Consider, for example, the provision in Article 27.3(b) of the TRIPs
agreement (of which more below) related to patents on life forms. The article refers
to essentially biological processes, but does this mean processes that occur
naturally or carried out by organisms? In reality, that provision, as many others, is
rather vague and, as with other items in patent law, it is designed to allow for the
greatest amount of patents in the field of genetic engineering. This is a policy choice
(not necessarily the best option), but its vagueness is a deliberate component.
The precautionary principle does not hold a monopoly over vagueness. But
vagueness and uncertainty is precisely what it is designed to deal with. And in order
to use this principle adequately, without transforming it into an instrument of
discrimination, it must be accompanied by legitimacy. This is only brought into the
system through intensive and protracted multilateral bona fide negotiations. If we
look at examples where the precautionary principle has been successfully used, this

12
is the salient feature. The Montreal Protocol mentioned above is, once again, the
best example.

Macroeconomics and Trade


Globalization and the expansion of trade could not have taken place without
financial deregulation. Capital flows underpin the expansion of trade and trade
liberalization relies heavily on the elimination of cumbersome controls that enforce
capital account restrictions. Also, if capital flows are restricted while trade
liberalization takes place, there is a higher risk of under or over-pricing as product
flows are used to cover capital movements and remittances of profitability.4
Deregulating the capital account was supposed to bring about better resource
allocation and lower cost of capital. Savings from developed countries would flow to
investments in developing countries, spurring growth in productivity and enhancing
economic growth. Deregulation in financial and banking systems would also allow
for better services through greater competition, lower interest rates and greater
rates of investment.5
But treating money and financial instruments as products that can be exchanged in
a marketplace, just like any other commodity is a fallacy. As Keynes pointed out,
money and financial instruments lack intrinsic value; they are extremely sensitive to
swings in confidence as to the future evolution of their value. Thus, although
financial liberalization did benefit some countries and several sectors (banking and
finance, brokerage firms, insurance and real estate), it also increased market
volatility, opened new avenues for speculative investments to the private sector and
led to lower investment rates. Market volatility and contagion have been
accompanied by slow growth and rising unemployment rates in most countries and
regions.
In interdependent financial markets, capital flows are conditioned by domestic, as
well as external factors. Domestic factors include the real interest rate and
expectations about the future evolution of several macroeconomic aggregates, in
particular the performance of the current account. External factors include the
international rate of interest, the state of other markets, and changes in the
regulatory framework in other economies (Shinji and Esaka 2001). Recognizing this
single fact is of utmost importance for its theoretical and policy implications.
As capital flows are subjected to minimal controls and restrictions, the relationship
between money supply, interest and exchange rates is modified. Thus, financial
deregulation restricts the scope of monetary policy. The best known example of this
is the impossibility to maintain the triple objective of an independent monetary and
fiscal policy, a fixed exchange rate and capital mobility.
4

In reality, profitability remittances through over and under pricing of inputs and final products among firms of a
single corporate group will continue to take place because of differences in tax rates.
5
Financial liberalization was forced upon the worlds economy in order to hedge against risk of fluctuating
exchange rates after 1973. It was also driven by the symptoms of a global recession at the end of the seventies
and a fall in productivity and profit rates in most developed countries. And by the time macroeconomic policy
started to be conditioned by financial and trade liberalization, macroeconomic stability became the number one
priority in the 1980s, leaving behind the commitment to full employment of the Bretton Woods era.

13

Although the open economy model promoted by the IMF is marked by serious
contradictions (Nadal 2004) the fund continues to recognize it as the sole reference
for macroeconomic policy. The IMF thinks that crises only arise from oversight,
errors in policy implementation and a deficient early warning system that prevents
timely adoption of corrective measures. The IMF is already proposing changes
along these lines, but the really touchy decisions concern the type of
macroeconomic policy package that it will recommend to the countries that come to
the IMF for advice and help. This is an especially delicate question given the
immense liquidity that pervades capital markets and the episodes of extreme
volatility that mark the dynamics of capital flows. At the very least, the IMF should
start by not condemning policies designed to protect countries. The IMF should
encourage countries to use Chilean-style holding-period taxes to discourage
excessive short-term capital inflows.
The full Mundell-Fleming model is afflicted by serious internal contradictions.6
Perhaps the most important one is the fact that although a flexible exchange rate is
critical for adjusting trade imbalances, capital mobility and anti-inflation policies
impose severe rigidities to this adjustment, causing over-valuation of exchange
rates and blocking the role of the exchange rate as an adjustment variable.7 It
should be kept in mind that floating exchange rates are not determined by market
balances influenced by the fundamental characteristics of an economy.
Also, capital inflows without public intervention expand the domestic money supply
as demand for assets denominated in the domestic currency increases. This leads
to a surplus in the capital account, an appreciating exchange rate and a drop in the
interest rate.8 This gradually reduces the flow of incoming capital and equilibrium is
restored in the balance of payments. But the expansion in the money supply can
bring about inflationary pressures and an even greater deterioration of the trade
balance. This can be curtailed by sterilizing the effects of the influx of capital
through open market operations. However, sterilization interrupts the adjustment
process, keeping the interest rate at a higher level than the international rate. This
leads to unsustainable configurations of the main macroeconomic variables.
The contradiction is defined in terms of two processes in the model. On one hand,
the model requires the interest rate to fall in order to restore equilibrium in the
money market in the face of incoming capital flows. On the other, sterilization
6

See Fleming (1962) and Mundell (1964). The Mundell-Fleming model does not have strict microeconomic
foundations, but its analytical structure depends on the notions that markets always clear, and that trade
liberalization is the best way to organize production and consumption. In fact, the close association between the
Mundell-Fleming open economy model and general equilibrium theory was acknowledged by its authors (see for
example, Mundell 1968), and this close relationship has also been recognized in more recent work
(Geanakoplos and Tsomocos 2001). The linchpin of the connection between the Mundell-Fleming and general
equilibrium models is the market clearing assumption, which in turn depends on the postulates of perfect
competition and flexible prices. The corollary to this reasoning is that if the open economy model is given
enough time, it will eventually lead to the desired results. Perfect capital mobility implies that small changes in
interest rates lead to very large capital flows.
7
Strictly speaking, the trade balance will deteriorate when the domestic currency becomes overvalued if the
Marshall-Lerner conditions are met, i.e. if the absolute value of the sum of the exchange-rate elasticities of
imports and exports is greater than one. Whether these conditions are met is irrelevant if the exchange rate is
impeded to act as an adjustment variable.
8
In the standard Mundell Fleming model when the money supply grows and the level of income remains
constant, the interest rate falls, reducing the cost of holding money and this re-establishes equilibrium in the
money market.

14
maintains the money supply constant and a higher interest rate. In practice, the
contradiction is resolved through intervention with sterilization, a higher interest rate,
a chronic currency overvaluation and a distorted adjustment process.
Capital controls can contribute to smooth cycles in the capital account, reduce
overall economic vulnerability (Furman and Stiglitz 1998; Ocampo 2003). In Chile,
unremunerated reserve requirements shielded the economy from overabundance of
short-term capital at times of surges and helped attain higher growth rates (FfrenchDavis and Tapia 2004). They also shielded the economy from contagion at a time of
great volatility caused by the Mexican financial crisis of 1994-1995. In Colombia,
capital controls also allowed for better handling of maturity periods of external debt
(Ocampo and Tovar 2003). In both cases, capital controls allowed policy makers to
regain some autonomy for a countercyclical monetary policy.
This is also consistent with the historical record of developed countries which shows
long periods of capital controls and only gradual liberalization for capital flows
(Eichengreen 1996). The experience of the past twenty years demonstrates that
premature and abrupt liberalization of the capital account is inappropriate for
developing countries. Even when strong regulatory regimes continued to exist, most
developing countries have found it difficult to adapt to the volatile environment of
international capital flows. A flexible approach in this domain can play a key role in
bringing about stability with adequate foreign investment levels. And although this
can increase the cost of certain investments in developing countries, that can help
increase economic efficiency.9
Capital controls are no panacea. Their central mission is to smooth the cycles of the
capital account, enhance stability and allow for a greater degree of independence of
monetary policy. This objective can also be attained with the use of balance of
payments provisions within the WTO framework. Although these measures were
reaffirmed in Marrakesh, they have been left in the backwaters of policymaking
thanks to opposition from dogmatic quarters in the WTO, the IMF and the U.S.
Treasury. These provisions can provide a constructive response to external
accounts crises (Nadal 1996) and should be reconsidered as an important tool in
the intersection between trade and financial flows.
All of this needs to be accompanied by active domestic policies for industrial and
agricultural development. In this sense, fiscal policy needs to go beyond the
shortsighted objectives of providing strong primary surpluses. As public debt
maturities improve, and as debt service to GDP ratios improve, fiscal restrictions
can be relaxed and greater investment in education, health, science and technology
will contribute to enhance competitiveness, improve welfare and consolidate
sustainability.
The worlds financial crises, especially in the last decade, have resulted mostly from
a combination of unsustainable external accounts, capital surges and reversion of
9

As is well know, today the amount of these transactions in the worlds currency markets is more than fifty
times the size of total foreign trade and long-term investments. A small tax of 0.3% on all such transactions
could play a constructive role in an international regime of financial regulation. It could very well be the source of
much needed aid to the poorest countries in the world and funding for large international environmental rescue
projects.

15
capital flows. The main thrust of our analysis here is that unless reforms of the
worlds trading system are accompanied by substantive changes in our approach to
macroeconomic policies, we will not be able to improve the chances of sustainable
development.

Central America: Trends in Trade, Macroeconomics and


Development
In Latin America, the pattern of restrictive macroeconomic policy over the past
fifteen years has led to a long period of sluggish economic performance. In the case
of Central American countries, this is shown by falling growth rates, low fiscal
revenues, unemployment and social inequality. The key issue here is that
macroeconomic policies have lost the capacity to act in a countercyclical manner,
and these economies have been left to ride the wave of globalization as best they
can. None of the Central American countries has anything resembling controls over
capital funds like the ones used in Colombia or Chile. The signature of the Central
American Free Trade Agreement (CAFTA) will impose severe limitations on the
regions degree of autonomy.
Table I
Growth Rates for Five Countries in Central America
1981-1985

1985-1990

1990-1995

1995-2000

2000-2003

Costa Rica

0.31

3.8

4.9

4.6

El Salvador

-2.6

1.8

5.5

3.5

1.9

Guatemala

-1.1

2.3

4.1

4.1

2.7

Honduras

1.5

3.3

3.8

3.2

3.6

Nicaragua

0.6

-3.4

1.5

5.1

2.7

Source: CEPAL (2004)

A cursory analysis of growth rates in the Central American region reveals that in the
aftermath of the eighties, growth returned timidly to the region. Countries that chose
to attract maquiladora industries (like El Salvador) show higher growth rates. Others
(Nicaragua) got on the bandwagon of the maquiladora investment boom later. All of
these countries suffered from the syndrome of concentrating exports in the United
States market. Thus, when the U.S. economy went into the recession of 2000,
exports dropped and growth rates slowed significantly. The presence and
consolidation of China in the U.S. market, as well as the attraction that it exerted on
many maquiladora investments, puts the Central American export sector at great
risk.
CAFTA will prevent these countries to impose performance requirements on these
industries. As with NAFTA, the Central American agreement will forbid instruments
that help build rich forward and backward industrial linkages between the
maquiladora sector and the rest of the economy, limiting their capacity to act as a

16
strong engine for growth. It will also impose the same level of protection for direct
foreign investments that NAFTA established in its Chapter 11 provisions. This will
subordinate environmental policies to the priorities of trade and foreign investment
(Suppan 2004).
Fiscal policy in Central America is used to transfer resources from the real sectors
of the economy to the sphere of financial services. This is done not by increasing
fiscal revenues, but by cutting expenditures. Data on six Central American countries
for the primary and economic balances reveals a clear-cut pattern over the past
eight years: the primary balance exhibits either a surplus or a small deficit and the
economic balance always shows a deficit. On the other hand, public debt service
becomes one of the single most important components of public expenditure, with
interest payments reaching the equivalent of 12% of total fiscal revenues. The
transfer of resources from the real to the financial sector has a cost for sectors that
are critical for social and environmental long-term sustainability.

Table II
Central America: Fiscal Accounts 1995-2003
Primary Balance (a)
Economic Balance (a)

Costa Rica El Salvador Guatemala Honduras Nicaragua Panam


1.9
-0.6
-0.3
-0.2
0.5
2.4
-2.0
-2.1
-1.5
-0.7
-2.2
-0.2

Interest Payments (b)


18
12
(a) Average percentage of GDP 1995-2003
(b) Average percentage of total fiscal revenues 1995-2003

11

7.2

13.6

11.8

Source: CEPAL (2004)

Already the trade balance shows a disturbing trend of growing deficits. In spite of
the presence of a significant maquiladora sector, it appears that the regions
exporting sector is not performing adequately. It remains to be seen if CAFTA
allows the signatory countries to reverse this negative trend.
Over the past two decades, the share of primary products in the regions total
exports has remained very high. For countries like Honduras, Nicaragua and
Guatemala, the share of primary products in total exports is close to 80%, indicating
that the natural resource base is, and will remain, under heavy pressure. The most
important components included here are cattle, shrimp, fish products, bananas,
coffee and other horticultural goods. All of them are environment-intensive and
they have all suffered from price volatility and a declining long-term trend.

17

Figure I
Trade Balance of Five Central American Countries
1995-2003
1000
500
Millions of US dollars

0
-500
-1000
-1500
-2000
-2500
-3000
-3500
1995
Costa Rica

1997
El Salvador

1999

2001

Guatemala

2002
Honduras

2003
Nicaragua

Source: CEPAL (2004)

In the case of Costa Rica and El Salvador, the importance of non-traditional exports
increases, but this entails its own problems. Maquiladora industries in the apparel
and electronic sectors have made an important contribution to exports, but this
sector has been seriously affected by the recession in the United States. Also, the
competition from China, both as an attractor of new maquiladora investments and
as a challenger in the U.S. market, threatens to erode the advantages of the region.
Besides, the growing share of Nicaragua and Honduras in the North American
market is also a factor that will slow down the contribution of these sectors.
The importance of primary goods in total exports will remain as a dominant trait.
CAFTA will not change this structure because of the factors mentioned above, but
also because the rationale of that agreement is precisely to take advantage of the
static comparative advantages in the region. Exports from this region will remain
prone to the long-term trend of declining prices for primary products (Ocampo and
Parra 2003). The region runs the risk of remaining in a lock-in trajectory with exports
originating in low-productivity sectors close to the natural resource base. In this
context of environmental-cost shifting, environment-intensive exports will continue
to put heavy pressure on land, water bodies and biodiversity.

Figure II

18
Exports of primary products
(Percentages of total exports)
1980-2002
120.0

100.0

80.0

60.0

40.0

20.0

0.0

Costa Rica

El Salvador

Guatemala

Honduras

Nicaragua

Source: CEPAL (2004)

Agriculture
The urgent task of reforming the worlds agricultural system lies at the center of the
problem area of trade, social responsibility and the environment. What we do today
to the agricultural system of the world will determine the history of our future as a
species. Yet, the world has been unable to reconcile adequate food production and
distribution systems, improving living standards, and environmental sustainability of
the agricultural system. Although global agricultural production has continued to
outstrip total population, the rate of growth of yields has been slowing down and
today it is one third that of twenty years ago (FAO 2003). On the other hand, per
capita cultivated surface has begun to contract indicating that we have reached the
limits of the agricultural frontier in many key areas of the world. Usage consumption
rates of irrigation have spelled overexploitation of many aquifers, and heavy use of
chemical inputs also contributes to pollution of underground and surface water
bodies. And all of this coincides with a situation in which close to a billion human
beings suffers from malnutrition.
The Uruguay Round incorporated agriculture into its negotiations and contributed to
trade liberalization in this key sector, but left untouched the capacity of developed
countries to channel resources to the agricultural sector. Today, total subsidies for
agriculture in the OECD countries are close to 340 billion dollars per year.
The strategic objectives of the URAA were to open up the markets of several highlypopulated countries to exports from the United States and Europe, and to maintain
a faade of discipline in the relations between these two giant agricultural
producers. It envisaged several avenues for the reduction of subsidies for the
agricultural sector, but it kept direct payments to farms if the payments are aimed at
reducing production and allowed payments that are decoupled from production. It

19
preserved the capacity of developed countries to maintain highly deleterious export
subsidies. The complex array of technicalities is not enough, however, to disguise
the fact that the URAA helped sanctify these subsidies. It did not open market
access for the products of developing countries while global agricultural commodity
prices suffered severe reductions and volatility increased. After ten years of
operations, the URAA failed to solve the complex questions of food rights, economic
development, social responsibility and environmental stewardship.
Behind this is the fact that the invisible hand metaphor does not work in
agriculture. Income elasticity of demand for food doesnt allow for expansion of
demand as prices drop. On the supply side, aggregate crop output changes little
with price because farmers use all their productive capacity all of the time and
cannot influence prices. This is why in the United States acreage has remained
more or less constant in spite of price reductions. Summarizing, timely selfcorrection does not occur. The current policy, based on the false premise that we
need to let markets operate freely, is unsustainable (Ray 2004, Ray, Ugarte and
Tiller 2003). Thus, agriculture demands supply management policies.
In spite of this, the United States abandoned the policy package that for decades
had sought to stabilize prices at levels adequate for consumers and producers,
guaranteeing adequate farm incomes. Instead, it opted for trade liberalization and
payment schemes that are decoupled from technology and output decisions.
Policy makers believed that in order to enable exports to drive agricultural growth,
markets should be allowed to work. But inducing export expansion through price
reductions backfired.
Since 1996, world prices for Americas chief farm exports have plunged more than
40 percent, but U.S. crop exports did not increase as a result (Ray 2004). This led
to dramatic loses in farm income and increases in government payments to farmers.
This spelled trouble for small producers in developing countries as dumping
practices destroyed their markets, impoverishing rural communities throughout the
world and benefiting vertically integrated agribusinesses. This is why the difference
between consumer prices and the price that producers receive is out of any
reasonable proportion.
In the future, the system that the URAA helped enshrine must be drastically
redesigned. In the first place, developing countries must have the right to use
quantitative restrictions (QRs) to protect themselves from dumping practices and to
de-link their key strategic sectors from the paradigm of the URAA. These QRs are
compatible with WTO and are recognized by Article XVIII of the original GATT.
Safeguards should also be made available for developing countries to protect their
producers from the effects of dumping.
The question of subsidies requires closer scrutiny. Recent studies show that
eliminating subsidies will not bring about the rise in agricultural prices that is
required to provide farmers with adequate income and agriculture with a healthy
foundation for sustainable production. Recent studies show that subsidy elimination
would bring about minor changes in several key crops and small acreage
adjustments; the price increases would not compensate for the decline in income
(Tiller and Schaffer 2004). This indicates that the solution to the global trend of low

20
prices is not simply the elimination of subsidies. So instead of judging national
programs by how much they cost, trade negotiators should discipline the tradedistorting impact of those programs. The world needs adequate crop prices that
contribute to a healthy and vigorous worldwide agricultural sector (Ray,
Ugarte and Schaffer 2003).
Because global agricultural trade is in disarray, a radically new approach is
required. We must replace the old system based on the URAAs nave illusion that a
free market would solve all problems, with a sound institutional and legal
framework that blends sound supply-management policy measures with adequate
support mechanisms in developing countries.
A new institutional arrangement, perhaps a new framework convention, needs to
tackle the issues of sustainable agriculture, biodiversity, food security and access to
genetic resources, not a piecemeal basis, but in one single undertaking. Only in this
manner can the objectives of food security and responsible environmental
stewardship be reconciled. The new convention should restate the fundamental
right of nations to defend themselves from dumping practices and from the market
distortions brought about by the concentration of corporate power. Countries would
be allowed to determine the level of support to their domestic producers and be
subjected to trade-distorting disciplines explicitly defined in this agreement.
In developed countries the validity of supply-management policies should be
recognized once again and support systems should not be considered as a priori
market distorting. The new framework should incorporate multinational supply
management if durable results are desired. These supply-management measures
would increase market prices to reasonable levels and, at the same time, reduce
volatility as controlling excess capacity in developed countries would become
central to agricultural policy.

International Commodity Agreements (ICAs)


International commodity agreements (ICAs) are an important component of the
road to greater market transparency and less volatility. In the past, UNCTADs
mandate was to use them to arrest the deterioration of terms of trade and to
stabilize markets whenever there were large fluctuations. Several agreements were
set up (coffee, cocoa, rubber, sugar, tin and tropical timber) but this role was
destroyed in the 1980s in the aftermath of the debt crisis and was never restored.
Over the past century, real prices of primary products have experienced a
significant declining trend (Ocampo and Parra 2003). The vulnerability of many
countries that rely on one or a few basic products for exports puts undue pressure
on people and the environment. ICAs could help change this situation. The need for
the reinstallation of ICAs as a relevant policy mechanism stems from the presence
of market failures as a result of price volatility and long-term trends of declining
prices for many primary commodities.
In addition, ICAs can reduce market distortions due to market concentration and
reinstate more transparency in trade through the supervision of operations where

21
giant corporations control more than 20% of the market. They can stabilize prices at
levels that are fair for consumers and producers and dovetail certification and other
resource management schemes with commercial trends. Producers that receive a
fairer deal through ICAs can be more easily persuaded to improve quality and
adopt cleaner process and production methods without exacerbating tensions
between trade partners.
ICAs can also blend trade concerns with technical and financial assistance that
help improve standards while restoring some sense to the notion of special and
differential treatment. The example of the International Tropical Timber Agreement
(ITTA), currently being re-negotiated, is encouraging as an example that helps
promote fair trade with sustainable use and conservation of tropical forests. New
agreements should learn from the experiences of the ITTA, enhancing its virtues
and mitigating its errors. The main objective of new multilateral agreements should
be a combination of sustainable management of resources, social responsibility and
recognition of the legitimate rights and interests of indigenous peoples and other
local communities.
A new generation of international commodity agreements could explore ways and
means to increase value added of raw commodities, providing developing countries
assistance to take advantage of new economic opportunities, from processing to
packaging. Adding value to these commodities will create forward and backward
industrial linkages that generate more employment opportunities and have healthy
multiplier effects in commodity production chains.
Of course, high prices alone will not guarantee sustainable livelihoods for the
worlds poorest farmers. A range of national and international policies, from credit,
land, technology and transportation to tariff protection and access to markets, are
essential if agricultural production is to bring a better future for farmers.

NAMA
Market access to non agricultural products (NAMA) deals with the reduction and
elimination of tariffs on products not covered in the URAA. In its most extreme form
this would establish the mandatory elimination of tariffs on all products. In addition,
the NAMA would target so-called non-tariff barriers to trade (NBTs), some of which
may be linked to environmental policies and other policies related to community
development. The big issue here is that reducing tariffs without additional social
safety nets and environmental protection can have negative effects on
sustainability.
Two very important sectors from the standpoint of global sustainability would be
directly affected by NAMA. The first is fisheries, a sector that is already heavily
overexploited. According to FAO 70% of the world's commercial fish stocks are
already over-exploited and 34 million people who earn less than one dollar a day
depend directly on fishing for their livelihood. The survival of many poor coastal
communities depends critically on the conservation of fisheries that may be already
threatened with collapse.

22
Abolishing tariffs in the fisheries sector will unleash a greater degree of fishing effort
over already exhausted fisheries. NAMA would induce catches beyond the
renewable capacity of resources, thereby impeding sustainable development of
fisheries. Further elimination of tariffs on fish products would likely lead to
overinvestment in the processing industries and generate additional pressure on
fleets and fishermen to increase effort and catch. This will affect marine ecosystems
as food chains are further disturbed. Coastal communities and small-scale fisheries
will be threatened by resource depletion.
The forestry sector would also be affected by NAMA because the elimination of
tariffs on wood products would increase logging in the world's forests. Some of
these forests harbor ecosystems that are unique from the standpoint of biodiversity.
It is estimated that hundreds of millions of poor people depend heavily on tropical
forests for their survival. Their food, fuelwood, and medicines come from these
forests; in addition, structural materials for housing and cash crops are essential
components of their daily livelihoods. If economic pressure to increase logging is
increased, they will also be affected by greater pressure on their resource base.
If NAMA is negotiated carelessly, it could pre-empt efforts to negotiate viable
agreements on sustainable stewardship and development in several sectors. It
would also impose a single format type of regime for many products that are close
to the natural resource base. What the world needs now is a set of new agreements
capable of dealing with the complex matrix of problems that are related to resource
management, production, and fair trade.

Intellectual Property Rights and Trade


Contrary to the views of trade policy analysts, the objectives of free trade clash
violently with those of intellectual property rights. The first require free competition
to attain efficient allocations of resources. The second create monopoly rights that
automatically entail loss of welfare. This is especially important ion the case of
patents, which are statutory monopolies. Nevertheless, these two objectives coexist
side by side as if they complemented each other, when in fact they entail a
monumental contradiction.
Patents are based on the idea that inventors are rewarded with monopoly rights in
return for disclosure of their inventions. In this manner, society can benefit from their
inventive activity and they can reap the monopoly rents that accrue to the protected
activities. Traditional patent attorneys always agreed that this monopoly protection
should only be available where there are clear and demonstrable benefits to society
outweighing the adverse effects of monopolies. They also knew that there is an art
of non-disclosure when filling patent applications and this is why the idea of society
recovering the costs of granting monopoly protection is a pious fiction. But
economists came along with the simplistic idea that patents are required as
incentives for inventive activity and R&D.
First, patent systems are not the powerful incentives for R&D that many believe.
Intercapitalist competition is the main force behind the need to innovate (Baumol
2002). This is why market-based capitalism can outperform other economic
systems when it comes to technical innovations. Patents, on the other hand, do

23
serve as important instruments in corporate strategies, rewarding rent-seeking
behavior and increasing entry barriers for potential competitors (Baker and Chitani
2002).
Secondly, the vast majority of inventions protected by patents never make it to the
production stage. This is because patents serve primarily the purpose of helping
segment markets in order to extend monopoly rents. Patents are not an incentive
for innovation, they are tools for inter-industry competition. A significant proportion
of patents is obtained through incremental innovations or superficial modifications
on previously existing products whose protection is about to expire.
Third, strength of IPRs in developing countries is not determinant for R&D
investment as studies have found (Kumar 1996). In addition, developing countries
are constrained to keep R&D investments at a very low level. Twenty-year patents
and wide patentability will not change this state of affairs. In addition, industrial
policy instruments that could be used to enhance assimilation of technological
capabilities have been forbidden by several components of the WTO system. This
makes technological development very difficult and the presence of a patent system
will not help. On the contrary, it is an additional barrier to technological acquisition
and it may delay innovation and dissemination of information.
Fourth, the TRIPs agreement carries a distorted patent system which blurs the all
important separation between invention and discovery. Granting patents on life
forms is the foremost example of this distortion. But the process may not stop here
and with the convergence of biotechnologies and nanotechnologies it may lead to
exclusive monopoly rights of entire environmental dimensions. Already the number
of patent applications from the biotechnologies has surpassed the capacity of patent
examiners to fulfill their responsibilities. This is dangerous precedent that was to be
reviewed according to Article 27.3(b) of TRIPs but that exercise is still to provide a
rigorous analysis of the performance of this rule.
Fifth, a system based on wide patentability and long life terms for patents can stifle
innovation. The potential cost of patent infringement and the uncertainties that this
generates can slow down innovators. In addition, costs of patent litigation can run
into the millions of dollars and small and medium firms cannot run the risk of getting
caught in this type of problem.
The Uruguay Round managed to incorporate intellectual property rights with trade
negotiations. Although there may be some genuine questions in the intersection
between these two domains, the agreement on Trade Related aspects of
Intellectual Property (TRIPs) is an example of how trade negotiations can be used
to impose unfair institutional arrangements on developing countries. In addition,
TRIPs involves an extraordinary distortion of the rationality of the patent system,
carrying significant risks for social welfare and the environment.
The original array of patent protection treaties only required members to set up a
patent system, they did not impose the obligation to grant patents on any specific
field. Those legal instruments accepted restrictions in areas such as public health,
the environment and on moral grounds. And as far as patent life terms were
concerned, they did not impose a uniform standard on member countries. The

24
technical secretariat of most of those treaties, the World Intellectual property
Organization (WIPO), was an organization managed from the perspective of
traditional trademark, copyright and patent attorneys.
All of this changed during the Uruguay Round. TRIPs imposed on WTO member
countries the obligation to grant and recognize patents in a very wide variety of
items. It also imposed the obligation to recognize and grant patents on life forms
(Article 27.3b), although this was to be reviewed in 2000. It also imposed long life
terms for patents of twenty years and made it very difficult to set up a compulsory
licensing scheme. For countries investing very little in R&D, as most developing
countries, this is not a good idea.
Already the patent system is plagued with abuses and distortions. For example, a
high percentage of patent applications and patents do not involve anything new,
nor do they imply an inventive step (two elements required by every patent
system). In biotech industries, many patents simply involveminor changes in
molecules of existing products whose patents are about to expire. In many cases,
these changes do not even have any therapeutic value (violating the utility
requisite for patents). These are the same abuses that are being projected into
developing countries by forcing global standards in IPRs.
It is important to return to a more rational system for the protection of intellectual
property. The first step should be to de-link intellectual property rights from the
WTO. This is needed in order to redefine a global patent system that is not marketdistorting and fulfills its mission to protect inventors rights. It should not impose
wide patentability and long duration for patents and it should abolish patents on life
forms, a major element distorting the patent system that has negative effects on
human health and access to genetic resources. The notion that this would throw the
biotech industry in disarray is preposterous. The real trouble for biotech firms comes
from the irresponsible use of molecular biotechnology (that remains a hit-or-miss
technology) and the reprobation of this by the market.
Other areas that need urgent attention include the granting of patents in health and
environmental goods. As patents do create barriers to entry, these sectors can be
negatively affected by an all too flexible IPR system. The recent battle over supply
of medicines to treat HIV/AIDS patients underscores this. But in the future we might
see other examples of patents blocking clean technology progress in developing
countries. Restoring elements of rationality in the international patent system should
be accompanied by restoring the capacity of developing countries to design and
implement industrial policies. WTO rules that forbid access to these policy
instruments are a mockery of the notion of special and differential treatment.

Investment and Trade (TRIMs)


The best example of how the special and differential (S&DT) clauses in the WTO
agreements have been betrayed is the agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of
Investment Measures (TRIMs). Through this agreement, developing countries have

25
been forced to forego the use of important industrial policy instruments. Policies
aimed at increasing local content in value added, or limiting imports to a certain
proportion of exports, are not allowed under the current version of TRIMs. Even this
was not considered sufficient and developed countries engaged in a big display of
diplomatic efforts to strengthen these provisions as part of the multilateral
investment agreement (MIA).
Thus, instead of protecting developing countries against the effects of market
concentration, the TRIMs ended up shielding powerful multinational corporations
against public policies in host countries. The policy instruments that are eliminated
by TRIMs are important in the context of industrial policy. Some of them are critical
in order to obtain technological capabilities and go into higher value added exports.
They are essential to building forward and backward inter-industry linkages, and
those linkages are the carriers of economy-wide multiplier effects.
The North American Free-Trade Agreement (NAFTA) carries in its Chapter 11 the
best example of how trade policy can put commercial concerns above
environmental and health objectives. In a perverse twist of priorities, special and
differential treatment is accorded to private multinational firms in detriment of public
interest in host countries. This restricts policy options and forces countries into
remaining in a sub-industrial stage. In the case of Mexico, although this is masked
by the presence of maquiladoras, the inability to construct backward linkages in
industry limits the ability of the exporting sector to pull the rest of the economy in a
healthy growth process. In fact, the growth of the maquiladora sector simply means
greater distortions in the countrys industrial system.
The WTO should allow developing countries to impose performance requirements
on foreign direct investment. Particularly important are requirements in terms of
greater local value added, trade balance restrictions (imports conditioned to export
performance), employment generation, regional growth and technological
development (transfer of technology). Also, a revision of the TRIMs is required to
incorporate the need for greater market transparency through the monitoring of
operations of multinational corporations.

Final Remarks (What Doesnt Work)


Reducing trade barriers is not an end in itself. The dynamics of trade negotiations
should stop being dominated by this fallacy. The goal is sustainability and
development, not free trade per se. So, before the world embarks in a new round of
multilateral trade negotiations, the WTO should proceed to assess carefully how the
existing agreements are being implemented and how they are performing.
Implementation problems persist and they need to be solved before jumping to new
endeavours. In particular, the WTO should look at the thorny question of who is
benefiting and who is losing from the existing institutional and legal framework.
Without this, no new issues should be considered.
WTO should be subordinated to the overarching objectives of sustainable
development, not to free trade. And in order to do this, it must get away from
procedures that diminish its legitimacy. Green rooms, mini-ministerials, the

26
manipulation of agendas and calendars, chair-driven reverse consensus and
negotiations under a closed-doors-no-minutes regimes must be abandoned. The
WTO secretariat needs to become an objective and impartial agent in the life of this
system.

REFERENCES
Ackerman (2004), An Offer you cant refuse. Free Trade, globalization and the
search for alternatives, in Ackerman and Nadal (2004).
Ackerman, F. and A. Nadal (2004)
The Flawed Foundations of General Equilibrium. Critical Essays on Economic
Theory. London and New York: Routledge.
Anderson, K. (1998)
Agricultural Trade Reforms, Research Initiatives and the Environment, in Lutz.
Ernst (editor), Agriculture and the Environment: Perspectives on Sustainable Rural
Development. The World Bank, Washington, D.C. [71-82]
Baker, Dean and Noriko Chitani (2002)
Promoting Good Ideas on Drugs: Are Patents the Best Way? The Relative
Efficiency of Patent and Public Support for Bio-Medical Research. Briefing Paper.
Center for Economic and Policy Research (CEPR). October 11, 2002. [38]
Electronic version available: www.cepr.org
Baumol, William J. (2002)
The Free-Market Innovation Machine: Analyzing the Growth Miracle of Capitalism.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Cole, M. A. (1999)
Limits to growth, sustainable development and environmental Kuznets Curves: An
examination of the environmental impact of economic development, Sustainable
Development, 7 (2) [87-97].
CEPAL (2004)
Estudio Econmico de Amrica Latina y el Caribe 2003-2004. Electronic version
available: www.ecla.org
Daly, H. (1993)
The Perils of Free Trade. Scientific American, November. [24-29]
Paul David (1975)
Technical Choice, Innovation and Economic Growth. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Debreu, G. (1974)
Excess Demand Functions, Journal of Mathematical Economics, 1 [15-21]

27

Eatwell, John and Lance Taylor (2000)


Global Finance at Risk: The Case for International Regulation. New York: The New
Press. [258]
Eichengreen, Barry (1996)
Globalizing Capital. A History of the International Monetary System. Princeton, N.J.:
Princeton University Press. [227]
--- (1999)
Toward a New International Financial Architecture. A Practical Post-Asia Agenda.
Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics. [189]
Eldredge, N. (1998)
Life in the Balance. Humanity and the Biodiversity Crisis. Princeton University
Press, Princeton
Ffrench-Davis, Ricardo and Heriberto Tapia (2004)
The Chilean-style of Capital Controls: An Empirical Assessment, Document
prepared under the ECLAC Project on Management of Volatility, Financial
Liberalization and Growth. Presented at the Latin American Studies Association
meeting, Las Vegas, October 2004. [36]
Fleming, M. (1962)
Domestic Financial Policies under Fixed and under Floating Exchange Rates,
International Monetary Fund Staff Papers 9. Washington, D.C.
Fisher, Franklin (1983)
Disequilibrium Foundations of Equilibrium Economics, Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Furman, J. and J. Stiglitz (1998)
Economic Crises: Evidence and Insights from East Asia, Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, no. 2. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution.
Geneakoplos, J. and D. P. Tsomocos (2001)
International Finance in General Equilibrium, Cowles Foundation Discussion
Paper. No. 1313.
Global Poverty Monitoring (2004)
Electronic version: www.worldbank.org/research/povmonitor/
Grossman, G. and A. Krueger (1995)
Economic Growth and the Environment, Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (2),
[358-377].
H.J. Habbakuk (1962)
American and British Technology in the 19th Century. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press

28
Hansen, S. (1990)
Macroeconomic Policies and Sustainable Development in the Third World. Journal
of International Development, Vol. 2. [533-557]
Houghton, J.T., Y. Ding, D.J. Griggs, M. Noguer, P.J. van der Linden, X. Dai, K.
Maskell, C.A. Johnson (2001) Climate Change 2001: The Scientific Basis.
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, UK.
Kumar, Nagesh (1996)
Intellectual property Protection, Market orientation and Location of Overseas R&D
Activities by Multinational Enterprises, World Development, 24 (4). [673-688]
Lall, Sanjaya (2002)
A Disturbing New Industrial Map of the Developing World. Presentation at the
University of Maastricht. [54]
Landes, D. S. (1969)
The Unbound Prometheus. Technological Change and Industrial Development in
Western Europe from 1750 to the present. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Mantel, R. (1974)
On the Characterization of Aggregate Excess Demand, Journal of Economic
Theory, 7 [348-353]
McCarthy, J.J., O.F. Canziani, N.A. Leary, D.J. Dokken, K.S. White (2001) Climate
Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation, and Vulnerability. Intergovernmental Panel on
Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.
Mundell, R. (1964)
Capital Mobility and Stabilization Policy under Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rates,
Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, 30 [421-431]
--- (1968)
Introduction to International Economics. New York: MacMillan.
Muradian, R., Martin OConnor and J. Martinez Alier (2001)
Embodied Pollution in Trade. Estimating the Environmental Load Displacement of
Industrialised Countries. Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei, Milan.
http://www.feem.it/web/activ/_activ.html
Muradian and Martinez Alier (2001a)
Trade and the Environment: from a Southern Perspective, Ecological Economics,
36 (2001). [281-297]
Murphy, Sophia (2004)
UNCTAD XI: Challenging the Commodity Crisis. Institute for Agriculture and Trade
Policy. June 2004. [8] Electronic version available at www.iatp.org.
Myers, Norman and Andrew H. Knoll 2001, National Academy of Sciences. (2001)

29
"The biotic crisis and the future of evolution", Proceedings National Academy of
Sciences, Vol. 98, Issue 10, 5389-5392, May 8, 2001.
Nadal, Alejandro (1994)
The Tuna-Dolphin Association in the Eastern Pacific Ocean Tuna Fishery:
International Trade and Resource Management Issues, Ocean Yearbook 11,
(Mann Borghese, E., N. Ginsburg and J. R. Morgan, editors). Chicago: University of
Chicago Press. [120-143]
--- (1996)
Balance-of-payments Provisions in the GATT and NAFTA, Journal of World Trade,
30 (4). August 1996. [5-24]
--- (2004)
Contradictions of the Open Economy Model as applied in Mexico, in Ackerman
and Nadal (2004). [133-148]
Ocampo, Jos Antonio (2003)
Capital account and Counter-cyclical Prudencial Regulations in Developing
Countries, Serie Informes y Estudios Especiales. CEPAL. 6 Febrero 2003.
Ocampo, Jos Antonio and Camilo E. Tovar (2003)
La experiencia colombiana con los encajes a los flujos de capital, Revista de la
CEPAL 81. [7-32]
--- and Mara ngela Parra (2003)
Los trminos de intercambio de los productos bsicos en el siglo XX, Revista de
la CEPAL, 79. [7-35]
Ray, Daryll E. (2004)
Agricultural Policy for the Twenty-First Century and the Legacy of the Wallaces
John Pesek Colloquium on Sustainable Agriculture. March 3, 2004. Iowa State
University. Ames, Iowa. [45]
Ray, Daryll E., Daniel de la Torre Ugarte and Kely J. Tiller (2003)
Rethinking U.S. Agricultural Policy: Changing Course to Secure Farmer Livelihoods
Worldwide. Agricultural Policy Analysis Center (APAC), The University of
Tennessee. [68] Electronic version available at www.agpolicy.org.
Sonnenschein, H. (1973)
Do Walras Identity and Continuity Characterize the Class of Community Excess
Demand Functions? Journal of Economic Theory, 6 [345-354]
Suppan, Steve (2004)
Analysis of the Central American Free Trade Agreement (CAFTA) Concerning
Agriculture. Institute for Agriculture and Trade Policy (IATP). April 22, 2004.
Electronic versiuon available at www.iatp.org.
Sebastian, I. and A. Alicbusan (1989)

30
Sustainable Development: Issues in Adjustment Lending Policies. Environment
Department Divisional Working Papers 1989-1996. The World Bank, Washington
D.C.
Shinji, Takago and Taro Esaka, "Sterilization and the Capital Inflow Problem in East
Asia, 1987-1997" in Regional and Global Capital Flows. Macroeconomic Causes
and Consequences. Ito, Takahoshi and Anne O. Krueger (eds.). University of
Chicago Press (2001) [197-226]
Tiller, Kelly J. and Harwood D. Schaffer (2004)
U.S. Cotton U.S. Cotton Subsidies Under Fire: Would Subsidiy Elimination Really
Help Farmers Worldwide? Beltwide Cotton Conference, San Antonio, Texas.
January 9, 2004. [23]
Tisdell, Clem (2001)
Globalisation and Sustainability: environmental Kuznets curve and the WTO,
Ecological Economics 39 (2001), [185196]
SIPRI (2004)
SIPRI Yearbook 2004. Armaments, Disarmament and International Security,
Stockholm International Peace Research Institute. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Sonnenschein, H. (1973)
Do Walras Identity and Continuity Characterize the Class of Community Excess
Demand Functions? Journal of Economic Theory, 6 [345-354]
UNCTAD (2003)
Trade and Development Report 2003. United Nations Conference on Trade and
Development. New York and Geneva: United Nations. Electronic version available:
www.unctad.org
--- (2004)
Trade and Development Report 2004. United Nations Conference on Trade and
Development. New York and Geneva: United Nations. Electronic version available:
www.unctad.org
UNIDO (2003)
Industrial Development Report, 2003. Electronic version available at:
www.unido.org
UNFPA (2002)
State of the world population 2002. People, poverty and possibilities. New York,
United Nations Population Fund. Electronic version available:
www.unfepa.org/swp/2002swpmain_spa.htm
Wilson, E.O. (1993)
The Diversity of Life. Harvard University Press, Cambridge.

31

You might also like