Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

Bernard Lietaer - New Money For A New World PDF From

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 375

BERNARD LIETAER & STEPHEN BELGIN

NEW MONEY
FOR A

NEW WORLD
I

o.A'

Ojr/
r1

ao.
o

j%
V

i
S

w,

SYNOPSIS

We can end the threats to our environment and aid dramatically in its restoration. We can help provide
meaningful work for all, with opportunities that enhance and replenish the world about us. We can
effectively address fundamental urban and rural concerns and the many diverse and often-divergent needs
of developing and developed nations alike. We can create a better world where life and all living systems
flourish. This is not an idealistic dream, but is rather a pragmatic attainment, achievable within our very
own lifetimes.

So write Bernard Lietaer and Stephen Belgin, authors of the much-anticipated book New Money for a
New World. Mr. Lietaer is a principal architect of the euro and author of the acclaimed international bestseller The Future of Money, which has been translated into sixteen languages. Mr. Belgin is the founder
and President of Qiterra Press, a publishing company dedicated to life-affirming works that improve the
human condition.

New Money for a New World examines a previously unexamined culprit for the many issues we face
today the monopoly of our centuries-old monetary system. This book provides many ways and means
that are readily available to stop the current juggernaut towards global self-destruction. Many of the
solutions offered within this book are more than theory. Communities from around the world have
successfully addressed a myriad of issues without the need to raise taxes, redistribute wealth, or depend
upon enlightened self-interest from corporate entities. Rather, the improvements were realized simply and
effectively by rethinking money.

With such a shift, everything is possible.

Rarely has a cultural look at money ever been presented with the depth and panache of this book. New
Money for a New World is of critical usefulness and could well start a movement towards a new use of
currencies and wealth that will bring constructive impetus to the emerging planetary civilization. Thus, it
is more than a book; it is a key process in whole system transition.

~Dr. Jean Houston, Author, UN consultant, and Host of A Passion for the Possible A PBS series

Table of Contents

SYNOPSIS
TITLE PAGE
READER COMMENTS
DEDICATION
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
INTRODUCTION
PART I - OUR MONEY, OUR WORLD
CHAPTER ONE - A Tale of Two Cities
CHAPTER TWO - Welcome to Moneyville
CHAPTER THREE - Megatrends and Money
CHAPTER FOUR - A Money Primer
CHAPTER FIVE - Money Is Not Value Neutral
CHAPTER SIX - Back to the Future
CHAPTER SEVEN - A Change of View
CHAPTER EIGHT - Economic Myopia
CHAPTER NINE - Lessons from a Depression
CHAPTER TEN - The Blind Spot
PART II - NEW MONEY
CHAPTER ELEVEN - Great Change
CHAPTER TWELVE - Efficiency, Resilience, and Money
CHAPTER THIRTEEN - Sustainable Development
CHAPTER FOURTEEN - LETS and Time Dollars
CHAPTER FIFTEEN - Social-Purpose Currencies
CHAPTER SIXTEEN - Commercial-Purpose Currencies
CHAPTER SEVENTEEN - The Terra, A Trade Reference Currency
CHAPTER EIGHTEEN - Two Worlds
PART III - THE MYSTERY OF MONEY
CHAPTER NINETEEN - Archetypes
CHAPTER TWENTY - The Missing Archetype and Money
CHAPTER TWENTY ONE - Repression of an Archetype
CHAPTER TWENTY TWO - Shadows
CHAPTER TWENTY THREE - Money and the Tao
CHAPTER TWENTY FOUR - Consequences of Repression
PART IV - MONEY, ARCHETYPES, AND PAST AGES
CHAPTER TWENTY FIVE - The Central Middle Ages Revisited
CHAPTER TWENTY SIX - Dynastic Egypt
CHAPTER TWENTY SEVEN - Dynastic Egypt Revisited
CHAPTER TWENTY EIGHT - The Balinese Exception
CHAPTER TWENTY NINE - Invitation To A New World
CHAPTER THIRTY - The Dynamics of Transformation and Money
ABOUT THE AUTHORS
COPYRIGHT
ENDNOTES

READER COMMENTS

The comments below for New Money for a New World also include endorsements for previous works in
which many of the same arguments were presented in a more academic fashion. Other comments will be
posted online on our companion website:

http://www.newmoneyforanewworld.com

New Money For A New World is one of those rarest of rare books that can truly help change the course
of humanityin just the way so many of us sense but dont know how to get there. With disarming
simplicity and amazing clarity, authors Bernard Lietaer and Stephen Belgin reveal the secret liberating
variable to empower rapid and profound societal and consciousness transformation and environmental
healingmonetary redesign. Read this book to see how you can participate in accelerating our arrival at
a regenerative and fulfilling new world.

~Richard Ruster, Ph.D.,

Founder, Center for the Human Dream,

Co-Creator, the Hummingbird Community,

Author of The Homing Process: A Unifying Theory of Evolving Systems.

This is an important breakthrough in the emerging new economics of sustainability and human
wellbeing.

~Ed Mayo

President, the New Economics Foundation

These are the smartest people thinking - and rethinking - about money today. If you are among the sad
majority who still think money is that green paper in your pocket, think again. The kinds of money
available to us are varied as goals we have for our economy. In a world where there is more than enough
stuff to go around, we deserve a money capable of reflecting rather than undermining the abundance we
have achieved. This book proves the point and points the way.

~Douglas Rushkoff

Author of Life Inc., and Program or Be Programmed

The 20th century was the age of competition and the 21st century will be the age of cooperation. The
concept of complementary currency this book elaborates on will be the keyword for global citizens who
want to live fully in the age ahead of us.

~Charmine Koda

Japanese Environmental Journalist

Others have shared Bernard Lietaers concern about a sustainable economy, but have not been able to
provide a realistic solution. In New Money for a New World, he and co-author Stephen Belgin show us
such a solution in a bold and fresh manner, and it is in this sense that this is an epoch-making book.

~Toshiharu Kato

Director Services Department, Ministry of International Trade and Industry (MITI), Japan

Exciting, challenging and profound; a unique and essential contribution to our understanding of money.

~Dr. Peter Russell

Author of The Global Brain and Waking Up in Time

This book gives the recipe on how we in the future can create a social economy which is more
responsible, more friendly towards the environment, and less filled with conflict.

~Professor Jesper Jespersen

Churchill College, Cambridge University (UK) and University of Roskilde (Denmark)

Something extraordinary and largely unreported is happening to money. This book looks set to be the
herald of the future money revolution.

~David Boyle

New Economics Foundation, London

This book really opened my eyes as to what money is about, and what its future is - and is not.

~Stephen Denning

Program Director, Knowledge Management, World Bank

This is a wise and incisive analysis of the nature of money in our society; the remarkable and pragmatic
solutions it offers demand of us that we think about money in entirely new ways.

~Professor Jacob Needleman

Philosopher; author of Money and the Meaning of Life

The mind of Bernard Lietaer is a rare mix of practical experience in modern finance, deep understanding
of history, and lively imagination about the future. Only such a mind could have produced so fresh and so
lucid an analysis of how money has become an obstacle to abundance and how conscious choices about
new kinds of complementary money can help us fuse underused resources with underemployed people.

~Harlan Cleveland

President of the World Academy of Art and Science


National currency is cold and selfish by itself. So let's create community currencies with which we can
warm up our communities as New Money for a New World recommends.

~Tsutomu Hotta

Former Minister of Justice and Supreme Court Judge in Japan.

Chairman, Sawayaka Welfare Foundation,

Founder of the Japanese Fureai Kippu currencies

The medium is the message. As Bernard Lietaer and Stephen Belgin point out, the money system is not
neutral. One way or another, our behavior is heavily influenced by it. Can we change the way it works?
This question concerns us all. The answer will help to decide the future of humanity and life on earth. The
authors authoritative practical experience of money and finance, underpinned by their awareness of the
worldwide shift of consciousness now taking place, results in many thought-provoking insights...It is not
necessary to agree with every detailed proposal in this informative and stimulating book, in order to
welcome it as an outstanding contribution to a vital question - the future of money in the Information Age.
I wholeheartedly recommend it.

~James Robertson

Author of The New Economics of Sustainable Development (1999)

and co-author of Creating New Money (2000)

New Money For A New World makes a simple and profound proposition: Unless we can balance the
current social and monetary structures, whose remedies are well described here, our shared desire for a
just, sustainable, and peaceful planet is simply not possible. ALL the good works that many of us are
involved in, admirable, even successful as they may be, are mere band aids, fingers in the dike. I
challenge any serious reader of this book to arrive at a different conclusion. Thats the bad news. The
good news is WE CAN MAKE IT! New Money For A New World offers unique effective tools by which
to resolve our core issues and co-create a better, vibrant future.

~John Steiner

Global Citizen

This book is truly essential for our survival. I was surprised how much I learned, (and how much I didn't
know about money). The writing style is as enjoyable as it is instructive.

~Margaret Wheatley

Author of Management and the New Physics

I have read three books which I consider to be truly uplifting and transformative: A Course in Miracles,
The Power of Now, and most recently, New Money for a New World. This work offers a clear roadmap
by which to resolve many of humanitys seemingly insurmountable crises without the need for

international treaties, more taxation, or the redistribution of wealth, all the while respecting and
potentially expanding our spiritual underpinnings. New Money for a New World is a gift to humanity, to be
read by everyone who dares to dream of a world gone sane. Bernard Lietaer and Stephen Belgin have
created a masterpiece.

~Dr. Frank Baylin

President, CEO - Baylin Publications

DEDICATION

This book is dedicated to the beloved memory

of two extraordinary women and mothers,

Agnes Lietaer-Catry (1914-2011)

and Edith Dernis-Belgin (1923-2011).

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

The authors would like to thank Dr. Sally Goerner and Dr. Robert Ulanowicz for their groundbreaking
work in systems physics and theoretical ecology, which provided the scientific basis in Chapter Twelve
and Chapter Thirteen.

We would like to acknowledge and thank our tireless editors Jonathan Kolber and Daniel Drasin, Jennifer
Dunne for her many vital professional and personal contributions, Jillian Reitsma for her valued
assistance with graphic design, Stephen DeMeulenaere for his research and input regarding Balinese
complementary currency systems in Chapter Twenty Eight, Margrit Kennedy for her work regarding
demurrage and complementary currencies, and our gifted webmasters Marcio Diaz and Gael Van
Weyenbergh. We wish to express our sincere gratitude to Michael Spolum and family, Tesa Silvestre, Lisa
Spiro Price, Eric Karlson, Sean Karlson, Molly Stranahan, Rebecca Gordon, Rob Gordon, Lisa Stone, the
Lipman Family, Ruby Begay, Susan Belchamber, Rachel Bagby, Edward Ciaccio, William Donohoe,
Mark Finser, Carol Newell, Derek Garcia, Nitin Gadia, Lion Albaugh, Lynn Gold, the Hummingbird
Community, the Triskeles Foundation, Anthony Dunkley, Chris Tucker, Phyllis Karlson, Evelyn and Sol
Resnick, Bertha Paul, Nicole Silvestre, Vincent and Mary Andreano, Alexander Belgin, and many others
too numerous to mention here for their support. We wish to also thank Jacqui Dunne, Deb Shapiro, and Ed
Shapiro for their assistance with a previous version of this book.

Finally, we are very grateful to the many pioneers and communities, past and present, whose insights and
efforts have contributed to a greater understanding of money.

BAL; SMB

INTRODUCTION

Everything is possible when everything is at stake.

~NORMAN COUSINS

Humanity is at a critical juncture, faced with two very real yet vastly different prospects. The
unparalleled achievements over the course of recent decades in one domain after another offer hope of a
vast renewal and golden age for society. In direct opposition to this is the persistence of a constellation of
seemingly insurmountable global issues that threaten us as never before. What is required is as
straightforward as it is profound. Our global civilization needs a new operating system, and fast.

Our seemingly paradoxical situation is explained by the fact that the very same ways of thinking that
brought about the Industrial Age and made possible many of our advancements, have also fueled the
myriad crises that are now converging upon us. In particular, many of the socioeconomic rules under
which we currently operate were actually put in place centuries ago, and were heavily influenced by a
worldview that failed to recognize that our planet is a living system and that every form of life has its
unique and valuable place and purpose in sustaining the larger web of life. In ignoring the conditions that
are necessary to the health of our ecosystems and communities, we have inadvertently fouled our nest.

As a direct consequence of our centuries-old ways of being and doing, we are now faced with: great
financial instability, growing disparities of wealth, resource wars, the breakdown of community, alarming
rates of species extinction and ecosystem depletion, and accelerating symptoms of climate change. As our
food, energy, health, education, economies, and financial systems show increasing signs of failing us, we
are being collectively called to harness our creativity and resources to take a major evolutionary leap.

Transitioning from self-destructive ways to life-affirming understandings, lifestyles, and systems is
indeed the great work of our times.

The looming question is, how can we reverse the downward spiral in which much of our world has
been caught?

One of the many blessings of our time is that there is a fast-growing global movement afoot, consisting
of many communities, businesses, not-for-profits, and governments, hard at work on this very question.
Their innovative efforts are already providing many success stories and inspiring new models to point to.
Neither creativity nor good intentions are lacking.

What has been sorely missing is an understanding of the important systemic causes of the challenges we
face, and a clearer sense of how fragmented efforts and experiments might evolve into comprehensive
solutions. The widespread deterioration of conditions that has occurred over the course of the last several
decades is bound to continue until and unless we can identify and effectively address the source of our
many concerns. To this end, there is at last some significant news.

A far better and more effective way to harness and direct our creativity and energy is now possible and
directly available to us. What is required of us is to start paying careful attention to a piece of the puzzle
that has been under the radar of the official and public debate: our monetary system.

Over the course of the past few decades, a quiet but significant transformation has been taking place
within the monetary realm. Thousands of initiatives from around the worldrun by villagers, nongovernmental organizations, small and medium-sized enterprises, multinationals, and governmentshave
each been rethinking money. They have made use of complementary currenciesmonetary initiatives that
do not replace but rather supplement the national currency systemto match unmet needs with unused
resources.

Among the almost inexhaustible range of vital concerns being addressed by new monetary initiatives let
us mention: social and ecological issues such as improved education, disease intervention, juvenile
delinquency, healthcare for the elderly, environmental cleanup, and city restoration; and commercial
applications such as job creation, loyalty mechanisms, stabilization of the business cycle, and more.

These initiatives burden no one and offer benefits to the whole of human society. These innovations do
not require raising taxes, the redistribution of wealth, bonds, charity, or loans from lending institutions or
government. Given what is at stake and what has already been achieved, it is encumbent upon us to at
least carefully consider what is now possible.

New Money for a New World is dedicated to pragmatic improvements in conditions through a greater
understanding of money, and through monetary initiatives that better serve the diverse and sometimes
divergent needs of each member of our global society and the living systems of this planet.

An Overview of New Money for a New World



The goal of each of the four parts of this book is to report, in as clear and concise a way as possible, the
insights and important options that are now available to us by rethinking money.

In Part IOur Money, Our Worldwe explore many of the features of todays monetary and banking
paradigms. The topics examined include:

1. the ways and means by which one city was able to tackle many of its concerns without having to
raise taxes, redistribute wealth, or seek outside assistance (Chapter OneA Tale of Two Cities);
2. the great mismatch between our money and our age (Chapter TwoWelcome to Moneyville);
3. critical issues facing our world and the monetary questions they pose (Chapter ThreeMegatrends
and Money);
4. long-held mysteries and some important agreements related to our money (Chapter FourA Money
Primer);
5. seemingly innocuous properties of our monetary system, particularly the feature of interest, and the
profound influence of the architecture of our money system upon society (Chapter FiveMoney is
Not Value-Neutral);
6. a little-known, historical Golden Age and its unusual monetary paradigm (Chapter SixBack to the
Future);
7. how our banking and monetary systems replicate beliefs, perceptions, and objectives of a former age
(Chapter SevenA Change of View);
8. traditional theories and assumptions about how economies work and the measurements used to gauge
their supposed health (Chapter EightEconomic Myopia);
9. how several communities were able to not only meet their needs but prosper during the depths of the
Great Depression, and the potential dire consequences of not heeding these vital monetary lessons
(Chapter NineLessons from a Depression);
10. how limited understandings regarding money impact reigning economic notions and policies
(Chapter TenThe Blind Spot).
In Part IINew Moneywe explore some of the many monetary tools and new economic understandings
available to us to help address the issues facing our world today. The topics explored include:

the unparalleled shift now taking place in society (Chapter ElevenGreat Change);
new economic insights derived from our understandings of natural ecosystems and other complex
flow systems (Chapter TwelveEfficiency, Resilience, and Money);
insights regarding what constitutes economic vitality, and its relationship to accepted notions of
economic growth (Chapter ThirteenSustainable Development);
two of the most ubiquitous complementary currencies in use today (Chapter FourteenLETS and
Time Dollars);
currency designs to help address specific social concerns (Chapter FifteenSocial-Purpose
Currencies);
currency designs to help meet the needs of business, especially small and medium-sized enterprises
(Chapter SixteenCommercial-Purpose Currencies);
a global reference currency design that addresses many of the limitations inherent in todays

international environment (Chapter SeventeenThe Terra, a Trade Reference Currency);


the likely consequences of addressing societal conditions within the framework of the existing bankdebt monetary paradigm (Chapter EighteenTwo Worlds).
In Part IIIThe Mystery of Moneywe explore the profound relationship between money and the human
psyche. The topics examined include:

patterns of emotions and actions that can be observed across time and cultures (Chapter Nineteen
Archetypes);
a fundamental archetype and its deep-rooted relationship to money (Chapter TwentyThe Missing
Archetype and Money);
the long and systematic repression of this same archetype (Chapter Twenty OneRepression of an
Archetype);
the manner in which repressed psychic energies manifest (Chapter Twenty TwoShadows);
the link between collective psychology, Taoism, and money systems (Chapter Twenty ThreeMoney
and the Tao);
the impact of the current monetary paradigm on society (Chapter Twenty FourConsequences of
Repression).
In Part IVMoney, Archetypes, and Past Ageswe explore the monetary systems, archetypal
constellations, and general conditions of several notable civilizations down through history. The topics
examined include:

medieval Western Europe viewed from an archetypal perspective (Chapter Twenty FiveCentral
Middle Ages Revisited);
an historical civilization whose unusual prosperity spanned more than 2,000 years (Chapter Twenty
SixDynastic Egypt);
Dynastic Egypt from an archetypal perspective (Chapter Twenty SevenDynastic Egypt Revisited);
the particular monetary and archetypal characteristics of an unusual culture that has endured for more
than 1,000 years and continues to this day (Chapter Twenty EightThe Balinese Exception);
a review of the findings and key conclusions of this work, and an invitation to continue our
exploration of money online (Chapter Twenty NineInvitation to a New World).
the vital role of monetary amendments as part of an ongoing process of societal maturation (Chapter
ThirtyThe Dynamics of Transformation and Money). This bonus chapter and additional supporting
materials are available online at our companions websites:
http://www.newmoneyforanewworld.com

and

http://www.lietaer.com

A number of chapters contain inserts that, while not essential to the argument at hand, offer supplementary
information that may be of interest to the reader.

PART I - OUR MONEY, OUR WORLD



Economics is about money, and thats why it is good.

~WOODY ALLEN

And money is about...what ?

CHAPTER ONE - A Tale of Two Cities



If the only tool you have is a hammer,

you tend to see every problem as a nail.

~ABRAHAM MASLOW

Garbage was a major problem in Curitiba, the capital of the southeastern state of Paran, Brazil.1 Its
urban population had mushroomed from 120,000 in 1942 to 2.3 million in 1997. Many of the inhabitants
lived in favelas, shantytowns made of cardboard and corrugated metal. Garbage collection trucks could
not enter these favelas as the streets were not wide enough. The garbage thus piled up and disease broke
out.

Jaime Lerner, who became mayor of Curitiba in 1971, did not have funds to apply customary solutions,
such as bulldozing the area or building new streets. Bond measures, further taxation, or federal assistance
were simply not options. Another way had to be found.

What Curitiba did have was an abundance of food, owing to the fertile lands and tropical climate of the
region. It also had a municipal bus system that was underutilized, with many favela residents unable to
afford public transportation. Mayor Lerner made use of these local resources to resolve urban issues and
transform Curitiba.

Large metallic bins were placed at the edge of the favelas. Anyone who deposited a bag full of
presorted garbage received a bus token. Those who collected paper and cartons were given plastic chits,
exchangeable for parcels of seasonal fresh fruits and vegetables. The bus tokens were also soon accepted
at local markets in exchange for food. A school-based garbage collection program was started as well
and supplied poorer students with notebooks. Tens of thousands of children responded by picking the
neighborhoods clean. In one three-year period, more than 100 schools traded 200 tons of garbage for 1.9
million notebooks. The paper-recycling component alone saved the equivalent of 1,200 trees each day!
The 62 poorer neighborhoods of Curitiba exchanged 11,000 tons of garbage for nearly a million bus
tokens and 1,200 tons of food. Parents also made use of the tokens to travel downtown, oftentimes to find
jobs. Other programs were created to finance the restoration of historical buildings, create green areas,
and provide housing, all by methods that placed little or no financial burden on the municipality.
Eventually, more than 70 percent of Curitiban households became involved in these programs.

The many initiativesenvironmental cleanup, city restoration, job creation, improved education,
disease intervention, hunger preventionwere each tackled without having to raise taxes, redistribute
wealth, issue bonds, rely on charity, or obtain loans from the federal government or organizations such as
the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund (IMF). The improvements burdened no one.
Everyone benefited.

The results in purely economic terms are worth noting. From 1975 to 1995, the Gross Domestic
Product (GDP) of Curitiba increased an average of 75 percent more than its parent state of Paran, and 48
percent more than the GDP of Brazil as a whole. The average Curitibano earned more than three times the
countrys minimum wage. If nontraditional monetary gains such as the exchange of garbage for provisions
are taken into consideration, the real total income for residents was at least 30 percent higher still. The

results in human termsin the renewal of dignity and hope for a better futurecan only be imagined.

Curitiba discovered a means by which to match unmet needs with unused resources. They did so by
making use of complementary currenciesmonetary initiatives that do not replace but rather supplement
the national currency system. This innovative approach provided much needed improvements to the local
economy. It enabled a developing and formerly impoverished city to empower itself and vastly improve
its conditions in the remarkable span of a single generation.

In 1990, Curitiba was honored with the highest award granted by the United Nations Environment
Program.

Growing numbers of concerned citizens and public officials find it increasingly doubtful that the
problems facing our communities, nations, and planet can be successfully addressed. The results achieved
by complementary monetary initiatives in Curitiba, however, as well as many other places around the
world suggest something quite different. Our current difficulties persist not because they are
insurmountable, but rather because we have focused on the symptoms rather than the systemic causes of
our many concerns. Most importantly, we have failed to more fully understand and make greater use of
one of the most powerful of all human creationsmoney.

To help illustrate what is taking place in our world, we offer a fictional absurdity, an allegorical place
called Hammerville.2

HAMMERVILLE

Hammerville derived its name from a peculiar oddity that distinguished it from other communities of its
time. For practically every application imaginablecutting, painting, cleaning, plumbing, building,
demolition, ploughing, harvesting, and so much elsethe hardworking people of Hammerville made
almost exclusive use of one tool: a hammer. It was the principal object in the hammer throw, hammer
bowl, and other popular sports. It was also a vital part of their cultural celebrations and the iconic symbol
of civic pride.

Over time, the hammer also became the most important mark of individual wealth. Although a few
hammer-dexterous individuals had the ability to use several hammers simultaneously, there was no
intrinsic need to own more than a few hammers. Nonetheless, it somehow came to pass that the more
hammers in ones possession, the higher ones standing in society became.

For a while, no one questioned the inherent limitations of their world. With few exceptions, if
something could not be built, fixed, or measured with a hammer, it was simply left undone. Screwdrivers,
ploughs, wrenches, and paintbrushes were nonexistent. Even the general concept of tool was not a part
of peoples reality. A hammer was a hammer and that was basically it. No other means existed to even
imagine, much less implement, options commonly available elsewhere.

Over time, Hammervilleans found themselves unable to cope. Their population grew, but no means
could be found to keep up with demands for sufficient housing, education, employment, healthcare, and a
host of other requirements. Conditions deteriorated, but no one could quite understand why. People
increasingly pointed the hammer of blame at one another. Some of the privileged hammer-rich questioned
the abilities of those less fortunate, and were, in turn, the subject of mounting resentment by growing
numbers of the hammer-less.

No one ever stopped to look at the limitations of the hammer itself. It was unthinkable that the most
important and almost exclusive object of so much good was simply not designed to address all of their
needs. Nor could this citizenry grasp the powerful link between their collective ignorance regarding tools,
the hammercentric ways in which they perceived themselves and their world, and what in fact they
believed to be possible or not. The good people of Hammerville were both defined and fated by the
limitations of their hammer-monopolized world, a world that despite all good intentions found itself in
peril.

Of course, the absurdities and collective lack of awareness of Hammervilleans could not possibly
occur in our world.

Or could they?

TWO WORLDS AND MONEY



This book recounts the story of two worlds, two paradigms. It offers a brief analysis of current conditions
and the logical outcome of attempting to solve existing problems using the same thinking that created many
of our concerns in the first place. The main body of this work, however, considers another prospect for
society and the systematic means by which it can be pragmatically realized.

This other world is one in which the long-term interests of humanity and the sustainability of our planet
balance the short-term interests of business and industry; where there is meaningful work for all and time
for ourselves, our families, and our communities; where the upbringing and education of our children and
quality care for our elders are realized and compensated for in equal measure to other forms of
employment so vital to society. This other world holds dear the diversity and sanctity of all life and the
life-affirming aspects of what it is to be fully human, and consequently, more humane.

The potential for just such a prospect is not only possible but is achievable within the span of a single
generation. Many of the elements required for these improvements already exist. Additionally, a wide
assortment of monetary tools similar to those used in Curitiba is readily available to us quickly, safely,
and inexpensively by way of a greater understanding of money.


The current monetary paradigm and its relationship to the critical issues of our day are examined in the
chapters that follow. We shall see that intentionally designed currencies can match many of the worlds
unmet needs by using the underutilized resources already at our disposal.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

Curitiba represents an important 25-year-old practical case study. It offers testimony that a dualcurrency approachone that uses both the traditional national currency and well-designed
complementary currenciescan successfully address a broad range of seemingly intractable issues
promptly and effectively by means that are non-punitive and of benefit to all. Other important case studies,
presented later in this work, show the broad range of applications made possible by use of these monetary
innovations.

The lack of awareness that defined and ultimately undermined Hammerville need not apply to us. But
we need to better understand moneyour hammerand how it is interwoven into every element of our
society.

CHAPTER TWO - Welcome to Moneyville



Our Age of Anxiety is, in great part, the result of trying to do todays jobs with yesterdays tools.

~Marshall McLuhan

We begin with this two-part, multitrillion-dollar question: How did a smart age like ours get into the mess
it now finds itself in, and what do we do to move forward? Consider the following.

Our achievements over the last century are without parallel. We have gone from the most rudimentary
understandings of genetics to mapping the entire human genome, from Morse code to binary code, from
horse and buggy to space exploration. We now have near-instant access to one another and more
information than all the universities and libraries down through the ages, combined!

Yet, while we can probe distant planets, we are threatened by a pollution mess on our own planet. Life
expectancy is greater than ever before, but retirement is increasingly problematic. We produce more than
enough food to feed the world, but too many go without. There is no end to the work that needs to be done,
with legions of willing, able people to do it. Nevertheless, we are plagued by a chronic scarcity of
gainful opportunities, made more dramatic still by financial crashes and chronic economic instability.

Though our many triumphs speak to a vast human potential, we currently find ourselves beset by vital
challenges that have thus far eluded the many attempts aimed at their resolution. In fact, despite some
breakthroughs and many valiant efforts in the public and private sectors, these challenges have escalated
in scope and severity with each passing decade. Why is this so?

The short answer is that it has something to do with money. Our plight is not, however, simply a matter
of the lack of money or the allocation of ever greater amounts of it. Trillions of dollars have been spent on
one issue after another, but have not, and cannot by themselves, stem the tide of continued deterioration of
our planet, or prevent the next downturn of the so-called business cycle. Our failed efforts are instead
linked to a collective lack of understanding regarding money and the use of a limited set of monetary
tools.

Sound vaguely similar to another place?

As absurd is it may at first seem, our postindustrial dilemma bears some similarity to the plight of
Hammerville. We too are confronted by issues that threaten us as never before. We too are baffled trying
to understand what is going on and what to do. We are engaged in short-term industrial-age practices that
persist despite mounting evidence of the dangers they pose to us all. In addition, we limit most of our
exhanges to the use of one tool that has become as important and ubiquitous in our monetized world as
hammers were in Hammerville.

We invite you to take an initial look at our accomplished yet troubled moment in time; a place that we
have come to think of as Moneyville.

THE NEW MONEY OF MONEYVILLE



Fish are not aware of water. This proverb speaks to the fact that some elements of our lives are everpresent but simply taken for granted. Such is the case with our world and money. Certainly, we pay
attention to how much money we have, how much more we need, and ways by which to try and obtain and
invest it. Rarely, however, do we stop to question the nature of money itself or the system by which it
functions. Money is simply, wellmoney. And we are all deeply immersed in its currents.

Money plays nearly as influential a role in Moneyville as hammers did in Hammerville, in more ways
than we might care to believe. It is at once one of the oldest, most pervasive, and influential of all humanmade creations. Yet, despite its enduring, prominent place in our world, money remains a mystery to
experts and laypeople alike.

No one actually knows for certain when money came into being. We do know that it predates the
written word and recorded history. One of the most celebrated economists of the 20th century, John
Maynard Keynes, pointed out:

Money, like certain other elements in civilizations, is a far more ancient institution than we were
taught to believe. Its origins are lost in the mists when the ice was melting, and may well stretch into
the intervals in human history of the inter-glacial periods, when the weather was delightful and the
mind free to be fertile with new ideasin the islands of the Hesperides or Atlantis or some Eden of
Central Asia.3

What is well established is that moneys influence has grown steadily over the centuries. Richard
Wagner, former president of the Institute of Certified Financial Planners, notes, Money is the most
powerful secular force within our world today.4 French monetary theorist, Jacques Rueff, goes a step
further, declaring, Money will decide the fate of mankind.5 Money is the principal means by which we
conduct business and interact with one another through countless daily exchanges of billions of dollars,
euros, and other national currencies. Todays global economy, the affairs of state, and our individual
survival all depend on money.

Yet, what do we actually know about this curious human creation? Where does it come from? Who
makes the rules? Why is it so hard to come by? Despite its role in our lives, most of us are simply baffled
by money. A deep collective blindness is at work that not only contributed to the demise of once mighty
Wall Street giants such as Lehman Brothers, but which threatens the fabric of modern society as never
before.

Consider, for instance, the gulf that divides our age and the type of money that is in use.

The Mismatch

For some obscure reason, few of the good citizens of Moneyville were ever made aware of a particular
disparity regarding our age and money. We are attempting to manage a host of 21st-century issues, while
the majority of the components that define our existing banking and monetary systems date back to a
former age.

The money that is in use today was actually designed in the 17th and 18th centuries, a mostly
preindustrial epoch untroubled by pollution, greenhouse effects, and overpopulation. The vast majority of
the worlds estimated 700 million people back then were farmers living in rural settings, who rarely
ventured far from their homes or villages, and whose economic activity consisted mostly of local barter
exchanges. Money was in limited use, especially in rural England, the country in which much of the
worlds current monetary paradigm originated.

But historical changes were beginning to take root. It was the dawn of the Industrial Revolution and
modern-day nation states. Both domestic and international commerce were on the rise, as were the
monetized transactions through which such commerce was facilitated. Whether by design or happenstance,
the monetary and banking systems that came into being back then reflected a new Modernist worldview,
and would become the most persuasive instruments of that ages key objectives: growth, competition,
nationalism, and industrialization.

Over the course of the next three centuries, virtually every nation on Earth would come to adopt the
same foundational tools that were built into those centuries-old systems. By performing their intended
functions, the banking and monetary systems facilitated the most extraordinary technological and industrial
achievements in all of history.

But todays dynamic, interdependent, 24/7, global village is vastly different from even a generation
ago, let alone centuries past. Many of the needs of society and our beleaguered natural environs are quite
different from any other known period of history. The finite set of tools that served so ably the ethos of
another age are far too limited in range and are simply not designed to address the requirements and
concerns of todays many diverse cultures, and the fusion of agrarian, industrial, and postindustrial
economies that together constitute our complex, interwoven, socioeconomic reality.

Yet, notwithstanding the great divide that sets our current world apart from centuries past, we continue
to employ almost exclusively the most persistent driver of the Industrial Ages valuesits monetary
system. This mismatch between our age and the ongoing monopoly of centuries-old money is at the core of
so many of our most important issues.

The following story helps illustrate what is now taking place today with regard to society and money.

THE MONEY GO-ROUND



A group of prominent citizens from a small town in Germany, which included the mayor, the head judge,
and a number of leading businessmen all dined together at a local restaurant. There was plenty of wine
with the meal, followed by after-dinner schnapps. It was well past midnight when the entourage finally
got up to leave, with everyone by then quite tipsy. But the festivities were not yet over.

The plaza just outside the restaurant was empty at that late hour, with a seasonal carnival then shut
down for the night. Nonetheless, one member of the inebriated group thought it would be good fun to take
a spin on the carnivals merry-go-round. He turned on the motor and leapt onto a chair. The others
followed suit.

The initial laughter soon ended, however, as one by one, each member of the group came to realize
their situation. The merry-go-rounds control button was now well out of reach, and no one could
dismount the ride without incurring serious injury.

The machine had been started easily, but the capacity to manage it was lost once it was in full swing.

Given the hour, the groups ongoing cries for help went unheard. It was not until after six oclock the
following morning that the local police and fire department were notified and the ordeal finally brought to
an end. But by then, one member of the group had died of a heart attack and three others were
unconscious. Following the incident, one of the survivors joined an obscure religious sect, while others
suffered psychological scars that lasted years.

The absurdity of this story is amplified by the fact that it is a true tale.6 For our purposes, it serves as a
metaphor for the state of the worlds current monetary system.

We are riding on a huge planetary machine that is on autopilot and accelerating out of control. Money
functions mostly without our awareness and in opposition to many of our current needs, placing each of us
and life on this planet increasingly at risk. Our collective unconsciousness with regard to money impedes
our ability to reach the stop button of this gigantic money-go-round, and has obscured our ability to
identify and address the root causes of some of our most serious concerns.

As mentioned, our troubles persist not because they are insurmountable, but rather because we are
treating symptoms instead of systemic causes and confining our efforts to the almost exclusive use of one
type of monetary toolnational currencies. Such currencies act as the monetary equivalent of a hammer,
and their exclusive use results in the persistence and escalation of the issues of our day.

Fortunately, there is another side to the tale of Moneyville, characterized instead by significant hope
and promise. Many new monetary tools are available to us today, made possible in large part by
thousands of communities around the world that are currently rethinking money. Like Curitiba, they are
finding innovative ways to match unmet needs with unused resources. In the process, they are helping the
rest of us to gain a greater understanding of money and its potential.

But before exploring what is possible in greater depth, we first need to better understand the
relationship between the issues of our time and the current monetary paradigm.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

Our present-day monetary system, in the form of a monoculture of national currencies, has not changed
essentially in centuries. This industrial-age paradigm continues to influence and dominate every important
aspect of our lives and the many personal and collective choices we makewhether we are aware of it
or not, whether we like it or not. Economists, financial experts, and laypeople alike have simply accepted
the de facto monopoly of this one type of money as if it were an immutable fact of life.

CHAPTER THREE - Megatrends and Money



The modern crises are, in fact, man-made and differ from many of their predecessors in that they can
be dealt with.

~REPORT TO THE CLUB OF ROME

There are a host of increasingly critical issues in Moneyville that require our attention. In ways that are
both obvious and obscure, each concern is related to money. We know, for example, that many
commercial practices, such as the clear-cutting of forests and unregulated pollution, are linked to longterm ecological consequences. We appreciate as well that issues such as unemployment, poverty, and the
challenges of eldercare are each linked to a chronic insufficiency of money.

Far less evident, however, is the connection between our vital concerns and the particular type of
monetary system in operation.

Examined below are five large-scale shifts in conditions of vital concern to society, hereafter referred
to as megatrends. These megatrends include: the age wave, the ecological credit crunch, the financial
divide, the job crisis, and economic instability. Each megatrend is followed by a money-related question
intended to encourage critical thought about the link between such matters and money.

In the examination of the following megatrends, we ask that the reader put on a special kind of lens that
allows for a journey less travelled. Certainly, the megatrends are of serious concern and if not dealt
with effectively, have the potential to cause irreversible damage. In this context, it is quite common to
view these global concerns as the enemy, intent on doing us harm. And like the chick below, we might
prefer to run for shelter.


These very same concerns, however, present us with a unique opportunity. Like taskmasters, they guide
us to places we would rather not explore. Though seemingly ominous, these megatrends oblige us to face

deeper insights and truths about ourselves and our ways of life. They also invite us to explore new
options in moving forward.

From this framework, the real enemies are not necessarily the problems, per se, but paradoxically our
very reluctance to face up to them and embrace the opportunity to transcend our imagined limitations and
grow. Such inquiry has led to profound insights and understandings about the influence of systems, and the
monetary system in particular, with the realistic potential to bring about a saner, more sustainable world.

The megatrends examined below are not intended as a comprehensive list of concerns, but are among the
most serious. Additionally, the data points cited below were last verified in September 2011. They do not
reflect the most current conditions but instead serve as markers to help indicate the general direction and
extent of change taking place in our time.

We start with the Age Wave, the slowest of these megatrends, but the one that is most inexorably
certain.

THE AGE WAVE



When Baron Otto von Bismarck set up Germanys first social insurance system in the 1870s, the
retirement age was established at 65. The catch was that the average life expectancy at that time was only
48 years. A mere two percent of the population would be left alive to enjoy their golden years.7 It was
likely inconceivable back then that such a social security plan could ever pose a burden to the state.

For 99 percent of humanitys existence, life expectancy has averaged about 18 years.8 This is obviously
no longer the case. One remarkable consequence of improved medicine and living conditions over the last
century is that two-thirds of all people who have ever reached the age of 65 are alive today.9 Within the
30 developed member nations of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD),
one out of every 11 people in the 1960s was 65 or older.10 Today, that number has increased to one out of
every seven people. By 2030, the proportion of elders living in the OECD is expected to swell to one out
of every four.11

While one can hope that this global greying trend will transform the incoming Information Age into an
Age of Wisdom, sobering economic issues must first be addressed.

One such issue is unfunded liabilitiesbenefits earned by todays workers but for which no reserves
exist. Funds that were supposed to be secure for future retirement repayments by the U.S. Social Security
system and other pension plans, have been paid out to those already in retirement and may not be fully
recovered. Unfunded liabilities have already accumulated to more than $35 trillion in OECD countries
alone. Adding healthcare to these costs could easily double that figure.12

Meanwhile, healthcare is becoming increasingly expensive. In 2008, as the global recession deepened,
the cost of total national health expenditures was expected to rise 6.9 percenttwice the rate of
inflation.13 At current rates, it is estimated that retiring couples in the United States will need at least
$250,000 in savings just to pay for the most basic medical coverage.14 As the availability of funds
continues to decline, the pressure on retirees and on society-at-large to assist them becomes ever more
difficult.

There are no historical precedents that we can draw from to handle the issues raised by this Age Wave.

The following hard money question synthesizes the dilemma that this Age Wave presents: How will
society provide the elderly with the money and resources needed to match their longevity?

THE ECOLOGICAL CREDIT CRUNCH



The Earths natural systems provide many products and processes vital to our economies and lives.
Increasingly, however, the resources that enable these critical life-support functions are being consumed
faster than they can be replenished. Human demand on the planets living resourcesour ecological
footprintnow exceeds natures regenerative capacity by nearly 30 percent.15

The World Wildlife Fund (WWF) reports, Just as reckless spending is causing a recession, so
reckless consumption is depleting the worlds natural capital to a point where we are endangering our
future prosperity.16

Over the past 150 million years, the rate of speciationthe creation of new speciesis estimated to
have either equalled or exceeded the rate of extinction. Humanitys impact over the past two centuries,
particularly recent decades, has turned that upside down. Up to 150 species are now becoming extinct
every day.17

Human encroachment is also shrinking the worlds rainforests. According to the Food and Agriculture
Organization of the United Nations (FAO), Deforestation continues at an alarming rate of about 13
million hectares a year,18 an area half the size of Great Britain. By way of an escalating feedback
mechanism, tree loss both contributes to and is exacerbated by other ecological concerns, including
biodiversity loss, soil erosion, and rising temperatures. The UN Climate Change Conference in Bali 2007
warned, If we lose the forests, we lose the fight against climate change.19

Regarding climate change, global surface temperatures are rising. According to NASAs Goddard
Institute for Space Studies, the decade from 2000 through 2010 was the hottest on record.20

The financial costs of climate change are staggering. Some 40 percent of world trade is based on
biological products and processes.21 A report commissioned by the British government estimates that by
2050 climate change will account for a yearly loss of at least five percent in global growth ($2.2 trillion
at current values). If the environmental, health-related, and known subsidiary effects of rising
temperatures are taken into account, the losses could amount to as much as 20 percent of annual global
GDP ($9 trillion).22 Even after tallying the total insurance losses from September 11, 2001, the worlds
largest reinsurance company, Munich Re, stated that its deepest concern for the future was not terrorism
but rather climate change.23

Paul Volcker, formerly chairman of the Federal Reserve and head of President Obamas Economic
Recovery Advisory Board, warned, If you don't take action, you can be sure that the economy will go
down the drain in the next 30 years. What may happen to the dollar and what may happen to growth in
China or whatever, pale into insignificance compared with the question of what happens to this planet
over the next 30 or 40 years if no action is taken [on climate change].24

The UN Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) has concluded that most temperature
increases since the mid-20th century are very likely due to the increase in human-generated greenhouse
gases.25 Though some debate still continues, the IPCCs findings are supported by the national academies
of science of every major industrialized nation.26 Most other ecological damage is probably linked to
human activity as well.


As is well documented, whenever serious financial interests are involved, calls for reform hit the
proverbial brick wall. Financial markets focus on the next quarters results, and even if a particular CEO
were to advocate longer-term priorities at the expense of immediate results, he or she would be
admonished or removed from office. Only when we have resolved the next money question is there any
real chance to address the ecological credit crunch in a timely and systematic way.

Our bottom-line money question here is: How can we resolve the conflict between short-term
financial interests and long-term sustainability?

THE FINANCIAL DIVIDE



The divide between the haves and the have-nots is growing worldwide. This disparity is now greater than
at any time since the beginning of the 20th century. A 2005 UN report estimated that the 50 richest people
in the world were earning more than the 416 million poorest.27

In the United States, most of the tremendous wealth generated in the past few decades has gone to a
very small percentage of the very rich. Of the surplus of over a trillion dollars generated between 1979
and 1999, 95 percent went to a mere five percent of Americans.28 The financial wealth of the top one
percent of U.S. households now exceeds that of the lower 95 percent combined.29 The pay gap between
top executives and average employees in the 365 largest U.S. companies soared from 42:1 in 1980 to
531:1 in 2000.30 And while the average income has increased by 9 percent for those in the top fifth of the
pay scale, it has instead decreased by 2.4 percent for those in the bottom fifth.31

Families are increasingly hard hit. After 50 years of work, the average American family manages to
amass savings of just $2,300.32 This is despite the fact that the average American worked two weeks
more in 2000 than a decade earlier. Increasingly, both parents must now be employed. In 1968, only 38
percent of married mothers worked for pay, while todays figure is more than 70 percent.33 Though such
data reflects societal changes and improved job opportunities for women, it also indicates the added
demands on families.

Wealth concentration is not isolated to America. Indonesias 15 richest families hold 61.7 percent of all
stock market holdings. The comparable figure for the Philippines is 55.1 percent, and for Thailand, 53.3
percent.34 Meanwhile, 80 countries have lower per capita incomes than a decade ago.

The outcome of this inequality is tangible: Of the worlds total population, 65 percent have never
made a phone call; 40 percent have no access to electricity. Americans spend more on cosmetics, and
Europeans more on ice cream than it would cost to provide schooling and sanitation for the two billion
people who currently go without.35 Three billion people presently live on $2 or less per day, and 1.3
billion of those get by on $1 or less.36 Approximately 1.2 billion do not have enough food or protein, and
between 2 and 3.5 billion do not get enough vitamins or minerals to remain healthy.37

The money question here is: How will we address economic inequality globally when even
industrialized nations are finding it increasingly difficult to provide for their own citizens?

THE JOB CRISIS



The world economy has been dramatically affected by todays ongoing economic downturn, with loss of
jobs an especially destabilizing factor. In January 2009, U.S. employers slashed 598,000 jobs, the biggest
monthly loss in 34 years.38 In Japan, unemployment jumped from 3.9 to 4.4 percent in November 2008
the biggest monthly increase in almost 42 years.39 In China, 20 million workers lost their jobs in 2008.40
The UN International Labour Organization (ILO) estimated that up to 51 million jobs would be shed and
push an additional 200 million workers into extreme poverty in 2009, mostly in developing economies.41

The global struggle for jobs is, however, not new. Former UN Secretary General Kofi Annan reported
in 2006 that at least 576 million able and willing people worldwide were out of work or chronically
underemployed, and were unable to escape extreme poverty.42 According to former Wall Street Journel
associate editor Paul Craig Roberts, Americans had already lost more jobs in the years preceding the
subprime mortgage debacle than at any time since the Great Depression.43 Citing the U.S. Bureau of Labor
Statistics, the New York Times reported that, the American economy has added virtually no jobs in the
private sector over a 10-year period from July 1999 to July 2009.44

The competition for jobs in the United States is expressed as a gradual degradation of employment
conditions. U.S. labor productivity, for instance, was up 1.8 percent in 2007, yet inflation-adjusted wages
were down 0.8 percent in that same year.45 According to the ILO, the average American worked 1,978
hours in 2000, up from 1,942 hours in 1990. This represents almost a week of extra work annually, within
a decade.46 Workaholism has become, for many, a tacit requirement for keeping ones job.47

One telling sign of the U.S. job crisis is the growing burdens that workers are expected to bear.
Corporations are scaling back on benefits such as health coverage and pensions. The average household
income is now barely higher than it was in 1973, while the volatility of earnings and financial risks have
soared. Unlike Europe, where job losses show up in raw unemployment numbers, U.S. indicators manifest
through what Yale political scientist Jacob Hacker calls, the great risk shift,48 in which new levels of
jeopardy and compromise are being placed onto workers without commensurate increases in income.
Even those families in which both parents are working are often one serious incidenta medical bill or
factory closureaway from disaster.49

The future looms uncertain. Though the Information Revolution offers much promise, it has not yet
shown any indication of leading to a postindustrial global economy that will provide sufficient job
opportunities for the 7.5 billion forecast by 2020, much less the current population.50

Jobless growthincreased overall earnings without a proportionate expansion of employmentis not
merely a forecast for major corporations, but has become an established fact and in many instances a
desired goal. Political and economic columnist William Greider observes, The worlds 500 largest
corporations have managed to increase their production and sales by 700 percent over the past 20 years,
while at the same time reducing their total workforce.51

Economists will correctly argue that improvements in productivity, which then lead to job losses in one
sector, tend to create jobs in other areas. In the long run, therefore, technological change does not much
matter to overall employment. These new technologies, however, are coming upon us faster and faster and
necessitate fundamentally new sets of skills and a massive displacement of jobs. If the change is rapid

enough, these job dislocations can be just as disruptive as permanent job losses.

Nobel laureate Wassily Leontieff has summarized the overall process as follows: The role of humans
as the most important factor of production is bound to diminish in the same way that the role of horses in
agricultural production was first diminished and then eliminated by the introduction of tractors.52 While
we could let the horses die out peacefully, what will we do with people?

The money question here is: How can we provide a living to additional billions of people when tens
of millions are out of work and our technologies make jobless growth a clear possibility?

THE BANKING/MONETARY CRISIS



Our banking and monetary systems are in a state of great instability. Though the economic crisis of 2008
2009 was the most severe disruption in decades, it was certainly not the only one. In just one 25-year
period (19711996), the World Bank identified 169 monetary crises and 93 banking crises, which hit 130
different countries.53 These figures do not include more recent and serious troubles, such as the Asian
crisis (1997), the Russian crisis (1998), the Argentinian crisis (2001), and the banking crisis of 20072008. In 2003, Nobel Laureate Joseph Stiglitz stated, Something is wrong with the global financial
system. International financial crises or near-crises have become regular eventsThe question is not
whether there will be another crisis, but where it will be.54

One systemic cause for this fragility is the global casino of unprecedented proportions that currently
determines our moneys value. Daily turnover in foreign exchange in 2010 was $4 trillion.55 This amount
is more than triple that of 2001 and excludes the large amount of derivative trading.56 Nearly 96 percent
of these transactions are purely speculativethey do not relate to the real economy or reflect the global
movements or exchanges of actual goods and services.57 Functioning primarily as a speculative market,
currency exchange is driven not only by tangible economic news but also by mere rumor and conjecture.

The economic pinch is being felt worldwide and by all sectors of the economy. Russian President
Dmitry Medvedev noted correctly that: Failure by the biggest financial firms in the world to adequately
take risk into account, coupled with the aggressive financial policies of the biggest economy in the world,
have led not only to corporate losses. Most people on the planet have become poorer.58

According to the U.S. Federal Reserve, 2008 saw a decline of $11.2 trillion in U.S. households net
worth (the difference between assets and liabilities). It was the sixth straight quarterly decline since the
peak in the second quarter of 2007 at $64.4 trillion.59 Meanwhile, home equity fell to 46.2 percent of
market value, the lowest level on record.60

The net effect of ongoing financial crises is the rapid shrinkage of the middle class. A few very rich
individuals are left at the top of the economic heap, with most others nearing or already in poverty. This
was the case with the Asian, Russian, and Argentinean crises, and could also occur in the United States
and elsewhere.


A more in-depth analysis related to the financial crisis is presented later in this work. Suffice it to say
here that given the key role of money in our world, disturbances to the banking and monetary sector
adversely impact the whole of society and exacerbate the megatrends. Downturns affect jobs, health
coverage, pension plans, and our ability to address a host of socioeconomic and environmental issues.

The last money question is straightforward: How can we better prepare for or actually prevent future
economic and monetary crises?

To help illustrate why our megatrends have thus far resisted efforts aimed at their resolution, we offer the
following parallel from the pages of medical history.

A MEDICAL ANALOGY

The emergence of our monetary paradigm occurred at a time when the medical treatment of choice for the
prevention and treatment of illness and disease was bloodlettingthe removal of often-copious amounts
of blood from patients. Though actually harmful to patients in the majority of cases, bloodletting remained
the most common medical practice from antiquity up until the late 19th century. When, for example,
George Washington came down with a throat infection, nearly four pounds of his blood were removed. It
was far more likely the treatment and not the illness that contributed most to his demise.

The practice of bloodletting and the many notions that justified it, as well as the explanations that were
offered time and again for a patients inevitable decline, went unchallenged by one generation after
another for the better part of 2000 years. Notwithstanding the brilliance of the theories in support of this
practice and the physicians that espoused them, both theory and practitioner were mistaken. But in the
absence of bacteriology, immunology, and other common understandings available to us today, this flawed
medical procedure had the appearance of certitude and managed to endure for millennia.

Our megatrends persist not because they are intractable but, once again, because we are using a very
limited set of monetary tools that were put in place by another age.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

Our ineffectiveness in the face of global challenges is not an expression of the intractability of climate
change, job losses, or other pressing megatrends. The persistence of such issues is instead related to our
continued inability, so far, to identify and address their root causes, and in particular, to more fully grasp
the link between so many vital concerns and money.

No matter how sincere the desire or how determined the effort, we simply cannot expect our
difficulties to disappear until and unless we understand the functional dynamics of the current monetary
system.

CHAPTER FOUR - A Money Primer



Money is like an iron ring we put through our nose. It is now leading us wherever it wants. We just
forgot that we are the ones who designed it.

~MARK KINNEY

If you find yourself confused about money, take considerable comfort in the fact that you are not alone.
John Maynard Keynes once quipped: I know of only three people who really understand money: a
professor at another university, one of my students, and a rather junior clerk at the Bank of England.61 A
prudent man, he didnt name them.

If the Great Recession has assured us of anything, it is the extent to which Keynes assessment still runs
true. Most of us, from leading economists and financial wizards to the average layperson, have never been
properly introduced to money. Given what is at stake today, it is high time and to the benefit of all to put
an end to this perennial mystery.

The following primer provides an overview of the basics of our modern-day monetary system.

THE MYSTERY OF MONEY



Every modern society, regardless of its cultural or political background, has accepted the current
monetary system. When the French and Russian revolutions overthrew the established order in their
countries (in 1786 and 1917, respectively), they changed just about everything, save for their currency.
Each society completely rebuilt its legal system. The French overhauled their entire classification of
measurements by creating the metric system, and even tried to change the calendar. The Russians threw
out the very concept of private ownership and nationalized all their banks and corporations. Nonetheless,
the monetary system remained exactly as before, with only one cosmetic differencethe bills were now
adorned with new mottoes and heroes. When Maos communist takeover occurred in China, and when
more than 100 colonial countries gained their independence over the past half century, the same
phenomenon occurred, that is, each simply copied the now-standardized national currency system.

Little understood to this day is that virtually all national currencies operational in our world
regardless of their country of issuance; their designation as dollars, euros, or pesos; or their material
composition, shape and particular motifsare each the same type of money.

The U.S. executive director to the IMF in the Clinton administration, Karin Lissakers, offered this
revealing definition: Money is magic. Central bankers are magicians. Like all magicians, they dont like
to show their tricks.62 Was she referring to real magic or simple parlor tricks? The answer is both.

Magic and mystery have surrounded money throughout its long evolution. For millennia, the magic was
religious in nature. Now high priests of business, wielding impenetrable scientific equations, perform the
magic using an intentionally cryptic language. William Greider, in his aptly named book on the Federal
Reserve, Secrets of the Temple, wrote: Like the temple, the Fed did not answer to the people, it spoke
for them. Its decrees were cast in a mysterious language people could not understand, but its voice, they
knew, was powerful and important.63

A congressional hearing with former chairman of the U.S. Federal Reserve Alan Greenspan, for
instance, had as much ritual and ambiguity as did the oracles of Delphi in ancient Greece, as reflected in
this typical Greenspan witticism: If I seem unduly clear to you, you must have misunderstood what I
said.64 It was only after his retirement that the chairmans own lack of clarity was revealed. Speaking
before the U.S. Congress in October 2008, Greenspan conceded his shocked disbelief regarding the
role that lending institutions, deregulation, and other policies played in contributing to the financial crisis
of 20082009.65

What is Money?

It is common to think of money in terms of its material representations. Down through the ages, money has
appeared to be a thingin fact, an incredible variety of things. Monetary historian Glyn Davies created a
complete alphabet with a selection of objects that have represented money in the past, starting with amber,
beads, and cowries, and ending with wampum, yarns, and zappozats (decorated axes).66

A simple thought experiment, however, helps distinguish money from other things. Assume you are
stranded alone on a deserted island. If you had a thing, say a knife, it is still useful as a knife. Yet, if you
had a million dollars in whatever formcash, gold coins, credit cards, or even zappozatsit becomes
merely paper, metal, plastic, or whatever. It no longer functions as money.

Events in recent decades have made further evident the nonmaterial nature of money. In 1971, the
United States ceased to define the value of the dollar in relation to the value of gold. Since then, the dollar
has represented a promise from the U.S. government to redeem the dollarbut with what? Another
dollar! At least when the dollar was backed with gold, it could more easily be assumed to have some
material value.

Money often appears to possess magical properties. Consider, for instance, that no self-respecting
magicians routine is complete without a decent disappearing act, a feat that money performs in a rather
spectacular fashion, especially of late! Once upon a time, when money was mostly gold and silver coins,
banks started issuing pieces of paper. These papers were simply receipts indicating how much of the
precious metal was being stored, and where. The disappearing act has since become increasingly more
sophisticated as paper money rapidly dematerializes into binary bits in the computers of bankers, brokers,
and financial institutions. There is now serious talk that it could all soon disappear into the virtual world.
Perhaps when the last dollar, euro, or yen has evaporated into the electronic ethers, the nonmaterial nature
of money will be understood.

In short, although money has taken many material forms throughout history, money is not a thing.

What, then, is money?

Money may be defined as an agreement, within a community, to use some standardized item as a
medium of exchange.67

As an agreement, money inhabits the same space as other social constructs, like marriage or lease
agreements. These constructs are real, even if they exist only in peoples minds. A monetary agreement
can be made formally or informally, freely or by coercion, consciously or unconsciously. Most people do
not consciously agree to use dollars or pesos, nor do we consider their nature. We just use them and in so
doing, automatically enter into an unspoken agreement with all others with whom we conduct business.

A monetary agreement is only valid within a given community. Some monetary agreements are
operational among only small groups of friends like chips used in card games, or within a larger
community like the citizens of a particular nation, or for restricted periods of time like the cigarette
medium of exchange among frontline soldiers during World War II. A community can be geographically
disparate, such as Internet users, and can include large segments of the globe, as with the case of the U.S.
dollar in its role as an international reference currency.


The key function that transforms a chosen object into money is its role as a medium of exchange for the
trade of goods and services. Other functions of money include its role as a unit of account, that is, a
standard numerical unit capable of measuring the value of goods and services; a store of value that can be
reliably saved, stored, and retrieved; and finally, especially of late, as a tool for speculation. Not all
currencies, however, necessarily serve all of these features.68

In summary, the magic of money is bestowed on something when a given community agrees to use it as
a medium of exchange. Conventional money and the monetary system are therefore not de facto realities
like air or water, but are choices like social contracts or business agreements. As such, they are subject to
review and amendment.

Another long-standing mystery is how and where our money is made.

MONEY CREATION

When asked why he robbed banks, American criminal-celebrity Willie Suttons reputed reply was,
Because thats where the money is. To better appreciate our agreements about money, it is first
necessary to understand the banking system, not because that is where money is kept, but rather because it
is where money is actually created.

Origins of the Western Banking System



During the Late Middle Ages, gold and silver coins were established forms of money. Those most
qualified to check the purity of these coins were the goldsmiths, who, coincidentally, also owned
strongboxes to protect against thieves. It thus became a prudent practice to give ones excess coins to the
goldsmith for safekeeping, who would issue a receipt for the coins and charge a small fee for the service.

When money was needed, owners could cash in the receipt, and the goldsmith would pay out the coins.
It soon became more convenient to settle an account by paying with the receipt instead. If the goldsmith
was known to be a trustworthy fellow, why risk moving the coins physically? The goldsmiths receipts
thus became a promise of payment. Anyone who accepted such a receipt was implicitly entering into an
agreement with the goldsmith. This was the origin of modern-day paper money.

In time, a few enterprising goldsmiths observed that the bulk of the coins stayed put in their strong
boxes. Depositors would rarely if ever retrieve all their coins at the same time. The goldsmiths could thus
issue receipts in excess of the gold coins stored on behalf of clients, and increase their income by lending
out money without having to increase actual reserves.

Hence, there was a gradual shift from money based on commodities such as gold or silver to money
based on credit or loans in the form of paper receipts. The same basic arrangement exists to this day, with
one major difference being that banks replaced the goldsmiths. Our lexicon reminds us of this link. The
transactions between goldsmiths and their clients took place on Italian benches, or bancos, the origin of
the word bank.69

European banking and the credit-based monetary system were thus simultaneously born in 13th-century
Italy. Many of the key ingredients were already in place: paper money as the counterpartys liability, the
importance of a good reputation for that counterparty, and the ability of the bankers to create more money
than the deposits they held in reserve. Today this latter process is called the fractional reserve system.

The remaining elements of todays banking system would be established several centuries later in preVictorian England.

Our Monetary Agreements



The late 1600s saw the dawn of the Industrial Revolution and the creation of modern-day nation states.
These developments required substantial resources, including more sophisticated types of investments
and monetary agreements. Thus, in exchange for a commitment to provide loans whenever governments
needed money, banks secured the exclusive right to create paper money as legal tender, that is, as the
currency accepted by government in payment for taxes.70

The longest surviving agreement of this kind originated in 1668 with the license of the Bank of the
Estates of the Realm, Swedens central bank (now known as the Riksbank). Two decades later, the Bank
of England was founded on a similar model, from where it spread around the world.71 According to
economist John Kenneth Galbraith, the Bank of England is in all respects to money as St. Peters is to the
Faith. And the reputation is deserved, for most of the art as well as much of the mystery associated with
the management of money originated there.72

The deal struck between the banks and government, in effect to this day, entitles banks to create new
money for the deposits they receive. The new money is generated in the form of a loan to customers of up
to 90 percent (a fraction) of the value of the deposit (held in reserve); hence the name fractional reserve
system.73 That new loansay, a mortgage to buy a houseusually results another deposit somewhere in
the banking system, in this case by the seller of the house. The bank receiving that next deposit is, in turn,
entitled to create a new loan for yet another 90 percent of that deposit, and the cascade continues from
deposit to loan to deposit again and again throughout the banking system. This money alchemy is one of
the most arcane secrets of our monetary system (see insert).

Money Alchemy

Modern money alchemy is officially called the fractional reserve multiplier. It starts with the
injection of say, 100 million units of high-powered money into the banking system by the central
bank of a nation, which issues a loan to pay for government bills for said amount. These funds are
then deposited in the banking system by the recipient, which enables the receiving bank to lend out
90 million units (90 percent of the original 100 million units), while the other 10 million remain on
deposit as sterile reserves).


The new loan for 90 million units will, in turn, lead to another deposit for that amount somewhere else,
enabling the next receiving bank to provide another loan for 81 million (which again represents 90
percent of the deposit), and so forth. This is how the original 100 million units will, after many iterations,
generate 900 million units of additional credit money as it flows through the banking system.

This convoluted mechanism is the end result of the deal struck between banks and governments. It is the
reason why money ultimately involves the entire banking system, and helps explain how money and debt
are literally two sides of the same coin.

Note that this entire money-creation process hinges upon loans. If all debts were repaid, bank money
would simply disappear! This is so because the entire process of money creation, as illustrated above,
would reverse itself. This process of paying off all loans (on the left side of figure 4.1) would
automatically use up all of the deposits (on the right side). Even the central banks high-powered money
would evaporate if the government were able to repay its debts.

This money-creation process is one of the more significant yet least understood aspects of the current
monetary paradigm. With our money set up as loans, we are all debtors, indebted to those who create and
loan us moneythe banking system. The implications of this money-creation scheme are profound and
far-reaching, as is examined in the next chapter.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

Magic and mystery have surrounded money throughout its long evolution. Given moneys key role in
society today, it is vitally important that we become as familiar as possible with this all-important human
creation. The first step is to understand that money is an agreement, and as such is open to amendment.

The current agreements we have regarding our monetary and banking systems were made in late 16thcentury England. The banks were given the right to create new money from the deposits they received,
which is now commonly known as the fractional reserve system. In this money-creation process, almost
all of our money is debt money, derived from loans made by our banking system. This arrangement, this
agreement, was made centuries ago in a very different place and time and under very different conditions.
Is it possible that there are other types of money better suited to manage todays challenges?

CHAPTER FIVE - Money Is Not Value Neutral



The most powerful force in the universe is compound interest.

~ATTRIBUTED TO ALBERT EINSTEIN

There is a long-held assumption in economics that money is value neutral, that is, money is simply a
passive medium of exchange that affects neither the transaction nor the nature of the relationships among
its users. This assumption is closely related to another traditional notion,economic man, which claims
that people invariably act with perfect rationality regarding economic decision-making in such a way that
maximizes their personal utility or wellbeing.

It should be noted, however, that these notions date back to the 18th century, before the advent of
discoveries regarding the human unconscious, and much of our current understanding regarding behavioral
and social sciences. These assumptions are rooted in a worldview that sought to fashion economics and
much of society along the lines of Newtonian physics, and which held that the same order and
predictability that defined plantary orbits would explain human behavior and investment patterns.

We now know that attempts to understand money and other complex socioeconomic phenomena through
a mechanistic, value-neutral lens are inherently misguided. The countless instances of irrational
exuberance and the boom-and-bust manias that have plagued our economies for centuries contradict the
very idea of economic man. Likewise, moneys supposed value neutrality is challenged by ample
evidence showing that different types of monetary systems promote distinctly different values and have
uniquely influenced societal behavior throughout history.

One of the key assertions of this work is that our money is value-nonneutral.

Money is a major determinant in the nature of our exchanges and the relationships among currencys
users. Each of moneys constituent parts, from the manner by which money is created, to whether or not a
currency bears interest, strongly influences our behavior patterns and plays a determinant role in shaping
the kind of economy and society in which we live.

All national currencies have the following key characteristics that persist as unquestioned features of
conventional money:

geographical attachment to a nation-state;
creation out of nothingfiat money;
issuance through bank debt
incurrence of interest.
Below, we examine how these seemingly innocuous components of our monetary system wields a
profound influence upon each and every one of us and on society at large.

NATIONAL CURRENCIES

National currencies have proven to be a highly effective means of strengthening national identity, as they
facilitate economic interactions with fellow citizens rather than with foreigners. Economist Charles
Handy explains moneys impact on identification within a given community: A common currency
translates into a common information system, so that its inputs and outputs can be measured and compared
across the parts.74 Money draws an information border between us and them, making tangible
boundaries that would otherwise be visible only in an atlas, reinforcing unity within the confines of a
nation-state.

During the breakup of the Soviet Union, for example, one of the first acts by each of the newly
independent republics was the issuance of their own national currency. The euro, the single currency that
officially replaced a dozen national European currencies, had as one of its principal aims the creation of a
European supranational consciousness and unity.

While it might be difficult today to imagine any currency other than those issued on a national or
supranational level, the vast majority of historical currencies were actually privately issued by local
rulers.

FIAT MONEY AND BANK DEBT



The word fiat is found in the Latin version of the Bible. According to Genesis, Fiat Lux(Let Light Be)
were the first words pronounced by God. The next sentence states, And light was, and He saw it was
good. Fiat implies the godlike ability to create something out of nothing (ex nihilo), through the power of
the Word.

All conventional national currencies in the world today are fiat currencies. They are created by an
authority that declares a particular medium of exchange as acceptable in payment of taxesthat is, as
valid legal tender. As we have seen, these fiat currencies are created as bank debt, under the hierarchical
authority of a national central bank.75

The convoluted bank-debt, money-creation process described earlier resolves the apparent
contradiction between two principal goals of pre-Victorian England: creating and supporting the nationstate on the one hand, while relying on private initiative and competition on the other. The monetary
system provides a smooth way to privatize the creation of a national currencytheoretically a public
functionvia the private banking system, while simultaneously maintaining pressure on individual banks
to compete for deposits.

Economists John Jackson and Campbell R. McConnell summarize an important aspect of bank debt and
fiat monetary systems: Debt-money derives its value from its scarcity relative to its usefulness.76 In
other words, money must be kept artificially in shorter supply than the need for it. It is this built-in
scarcity that keeps everyone doing what they must to obtain this vitally important commodity. From a
banking perspective, failure to maintain this scarcity results in inflation and even hyperinflation, and
erodes a currencys value.

The necessity of managing scarcity is one reason why todays monetary system is not self-regulating,
but instead requires central banks supervision. Central banks also compete among themselves to keep
their own currencies in short supply, so that the relative value and scarcity of their currencies are
maintained internationally. They accomplish this by raising interest rates whenever they need to tighten the
money supply, thereby making it more expensive to borrow.

Among its many profound impacts upon society, this artificially-maintained scarcity creates strong
incentives to compete rather than cooperate.

INTEREST

Though loans and interest likely date to pre-urban societies, the first written evidence of interest goes
back to ancient Sumer where it was known as ms, which also meant a lamb. This followed from the
practice by which, in return for permitting a flock of sheep to graze on ones property, the landowner had
the right to choose a lamb born from that flock. This denotes the original relationship between loans,
interest, and rural produce.77 According to Stephen Zarlenga, Director of the American Monetary Institute,
loans were made in seed grains, animals, and tools to farmers. Since one grain of seed could generate a
plant with over 100 new grain seeds, after the harvest farmers could easily repay the grain with interest
in grain.78

But what will an ounce of silver or gold generate? Once interest was applied to money, a fundamental
debate arose that has continued to this very day. One of the central areas of concern is how much interest
should be applied to a loan.

Interest and Usury



While usury is today considered an excessive interest rate, it was formerly defined as charging any
interest on money. The practice of charging interest on money was not officially sanctioned in the West
until the reign of Englands King Henry VIII. He legalized interest in 1545 following his break with the
Roman Church. Up until that schism, all three religions of the Book (Judaism, Christianity, and Islam)
prohibited usury (see insert).79

Usury and Religion

It is written in the Hebrew Scriptures: Unto thy brother thou shalt not lend upon usury, that the Lord
thy God may bless thee in all that thou settest thine hands to (Deuteronomy 23:20). Islam is even
more universal in its condemnation: What ye put out as usury to increase it with the substance of
others, shall have no increase from God (Koran Sura 30:38).
Since the modern monetary system evolved predominantly under Christian influence, it is this
religions changing views of usury over time that merits particular attention. The denunciation of
usury as a mortal sin was one of the most persistent dogmas of the Catholic Church. Clement of
Alexandria, an early church father, specified in his Stromata, Chapter XVIII, The law prohibits a
brother from taking usury; designating as a brother not only him who is born of these same parents,
but also one of the same race and sentiments.80
The First Council of Carthage (345 CE) and the Council of Aix (789 CE) declared it to be
reprehensible even for laymen to make money by lending at interest. The Canonical Laws of the
Middle Ages absolutely forbade the practice.81 The Council of Vienne (1311 CE) went so far as to
declare that those who maintained that there was no sin in demanding usury, should themselves be
punished as heretics.
The original doctrine against usury was finally questioned within the Catholic Church itself in
1822. The case involved a woman from Lyons, France, who was refused absolution unless she
returned the interest she had earned. Clarification was requested from Rome, which responded: Let
the petitioner be informed that a reply will be given [to] her question when the proper time comes
Meanwhile she may receive sacramental absolution, if she is fully prepared to submit to the
instructions of the Holy See. A forthcoming resolution was promised again in 1830 and for a third
time in 1873. This promised clarification never came.
Thus, the sin of usury, which was never officially repealed by the Church, was simply forgotten.82

Interest and Lending



Interest serves key functions during the lending process. Researcher Andrew Lowd points to three factors
for reasonable interest rates: default protection, inflation, and opportunity cost.83

Default Protection. Interest protects lenders from potential loan defaults. Known as risk premium,
the interest in such cases acts as a fair precaution to ensure that the lender receives back at least the
amount lent out to borrowers.

If, for example, 105 loans of $1,000 each are made, but only 100 are repaid, $5,000 is, in effect, lost.
Not knowing which of the borrowers will default, the lender spreads the risk out over all the loans by
charging a five percent interest charge to each borrower. The interest serves as a small borrowers fee for
the convenience of making additional funds available as a loan.

Inflation. Defined here as a sustained increase in the general level of prices, inflation necessarily
decreases the purchasing power or value of money over time. If a lender makes a loan with the inflation
rate at three percent annually, the money automatically loses three percent of its value per year, even if the
borrower is perfectly reliable and trustworthy. By charging an interest rate equal to the prevailing rate of
inflation, lenders act to ensure that their money maintains its value.

Opportunity Cost. Money can be used as a means to make more money. By loaning money to a
borrower, lenders forgo their own opportunity to make a profit. Charging interest compensates for the
lenders missed opportunity.

What is of particular relevance here with regard to moneys value-nonneutrality is the impact of interest
on our behaviors.

Behavioral Effects of Interest



Though the full implication of interest is seldom understood, its behavioral effects are pervasive and
powerful. Three patterns directly related to this built-in feature of our monetary system include:

1. encouraging competition;
2. fueling economic growth;
3. concentrating wealth.
1. Encouraging Competition

Charging interestone effect of money created as bank debtforces competition beyond that which
would occur naturally.

Consider bank loans. When a bank creates money, say by providing a $100,000 mortgage, it only
creates the principal for that loan. The bank does not create the interest on that loan, but expects a return
of some $200,000 over the next 20 years or so. The bank requires the borrower to earn this second
$100,000.

The following story illustrates how interest is woven into the fabric of the monetary system and how it
stimulates competition.

The Eleventh Round

Once upon a time, there was a small village where people knew nothing about money or interest.
Each market day, people would bring their chickens, eggs, hams, and breads to the marketplace.
There they entered into the time-honored ritual of negotiations and exchange for what they needed.
One market day, a stranger with shiny shoes and an elegant hat came by and observed the process
with a smile. When one farmer ran around to corral six chickens needed in exchange for a ham, the
stranger could not refrain from laughing.
Poor people, he said. So primitive.
Overhearing this, the farmers wife challenged him: Do you think you can do a better job
handling chickens?
The stranger replied: Chickens, no. But I do have a much better way to eliminate the hassles.
Bring me one large cowhide and gather the families. I will then explain this better way.
As requested, the families gathered, and the stranger took the cowhide, cut perfect rounds in it, and
put an elaborate stamp on each. He then gave ten rounds to each family, stating that each round
represented the value of one chicken. Now you can trade and bargain with the rounds instead of
those unwieldy chickens, he said.
It seemed sensible. All were impressed by the stranger.
One more thing, added the stranger. I will return in one years time, and as a token of
appreciation for the improvement I made possible in your lives, I want each of you to bring me an
extra round, an eleventh round.
The wife was concerned. The eleventh round was never created; it was never cut from the
cowhide. She then asked, But where will that round come from?
Youll see, replied the stranger with a sardonic smile.

As the stranger suggested, it was far more convenient to exchange rounds instead of chickens on
market days. But this convenience had a hidden cost: the eleventh round generated a systemic
undertow of competition among the participants. One out of every 11 families would have to lose the
equivalent of all its rounds in order to pay the stranger, even if every villager managed their affairs
responsibly.
The eleventh round and the competition it generated impacted another age-old tradition as well.
During harvests, or when someones barn needed repairs after a storm, the villagers simply helped
one another, knowing that if they themselves should one day have a problem, others would in turn
come to their aid.
When a storm threatened a few of the farmers the year following, there was an uncharacteristic
reluctance to assist neighbors. Families were now wrestling one another over that eleventh round.
The introduction of interest-bearing money actively discouraged the long-held tradition of
spontaneous cooperation among the villagers.

The Eleventh Round is a simplified story for non-economists. The impact of interest was isolated
from other variables by making the assumption of a zero-growth society: no population increase, no
production increases, and no increases in the money supply. In practice, all three variables (population,
output, and money supplies) do change over time, further obscuring the impact of interest. The point of the
Eleventh Round is that, all other things being equal, the artificial competition to obtain the money
necessary to pay the interest is structurally embedded into the current system.

So how does a loan whose interest is never created get repaid? Interest repayment requires the use of
someone elses principal. Scarcity is generated by not creating the money required to pay interest. It
forces people to compete with each other for money that was never created, and penalizes them with
bankruptcy should they not succeed. When a bank checks credit worthiness, it is really verifying a
customers ability to compete successfully in the marketplace to obtain the money required to reimburse
both the principal and interest. Ultimately, someone must always lose. Scarcity is the hidden engine that
drives our bank-debt monetary system.

In the current national currency paradigm, one reason why so much attention is paid to central bank
decisions is that increased interest rates necessitate more bankruptcies in the future. The economic pie
must grow that much faster just to break even. The monetary system therefore obliges us to incur debt and
then compete with others through our exchanges to pay the resulting interest to the banks or lenders. No
wonder it is a tough world out there, and those who live within a competitive monetary system readily
accept Darwins supposed survival of the fittest.

An ever-mounting body of evidence, however, supports a less harsh and even wholly contrary
interpretation of the natural world.

Kinji Imanishi, the late professor of biosociology from Kyoto University, challenged the stereotypical
Darwinian vision of nature as a struggle for life. The survival-of-the-fittest model is completely blind to
the many frequent cases of symbiosis, joint development, and harmonious coexistence that prevail in all
domains of evolution. Even our own bodies would not be able to survive long without the symbiotic
collaboration of billions of microorganisms in the digestive tract.84

Evolutionary biologist Elisabet Sahtouris points out that predominantly competitive behavior is a
characteristic of a young species during its first forays into the world. In contrast, in a mature system like
an old-growth forest, the competition for light, for instance, is balanced by intense cooperation among

species. Species that do not learn to cooperate with others with whom they are codependent invariably
disappear.85

Although the theories of Social Darwinisma 19th century movement that advocated survival of the
fittest as applicable to human societyhave long been debunked, some of their tenets still linger. Many
people maintain that competition and cruelty are natural and inevitable tools for survival, and are inherent
to human nature. Yet, contrary to popular belief, Charles Darwin himself did not see competition as the
foremost tool for continued existence in the evolution of humankind (see insert).

Darwin, Loye, and Survival of the Fittest

Evolutionary systems scientist David Loye, in his books The Great Adventure and Darwins Lost
Theory of Love, points us back to the very source of Darwinism itself: Charles Darwin. After On the
Origin of Species (1859), Darwin wrote another book, The Descent of Man (1871), in which he
points out that the brutal and bloody theory in Origin pertains only to prehuman evolution.
Loye explains that in The Descent of Man, which deals primarily with human evolution, Darwin
actually writes only twice of survival of the fittestand one of these times is to apologize for
exaggerating the importance of this idea in Origin of Species!86
Furthermore, in this book of 848 pages in fine print, he [Darwin] writes only 12 times about
selfishness, which by now hordes of sociobiologists, evolutionary psychologists, and best-selling
books have assured us is the central survivalist motivation for human evolution high and low.87 The
misunderstood theory of evolution simply does not apply to the evolution of human society, because
once human consciousness comes into play everything changes. As Loye points out, what Darwin is
actually writing about in Descent can be clearly inferred by the word count:
survival of the fittest, 2 times
selfishness, 12 times
moral sensitivity, 92 times
love, 95 times
habit, 108 times
More surprising still, as Loye uncovers, Darwin wrote in Descent more than a century ago:

As important as the struggle for existence has been and even still is, yet as far as the highest part of
our nature is concerned there are other agencies, which are more important. For the moral qualities
are advanced, either directly or indirectly, much more through the effects of habit, by our reasoning
powers, by instruction, by religion, etc., than through natural selection.88

Descent was completely overlooked, not because it was less valid than Origin, but rather because it
contradicted the bias of the age in which Darwin lived. That competitive bias is still reinforced in the
world today by the monetary system, especially through the built-in feature of interest.


2. Fueling Economic Growth

The key assumption of the Eleventh Round is that everything remains the same, one year to the next. In
reality, we do not live in a world of zero growth. Population, production, and the money supply all grow
at varying rates, making it more difficult than in the Eleventh Round to notice what is taking place.

Perpetual growth is not just another fact of life. The monetary system acts like a treadmill requiring
sustained economic growth, even if the average real standard of living remains stagnant. The interest rate
determines the average rate of economic growth needed just to remain at the same place.

Presently, the monetary system takes the first slice of the ongoing growth to pay for interest. Agrarian
societies customarily sacrificed the first fruits of the harvest to their gods, while we instead now give the
first yields of our toils to the institutions that manage our money.


3. Concentrating Wealth

A third effect of interest is the continual transfer of wealth from the vast majority to a small minority. The
wealthiest receive an uninterrupted profit from whoever needs to borrow money. A revealing study on the
transfer of wealth via interest from one economic group to another was performed in West Germany in
1982 (Figure 5.1).89

Germans were grouped into ten income categories of about 2.5 million households each. During that
year, transfers between these ten groups involved a total of DM 270 billion in interest payments
(approximately $120 billion at the time). A stark way to present the process is to graph the net interest
transfers (interest earned minus interest paid) for each of these ten household categories.

The net effect is that the top ten percent of households received a net transfer of DM 34.2 billion in
interest from the remaining 90 percent of society during the year in question. The greatest sums of interest
were transferred from the middle classes (categories three to eight), each of which transferred about DM
5 billion to the top ten percent of the households (category ten). Even the poorest households transferred a
substantial DM 1.8 billion of interest each year to the wealthiest group.

The graph illustrates this systemic transfer of wealth from the bottom 80 percent of the population to the
top 20 percent, and especially to the top ten percent. This transfer occurs independently of the cleverness
or industriousness of the participantsa classical argument often used to justify differences in income
and is instead a direct result of the type of money in use.

Is it mere coincidence that once interest became legal, all democratic countries created income taxes
and income redistribution schemes to counteract at least part of this wealth transfer process?

No equivalent study isolating the effects of interest payments on the concentration of wealth yet exists

for other countries. This process is, however, occurring everywhere, because by definition interest
payments transfer weatlh from those who have to borrow to those who can afford to lend money out.
Available data suggests that economic disparity is, for example, even more dramatic in America than in
Germany, with the U.S. middle class particularly adversely affected. The share of wage income earned by
those in the 2080 percentiles fell by one-fifth between 1966 and 2001. Those in the 8090 percentile
income group instead maintained their percentage of earned income, while those in the 9599, 9999.9,
and 99.9100 percentiles earned 29 percent, 73 percent, and 291 percent more, respectively.90

This concentration-of-wealth mechanism is, strictly speaking, a structural issue. Nonetheless, its
behavioral effects are quite significant. Consider, for example, that the vast majority of us must work ever
harder to maintain our middle-class lifestyles. This same mechanism not only corroborates the perception
that the rich keep getting richer, but reveals that this concentration of wealth is an ongoing, selfperpetuating, systemic reality that endures despite our efforts to address it.

Interest-bearing money and the transfer of wealth it perpetuates have many important consequences,
including the steady erosion of one of the key elements required for societies to functiontrust. Todays
societies are instead plagued by mistrust in our hopes for the future, in our leaders and institutions, and
ultimately, in one another. It is trust that backs our money and allows a free nation to function optimally.
And it is the corrosive effects of a deficit of trust that ends relationships, divides nations, and has
undermined entire civilizations down through history.

Much of todays focus is placed on the accumulated negative consequences of industrialization, such as
pollution, global warming, and our economic woes. It should be understood, however, that it is not
interest-bearing money that is the principal cause of these and other troubles, but rather the fact that it is
the only type of money available. What kinds of economic and behavioral patterns could be engendered if
there were different types of currencies working side by side with central bank-issued money?

The importance of moneys non-neutrality and the extent to which it is linked to the human condition is
examined further in Part III of this work. Suffice it to say here that moneys impact on society is of vital
importance. Our ability or failure to understand this seemingly obscure feature of money may very well
determine our capacity to successfully navigate the challenges of our age and realize a better future.

It may be difficult to imagine monetary systems other than the one currently in use, or how they might
function and what effects, if any, they would have on society. Fortunately, we now have sufficient
information to piece together the monetary paradigms of several past ages, as well as the different
economic and social patterns they generated. One such epoch is explored next.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

Money is not value-neutral, but instead profoundly impacts the kind of society we live in. Interest-bearing
national currencies were the hidden engines that propelled civilization into and through the Industrial
Revolution. Both the best and the worst of what the Modern Age has achieved can be directly or
indirectly attributed to the architecture of our money and the values they encourage, including:
competition, the need for perpetual growth, and unrelenting wealth concentration. By intelligently
engineering money, we can also engender different kinds of behavior and expect different societal results.

CHAPTER SIX - Back to the Future



The icons of old are the coding of tomorrow.

And tomorrow holds the promise of recovery of forgotten wisdom.

~JEAN HOUSTON

Historical evidence informs all our social, cultural and economic knowledge. In economics, however, it
is only very recent data that tends to be considered, based on the assumption that experiences from past
ages are not relevant to contemporary economic issues. Yet, our banking and monetary systems have
remained fundamentally unchanged for centuries. Failure to examine the more distant past prior to the
inception of the current paradigm risks overlooking potential insights useful for today.

One historical period of particular relevance is explored herein.

THE CENTRAL MIDDLE AGES



Once upon a time, there existed an age blessed by an uncommon prosperity that enriched each segment of
society. There was work for all, with favorable working conditions and abundant time for family,
community, and personal pursuits. This epoch was also characterized by significant advancements in
science, technology, education, literature, music, arts, craftsmanship, and more. Its ethics included
cooperation, an unusual civic pride, and long-term thinking. The many unusual traits of this period
culminated as well in the creation of some of the most beautiful and enduring public works the world has
ever known.

Though seemingly like some fairy tale, this age not only existed, but endured for centuries. It flourished
in the very same region from where our current monetary and banking systems originatedWestern
Europe. It came into being, however, long before the advent of our present monetary paradigm and the
modern era. A millennium hence, this bygone age offers unique lessons for us today.

The Middle (or Medieval) Ages were so named because this time period was the expanse of
European history in the middle of the high civilizations of Rome (ending in the mid-400s CE) and the
Renaissance (beginning in the late 1400s). This entire epoch is also commonly referred to as the Dark
Ages, as popular belief regards this period as one of dismal poverty and primitive lifestyles, crowned
by the horrific plague. The term medieval is still used today as a derisory label to dismiss something as
hopelessly primitive.

Many of the opinions regarding this age, however, date back to 19th century assertions, which have
since been proven to be incomplete or entirely mistaken. The Middle Ages spanned more than 1,000
years. Recent scholarship has unveiled key distinctions regarding what transpired over this long expanse
of history.

A dismal view certainly remains justified for the epoch following the collapse of the Roman Empire
the Early Middle Ages (5th8th centuries)and is much more accurately descriptive still of the dramatic
closing medieval centuries. It is in fact the particularly appalling Late Middle Ages (14th15th centuries)
that provided much of the fuel for the dark image that future generations would project, inaccurately, onto
the vast entirety of the medieval millennium.

There were, however, two and one-half centuries during the medieval epoch when something quite
different took place. This middle period is the Central Middle Ages.

Highlights of the Central Middle Ages



Toward the middle of the 10th century, a marked shift in consciousness paralleled dramatic economic
improvements in many areas of Western Europe. The progress spanning 10401290 is noted by medieval
scholars as the First Modernization, the European Takeoff, and the True European Renaissance.
Between 11801230, for instance, the first wave of universities was founded in Europe.91 Abstract
sciences, such as mathematics, once thought to have developed in the official Renaissance of the 16th
century, occurred instead centuries earlier during this period.92

The Central Middle Ages were also characterized by a most unusual prosperity.

Prosperity for All

The prosperity of this era was quite unusual not only in quantitative terms, but also by the extent to which
it benefited the general populace. A number of contemporary medievalist historians report that the quality
of life for ordinary people in the 12th century may very well have been the highest in all of European
history, comparing favorably in important respects even to present-day conditions. Workers, for example,
seldom had fewer than four courses at lunch or dinner and enjoyed three or even four meals a day. Daily
caloric intakes, estimated at 3000 calories in developed countries today, was instead 35004000 calories
in the Central Middle Ages.93

Working hours were limited as well. When the dukes of Saxony tried to extend the workday from six
hours to eight, workers in the region rebelled. Sunday was the Day of the Lord and the appointed day
for public matters, while the so-called Blue Monday was designated as a free day, set aside for the
general public to attend to their private affairs. In addition, there were at least 90 official holidays
annually. In some regions, there may have been as many as 170 holidays in a single year!

In addition to favorable working conditions, the working class also enjoyed a remarkable level of
economic independence. As medieval economic historian Guy Bois explains: In the agricultural sector,
for the first time the small landowners as a group become much more productive than the Seigniorial
holdings. In short, Europe becomes more and more a world of small producers with the family unit as its
fundamental engine.94

A number of medieval historians offer testimony to the expansion and improvement that took place in
virtually every dimension of Central medieval society. Medievalist Marcel Bloch claims that increased
private ownership is accompanied by the largest increase in cultivated agricultural land in the entire
span of the historical record.95 Guy Fourquin reports: not only did the land available expand, but also
the average yields more than doubled in most cases.96 F. Icher writes: Between the 11th and 13th
century, the Western world experiences a high level of prosperity that is reflected concretely by a
demographic expansion without precedent in history.97 Between 1000 and 1300, Europes population is
generally estimated to have increased an unprecedented twofold, one expression of the increased capacity
to feed and maintain the population. Moreover, as Guy Bois writes, Growth isnt limited to a
demographic explosion combined with a strong agricultural expansion. A flourishing commercial
expansion was its third dimension.98

Medievalist Jean-Pierre Bayard reports that, ordinary life is revolutionized: coal is used for heating,

candles for lighting, eyeglasses for reading, glass is used more and more commonly, paper is
manufactured on an industrial scale.99 Robert L. Reynolds writes, [There is] a growing manufacture of
textiles, pottery, leather goods, and many other things. The products get better and better. Prices go down
in terms of man hours because of more efficient management, improvement in tools and machinery, and
better transport and distribution.100 According to medievalist R. Phillippe, at the beginning of the 12th
century there were in operation in France alone no fewer than 20,000 water mills, which represented the
energy of 600,000 workers. Such technologies liberated massive amounts of labor.101

Urbanization, previously thought to take off with the Industrial Revolution of the 1700s, began during
the Central medieval period. Frances and Joseph Gies write, Europe was turning from a developing into
a developed region. The growth of industry meant the growth of cities, which in the 12th and 13th
centuries began to abandon their old roles of military headquarters and administrative centers as they
filled with the life of commerce and industry.102 Robert Lacey and Danny Danzinger report that
Warwick, Stafford, Buckingham, Oxfordmost of the county towns of modern England originated in the
tenth century.103

Guy Bois summarizes:

One can only be impressed by the extraordinary vitality and power of the changes that occurred
during those three centuries. Whether one considers the demography, the urbanization, the techniques,
the relationships between labor and money, every one of these aspects of society was completely
revolutionizedOne will have to wait five hundred years to live another wave of transformation of
that scale: the capitalist Industrial Revolution.104


Heights

Confirmation of the unusual prosperity of this age comes in an equally unusual form of physical evidence:
bodily remains.

It is well known that todays generation is substantially taller than the previous onebetter nutrition
and care, particularly in youth, is credited with this process. In a study of the skeletons of bodies in the
same geographical areaLondoninformative findings emerged. The women of London were taller on

average during the 10th12th centuries than any other period in recorded history, measuring a whopping 7
centimeters taller than her Victorian counterpart and even 1 centimeter taller than today! Regarding males,
it is only within the past fifty years that they have caught up to and, by 1998, finally outgrown their
medieval counterparts, by a mere two centimeters (see Figure 6.1).105

The increased height of Londoners of the Central medieval period appears to reflect the greater quality
of life for men and women of that epoch.

Age of Cathedrals

This medieval epoch has also been referred to as the Age of Cathedrals,106 as nearly all of the
cathedrals of Europe were built at this time. Historian Sacheverell Sitwell writes, It was the greatest
period of building activity that there has ever been, and no mere catalogue of names and places can
convey any idea of the strength and quality of its products.107

It is estimated that by 1300 CE there were almost 1,000 cathedrals in Western Europe, alongside
350,000 churches and several thousand large abbey foundations. Yet, the total population back then is
estimated at only 70 million, which calculates to an average of one Christian place of worship for every
200 inhabitants. The ratio was even higher in parts of Hungary and Italy: one church for every 100
inhabitants!108

This medieval building phenomenon is more remarkable still given that there was no central authority,
church or otherwise, in charge of initiating or funding the construction of these cathedrals. Contrary to
popular belief today, these structures were neither built by nor belonged to the church or nobility.109 Local
nobility and royalty customarily did make contributions, but these monuments were typically owned and
financed by the citizens of the municipalities where they were built.110

The cathedrals embody some of the most beautiful gifts of Western history. These monuments stand as a
strong statement of faith, ingenuity, and generosity. From a narrower economic viewpoint, they also
offered a viable long-term income strategy for the community (see insert).

Cathedrals: an Investment Forever

Besides their symbolic and religious roles, the cathedrals served another key function. Attracting
currency into a community has clear economic advantages, as those living in proximity to todays
tourist attractions such as Disney World will confirm. In medieval times, this was realized by
attracting pilgrims, who played a similar economic role to that of todays tourists. A proven way to
draw pilgrims was to build the most accommodating and spectacular cathedral in the area, which
may help explain why medieval communities built cathedrals that could house two to four times their
own population.
Additionally, these cathedrals, which were built to last forever, created cash flow not only for the
population of the time, but for many future generations. The bulk of the businesses in Chartres,
France, for example, still thrive today from tourists coming to visit its medieval cathedral 800 years
after its construction.

Few medievalists today doubt the extraordinary economic and building boom of the Central Middle
Ages. One fundamental matter, however, remains unresolved: The medieval blossoming has been
described many times in its manifestations, its chronology, and its many facets, but never explained. Its

mechanism remains an enigma.111



The economic mechanism that justified the remarkable blossoming of that period remains unclear.
Where did the resources come from to fund hundreds of building projects on the scale of cathedrals? Faith
and devotion alone cannot explain this construction any more than they can explain the remarkable
prosperity of the ordinary people.

One medieval feature has, however, gone almost entirely overlookedthe monetary system. This
previously ignored element may help explain the peculiar dynamics of that period.

The Invisible Engine

Two different types of currencies functioned in parallel to one another throughout much of Western Europe
during the Central Middle Ages. One type of currency consisted of centralized royal coinage, with many
features in common with present-day national currencies. Its usage was primarily for long-distance
trading and for the purchase of luxury goods. The second type of currency consisted of an extensive
network of different local currencies, used primarily for community exchanges.

Many of the local currencies had a very peculiar featurea demurrage charge. Similar to a negative
interest on money, the demurrage feature functions like a parking fee, which is levied for holding onto the
currency for too long without spending it.

The demurrage was implemented through a general recoinage practice, enacted during the transfer of
power to a new lord, usually due to the death of ones predecessor. As a rule, four old coins were handed
in and exchanged for three new ones, each with the same individual value of the coins that they replaced.
This tradition, called renovatio monetae, amounted to a 25 percent tax payable by anyone in possession
of dated coins at the time of recall. The uncertainty about the duration of a lords life (and thus, the
functional lifespan of the currencies) acted as an incentive for users to spend or invest rather than save
such coins.

In technical terms, when demurrage is applied, money continues to function as a medium of exchange
but no longer serves as a store of value, that is, something worth hoarding. Though saving was very
much encouraged, it was not done by storing currency, but took the form of productive assets. Examples of
such investments were land improvements or high-quality maintenance of equipment such as water wheels
and windmills, or enduring investments in the community such as the cathedrals. The specifics of how
demurrage was applied differed from region to region, but generally speaking, provided a built-in
incentive to invest in this way.

Written records from the period offer testimony to the benefits of this kind of savings. A significant
number of mills, ovens, winepresses, and other heavy equipment were improved upon or even completely
rebuilt each year. They did not wait until anything was breaking downOn average, at least ten percent
of all gross revenue was immediately reinvested in equipment maintenance.112 No other period since
then has encouraged such intensive preventive maintenance.

In effect, a pattern of longer-term investments became the norm rather than the exception. For those with
demurrage currency to spare, investing in the cathedrals was likely an ideal way of demonstrating ones
faith while also providing benefits for the community. The medieval cathedrals, still standing today and
continuing to receive visitors from around the world, are enduring testimonies to the long-term vision of

that former age.



Demurrage-charged complementary currencies also help to explain the particular Central medieval
economy. Given that savings were inherently discouraged by demurrage, these currencies would remain in
circulation and were exchanged with far greater frequency at all levels of society, in contrast to other
forms of money. The greater velocity of circulation (a higher frequency of transactions with the same
given coin) enabled the less-privileged classes to engage in substantially more transactions, which
significantly improved their standard of living.

THE END OF AN AGE



This Golden Age came to a brutal end at the closing of the 13th century. The plague, otherwise known as
the Black Death, is customarily blamed for causing the misery that subsequently befell Europe. Recent
findings tell another tale.

Though usually cited as the cause of the later medieval horrors, the outbreak of the plague did not occur
until 13471349. Yet, the population started plummeting two generations beforehand. Mostly overlooked
is the fact that the Black Death was preceded by decades of economic and social devastation.

A major economic crash occurred during the period of 128095. A majority of the population, urban as
well as rural, ended up being reduced to living at subsistence levels in the last decade of the 1200s. The
economic downturn was then followed by widespread famines, epidemics, and extensive loss of life from
1300 onwards, decades prior to the outbreak of the deadly pestilence. From 13151322, the noted Great
Famine took place. Historian Henry S. Lucas estimates that hunger killed ten percent of Europes
population.113

Accounts from the period describe the severity of conditions: So many men and women died every
single day from all social classeswealthy, middle class and poorthat the priests couldnt bury them
fast enough, so that the stench in the air was everywhere.114 A London chronicle reported that, the poor
people ate for hunger cats and horses and dogsSome stole children and ate them.115

Again, all these events took place decades before the first outbreak of the plague. Historian Daniel
Power writes, One needs, I believe, a lot of blindness to describe the outbreak of the Black Death as an
accidental and exogenous event. Isnt it most surprising that this disaster happened only after 60 or 70
years of total misery?116

It is now known that more than a half century prior to the plague, disastrous monetary changes were
implemented.

Political and Monetary Chnges



A historic power shift occurred in Western Europe during the 13th century, whereby the doctrine of King
by Divine Right was taken to its extreme. Local governments and administrations were overrun by
strong, rapidly growing central authorities with commanding kingdoms and large armies. The dual
currency system was abolished and replaced by the imposition of a monopoly of royal coinage. King
Louis IX of France specified that only royal mints had the right to issue coins in the realm.

Though it would take several decades, the elimination of local currencies eventually became sufficient
for the monetary contraction to have an overall economic impact.

The final kiss of death to the good monetary period in Central medieval France came in 129498
when, in preparation for war, King Philip IV, resorted to the debasement of royal money to meet his
urgent income requirements. Debasement is a process in which the precious metal content of a coin is
significantly reduced. By taking this expedient debasement road, and by doing so on a huge scale, Philip
IV set into motion severe inflation and economic disaster.

In practical terms, these monetary changes of centralization and debasement resulted in a double
economic hitmonetary contraction followed by inflation. With the abolition of the local currencies,
there was now complete dependency on the official, centrally issued coinage. The debasement in the late
1290s resulted in massive inflation. Existing contracts or monetary agreements became, in effect,
meaningless. A modern parallel would be the Great Depression of the 1930s, in which the money supply
shrank, followed immediately by hyperinflation, as occurred in 1920s Germany and in 1970s Brazil.

The medieval economic crisis led to a general societal breakdown and decades of famine and death.
The physical weakening of the population was sufficiently extensive to render conditions ripe for the
plague to become one of the worst pandemics in all of history. The Late Middle Ages that followed were
indeed dark.

As Guy Bois explains: This depression would be a long oneit would last one and a half centuries; it
would be painful to a degree that we still have difficulty imagining. No aspect of social life would be
protected from this collapse.117

Although a few local currencies managed to survive until the 18th century, the medieval experiment
with complementary currencies would not be repeated on such a scale. Complementary currencies never
again reached the critical mass needed to significantly impact the standard of living of Western society.

Twice and Thrice Upon A time



Support for the role played by monetary paradigm in the realization of this Golden Age, as well as its
demise, is offered by a nearly identical scenario found in another ancient civilizationDynastic Egypt.

Egypt enjoyed one of the highest standards of living of the ancient world. Its economy afforded Egypt
the capacity to be the first known civilization to offer assistance in the form of foreign aid to other
societies. Like its medieval counterpart, Egypt had a dual monetary system, with long-distance currencies
much like our own national currencies, together with demurrage-charged local currencies that enabled
local exchanges among the working classes. Unlike the Central Middle Ages, however, Egypts economy
and dual monetary system endured not hundreds but thousands of years. The end of this age, like that of
medieval Western Europe, coincided with the introduction of a currency system similar to todays national
currencies, which was imposed on the Egyptians by the conquering Romans.

Another example of an unusual economy and monetary system that dates back to the medieval period,
but which continues in part to this very day, is found in Bali. Though its monetary system has undergone
changes in recent decades, Bali maintains at least some of the traits found in Central medieval Europe and
Dynastic Egypt. The economies, monetary systems, and societal conditions of Bali, the Central Middle
Ages and Dynastic Egpyt offer important insights about how we might improve conditions in our world
today, and are therefore the subject of further investigation in Part IV of this book.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

The complementary currencies of the Central Middle Ages came and went without any awareness of their
role in shaping the investment patterns that created a Golden Age. Yet, when local currencies
disappeared, cathedral building also stopped. What changed? It wasnt peoples faith: there is no
evidence that Europeans were less devout in the 14th century than in the 12th.

In this light, the Central Middle Ages revealed two important characteristics of money: its valuenonneutrality and its potential for addressing large-scale social issues. It is only a millennium after the
fact that are we beginning to understand how local currencies, particularly those using demurrage,
induced long-term investment and cooperative behavior patterns that benefited both the local economy
and the entire population, regardless of socioeconomic levels.

CHAPTER SEVEN - A Change of View



We take a handful of sand

from the endless landscape of awareness around us

and call that handful of sand the world.

~ROBERT PIRSIG

It is not simply that our banking and monetary systems are centuries old that makes them problematic. It is
the fact that these two systems are the key replicators and propagators of a set of beliefs, perceptions, and
objectives that do not accurately reflect many of the core values, conditions, and requirements of our
current age.

The creation of these two influential systems was part of a massive wave of change that swept over
Western European society during the 1700s, from secularization, democratization, and the creation of new
nation-states, to commercialization, the rise of a middle class, and more. The Industrial Age and its new
socioeconomic order were accompanied by novel beliefs and perceptions regarding the world and
humanitys place in the cosmic scheme of things. That emerging worldviewModernismhas informed
our ways of being and doing from then until now.

Today, we are in the midst of another period of transformation, perhaps the most profound in human
history. Our understandings, realities, many collective beliefs and objectives have shifted dramatically,
particularly in recent decades. Yet, the same systems and institutions that helped shape society from the
1700s, continue to function in similar fashion to this day, and enforce outmoded ways and means that no
longer accurately reflect present-day thinking and requirements.

There is an obvious need and a growing consensus from around the world for reform. But we must ask
ourselves how this is to be pragmatically accomplished. How do we transform our systems and
institutions to better reflect our core values and todays changing realities?

We examine below how the conditions, objectives, and limited understandings of a former age
coalesced into a single dominant worldview; how that set of perceptions influenced our economic tenets
and practices; and the consequences upon our world of those activities born under the influence of
Modernism.

We begin with a brief look at societal conditions in Western Europe following the demise of the Central
Middle Ages, the reaction to which gave root to the modernist perspective.

SEEDS OF CHANGE

The late medieval and premodern periods from the 1300s to 1600s involved dramatic reversals to the
widespread economic prosperity and social progress enjoyed throughout much of Western Europe during
the Central Middle Ages.

The economic downturn of the late 1200s led to centuries of extreme hardship for the masses and
concentrated wealth for a privileged few, with little or no opportunity for upward mobility. With the rare
exception of a small, developing urban middle class of burghers, the overwhelming majority of people
were born into and remained trapped in poverty.118 The late medieval status quo maintained its
sociopolitical and religious repression through an authoritarian Church and titled upper class. This class
system was supported by the prevailing belief of a universal order in which, just as the planets and sun
rotated around the Earth, ones station in societys pecking order was fixed at birth and remained constant
throughout ones life.119 The underlying pretext for this social order was rooted in the old notion that man
was, A stranger to himself, incapable of self-knowledge; thinking himself good and virtuous, but in
reality full of pride and disordered loves.120 In essence, the populace was deemed incapable of
governing itself and, for its own worldly good and eternal salvation, must submit to religious authority
and the supposedly divinely ordained rule of monarchy.

Mounting tensions and calls for religious and social reform eventually found support in the form of a
new technologythe printing press. The Ninety-Five Theses of Martin Luther in 1517 and other works of
dissent were disseminated in the vernacular of the masses and helped bring about the Protestant
Reformation. Printing also led to the publication of new scientific journals. Inventors and researchers
could now share findings and learn from one another as never before. This led to an epoch of
unprecedented discoverythe Scientific Revolution.121

In 1543, Nicolaus Copernicus placed the Sun, not the Earth, at the center of the solar system. The works
of Galileo, Johannes Kepler, Isaac Newton, and others followed. Of more lasting importance than any
particular finding, however, was the establishment of a new, more reliable method of inquiry. The late
scholar Joseph Needham noted that, During the Renaissance in the West, in the time of Galileothe most
effective method of discovery was itself discovered.122

For centuries, lifes mysteries had been defined by the process of Revealed Truth,presumed direct
communication from the divine. The medieval world was widely perceived as inhabited by angels and
demons, spirits and souls, occult powers and mystical principles. Some medieval scientists spoke about
the soul of a magnet as easily as they spoke about its mass.123 Scientific inquiry changed all this.

Investigation and the acquisition of knowledge could now be approached through observable,
empirical data, experimentation, and the testing of hypotheses. Conclusions were reproducible and often
enjoyed precise mathematical backing. Keplers findings on Mars elliptical orbit, for instance, were
accompanied by nine hundred pages of computations. Newtons laws of motion and universal gravitation
were supported by another of his inventionscalculus.124

The implications were profound and extended far beyond physical principles and planetary motions.
An exquisite order to the natural universe was being uncovered, not by revelation, but by scientific
inquiry. Evident, as well, was the considerable ability of people to think and reason far beyond medieval

notions of humankinds fallen state.



Copernicus heliocentric theory, for example, raised the seditious question: Could humanitys place in
the great order of things also be mutable? Doubts mounted regarding the supposed infallibility and
presumptive authority of the church and nobility. Hope and confidence grew that critical thought could be
applied to other domains, and to the formation of a more just society governed by and for the people.

Western society was at the dawn of a comprehensive transformation.

The Advent of Modernism



New discoveries and abhorrence of past societal conditions contributed to sweeping changes in Western
Europe with the Age of Enlightenment.125 Pioneered by such intellectual leaders as John Locke, Voltaire,
Jean-Jacques Rousseau, Adam Smith, Benjamin Franklin, and others, modern society emerged in a
whirlwind of brilliant philosophy and a noble outpouring of revolutionary ideas. Its nascent worldview
Modernismunderscored a dedication to freedom, reason, critical thought, and a new sense of
humanitys place in the universal order.

Ideas led to demands and, on occasion, rebellion. In 1688, Englands Glorious Revolution curbed the
power of the king, produced a Bill of Rights, and ushered in modern parliamentary democracy, making
that countrys government the first model of Enlightenment thought. Other independence movements and
constitutional reforms followed in America, France, and elsewhere. To help insure against past abuses,
measures such as the separation of church and state were constitutionally enshrined.

The emergence of this new age and social order was enabled by a new monetary system, and
accompanied by a new social scienceeconomicswhich provided a technical foundation and school of
thought for moneys dissemination.

Monetary and Commercial Changes



Sociopolitical change was accompanied by historic banking, monetary, and economic reforms. As
mentioned, the central banks of Sweden and England were formed in the 1600s.126 Each bank obtained the
exclusive right to create paper money as legal tender in exchange for its commitment to provide the funds
required by sovereigns and governments. These measures brought about the institutionalization of the fiatbased, interest-bearing, bank-generated, national currency system in use today. Though the immediate
purpose of the structural monetary changes in both Sweden and England was to raise sufficient funds in
preparation for war (against Denmark and France, respectively),127 these reforms eventually enabled
many of the changes that defined this age.

The new nation-states and the Industrial Revolution required enormous capital investments for
improvements to infrastructure, including the construction of roads, canals, railways, large factories, and
expanding urban centers. Increased trade and colonization by maritime nations also required large sums of
money for shipbuilding and exploration.

To help stimulate private investment into these novel and often risky financial ventures, a new business
entity was createdthe joint-stock companywhich limited the liability of investors to the extent of
their personal investment without endangering their other properties.128 New commercial laws and civil
arbitration facilities were established as well, to also help ensure investments and economic progress.

Another key monetary issue was standardization. Up until this period, a myriad of trading currencies
were in use, including ducats, florin, noble, guinea, and grosh, but they lacked a standard of value. An
essay in 1717 by Newton purportedly inspired the founding of the gold standard, which fixed a unit of
account to a precise weight in gold.129 Among its many advantages, the gold standard greatly facilitated
international trade.

Economic matters were given extensive consideration during the Enlightenment. Its leaders were not
just philosophers, but pragmatic businessmen who understood that ideals such as inalienable rights and
the pursuit of happiness must include economic and financial reforms. Property rights, free trade, and
enterprise were seen as vital interacting pieces in a holistic drive towards the liberalization and
maturation of society. Voltaire said, Where there is not liberty of conscience, there is seldom liberty of
trade, the same tyranny encroaching upon commerce as upon religion.130 Adam Smith argued that with
each individual and nation free to improve their own economic position, and with economic systems
designed to encourage and utilize the best skills of all, everyone in society benefited.

Indisputable economic benefits were realized through industrialization. It provided greater assurance
and regularity of wages in comparison to the erratic harvests, outright crop failures, and other vicissitudes
of agrarian-based economies. Many new jobs, professions, and opportunities for upward mobility
emerged that were previously unavailable. Economist Alec Tsoucatos explains that prior to
modernization, the principal means of enrichment was through war, by plunder, inheriting it by death, or
acquiring it through marriage. For the first time, money and wealth were now possible through work and
enterprise.131

Economic progress was gradually accompanied by a host of social improvements. These included
lower infant mortality, decreased death from starvation, eradication of some fatal diseases, universal

primary education, the birth of the middle classes, and eventually, though accompanied by many struggles
and sacrifice, more equal treatment of people from different backgrounds.132

Yet, for all the improvements it wrought, modernization and its accompanying worldview were laden
with limitations. Many of todays critical issues can be traced back to the shift to this dominant
intellectual framework, and to the fact that it was not only progressive but also profoundly reactionary.
Modernism set its sights on the future while denying many important and valuable elements of our past. It
would take centuries to realize that a more optimal approach to healthy transformation was possible,
achieved not by a process of reaction and denial, but rather by inclusion, integration, and a deeper
appreciation for the power and influence of systems.

A Rational New World



Modernism was rooted in the determination to form a new society based on reason and the precision of
18th-century empirical science. It was also fashioned by a resolve to prevent a return to the conditions
that had plagued past centuries. This resulted not just in many innovations, but in an extensive process of
exclusion as well. Practically anything premodern or nonscientific in nature came to be considered
primitive, antiquated, and inferior. If something couldnt be measured, it was considered irrelevant.133
Entire realms of human experience that did not lend themselves to modern analysis or quantification were
partially or wholly discounted. Discounted as well were many time-tested customs and the notion that the
past could contribute in any meaningful way to the formation of modern society. This precluded any
insight into the role that complementary currencies played during the Central Middle Ages. There was, in
fact, little if any common knowledge regarding the very existence of a medieval Golden Age.134


Similarly, the prevailing mindset of the time did not lend itself to inquiry into the functional dynamics
of money, particularly the notion that different types and particular features of money could induce
specific behavior and investment patterns. Different types of money and their impact upon society were
simply not taken into consideration. The principal focus vis vis the new monetary system was that it be
streamlined, efficient, and codified.

These exclusions point to one of the great ironies regarding Modernism. Though it developed in
reaction to the narrow, rigid mindset of another age, the modernist worldview assumed its own insular
monopoly of legitimacy in the interpretation of reality.

Modernisms new, supposedly rational understanding of the world was tainted by a skewed
hyperrationality, referred to as the Technocratic Materialistic Mechanistic (TMM) model.135

Three of TMMs leading myths include:


Modernism is the only legitimate approach to knowledge;
Modernism is innately superior as it alone is capable of understanding and knowing everything;
it is possible to be absolutely logical, rational, and objective.
It was in this reductionist, mechanistic milieu that a one-type-fits-all national currency system emerged,
which, by design or happenstance, reflected the prevailing worldview of the period. It is also under the
influence of this same mindset and its inherent limitations that the development of Traditional Economics
the set of ideas that has dominated economic thinking and practicescame into being, as discussed
next.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

Our present-day banking and monetary systems arose as part of a massive societal shift during the 1700s
in Western Europe. The new banking and monetary paradigms that emerged during the Enlightenment
enabled industrialization, nation-states, the emergence of a middle class, secularization, and
commercialization. The new accompanying worldview was itself a reaction to the pre-scientific,
religious mindset which preceded it. Though Modernism brought with it many benefits, the new mode of
inquiry rejected many of the beliefs and customs that preceded it. Ironically, by pursuing knowledge in
this analytical manner, substantial pieces of human experience and history were ignored, including many
valuable monetary insights and practices that benefitted society in the Central Middle Ages.

CHAPTER EIGHT - Economic Myopia



Economics has never been a science.

And it is even less now than a few years ago.

~PAUL A. SAMUELSON

Economics participated in a unique, profound way in the transformation of modern society. Like the
current monetary system, economics was not only influenced by, but also became a key replicator of, the
modernist perspective and the quest for a society based on Enlightenment ideals.

Following the great scientific discoveries of Newton and others, all efforts were made to transform
economics into a science and strip it of the kinds of inquiries and concerns that it upheld previously as a
field of applied moral philosophy. This was mainly accomplished through the fields attempted integration
with mathematics. From the Scientific Revolution onwards, mathematical language was increasingly used
to describe an ever-growing range of natural phenomena. Problems that have baffled humankind since
the Greeks, from the motions of planets to the vibrations of violin strings, were suddenly mastered.136
There was hope that, fueled by precise empirical data, economics could provide modern society with the
same predictability and order as was found in physics.

At the time of its founding in the mid-1700s, however, economics was limited to algebra and a few
numerical examples, nothing more. Advanced mathematics and economic theory did not converge until the
latter half of the 1800s in conjunction with the concepts of supply, demand, balance, and the equilibrium
theory.

THE EQUILIBRIUM THEORY



From Smiths day to our own, economists have studied how the supply and demand for goods and
services affect their price. Many economists argued that in a free, competitive marketplace, the quantity of
goods demanded by consumers, and the amount supplied by producers, would come into balance with one
another.

This concept of balance was of particular interest to late 19th century economist Lon Walras, who saw
a parallel between equilibrium points in physics and balancing points in economic systems. He asserted
that given the available resources, participants in a free and fair market economy trade their way to a state
of equilibriuma natural resting point where supply equals demand, resources are allocated to their most
efficient use, and the welfare of society is optimized. Walras also believed that this equilibrium point
could be mathematically computed.

Using sophisticated, physics-based differential equations, Walras immortalized the equilibrium theory
in his magnum opus, Elements of Pure Economics (1874). This work became foundational to the ideas
and mathematical direction that have dominated traditional economic theory for more than a century.
Unfortunately, the math and many of the assumptions used to formulate the equilibrium theory were
fundamentally flawed.

The equations derived entirely from the First Law of Thermodynamics (Conservation). This law states
that energy can be converted from one form to another, but it is neither created nor destroyed. This first
law is, however, only one part of the thermodynamic story.

Entirely missing from Walrass formulation was the Second Law of Thermodynamics, which states that
entropya measure of disorder in a systemis always increasing. Over time, all structures and patterns
break down and decay. Cars rust, buildings crumble, mountains erode, apples rot and cream poured into
coffee dissipates until it is evenly mixed.137

Entropy is inevitable in systems that are self-contained, at rest, and in equilibrium, that is, closed. But
we now know that the economy is anything but in equilibrium, at rest, or closed. It evolves, adjusts,
expands, contracts, and is inextricably linked to a changing environment, absorbing massive amounts of
energy from outside the system (such as solar, mineral, human, and animal inputs) and emitting equally
massive byproducts into the universe (such as gases, waste, and pollution). The economy actually has
little in common with mechanical models found in Newtonian physics. The economy instead exhibits
many traits and emergent properties common to complex, adaptive, open systems found in nature and the
biological sciences.

Additionally, to ensure that his mathematical theories worked, Walras made use of impractical
idealized assumptions. These included perfectly functioning free markets, perfectly efficient corporations,
brilliant players who knew everything taking place in the markets, and more. In reality, however,
corporations, shareholders, and many others who constitute the marketplace and economy are, at best,
interacting in a complex, imperfect, ever changing, dynamic world.

In his book, The Origin of Wealth: Evolution, Complexity, and the Radical Remaking of Economics
(2006), Eric Beinhocker details many of the inherent misconceptions in the equilibrium theory and in
Traditional Economicsthe economics found in university textbooks, discussed in the news media and

referred to in the halls of business and government.138



Among the many important consequences of the misclassification of economics and the exclusive use of
the First Law of Thermodyamics was the assumption that new wealth, like energy, is neither created nor
destroyed. Rather, the world begins with a finite set of commodities that are allocated among users.139
Citing Philip Mirowsku of Notre Dame, Beinhocker writes that, In general equilibrium models, the
economy cant create new wealth any more than a lump of coal can reproduce.140

With respect to Walrass implausible assumptions, Beinhocker cites Axel Leijonhufvud, an economist
at the University of California, Los Angeles, who comments that, [Traditional Economics] models
incredibly smart people in unbelievably simple situations while the real world is in fact more accurately
described as believably simple people [coping] with incredibly complex situations.141

Walras, like his contemporaries, was driven by noble intentionsto imbue economics with
mathematical certitude and to provide society with a field of science to ensure order, stability, and
predictability in the marketplace. But these lofty ends were never realized. The misclassifications and
reductions inherent in the general equilibrium theory instead, acted as a straightjacket, forcing
economists to make highly unrealistic assumptions and limiting the fields empirical success, leading
Beinhocker to conclude that, Walras willingness to make tradeoffs in realism for the sake of
mathematical predictability would set a pattern followed by economists over the next century.142

The same pattern of reductions found in the general equilibrium theory and in traditional conomics
would also come to inform our systems of national accounts.

THE GNP, GDP, AND THE FLOW OF MONEY



The crash of 1929 and the depression that followed forced economists and nations to question their
assumptions about how the economy actually worked. In 1932, the U.S. government hired a young
economist and statistician to develop a set of measures on which to base a new national accounting
scheme. Simon Kuznets created the Gross National Product (GNP).

The GNP computed the value of goods and services produced by businesses and citizens, both at home
and abroad. Though more comprehensive and sophisticated than any previous accounting system, its
underlying assumptions reflected the same type of reductionist thinking as that found in the general
equilibrium theory.

The GNP assumes that all economic activity can be measured simply and accurately by price and value,
and thus by the flow of money. Accordingly, the lone criterion used by the GNP to indicate the economic
wellbeing of nations is the use of money. In 1991, the GNP was replaced by the Gross Domestic Product
(GDP), which modified slightly who is included in the metrics, but not what it measuresmonetized
transactions.143

According to the rationale of the GDP, each and every monetary transaction is considered a gain, while
any exchange of a good or service that does not involve the direct use of money is disregarded. Barter
exchanges, for example, are not tracked. Nor are domestic care and volunteer work taken into account.
Yet, the same work performed by someone paid in dollars (or any other national currency) is measurable
and, therefore, does count. It has been estimated, for instance, that if parents were paid for all the services
rendered in raising a child, they would bring in $134,000 a year.144 This figure compares with average
annual earnings of $52,000 by a registered nurse and $34,000 by a firefighter.145 The dramatic difference
in wages is not due to higher pay per hour for parents, but to the extra hours of work they put in.


The consequences of not taking into account nonmonetary activities are unfortunate and significant.
Many such exchanges are critically vital to the social fabric of society and comprise a significant portion
of overall economic activity in communities and nations. Yet, they remain invisible to conventional
economics because no money changes hands.

The decline of a nonmarket economy, such as the social breakdown of a family or community, is a
negative prospect for society. Yet, from a strictly monetized economic perspective, it is not measured and
therefore has no value. If, however, the breakdown gets to the point where paid intervention is needed, the
costs of social decay are then registered as profit.

As economists Clifford Cobb, Ted Halstead, and Jonathan Rowe have pointed out, The GDP not only
masks the breakdown of the social structure and the natural habitat upon which the economyand life
itselfultimately depend; worse, it actually portrays such breakdown as economic gain.146

Costs associated with psychological counseling, social work, and addiction treatment, which arise
from the neglect of the nonmarket realm, are tallied as economic gains. Crime adds billions to the GDP
due to the need for prison buildings, increased police protection, and repair of property damage.
Similarly, the depletion of our natural resources, the clean up and medical treatments associated with
industrys toxic byproducts, the costs of ecological disasters such as the Exxon Valdez and recent British
Petroleum oil spills, the terrorist attacks of 9/11, relief efforts following Hurricane Katrina, the
devastation caused by wars, and the hundreds of billions of dollars allocated in emergency stimulus
packagesall register as improvements to a nations economy by the curious standards of the GDP.

Economists and politicians alike have long been aware of the shortcomings in our economic accounting

systems. Criticism can be traced back to the 1930s, and to the GNPs principal architect, Simon Kuznets,
who cautioned that: The welfare of a nation can scarcely be inferred from a measure of national income.
If the GNP is up, why is America down? Distinctions must be kept in mind between quantity and quality
of growth, between costs and returns, and between the short and long run.147

Seven decades later, critical analysis continues. Former World Bank economist Herman Daly put it this
way: The current national accounting system treats the Earth as a business in liquidation.148 Many
others have echoed similar sentiments (see insert).

Robert F. Kennedy and the GNP

The following critique of the GNP was given by Robert F. Kennedy at a rally for Friends of the Earth
in New York in 1963. It was reechoed in large part by the Senator in one of his last speeches in
March 1968.
The Gross National Product includes air pollution and advertising for cigarettes, and ambulances
to clear our highways of carnage. It counts special locks for our doors, and jails for the people who
break them. GNP includes the destruction of the redwoods and the death of Lake Superior. It grows
with the production of napalm and nuclear warheadsand if GNP includes all this, there is much it
does not comprehend.
It does not allow for the health of our families, the quality of their education, or the joy of their
play. It is indifferent to the decency of our factories and the safety of our streets alike. It does not
include the beauty of our poetry or the strength of our marriages, or the intelligence of our public
debate or the integrity of our public officialsGNP measures neither our wit nor our courage,
neither our wisdom nor our learning, neither our compassion nor our devotion to our country. It
measures everything, in short, except that which makes life worthwhile.149

Despite the obvious limitations of our accounting schemes, and the availability and success of more
relevant measurement tools such as the Calvert-Henderson Quality of Life Indicators,150 the GDP
endures. So too do the many questionable practices it helps legitimize by means of their portrayal as gains
to the nation. This same accounting mechanism has in fact now been adopted worldwide, with predictably
destructive results. Indonesia, for example, has been a huge success story since the 1970s according to
GDP standards. But it achieved this status by clearcutting its forests, exhausting its soil, and selling off
precious nonrenewable mineral wealth. In short, it sold off its future to pay for accounting measures of
success.151

According to Clifford Cobb, Ted Halstead, and Jonathan Rowe, the GDP endures because, [It] serves
deep institutional cravings, combining the appearance of empirical certitude and expert authority with a
readymade story line.152 That story line, that money activity and concomitant economic growth result in
happiness and security, is so entrenched that it now defines our consumer driven Western society.153

The GDPs continued use is explained further by the fact that, given the confines of the mindset from
which it emanated, the national accounting scheme appears to make sense; that is to say, it accurately
reflects the rationale and entrenched reductionist strains from which it and our economic and monetary
paradigms emanated. When, for example, economists refer to the economy or to the market, they often
intend only that portion of the economy or market that is readily measureable, not the entire economy. It is
only when economic thought is linked up to real world outcomes and the whole economy that the flaws in
our thinking and practices become obvious and costly.


It was under the influence of this same industrial-age mindset that our monetary system and economic
tenets took root. But given what is now taking place, and what is now needed, it is time to review and
amend our modern beliefs, tenets, and systems with the same strength, conviction, and purpose as
Enlightenment leaders did with premodern European society.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

The general equilibrium theory and the GDP are emblematic of a mindset that, with all good intentions,
sought to make perfect sense of a world by taking into account only limited, readily quantifiable aspects
of our lives and activities. The tradeoffs and omissions that were made in the quest for mathematical
certitude and economic predictability, however, contributed instead to limited understandings and many
unintended, often costly consequences.

The same externalities that were excluded from traditional considerations constitute many of the very
practices and issues that now threaten the environment and society. Additionally, the solutions that are
required to address our concerns and bring about improvements simply are not to be found within the
confines of traditional economic thought and its limited set of tools. It is only by broadening our
understanding and by venturing outside, that solutions become both apparent and available.

CHAPTER NINE - Lessons from a Depression



A man is wise with the wisdom of his time only,

And ignorant with its ignorance.

~HENRY DAVID THOREAU

In 2008, the world economy went belly-up. Tens of millions of jobs and trillions of dollars of wealth
were lost. Few analysts saw the crisis coming. Preceding the recession, many economists were instead
congratulating themselves over the success of their field. Nobel laureate Robert Lucas, for instance,
declared in his 2003 presidential address to the American Economic Association that, [the] central
problem of depression-prevention had been solved.154 Lucas was not alone in his assessment. Another
Nobel laureate, Paul Krugman, notes that leading up to the downturn, many economists were, blind to the
very possibility of a catastrophic failure in a market economy.155

A few short years following the most severe downturn in seven decades, and the predictive failure by
the overwhelming majority of experts, confusion about the economy abounds. As occurred in the early
stages of the Great Depression, each hint of economic improvement is hailed by governments, banks, and
regulators as evidence of the end of the crisis. Such pronouncements, however, now as in the past, are
influenced by the apprehension that saying otherwise would only aggravate the situation. As The
Economist noted in its lead story on October 11, 2008: Confidence is everything in finance.156

But confidence in todays supposed economic recovery is not shared by all. At least some of the
countless millions of recent additions to the ranks of under- or unemployed, who struggle mostly in vain to
find jobs, are not likely to feel so optimistically inclined. They are joined by other concerned citizens
from around the world, and by a small but growing assembly of noted economists, including Krugman,
who, by mid-2010 stated on record that we are, in the early stages of a new depression.157 So-called
signs of economic recovery are instead seen by at least some experts as misleading and transitory,
reminiscent of what occurred during the 1930s.

History shows that periodic surges to the economy did occur in the early 1930s, but were short-lived. It
was not until years after the 1929 stock market crash that a depression was understood and acknowledged
to be taking place. Policymakers, Wall Street giants, economists, investors and many others back then had
failed to appreciate what was unfolding and misinterpreted each fleeting advance as the hoped-for
turnaround of the markets. But hope proved no match for faulty assumptions about how the economy
actually works, or the failures in policy that derived from such notions. The Great Depression would
persist for a decade and degenerate into the most catastrophic bust in modern history. In a number of
disconcerting ways, history is now repeating itself.

In the above-cited 2008 article regarding the downturn, The Economist went on to say: With a flawed
diagnosis of the causes of the crisis, it is hardly surprising that many policymakers have failed to
understand its progression.158 This is indeed the case, although in a more profound manner than is
generally appreciated.

A lot of energy and ink has been spent trying to allocate the blame for the recent disaster. Greed in the
financial sector, lack of oversight by regulators, policies that over-emphasize deregulation, and

incompetence at various levels, have all been cited. Our view is that any or all of these may have played
a role, but at the core we are dealing with a much deeper systemic issue related to our monetary
paradigm.

While the global recession is the biggest one since the 1930s, it isnt the first such crisis. Economic
troubles are, in fact, all too common. The World Bank has identified no less than 96 banking and 176
monetary crises in one 25-year-period alone, beginning with the floating exchange regime introduced by
U.S. President Nixon in the early 1970s. Additionally, long before this period, banking and monetary
crises were, in the words of historical economist Charles Kindleberger, hardly perennial.159
Kindleberger inventoried no less than 48 massive crashes between the 1637 tulip mania in Holland and
the stock market crash of 1929. According to the U.S. National Bureau of Economic Research, 47
recessions have befallen the United States alone since 1790, a dozen of which occurred in the decades
following the Great Depression.

These repeated breakdowns in different countries and times, under different regulatory environments,
and in economies with very different degrees of development, should be seen as telltale symptoms of an
underlying systemic, structural problem.

If such a deeper systemic issue is in fact involved, it would explain why each new set of regulations
achieves, at best, a reduction in the frequency of banking and monetary crises, without getting rid of them
or their horrific economic and sociopolitical costs. A deeper structural problem would also explain why
even some of the brightest and best educated people on the planet have not been able to avoid major
financial catastrophes, however diligently they do their work, whether on the regulatory or on the
financial services side. Finally, if our monetary system is in fact a structural accident waiting to happen,
then even if it were possible to perfectly control greed through innovative and tight regulations, such
measures would only defer when the next disaster will hit.

Until and unless there is review and amendment regarding these critical matters, we cannot expect an
end to repeated and costly financial disruptions, or realistically hope for lasting improvements to our
economies.

In support of our claims regarding the monetary paradigm and the relief that is possible with new
initiatives, we offer the following all-but-forgotten accounting regarding the role of complementary
currencies during the difficult Depression years in Europe and the United States.

COMPLEMENTARY CURRENCIES AND WW II



Scores of complementary currencies were in operation during the 1920s and 1930s, and included
initiatives from Germany, Austria, France, Italy, the Netherlands, Sweden, the Baltics, Canada, Mexico,
China, the United States, and other nations. Many programs were undertaken in response to the dramatic
conditions of the period, with the inability of communities large and small to meet their socioeconomic
needs. Two popular initiatives in Germany and Austria, and the U.S. response to complementary
currencies in the leadup to World War II, are of particular relevance today, and are explored next.

German Hyperinflation and the Wra System



The German economy and its currency had been in trouble for years prior to the depression. In 1913,
prior to the outbreak of World War I, one U.S. dollar was worth 4.2 German marks.160 By the time
Germanys inflation peaked a decade later in November 1923, the exchange rate for one dollar reached an
untenable 4.2 trillion marks. A postage stamp cost billions and a loaf of bread required a wheelbarrow
full of money. Almost one hundred million trillion German marks were then in circulation.161 Daily salary
negotiations preceded work, wages were paid twice per day, and earnings were typically spent within the
hour.

Sparked by these desperate conditions, people looked for alternative means to meet their needs. This
led to growing interest in complementary currencies, which was inspired in large part by the teachings of
Silvio Gesell, a merchant-turned-social activist and economist. Gesell founded the principles of modern
demurrage and advocated its use as a means to help ensure moneys circulation (see insert).

Silvio Gesell, Demurrage, and the Wra

Much of the credit for the understanding and use of demurrage in the 20th century is attributed to
Silvio Gesell, who provided a modern theoretical framework for this practice.
Gesells ideas regarding demurrage derived from railroad and shipping vessel practices. The
quicker a freight train or cargo ship could be unloaded and reloaded, the greater its earning power.
To encourage quicker turn-arounds, a charge was levied for the time the train or vessel remained
unused, beyond an allotted time for unpacking. The term coined for this purpose was demurrage
(from the French verb, demeurer, to delay).
Gesells interest in economics and money derived from his own personal experience with
downturns. In 1887, Gesell moved from Europe to Buenos Aires where he went to work in his
brother's business. But a depression in Argentina hurt the business considerably and led Gesell to
reflect upon the structural problems caused by the monetary system. In 1891, Gesell released his first
writing on this topic: The Reformation Of The Monetary System As A Bridge To A Just State,
followed by Nervus Rerum and The Nationalization Of Money. He left the business with his brother
and returned to Europe in 1892, where he studied economics and worked for decades on monetary
reform.
In 1929 an organization based on Gesells teachings was formed in Germany. Its name was the
Wra (VAIR-a) Tauschgesellschaft (or Wra Trading Company).162 The founders coined the term
Wra, which is a combination of the German words Ware (goods) and Whrung (currency).
The aim of the Wra Trading Company was to fight stagnation of the market and unemployment.163
It issued a currencythe Wra billwhich had a small monthly demurrage charge in the form of a
stamp fee to ensure that the currency would circulate and not be hoarded.

The Wra stamp scrip (a currency with a stamp fee) drew international attention after its success in the
German community of Schwanenkirchen.

Up until hyperinflation, the largest employer and economic mainstay of Schwanenkirchen had been the
local coalmine. But like many other businesses in Germany during the 1920s, it was forced to file for
bankruptcy. Operations were shut down and the coalmine went on sale for 8,000 reichsmarks, far below
its estimated value.


One former production engineer wanted to purchase the mine, but could not get a bank loan. Max
Hebecker instead decided to apply the concept of the Gesell-inspired Wra stamp. Hebecker gathered the
miners, local shopkeepers, and others that would be affected by the new local currency. He explained to
all that the coalmine could be reopened, but only if each were willing to accept payment in Wra scrip in
replacement of the virtually worthless national currency. The coal inventory extracted from the mine
would provide the backing for the scrip. Following a lively exchange, all parties finally agreed.

The decision to accept the complementary currency turned out to be economically very sound. During a
time when many other businesses and communities in Germany were struggling to survive, the Wra not
only saved the coalmine and revitalized the local economy, but also began to circulate nationally.

Over 2,000 businesses throughout Germany were soon accepting and paying one another with Wra
scrip. Many banks even opened Wra accounts. The Wras great success, however, also turned out to be
its downfall.


Germanys central bank, the Reichsbank, grew concerned over the popularity of the Wra and other
local currencies then in circulation. The relief to businesses during the difficult downturn, and the longerterm potential benefits provided by these complementary currencies to the national economy (and to the
banking system itself), were outweighed by their perceived threats to the hegemony in the issuance of
money by the central bank. Consequently, in October 1931, by legislative action through the Brningsche
Notverordnungen, (Brnings Emergency Regulations, named after Heinrich Brning, then Germanys
Reichs-chancellor and foreign minister), the Wra and other complementary currencies were declared
illegal in Germany.164

Two years following the banishment of complementary currencies, as the economy continued to
plummet, a dramatic shift took hold of the German political landscape.

Rise of the Nazi Party

The repression of complementary currencies, together with other anti-inflationary decisions by the
Reichsbank, led to a sharp decline in the German money supply.165 This resulted in the shut down of the
Schwanenkirchen mine and hundreds of other businesses. Unemployment thus soared once again.

Given that the reigning monetary monopoly made it increasingly more difficult for people to help
themselves on a local level, advocates of centralized solutions gained appeal. In the beer halls of
Bavaria, an obscure Austrian immigrant began drawing audiences to his fiery speeches, with promises of
a return to jobs and glory. His name was Adolph Hitler.

Some may consider the simultaneous ban of complementary currencies, deterioration of economic
conditions, and the rise of radical authoritarian political ideology as unrelated coincidental occurrences
isolated to Germany. It should be noted, however, that a nearly identical set of circumstances was taking
hold concurrently in neighboring Austria.

Austria and the Wrgl



When Michael Untergugenberger was elected mayor of Wrgl, Austria, he faced high unemployment and a
near-penniless constituency. He had a long list of projects he wished to accomplish, along with many
willing and able people to do the work. But only 40,000 shillings remained in the bankjust enough to
pay the salaries of about 20 people for one month, a pittance compared to the cost of what was needed.

Rather than spend the last of the limited funds on a long list of projects, the mayor instead put the money
on deposit with a local bank as a guarantee for 40,000 shillings worth of Wrgls own complementary
labor certificates, officially termed Banknotenausweis, which soon came to be referred to simply as the
Wrgl (VUR-gul). Like the German Wra, the Wrgl was a stamp scrip that included a relief tax,
which was actually a demurrage charge applied through a stamp affixed each month at 1 percent of face
value. As with other demurrage charges, this relief tax acted as an incentive to keep the currency in
circulation. Those paid in Wrgl made sure to spend it quickly. The extra money in circulation led to
additional employment opportunities in the community.

The Austrian Wrgl, like the German Wra, was a dramatic success. Wrgl quickly became the only
town in Austria with full employment. This was made possible through the rapid circulation of the local
stamp scrip, which was estimated to have created eight times more employment than national shillings
would have. The demurrage-charged, anti-hoarding feature proved particularly effective as a spontaneous
work-generating device.

Swiss essayist Alex von Muralt, who investigated the Wrgl at the time, reported the mayors delighted
comments that, taxes were eagerly paidin a number of instances in advance.166 Following his
investigation, Von Muralt concluded:


This eagerness to pay taxes may be, in my opinion, simply owing to the fact that the businessman
who finds at the close of the month that he holds a considerable amount in relief money [Wrgl], can
dispose of it with the greatest ease and without loss by meeting his parish [local tax] obligations. A
change of attitude has manifestly taken place. If formerly the paying of taxes was deferred to the last,
now it occupies first place.167

Word of the Wrgls success spread. More than 200 other towns and villages in Austria wanted to
adopt this complementary currency system to address their own economic concerns. The French Prime
Minister, Edouard Dalladier, made a special visit to see first-hand the miracle of Wrgl.

It was at that point that the Austrian central bank reacted. Like its German counterpart, the central bank
decided to assert its monopoly rights, making it a criminal offense to issue the currency. The
complementary currency was banned and in a very short span of time following, the town of Wrgl
returned to 30 percent unemployment. Predictably, as in neighboring Germany, Austrias economy
continued to decline.

During the Anschluss of 1938the occupation and annexation of Austria into Nazi Germanymany
Austrians openly welcomed Adolph Hitler as their economic and political savior.

Americas Fateful Decision



The success of the Wrgl soon caught the attention of U.S. policy makers, who were then struggling with
the Great Depression and massive unemployment. Conversations ensued between Yale professor and
noted economist Irving Fisher, Harvard economics professor Russell Sprague, and Undersecretary of the
Treasury, Dean Acheson. Each became convinced that the Wrgl model offered a clear and prompt way
out of the Depression. Fisher stated for the record: The correct application of stamp scrip would solve
the Depression crisis in the United States in three weeks!168

The three men met with President Roosevelt in which a Wrgl-type scrip was recommended. Fisher
reported that though Roosevelt was himself impressed, the final decision regarding complementary
currencies was left to advisors who instead favored a series of new centralized programs for which
political credit could be more easily claimed. These new programs included the expansion of the
Reconstruction Finance Corporation and large-scale work-creation projects managed by the Federal
government, all part of what would eventually become popularly known as The New Deal.

The emergency currencies, the code name given for complementary currencies, were banned by
executive decree. This ban applied to any and all such currencies then in existence and any that might be
proposed. No official reason is known to have been given for the ban. The end result, however, was that
the United States failed to take advantage of such monetary innovations to address the economic crisis of
the 1930s.

Contrary to popular belief, the centralized initiatives taken by the Roosevelt administration did not
actually pull the United States out of the Great Depression. Certainly, the public works programs that
were enacted did provide employment opportunities to many hard-working people and built vast, vital
public infrastructure that we take for granted even today. But most economic historians today agree that
the U.S. economic recovery was due mainly to the war effort. Roosevelt himself declared this to be the
case, stating: It was Dr. Win-the-War, not Dr. New Deal, that ended the Depression!169

It bears noting that the disregard of such a solution by the United States is ironical given the particular
history and struggles of this nation regarding monetary matters. Complementary currencies were in
widespread use in the American colonies prior to its struggle for independence from Great Britain.
Colonial scrip, the term given to these currencies, was issued in each of the thirteen colonies, beginning
with Massachusetts in 1669 and ending with Virginia in 1755. The suppression of this scrip with the
Currency Act of 1764 by the English Parliament has even sometimes been presented as a cause for the
American Revolution.170

Social and Political Lessons



What may initially appear to be boring technical decisions related to banking and currency matters are
found to hold profound social and political implications. It cannot be irrefutably proven that Hitler would
not have been elected, or that Anschluss and World War II would have been avoided, had complementary
currencies such as the Wra and the Wrgl been allowed to flourish. Many other variables certainly
impacted upon such sweeping phenomena as well. Nonetheless, historical records do clearly show that
the suppression of these popular grassroots initiatives had a significant negative impact on employment
and the economy in both Germany and Austria. It is also quite evident that deteriorating economic
conditions contributed directly to the degeneration of these sophisticated democracies into ruthless
dictatorships that went on to embroil the world in conflict.

Monetary crises invariably provoke fear, despair, and anger. This is an explosive social mix that
reckless demagogues can and do exploit, even today. What started as a monetary problem in the former
Yugoslavia, for example, was aggravated by the IMF readjustment program, and degenerated into
intolerance toward others. Minorities were used as scapegoats by ethnic leaders to redirect anger away
from themselves and toward a common enemy, providing the sociopolitical context for extreme nationalist
leaders, such as Milosevic in Serbia, to reassert their power. Within days of the 1998 monetary crisis in
Indonesia, mobs were incited to violence against Chinese and other minorities. Similarly, in Russia,
discrimination against minorities was aggravated by the financial collapse of the 1990s.

Just months prior to such economic disturbances, few among the intelligentsia in these countries had
imagined the possibility of such dramatic social turmoil. Yet, particular monetary decisions dramatically
impacted the economies and sociopolitical framework of their societies. It is often forgotten that until the
monetary collapse of the 1920s and the takeover by the Nazis, Germany was among the most advanced,
educated, and cultured nations on Earth. Outlawing well-designed local currencies likely contributed to
the tragic events of that period.

Monetary issues are often painted in purely technical terms, supposedly to be left for so-called experts
to resolve. As has been amply demonstrated down through history, however, monetary and financial
problems become a most explosive powder keg with formidable social and political effects.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

A seemingly endless series of financial crises have plagued the worlds financial system for centuries.
The fact that these crises recur in all kinds of economies and nations on a continuing basis, points to a
systemic root issue.

Highly successful complementary currency initiatives in the years preceding WWII offer us important
lessons. The Wra and Wrgl each produced nearly miraculous results in turning around the local
economies at a time when the national economies were in dramatic decline. In America, similar
complementary currency programs were advocated on a national basis to deal with the ongoing
depression. One noted economist, Irving Fisher, estimated that such measures would bring about the end
of the contraction in a matter of weeks. But President Roosevelt instead opted for the New Deal and
America languished economically until WWII.

Economic concerns have important social implications. Before the Nazi period, Germany was widely
regarded as one of the most civilized nations on Earth. Monetary crises cause great turbulence, which
demagogues exploit. The lessons of Germany, Austria, and many other nations serve as important
historical reminders for us all. Money matters are intrinsically linked to many important societal
concerns.

CHAPTER TEN - The Blind Spot



The real voyage of discovery

consists not in seeking new landscapes,

But in having new eyes.

~MARCEL PROUST

The human eye has a biological blind spot, a place in the visual field of the retina through which the optic
nerve passes, where we literally cant see anything. Traditional economics has a collective blind spot as
well regarding one of the most coveted and influential of all human creationsmoney. This blindness is
directly linked to many of our most vital concerns.

A few of the many consequences of this collective blind spot are briefly examined below, along with a
few of the mechanisms for its existence and continuance. We begin with a look at how our lack of
understanding regarding money impacts the enduring divide regarding intervention in the marketplace.

ECONOMIC DOCTRINE AND MONEY



One of the many profound effects of the Great Depression was the specter of doubt it cast upon the
predominant classical notion that an economy functions best when left to its own devices. Neoliberal free
market orthodoxy has long maintained that public intervention into the private marketplace is misguided
and unnecessary because intrinsic market forces can and will self-correct any disruptions such as the
periodic ups and downs of the economy, especially over the long run. This perspective dominated
economic thought prior to the 1930s.

A rare dissenter to such free market notions was the celebrated depression-era economist John
Maynard Keynes. The job losses and prolonged suffering of the period prompted Keynes famous quip:
The long run is a misleading guide to current affairs. In the long run we are all dead.171

It bears recalling that the drastic decline of the world economy during the 1930s persisted for the better
part of a decade in many countries, and finally came to an end only due to a world war. In stark contrast to
free market beliefs, the revolutionary idea of Keynes was that in the event of a significant market
disruption, timely and sufficient intervention was mandated to restore the economy. He further argued that
the only entity with the capacity to intercede in a sufficient manner was government.

A bit of review, however, reveals how our collective blindness with regard to money calls into
question key underlying assumptions on both sides of this long-standing economic divide between
neoliberal non-interventionists, and neo-Keynesian interventionists.

With regard to free market theory, a marketplace that is restrained by a monopoly in the issuance of
money, with the predominance of one type of bank-debt money, should be considered anything but free.
Our centuries-old monetary and banking paradigms continually reinforce a circumscribed set of
industrial-age values and a narrow range of predictable outcomes, including: widespread scarcity, the
concentration of wealth, short-term investment patterns, the amplification of the business cycle, and the
resultant lack of not only meaningful work but sufficient job opportunities of any kind. Moreover, and
again contrary to commonly-held notions of free markets, todays globalized economic reality demands
increasing conformity by virtually all its many participants, no matter their particular and oftentimes
diverse socioeconomic requirements or aspirations. In essence, our monetary state of affairs not only preempts the possibility of a genuinely free market, but instead mandates strict compliance and the continued
intervention by central banks and government to try and restore stability to an inherently unstable system.
Free market doctrine in fact endorses a free market for virtually everything except the structure of the
monetary system itself, and instead accepts the monopoly of bank-debt-based money as an economic fact
of life.

The same blind spot regarding money also undermines Keynesian-type interventions into the
marketplace. It has been argued, for instance, that the emergency measures undertaken by the Bush and
Obama administrations, with the Troubled Assets Relief Program (TARP) and historic stimulus packages,
were necessary to prop up the banks and avert a general economic meltdown. But to what end? The influx
of trillions of dollars to the banks and other financial giants has not significantly impeded any of the highrisk activities by Wall Street that contributed to the most recent crash. Nor have these interventions
resulted in notable job creation or increased liquidity to Main Street, several years later. These packages
have instead diverted already-scarce public funds from other important socioeconomic concerns.
Additionally, this allocation of taxpayers money, by definition, comes in the form of interest bearing,

bank-debt currency, which was borrowed by governmentand at a time when deficit spending was
already dangerously high. The obligation to repay these loans with interest only serves to further
aggravate the already-heavy burdens on the current population, and is likely to adversely affect future
generations of taxpayers as well.

With regard to repayment liabilities, it should be noted that whenever a bank deemed too big to fail
gets in real trouble, the recipe has been the same since the 1930s: the taxpayers end up footing the bill,
thus allowing these banks to start all over again.

For each of the 97 major banking crashes around the world in recent decades, taxpayer bailouts have
been the answer in every instance. The U.S. Reconstruction Finance Corporation from 1932-53, for
example, was funded by government by way of taxpayer money. The U.S. government repeated the
exercise from 1989-95 with the Resolution Trust Corporation for the Savings and Loan crisis, and once
again with TARP in 2008. Other recent examples include the Swedish Bank Support Authority from 199296, and the Japanese Resolution and Collection Corporation, still ongoing, which started in 1996. During
the 2008 crisis, among the first institutions saved in this manner were Bear Stearns in the United States
and Northern Rock in the United Kingdom. Likewise, in October 2008, European governments pledged an
unprecedented 1.873 trillion euros, combining credit guarantees and capital injections into banks, all by
means of taxpayer money.


In essence, having overlooked the structure of the monetary system itself, each side of the economic
chasm unwittingly contributes to outcomes that are quite inconsistent with its own cherished ideals and
stated objectives. Supposedly free markets wind up requiring burdensome and expensive intervention.
Keynesian-type deficit measures instead leave in their wake massive debt, oppressing taxpayers and
society. Our collective blind spot renders traditional economics incapable of addressing the deeper
systemic issues that contribute to our many repeated financial and economic crises.

How did this blindness come to be, and why does it persist?

Collective Conditioning

Our modern monetary and banking paradigms were not arbitrary designs that merely came into being
without context. These systems are, as previously mentioned, reflections of a set of perceptions, beliefs,
values, and objectives that emerged in Western Europe with the Enlightenment and the industrialization
model that followed, and which, centuries later, continues to spread around the world. The particular
competitive, hierarchical, and wealth-concentrating orientations of these systems, however, are not
exclusive to our modern age, but can be seen as well in the monetary systems as well as the cultures of
civilizations down through the ages, including ancient Sumer, Babylon, Greece, Rome, and Western
society from the Renaissance all the way up until today.

Each of the aforementioned societies had in common a patriarchal emphasis accompanied by a
monopoly of a single currency. That currency was imposed from the top down, was hierarchically issued,
was either naturally scarce or maintained such scarcity artificially, and carried positive interest rates. The
particular forms of these currencies varied widely, from standardized commodities and precious metals to
pieces of paper and electronic bits. But each society held in common the crucial agreement that only their
one specific currency could be used for payment of taxes, that this currency could be stored and
accumulated, and that borrowing of the currency required payment of interest.

It bears noting that even societies and economies with very different ideologies, such as communism
and capitalism, nonetheless share at least one trait in commonthey all impose a monopoly of bank-debt
money. The one main difference between the two ideologies with regard to their monetary and banking
paradigms is that the banks in communist countries are state owned, while the banks in capitalist nations
are privately held, with the occasional exception occurring during bank-related crises when governments
must step in, as occurred with the downturn of 2008. While the ideological warfare between capitalism
and communism has placed considerable emphasis on the myriad ways in which the two systems differ,
their nearly identical monetary paradigm has been almost totally overlooked. This oversight is yet another
expression of our long-standing, collective monetary blind spot.

Down through history, societies that instead tended toward a matrifocal orientationwhereby feminine
values are honored as well, with a greater balance between feminine and masculine perspectiveswere
more inclined to make use of very different monetary structures.

Several prominent matrifocal civilizations are known to have embraced a dual-currency system instead
of a monoculture of one type of money. The first currency was used for trading long distance with
foreigners, and was very similar to those used by more patriarchal societies. The second type of currency
was, however, quite different, as it was mainly exchanged within and created by the local community, was
issued in sufficiency, and didnt bear interest. In the more sophisticated cases, this local currency even
had a demurrage fee that, as mentioned previously, systematically discouraged accumulation, and instead
promoted ongoing circulation of this currency as a pure medium of exchange, not as a store of value. This
was the case, for instance, with the corn-backed currencies used for more than a millennium in Dynastic
Egypt during the time of the Pharaohs, and was one of the secrets of that ancient societys remarkable
wealth. Another example, as noted, is the Central Middle Ages in Western Europe, whereby various local
currencies contributed substantially to the remarkable collective wealth and wellbeing of the epoch. The
link between the money and cultural values of these societies are examined in greater depth in Part IV of
this book.

Institutionalized Status Quo



Sometime during the 18th and the 19th centuries, a decision was made that the monopoly of a single
currency issued through bank debt should be institutionalized. The particular body charged with that role
in each country is its own central bank, with the IMF and the World Bank each added to the panoply
following ratification of the Bretton Woods agreement in 1945. These institutions have important and
useful tasks in preserving the integrity of the overall financial system. They are also the guardians of the
prevailing monetary orthodoxy and its core tenetthat achieving the objective of monetary stability
requires safeguarding the monopoly of the existing money creation process as well as that of a single
national currency, one in each country or group of countries. Though created to safeguard the economy,
these institutions are nonetheless afflicted by the same collective blindness regarding money. Thus, they
preserve the very orthodoxy that has gotten us in trouble time and again, which spawns and then protects
banks that can become too big to fail, and which dispels any action to review and amend our monetary
and banking systems. This institutionalized status quo serves to insulate us not from harm but from
detection and amendment of our collective blind spot regarding money. Consequently, the ongoing
industrial-age paradigm continues to reign unquestioned.

Challenging the status quo in any field is always a daunting business, and is particularly so with the
monetary paradigm given the influence of money and the collective lack of understanding regarding it
nature. But it is precisely because of its unique influence as well as its inherent potential for improvement
to our world that we must endeavour to better understand and make greater use of this singular humanmade creationmoney.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

From its very inception, traditional economics has suffered from a blind spot with regard to money. This
failing is attested to by the fact that, while the vast majority of economists universally regard monopolies
as destructive, the monopoly of one type of money has continued unchallenged from Adam Smith onward.
This collective blindness with regard to money, shared by layperson and expert alike, is the source of a
number of concerns and consequences, catalogued in this Part I.

Our money journey continues in Part II with a look at some of the many monetary tools that are readily
available to address important issues of our day, and the pragmatic possibilities that exist to create a
better world, made possible by rethinking money.

As it happens, growing numbers of communities from around the world are rethinking money. Their
efforts are helping to show us innovative, pragmatic ways and means by which to match unmet needs with
unused resources.

PART II - NEW MONEY



Society will, only a few generations from now,

be as different from modern industrial society

as that is from a society in the Middle Ages.

~WILLIS HARMAN

CHAPTER ELEVEN - Great Change



Every few hundred years in Western history, there occurs a sharp transformation. Within a few short
decades, societyits worldview, its basic values, its social and political structures, its arts, its key
institutionsrearranges itselfWe are currently living through such a time.

~PETER DRUCKER

In 1900, there was not a single airport, television set, or credit card. There was no theory of relativity, no
quantum mechanics, and no GDP. Genetics, immunology, and endocrinology did not yet exist, and
hormone was not even a word. Hollywood was a bunch of farms and the sun never set on the British
Empire. The life expectancy was 47.6 years for Caucasian-Americans, while for African-Americans it
was a mere 33.0 years.172 The worlds 1.7 billion people lived and worked mostly in rural
surroundings,173 and the overwhelming majority of women around the world could not vote.

A generation or so ago, there was no e-mail, no laptops, or DVDs; no ATMs, subprime mortgages, or
euro. Chinas economy was mostly agricultural, Eastern Europe was under the grip of the Soviet Union,
and apartheid continued its reign in South Africa. There was not yet a single reported case of AIDS, the
concepts of sustainability and climate change were first beginning to enter mainstream awareness, and the
worlds population had more than doubled since 1900.174

In early 2007, Japans industrial output reached an all-time high,175 Lehman Brothers was the fourthlargest U.S. investment bank,176 and for the first time ever, a woman led in an American presidential
primary. By late 2008, Japanese output sank to its lowest level on record, Lehman Brothers was
bankrupt,177 and the U.S. presidential elections made history.

Other milestones in 2008 included: the worst quarterly losses by one corporation ($61.7 billion by
AIG),178 the greatest annual earnings by another corporation ($45 billion by Exxon Mobil),179 tens of
millions of job losses, the lowest interest rates by the Bank of England since its founding in 1694,180 and
the most dire warnings to date regarding climate change.181 In early 2009, a century or so after the first
Wright Brothers flight of 120 feet in 12 seconds, NASA launched the Kepler Mission in search of other
habitable planets in our galaxy, while here on Earth, President Obama took office, inherited the worst
economy since the 1930s, and signed off on the largest stimulus bill in history.182

As 2012 approached, political, social, and economic tensions mounted around the world. Regime
changes swept across the Middle East and North Africa as part of the so-called Arab Spring. Austerity
measures aimed at dealing with the growing debt crisis led to protests in Greece and other parts of
Europe. The Indignants Movement in Spain called for radical economic and political reform. The ongoing
Occupy Movement, which began in Kuala Lumpur on July 30, 2011, with Occupy Dataran, spread to Wall
Street and by November, 2011, to more than 2,300 towns and cities across the globe. And the worlds
population had more than quadruppled since 1900 to 7 billion.

We are living in a time of epic transformation. Though extraordinary in its breadth, scope, and
potential, many of the undercurrents of societal change have happened before. Such shifts, referred to as
Big Change, are described by systems scientist and nonlinear dynamicist Sally Goerner as like a seventh
wave swollen with streams from many directions, sweeping away the social reality and worldview that

was, leaving new ones in their wake.183 Former instances of Big Change include the fall of the Roman
Empire, the rise and fall of the Central Middle Ages, and the Age of Enlightenment.

As in the 1700s, many entrenched ways of being and doing are increasingly in conflict with the realities
and requirements of our time. This is particularly the case with our industrial-age economic tenets,
financial institutions, business practices, and banking and monetary paradigms. As in the past, there are
mounting calls for reform and change.

But what types of reforms? What manner of change?


Though there is growing recognition that we are in the midst of a postindustrial shift, many questions
remain about what this will mean in practice. Consensus on how to tackle the issues of our day is also
lacking. Whatever measures are taken must speak to a number of inconvenient truths.

Author and educator Duane Elgin notes:

Never before has humanity been on the verge of devastating the Earths biosphere and crippling its
ecological foundations for countless generations to come. Never before has the entire human family
been required to work together to build a sustainable and meaningful future. Never before have so
many people been called to make such sweeping changes in so little time.184

In addition, history cautions us that societal transformations are often associated with tumult and loss.
The philosopher Alfred North Whitehead observed that, it is the first step in sociological wisdom to
recognize that the major advances in civilization are processes which all but wreck the society in which
they occur.185 Though accurate, Whiteheads reflection is not uniform and applies mainly to those who
still cling to former belief structures. The shift into the Central Middle Ages, for example, appears to have
been a mostly peaceful, constructive process that improved conditions on a broad scale. A similar
prospect exists in our time.

Notwithstanding the enormity of the task before us, there are whispers of cautious optimism by a small-

but-growing body of respected scientists, sociologists, economists, and others. Each has identified in
todays shift the potential not only to address our many concerns, but to realize vast improvements for the
whole of humanity. It is one of todays many great ironies that at the very moment we find ourselves
confronted by a host of unparalleled challenges, there is concurrently the potential for the greatest positive
transformation in all of recorded history. The key word, however, is potential. A better future is not
assured us but will depend heavily upon an informed general public and leadership that together make
informed decisions.

In Part II, we look at some of the many obvious and not-so- obvious reasons for hope in our time. We
will focus on insights and strategies, particularly within the monetary and economic arenas, that can help
bring about significant revitalization. We will also examine some of the many reasons why the current
societal shift is the first instance in recorded history of a phenomenon referred to as Great Change.186

TOWARDS GREAT CHANGE



Todays shift distinguishes itself from others in myriad ways, including its extent and impact. Its epicenter
is not restricted to any one people or region but is instead erupting in many places at once, influencing the
full spectrum of human and natural habitats, from Wall Street, Main Street, and the remote villages of the
developing world to virtually every living system on Earth. Everyone and everything is affected.

This shift is accompanied as well by an epic progression in perceptions. As noted, our seemingly vast
and ever-abundant planet, whose great mysteries were once explained by myth and dogma, was widely
held to be the center of the universe. Scientific inquiry and a new modernist worldview came into being
and transformed many things: from our understanding of planetary orbits, governance, and economics to
humanitys place in the cosmic order.

As yet another perspective takes hold, today, change is upon us once again. With many times more
people, greenhouse gases, peak oil, shrinking forests, and other diminishing resources, our world appears
far more finite, vulnerable, and complex. Physicists are now seriously postulating an intricate, quantum
multiverse, composed of infinitesimal strings, space, and energy, with many more than three dimensions.
We are discovering that biological systems, humans included, are governed not only by DNA but by a
genetic setting that includes billions of microbes and trillions of viruses living in symbiosis within each
of us, all working together in ways that leave our mind mysteriously free to focus on getting our bodies to
the office and wondering whats for lunch.187 Additionally, we are discovering that human biology is
governed not only by inherited genetics but by attitudes and lifestyle choices, as revealed by the newlynamed discipline of epigenetics.

In short, we are living with multiple potential realities simultaneously coexisting at the same point in
time. This changes many things, including a new multidimensionality and framework in the acquisition of
knowledge. Systems analyst Jamshid Gharajedaghi writes:

There is a shift in our understanding of the nature of the beast from a mindless mechanical system to
a multi-minded socio-cultural system[and] in our way of knowing: from analytical thinking, the
science of dealing with independent sets of variables, to systems thinking, the art and science of
handling interdependent sets of variables.188

In a radical departure from Modernism, with its dismissal of entire realms of inquiry, a new, greatly
expanded and dynamic framework is emerging. This new inquiry retains the rigor and empiricism of
modern science while greatly expanding and enhancing the picture. It allows one to go into almost any
field of inquiry and organize outlier insights that include and integrate information from a much broader
range of sources: past as well as present; Eastern as well as Western; traditional as well as contemporary;
intuitive and experiential as well as empirical and mathematical; interdisciplinary, multidisciplinary, and
transdisciplinary as well as conventional areas of inquiry. Whereas modern science has been built around
materialism, reductionism, linear causality, and disorder, new science is oriented towards energy flow,
inclusion, complex causality, and systemic patterns that hide beneath the chaos of local vicissitudes.189
Hardly anything appears quite the same.

The medical realm is one example, and helps to illustrate the broader shift now taking place.

Integrative Medicine

Modern medicine views patients, illness, and disease in material terms, with emphasis on the physical
body separate from the mind and spirit. It directs treatment accordingly around surgery, pharmaceuticals,
and germicides. Its orientation is analytical, mechanistic, and reductionist, not systemic. As a result,
modern medicine has not been very successful in dealing with system-based diseases, including three of
the leading causes of death: cancer, diabetes, and heart disease.

Integrative medical programs instead complement conventional techniques with alternative therapies
such as acupuncture, Ayurveda, biofeedback, chiropractic, yoga, and diet-based therapies, each of which
conceptualizes the body as matter/energy/flow systems. This new framework takes a holistic, systems
approach toward the understanding, treatment, and prevention of illness and disease.

Decades ago, few patients or practitioners in the West knew much about nontraditional therapies. This
is no longer the case. In Britain, 42 percent of all physicians now routinely make referrals to
homeopaths.190 Most European pharmacies dedicate more shelf space to herbal medicines than to
pharmaceutical drugs. In America, there are more visits to unconventional therapy providers than to
primary care physicians.191

John Astin of Stanford Universitys School of Medicine offers the following interpretation for this shift:

Users of alternative health care are more likely to report having had a transformational experience
that changed the way they saw the worldThey find in [alternative therapies] an acknowledgment of
the importance of treating illness within a larger context of spirituality and life meaning The use of
alternative care is part of a broader value orientation and set of cultural beliefs, one that embraces a
holistic, spiritual orientation to life.192

It should be noted that this shift away from strict reliance on conventional medicine hinged on robust
empirical evidence that predated its general acceptance by decades. The grassroots movement toward
holistic medicine began in the face of once considerable opposition to alternative methodologies by
conventional medicine. A similar phenomenon is occurring presently in the monetary and economic
realms.

Monetary, Economic, and Social Change



For years preceding the global financial crisis, Wall Street enjoyed stunning windfall profits, seemingly
affirming the logic of the reigning neoclassical orthodoxy. Yet, despite boom numbers, soaring indicators
such as the GDP, and the certitudes of an impressive list of free market adherents, a groundswell of
disenchantment grew in opposition to the direction of the economy, as smaller players, developing
countries, and the environment struggled. One expression of the growing divide was a grassroots
explosion of complementary currency initiatives, from a mere handful in the 1980s to thousands today in
diverse communities globally. With regard to current economic policies and direction, dissatisfaction
appears to be at a record high. In late 2009, twenty years after the fall of the Berlin Wall, a BBC poll was
conducted across 27 countries from around the world. Only 11 percent of those questioned said that the
dominant economic framework was working well.193 Though these opinions were very likely influenced
by the then-current economic downturn, discontent with the economic order has been mounting steadily
for decades.

In the largest survey of its kind ever undertaken, with cumulative surveys involving 100,000 adult
Americans and 500 focus groups conducted over a 13-year period, a significant portion of the U.S.
population was found to hold views that diverged from mainstream thought and the economic status quo.
Unlike the aforementioned BBC poll, this study was conducted years prior to the recession, during a
period of relative stability (1987 to 1999). As reported by researchers Paul Ray and Sherry Anderson in
The Cultural Creatives: How 50 Million People Are Changing the World,194 the findings indicated that
the value orientation of tens of millions of Americans was not adequately reflected in mainstream
business, finance, politics, and culture. The many issues cited included:

concerns with big business and the means used to generate profits;
practices that exploited resources and poorer countries;
the effects of globalization;
the lack of meaningful work;
mass consumption;
materialism;
womens issues in business and other realms;
and a number of quality-of-life concerns.
There was a willingness to pay higher taxes for improvements and a desire that government spend more
money on education, community programs, and support for a more ecologically sustainable future.
Political affiliations varied, but many of those surveyed considered themselves independents, not aligned
with any political party.

No detailed survey similar to that of Ray and Andersons has yet covered the globe. In 1997, however,
the European Unions monthly Euro-Barometer surveyed all its member nations, employing the same
values-based questionnaire.195 The findings mirrored those cited above, with at least as many Europeans
sharing values similar to those of their American counterparts. Similar results were obtained elsewhere
and were as strongly felt in developing countries as in developed ones.196

Many of those who share similar views are likely participants in what author and social activist Paul
Hawken more recently referred to as the largest and fastest growing social movement in history. In his

book, Blessed Unrest: How The Largest Movement in the World Came Into Being and Why No One Saw
It Coming (2009), Hawken estimates that several million organizations, mostly nonprofits (NGOs), are
working to tackle economic, social, environmental, and other concerns in communities of virtually every
nation around the world.197 Without much fanfare, their efforts, ingenuity, and creativity are addressing
many issues not being attended to by government. These findings mirror Ray and Andersons depiction of
a new culture being created. As this subgroups numbers of this subgroup steadily climb, so does its
impact on civil society and the transformation now taking hold.

In essence, a new worldview is emerging. Its perspective embraces input from many diverse points of
view, and is aligned with a new stage of science increasingly identified as integral science.198 This
moniker proclaims a profound relationship between values orientation and emerging science. The integral
approach is providing insights and benefits in many domains. In medicine, for example, it has led to
breakthroughs in the treatment and prevention of a wide range of disorders.

The same holds true for new monetary choices and economic reforms. For the first time in history,
using the same precision and language demanded by scientists, it can now be shown why complementary
monetary initiatives and the financial reforms demanded by mounting numbers of concerned citizens are
not only popular but empirically valid. This indeed changes many important things.

New approaches now make it possible to demonstrate why:

it is far better for the economy to engage in sustainable development rather than mere growth;
a healthy economy requires resilience, not just efficiency;
policies that favor Wall Street over Main Street are contraindicated on grounds of
counterproductivity;
a vibrant, stable economy depends as much if not more upon many healthy smaller players as it does
upon a small number of big guys;
caring for our young, the elderly, our environment, and natural resources are not just morally sound,
but are also empirically and economically the correct choices.
New evidence also explains why an assortment of currencies working alongside and complementing
our national currency system is of benefit to all, and why monopolies of any kindparticularly a
monopoly in the issuance of moneyis neither sustainable nor in our collective interest.

In essence, the integrative scientific and economic framework affirms:

the triple bottom line approach of building social, economic, and environmental health;
the rediscovery of Adam Smiths original vision of free enterprise networks;
and the vital role played by complementary currencies towards the realization of the kind of
sustainable vitality that reliably maintains and enhances the health and well-being of all levels of our
global civilization.
For these reasons alone, the transformation now taking place is quite significant. But other vital reasons
add to the enormity of what is currently happening, and deserve brief mention here.

A Milestone for Humanity



In historical terms, a new worldview is a very rare occurrence, and as such represents in and of itself a
significant shift. The advent of an integrative culture implies an even greater milestone for humanity.
Unlike the old changing of the guard, with the replacement of the medieval religious mindset by
Modernism, what is occurring now is more than a simple reaction to and substitution of one worldview
by another.

In the words of John Astin:

The appearance of this integrative culture is about healing the old splits: between the inner and outer,
spiritual and material, individual and society. The possibility of a new culture centers on
reintegration of what has been fragmented by Modernism: self-integration and authenticity;
integration with community and connection with others around the globe, not just at home; connection
with nature and learning to integrate ecology and economy; and a synthesis of diverse views and
traditions.199

What appears to be unfolding is a reemergence and healing of human energies and values that have long
been repressed in society. The evolutionary shift from modernist to integrative values is of such
importance that it can only be compared with the move toward reason in classical Greece, with one
significant differencethe current transformation is bound to be much faster. Greek rationalism took
centuries to spread to other areas of the Mediterranean world. Civilization had to wait many more
centuries still for the Renaissance and the Enlightenment to finally mainstream these concepts into
everyday life and spread them around the world. In contrast, as events in our present world and societies
demonstrate, the shift toward integrative values is already occurring at the speed of a veritable tidal
wave.

For these reasons and others considered later in this book, the current transformation is considered to
be the first instance of Great Change. The implications for humanity of the current transformation are still
being assessed and will take decades to understand more fully. What is already apparent with this shift,
however, is the potential for fundamental improvements to the human condition and the renewal of our
natural life-support systems.

To this end, to the revitalization that is readily possible, we examine in the following chapters of Part II
the highlights of a new economic framework, and some of the many monetary initiatives that are now
available to communities and society-at-large.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

We are in the midst of the most comprehensive societal transformation in recorded history. All human
systems and all living systems are in the process of being affected. Part of this Great Change is a new
scientific inquiry that is providing a more holistic approach to the pursuit of knowledge. This integrative
inquiry is already revolutionizing our understanding in a great many important domains, from ecosystems
and medicine to economics and monetary systems. Some of the many implications for economics are
considered next.

CHAPTER TWELVE - Efficiency, Resilience, and Money



The very process of the restoring the land to health

is the process through which we become attuned to Nature

and, through Nature, with ourselves.

~CHRIS MASER

Our perceptions have undergone great changes over the centuries. Evolving views of our planet, for
instance, have matured from a stationary orb at the center of a divinely conceived order, to an immense
world in a mechanistic universe, to a living planet with limited resources suspended in a
multidimensional, energy-based cosmos.

This progression in understanding mirrors the continually evolving expressions of governance,
economic rules, and monetary paradigms that have taken place from a premodern, theocratic, agriculturalbased society, in which most financial exchanges took the form of barter; to modern democracies and
industrialized economies, with increasingly concentrated financial wealth dominating a monetized, global
marketplace; to an emerging postmodern landscape in search of more sustainable ways and means of
meeting the requirements of the worlds many diverse peoples and natural ecosystems.

In support of humanitys epic journey and 21st century objectives, we explore herein a conceptual
framework that offers new understandings and solutions towards sustainable development, with relief for
both the economies and living systems of this planet.

FLOW SYSTEMS AND ECONOMICS



Advancements in recent decades in a number of domainsfrom systems theory, complexity theory, and
information theory, to the study of natural ecosystems and what makes them sustainablehave contributed
to a new theoretical scaffold for economics. This integrative, empirically backed model likens economies
to complex, adaptive, living systems in which matter, energy, and information continually flow.

Flow systems exist throughout nature. Our circulatory system, for example, provides a nourishing
supply of blood to every cell in the human body, without which we would quickly die. Similarly,
ecologists view natural ecosystems as energy and flow systems, in which the natural food chain is
actually a streaming network of matter, information, and energy built of complex relationships among
organisms. Energy radiates from the sun onto the planet. Plants capture the suns energy through
photosynthesis and transform it into biomass. Animals eat the plants and one another in a chain up to the
top predator, only to die and decompose. Bacteria and other microorganisms recycle their decomposed
remains.

Economies, like natural ecosystems, are also complex flow networks. They consist of millions of
businesses and productive activities whereby outputs of one entity serve as inputs to others and to
consumers, in a vast web that processes and circulates energy, information, and resources through
practically the whole planet.200

Though complex, some structural patterns of these networks are predictable and independent of the
nature of what flows through them, be it biomass in an ecosystem, information in an immune system,
electrons in an electrical distribution system, or money in an economy. What makes these patterns
predictable is the universality of their structures.

Theoretical nonlinear physicist Predrag Cvitanovi explains:

The wonderful thing about this universality is that it does not matter much how close our equations
are to the ones chosen by nature, as long as the model is in the same universality classas the real
system. This means that we can get the right physics out of very crude models. The existence of such
universal patterns and dynamics explains why similar energy-flow concepts and analysis methods
apply to economic systems as well as natural ones.201

In essence, understanding how ecosystems and other complex flow networks maintain sustainability
allows us to apply this same knowledge to economic systems. A summary of the findings is described
below. With the aforementioned caveats in mind regarding the application of mathematical proofs to realworld situations, interested readers may refer to the relevant paper.202

EFFICIENCY AND RESILIENCE



It is now known that long-term sustainability in real world networks such as ecosystems depends on an
appropriate balance between two opposing requirementsefficiency and resilience.

Efficiency in a complex network is defined as a networks capacity to process volumes of whatever
flows through it in a sufficiently organized and streamlined manner so as to maintain the integrity of the
network over time.203

Resilience is that same networks rebound capacity, that is, the ability to retreat elegantly and safely to
fallback positions, to access a diversity of options to meet the needs of unexpected disturbances, and to
spawn innovations for ongoing development and evolution.204 For any complex flow system to sustain
itself over time, it thus needs to not only be efficiently organized but must also be resilient, able to
withstand changes in its environment, be it drought or disease in a natural ecosystem or downturns in an
economy.

Two structural variables of any complex system govern the degree of efficiency versus resilience. One
such element is diversity, the existence of different types of agents acting as nodes in the network. The
other is interconnectivity, which measures the number of pathways between the given agents. Diversity
and interconnectivity play key roles in the efficiency and resilience of any complex system, but in
opposite directions.

All other things being equal, a systems resilience is enhanced by both greater diversity and
connections, as they provide more agents and channels to fall back on in times of trouble or change.
Efficiency, on the other hand, increases through streamlining, which typically implies reducing diversity
and connectivity. A dynamic push-pull between efficiency and resilience is crucial to the long-term health
of a system whose optimal fitness requires a specific balance between these two poles.


Figure 12.1 Simplified Sustainability Curve of a Natural Ecosystem205

A predator animal, for instance, may eat a variety of species, or depend instead on only a single
species for its food supply. In the latter case, this hunter will likely be more skilled when it comes to
catching its favorite prey, but find it hard to adapt if that one food supply becomes scarce. Consequently,
the feeding network of this predator, while efficient, is not very resilient, and is at risk of dying off with
unfavorable changes to its environment.

Efficiency and resilience are both controlled by diversity and connectivity. Since diversity and
connectivity can each be precisely measured, the fitness and sustainability of any given complex flow
network can be mathematically determined as well. In all real-life sustainable systems, the relationship
between sustainability, resilience, and efficiency follow a conceptual curve that is illustrated in a
simplified manner in Figure 12.1.

Note that in nature, the optimum point whereby sustainability is maximized invariably lies closer to
resilience than to efficiency. Moreover, all sustainable ecosystems have their most critical parameters
within a very specific and narrow range, which can be computed with precision. This range is referred to
as the Window of Viability.206

Healthy ecosystems keep their diversity and numbers of pathways within a certain range that is neither
too much nor too little. This is because flow networks that are overly efficient tend to become too brittle,
whereby one small break may cause the whole system to collapse. On the other hand, overly diverse
networks tend to become stagnant, in which energy, resources, and information wander through a tangle of
meandering pathways that lead to nowhere.

Let us emphasize that the relationships between efficiency and resilience, the role of the structural
variables of diversity and interconnectivity, and the window of viability, are all requirements and
emergent properties of not only natural ecosystems but of any complex flow network system.

The concept of efficiency is so deeply ingrained in our thinking today, especially in engineering and
economic thought, that it may be difficult for most of us to imagine how anything could be too efficient.
But the lesson of recent crises is precisely thatover-efficiency. Consider, for example, the blackouts of
entire electrical distribution networks that have occurred in the Northeastern United States and other parts
of the world.207 These failures followed decades of engineering optimization for greatest efficiency, an
unintended consequence of which was that these distribution systems became brittle.

The same principle of a balance between efficiency and resilience also applies to the viability of
enterprises and economies. To address multiple contingencies and survive challenging times,
organizations must be adaptable and resilient, able to change their ways as needed. Healthy businesses
must maintain resilience by creating and maintaining appropriate systems of production, marketing,
delivery, accounting, and training. But organizations must also maintain competitiveness by honing the
efficiency of their processes, which is typically accomplished by streamlining.

Todays emphasis on maximizing efficiency underscores the current general belief that all
improvements need to proceed further in this same direction. But when managers over-emphasize
streamlining and other short-term efficiencies at the expense of long-term resilience, they may be
sacrificing viability. Such an orientation keeps driving us further away from sustainability.

One dramatic example of what can happen when efficiency is pushed too far comes from global supply
chains that revealed themselves incapable of dealing with the aftershocks of the Japanese 2011 disaster.

For instance, two Japanese companies that have damaged factories produce 90 percent of the market of a
speciality resin used to bond parts of microchips that go into all smartphones. These lean, just-in-time
supply chains should be reviewed with a just-in-case approach.

These considerations have direct relevance to our monetary and banking paradigms and to the credit
crunch of the last several years.

Money, Efficiency, and Resilience



Money, the codified agreement that circulates throughout our global economic network, is maintained as a
monopoly of a single type of bank-debt, fiat-based, interest-bearing currency. The technical justification
for this monopoly is to optimize the efficiency of price formation and exchanges in national and
international markets. Massive legal and regulatory mechanisms are in place to ensure and maintain this
monopoly, mainly through the requirement that only national currencies are acceptable as legal tender for
payment in taxes.

The current monetary paradigm is, in effect, equivalent to a planetary ecosystem where only one single
type of plant or animal is tolerated and artificially maintained, and where any diversity is eradicated as an
inappropriate competitor because it would reduce the efficiency of the whole. Only one end result is
possible in such a scenariothe collapse of the system as a whole.

Complementary Currencies and Resilience



The solution that leads toward monetary sustainability defies conventional economic thinking, which
mistakenly assumes monopolies for national currencies as a given. Sustainable ecosystems demonstrate
that flow systems require sufficient diversity and connectivity at different scales covering all levels.208 A
monopoly of one type of centralized currency, particularly one that requires artificial scarcity to maintain
its value, is not compatible with such a role. A monoculture of bank-debt national money may have been
appropriateperhaps even necessaryfor an industrial-age world to emerge. But this paradigm is
without question far too limited for a 21st-century pluralistic society seeking innovative, sustainable,
postindustrial economic solutions.

Even some of the more simple complementary currency systems can empower people. The use of these
monetary tools allows many more people to participate in exchanges, and provides a richer
interconnectivity among the constituents of an economy. Complementary currencies thereby serve to prod
the overall system back towards more sustainability.

Complementary currencies improve the resilience of the whole economy by providing greater diversity
in exchanges; they enable transactions that otherwise wouldnt occur, through connections that otherwise
wouldnt exist. Though traditional economics tends to dismiss the contributions of complementary
currencies on the grounds that they are less efficient, systems thinking demonstrates the fundamental flaws
in that argument. Though complementary currencies may reduce overall efficiency, they increase
resilience and engender a more sustainable economy. When diverse types of money reach every level of
society, a richer socioeconomic fabric is inevitably woven that is far more pliant, able to better withstand
and deal with multiple contingencies and changes to the environment. The system thus becomes more
stable. This is the structural lesson of natural ecosystems.

New understandings regarding complex flow systems and the need for resilience points a way towards
the long-term health of our economies. It also helps clarify why todays pressure for ever-greater
efficiency actually destabilizes the economy by relentlessly repressing diversity. The lack of diversity
erodes businesses, communities, and the well-being of the billions of people that interact through our
economies.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

A new way of understanding any type of complex flow system is now available. A continuous exchange of
energy, matter, and information outputs from one part of a system serve as inputs to another part of that
same system. Importantly, understandings gained from any one kind of flow system are applicable to all
others with the same structure, be they ecosystems, electrical distribution systems, human immune
systems or entire economies.

Flow systems that are optimally sustainable enjoy a dynamic balance between efficiency and
resilience. Excessive efficiency occurs in the case of too little diversity or too few connections, and can
result in the sudden collapse of a network. Resilience is instead enhanced by increasing diversity and
connections. These findings have vital implications for our financial, economic, and monetary systems.

CHAPTER THIRTEEN - Sustainable Development



Growth for the sake of growth

is the ideology of the cancer cell.

~EDWARD ABBEY

Understanding the need for a balance between efficiency and resilience, together with the ability to
measure a networks structure, allows for a deeper, more accurate assessment of a number of vital
contemporary issues. One such issue, and a key factor related to most of our current socioeconomic and
environmental concerns, is that of sustainable development.209

ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT VERSUS GROWTH



Traditional economic thought and practices have placed great emphasis on continued economic growth.
Widely considered to be synonymous with development, economic growth is the main criterion used to
determine overall economic vitality and is a key objective in economic planning and policies. Yet, many
accepted assumptions regarding the concept of growth reveal themselves to be just thatassumptions.

Even the most basic questions regarding growth defy simple answers. How, for example, do we define
economic growth? Which criteria and methods should be employed to measure it? What kind of growth is
actually good for the long-term health or sustainability of an economy? Confusion and misconceptions
associated with this subject matter have contributed instead to policies and practices that exacerbate
ongoing economic instability, inequities, hardship, and ecological devastationhardly expressions of
health or sustainability.

For decades, mounting numbers of concerned citizens have intuitively understood and identified many
supposedly growth-oriented economic activities as deleterious to society and the actual economy of
peoples and nations. Such concerns, however, lacked the kind of supporting empirical evidence deemed
acceptable by traditional economic protocol. Consequently, growth has persisted as a key objective and
desired outcome in most economic pursuits.

Fortunately, new findingsparticularly with regard to flow networks, resilience, and sustainability
enable a much clearer understanding of what actually constitutes healthy development, and the means by
which to differentiate it from mere growth. We now know, for example, that a large ecosystem that lacks
sufficiently diverse nutrient pathways, such as the lack of ample waterways or nourishing topsoil, is not
properly prepared to withstand challenges such as drought or disease. Size alone does not make
ecosystems sustainable. The same structural rules apply to any type of flow system, including our
economies.

An economy that lacks resilience cannot be considered to be optimal, no matter how seemingly big or
efficient it may be. Even Simon Kuznets, the principal architect of the original GNP national accounting
scheme, cautioned that economic wellbeing cannot be determined by volume or growth alone. Theoretical
ecologist Robert Ulanowicz points out that the long-term sustainability of any type of flow system
depends on a judicious balance of size in conjunction with internal structural development. These insights
regarding flow systems, together with advancements in our understanding of money, allow for a much
clearer and more accurate assessment of the conditions needed by free-enterprise networks to produce the
kind of economic vitality that enhances the wellbeing at all levels of our global civilization.

In economies, volume is measured by Gross Domestic Product (GDP). In ecosystems, size is generally
measured by the Total System Throughput (TST), which gauges the total volume of nutrients, biomass, or
energy moving through a system. Both GDP and TST are, however, poor measures of sustainability in that
they each measure only size (volume), while ignoring the agents and pathways needed to process
resources and circulate energy in a network structure to all parts of the whole. This leaves metrics such as
the GDP unable to distinguish between the kind of frenetic growth that occurs in a bubble economy and
that of healthy development in a resilient economy.

Sustainability in Natural Ecosystems



A simple ecosystem example from Dr. Ulanowicz clarifies how tradeoffs among efficiency, resilience,
and growth affect a flow-systems long-term health. The following study observed the American alligator
in one of its natural habitats, the Cypress wetlands of South Florida.210

One of the alligators important sources of biomass (carbon flow or food) is freshwater prawns. The
alligators do not, however, normally feed directly on the prawns themselves, but obtain this biomass
indirectly by instead consuming other predators that in turn feed on the prawns. Three such intermediate
predators include: large fish, turtles, and snakes.

In this example, the most efficient pathway between prawns and alligators is via large fishes. If, as is
often the case in economics, efficiency were taken as the sole criterion for vitality, then the flow path
through the fish would grow at the expense of less efficient routes until it completely dominated the
transfer. In such a scenario, the increase in efficiency almost doubles and also creates a 20 percent jump
in volume (available biomass). A comparable economic event would be a massive increase in
productivity and efficiency that leads to a dramatic leap in GDP and growth, which is then conflated with
healthy development.211

In this ecosystem scenario, the resilience for this highly efficient system vanishes completely. The
alligators are now strictly dependent on large fish as their only food source. Should some catastrophe
occur to these now overly efficient predators, like a virus wiping out the fish population, all transfer from
prawns to alligators would cease, with potentially cataclysmic consequences for the predator species.
The growth that would have taken place is based on a shaky foundation and is not sustainable.

Dr. Goerner points out that this natural ecosystem situation mirrors what occurs in the marketplace. The
surges in GDP growth that often accompany increased efficiency may give the appearance of economic
vitality but could mask increasing brittleness. One example of systemic fragility is found in the energy
sector, with global dependence on oil as the primary source of fuel, whose production and supply is
limited to a few, very large suppliers. Any disruption here bodes ill for the economy at large due to the
absence of viable contingencies and alternative sources to turn to. In other words, there is a lack of
resilience.

Global dependence on large agribusinesses presents a similarly serious threat. A mere ten to twelve
companies now control over 80 percent of the worlds food supply of cereals, grains, meat, dairy, edible
oils, fats, and fruits.212 Such consolidation may, as some economists claim, represent the most efficient
path from resource to consumer. But the global food system is left with few options should political,
economic, microbial, or climate-change-induced events disrupt one or more major pathways.
Consolidation of this kind puts all of ones eggs in a single basket; it errs on the side of efficiency and
courts disaster by eliminating resilience.

Systems that, in contrast, maintain proper resilience during growth are more likely to adapt to crises in
ways that largely protect TST. In the alligator biomass transfer example, healthy populations of turtles and
snakes would provide alternate pathways and allow the system to adapt while maintaining flow in case of
a fish virus outbreak. Though the loss of large fish does cause sustainability to drop by almost half, the
TST volume only drops a modest 2-3 percent, and the efficiency loss is slight as well. Most notably, total
collapse of the system is avoided. The alligator still receives a plentiful supply of biomass.


Such numbers substantiate diversitys role in supporting a soft-landing response to the booms, busts,
and other periodic disturbances that inevitably befall an economy. The ability to quantify resilience also
provides an empirical basis and new appreciation for the small, diverse economic networks that make up
the bulk of any economy, and lends support to concerns about, for instance, the plight of small farms that
provide vital, alternate food-supply pathways for the global food-security crisis (that many experts argue
lies on the horizon). In short, understanding the need for resilience discredits the idea that focusing on
highly efficient big businesses is the surest path to economic health.

Sustainability and Positive Feedback



Understanding the tradeoffs required for long-term economic vitality helps us aim policies toward a more
appropriate balance between efficiency and resilience. There is, however, more to this story, especially
in trying to grasp phenomena such as the booms and busts of the business cycle. For this, we must turn to
positive feedback circuits that take the form of centripetal pull.

The following example, named after one the worlds largest corporations, helps illustrate how selfreinforcing or autocatalytic forces draw ever more resources into their sway, like an expanding whirlpool
that sucks all surrounding flows into itself.

The Walmart Effect



Walmart runs a chain of large U.S. discount department stores and membership-required warehouse
outlets. The Walmart Effect is one in which large, highly efficient companies, supported by local
economic development offices, tend to erode surrounding economic networks even as they increase GDP.

For decades now, most economic development offices have focused on creating incentives to lure big
corporations to set up shop in their locale in hopes that jobs and taxes would best trickle down from
there. This approach skyrocketed because of increasing emphasis on GDP growth, and resulted in mutualbenefit deals between the giant, deregulated corporations and allied economic development officers,
academicians, and politicians.

Support for big-box retailers seemed sensible. Greater economies of scale means lower prices,
which naturally and progressively pulls in more consumers and money. This centripetal pull causes
corporate and government coffers to swell along with the GDP. The benefits of this centralizing circuit
appeared as much undeniable as it was self-perpetuating. Those who supported the process were
rewarded, while those who did not were simply removed.

Champions of such policies failed, however, to consider the price paid for this in social and economic
erosion.

As noted in the documentary Walmart: The High Cost of Low Prices,213 the efficient, big-box retailers
drive smaller, more diverse local enterprises out of business, mainly through lower prices. These same
retailers then take full advantage of this situation by lowering worker wages, removing benefits, and
finally increasing prices after local competition has been weakened. Main Street shopsone of the prime
losers in this processdisappear one by one, leaving the center of town run-down and unsafe, and
begging for another publicly funded, urban renewal effort. Much of the money and benefit of large-scale
efficiency are ultimately drained from the local economy and siphoned off to distant headquarters.

A 2002 study in Austin, Texas, for instance, showed that for every $100 local consumers spent at a
national bookstore, only $13 was spent in the local economy, whereas the same amount spent at local
bookstores yielded $45.214 A 2003 study of Mid-coast Maine expanded this finding, showing that local
businesses spent 54 percent of their revenue (in goods, professional services, wages, benefits, etc.)
within Maine, while big-box retailers spent just 14 percent of their revenue locally, mostly in the form of
payroll.215

This centripetal drain from the local community to corporate coffers erodes the social and economic
vitality of a community. The ultimate costs to local governments far outweigh the tax revenues that the big
retailer adds. The overall impact in lost jobs, lower wages, over-extended infrastructure, and the erosion
of community wellbeing can be dramatic.

The innocence with which this process proceeds explains why strategies that are intended to increase
economic health often erode it instead. An autocatalytic circuit grew out of natural desires for progress in
the form of economic growth, the kind that GDP numbers celebrate. More and more resources from the
local community were pulled into this loop, which resulted in the loss of diversity, jobs, profits, and local
resilience. Policies that promote centripetal economic growth have in common a wealth-concentrating
vortex that simultaneously breeds brittleness at its periphery and unsustainable surges at its center.


The 2008 banking and financial crisis, initially triggered by the mortgage derivative bubble, illustrates
how this very process works on a broader scale than what has been described thus far.

Autocatalysis and the Global Downturn



In the period leading up to the global downturn of 2008, a profit-driven circuit had been well established,
formed by deregulated bankers in search of new sources of income, stockbrokers in search of hot new
products to sell, and big institutional investors in search of higher returns. Gains in any one part of this
self-amplifying circuit benefitted other segments of the same internal circuit, but to the detriment of the
resilience of the economy-at-large. This autocatalytic loop grew rapidly by drawing in resources from the
greater economy through ever more-efficient, though dangerous, pull techniques, mainly in the form of
risky derivative instruments, which served to concentrate or pull wealth into the hub. This was
accompanied by a kind of rigid group-think that dismissed traditional risk assessments, which was
realized via intense selection pressures that lavishly rewarded those who increased gains, and eliminating
the jobs of those who did not.

While the derivative mess helped trigger the crisis, the erosion of other sectors created an underlying
systemic risk in the form of brittleness. Not only was the broader economy left increasingly vulnerable,
but the banking and financial sectors were also left exposed. The most vital factor behind this erosion and
brittleness traces right back to the same epicenterto the banking and monetary systems themselves.

The crash of 2008 predictably devolved from a financial crisis into a liquidity crisis, in which the
banks and financial sector, needled by the pressure to rebuild their balance sheets and reacting to the shift
in economic climate, did what they usually do in such risky circumstances. At the very moment when
Main Street needed it most, the large financial institutions reduced lending. Lacking credit, businesses and
consumers were simply forced to tighten their belts and economic activity slowed down. As occurred in
the 1930s, many businesses were forced into insolvency and massive unemployment ensued.

Our ongoing monetary and banking paradigm amplifies the business cycle. It helps drive a good economic
period into a potential inflationary boom, and a difficult period into a bust. It does this by making more
credit available when it is least needed during high times, and by making credit less accessible when it is
most needed during periods of contraction. Central banks try their best to counteract this cycle, but have
limited success, at best.

The increased instability caused by this amplification of the business cycle is abetted further still by the
destabilizing autocatalytic centripetal phenomenon, which pulls resources in from the greater economy, be
it through subprime mortgages, derivatives, or other means. Both the amplification of the business cycle
and autocatalysis contribute to the kind of loss of resilience that helped escalate the downturn of 20082009, into the worst recession since the Great Depression.

Joseph Tainter points out in The Collapse of Complex Societies that autocatalytic economic circuits
follow a path similar to that of the Roman Empire: they grow, dominate their surroundings, reach their
limits, and if left unchecked, end in collapse due largely to erosion of small farmers, local governments,
and other non-epicenter networks.216 Understanding this process empirically grounds the age-old claim
that monopolistic concentration, insider trading, speculation, and sheer greed are all bad for economic
health. Some regulations, like the Glass-Steagall Act of 1933, counteracted this by barring Wall Street
investment banks from owning community savings banks. Such measures were effective because they
blocked too much autocatalytic alignment. This act was, however, repealed (under the Clinton
administration) after intense lobbying by the banking system, and is another manifestation of the same
recursively self-serving process.


Structurally, this autocatalysis is compounded by the current monetary and banking paradigms, with a
monopoly in the issuance of money; that is, by the very same sector that wields such enormous influence
on all else in our monetized economy, including the booms and busts of the business cycle. The continued
lack of reassessment and amendment to these paradigms, together with unchecked autocatalytic circuits,
are as dangerous a mix of ingredients as one can imagine with regard to the sustainability of our global
economy. Until and unless addressed, this perilous status quo virtually ensures continued lack of
resilience, instability, and ongoing crises.

RETHINKING THEORY AND PRACTICE



Current economic theory rests on the assumption that economic laws, such as standard supply-anddemand dynamics, hold true regardless of the resilience of the underlying networks. But GDP growth only
counts the volume of monetary exchanges; it ignores whether such exchanges actually contribute to or
destroy economic resilience. Supposed growth, as gauged by this primitive accounting scheme, may
instead mask declines taking place in various parts of the economic web by allowing massive gains in one
sector, such as hedge funds, to be conflated with health for the whole. As noted, this blindness to network
health renders traditional economic theory incapable of understanding, much less predicting, bubbles,
which, in the context of this economic framework constitutes growth without underlying structural
development. The various schools of traditional economics are also unable to foresee the kind of
widespread economic instability that now threatens the world.

The lack of attention to the erosion of lower-scale networks has opened the door to policies that have
accelerated destruction at every level of the economy. Reigning economic thinking of the last several
decades, devoted to regulating capital, has removed many of the obstacles to wealth concentration long
known to create harm. Blind faith in market efficiency and the seeming correctness of maximizing profits
regardless of the costs to anyone or anything else, has bred disdain for moral concerns, including harm to
smaller economic actors.

Where an underlying stability once supported the monetary domain, our collective blindness has now
inevitably caused that stability to collapse. The damage done to peopleas consumers, laborers or
operators of small businessesand the continued onslaught upon the environment caused by predatory
practices, externalization of costs, toxic products, as well as a lack of monetary choices, were all
rationalized as necessary collateral damage and creative destruction. But the destruction factor now
impacts the whole of the economy and virtually every living system of this planet, and seriously
compromises our future prospects.

A long list of critics (including Joseph Stiglitz,217 Robert Pollin,218 John Saul219) point to the more than
100 major banking crises,220 the increasing concentration of wealth and power,221 the elimination of good
jobs,222 and the erosion of civil liberties, public health, and democracy,223 all of which have accelerated
between the 1970s and today. Each is an expression of the inherent unsustainability of our present
economic regime.

This combination of blindness and disregard leads to widespread brittleness that, as the ongoing
economic crisis shows, threatens big and small alike. It also highlights the fallacy of other common
assumptions, including:

increasing efficiency always improves economic health regardless of the harm that financial
efficiencies can cause to people, communities, and our planets ecosystem;
highly skewed distributions of wealth, power and size do not affect economic health;
money is value neutral, and our fiat-based, bank-debt monetary system can meet all of humanitys
many diverse needs.
Another road to socioeconomic vitality is available to us. A whole currency innovation movement has
emerged over the past decades, thanks in large part to the efforts of pioneers from many countries. In the

United States, much of the credit goes to innovators such as Hazel Henderson,224 Edgar Cahn,225 Paul
Glover,226 Thomas Greco,227 Sergio Lub,228 Susan Witt,229 Wilson Riles, Arno Hesse, Guilllaume Lebleu,
Nipun Mehta, Matthew Edwards, Charlie Rebich, as well as hundreds of grassroot activists too numerous
to mention here. The next chapters will document some of the results.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

Traditional economics places a great deal of emphasis on growth. This parameter, as measured by
GDP, is widely assumed to be synonymous with healthy, economic development. Recent findings,
however, derived in large part from our understanding of flow systems, calls into question many long-held
growth-related assumptions and activities.

One of the many ways in which growth is conflated with overall sustainability is how current policy
and activities benefit dominant players at the expense of the greater economy. The present monetary and
banking paradigm, together with the phenomenon of autocatalysis, enables large institutions to become
ever larger, thereby reducing connections and diversity in the system.

This relentless emphasis on GDP gains, efficiency, and growth, at the cost of resilience, together with
the lack of diversity embodied in our monetary paradigm, constitutes a structural cause for the instability
of our economies. A balance between efficiency and resilience is essential for sustainable development.

CHAPTER FOURTEEN - LETS and Time Dollars



How wonderful it is that nobody need wait a single moment

before starting to improve the world.

~ANNE FRANK

As in other major societal transformations, monetary changes are a vital component of todays Great
Change. Prompted in large part by the inability to address issues by traditional means, and spurred on as
well by low-cost computing, more and more communities are getting involved with new complementary
currencies. Only a small handful of such currencies were known to be operational during the 1970s.
Today several thousand systems are operational worldwide.230 A very conservative estimate of the rise in
the number of systems is illustrated in figure 14.1.

It bears noting that only those social-purpose complementary currencies identified as operational in a
dozen countries as of 2009 are represented. Excluded from the figure are the thousands of loyalty
currencies (discount coupons, airline miles, etc.) used for commercial purposes and the countless socialpurpose currencies that do not advertise their existence outside of their immediate geographical
environment.

Two of the most popular complementary currency systems operational today are LETS and Time
Dollars. Each of these currencies is an example of a mutual credit system, designed to help facilitate
exchanges in communities in which national currency is either lacking or otherwise inadequate to meet
local needs. A brief description of each system follows, beginning with the most ubiquitous and one of the
most easily adopted of all social-purpose currenciesLETS.

LETS

There are many flavors of Local Exchange Trading Systemsor LETS. One example is LETSystem,
which originated in a once-prosperous fishing community near Vancouver, Canada during the 1980s. The
community had fallen on hard times; local unemployment persisted at nearly 40 percent despite the
presence of a large, skilled labor force and the continued demand for goods and services by the local
population. LETSystem was created to help facilitate the local trade of goods and services. As
LETSystems founder Michael Linton observed, the missing link was money. Without it, transactions
simply could not take place. According to Linton:

The greatest deficiency of conventional money is that for too many, it is simply not available. By its
very design, there is only a limited amount of it created. And, as conventional money must come from
somewhere outside the local community, it inherently doesnt understand or concern itself with the
needs of a particular community.231

Exchanges in a LETS system take place using either LETS money alone or in combination with national
currency. A gardener or car mechanic, for example, might ask only LETS money in exchange for services
rendered, or accept partial payment in both LETS and in national currency. The proportion of LETS and
national currencies used in each exchange is determined by the participants themselves on a case-by-case
basis. The material inputs used in most LETS exchanges, for instance, fertilizer or car parts, are
customarily paid for using national currency. The service inputs tend to be paid in LETS.

Exchanges in the LETS system take place using either LETS money alone or in combination with
national currency. A gardener or car mechanic, for example, might ask only LETS money in exchange for
services rendered, or accept partial payment in both LETS and in national currency. The proportion of
LETS and national currencies used in each exchange is determined by the participants themselves on a
case by case basis. The material inputs used in most LETS exchanges, for instance, fertilizer or car parts,
are customarily paid for using national currency. The service inputs tend to be paid in LETS.

LETS is a mutual credit system, whereby the currency to be used in a particular exchange is created at
the time of a transaction. When an exchange takes place, the account of the individual supplying the goods
or service is credited, while the recipients account is debited. Credit balances indicate that an individual
has provided goods or services to fellow community members in excess of the amount of goods or
services redeemed, and vice versa for debit balances.

This system ensures that the supply of LETS within a community is sufficient and self-regulating. Like
other mutual credit systems, LETS enables participants to benefit from whatever resources are available
within the trading community. It thereby overcomes the systemically imposed scarcity of a national
currency.

In contrast to conventional money, a negative balance in LETS is not a problem but instead is an
indication that this particular member has purchased more goods and services from other members. Those
with a negative balance are simply called upon to offer goods or services in return, further increasing the
communitys collective wealth. Some LETS programs set debt limits to avoid abuses, but there is
generally a common understanding that debts will be repaid.

Because open records are customarily kept of both credits and debits, those LETS users who refuse or

fail to repay their debts (by serving or supplying goods to fellow community members) can be identified
easily and barred from future participation. This built-in transparency ensures checks and balances, and
engenders greater trust among users. Thus it is a self-regulating system.

One important advantage of LETS compared to conventional money is that it promotes the use of skills
and services that are otherwise less likely to be considered for trade, such as having someone else
perform ones cooking, driving, web designing, gardening, etc.

James Taris writes in The LETSaholic TWIST:

Having a limited income meant I could only afford to pay for the essentials in my life; everything
else became a luxury. But all that changed with LETS Very soon I was mowing lawns, removing
rubbish and painting rooms. Later I was also designing business cards, brochures and newsletters.
And in return, I received massages, piano tuition and restaurant meals, computer support, computer
software, and web design services. I would have reluctantly bypassed all of these goods and
services if I had to pay for them in cash. LETS made them all possible.232

Typically, the value of one LETS unit is equivalent to one unit of whatever national currency is used in
that community. Setting up a local LETS exchange is a straightforward process. Its few requirements
include: a basic agreement to use LETS amongst participants, a user-accessible, transparent accounting
mechanism, and the creation of a member directory listing each respective members offers and/or needs
priced in LETS units.

LETS programs are currently operating in many different parts of the world. In Australia, there are an
estimated 200 different LETS programs. England has more than 300 programs. A partial list of other
nations with LETS programs includes: Argentina, Austria, Belgium, Brazil, Canada, Chile, Colombia, El
Salvador, Finland, France, Germany, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Ireland, Israel, Japan, New Zealand,
Nigeria, Norway, Poland, South Africa, Switzerland, Thailand, and the United States.

TIME DOLLARS

Time Dollars, also known as Time Banking, was created by distinquished American attorney Dr. Edgar
Cahn, who observed that formally paying peopleby whatever meansempowers them. He emphasizes
that, counting what people do is a way of valuing what they do.233 Given the inherent scarcity of
national currency, Cahn conceived of using time as a medium of exchange. The basic unit of account is a
Time Dollar, equivalent to one hour of service, which can be spent for goods and services available
within a given community.

Time Dollars works in the following manner, as explained on the Time Dollars website:

At its most basic level, Time banking is simply about spending an hour doing something for
somebody in your community. That hour goes into the Time Bank as a Time Dollar. Then you have a
Time dollar to spend on having someone doing something for you. Its a simple idea, but it has
powerful ripple effects in building community connections.234

Time Dollars, like other complementary currency systems, link a communitys unmet needs (the
services requested) with its unused resources (community members with time and services to render).
Like LETS, Time Dollars facilitates transactions that likely would not take place otherwise. Time Dollars
can be as simple as a group of moms getting together to share carpooling of kids, grocery shopping, taking
care of elderly parents, walking dogs, or helping out with homework.

Time Dollars builds and strengthens relationships within its community of users. In one ten-year, $51
million joint study, researchers from Harvard, Columbia, and the University of Michigan endeavored to
identify what helps make neighborhoods safe.235 The multimillion dollar answer was not additional
police officers or more government assistance. Rather, the study concluded that community safety
depended on collective efficacy, a fancy term for neighbors looking out for each others kids to curtail
destructive behaviors. Time Dollars improves collective efficacyand local resilience as well.

The acknowledgement of services via a currency also reinforces volunteerism. Research conducted at
the University of Marylands Center on Aging demonstrated that roughly one third of Time Dollars
participants had never volunteered before. The same research showed that the use of a complementary
currency induces people to continue volunteering over time. The dropout rate, which typically reaches 40
percent in purely volunteer-based programs, is only three percent in these hybrid voluntarism programs
that provide modest payment in complementary currencies.236

The Time Dollars system is being applied to address a number of social issues. In Brooklyn, N.Y., a
health insurance company called Elderplan accepts 25 percent of the premiums for its senior health
programs in Time Dollars. Preventive measures, such as fixing a broken bathtub rail, are provided
through Elderplans Care Bank, a Time Dollar exchange.237 The Elderplan model is now available in all
five boroughs of New York City.

Another successful application is the Time Dollars Youth Court. Founded in 1996, it has become a
cornerstone of the juvenile justice system in Washington, D.C. Juveniles accused of nonviolent offenses
are tried before a jury of their peers, that is, other juveniles who have been convicted of similar offenses.
Those found guilty must make a requisite apology, and submit to life-skills counseling and a combination
of community services, such as tutoring of younger students or service on a Youth Court jury. In return for

rendering these services, tutors and Youth court jurors earn Time Dollars, which can be redeemed for
recycled computers, savings bonds for college, educational trips, special events, and more.238

The programs effectiveness has attracted significant attention. Participation in the Youth Court has
reduced first-year recidivism by half.239 The Youth Court now processes approximately 60 percent of
nonviolent, juvenile offenders first cases. The program has been officially sanctioned by the D.C.
Superior Court to work with the criminal justice system in a partnership for the purpose of jointly
developing a diversion program which provides a meaningful alternative to the traditional adjudicatory
format in juvenile cases.240 Similar programs are being implemented in South Africa and Jamaica.

In some Chicago schools, a Time Dollars program incentivizes tutoring of younger students by older
students. The hours spent tutoring can be used to obtain, for example, refurbished computers. A Time
Dollars credo states, You have something your community needs, you should be rewarded for offering
it.

Another application that makes us of Time Dollars is a prison program, currently operational in the
United States and Great Britain. Inmates are offered the opportunity to earn Time Dollars by refurbishing
bicycles. The Time Dollars earned can then be used by the families of participating inmates for their own
needs, while the bicycles are sent to Africa as part of an aid program.

The cost of starting a Time Dollars program is minimal; communities can use a blackboard or a piece
of paper to keep a tally. For larger-scale projects, a timekeeper computer program can be downloaded for
free from the Internet. Time Dollars is also scalable to accommodate any level of participation. Its
scalability, cost-effectiveness, ease of use, and benefits to community members make Time Dollars a
popular choice among students, retirees, and the unemployed.

There are approximately 350 Time Dollars programs now operating in 22 countries on six continents.
In the United Kingdom, where the system is referred to as Fair Shares or Time Banking, an estimated
79 programs are currently in operation with another 80 now in development. In both the United States and
Japan there are 65 to 70 established Time Dollars programs. Other countries that have recently adopted
the system include Senegal, Ghana, and New Zealand.

Both Time Dollars and LETS cater mostly to the needs of individuals and are designed specifically for
smaller, lower-income communities where, for whatever reason, there is insufficient national currency.

In recognition of the social contributions offered by Time Dollars, three separate Internal Revenue
Service (IRS) rulings make this complementary currency officially tax-exempt in the United States.241

COMPLEMENTARY CURRENCY REFLECTIONS



An understanding of LETS, Time Dollars, and similar mutual credit complementary currency designs
helps shed light on matters associated with money, including: moneys value-nonneutrality; currency
designs and inflation; and the advantages of money, including complementary currencies, in comparison to
barter.

Currencies and Behavioral Changes



In keeping with the value-nonneutrality of money, currency designs have the potential to elicit specific
behavior patterns. Complementary currencies engender attitudes and interactions that are distinguished
from those customarily associated with our national currency paradigm.

LETSystem founder Michael Linton observes:

Community currencies seem to engender different attitudes. Fear disappears. People arent overly
concerned about individual trade balances or who benefits most in a particular transaction. A
different type of exchange comes into existence. Local currencies go round and round and come
back: Joe does this for Mary, Mary does this for Jim, and Jim helps Joe. Life is cyclical, I serve my
neighbor then another neighbor serves me. Community currencies encourage people to support each
other, which is really the business of life. And it slowly restructures the economy into a more benign
form, generative of quality of life, social capital, and common wealth.242

What is the reason for the occuring behavioral differences when conventional money or communityoriented mutual-credit systems are used?

As the Eleventh Round story in Chapter Five illustrates, the interest feature built into conventional
money drives the competition for a scarce currency. Most complementary currencies instead do not bear
interest, and some make use of a demurrage. Within mutual credit systems, artificial scarcity need not be
maintained; the currency is automatically created in sufficiency when an agreement to trade is reached.
Thus, the two hidden mechanisms that promote competition in conventional money (scarcity and interest)
are both absent in complementary currencies.

This structural difference helps explain why mutual credit and other social-purpose currencies
engender cooperation and a sense of community among their users. These systems are simply a
formalization of the tradition of helping each other, as in gift exchanges among neighbors that were
embedded in almost all past societies. In southern France, for example, these activities were called aller
aux adats (coming to the aid).

Complementary Currencies and Inflation



The structure of well-designed complementary currencies also clarifies why, in contrast to what some
economists might suspect, this form of money does not add to inflationary pressures. Inflation risk would
be valid if, and only if, the complementary currency were designed as a fiat currency, like the dollar, euro,
pound, and other national currencies. LETS and Time Dollars are not fiat currencies; they are each mutual
credit systems, in which money is created only when an agreement is made, with a simultaneous credit
and debit charged to the parties involved. This ensures that just enough money is created specifically for
the transaction at handand no more. In this way, all mutual credit currencies automatically create their
corresponding supply of goods and services when they are put into circulation.

It is essential to understand that most complementary currencies are intrinsically different from fiat
currencies and are intentionally designed to avoid contributing to inflation. All our notions regarding
inflation emanate from a traditional economic perspective, which implicitly assumes a monopoly of one
single fiat currency in use within a given country or region. This perspective holds that inflation results
whenever there are not enough goods and services produced for the quantity of money in circulation. Such
a premise is, however, simply not applicable to well-designed complementary currencies.

LETS, Time Dollars, Money, and Barter



LETS and Time Dollars are both money, and like other complementary currencies, enjoy the full
functionality of money. They should not be mistaken for barter exchanges, in which goods and services are
swapped bilaterally without any standardized medium of exchange. An inherent limitation of barter
exchanges is that they require a double coincidence of wants;243 resources and needs must match up
perfectly between two parties for a transaction to take place. In a barter transaction, if one person needs
shoes and another food, the exchange can only be completed if each possesses the particular item wanted
by the other.

As money, LETS and Time Dollars overcome the limitations of barter. Each system provides an
internal currencya medium of exchange used by all members within a given LETS or Time community
which permits participants to select from a much wider variety of goods and services. LETS, Time
Dollars, and other complementary currencies enable many exchanges that would not otherwise take place
and allow communities and society-at-large to better meet their many needs.

Many other social-purpose complementary currency designs are possible, two of which are examined
in the next chapter.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

There is no lack of work to be done in the world. There are children to be educated, shelters to be built,
ecological systems to protect, sick and the aged to be cared forthe litany is endless. In addition, there
are hundreds of millions of unemployed or underemployed people who are ready, willing, and able to
work.

What has been lacking is money, especially different types of money. We can easily make agreements to
interact and assist one another. We do not need gold to back our currencies; garbage was turned into
money in Brazil. LETS and Time Dollars demonstrate that in crafting monetary agreements, we are
limited only by our imagination and competency to make use of these new monetary tools, and the courage
to innovate.

Our national currencies are but one form of money. Just as no single tool can build a house, no single
type of money, no matter how ingenious or robust, can be designed to address each and every one of the
many and sometimes divergent requirements of society. Moreover, given the particular architecture of our
current money, with its artificially maintained scarcity, there will never be sufficient sums of national
currency available to meet our many and ever growing demands. A one-type-fits-all monetary design
makes as much sense as artificially limiting our use of tools to hammers when so many other specialized
tools are readily available for practical use right now.

CHAPTER FIFTEEN - Social-Purpose Currencies



There is a loftier ambition than merely to stand high in the world.

It is to stoop down and lift mankind a little higher.

~HENRY VAN DYKE

An all-too-common reality of most societies today is the inability to adequately address an extensive list
of social concerns, in no small measure due to the chronic lack of necessary funds. In stark contrast to the
trillions of dollars made available by governments to the financial sector during the banking crash of
2008, hard-fought battles must be continuously waged to raise even the most basic sums necessary to
address a wide range of health, education, and welfare issues in most developed and virtually all
developing nations around the world. This struggle is not an accident, but is instead the logical outcome
of a society shaped and constrained by our centuries-old monetary and banking systems. These systems
currently maintain a virtual monopoly with regard to the money in play, and place almost exclusive
emphasis on industrial and commercial interests.

It must be reemphasized that our national currencies are but one type of money. No single monetary
design is capable of addressing the full spectrum of both societies commercial and social requirements.
Fortunately, there is a growing recognition of the necessity for different currency designs that, working
alongside the dominant currency system, can address a much greater range of todays vital needs.

In the following pages, two social-purpose currency designs are showcased as examples of what
becomes possible by rethinking money. Unlike LETS and Time Dollars, each of which are basic
complementary currencies applicable in a generic way to a variety of different applications, the two
currencies examined herein are more specifically designed to help address particular sectors of social
concern for a society, namely health care and education. The following initiatives also serve to illustrate
how important social needs can be met in the face of limited public funds.

We begin with the ongoing economic struggles in one of the worlds leading economies and its
endeavors to provide adequate health care for its mounting elderly population.

JAPAN AND THE FUREAI KIPPU



Although sometimes mischaracterized as a nation of imitators, Japan is unquestionably a leading
innovator of complementary currency initiatives.244 Consider the following:

Japan has the largest number of complementary currency systems in the world today, with more than
780 operational systems.
Japan also has the largest diversity of ongoing complementary currency experiments. More than 260
different types of systems have been tested nationwide. This represents an almost 100 percent
increase in Japan since 2002 and amounts to more types of systems than the rest of the world
combined!245
Japan additionally led post-World War II complementary currency efforts, beginning with a
visionary, award-winning article by Teruko Mizushima in 1950.246 Mizushima developed the core
ideas of a time-based currency and a time bank, and went on to establish her own volunteer labor
bank in Osaka in 1973, which is still in operation today.247
But, why is such a vast and diversified complementary currency movement happening in Japan?

Japans Meltdown and Currency Experiments



In 1990, Japan hit an economic wall, similar in effect to what the crisis of 2008 meant for the United
States. Triggered initially by a real estate crash, this economy has been plagued by declines for the better
part of the last two decades. The total wealth lost in Japan during the first five-year downward period
alone, from 1990-1995, is estimated in excess of $10 trillion, resulting mostly from real estate and stock
market losses. This loss represents two years of the Japanese GDP at the timethe equivalent of the total
losses incurred by Japan during the entire span of World War II!

Until 1995, most Japanese believed what they were being toldthat just as in any other business cycle,
things would get better after a few years of tough times. But every conventional recipe was tried to
relaunch the economy: dropping interest rates (all the way to zero), gigantic public work projects (by
encasing in cement 60 percent of the Japanese shoreline), tax cuts; massive deficit spending (to the point
where governmental debt represents 200 percent of annual GDP!), and a desperate attempt to increase
consumption through a coupon system. None of these conventional solutions succeeded in getting the
economy back on track. The effects have been devastating and in a growing number of cases, fatal. For
example, in Japan there is a suicide every 15 minutes, mostly involving men with families who are taking
their own lives due to financial stress.248

Gradually, the government and grassroots circles began to look at less conventional solutions. It is in
this context that the blossoming of Japanese complementary currencies was started.

From the mid-nineties onwards, the Japanese government began to quietly but ambitiously experiment
with complementary currency innovations. Under the guidance of Toshiharu Kato, the former head of the
Services Department of the Ministry of Economy, Trade and Industry (METI), dozens of new currencies
were designed. A number of nongovernmental initiatives also began at the grassroots level.

Rui Izumi, an associate professor at the School of Economics, Senshu University in Tokyo, points to
government support as a major contributor to the growth in complementary currencies:

The central government and many local governments are supporting local currencies in positive
ways. For example, they have given financial support to some organizations, and [both] the Minister
of METI and the president of the Bank of Japan have made several encouraging remarks publicly
about these systems.249

These government-sponsored projects were implemented in communities of very different scales,
ranging from small villages to entire prefectures (roughly equivalent to a U.S. county), and involved
millions of people. The trials ran for a period of three years or so, and the results were carefully
observed. The purpose behind the currency experiments, the cost of which was estimated at over $10
million per year, is to understand as fully as possible what works best and under which circumstances.

In accordance with the well-known Japanese decision-making tradition, before a significant change is
made and publicized, it must first reach an approval through consensus. This process is still taking place,
and consequently, the currency initiatives have not yet been implemented to scale.

In the midst of this unusual Japanese research and development phase, hundreds of currencies were
privately initiated. One family of such systems is the Fureai Kippu, a health care system designed to help

address the economic consequences of an aging society.


The Fureai Kippu



Two-thirds of all humans who ever lived to 65 years or older are alive today. The nation with the largest
aging population in the developed world is Japan, with some 1.8 million elderly or handicapped citizens
currently in need of daily care. The number of elders is expected to double over the course of the next
decade.

Traditionally, two strategies have been used worldwide to try and deal with the economic
consequences of this Age Wave:

trying to honor the financial promises that were made to the retired and elderly at the risk of fiscal
bankruptcy, as seen, for example, in some Scandinavian countries;
gradually cutting support to the elderly to match available funds, as seen in the United States and
Great Britain.250
Tsutomu Hotta, a highly respected former Minister of Justice in Japan, realized that these two principal
conventional strategies were unsatisfactory. In 1991 he decided to tackle Japans Age Wave using a
different approach. He created a new complementary currency system, the Fureai Kippu, whose literal
translation is Caring Relationship Tickets. The Sawayaka Welfare Foundation further developed this
idea in 1995.

The Fureai Kippu system provides the elderly and handicapped with many services not covered in the
official national health care program. Its units are accounted for in hours of service. Various kinds of
services have different valuations. Assistance with bathing, for example, can be given a higher hourly rate
than shopping.

In what amounts to a health care time-savings account, those who care for the elderly in the Fureai
Kippu system accumulate credits and may draw on them in a variety of ways. Caregivers may elect to
electronically transfer part or all of their Fureai Kippu credits to parents or relatives who may live in
another part of the country, or may instead make use of these credits if they themselves get ill. Such
options ensure that ever more people are cared for. Electronic clearinghouses perform these credit
transfers.

The elderly receiving care report strong preferences for the services offered by Fureai Kippu
caregivers to those who are instead paid in conventional national currency. The main reason cited is the
qualitative difference in the relationships. Fureai Kippu recipients consider the care to be more personal.
Many of the caregivers involved in these programs report similarly that they often perceive the elders they
treat as surrogates for their own parents. In short, the relationship is different!

An estimated 387 Fureai Kippu systems are now operational in Japan.251 The economic savings are
substantial; the human support network makes it possible for the elders to stay in their own homes longer
or return home sooner after a medical intervention, rather than remaining in far more costly clinical or
hospice settings. The savings, the human interaction involved, and the greater sense of community that is
engendered benefit all. And, as in the case of Curitiba, Brazil (see Chapter One) these benefits are
derived without having to raise taxes or divert funds from other vital programs. No one is burdened for
the improvements.


Takeo Hiranuma, a former head of Japans METI, stated in no uncertain terms: The use of
complementary currencies can bring an end to the long-lasting deflation of the Japanese economy by
supplying additional monies of various types at the local level.252

To give some sense of the sheer magnitude of the initiatives now taking place in this prominent world
economy, the following maps of Japanese complementary currency initiatives are offered. Keep in mind
that the 387 branches of Fureai Kippu have not been included, as they would simply overwhelm the map
to the point of making it unreadable.

The Japanese Exception and Its Significance



The two decades long Japanese crisis, as it is typically described in the Western media, may not be an
isolated Japanese economic problem. Their ongoing recession may instead be the symptom of a structural
world crisis that chronologically happens to have hit Japan first. The arrival of the so-called Information
or Knowledge Age represents a major structural shift; it is not only a new beginning but marks an end as
well. The last shift of such magnitude occurred when the Industrial Age precipitated the end of the
Agrarian Age. Such dramatic shifts are far from painless. One need only look at what happened to the
farmers, many of whom lost their livelihood and way of life; or the landed gentry, who saw their values,
power, and traditions fade into irrelevancy as the Agrarian Age ended.

If Japan is but the first nation to experience what is inevitably waiting for the industrialized world, then
the rest of us had better take notice.

Until recently, the classical European recipe has been to do a little more like the United States and
everything will return to normal. In the aftermath of the Great Recession, however, with millions left
unemployed, after the bursting of the U.S. high-tech and real-estate bubbles, Europeans are slowly facing
up to the realization that what happened in Japan may also happen in the United Kingdom, Italy, France,
Greece, and elsewhere. The specter of deflationa systemic sign of overcapacity across the boardis
now considered a serious possibility outside of Japan as well.

A similar path of denial can be expected in the coming years by the United States, repeating a mantra
heard by the Japanese for more than a decade: Next year, the economy will be back to normal. We can
also expect similar economic proposals and debates regarding tax cuts, lower interest rates, and public
works. But if we are in effect living through a structural shift at the end of the Industrial Age, such recipes
will predictably fail, similar to what has transpired in Japan.

It is under this light that what is going on in Japan in the domain of complementary currencies is
relevant for the rest of the world. One of the worlds leading economies has turned itself into a real-life
laboratory for resolving a variety of economic and social problems from the bottom up, thanks to
monetary innovations. China and Switzerland are now in the process of implementing Japanese-style
Fureai Kippu system experiments for their own elderly and disabled. Can the rest of the world afford not
to learn from those experiments?

THE SABER

The Saber (sah-BAIR), derived from the Portuguese word for knowledge, is a Brazilian
complementary currency initiative created to address educational needs, designed in collaboration with
Professor Gilson Schwarz from the University of Sao Paolo.253 Unlike LETS and Time Dollars, both of
which are mutual credit systems, the Saber currency is backed by conventional fiat money. Though
intended specifically for use in education, this particular design also helps to illustrate how limited public
funds can be leveraged to provide a much greater return for use in meeting societies needs.

Brazils institutions of higher learning are running below capacity; university lecture halls are rarely if
ever filled. This is related to the economic realities of the country, with large numbers of poor. As
elsewhere, adolescents from poor backgrounds are less likely to pursue higher educations. Though the
economics of education is a very complex issue, inadequate subsidies limit the availability of educational
tools, resources, and personnel to help students excel, particularly those students from economically
depressed areas. Additionally, poorer students, even those who do excel, usually lack sufficient personal
financial means to afford higher educations.

When Brazil privatized its mobile telephone industry in 1998, it introduced a special one percent tax
that was earmarked for higher education purposes. By 2003, this Education Fund had grown to more than
$1 billion. The question on Professor Schwarzs mind was how to get the best bang for the billion?
Conventional solutions, such as the American GI Bill, which helps finance education for those veterans
who have served in the military, provide student loans directly to individual applicants for their own
education alone. Brazils proposal instead creates a learning chain that co-involves a number of
students and allows each to benefit from the same initial amount of money.

The original design for the Saber education currency was allocated first to primary schools,
particularly in poorer communities where school funding is not sufficiently available. This currency is
designed to incentivize students to help both themselves and other students through tutoring. Each Saber is
first given to the youngest students in primary schools, who transfer this currency to older students (for
instance, 3rd graders) in return for the help they receive with their schoolwork. In compensation for the
hours spent mentoring, these older students can make use of the Sabers they earned to get assistance from
4th or 5th graders, and so on.

Through this learning chain, anywhere from five to ten students receive help from advanced students
using the Saber. At the end of this cycle, the currency would finally go to senior students who could then
use the Saber to pay for part or all of their university tuition.254

Private universities could exchange Sabers for conventional money with the education fund, but at a
discount of up to 50 percent. This approach not only helps students, but makes economic sense to
universities. The marginal expense incurred by an additional student has little impact on universities as
most of their expenditures are fixed. Similar to empty seats on an airplane or in a movie theatre,
universities remain open and professors teach whether a lecture hall is full or half empty. Better to get
half of a tuition fee for an otherwise vacant seat than none at all.

The benefits of the Saber not only include economic savings but extend to other important social returns
as well.

A Learning Multiplier

Several decades of research have shed new light on learning retention, that is, how much of what is
being taught is remembered. Retention depends less on the person who is learning or on the particular
topics of study, but is instead more directly related to the kind of delivery mechanism involvedthe
process by which the learning takes place. Research shows that average learning retention rates are
dramatically higher when learning occurs actively rather than passively, as illustrated in the learning
pyramid, next page.255

What is striking is that traditional education systems commonly use the two least effective methods
available: lecturing and reading, by means of which only 5-10 percent of what is being taught will be
remembered. In stark contrast, an impressive 90 percent retention rate applies to what one teaches others.
There is therefore, a ninefold to eighteenfold increase in learning retention rates.

Factoring in retention rate gains and other benefits derived by using Sabers amounts to a very
significant bang for the educational buck:


Figure 15.1 - Learning Pyramid

a fivefold minimum leverage increase via the learning multiplier (the number of students making use
of each Saber), which allows educational funds to be used for many more than one student;
a tenfold average leverage increase in learning retention, via active tutoring (actually from ninefold
to eighteenfold increase, but averaged out to its near lowest estimate);
a twofold leverage increase as a result of the 50 percent discount applied to redemption of Saber
complementary currencies by the Education Fund.
The overall multiplier effect of using Sabers is at least a hundredfold (5 x 10 x 2 = 100).

This rough estimate of $100 billion in education benefits by use of the Saber compared to $1 billion
obtained through conventional scholarships, though significant, still does not tell the whole story. Other
benefits, though less-readily quantifiable, include: maximization of university facilities; the hope,
opportunity, and stronger bonds generated among students; and the related benefits to family members, the
community, and society as a whole of increased educational opportunities.


The Saber program could also be expanded beyond the conventional classroom. Students could, for
example, teach their newly learned reading and writing skills to illiterate parents or grandparents, or help
the elderly and handicapped by reading or recording oral histories of a region. These types of programs
would encourage intergenerational relationships and further learning, provide extra-needed assistance for
the elderly without burdening government coffers, and offer students the opportunity to experience the
sense of accomplishment that comes with active citizenship through rendering service to others.

The Saber and the Brain Shift



One of the few certainties we have about our collective future is that it will require a massive amount of
learning by just about everybody, everywhere. As noted by a background paper for the OECD Innovation
Strategy, improvements in learning could very well become a key leverage point for successfully meeting
the challenges of the 21st century: Only countries that implement policies to reform their education to
promote adaptability and creativity in adults and children are likely to remain at the forefront of
human development and technology. 256Other recent reports from different countries have come to a
similar conclusion.

The problem is that most educational systems today are not designed with 21st century understandings
or objectives, and do not promote adaptability and creativity. Current education and training systems
instead tend to develop conformity and alignment instead of creativity, competition instead of
collaboration, and knowledge reproduction instead of knowledge creation!257 The public educational
systems in the United States and many other countries today are, in fact, based on a very narrowly-focused
set of industrial-age assumptions and objectives that, like our monetary system, date back centuries (see
insert).

The Origins of todays Public Education

Todays education system is based on a model to create a society of dutiful, obedient foot soldiers.
As Thom Hartmann points out in his book, Beyond ADD, our system of learning dates back to early
19th century Prussia (now Germany), a country renowned for its merciless and efficient armyuntil
it suffered a staggering military defeat at the hands of Napoleon. Prussias shocked leaders were
determined to find out why their soldiers had gotten so soft. Philosopher Johann G. Fichte, in his
Address to the German Nation, indicted the countrys school system, citing its failure to produce
compliant pupils. Brash, undisciplined students, he asserted, went on to become disobedient and
rebellious soldiers.
In 1819, Prussia established a universal compulsory school system with the goal of producing
dutiful children who would follow orders and become winning soldiers. This strategy worked, at
least for a time. Over the next five or six decades, Prussia became a leading industrial and military
power due largely to an efficient, though uninspired workforce and army.
Governments from other nations sent representatives to Prussia to discover its secrets of success.
Horace Mann, an influential educational figure from America, was among those summoned. Duly
impressed, Mann raved about how the disciplined Prussian school system could be useful in
America to cure social ills, tame the Wild West, and provide quality workers.
Not surprisingly, U.S. industrial leaders embraced the concept of a system that would provide
colonies of compliant workers to labor in factories and on railroads. In the words of Hartmann, "So
began the dumbing down of America.258

Like our monetary paradigm, the education system that came into being in the 19th and 20th centuries
confined itself to a very narrow set of industrial-age objectives and suffered from the limited
understandings of the period regarding human intelligence and learning. Moreover, this system of teaching
was unaware of and not prepared for the shift that has been taking place in recent decades from left to
right brain thinking.

It has been known for some time that there are different forms of intelligence. Project Zero at Harvard
has documented eight distinct types, out of which primarily two are developed and measured in the
conventional education system: the verbal/linguistic and the logical/mathematical. The other six forms of
intelligence tend to be simply ignored.259 A child who is gifted primarily in one of the other modes of
learningmusical, spatial, bodily/kinesthetic, intrapersonal, interpersonal, and pattern recognitionis
likely to end up being considered as mediocre and become an educational failure.

Different forms of intelligence are, however, only part of the story. What has also been pretty much
ignored are the different ways in which we process information and learn.

In their first book, Right Brain Children in a Left Brain World, authors Jeffrey Freed and Laurie
Parsons-Cantillo, point out that the two halves of our brain each process information, but in different
ways. A significant and growing percentage of our population are not internally wired to learn by
traditional left-brain teaching methods such as passive listening and memorizing facts.260 As educator and
pyshologist Linda Kreger Silverman explains: The left hemisphere is analytical, sequential, and timeoriented. The right hemisphere perceives the whole, synthesizes, and apprehends movement in space.261
More students today respond to right-brain dominant methods that are more experiential, kinesthetic, and
emphasize an explorative dialogue among students and with teachers.

According to Freed:

Why are we facing such a crisis in education? I would argue that our left-brained schools have rarely
placed an emphasis on creative, critical thinking. Our schools have historically churned out
graduates who, while strong on regurgitating information, lack problem-solving skills. Children are
taught to conform rather than challenge authority; the result is they often lack the ability to make
connections and think in fresh, inventive ways. The traditional American school, with its emphasis
on order, drill, and repetition, probably did a respectable job educating children at a time when kids
were left-brained, less hyperactive, and not so stimulated. The problem is that students today are
fundamentally different. Our classrooms are being flooded by a new generation of right-brained,
visual kids. While our school system plods along using the same teaching methods that were in vogue
decades ago, students are finding it more and more difficult to learn that way. As our culture
becomes more visual and brain dominance shifts to the right, the chasm widens between teacher and
pupil. Our schools are no longer congruent with the way many children think.262

In their second book, Right Brain Children in a RIGHT Brain World (Qiterra Press, 2012), Freed and
Parsons-Cantillo report on the magnitude of the shift that is taking place, with more than half of todays
school age children believed to be right brain learners. Dr. Silverman estimates that one third of todays
student population are strongly right-brained; another 30 percent rely on both hemispheres but tend to
favor the right.263 This is a substantial increase from 1997, at which time approximately 40 percent of
children were right brain learners. This shift in how we access information is in no small measure related
to technological advancements in recent decades, including the internet, calculators, smart phones, video
gamming, and other forms of interactive media.

Freed and Parsons-Cantillo see in the Saber not only an economic instrument to enhance educational
opportunities, but also as a means to help develop collaborative skills among students, to cater to the
individual forms of intelligence of each child, and to enhance learning among right-brainers.

Saber and Demurrage



Demurrage can be used to help manage the balance between the numbers of students wanting university
seats each year and availability. A demurrage fee would be applied to encourage students to use Sabers in
accord with the year printed on the Saber. If they were not used to pay for tuition before or during that
year, they could be exchanged for Sabers of the following year but with a penalty of, say, 20 percent,
when a new expiration date is stamped on the paper currency. This gives a strong incentive to use the
Sabers on or before the deadline.

Saber and Inflation



Three factors make the noninflationary dynamics of the Saber fundamentally different from those of
regular money. They are:

Sabers are only redeemable into conventional money by universities or third-level educational
institutions within the system, and only for educational purposes;
the quantity of Sabers issued would be equal to the universities capacities to increase their number
of students, thereby avoiding the inflation problem generated by a currency that is created in excess
of the goods or services available. Extra students would be using seats that would otherwise be
empty;
the demurrage fee of 20 percent ensures that the Sabers circulate only for a limited and controlled
time period, further reducing the possibility of excess currency.

Support for the Saber



A variation of the original Saber project is being developed by Professor Schwarz, with funding by
Brazils Ministry of Science and Technology, Brazils Ministry of Culture, and the Brazilian Development
Bank (Banco Nacional de Desenvolvimento Economico e Social, or BNDES). It should also be noted that
the Saber also enjoys support from the central bank of Brazil, which has formally acknowledged that
social currencies not only do not pose a threat to conventional monetary management, but instead
provide a significant positive contribution to the social fabric and the economy in general.

The legal counsel of Brazils central bank has recently concluded that: social currencies should be
regarded as public policy instruments for local development compatible with monetary policy.)264
This is the first central bank to make such an acknowledgment. Other countries have expressed interest in
this concept.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

Many of our most pressing social concerns are treatable. Improvements can be made without the need to
increase taxes, redistribute wealth, borrow, or otherwise increase burdens on already limited public
resources and overtaxed economies. Communities around the world are instead finding relief in the form
of complementary currencies, such as the Fureai Kippu and the Saber. These monetary initiatives can be
designed specifically to address particular concerns by ways and means that do not hurt anyone and
instead promote the general good. Many different monetary designs and improvements are now readily
available, made possible by the revolution now taking hold in our understanding and use of money.

Society functions in a manner consistent with the systems that are in place. Until and unless there is
amendment to the operating systems that govern society, the desired changes and improvements sought by
growing numbers of concerned citizens will simply not take hold. But by rethinking money, many new
options and opportunities do become readily available.

CHAPTER SIXTEEN - Commercial-Purpose Currencies



Sure, moneys all wrong, and the devil decreed it;

It doesnt belong to the people who need it.

~PIET HEIN

While many communities around the world are turning to complementary currencies to help address an
ever-expanding range of social issues, new monetary innovations are also being applied increasingly to
business-related concerns and objectives. As noted, complementary currencies have been employed for
commercial purposes down through history and are finding increasing use again today in business.

One of the most extensive uses of complementary currencies is the familiar loyalty mechanism used by
airlines, credit card companies, hotels, and travelers worldwidefrequent flyer miles. Though not
customarily thought of as such, frequent flyer miles are a complementary medium of exchange, with ever
increasing opportunities offered to earning flight miles, be it with purchases made through branded credit
and debit cards, eating at participating restaurants, renting vehicles, and the like. There are many
opportunities as well to make use of these earned miles for an expanding array of products and services.
These and other commercial-purpose currencies have clearly demonstrated that such systems need not be
restricted to small-scale objectives or local applications alone. During the first 20 years of operations,
9.77 trillion frequent flier miles were awarded, and this number is still growing at a rate of 11 percent per
annum.265

Two of the many timely and vital commercial complementary currency applications are examined next.
Each initiative is designed to help businesses, particularly those that are small to medium-sized, weather
the ups and downs of the business cycle, and to help ensure against the loss of jobs during downturns. We
begin with the longest surviving commercial-purpose complementary currency in the Western world, the
Swiss WIR.

THE WIR AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE



An insidious feature of economic downturns is the accompanying freeze on credit by banks to businesses.
The present money-creation process tends to amplify the fluctuations of the business cycle. When business
is good in a particular market, banks tend to be more generous in terms of credit availability, thereby
pushing the good times into a potentially inflationary boom period. Conversely, as soon as the business
horizon looks less promising, access to credit is tightened, contributing to the deterioration of a minor
business dip into a full-blown downturn.

With the loss of liquidity, a domino effect ensues. Spending decreases, businesses get stuck with
inventory, orders to suppliers for materials and services for new products dry up, and so on. A chain of
bankruptcies is started with all its effects on unemployment and related social problems. The credit crisis
that accompanied the global recession is one case in point. Though central banks try to counteract this
cycle, their success is variable, at best.

Several years following the recent global downturn, the economic climate remains uncertain. Many
companies struggle to stay afloat, while U.S. unemployment remains stubbornly highwell over 9
percent according to official estimates, with unofficial figures much higher still.266 The jobless face fierce
competition for work, and those with a job are watching their paychecks shrink.267 While the trillions in
bailouts aims at preventing a repeat of the 1930s, these sums could not prevent the massive disruption that
has taken place, nor has it restored confidence in the marketplace. According to an Associated Press-GfK
poll taken in the first half of 2010, only 20 percent of Americans surveyed believed that the economy was
doing well.268 Given the banking systems inherent aversion to risk, credit availability remains hard to
come by and is not likely to return to pre-recession levels any time soon.

All of this begs the question: What can be done to help businesses weather this and future economic
storms?

Options, though not necessarily of the conventional kind, certainly do exist. One example of what is
possible comes to us from Switzerland during the difficult Great Depression period.

Switzerland enjoys one of the most stable economies and highest standards of living in the world.
Factors often cited for the economic well-being of this nation include tourism, chocolates, precision
watches, a world-famous banking system, and political neutrality during and following World War II.
While each of these may well play a role, a unique, little-known, but very robust complementary currency
has also contributed to the countrys economic stability for the past 75 years.

This nation is home to the oldest continuously functioning complementary-currency system in the
Western world. Called the WIR, it is a Swiss acronym for Wirtschaftsring-Genossenschaft, which roughly
translates as Economic Mutual Support Circle. Wir is also the pronoun we in German.

In the early 1930s, Switzerland was faced with economic woes similar to those of neighboring
Germany and Austria. By the time of its inception in 1934, WIRs 16 founding members and many of their
clients had received notices from their respective banks that credit lines were going to be reduced or
eliminated. Bankruptcy was only a matter of time. Unable to count on the banking sector to obtain the
necessary capital during this difficult period, these Swiss businessmen decided to create a mutual credit
system among themselves, and invited their clients and suppliers to join. Unlike the afore-mentioned Wra

and Wrgl systems, the Swiss initiative managed to not only survive the period, but continues quite
successfully to this very day.

The WIR provides more than seven decades of experience and demonstrates the degree to which
complementary currencies can assist both individual businesses and the economy-at-large.

How It Works

When business A makes a purchase from business B, As account is debited and the corresponding amount
is credited to Bs account. The unit of account is the WIR, with parity between it and the Swiss franc (one
WIR equals one Swiss franc). The currency is designed to serve only as a medium of exchange to
facilitate business transactions. WIR accounts do not bear interest and do not serve as a practical store of
value.

The WIR (veer) was devised to counteract the business cycle. This internal currency is used to
purchase and sell goods and services from business members within the WIR network, especially when
national currency is difficult to come by, as occurs during economic downturns. When banks tighten
lending practices, members of the WIR network can simply opt to accept or borrow the readily available
WIR complementary currency to continue transacting business, thus diminishing the likelihood of more
severe supply or demand side disruptions. Once the economy improves and bank credit is again
normalized, WIR members can then shift back once again to the national currency. In essence, the issuance
of WIR currency expands and contracts countercyclically with the Swiss franc economy.

The countercyclical function of the WIR provides an important macroeconomic advantage not only to
WIR members but also to the Swiss economy as a whole. A notable quantitative study on the WIRs
macroeconomic impact was conducted by Dr. James P. Stodder, professor at the Lally School of
Management and Technology at Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute. Dr. Stodders study concluded that:
Growth in the number of WIR participants has tracked Swiss unemployment very closely, consistently
maintaining a rate of about one-tenth the increase in the number of unemployed.269

Simply stated, the study showed that the WIR system contributed significantly to the stability of the
Swiss economy and to its low unemployment rates. When the conventional Swiss franc economy slows,
more people and firms participate in the WIR economy, thus demanding fewer disruptions to business and
far fewer layoffs. The WIR functions as a powerful stabilizing mechanism that limits the severity of the
business cycle and the inevitable ups and downs of the economy.

Professor Tobias Studer, from the Center of Economic Studies at Basel University, Switzerland,
considers the Stodder research a breakthrough. He reports:

For the first time, an independent American researcher has arrived at a surprising conclusion: far
from representing a factor of disturbance for the national monetary policy, the credits created by
WIR constitute a support of the National Bank [the Swiss central bank] in pursuit of its monetary
policy objectives.270

History and Scope



It bears noting that the WIRs contributions to both the economy and the banking sector were not always
so well appreciated. When operations first began in the 1930s, the WIR was erroneously viewed as a
direct threat to the banking systems hegemony, and, prompted a similar response to those taken by the
central banks in neighboring Germany and Austria at the time (against the Wra and Wrgl, respectively).
The Swiss banks proceeded to mount an aggressive press campaign to stop this complementary currency
initiative from occurring. Miraculously, their hostile efforts failed.

In the first three months of operations, the WIR attracted 1,700 participants. Within a year, more than
3,000 businesses made use of this complementary-currency system, and were linked with one another by a
catalog of 850 unique categories of goods and services. A cooperative was established to track WIR user
accounts, which soon allowed participants to borrow WIR at the low interest rate of 1-1.5 percent. These
loans, similar to those issued by a conventional bank, were backed by inventory, real estate, and other
hard assets. The system was ultimately credited with saving many of the businesses involved.271

The system remains fully operational today, with more than 65,000 members participating in WIR
nationally. This represents nearly one quarter of all Swiss businesses. In 2006, trading volume in WIRs
was 1.67 billion Swiss francs ($1.4 billion).272 WIR owns its own bank that operates in both Swiss
francs and WIR, with six regional offices that conduct business in four languages.

Members tend to participate in WIR exchanges for the following reasons:

cost efficiencycommission on sales and payment expenses are limited to 0.6 percent on deals
completed in WIR;
cheaper and more readily available credit than is issued in national currency, particularly during
downturns;
auxiliary services such as direct mail, publicity among members, publications, and more, encourage
and support small to medium-sized businesses;
access to a large, varied, and prescreenedthus dependable and credit-worthyclient base, which
helps engender trust, a key ingredient with all currencies;
ways and means to continue to conduct business during periods of contraction or high interest rates.
Within the context of the recent global economic crisis and the corresponding credit crunch threatening
countless businesses, the question that begs to be asked is, might the WIRs proven ability to facilitate
business activity and employment during economic downturns be of use by other communities? Given
that complementary currencies have become well established in one of the most conservative, hard-nosed
capitalist countries in the world because they make both business and macroeconomic sense, why should
it be any different in the United States and elsewhere?

The case is made below for expanding the WIR model as a means of reducing the impact of the global
financial crisis on businesses and governments, both locally and nationally.

COMMERCIAL CREDIT CIRCUIT (C3)



What began as a financial and banking crisis in 2008 rapidly turned into a major job crisis. The bulk of
the global economy and the vast majority of private jobs are provided by small and medium sized
enterprises (SMEs). The survival of many such firms was put at risk due to cash flow problems related to
the downturn.

The Problem

Under the current paradigm, SMEs rely upon banks and other finance institutions for credit. When credit
lines are tightened, the entire economy is adversely affected, especially SMEs. These firms must
overcome unique hurdles to continue operations, particularly during downturns. Unlike large customers
who are given 90 days or more to pay for services and goods, SMEs are pressured for prompt payments,
often within 30 days. When banks either refuse to provide bridge financing or do so at steep conditions, a
deadly cash flow trap ensues for SMEs. This has long been an endemic issue in developing countries, but
lately has become more critical in developed countries of late as well.

The Solution

The Commercial Credit Circuit (C3), like the WIR, provides another option for needed liquidity, and at
more reasonable costs than are typically available. This is accomplished by forming a credit circuit
among SMEs, their customers, and suppliers, with the addition of an insurer. For a small cost, the insurer
underwrites the business deal to guarantee that all parties involved with a business transaction will
receive payment.

Unlike the WIR, any transaction using C3 is fully convertible at any time into national money, allowing
this currency system to more easily attract business entities that might otherwise shy away from a
complementary means of payment.

How it Works

Let us say that a theatre seat manufacturer receives an order for 100,000 seats from a reputable firm, who
will pay for the seats by check on delivery. The manufacturer (business A) has its own workers to
produce the seats, and a supplier for the requisite materials (business B). Everything is in place to make
the deal happen except for the money needed to pay workers and business B. Normally, business A would
have to go to a bank for a bridge loan for this situation, which, depending on factors such as the business
climate at the time, may or may not be successful. With C3, the needed financing is available in another
way.

The process uses insured invoices or other payment claims as liquid payment instruments within a
business-to-business clearing network. Each recipient of the liquid payment instrument has the choice to
either convert it into national money (at a cost), or directly pay its own suppliers with the proceeds of the
insured invoice. The manner by which C3 works is described below.

C3 Step by Step

1. The business that initiates a C3 transaction (business A) starts by securing insurance for an invoice
up to a predetermined amount, based on the specific creditworthiness of their own business and that
of the claims they obtain on third parties (the clients of A).
1. Business A opens a checking account in the clearing-network, electronically exchanges the
insured invoice for clearing funds, and immediately pays its supplier (business B) with those
funds via the network.
2. To receive its payment, business B only needs to open its own checking account in the network.
3. Business B now has a positive balance on its account in the network (regardless of when the
original invoice comes due from business A).
4. Business B is thus in position to proceed with one of two options: either cash in the clearing
funds for conventional national money (at the cost of paying banking fees plus the interest for
the outstanding period (say, 90 days); or paying its own supplier (business C) with the
corresponding clearing funds (at no cost).
5. Business C only needs to open an account in the network. It then has the same two options as
business B: cash in the funds for national money, or spend the C3 funds in the network. And so
on
6. At maturity of the invoice, the network is paid the amount of the invoice in national money,
either by the client of business A, or (in case of default by that client) by the insurance company.
Whoever owns the C3 funds secured by the insured invoice can cash them in for national money
without incurring any interest costs (though any associated banking fees still apply).

Benefits

The benefits to participating businesses in C3 include:

Businesses increase their access to short-term funds as needed to improve their working capital and
the use of their productive capacity. The size of this credit can be built up to a stable level between a
quarter (covering therefore up to an average of 90 days of invoices) and half of annual sales, at a
cost substantially lower than what is otherwise possible.
Suppliers are paid immediately, regardless of the payment schedule of the original buyer. Thus,
ample liquidity is available at very low cost to the entire SME network. The approach provides a
viral spreading of participation to the C3 networks from clients to suppliers.
All the necessary technologies are proven; new legislation or government approvals are not
required, and the necessary software is available in open source. Only invoices that are 100 percent
guaranteed and 100 percent computerized are acceptable in a C3 system. C3 thereby encourages the
generalization and more efficient use of IT infrastructure among SMEs, including the opening of new
markets and marketing channels through e-commerce.
Government benefits, especially at the regional level, include:

Additional income streams are provided for government. An effective way to encourage C3 strategy
usage is for governments to accept payment of taxes and fees in C3 currency. This encourages others
to accept C3 payment as well, and provides added income to government from transactions that
otherwise would not occur. Additional income in national currency becomes available automatically
no longer than 90 days after the payment, with no disruption to existing procurement policies. This
strategy is now under serious consideration for use by the government of Uruguay.
The C3 approach is a dependable way to systemically reduce unemployment. Governments at
different levels (federal, state or regional) can contribute to a joint guarantee mechanism, which
would be considerably cheaper to fund than subsidies.
C3 helps shift economic activities from the black or grey economy into the official economy, because
SMEs need to be formally incorporated to participate, and all exchanges are electronic and therefore
traceable.
C3 systems are best organized at a regional level, so that each network remains at a manageable
scale. Businesses with an account in the same regional network have an incentive to spend their
balances with each other, and thus further stimulate the regional economy. C3 provides a win-win
environment for participants, and promotes other collaborative activities among regional businesses.
Each C3 network should use the same insurance standards and compatible software to interconnect
as a network of networks to facilitate exchanges internationally.
Benefits to banks and the financial system include the following:

C3 significantly streamlines the lending and management for insurance and for loan providers. As the
C3 process is entirely computerized, SMEs can become a more profitable sector for banks, as the
credit lines are negotiated with the entire clearing network, thus providing the financial sector with

automatic risk diversification among participants in the network. In the upcoming surge of new
competitors in the marketsuch as Facebook, Google, or Tesco currencies and banksthis
monetary innovation provides an additional window for banks to sell their core activities.
Most banks are also involved in providing insurance services. C3 opens up a whole new market for
insurances and credit, all the way down to services for microfinance enterprises. As C3 is fully
computerized, even such small-scale entities can now be serviced at a very low cost.
The C3 mechanism systemically contributes to the stability of employment and of the entire economy,
which is helpful for the overall solidity of the banks portfolios.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

Owners of small businesses can do something more than hope that the economy gets better, or that
someone else will see to their needs. The WIR and the C3 are easily implementable and provide cash
flow and other benefits for all those directly involved in these complementary currency programs, as well
as to the economy-at-large. Additionally, the software required for C3 is available in open source to
encourage start-ups of such systems anytime, anywhere. If Uruguay can achieve this on a national scale, it
can be done on any other scale that makes sense to the participants.

CHAPTER SEVENTEEN - The Terra, A Trade Reference Currency



Many have a wait and see attitude to innovate proposals of this nature, but they shouldnt with the
Terra. Such a Trade Reference Currency reduces risk, stabilizes the world economy, and is a more cost
effective approach for international business.

~TAKASHI KIUCHI

Chairman, The Future 500

Former CEO, Mitsubishi Electric, America

The world needs a global currency that is nobodys national money. This may at first appear as a
surprising idea, but there are several powerful reasons to justify it.

WHY A NEW GLOBAL CURRENCY?



There are two key reasons why a specialized global currency is required today:

Geopolitical: If the dollar should lose its privileged status as a global reserve currency, we can
expect a power grab by other currencies for influence in their respective regions, which has
historically generated many wars.
Practical: A specialized global currency can be designed and administrated to resolve several key
issues, including economic instability and corporate short-termism.
A few words are warranted on each of these arguments.

Geopolitical

The dollars use as a global reserve currency gives the United States a particular advantage as the only
country today that can afford a permanent deficit in its trade. This is because central banks are obliged to
accept dollars under the current rules of the IMF. Such an advantage, however, should not be considered a
permanent status. This same torch was passed from Britain to America after World War II. Some people
claim that it may well soon pass, in turn, to China.

Such transitions often incur friction, and fights for monetary zones of influence usually provoke damage.
The most dangerous period occurs during the decline of a hegemonic power whereby the old guard no
longer commands enough power to impose its own solution, but still retains sufficient influence to block
any solution proposed by others. This is the situation we find ourselves in today. If a dollar crisis should
erupt, the most likely outcome will be a fragmentation of the global system into three monetary zones: a
dollar-dominated zone in the Western hemisphere, a european-dominated zone, and an Asian zone (still
under preparation). We might expect high volatility between these monetary zones, even more than what is
presently taking place with national currencies. It is also likely that foreign exchange controls will
materialize between these zones, which will be costly and otherwise problematic. None of this is
advantageous or conducive to peaceful economic and political evolution.

The introduction of the global Terra Trade Reference Currency (TRC) avoids a major potential source
of conflict, while solving important problems for all those businesses and other entities that depend on
easy and efficient global commercial exchanges.

Practical

Introducing a special-purpose global currency resolves several other key issues of particular importance
today. Contrary to what takes place with conventional money, the Terra would spontaneously operate
countercyclically with the business cycle and contribute to the stabilization of the world economy.
Perhaps most importantly, the Terra is designed to give multinational corporations a strong incentive for
long-term thinking.

Given the stakes that are involved and the current financial instability, we believe this to be a timely
and vital proposal.

Even with the detail given here, this chapter should be considered a mere overview. For those
interested in a deeper understanding, please consult the White Paper available for download on dedicated
web sites.273

CHARACTERISTICS OF THE TERRA



The Terra is based on fundamentally distinct principles from conventional, bank-debt issued money. Key
differences include:

The Terra is 100 percent asset-backed, while conventional money is backed by nothing except the
belief that other people will accept it. Therefore, by definition, there can never be fractional reserve
Terras, and the supply of Terras does not rise or fall with the expansion or contraction of bank
credit.
The Terras assets consist of a balanced basket of a dozen of the most representative commodities
and services in the world economy. This global reference currency thereby offers a natural inflation
hedge.
The Terra, like the WIR and C3, is naturally countercyclical and therefore helps stablize the
economy. Conventional money creation tends to be naturally procyclical, that is, it accentuates the
repeated booms and busts that destabilize the economy, even as central banks try to counteract this
phenomenon.
The Terra does not bear interest. It instead has a demurrage charge of 3.5-4 percent per year (to
cover the cost of storage of the commodities backing the Terra). The Terra is therefore only a trading
and contractual instrument, not a store of value. The Terra therefore encourages trading, while
conventional money encourages accumulation.
The Terra is managed by the Terra Alliance, while conventional money is managed by central banks.
The alliance doesn't decide when to create or redeem Terras; member participants make such
decisions.
Four types of entities participate in the Terra system: Terra backers, Terra users, commodities/futures
markets, and the Terra Alliance itself. In addition, other organizations or individuals may piggyback off
the Terra system, using it simply as a contractual reference unit without participating in the system itself.

The Terra Mechanism



The Terra Alliance operations are now examined.

Creation of Terras

A member with excess inventory of one of the commodities comprising the Terra, can sell such inventory
to the Alliance. By triggering the issuance of the Terra as an inventory receipt (which is paid for and
denominated in Terras), that member is then functioning as a Terra Backer. This is how Terras come into
being. They are in a sense, warehouse receipts, which are an historically very old form of money.

What is a Terra Unit?

A Terra Unit is a claim against a portion of the asset holdings of the Terra Alliance. The Alliance
warehouses large quantities of the commodities comprising the Terra. These quantities always equal, in
total, the amounts necessary to redeem all of the Terra units in existence.

To use a simplified example, suppose there were 100 Terra units in existence and each unit represented
1 ounce of gold, plus 1 pound of copper and 1 bushel of wheat. In that case, the Terra Alliance would
warehouse 100 ounces of gold, 100 pounds of copper, and 100 bushels of wheat at all times.

Taking a more realistic example, suppose that an oil-producing member decides to sell 1 million
barrels of crude oil to the Terra Alliance in exchange for Terras. Given that crude oil is one component of
the Terra basket, the Terra Alliance will use commodities markets to sell enough of the oil and buy
enough of the other 11 components such that all 12 components are once again equally represented in the
Terra basket.274

Conducting Trade in Terras

Once Terras are brought into existence, they can be bought and sold like any other form of money or
commodity. There is, however, a demurrage charge on Terra holdings, at a rate of approximately 3.65
percent per year. Stated differently, a time penalty on keeping Terras is being charged at the rate of about
one hundredth of one percent (.01 percent) per day. Due to the electronic nature of the Terra and the
power of modern computers, this parking fee can be allocated between the traders precisely based on
how long they held onto the Terra units, even down to the minute. This inflation-protected currency
therefore offers a permanent incentive to encourage trading with it. Each entity accepting a payment in
Terra becomes one of the Terra Users.

Redemption of Terras

When members decide for whatever reason to redeem Terras for national currency, they need only present
their Terras to the Terra Alliance. They thereby become the final user. When such a redemption request
is made, the Terra Alliance will sell a sufficient portion of its basket to generate the cash needed to cover
the redemption, and the final user pays a 2 percent transaction fee. This fee aims at discouraging the
cashing of Terras for conventional money. The Alliance will then pay out the proceeds in conventional
money through participating banks.

Piggybackers

There is a last group of parties who will benefit from the existence of Terras, even though they may never
have any dealings with the Alliance, or even may never actually own Terraspiggybackers. Not wishing
to be tied to the vagaries of a particular national currency, they could simply use the Terra as a trade
reference currency, pricing contracts in it but settling those contracts in an equivalent amount of some
other national currency, as agreed upon contractually with the other party.

Refinements

More sophisticated implementations of the Terra can include in the model Terra basket claims for future
services, and even artificial assets such as carbon emission rights. Theoretically, any product or service
could be included in the basket at the condition that it can be standardized and that a corresponding futures
market can be organized.

An Example of the Terra Mechanism



Lets consider a series of transactions made possible by an oil producers decision to accept payment in
Terras rather than conventional money (see Figure 17.1).

1. (a). An oil producer with an excess inventory of 1 million barrels of oil sells that quantity of oil to
the Terra alliance instead of selling it for conventional money. (Note that this decision is more likely
during a downturn, when demand for oil and other commodities declines and when extra sales on the
market would further depress the price).

(b). and (c). The Terra alliance sells some of that oil to increase its holdings of the other 11
component commodities.

(d). The alliance credits the Terra account of the producer with a quantity of Terra units equal to the
purchasing power of 1 million barrels of oil at that time.

2. (a). The oil producer uses some of those Terras to buy an oil rig from a company willing to accept
the Terras in trade.

(b). The rig supplier uses some of the Terras to buy components from its own supplier.

(c). The process continues with the Terras circulating like any other type of money until they are
redeemed.

3. The oil producer, rig supplier, and other Terra users each pay a demurrage charge when using the
Terra, based on how long their Terras were held in their accounts.

4. (a). Whenever Terras are redeemed, the final user will be charged with a 2 percent redemption
fee.

(b). In addition, the Terra Alliance sells that portion of its commodity holdings to which those Terras
have rightful claim, and pays the redeeming party in conventional currency.

5. Piggybackers simply use the Terra as a trade reference currency, pricing contracts in it, but settling
those contracts in an equivalent amount of some other national currency, as agreed upon contractually
with the other party.

Benefits of the Terra



The Terra trade reference currency provides benefits to particular segments of the economy, including:
businesses engaged in international trade, governments of both developed countries and less developed
countries (LDCs), and the nations that are trading partners.

The benefits include:

1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.

a more level playing field among nations;


lower costs of international business;
increased investment in LDCs;
improved stability of the global economy;
protection against inflation;
a shift from short-term to longer term planning.

Let us consider each of these benefits in turn.



1. A level playing field among nations

About two thirds of the time, management of a national currency is beneficial for both the national
economy and world economy. But that still leaves a third of the time in which a policy that is beneficial
for the national economy is detrimental to the world, or vice versa.

When, for instance, the British pound was playing the role of a global currency (from the 19th century
and particularly during the first half of the 20th century), there was a tendency to favor the international
role of the pound over its role for the domestic economy. That tendency helps explain why Britain was the
last country to be able to get rid of war rations after World War II.

When the U.S. dollar started playing the role of a global currency, these priorities were reversed. As
Paul Volcker stated when he was Chairman of the Federal Reserve: Americans are paying my salary, so I
am managing the dollar to the benefit of America.275 We claim that both these outcomes are undesirable.

The Terra solves the quandary between national and global interests by leaving all nations free to
manage their currency as they please, without any detrimental effect to their own national economy or to
that of the world. By virtue of being privately issued, with all participants enjoying equal benefits of use,
participation in the Terra system eliminates the lopsided effects of granting preferred TRC status to any
single nation or group of nations.

2. Lower costs and risks for doing international business

International business activities typically involve someonebe it the buyer, seller, or even bothtaking a
currency risk. In theory, with todays 24/7 electronic currency exchanges, trading in currencies, either
immediately or at some future date (futures contracts), should be straightforward. In practice, the
cumulative costs of such insurance are instead quite high, and efficient markets exist only for half a dozen
major national currencies.

The volatility of the Terra would be less than a quarter of what we currently experience between major
national currencies, even if only 9 major commodities are included in the basket. Both the risks and the
cost of hedging those risks would therefore be significantly lower when using the Terra compared to
todays national currencies.

3. Increased investment in LDCs

Less developed countries tend to be resource-rich and infrastructure-poor. By making their resources
central not just to certain specific kinds of economic activities but to the international financial system
itself, powerful incentives will exist for multinational entities and nations to help these LDCs develop
their infrastructure and resources.

4. Improved stability of the world economic system

Recent decades have seen numerous boom and bust cycles that originated in one nation, but which
cascaded contagiously across international borders.

When banks collectively perceive economic activity as slowing, they withdraw credit from borrowers
because of the possible increased risk. While this is sound practice for individual banks, it is detrimental
for the economies involved, and even for the banking system as a whole. The very act of withdrawing
credit makes it harder for the businesses involved to survive. By similar logic, when the economy is
good, banks eagerly lend money, thereby potentially driving a healthy economic period into an
unsustainable bubble. This amplification of the business cycle is what is meant by procyclical money
creation.

The Terra offers three ways by which it actually helps to balance out the boom and bust cycles.

First, it acts as a countercyclical money creation process. The particular time periods when producers
of raw materials have excess inventories (that can be sold against Terras) tends to coincide with the
downturn of the business cycle.

Second, it offers a complementary monetary system for international trade that is not tied to credit
creation or withdrawal but rather to valuable assets.

Finally, it allows resource suppliers to sell those resources for Terras when there may not be enough
buyers who can pay in traditional money without significantly depressing the price. This, in turn,
generates self-funding buffer stocks. Thes stocks can become critical in the case of crop shortages or
failures due to climate change, particularly in the domain of food commodities. Global stocks are already
dangerously low.

5. Protection against inflation

By structuring the Terra upon the foundation of a representative basket of goods and services that are
central to economic activity worldwide, the Terra serves as a kind of proxy for the most significant
international inputs of the world economy itself. The value of the Terra would therefore adjust
automatically to inflationary pressures due to these inputs.

Using the Terra for contractual agreements, particularly longer term ones, would therefore be an

automatic inflation hedge.



6. A shift from short-term to longer-term thinking

As has been discussed elsewhere in this book, an overemphasis on short-term thinking has contributed to
many of our problems today. Stockholders in public companies typically hold management accountable
for quarterly results. Long-term threats such as global warming, ocean acidity, and deforestation do not
enjoy constituencies willing and able to make long-term investments necessary to rectify them. These are
but symptoms of a widespread systemic failure of money.

It is the nature of interest-bearing currencies that a dollar today is worth more than a dollar tomorrow.
This encourages a focus on short-term cash flow, and the higher the rate of interest the more short-term
becomes the thinking. In contrast, exactly the opposite is true with a demurrage-charged currency. Almost
all corporate decisions on investments or allocations of funds are undertaken using the Discounted Cash
Flow technique, whereby the interest rate is part of the discount rate. Demurrage is instead a negative
interest rate that reduces the discount applied.

The historical record shows that the impact of money on investment timelines isnt just theory: in
cultures where demurrage-charged currency complements interest-bearing currency, a longer planning
horizon develops and more long-term investments are made. Examples of this include the Central Middle
Ages and Dynastic Egypt (described in more detail in Part IV).

This difference in planning horizons can be compared to a well-known principle of inventory
management. Sophisticated companies strive to have exactly the right amount of each production
component (asset) on hand when needed for their production activities. Too little, and they cannot fulfill
orders. Too much, and they are wasting money on inventory carrying costs. The concept is called just-intime inventory.

Money is also an asset, and can therefore be inventoried. Demurrage-charged money such as the Terra
is expensive to hold. Therefore, if you receive it sooner than you need it, you are wasting money. Such a
system encourages a mindset of receiving money only when it is actually needed in the future. It
encourages a more forward-looking mindset, which balances the immediacy of interest-bearing money.

Differences from Earlier Proposals



The Terra is a commodity-basket currency. Several proposals of this kind have been made by noted
economists for more than a century.276 The main reason why these other plans have not been implemented
is not due to a technical fault of the concept itself, but rather that they were aiming at replacing the
conventional monetary system. Such replacement would have put in jeopardy powerful vested interests.
This is not the case with the Terra proposal. The win-win strategy underlying the Terra mechanism
includes the financial sector as well. Anything that exists under the current monetary modus operandi
would remain in operation after the introduction of the Terra, as it is designed to operate in parallel with
the existing system.

The political context for a new international monetary treaty, a new Bretton Woods type agreement, has
not been available. The Terra avoids this difficulty by relying on private initiative. From a legal or tax
standpoint, it would fit within the existing official framework of international barter (technically called
countertrade), and not require any new formal governmental agreements to make it operational.

The final conceptual difference between the Terra and all previous proposals, and perhaps the most
important one, is the use of demurrage. The fact that the storage costs of the basket would be covered by
the bearer of the Terra resolves the inherent problem that previous commodity proposals faced and
couldnt resolve: namely, who will pay for it all?

Growing concern and dissatisfaction with todays monetary situation has led to renewed interest in a
return to the gold standard. Some of the advantages and disadvantages are discussed below.

Advantages of the Gold Standard

The gold standard has indeed some systemic advantages compared to the current system. Specifically, two
advantages are worth mentioning. First, the gold standard would reduce inflationary tendencies because
gold cannot be created at will by governments or the banking system. And second, the gold standard is
more symmetric, in that it provides corrective mechanisms to both those countries with a balance and
payment surplus as well as to those with a deficit, so as to correct their balance of payments. Under the
gold standard surplus countries would automatically see the value of their currency increase, which
would make their products more expensive in the global market and reduce exports over time, thus
bringing their trade balance back into equilibrium. Similarly, countries with a deficit would see their
currency devalue, automatically making their products more competitive, which would, over time, bring
their trade balances back in equilibrium.

The reigning Bretton Woods system is instead not symmetric: deficit countries are penalized, while
those with a surplus have no incentive to bring their balances back to zero. The origin of this lack of
symmetry can be traced back World War II, and expectations by the United States that it would be the only
country whose productive capacity was left intact after the war. This advantageous position turned out to
be only temporary, however, and today countries like China and Germany are taking advantage of this
asymmetry.

Disadvantages of the Gold Standard

The gold standard has also some limitations, especially when compared to the Terra. In reality, the

genuine gold standard was formally implemented for only a brief period.277 By 1910, for instance, the
Bank of England covered only about 20 percent of its emissions of Pound sterling with gold. This fact
was kept from the public at the time, and illustrates how easy it was for a central bank to abuse the
system. The same could easily happen again if the gold standard was reintroduced.

Another limitation is that the price in the gold market today is easily manipulated, given that its volume
is so limited.

The Terra, which would include gold as one of the commodities in the Terra basket (at levels that range
from 5 to 10 percent of the basket's value), would avoid the pitfalls cited above. Terras would be issued
only as inventory receipts and would be audited publicly to ensure that this remains so. Furthermore, it
would be impossible to manipulate simultaneously all the commodities that are part of the Terra basket.

In short, the Terra would provide benefits similar to those of the gold standard, without having its
drawbacks.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

The Terra Trade Reference Currency is poised to more cost-effectively enhance barter and countertrade,
currently already a multi-billion dollar industry. It does not require any new regulations or laws and
provides a means to conduct business that otherwise might not take place, creating or saving jobs, and
strengthening economies. The Terra TRC would automatically work to counteract the boom and busts of
the business cycle and stabilize the economy by providing more cash during downturns, and cooling off
inflationary pressures in the peak of an upturn. Most importantly, it will resolve the current conflict
between short-term financial interests and long-term sustainability.

Along with creating greater stability and predictability in the financial and business sectors, the Terra
TRC provides a robust standard of value for trade. It makes available, for the first time since the goldstandard days, a robust international standard of value that is inflation-resistant.

The Terra and other complementary currency proposals explored in previous chapters give some idea
of the scope and diversity of how these applications can be used to resolve critical issues we face.

CHAPTER EIGHTEEN - Two Worlds



Two roads diverged in a yellow wood, and I

I took the one less traveled by,

And that has made all the difference.

~ROBERT FROST

We live in critical times, faced with a series of epic concerns that threaten humanity as never before. In a
university commencement address, entrepreneur, environmentalist, and author Paul Hawken stated clearly
what is demanded of us:

Class of 2009: you are going to have to figure out what it means to be a human being on Earth at a
time when every living system is declining, and the rate of decline is accelerating. Kind of a mindboggling situationbut not one peer-reviewed paper published in the last thirty years can refute that
statement. Basically, civilization needs a new operating system, you are the programmers, and we
need it within a few decades.278

Over the course of the last several decades, not one of the major megatrends facing our planet has been
adequately addressed. In stark defiance of the growing awareness, concerns, and the many valiant efforts
on the part of individuals, communities, non-profit organizations, and nations, each of the worlds major
concerns have instead only gotten worse. This decline and the persistence of our megatrends is not by
accident. It was foretold more than a decade ago in The Future of Money (Random House, 1999), during
a period of relative economic and political calm, before the dotcom crash, before 9/11, before the wars in
Iraq and Afghanistan, and nearly a decade prior to the Great Recession.

In other words, the events and policies that took place over the course of this last decade, though
having exacerbated our situation, were not in and of themselves the origins of our ongoing concerns. The
root cause of our megatrends is instead directly linked to our centuries-old monetary paradigm.

The continued lack of monetary rethinking will make the persistence of our major concerns and the
continued degeneration of conditions as predictable and irrevocable in the coming decade as in the past.
This was a core thesis back in 1999 and remains so today. The key difference between then and now is
that the need to act is far more urgent and the time in which to do so is much shorter still.

Our main focus throughout this book is to offer a sense of what is possible by venturing outside the
confines of the current paradigm and exploring options available to us by rethinking money. In the pages
that follow, we instead explore the approaches being taken within the given framework of the existing
bank-debt monetary paradigm and the societal conditions that it portends. It should be understood that
what is written below is not theoretical but has already begun to be set in motion. We repeat the claim
made back in Chapter One:

The kind of world we live in is directly linked to the type of monetary paradigm that is operational.

DEBT-BASED STRATEGIES

Summarizing the key conclusion of the previous chapters, the prevailing monetary paradigm can be simply
stated as follows:

all exchanges in every country around the world today take place through a monopoly of a single
currency;
that one currency takes the form of bank debt.
For more than a generation, debt has been touted as the answer to all economic troubles. This is not
only the case for individuals, but applies to corporations, governments, and the financial sector. That
supposed solution is, however, now becoming less available, or not available at all, principally because
excessive debt has itself become a big problem. The consequences of remaining trapped within this
conventional monetary box under such circumstances are profound.

Salvation Through Debt?



How have we arrived at this outcome in which excessive debt has become such a widespread problem?

At the individual level, getting in debt seems one of the few remaining rites of passage into adulthood.
Getting ones first credit card is often perceived as more important than casting ones first vote, and
buying a first house invariably means committing to a mortgage that is a substantial multiple of most
annual incomes. Even if one doesnt indulge in either of these rites, a substantial slice of ones taxes is
earmarked to pay interest on our governments national debt. Over the past half-century, total private debt
in America has increased dramatically, from around 50 percent of GDP in the 1950s to a staggering 300
percent today.279 This level has been reached, ominously, only once before: in 1929, just before the Great
Depression.

Accumulating debt has also become fashionable for corporations, a consequence of which has been the
steady, continuous deterioration of corporate credit ratings. For instance, Standard & Poors median
corporate rating went from A in 1981 to the current BBBjust one step better than junk status.280 It
should be noted, however that corporate debt is far from uniformly distributed. Many American firms
reduced their appetite for debt after 2000, with the end of the dotcom bubble and the spectacular demise
of WorldCom and Enron. But the wave of leveraged buy-outs (LBOs) continued a bit longer, and left all
companies involved with a lot more debt on their balance sheets.

No industry has become more addicted to debt than finance. In America, while the non-financial sector
increased its debt-to-GDP ratio from 58 percent in 1985 to 76 percent in 2009, the financial sector went
from 26 percent to 108 percent over the same period.4 Furthermore, the financial sector steamedahead
longer than all the rest, right up until the day of the financial crash of 2007-8. Indeed, leverage is just one
way to further push the financial efficiency of the system: its capacity to increase throughput for a given
capital base. This extra leverage contributed predictably to the fragility of the whole financial system.
Ironically, this same debt led financial institutions to lose trust in some of their own colleagues, which in
turn triggered the meltdown and brought down giants such as Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers.

Other possible consequences of the global banking crisis of 2008 were likely averted by means of
massive governmental support for the financial sector. This was immediately followed by large-scale
Keynesian stimuli to avoid a deflationary depression. Both these actions have, however, resulted in
enormous budgetary deficits and additional public debt. In other words, excessive debt in the financial
sector was solved by more debt in the public sector. In an ironically compounded next step, the
financial sector has now turned against its savior of a year or so earlier, waving the spectre of defaults
back at governments.

The threat of debt to an economy is clearly not an unknown one; only the scale has been increased over
the centuries. In the 18th century, Wealth of Nations author, Adam Smith, warned: When national debts
have once been accumulated to a certain degree, there is scarce, I believe, a single instance of their being
fairly and completely paid.281 A more ominous caution still comes from noted economist Ludwig von
Mises: There is no means of avoiding the final collapse of a boom brought about by credit expansion.
The alternative is only whether the crisis should come sooner as the result of voluntary abandonment of
further credit expansion, or later as a final and total catastrophe of the monetary system involved.282 In
other words, in continuing as is, a major economic crash appears unavoidable. The only remaining

question regarding the crisis is the time frame.


Withdrawal Pains?

A lead editorial by The Economist in June 2010 made the claim that Debt is as powerful a drug as
alcohol and nicotineWeaning rich countries off their debt addiction will cause withdrawal symptoms.
Austerity does not appeal to voters, who may work off their frustrations on politicians and (worse)
foreigners.283 If we remain within the box of monetary orthodoxy, this statement will not only certainly
prove true, but is in actuality only a very mild assessment of the situation we have created.

As forecast a decade ago, the convergence of global megatrends will oblige us to rethink our monetary
system before 2020. The case then was that our monetary system will prove incapable of answering the
following money questions:

How can we provide the elderly with sufficient money to match their longevity?
What can we do when jobs become really scarce?
How can we resolve the conflict between financially driven short-term planning and long-term
needs?
How can we deal with systemic financial and monetary instability?
More than a decade later these questions and the issues they refer to have become more urgent and
imperative than ever.

What is now being predictably added to our challenges are massive pressures on governments to
reduce their deficits. As of 2011, talks of neo-Keynesian stimuli are over, while deficit reductions are in.
This austerity will induce a prolonged period of job scarcity, much longer and painful than most people
expect. Among other things, high unemployment is directly linked to housing problems, one of the major
triggers of the 2008 crisis. Housing recoveries do not take place unless there is sustainable job growth.

Our view is that we are living through a variation of what took place seven decades ago. Today, we
tend to describe the Great Depression as starting with Black Friday in 1929, followed by a continuous
period of economic stress that stretched painfully on for most of the 1930s. That was not, however, the
way it was perceived at the time by policy makers, the media, or citizens. People who lived through that
period experienced it as a long succession of small ups and downs. Short-term improvements and hopes
that were triggered by new government or private initiatives were each subsequently dashed by
subsequent disappointment.

We are currently on an eerily similar track. Waves of stories about green shoots, amplified by the
media and politicians, are each dispelled by subsequent, unexpected bad news. Big hopes that have been
pinned on governmental stimulus programs are now dashed when austerity measures are, by necessity,
implemented.

Another important consideration is the psychological, social, and political consequences of this state of
affairs, which is not easy to fathom. But one should expect large-scale social unrest in a number of
countries, which historically plays into the hands of extremist political parties and populist leaders.
History also teaches us that there is a high risk that such scenarios end up being resolved in one way or
another through wars. To repeat, President Roosevelt himself admitted that it was only through
involvement in World War II that the United States managed to finally extract itself from the Great

Depression.

What is the proposed solution by the financial system, working of course within the existing paradigm,
for solving excessive governmental deficits? It is privatization.

THE U.S. PLANP3s



The conventional strategy currently proposed by the financial sector involves nothing less than the
systematic privatization of most publicly owned infrastructures in the United States. The mechanism,
called Public-Private Partnerships (P3s), consists of the sale of most existing publicly owned highways,
roads, bridges, tunnels, sewage and water treatment facilities, and more, all occurring through a series of
existing and specially created funds. This is not some hypothetical possibility. This supposed solution
is already being implemented in Illinois, Florida, and California, with 40 other states waiting to follow
suit.

Only months after the near meltdown in the Fall of 2008, 18 American financial companies including
Carlyle, Abertis, Morgan Stanley, Freshfields, and Allen & Overy prepared a document entitled Benefits
of private investment in infrastructure.284 In it are contained all the financial and legal details for a
systematic privatization strategy to be applied in the United States. The scope of this strategy was
summarized in the article in Euromoney entitled: The Road to wiping out the U.S. Deficit Some quotes
follow.

In 2009, the US government has spent $1.4 trillion more than it received in taxes and raised in debt.
There are very few options left. So we will see a gravitation towards new P3s. If one assumes that
the federal government will not be selling the navy or the municipalities their schools, there is still
an immense amount of assets that can be sold. For instance, the value of all the highways and roads
owned by states and municipalities is $2.4 trillion. There are $550 billion of sewerage assets at
state and local levels along with a further $400 billion of water assets. Even at the federal level
there is $42 billion-worth of amusements and recreation assets. And in the real estate sector, the
federal, state and local governments own assets worth $1.09 trillion.285

Traditionally, the main obstacle for the sale of public assets came from the political sector, as it
alienates voters. More recently, however, the political landscape with regard to P3s has changed (see
insert).

Euromoney P3s Data Points

The following quotes and data offer some illustration of the extent of development of P3s in the
United States as of early 2011.286
The moment the political pain from cutting services is more than the votes lost in selling assets,
this market will take offAt grass-root level, that political pain threshold has been reached.
As California lurches through another budget crisis, Governor Arnold Schwarzenegger has put on
the block assets including prisons, roads and windfarms.
Indiana sold the Indiana Toll Road in 2006 to Cintra and Macquarie for $3.8 billion.
In Chicago, mayor Richard Daley has embraced asset sales with a fervor not matched anywhere
else. He sold a 99-year lease to run the Skyway in 2005 for $1.83 billion to a consortium also
comprising Macquarie and Cintra. He subsequently tried to sell Chicagos Midway airport for $2.5
billion in 2008, and in 2009 successfully sold the citys parking system in a deal that raised $1.1
billion. The Chicago parking deal was a huge success in every way but one: the transition from
public to private ownership caused massive disruptions and a public outcry from residents about a
400 percent increase in the tariffs.

Transactions are now underway in Hartford, Harrisburg, Indianapolis, Pittsburgh, Las Vegas and
Los Angeles.
In essence, politicians realize that the political cost in not doing this is greater than in doing it. The
tipping point has been reached.

Another traditional opponent to the sale of public assets are labor unions. But, like the political sector,
unions are showing signs of coming around to the idea of privatized infrastructure. The reason for this
about face is predictably financial. Financiers are now offering union pension funds access to a share of
the deals. A quarter of the assets of the $4 billion Macquaurie Infrastructure Partners has come from
union pension fundsIn November 2009, Carlyle closed a deal with co-investment of the Service
Employees International Union (SEIU).287

One can also expect that the financial pressures on municipalities, states, and the federal governments
will continue to build up for as long as needed to implement this plan. The only likely exceptions are with
regard to military facilities and locally owned primary and secondary schools. Everything else is being
considered for sale. How will people react when the streets on which they live become electronic toll
roads? Can one avoid wondering about the price the White House or State Capitols will fetch in a fire
sale market, or under what conditions the government will be able to rent its real estate back after the
sale?

It is only fair to note that there are important instances in which privatizations can be successful and
beneficial, as has been proven in the case of telecoms and mobile phone businesses. But not all
privatizations have proven desirable for citizens. Whatever ones particular viewpoint, should the case
for privatizing most of an existing national infrastructure not be worthy of at least some democratic
debate? Or will this not even be possible during a sudden financial emergency?

There is no reason to believe that such policies would be limited to the United States. As part of the
IMF loan of 2011, Greece had to commit to 50 billion euro worth of privatizations. Another example is
Italy where the government of Silvio Berlusconi sold assets that have been in state ownership for
centuries.288 Neither should we expect that such sales of national assets to the financial sector will remain
voluntary. After all, transactions of this kind were common practice as part of conditionalities to
developing nations seeking IMF support during the 1980s and 1990s. Similar types of conditionalities
regarding privatization could be adopted in the future. It bears mentioning that the main function of the
IMF is to safeguard the interests of the banking sector. The IMF is therefore an enforcer of the existing
paradigm.

Next Questions

Some questions beg consideration regarding the consequences of this privatization evolution. What, for
example, happens after such a strategy has run its course, say over the next decade, and almost everything
has been privatized? Why will governments then be more creditworthy when they will have to pay rent on
everything they use?


This coming decade happens to be the very one in which governments will be required to address some
very critical issues. One such issue is the need to birth a post-carbon economy, which the worlds
scientists claim is needed in order to avoid an irreversible global climate change and biodiversity
collapse. The trillion-dollar question becomes: what can the public sector realistically do to meet such an
unprecedented challenge, when governments are struggling for financial survival?

From another perspective, why should anybody bother to vote for a government that has become
structurally and financially incapable of significant actions?

Another question, made in the form of a request, came from President Obama when he presented the
U.S. budget for 2010: We simply cannot continue to spend as if deficits dont have consequences. In
order to meet this challenge, I welcome any idea.289

Unfortunately, there are no new ideas, nor can there be, within the context of the given paradigm.
Moreover, in a system with no self-correcting device except explosion, a crash such as that predicted by

Von Mises is inevitable. The Wra, Wrgl, and the WIR offer lessons from which we have not yet
learned.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

We end Part II of this work by reiterating a few paragraphs presented in Chapter One.

This book recounts the story of two worlds and two paradigms. It offers a brief analysis of current
conditions and the logical outcome of attempting to solve existing problems using the same thinking that
created many of our concerns in the first place.

The main body of this work, however, considers another prospect for society and the systematic means
by which it can be pragmatically realized.

This other world is one in which the long-term interests of humanity and the sustainability of our planet
balance the short-term interests of business and industry; where there is meaningful work for all and time
for ourselves, our families, and our communities; where the upbringing and education of our children and
quality care for our elders are realized and compensated for in equal measure to other forms of
employment so vital to society. This other world holds dear the diversity and sanctity of all life and the
life-affirming aspects of what it is to be fully human, and consequently, more humane.

The potential for just such a prospect is not only possible but is actually achievable within the span of a
single generation. Many of the elements required for this to happen already exist. Also required is a wide
assortment of innovative monetary tools, similar to those used in Curitiba, Brazil, that are made available
to us quickly, safely, and inexpensively, by means of a greater understanding of our money.

PART III - THE MYSTERY OF MONEY



To find the soul of modern man and woman, begin by searching into

those irreducibly embarrassing facts of the money complex,

that crazy crab scuttling across the floors of silent seas.

~JAMES HILLMAN

CHAPTER NINETEEN - Archetypes



What lies behind us and what lies before us

are small matters compared to what lies within us.

~RALPH WALDO EMERSON

Up until this juncture in our exploration, we have dealt with money as an exterior reality, something that
shapes society out there. In Part III, we explore how money connects in here, inside our own psyche,
where the engine driving so much of our lives resides. Indeed, we need to become aware of the way
monetary systems shape our collective emotionsor perhaps, how collective emotions shape our choices
in monetary systemsso that we can make conscious choices in moving forward.

When assessing fundamental change in our monetary system, we need to address some pertinent
questions, such as:
Why is the peculiar kind of monetary system we have today considered obvious by so many cultures?
Where does the dominant power of money emerge from?
Are greed and fear of scarcity actually indelible reflections of human nature and material reality, and
if not, what is it that engenders and reinforces these specific collective emotions?
In short, what are the origin and mechanism of the emotional dimension of money?
We wish to caution the reader that the following exploration will put us in touch with one of the
foremost taboos of Western society. Inquiries about how much money someone has, or where it comes
from, are considered even more inappropiate nowadays than the topic of sexuality. Talking about a taboo
is hazardous. By definition, pointing to a societys shadows risks upsetting some readers. We ask that each
of you please take responsibility for the emotions that may arise along the way. We believe, however, that
it is by shedding light on the above-cited questions that we can achieve the degrees of freedom necessary
to reenvision our money in depth.

OUR COLLECTIVE INHERITANCE



The recent mapping of the human genome reveals the extraordinary likeness of all human beings. If the
DNA of each person were a book of 100 pages, the differences between our individual books would be
measured not by chapters or pages, but by little more than a phrase or short sentence. While our covers
our outward appearancesmight vary considerably, more than 99.9 percent of our wording would
instead be identical. Genetically, at least, it is quite accurate to affirm that the bonds that unite us as a
species far exceed any and all things that differentiate us as individuals, whether through our race,
nationalities, cultures, or beliefs.290

Our commonality is to be found not only in our heritage, biochemistry, and physiology, but in our
psyches as well.291 While much of our identity is unique and influenced by individual circumstance, there
also exist many predispositions, behaviors, and values that belong to the human race in general. Just as
apes, bees, and cats are each born with certain innate traits common to their species, so do humans enter
life with certain emotions, propensities, and behavior patterns that are universally human. Our
psychological common base, the so-called collective unconscious, contains the vast heritage of
humankinds evolution, born anew in every individual.

One of the many things we as modern humans share in common is a collective set of attitudes and
assumptions regarding money. Though it is not customarily considered as such, money is a projection
from the collective unconscious.

As previously noted, money is an agreement, a mental construct. Philosopher and author Jacob
Needleman observes, Money isin the end, a product of the mind.292 By its very definition, money is
also a collective affair, in that it can only exist within a community. Additionally, money is not value
neutral; different types of money predispose us to feel, think and act in particular ways, mostly in an
unconscious manner, without our awareness. Moreover, each society considers its own monetary system
as self-evident, regardless of whether it uses stones, pieces of metal, colorful paper, or electronic bits as
currency. Each of these monetary facets speaks to the collective unconscious nature of our relationship
with money.

To have money better serve our needs, it is important that we understand how and why our monetary
system leads us to places few of us might consciously choose to go. One means available for our
investigation is Archetypal Psychology, a field that provides a lens and language by which to explore the
collective unconscious.

Archetypal Psychology was founded by famed Swiss psychologist Carl Gustav Jung (1875-1961). This
field of psychology was developed further in the second half of the 20th century by psychologist James
Hillman and others.293 Jung was able to apply his understanding of the collective psyche to events taking
place in our world, including his ability to forecast the rise of fascism in Europe as early as the 1920s. In
Part III, insights from this field are applied to further our exploration of money.

For our purposes, only two of the key concepts of Archetypal Psychology need to be grasped:
archetypes and shadows. These building blocks help to show how we are predisposed to relate to one
another and the world around us, and the role that money plays in our lives.

ARCHETYPES

A core focus of Archetypal Psychology is the archai, the deepest patterns of psychic functioning, the
fundamental fantasies that animate all life. Jung put forward this short definition, Archetypes are to the
soul what instincts are to the body.294

Jungian psychologist Bernice Hill offers this explanation:

Archetypes are primordial, universal energy patterns developed over eons of time and moving
throughout the world and human history. They carry a full range of positive and negative
possibilities, but they cannot be known completely or directly through the intellect alone. They
inform our behavioral patterns and attitudes, and are found in art, dreams, symbols, cultural stories,
and myth(s).295


For the purposes of this work, archetypes may be defined as: patterns of emotions and actions that
can be observed across time and cultures. This working definition remains valid even if one is not
comfortable with the Jungian approach to psychology.

Archetypes and Myths



One way to better understand archetypes is through popular myths. Now-popular attitudes might deem a
work dedicated to issues such as our monetary system and societal challenges a strange place to employ
myths, because many people today consider myths to be only pre-scientific tales about the origin of
mankind or about some imaginary heroes or divine beings, and thus of limited value.

Myths are, however, valid descriptions of psychic sequences; they are favorite scenarios that illustrate
how specific archetypes manifest, regardless of time or cultural context. Myths are not some unique hero
or gods story; they instead reveal shared aspects of who we are. According to mythologist Joseph
Campbell, myths represent, Powers that have been common to the human spirit forever, and that
represent the wisdom of the species by which man has weathered the millenniums.296 Scholar Eric
Robertson Dodds defined myths as, The dream-thinking of a whole civilization.297 They are revelations
and expressions about the make-up of our collective being.

Archetypes can be found in hundreds of mythological, classical, and symbolic figures. Joseph
Campbell identified and wrote about the Hero with a Thousand Faces, as one universal and
quintessential story found through the ages that transcends the boundaries of culture. This hero is seen in
Sumer as Gilgamesh, in ancient Greece as Hercules, in the Middle Ages as knights in shining armor, or in
Japan as the fearless Samurai.

As Jung described:

These hero myths vary enormously in detail, but the more closely one examines them, the more one
sees that structurally they are very similar. They have, that is to say, a universal pattern, even though
groups and individuals developed them without any direct cultural contact with one another; for
instance, tribes in Africa or the Incas in Peru. Over and over again one hears tales describing a
heros miraculous but humble birth, his early proof of superhuman strength, his rapid rise to
prominence or power, his triumphant struggle with the forces of evil, his fallibility to the sin of pride
(hubris) and his fall through betrayal or a heroic sacrifice that ends with his death.298

The Hero is just one archetype among many. Archetypes are features of our collective human psyche
through which our unconscious interacts with the exterior world. Jung claimed, It is a function of
consciousness not only to recognize and assimilate the external world through the gateway of the senses,
but to translate into visible reality the world within us.299 He asserted that, All the most powerful ideas
in history go back to archetypes. This is particularly true of religious ideas, but the central concepts of
science, philosophy, and ethics are no exception to this rule.300

Every aspect of our lives is permeated by archetypes. We visit the archetypal realm in our dreams,
though we may be unaware of it. Advertisers, political strategists, and the Hollywood industry use
archetypes to prompt us to feel or react in certain ways.

Media stories that capture the imagination of the masses are invariably rich in archetypal content. The
fact that more than one billion people around the world, regardless of their cultural affiliations, watched
the funeral of Princess Diana, indicates the archetypal nature of the princess story. She embodied the
Cinderella archetype, the supposedly common girl whose uncommon grace, beauty, and innate goodness
are recognized and rewarded by the prince, who chooses her over all other women. We loved her because

she was one of us, and represented what is good in us. Diana also embodied parts of the archetype of the
tragic Lover, as seen in Romeo and Juliet.

A Map of the Human Psyche



There are hundreds of different archetypes that embody the vast array of human characteristics. To capture
a broad range of human experiences in a simplified manner, Jungian psychologists Robert Moore and
Douglas Gillette have developed a map of the human psyche based upon Jungs Quaternion, consisting of
four of the major archetypes found in all cultures.301 These are the Sovereign, Warrior, Lover, and
Magician.

The Four Major Archetypes

The Sovereign energy is the integrating force at the core of the psyche. It activates, accepts, and integrates
the forces of all other archetypes, and makes the necessary sacrifices (from sacer facere, literally
making sacred) for the good of the whole.

The Warrior energy masters discipline, asceticism, and force. The Warrior protects what needs
protecting for the common good and destroys what needs to be eliminated, to enable the blossoming of
new life.

The Lover energy masters sensuous pleasure without guilt. It is the power of empathy and
connectedness to other people and all life. The Lover is sensitive to art and beauty.

The Magician energy masters knowledge of the material world through science and technologies, as
well as that of the immaterial worlds of spiritual, religious, or philosophical teachings. The Magician
draws connections between both realms.


Each archetype is active both at the individual and collective levels. Well-established organizations at the
collective level embody these archetypal energies. Governments, for example, play the role of the
Sovereign. Corporations and armies carry Warrior energy. The arts give expression to the Lover. Science,
technology, academia, and religion embody the Magicians role.

It should be noted here that Jungs Quaternion lacks at least one important archetype. The missing

archetype is suggested by Joseph Campbells observation that one dominant myth has shaped most
civilizations: each culture may emphasize particular archetypal forces and the hero may be a god or a
mortal, young or old, rich or poor, king or commoner, but the hero is always a male.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

Archetypes represent the deepest patterns of our psyches and are, by definition, observable through the
ages and across cultures. They influence virtually every aspect of our lives, including our behaviors,
philosophies, religions, and mythologies.

There is one essential archetype, however, missing from the Quaternion, which has been repressed for
a very long time.

CHAPTER TWENTY - The Missing Archetype and Money



The door to transcendence, to transformation and enlightenment,

is a door that leads into a hall of mirrors.

Wherever you look, there is only you looking back.

~L. D. THOMPSON

Clear and mounting evidence demonstrates that for much of human history, a fundamental archetype has
been the object of systematic and substantial repression. The missing archetype is the Great
Nurturer/Provider, whose most common form is feminine and which is referred to as the Great Mother.

It is this feminine dimension of this archetype that has been the subject of almost continued repression
through several millennia. The consequences of this repression run deep and are intimately connected to
the subject of money. Our next focus on our exploration of money is therefore the Great Mother archetype.

ARCHETYPAL EVIDENCE AND SIGNIFICANCE



One very effective way to understand a particular society is to look at its images of the divine. The Great
Mother was honored and active over tens of thousands of years and over vast geographic areas. Her
presence has been documented from the earliest times of human consciousness. Her image has been
carved in mammoth ivory, in reindeer antlers, and on stone at the entrance of sacred caves. Great Mother
effigies were the most common figures of the upper-Paleolithic period (30,000-9,000 BCE). Her
predominant importance in ancient times is illustrated by the fact that four times more feminine than
masculine prehistoric figurines have been uncovered.302

The term Great Mother is not meant to imply that an identical, specific image was venerated. Her
various images, however, do share unmistakable and important characteristics reflected in nature, in each
of us individually, and in the whole of humanity. She holds the mysteries of life and death, reproduction,
and fertility. She also embodies all that gives us sustenance, including money.

The first forms of religious expression often found in archaeology and across cultures are images of a
mother pregnant with or nurturing her child, identified as the Great Mother or the Fertility Goddess. As
Marilyn Yalom, author of A History of the Breast, explains:

At the beginning was the breast. For all but a fraction of human history, there was no substitute for a
mothers milk. Until the end of the nineteenth century, when pasteurization purportedly made animal
milk safe, a maternal breast meant life or death for every newborn babe. Small wonder that our
prehistoric ancestors endowed their female idols with such bosomsIt takes no great stretch of the
imagination to picture a distraught Stone Age mother begging one of those buxom idols for an ample
supply of milk.303

To better appreciate the greater dimensions of this archetype and its vital relevance to humanity and the
issues of our day, we must, however, transcend the reductionism that tends to see in Great Mother figures
only sexuality, fertility, and nurturing of children. The Great Mother connects the human body and the
Earth to the mystery of the sacred. She celebrates the process of time cycles and life itself in all its forms,
all renewal, all growth, the paradox of life-death, all change, and all continuity.

Author and educator Starhawk explains:

She is first of all Earth, the dark, nurturing mother who brings forth all life. She is the power of
fertility and generation, the womb, and also the receptive tomb, the power of death. All proceeds
from Her, all returns to Her. As Earth, She is also plant life, trees, and the herbs and grains that
sustain life. She is the body, and the body is sacred.304


Archaeologist Marija Gimbutas described the Great Mother as: The symbol of unity of all life in
Nature. Her power was in water and stone, in tomb and cave, in animals and birds, snakes and fish, hills,
trees and flowers. Hence, the holistic and mythopoetic perception of the sacredness and mystery of all
there is on Earth.305

THE ARCHETYPAL HUMAN



Jungs Quaternion can now be expanded to include the missing Great Mother archetype, to provide a more
complete map of the archetypal human, as seen in Figure 20.1.


This archetypal map is not intended to be all-encompassing. Far more comprehensive and complex
representations of the human psyche could readily be constructed. The objective here is to use the fewest
number of archetypes to portray the most important aspects of the collective human. The five archetypes
described above may be considered as primary landmarks that comprise the vast territory of the
collective human psyche. As foundational elements, we should understand that any disturbances here
would have a profound impact upon individual and collective emotions and behaviors.

EARLY MONEY AND THE GREAT MOTHER



The intrinsic relationship between money and the Great Mother was self-evident to much of the ancient
world. For tens of thousands of years, the Great Mother was the mythical connection to the mysteries of
life and to the most fundamental aspects of existence. Similarly, money represents abundance, generosity,
sustenance, and is at its deepest level connected to our very survival. Substantial evidence demonstrates
that not only was money invented during the extensive period when the Great Mother archetype was
honored, but that moneys earliest forms were directly related to her.

Cattle, the First Working Capital Asset306



Cattle played a major role as both a medium of exchange and unit of account in much of the ancient world.
For instance, the poet Homer (7th century BCE) expressed wealth in heads of cattle. Cattle are still used
today in ranching societies as a unit of economic measure, as noted by the colloquialism, Hes worth a
thousand head (see insert).

Money and Cows

One side effect of the use of cattle for monetary purposes has been that the number of head, rather
then the quality or health of the animals, was valued. A contemporary agricultural expert tried to
persuade Wakamba tribal chiefs from eastern Kenya not to keep diseased and old cattle. The
response he received was, Listen, here are two pound notes. One is old and wrinkled and ready to
tear, this one is new. But they are both worth a pound. Well, its the same with cows.307

The roots of popular terms point directly back to cattle. The English word pecuniary (financial)
comes from the Latin pecus, meaning cattle. Similarly, the word capital is derived from the Latin
capus or capitis, meaning head.308 The word fee evolved from vieh, meaning cattle in Old
Germanic.309

Cattle have been linked to feminine archetypal symbols of fertility and abundance from prehistory
onwards. The cow symbolized the Great Mother nearly everywhere in ancient myths. Cows offer literal
sustenance by virtue of their milk and they are ferociously protective of their young. Inanna, the Great
Mothers representation in ancient Sumer, appears in the late fourth millennium BCE as the patron deity of
the city of Uruks central storehouse. In her name was written, Heaven is mine, the Earth is mine. I am a
splendid wild cow!310

In Egypt, the Great Mothers name was Hathor. She was the Goddess of Beauty and Plenty, whose
udder overflowed to the point of creating the Milky Way, the term in use today still for our own galaxy.
Hathor gave birth every day to the sun, her Golden Calf. Her horn was the sacred Horn of Plenty
the cornucopiaout of which poured all the fruits of the world.


Many cultures held the cow as sacred. The classical symbol of the Moon Goddess was the white cow,
akin to the White Buffalo Woman of some Native American traditions. In Irish mythology the cow was
Glas Galven, Goddess of the Sky.311 In Hinduism, the cow is a representation of Kali, and remains sacred
to this day.

Gold and Amber



The use of gold as currency is also intrinsically linked to the Great Mother archetype, with explicit
mythological evidence from many cultures. For instance, Hathor, the Egyptian Cow Goddess, was called
the Golden One. Ancient Nordic legends refer to Gullveid, the Golden Goddess who was the owner
of treasures of gold. Lakshmi, the Hindu Goddess of Abundance and Wealth, is referred to this day as the
Goddess of Gold.

Amber was another commodity currency used in antiquity and was especially important in international
sea trade. In Dynastic Egypt, it was more highly valued than gold. Found in its natural state of fossilized
resin, then as now, on the beaches of the Baltic Sea, pieces of amber were considered to be the tears of
the Great Mother.

The Cowrie

Another form of money related to the Great Mother is the cowrie. Cowries are small, smooth shells
usually found in the seas off tropical islands. They were an ancient form of currency used in Africa and
elsewhere, and remained in circulation in some countries, such as Nigeria, until quite recently.

In ancient China, the cowrie played such an important monetary role that its pictogram was adopted in
written language as the character for money. The first Chinese production of bronze and copper currency
took the form of imitation cowries.312

Monetary historian Glyn Davies explains the cowries enduring choice as a form of money:

The cowrie shell, of all forms of money, including precious metals, was current over a far greater
space and for a far greater length of time than any otherCowries are durable, easily cleaned and
counted, and defy imitation and counterfeitingFor many people over large parts of the world, at
one time or other they have appeared as an ideal form of moneyThey were still officially accepted
for payment of taxes until the beginning of the twentieth century in West Africa.313

The vulva-like cowrie shell is associated with water, the setting in which the shell is formed. In many
cultures, water is traditionally related to the Great Mother through its symbolic elemental connection with
fertility, sexuality, prosperity, and fecundity.

The cowrie is also associated with death, in that its utility as currency starts only after the death of the
creature that originally inhabited the shell. It has appeared in burial ornaments as far back as Paleolithic
times. French archeologist Abb Breuil explains the cowries presence in tombs: It connects the death
with the cosmological principles of water, the moon, the feminine and rebirth in the new world.314


In Spanish, the feminine name Concepcin (conception) is still abbreviated as Conchita (literally,
little shell, which is also the slang for the female sexual organ). To the Aztecs, the moon Goddess
Tecaciztecatl, whose name translates as the one from the shell, controls the process of birth and
generation and is represented by a vulva.315

The cowrie shell is also etymologically connected to the Great Mother archetype through cattle. The
word cow comes from the Sanskrit gau and the Egyptian kau. It is also the origin of the words gaurie
or kaurie, from which the English term cowrie shell derived. The words cow and cowrie shell thus

literally share common ancient roots.


The Shekel

In addition to her generic linkage with money, the Great Mother was connected to many of the earliest
coins. The ancient Sumerians called their first coin-like object the shekel, derived from the words she
(meaning wheat) and kel (a measurement similar to a bushel). Hence, this coin was a symbol of the
value of one bushel of wheat.

The shekel was originally used as proof that wheat taxes had been paid to the temple of Inanna, the
Sumerian goddess who ruled over life, death, sexuality, fertility, and wealth. Her temple, as well as being
a ritual center, was also the storage place for reserves of cereals, which supported the priestesses and the
community, particularly in lean times.


Farmers brought their contribution of wheat to the temple to fulfill religious obligations to society and
to the Goddess. In exchange, they received a shekel, which then entitled them to sacred sexual intercourse
with the priestesses at festival time.

Two thousand years later, the Judeo-Christian worldview reinterpreted these rituals quite differently.
The Bible describes these priestesses as temple prostitutes.316 Such practices and their significance,
however, must be understood within the context of their particular culture and time. The priestesses were
representatives of the Great Mother, and intercourse with them was considered as a holy rite with the
Goddess of Fertility herselfnot an act to be taken lightly. At that time, fertility was truly a matter of life
and death, as failure of the crops meant starvation. To the Sumerians this ritual was sacred and ensured
fertility in crops, animals, and children, each of which were requisites for survival and future prosperity.
The word shekel survives in modern-day Hebrew as Israels monetary unit.

Juno Moneta

The word money is itself related to the Great Mother, deriving from the Latin moneta. The first Roman
mint operated out of the basement of the temple of the Goddess Juno Monetasymbolically, her womb.
The choice of that particular location within the temple is a direct reminder of the relationship of money
to the essential feminine (see insert).

The Goddess Juno Moneta

Juno was a very ancient Italic goddess, initially different than the Greek Goddess Hera, with whom
she became culturally amalgamated later during the expansion of the Roman Empire to Greece. Both
Juno and Hera, however, were essentially Goddesses of Womanhood.
Juno was part of the Capitoline triad, the Trinity that ruled Rome (with Minerva, the Goddess of
Wisdom, and Jupiter, the Sky God). As daughter of Saturn, Juno ruled menstrual cycles and was,
therefore, worshipped by Roman women every month at the Calends, the first day of the new moon.
Juno presided at all key feminine occasions: she was the Juno Pronuba, who made marriage
abundantly fertile; Populonia, the Goddess of Conception; Ossipago, who strengthened fetal bones;
Sospita, who ruled labor; and Lucina, the Birth Goddess, who led the child to the light.317
To the Romans, just as every man had his genius, the essence of his masculinity, every woman had
her juno, the essence of her femininity. One modern relic of the Great Mother tradition is that many
brides still choose to marry in June, because it used to ensure the blessings of the goddess for whom
that month is named.318

CLOSING THOUGHTS

The creation of money was inherently and symbolically related for millennia to the Great Mother
archetype. Every monetary transaction was seen at that time as a way of honoring the Great Mother and
the abundance she represented.

All this happened, of course, when words reflecting feminine characteristics had not yet acquired their
pejorative bias. Words like silly still meant blessed by the Moon Goddess Selene, and hysteria
implied having a womb, not a mental disturbance.

CHAPTER TWENTY ONE - Repression of an Archetype



We rarely hear the inward music,

but were all dancing to it nevertheless.

~RUMI

How then, did money come to be divorced from the archetype that had inspired it? The key is the
repression of the feminine in general, and the Great Mother archetype in particular.

CLIMATE CHANGE AND INDO-EUROPEAN INVASIONS



Repression of the feminine traces its origins back to the rise of aggressive warrior energy during the
fourth millennium BCE. This followed a period of massive climate change, which led to intense
desertification from North Africa through the Middle East all the way to southwestern China. As a result,
these lands, which include the Sahara, Arabian, Syro-Iraqi, and Gobi deserts, were no longer able to
support farming or wildlife.

According to one hypothesis, Indo-European invasions were a chain reaction of large-scale population
dislodgements initially triggered by this climate change. Affected communities could no longer depend
upon their own lands to meet their requirements. They thus became pillaging, nomadic, authoritarianruled, patriarchal societies that spread their violent behavior over very large distances. The communities
that came in contact with these nomads were either exterminated or survived only by toughening up and
adopting warlike cultures themselves.319 Data to support this hypothesis includes geological and
archeological evidence of increasing desiccation, and the geographical distribution of societies most
closely associated with the more extreme forms of feminine repressionstill observable todayin and
around the big desert areas.


The powerful influence of the Great Mother during the Stone Age began to wane. Male deities,
particularly gods of war and conquest, replaced images of her. As archeologist Philip van Doren Stern
describes: Along with ruthless invasions, undeclared warfare, and appropriation of women as their
rightful spoils, they [warrior tribes] were developing a society in which masculinity was supreme. An
insatiable desire for property and power, together with insensitivity to pain and suffering, characterized
everything they did.320

After military conquest, the standard procedure by these warrior cultures was to kill off all the adult
males of the vanquished group, then rape and enslave the females. In the short span of a few generations,

the genetic and cultural makeup of entire regions was dramatically transformed. The ancient all-powerful
Great Mother was divided into different goddesses to fill many different functions, each of whom became
attributes or less important partners of dominant male gods. Repression, control, and subservience of the
feminine, particularly the sexuality and fertility aspects of the Great Mother, have been familiar outcomes
ever since.

GREEK CIVILIZATION

The incomparable contributions made by Greek civilization to virtually every aspect of human endeavor
including architecture, drama, governance, modern language, geometry, medicine, and philosophyare
well noted and have profoundly influenced and enriched our world. Greek culture was, however, also
strongly patriarchal and played an influential role in the sweeping alteration of so-called archaic
matrifocal mythologies into patriarchal ones.321 The amber tears of the Great Mother, for instance,
became the tears of Apollo, which he shed upon his exile from Olympus to Hyperborea.

The Greek awakening of the so-called rational mind provided new arguments for the repression of
the feminine, and became the cornerstone of Western thinking for the next 25 centuries. These include
Parmenides purported declaration of the independence and superiority of reasonportrayed as a
masculine attributeas the only legitimate judge of reality. All the senses were believed to mislead.
Intellectual reason alone is able to perceive reality.322

Socrates and Plato built on this intellectual argument. Reason became associated with the
transcendental, spiritual desire, and the absolute. Everything considered to be outside of reason was
dismissed as irrational. The inherent imperfections of matter and the senses, together with instinctual
desires and the relative, were all ascribed to the feminine.

Aristotelian philosophy subsequently claimed that women are incomplete and damaged human beings
of an entirely different order than men: For the female is, as it were, a mutilated male.323 Her womb is
but a passive receptacle for the holy male sperm. Aristotles conclusion was, The male is by nature
superior, and the female inferiorthe one rules, the other is ruled.324 Twenty-three centuries later,
Sigmund Freud would still refer to this incompleteness in womens nature as proof of their natural
inferiority.325

For the ancient Greeks the very act of founding a civilized community became symbolized by cutting
the feminine (see insert).

Cutting the Feminine as a Civilizing Act

Greek priests would found a new city by cutting a large cow-skin with a knife into a single, thin,
uninterrupted rope. That rope would then be spread out to create the perimeter of the new city. This
ritual was a metaphor for expunging the feminine naturesymbolized by the cow-skinthereby
creating an ordered civilized space.
The founding ritual for Roman cities had the same symbolic content. Rome itself and all
subsequent cities founded by Romans involved ritually cutting the Earththe symbol of the feminine
with a plow, replacing the Greeks knife, pulled by oxen to mark the perimeter of the new town.

WESTERN RELIGION

The consequences of Great Mother archetypal repression were felt in all major domains of human activity
and belief systems, particularly religion. As the roots of our contemporary monetary system emanate
almost exclusively from Western civilization, we focus on its predominant religion over the course of the
last 1,500 yearsChristianity.

Although we draw attention to the excesses and patriarchal attitudes associated with the Church through
the centuries, it is important to keep in mind that Christendom was also responsible for Western
civilizations honoring of the Lover archetype. This is expressed in such noble ethics as charity, caring for
ones neighbor, the concept of loving ones enemy, blessing those who curse you, doing good to those who
hate you, and praying for those who would persecute youvalues that were nonexistent in Antiquity.326
The Church also concretized these noble values systematically on a pragmatic level, in the many vital
services and support structures for communities, for example, orphanages, hospitals, and charitable
foundations. In addition, and as noted earlier, Christianity was also a primary opponent of the practice of
usury.

Nevertheless, monotheismthe belief that there is only one God, who is masculinewould over time
leave less and less room for the Great Mother and feminine values. The sole male skyward deity, who
ruled as absolute monarch from the heavens, would negate the earth-bound divinities, with repression of
Great Mother arechetypal energies.


Adam and Eve, the biblical creation story of Western culture, made Eve, the mother of all living

things, responsible for the Fall and for all subsequent suffering of humankind, along with her accomplice
the serpentnot surprisingly, one of the oldest symbols of the Great Mother.

Attacks on the remnants of the Great Mother cultures can be further explained by history. Christianity
initially spread most successfully in the cities of the fallen Roman Empire. Its foremost opposition came
from the pagans (literally, pagani, meaning people of the countryside) or from villagers (those living in
rural villae, from which derive the words villain and vilify), who were more closely connected to
nature, the land, ancient fertility rituals, and thus to the Great Mother.

Centuries later, repression of the Great Mother archetype would find its most violent expression in the
Inquisition, in which an estimated six million women would be burned at the stake or otherwise put to
death as witches.327 This appalling period of history, which spanned more than three centuries, coincided
not with the dark Middle Ages as is commonly thought, but rather with the Renaissance and the early
Modern period (15th to 18th centuries CE).328 It was during that same period that our present-day
monetary system took form.

Western civilizations extraordinary continuity down through the ages with regard to the repression of
the feminine can be summarized by the following set of quotations:

Sin began with a woman and thanks to her we all must die.

Ecclesiasticus 25:24 (second century BCE)

Women are the gate of the devil, the patron of wickedness, the sting of the serpent.

St. Gerome (fifth century CE)

Men have broad shoulders and large chests and small narrow hips and are more understanding than
women,who have but small and narrow chests and broad hips;to the end they should remain at home,
sit still, keep house and bear and bring up children.

Martin Luther (16th century)

Husband and wife are one person in law; that is, the very being or legal existence of the woman is
suspended during the marriage.

William Blackstone (18th century)

While the closing decades of the 20th century enjoyed palpable strides forward in the reemergence of
feminine values, five millennia of repression continue to permeate the beliefs and systems of Western
society, particularly our monetary system.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

The importance of the Great Mother archetype to humanity is clearly noted by the responsibilities
entrusted to her symbolic care. This was acknowledged and expressed throughout antiquity by her many
representations in moneythe tool that provides the means to achieve our sustenance and very survival.
The symbolic thread continues to this day, as noted in the etymology of the words capital and money.

CHAPTER TWENTY TWO - Shadows



The Dark is the Light we cannot yet see.

~V.J. SHAWKAR

The invention of money occurred during the vast period in which much of the world honored the Great
Mother archetype. Our system of national currencies came about, instead, at the onset of the Industrial
Age, in a culture conditioned by severe repression of this same archetype. The link between our money
and this repression has many profound effects.

To provide a deeper understanding of moneys impact upon us, another basic concept of Archetypal
Psychology relevant to our work is herein introducedshadows. Shadows helps explain how specific
actions and attitudes come into being, persist, and spread. Its influence is typically unconscious.

SHADOWS

When an archetype is repressed, it does not just disappear. By definition, the rejected psychological
content instead manifests in a destructive shadow form.

Carl Jung explained:

The psychic energy that appears to have been lost [by the repression of an archetype]forms an
ever-present and potentially destructive shadow to our conscious mind. Even tendencies that might
in some circumstances be able to exert a beneficial influence are transformed into demons when they
are repressed.329

When repressed, an archetypes energy can manifest as one of two shadows. One represents the
repressed archetypes characteristics in excess; the other, in deficiency.330 An individual who represses
his or her inner Sovereign archetype, for example, tends to behave either as a tyrant or abdicator. The
tyrant possesses an excess of the Sovereigns emotional and behavioral attributes, while the abdicator has
a deficiency of the same characteristics. Similarly, the repressed Lover becomes either addicted (excess)
or impotent (deficient). The two shadows of each archetype are two faces of the same coin.

FearThe Common Denominator



The common denominator that connects the two shadows of a given archetype is always fear. Fear is
normally a healthy emotion. For example, when a car veers out of control in front of one, fear unleashes
an adrenaline rush that prompts one to react more rapidly to protect oneself. Normally, ones emotions
stabilize back to neutral after the danger is over.

When a fear gets permanently embodied, or when it freezes up in an individuals personality as an
enduring rather than a transient reaction, it is no longer a healthy emotion, but instead becomes
pathological. Such pathologies can manifest on an individual or a collective level, thus becoming a
characteristic of a societys culture. This embodied fear splits the archetypal energy into two, so that
now-repressed archetype manifests in the form of two polar shadows, as illustrated in Figure 22.1 with
the splitting of the Sovereign archetype into its two shadows, the tyrant and the weakling, due to the
prevalence of fear.

The same fear also links the two shadows of an archetype. When one scratches below the surface of a
tyrant, one invariably discovers a weakling (abdicator). Conversely, when an abdicator is given power
over someone else, he or she will start acting as a tyrant. This is brought on by the unresolved fear
responsible for the splitting of an archetype in the first place. A tyrant, for instance, is primarily afraid of
appearing weak, while an abdicator is fearful of appearing tyrannical.

Additionally, someone who is under the influence of one of the shadows will automatically tend to
attract people who embody the opposite shadow. A tyrant will tend to be surrounded by abdicators and
vice versa. It is one common way whereby, in Jungs words, we, Translate into visible reality the world
within us.

The Shadow is Not the Enemy



It seems logical to regard the shadow as the enemy. It is the problem we would most like to be rid of, the
face we do not want to acknowledge, the aspect of ourselves that elicits the most disapproval from our
culture, our family, and ourselves.

The shadow is also our taskmaster, however, relentlessly urging us to grow and evolve. When the ego,
the conscious perception of the individual self, narrows our feelings to an acceptable rangethe image of
what is culturally appropriateand when personal will is used to maintain that image, the shadows begin
to haunt us. Shadows take us to places within ourselves we would rather not explore. Although
unpleasant, their role is not to harm but rather, to assist by obliging us to face our own vulnerabilities.
Paradoxically, the real enemy is our very reluctance to face the shadows and embrace them in the first
place.

In this framework, consciousness can be seen as a personal theater where the ego, individual
unconscious, archetypes, and their shadows all play their respective roles. By its very nature, the ego is
unaware of these other actors. It is convinced that it alone is in charge, operating under its own free will.
Yet, as long as an archetype has not been integrated, the ego will be dominated by the fear-ridden axis
between the two shadows, acting out one or the other.

The only way to escape from the influence of the shadows is to overcome our fears and embrace them.
By doing so, shadows are no longer in control and the power and wisdom of the repressed archetype can
be accessed. This is referred to as integrating the archetype.

This process of integration is not easy. But the effort and suffering that often accompanies it are but
preludes to the reawakening of the sacred in daily life. The rewards associated with shadow work have
been recognized by many respected figures down through the ages, as noted by the following quotes:

If you bring forth what is within you,
what you bring forth will save you.
If you dont bring forth what is within you,
what you do not bring forth will destroy you.
Jesus331

Chaque ombre son me reconnait la lumire
(Each shadow in its soul recognizes the light)

Christian Tzara

If only it were all so simple!
If only there were evil people somewhere
insidiously committing evil deeds,
and it was necessary only to separate them
from the rest of us and destroy them.
But the line dividing good and evil
cuts through the heart of every human being.
And who is willing to destroy a piece of his own heart?


Aleksandr Solzhenitsyn

Shadows of the Five Essential Archetypes



Illustrated below is the archetypal human along with the excess and deficit shadows of the five essential
archetypes.


The shadows of the Sovereign are again, the tyrant and the abdicator. The shadows of the Warrior are
the sadist (excess) and the masochist (deficit). The Lovers two shadows are the addicted (excess) and
the impotent (deficit). The two shadows of the Magician are the hyperrationalist know-it-all (excess)
and the indiscriminate or chaotic fool (deficit).

Of particular interest are the shadows of the Great Mother, for, as noted, this archetype is most closely
associated with money. Her long and systematic repression has created deeply etched shadows in the
collective unconscious and in our monetary system. Many of the most important challenges we face today
can trace their origins directly or indirectly to her extensive repression. Her two shadows are greed
(excess) and fear of scarcity (deficit).

To provide us with an adequate language and framework with which to more precisely capture
distinctions between archetypes, shadows, and their relationship to money, we turn briefly to Taoism and
the concept of yin-yang.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

Another fundamental concept of Archetypal Psychology is shadows. When an archetype is repressed, it
does not just disappear, but instead manifests in a shadow form, either in excess or in deficiency. The
common denominator that connects the two shadows of a given archetype is always fear.

Though it seems logical to regard the shadow as the enemy, it is also our taskmaster, relentlessly urging
us to grow and evolve. The way to escape from the influence of the shadows is to overcome our fears and
embrace them. In so doing, shadows are no longer in control, and the power and wisdom of the repressed
archetype can be accessed.

CHAPTER TWENTY THREE - Money and the Tao



The Tao is called Great Mother.

Empty yet inexhaustible,

It gives birth to infinite worlds.

~LAO TZU

Another lens on archetypes and money is provided by the philosophy of Taoism. The Tao, (pronounced
Dao or Dow), meaning The Way, explains all forces in nature as complementary pairs, such as
Earth-Heaven, water-fire, inhaling-exhaling, pulling-pushing, and so on. These apparent polarities are
referred to as yin-yang pairs. Although such polarities are seemingly separate forces, this ancient
Chinese philosophy, like modern physics, which regards action and reaction as inseperable, sees each
element as necessary parts of a greater unity.

Yin denotes the essential quality of the feminine, which is not to be confused with the biological
female. Similarly, yang is not synonymous with the physical male. According to Taoism, a dynamic
equilibrium between these two polarities is required for a healthy expression of the natural order, both in
the world about us and in ourselves. For example, a male is not complete without accessing his feminine
dimension, just as a female is not complete without embracing the masculine within herself.332

The seemingly exotic terminology of yin-yang is used because Western languages and philosophies tend
to lack a vocabulary that adequately captures this concept. Jung stated:

Unfortunately, our Western mind, lacking all culture in this respect, has never yet devised a concept, nor
even a name, for the union of opposites through the middle path, that most fundamental item of inward
experience, which could respectably be set against the Chinese concept of Tao.333 This philosophy dates
back to prehistory to the teachings of Lao-Tzu (see insert).

Lao-Tzu and the Tao

The concept of yin-yang in China seems to have originated in prehistoric times. The semimythical
Yellow Emperor, estimated to have lived around 2500 BCE, used yin-yang concepts extensively in
medical texts. The classical form of Taoism is believed to have been founded sometime in the 6th
century BCE by the Chinese scholar Lao-Tzu, curator of the emperors Imperial Library.
Legend has it that in his old age and disgusted with courtly chicanery, Lao-Tzu resigned from his
respected post, left most of his belongings behind, mounted a water buffalo, and headed off to live
his remaining years as a recluse. But before doing so, he was stopped by a gate guardian who asked
him to first please sum up all he had learned from a life spent with the greatest book collection of the
Empire.
On the spot, Lao-Tzu wrote the Tao Te Ching. Consisting of only 5,000 ideograms, it is the
shortest treatise on good living in existence. It begins with the immortal words: The Tao that can be
spoken is not the real Tao. The Name that can be named is not the Eternal Name. This opening
conveys that language and intellect are the first barriers to knowing The Way.
Lao-Tzu stressed the importance of living in a balanced flow, valuing both the feminine and

masculine, and the equality between men and women.



Some traits associated with yin-yang are summarized in Figure 23.1. This figure can be read top-down
to identify internal yin and yang coherencesthe logical connection whereby these concepts reinforce
each other in a consistent worldview. The same figure can also be read horizontally, focusing on the
polarities between yin and yang manifestations listed in each half of the diagram.

It should be emphasized that the prime importance is an appropriate balance between yin and yang.
Taoists warn against falling into the trap of believing that either yin or yang, or any one of the values
represented in each of these polarities, is right or wrong, good or bad.


The key point is that both yin and yang are necessary in life. Without this balance, dangerous
pathologies can develop, as displayed by the shadows.

YIN AND YANG SHADOW AXES



As discussed earlier, when an archetype is repressed its essential energies are expressed as two
shadows, each of which manifest deficit and excess aspects of that particular archetype. Employing Taoist
concepts, deficit aspects can be understood as yin shadows, while excess aspects can be labeled yang
shadows.

With respect to the five major human archetypesthe Sovereign, Warrior, Lover, Magician, and Great
Motherthe yin (deficit) shadows are, respectively: abdication, masochism, impotence, inability to
discern, and fear of scarcity. Together they form a collection of shadows referred to as the yin shadow
axis.

The yang shadow axis consists of the yang (excess) shadows of each major archetype, namely: tyranny,
sadism, addiction, hyperrationalism, and greed.

Today in our society, a broad spectrum of patriarchal influence, together with the specific repression of
the Great Mother archetype, has led to the dominance of the yang shadow axis in our society. For
example, we are vulnerable to tyrannical leaders who abuse their office, ruling over rather than serving
the good of their constituencies. From the ancient Assyrians, who flayed and impaled men alive for sport,
to the atrocities and genocides of World War II, Bosnia, Rwanda, and Darfur, the sadist shadow has been
with us for a gruesomely long time. Addictions of all varieties have become endemic in our society, and
include illegal addictions such as heroin or cocaine; legal habits such as caffeine, alcohol, and tobacco;
and other compulsive behaviors condoned in mainstream culture, such as workaholism; addiction to
control; obsession with escapist entertainment; and codependency. Ironically and irrationally, reason is
exalted to the exclusion of all other ways of knowing, resulting in a hyperrationality that narrows and
even perverts our thinking. Finally, we feel constantly driven by greed to accumulate more money, goods
and possessions, and to act in such ways despite our deeper desires and better judgment.

The pervasiveness of greed and other yang-shadow emotions and behaviors in many races, cultures,
and religions down through history lends support to the illusion that they are normal expressions that
simply reflect who we truly are.

Our archetypal framework, however, tells a very different story. Though commonly present and very
persistent, many of our feelings and actions are inconsistent with a healthy yin-yang balance and point
instead to a widespread and long-standing pathology. The prevalance in our society of tyranny, sadism,
addiction, hyperrationalism, and greed are each expressions of the yang shadow axis. Together with the
Great Mothers yin shadowfear of scarcitythese aberrant, unhealthy behaviors lead us directly back
to our monetary paradigm.

YIN AND YANG CURRENCIES



The distinction between yin and yang can be applied to currency designs based upon their underlying
agreements, along with the behaviors and emotions they engender. The agreements with regard to our
current official monetary system includes a strong hierarchical control via central banks.334 The
embedded interest feature creates competition, as well as the need for perpetual growth and the
concentration of wealth, and it rewards the accumulation of money. It is on the basis of these inherent
patterns that our conventional money can be understood as a yang-type currency. Given that every single
one of its features is yang, this money can even be described as extreme yang.

Other types of monetary systems, like Time Dollars, LETS, and some of the local currencies used in the
Central Middle Ages, promote entirely different types of behavior. Some of these currencies were
available in sufficiency, provided incentives for circulation and distribution, and promoted cooperation
and community building. Money designs with such characteristics reflect yin energy and can therefore be
referred to as yin-type currencies.

It should now be clearer why we describe differently designed national and local currencies as
complementary. Yin-yang pairs, by their very definition, complement each other. And as Lao Tzu
pointed out: When yang and yin combine, all things achieve harmony.335

Central to our issues is that in the currently dominant monetary paradigm there is a lack of yin currency
to balance the monopoly of yang-type national currency. This lack is directly related to the fact that in our
culture the Great Mother archetype has been systematically devalued and repressed.

Shadow Money

Money, as noted, is a key attribute of the Great Mother. Repression of this archetype led to the
development of monetary systems that embodied her two shadows. On a historical level we can
understand how and when these shadows were programmed into the monetary system. After all, this
system was developed during the pre-Victorian era, a time of intense rejection of the feminine in almost
every way, as reflected in religion, philosophy, ways of knowing, and the treatment of women themselves
after three centuries of witch hunts. Since our monetary system developed in the midst of this archetypes
repression, it encapsulated the Great Mothers shadows rather than her wisdom.

Not only are greed, and fear of scarcity, embedded in money, but the fear that links them is also
perpetuated in an endless, vicious cycle by our monetary system. A well-known clich on Wall Street
goes: Financial markets know only two emotions: greed and fear. Fear customarily characterizes many
peoples relationship to money and drives our financial decisions and markets, while scarcity is built
directly into our bank-debt monetary system. It is scarcity that maintains the value of our national
currencies.

We depend on this scarce type of money for nearly everything we need, do, and aspire to. Yet, this
built-in scarcity leaves many of us without sufficient means to meet even the basic requirements for
survival. This lack perpetuates fear, regardless of our own particular financial situation. Even those who
have sufficient money are aware of the fortunes won and lost every day in the fluctuating marketplace. The
poor, disenfranchised, and homeless serve as constant reminders of the fate that awaits the rest of us
should we happen to become the next losers in the current paradigm. Our sense of financial security is
tenuous at best. This causes many to experience the world as a place in which we must struggle to
survive.

These shadows and the behaviors they engender can be found in all societies that live with a monopoly
of yang money. These emotions and behaviors persist, not because they represent who we really are, but
rather because of the unnatural state in which we are forced to live. This state of affairs is perpetuated by
the monopoly of our national currencies, and amplified by a particular capacity of money to replicate
information.

Money as an Information Replicator



Chilean biologists Humberto Maturana and Francisco Varela describe how systems form and maintain
themselves through replication: This process occurs at all levels: molecular, biological, and social. For
every system has its own characteristic replication that forms, expands, and holds systems together.336

Replicators of ideas and collective emotions are instruments that maintain particular social systems.
These collective ideas and emotions are sometimes called memes, analogous to the genes in
biological systems. These memes are the building blocks of a societys constituent parts, including its
structures and dominant beliefs.


Money is part and parcel of our oldest information system. Writing itself seems to have been initially
invented by the Sumerian civilization to record financial transactions, as confirmed by the earliest tablets
found in Uruk. Our monetary system now functions as a key information replicator, a vital linchpin that
drives particular and consistent behavior patterns. Every dollar created and spent reinforcesreplicates
the values that are deeply embedded in the basic design of our currency systems.

Money shapes our beliefs and social structures and tells us what is and is not possible. This explains
how, with the best intentions, even with totally different personal values or perspectives, regardless of
gender, race, or socio-cultural biases and affiliations, most of us behave in a manner consistent with the
yang shadow axis to obtain money. One expression of this is the emphasis on competition over
cooperation. Without it, Western civilization would look and act very differently. Our money is one of the
key information replicators that ensures that competition is emphasized throughout society.

Fear of scarcity and the axis of excessive yang shadows are continually reinforced by our yang-type
national currencies. This is reflected in many of our cultural stereotypes, such as the tyrannical, greedy
scrooges who sadistically enjoy their power over others. A more recent stereotype is the workaholic
executive, addicted to accumulating money, power, and glory, often at the price of any ultimate
satisfaction. He ends up lonely in a meaningless world.

In professional life, many feel the need to ignore their own and other peoples emotions in the
performance of their jobs. In the domains of media, medicine, and finance, professionalism is equated
with taking a hyperrational distance from other people, and is oftentimes seen by others as cynicism and

emotional disengagement.

As things stand now, our true natures are not necessarily reflected by our collective ways of being and
doing. We live in a global matrix, in which many of our collective emotions and patterns of behavior are
instead conditioned by a monopoly of yang-type currencies that reinforce a very particular, limited set of
values on the whole of society and each of us individually. Some of the consequences of this conditioning
are examined next.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

Our financial markets know only the two emotions of greed and fear, because all financial markets have
one common denominator: the type of money that is used to value nearly everything. Financial markets
simply mirror our collective archetypal wounding.

It must be remembered that it is not money itself that is at fault here. Rather, it is the monopoly of yangtype currencies that, like hammers, are imbued with only a limited set of functionalities. When only
hammers are available, we start treating everything as nails.

Despite the many services rendered and achievements made possible by our monetary system, it is the
monopoly of national currencies in our world that continually reinforces imbalance. Unlike Hammerville,
whose use of only one tool came about through ignorance alone, our limited monetary toolsetby and
large the same once created centuries ago at the beginning of the Industrial Agewas brought about not
just by ignorance, but also by a long-standing archetypal repression. We examine the consequences more
closely in the following chapter.

CHAPTER TWENTY FOUR - Consequences of Repression



That which we do not bring to consciousness

appears in our lives as fate.

~CARL GUSTAV JUNG

When modern psychology and psychotherapy came into being, much of their focus centered on the
individual patienton his or her trauma and personal psychological framework. Many of our challenges
and behaviors, however, do not emanate from individual disturbances alone.

Archetypal psychologist James Hillman observed:

Too many people have been analyzing their pasts, their childhoods, their memories, their parents,
and realizing that it doesnt do anythingor that it doesnt do enough. Psychotherapy theory turns it
all on you: you are the one who is wrong. [But] If a kid is having trouble or is discouraged, the
problem is not just inside the kid; its also in the system, the societyProblems come from the
environment, the cities, the economy, racism. They come from architecture, school systems,
capitalism, exploitation.337

Problems also derive from money choices. As noted, each type of currency is imbued with specific
design features that encourage or discourage particular behaviors and values. Our national currencies
were simply not structured to address social, economic, or ethical concerns. Rather, they are international
trading currencies designed to promote specific business needs, and to this restricted end they have
performed admirably. Though money is not inherently good or bad, and certainly not the root of all evil,
the particular design of our national currencies does promote greed, as well as fear of scarcity.338 Given
moneys innate capacity to replicate information, and lacking any significant yin-currency system to
provide a counterbalance, the skewed yang shadow axis dominates unchallenged, the consequences of
which are profound.

MONEY AND UNDERDEVELOPMENT



Geopolitical power considerations were the main influence that determined the monetary order. Under
todays monetary rules, less-developed countries must borrow hard currencies from the richest
countries to keep their economies running. These countries require more and more money just to pay back
the interest on previous loans, the payments for which currently amount to about $300 million per day.
Activist and rock star Bono notes:

Africa (alone) spends $200 million every week repaying its debts to the West. That made no sense to
me. It means that for every 1 western governments give to the poorest nations, the poor nations pay
back 3 to the west! Is that not barbaric? Is it not barbaric that Tanzania spends more on repaying its
loans than it does on health care and education combined?339

After the G8 summit in Okinawa in 2000, former President Obasanjo of Nigeria made this comment on
Nigerias debt:

All that we had borrowed up to 1985 or 1986 was around $5 billion. So far we have paid back
about $16 billion. Yet we are being told that we still owe about $28 billion. That $28 billion came
about because of the foreign creditors interest rates. If you ask me what is the worst thing in the
world, I will say it is compound interest.340

When President Obasanjo spoke out a decade ago, the developing world was spending $13 on debt
repayment for every dollar it received in grant aid.341 A mere decade later, the repayment cost has nearly
doubled to over $25 for every dollar borrowed.

The monetary rules that have been applied by the IMF to developing nations through its structural
adjustment programs have been widely criticized. Such adjustment programs, in play since the 1980s,
include prioritizing the payback of interest on foreign loans, even if it means dismantling the recipient
nations educational systems and other long-term social investment programs. It has been claimed that if
these same rules were applied to the United States, this superpower would itself regress to Third World
status in as little as one or two generations. Would not everybody, including the First World and its
financial institutions, be better off if all countries were truly able to develop themselves, free of these
draconian constraints?

Some efforts have been made to counteract the consequences of excessive Third World debt. For
instance, the Millennium Movement successfully promoted the cancellation of at least part of the debt of
the poorest countries, although the debt was not actually cancelled. Rather, the otherwise unpayable debt
was transferred to U.S. and European governments that, in turn, passed it onto their own taxpayers, who
ended up paying banks on behalf of the developing countries. With such debts written off, these poorest
countries are in a position to start going into debt all over again. This approach leaves fundamental
questions unaddressed. What, for instance, prompts us to create an international monetary system and to
maintain rules that make this debt necessary in the first place? Is it not time to address systemic issues
with systemic solutions?

Though assistance programs and loans to developing nations in the form of national currencies may
have noble objectives, the very act of introducing a monopoly of a yang-type currency into a culture can
have disastrous effects. We should remember that our national currencies were never designed to promote

values such as cooperation or equality, or address the vast majority of our social needs. They were
specifically designed to promote industrialization, competition, and nationalism. This very same currency
that we are now usingunsuccessfullyto assist developing nations was instead actually used quite
effectively to colonize, not liberate, many of those same nations, as seen in Ghana (see insert).

The Ghana Hut Tax

The British faced an interesting problem in the 19th century, when they colonized what would later
become the nation of Ghana. At the time, Ghana consisted of several hundred more or less
sustainable communities, each contained within their own traditional region. They traded, but only
with one another in closed circuits established by tradition among the different tribes. This trading
system permitted Ghanaians to meet their basic requirements. It also provided some measure of
independence from the colonial government and the need for British goods. Yet, one goal of having a
colony is to procure a secure market within a well-controlled territory. The British, therefore, sought
to break up the self-contained, regional patterns in order to create a demand for British goods and to
secure colonial control of the area.
The British solution was not to start a big advertising or marketing campaign for their goods. It
was not even to try to prohibit the old exchange patterns or use coercion to create new ones. It was a
lot cheaper, simpler, and more elegant than that. The colonial government simply created, for the first
time, a national Ghanaian currency together with a very modest hut tax. The tax, (of one shilling
per household per year) would be payable only in that national currency. Lo and behold, within a
few years, most of the traditional sustainable systems collapsed. Why?
Every hutevery extended family unit in the countryneeded to earn some of this new
currency to pay their hut tax. This could only be done by trading outside of their traditional
framework within a new national system. That alone was sufficient to break up long-standing
patterns of regional sustainability.

The lesson should be clear: trying to encourage local or regional development, while simultaneously
maintaining a monopoly of a national or supranational currency, is like treating an alcoholic with alcohol
prescriptions. The monopoly of bank-debt money affects all of us, in developing and developed nations
alike. It coerces virtually all those who come into contact with it to behave in ways that are consistent
with the yang shadow axis.

The entire field of economics has been based on the erroneous assumption that something in human
natureand not the type of money usedis what predetermines our behavior patterns.

Economics and the Economic Man



It was at the height of patriarchy in Western society, when the last witches were still being burned in
Europe, that Adam Smith wrote his Theory of Moral Sentiments (1758) and Wealth of Nations (1776).
He observed that in all modern societies there existed a universal desire for individuals to accumulate
money. This observation heavily influenced the development of Smiths theoryeconomicswhose
purpose it was to allocate scarce resources through the means of individual private accumulation.

The psychological cornerstone of economic theory became the idea of the economic man. This notion
is defined as, a hypothetical man supposed to be free from altruistic sentiments and motives interfering
with a purely selfish pursuit of wealth and its enjoyment.342 It should be noted that this concept was not
introduced nor mentioned by Smith himself.

In traditional economic models, we are all expected to find the economic man within us and empower
him to act. That is, we are supposed to act purely rationally and selfishly, and this process will ultimately
benefit all. This notion has, however, long begged contention (see insert).

The Mythical Economic Man

The psychological assumptions behind the mythical economic man present substantial problems.
The definition itself implies that everyone can and should be totally rationalthat is, behave in
accord with the hyperrational yang shadow of the Magician. In other words, this definition asks us to
push aside any vestige of the various yin aspects of ourselves, including any concerns for our
communities.
When the Great Mother is repressed, yin ways and means of knowing are automatically devalued,
together with the rest of the yin coherence.
The concept of economic man also assumes that group behavior is of the same nature as individual
behavior. No room is left for any group psychology that may differ qualitatively from individual
behavior. The hypothetical economic man entails the mistaken fallacy of composition, which fails
to take into account that the whole is greater than the sum of its parts.
Gustave Le Bon, a pioneer of social pyschology, made the following point: Individual members,
however like or unlike their model of life, occupations or intelligence, find themselves overruled by
a collective mind set. This way of feeling, thinking and acting directs the individual to behave quite
differently from what he would do alone.343
Le Bons definition of group psychology is quite consistent with the findings of his contemporary
Jung, regarding the collective unconscious.

Economics and the Yang Perspective



In all fairness, most economists have long been aware of the oversimplifications built into economic man
and do not take its assumptions literally. Economist Wesley Clair Mitchell pointed out, Economics
without input from psychology is similar to doing mechanics while ignoring the laws of physics.344 Even
so, the economic man hypothesis persists as an implicit and necessary condition to make the equations of
conventional economics work.

Moneys value-nonneutrality and other more recent findings all point to the very important links
between the type of money used and economic behaviors. Instead of being a passive facilitator of
exchanges, as traditional economic theory posits, the monopoly of a yang-type currency deeply affects the
relationships between, and the collective psychology of, the people who use it. Yet, as great as this impact
is, it is only the first consequence of archetypal repression and the yang shadow axis.

THE DOMINATOR PARADIGM



Some of the better-known social pathologies of modern-day society include narcissism, consumerism, and
fundamentalism. Though they may not appear to be related to our monetary system or to the repression of
the Great Mother archetype, our conventional currencies nonetheless feed and activate these pathologies
continuously in a catalytic manner. This activation occurs by means of the dominator paradigm.

Dominance is the need to control or maintain authority over others to attain a sense of security or
identity for oneself. The desire to dominate justifies the need for a repressive social order, and is deeply
linked to our historical patriarchy. Recall here the tyrant, the excessive yang shadow of the Sovereign
archetype. Intrinsic within this dominance paradigm, and connected to the patriarchal ideology, is a belief
in total control over others. This is expressed as an imagined sense of security founded on power by
whatever means necessary, whether military, political, economic, religious, or psychological.

Other processes that relate to the dominator paradigm in our society today include the glamorization of
violence, vicious forms of sport and play, and the fascination with war and aggressive technologies.
While we are all subjected culturally to the yang shadow axis, some are more prone to it than others.
Someone who is stuck in this shadow axis tends to create a separate and superior identity, and
automatically casts as others those entities or people that he or she fears, cannot control, or does not
understand. These others tend to include any group associated with yin characteristics, such as women
and Nature, different cultures and races, and so-called primitive societies. This helps explain the long
history of the portrayal and the dismissal by mainstream Western society (which is itself caught in a yang
shadow axis) of any such others as weak, impotent, irrational, masochistic (each of which are yin
shadows), and thus deserving to live in scarcity.

Narcissism and Consumerism



The dominator paradigm has a significant cost, not only for those who are dominated, but also for the
dominators themselves.345 It is at the origin of what psychologists have called the narcissism of Western
culture.

Psychologist Ondine Norman describes the key components of this narcissism:

One of the most relevant and important diagnostic characteristics of narcissism is the lack of
empathy for others. This is a key feature of the dominator paradigm. One cannot even imagine
partnership or the capacity for mutual relationships if one is not able to experience some level of
empathy for anothers experience.346

Such a lack of empathy leads directly to a sense of meaninglessness. Meaning always arises out of
relationship, whether with loved ones, God, nature, or ones country. The inability to connect with others,
therefore, predictably accentuates a sense of meaninglessness, creating what has been referred to as the
feeling of an empty self.

Psychologist Christopher Lasch points out that narcissism does have some features that are useful in our
society: The management of personal impressions comes naturally to [the narcissist], and the mastery of
its intricacies serves him well in political and business organizations.347 The same narcissist, however,
also demonstrates traits that are at the origin of many of societys difficulties, from the incapacity to
establish long-term partner relationships to the adoption of what Jungian analyst Mario Jacoby describes
as super materialistic and environmentally unsustainable consumerist lifestyles.348


The empty self is also the hook by which consumer advertising works. As B. Earl Puckett, president of
Allied Stores Corporation, a large U.S. department store chain, explained, It is our job to make women
unhappy with what they have.349 A key aim of advertising is to make people feel empty, incomplete, and
dissatisfied. The ads message to our subconscious is: if only you were to wear this brand of sneakers,
drive this car, have the next updated technology, or use this perfume, you would finally be whole and no

longer feel your emptiness.


Fundamentalism

Another phenomenon linked to the dominator paradigm is fundamentalism, which is not about what one
believes in, but rather about how one holds those beliefs. Fundamentalism arises when someone regards
his or her own beliefs as the absolute Truth and, therefore, considers all other opinions or faiths to be
illegitimate.

Fundamentalism is another way that people deal with the fear of meaninglessness and the empty self.
Jacoby writes:

Whenever archaic rage combines with the search for high ideals and the necessity to find meaning in
ones life, rage with all its consequences may flare up in the name of whatever the ideal. Any horror,
rage, and vengefulness can then be justified on the basis of the ideal one is apparently serving.350

One extreme manifestation of fundamentalism is terrorism.

AND THE WINNER IS?



Who truly benefits in a society that is skewed toward patriarchy and lacks archetypal balance? Who wins
with a monetary system that promotes this imbalance, which imposes scarcity on the many, and
concentrates wealth in the hands of a very few? Clearly the majority of the billions of poor in our world
suffer disproportionately. But though it might seem that men and the wealthy are the likely beneficiaries of
such a paradigm, the reality is somewhat more complex.

Effects on Men

If we understand Western culture as a patriarchy, we might logically tend to place men at its helm. This
was the assumption of Pulitzer Prize-winning journalist and feminist Susan Faludi, as she began research
for her book Stiffed: The Betrayal of the American Man. Her findings, however, surprised even her.

Faludi reports that in our patriarchal society, men are asked to need nothing and no one, and to support
their families with total confidence. They are told to go out into the world, into the market, to win, and
win big. They should know what they want out of life and how to get it. And throughout, they are to remain
unstressed, detached, and ready to do whatever is necessary to protect their families and country.

While the term patriarchy implies that men are in control of everything, they are in actual fact often
denied the ability to determine their own lives. They are not given the space or tools to express and work
with their full range of emotion or to better know themselves. Some men, particularly in light of todays
increasing unemployment, feel so lost and out of touch that they lash out.

Faludi began her research by attending a mens domestic violence group. She reported:

The men I got to know in the group had without exception lost their compass in the world. They had
lost or were losing jobs, homes, cars, families. They had been labeled outlaws but felt like castoffs.
Their strongest desire was to be dutiful and to belong, to adhere with precision to the roles society
had set out for them as men.351

Faludis research reveals something important about the patriarchy in which we live. Men feel the
contours of a boxbut they are told that box is of their own manufacture, designed to their
specifications.352 That boxthe patriarchygives the illusion of power but instead causes immense
suffering for men as well as women.

The wealthythe other supposed class of winners in our societylike men in general, have their own
issues.

The Wounds of Wealth



The psychological issues resulting from this imbalanced monetary situation can be understood as
wounds because they run deep and touch our most vulnerable nerves, and they are almost impossible to
avoid. These wounds can undermine our relationships and make us doubt our own self-worth. Most of us
have empathy for the plight of those who suffer from the scarcity that arises from living with insufficient
money. The wounds created by poverty are indeed pervasive, devastating, and easily understood. But the
monopoly of yang money affects all economic classesthe rich as well as the poor. Less appreciated are
the formidable issues of having too much money.

Jungian psychologist Bernice Hill has identified four wounds of wealth, which appear at successive
levels of intimate interaction, including: burdens of expectation, isolation, unhealthy family dynamics, and
crisis of identity (see insert).353

Four Wounds of Wealth

1. Burdens of Expectation. Those few who are considered wealthy are often the targets of the fears,
needs, and expectations of the many who lack money. Societal expectations permeate many aspects
of life, including that of supporting charities and generally doing the right thing, which often
translates into writing check after check. When asked to attend an affair or participate in an event,
social or otherwise, the affluent are left to ask themselves, Am I or my checkbook being invited?
2. Isolation. Similarly, the wealthy must question if their personal relationships are based on
money or status, rather then genuine caring and true feelings of friendship. As a consequence, the rich
tend to socialize only with those from similar financial and social backgrounds, and experience a
deep sense of isolation. The painful question lingers, If I didnt have any money, how many of my
friends would still be my friends, and how might I find out? Love, popularity, and camaraderie can
be as paper-thin as money itself.
This lack of trust is reflected in the security measures that are taken: the higher walls built around
their homes, possessions, and lives, literally and psychologically. In the end, the affluent tend to seek
refuge in golden ghettos.
3. Unhealthy Family Dynamics. How often do we hear of rich-family feuds, the nagging fears and
general angst regarding inheritances, wills, and the pressures brought to bear on siblings regarding
proper behavior? Even the most intimate relationshipschoosing the right mate in marriageare
subject to all-important pre-nuptial agreements, becoming yet another business contract. Unhealthy
family dynamics is another wound associated with wealth.
4. Crisis of Identity. Most importantly perhaps, particularly for those who have inherited wealth,
are the questions of identity and self-worth. Who am I? can be a painful question when your main
public identity is that you have money. Philosopher Jacob Needleman observes that The only thing
that money will not buy is meaning.354 Often, wealthy people find that their money has brought them
guilt, anxiety, and a sense of meaninglessness.

In an environment where so much is shaped by our financial worth, the scarce commodity is trust. Each
of these four wounds has in common a loss of trust: in society, in friends, in family, and finally, in oneself.
An all-too-common response to the issues faced by the wealthy is, I wish I had that problem. This
denies, however, the depth of the pain experienced by some.


Clearly, rich and poor suffer within this current monetary paradigm. Individuals within each economic
group face their own wounds associated with money. These wounds point to the fact that nobody wins
with a one-size-fits-all monetary system, which encourages only some aspects of human nature and
replicates greed and fear of scarcity.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

We live in a world that uses predominately one type of money, which came into being centuries ago and is
embedded with industrial-age values. Few can escape the imbalances and struggles that result from the
limitations imposed by this medium of exchange.

Yang shadows are the hidden roots of many of our most serious contemporary societal ailments. Rather
than a simple cause-and-effect situation, there is instead what chemists refer to as a catalytic effect: an
ingredient that does not appear to be involved in the reaction but, nevertheless, powerfully activates it.
The social ailments listed are not necessarily mechanical results of the monetary system alone, but rather
are the results of an axis in which our money is a decisive information replicator.

The modern monetary system provides rewards for those who accumulate money, with earned interest,
prestige, and material comfort. This same system also ruthlessly punishes those who do not or cannot
participate, by means of bankruptcy and poverty. The game continues without end, and the results are
devastating: tens of thousands of people, the majority of them children, die from starvation each day. That
is not a game. It is a holocaust.

To become individually and collectively whole, integration of all archetypal energies and both yin
and yang coherences are required. Repression of the feminine cannot continue, not just because it is
inherently wrong, but because it is destroying us.

Reintegrating Great Mother energy does not mean, however, switching from a patriarchal society to a
matriarchal one. It cannot be emphasized enough that the sought-after outcome is to find a new balance
between the masculine and feminine, an equilibrium that honors the specific contributions of each. But
such a balance requires an integrated monetary system with both yin and yang currencies working
alongside one another in complementary fashion to meet our many diverse and divergent needs and
aspirations, and which allow for a full expression of our archetypal energies.

PART IV - MONEY, ARCHETYPES, AND PAST AGES



Money ranks as one of the primary materials with which

Mankind builds the architecture of civilization.

~LEWIS LAPHAM

CHAPTER TWENTY FIVE - The Central Middle Ages Revisited



History is a guide to navigation in perilous times.

History is who we are and why we are the way we are.

~DAVID C. McCULLOUGH

It is our contention that archetypal repression is linked to our monetary system and to the virtual monopoly
of yang-type national currencies. Our monetary paradigm acts as a relentless information replicator of
skewed patriarchal values, which include the two shadows of the Great Mother archetype: greed and fear
of scarcity. It is therefore not with idle curiosity that we examine societies with dual-currency systems
that honored feminine as well as masculine values.

We therefore turn our focus once again back to a more distant epoch in which dual-currency systems
and a different archetypal framework were in operation.

The purpose of our exploration extends beyond obscure monetary issues in past civilizations. As we
have seen, the current paradigm is linked to and may be triggering any number of negative consequences
for society, including depletion of precious resources and long-term damage to our ecosystems. Insights
from the past that could help point the way to a more balanced future are of vital importance to us today.

THE MEDIEVAL ARCHETYPAL FRAMEWORK



As noted previously back in Chapter Six, the Central Middle Ages distinguished itself from other periods
of Western history by a unique form of prosperity that benefitted all classes of society. Unusual investment
patterns in productive assets were commonplace as well. Evidence of the long-term thinking and superior
craftsmenship of this age endure to this very day in the form of such public works as the cathedrals of
Western Europe.

Another hallmark of this medieval epoch was their dual-currency monetary system. Long-distance
currencies, similar in function to todays national currencies, were complemented by local means of
exhange, some of which were demurrage-charged and accessible to all social classes. These
complementary currencies likely played a significant role in the accomplishments of this age. Moreover,
the elimination of the local currencies coincides with the sudden and dramatic demise of this golden
epoch in the waning years of the 1200s.

The distinctive elements thus far noted, however, tell only part of the story. Another dimension of this
remarkable age is revealed to us through the lens of Archetypal Psychology.

We begin by examining the status of women during the period.

A Half-Renaissance for Women



It will be recalled that the study of bodily remains revealed that the women of Central medieval London
were the tallest in all recorded history. These findings not only suggest the high standard of living enjoyed
at that time, but may also reflect another important dimension of this age.

Historian Erika Uitz writes, In the 12th century a window of freedom began to open for town-dwelling
European women, only to close again before the end of the 15th century.355 While conditions were not
idyllic, women were unquestionably much freer than either before or after this period. The official
Renaissance that came into being later, was comparitively speaking of far lesser equality or enlightenment
for women, despite being full of progress in the arts and other domains.356 It is not until the last half of the
20th century that women began to reclaim many of the rights and opportunities that were the norm in the
Central Middle Ages.

Work was broadly available for women. Of the 312 professions formally registered as mtiers
(occupations) in France at the end of the 13th century, women were officially employed in 108. The
Parisian tax registers of 1292 paint an even rosier picture: women worked in 172 different occupations,
including barrel making, soap boiling, candle making, bookbinding, and doll painting. Though rarely,
women also worked as butchers and, according to Uitz, were involved even in mining, sword and
scythes making.357

Women were typically more literate than men among the lay population. While boys and men of
aristocratic lineage were trained primarily in the subjects of weapons and warfare, women were routinely
trained in reading, writing, singing, and painting. This training was not limited to aristocratic women, but
also included daughters of servants and artisans.358

Central medieval women also enjoyed an unusually high level of freedom concerning property. In
England, Only thirty wills survive today from that late Anglo-Saxon period [10th to 11th centuries] and
ten of these are the wills of women, each of whom was a significant property owner, with the same rights
of ownershipas any man.359 Women also had control over large endowments as founders of
monasteries and as general benefactors, making them notable figures in their communities.

Women played a surprising role as well in many religious institutions. Many monastic communities
were double houses, having one monastery for nuns and another for monks, with both houses under the
same jurisdiction. One study of 50 such double houses reports that all were under the direction of a
woman. Everyone answered to an abbess, not an abbot!360

The arts blossomed during this age and many women played prominent roles. Among the famous
mystics and authors, are included the likes of Hildegard von Bingen, Herade von Landsberg, Margery
Kempe, Julian of Norwich, Catherine of Siena, and Catherine of Genoa.

Notable women of the period had significant influence on the intellectual life and politics of the age.
This included the likes of Queen Anne, Countess Mathilde, and Eleanor of Aquitaine. As Duchess of
Aquitaine, Eleanor was wealthy and powerful in her own right. But as queen consort first of France
(11371152), then of England (11541189), following her annulment from King Louis VII and subsequent
marriage to Henry II, she became one of the most powerful of all Central medieval figures. She also sired
two of Englands future kings: Richard the Lionheart and King John. One of Eleanors lasting

contributions was as a patron of Courtly Love literature (see insert).



Courtly Love

Of the many artistic achievements realized during this rich cultural period, the most progressive and
enduring expression was the literature of "Courtly Love" (LAmour Courtois). It marked a significant
change in the way Western civilization viewed the concept of love. Courtly Love and its literature
have been considered An essential stage in the emancipation of women.361
This literature portrayed a glamorous, new romantic life, which often included secret and
forbidden extramarital affairs. These affairs occurred particularly among nobles and aristocrats in
the milieu of royal courts (hence, courtship, courtesy, and courtesan), with the male typically vying
for the prized affections of the exalted lady mistress.
Patronage by the likes of the Count of Toulouse and Eleanor of Aquitaine reveals the importance
of and support for this literature from the highest levels of power.
Courtly Love originated from the late-11th century region of southern France, called Languedoc.
This literature emanated from a worldview referred to as Gai Saber, literally the happy wisdom
or happy science. Gai Saber and Courtly Love effectively challenged and redefined some of the
most traditional Christian ideals, including love, marriage, virtue, and fundamental concepts such as
manhood and womanhood.
Historian Rgine Pernoud proclaims: Love was invented in the 12th century.362 According to Uc
de St. Circ, a 13th-century troubadour, Courtly Love for a man is to reach heaven through a woman.
It transformed the view of women from that of property to lover and partner.
Noted novelist and scholar C.S. Lewis declared:
[Courtly Love] effected a change that has left no corner of our ethics, our imagination, or our daily
life untouched. It erected impassable barriers between us and the classical past or the Oriental
present. Compared with this revolution, the Renaissance is a mere ripple on the surface of
literature.363

The profound social impact of Courtly Love is explained not just by the nature of its content, but by its
availability to a much broader audience: it was the first poetry written in popular language. Previous
literature was written in scholastic Latin and was typically accessible only to church-trained scholars.
First appearing in Occitan, or Langue dOc, the language of the southern half of France during that time,
this movement spurred the development of poetry in many other nascent vernacular languages, including
Catalan, Germanic, English, and Italian.364 Literary historian Meg Bogin explains, For the very first time,
common folk actually had something to read!365

The freedom, quality of expression, and values embodied by this literature would vanish with the end
of this medieval period. Courtly Love would, however, come to influence Europe yet again, after its
rediscovery in the 18th century, during which time it was instrumental in spawning the Romantic
Movement.366

Some historians have tried to explain the unusually active role of women during the epoch as due to
simple labor scarcity. Yet, if working opportunities were in short supply, why were there six-hour
workdays, 90 or more holidays, and Blue Mondays? Why would people invest so much time in chiseling
ornate sculptures in remote corners of gigantic cathedrals? More puzzling still, why would anybody build
cathedrals with the capacity to house three or four times the entire towns population, whose completion
would never be seen by its originators during their own lifetimes?

The particular dedication of the cathedrals offers testimony that something more significant was afoot.
Nearly all of the French cathedrals built during this time were dedicated not to Jesus, whose religion they
were supposed to be about, but rather to Notre Dame (Our Lady). More peculiar still was the form in
which Mary was widely representedin the powerful archetypal image of the Black Madonna.

The Black Madonna



During this unique age, the Black Madonna manifested as the periods most original and preeminent
religious icon. The most venerated statues, important pilgrimagesincluding the famed Santiago de
Compostelaand many religious centers all honored her. Well over 500 Romanesque statues of the Black
Madonna have been identified as originating during the Central Middle Ages.367 In France alone, no less
than 80 cathedrals, more than 250 churches, and 302 dedicated sanctuaries were built specifically to
venerate her.

The Black Madonna was also a major theme in the poetry of Courtly Love. While Black Madonna
icons certainly existed before Courtly Love verse, the explosive proliferation of statues around much of
Europe coincided with the spreading of that literature. Courtly Love troubadours wrote about Notre Dame
de la Nuit, and honored her as the Madonna of Transformation, and as the Queen of their spiritual
quest.368

Scholar Petra von Cronenburg concludes: The literature of Courtly Love, the mystical love for the
Black Madonnaall had one common purpose: the internal experience of the Hieros Gamos (sacred
marriage) with androgynous qualities, the integration of the masculine and feminine within, the merging of
the human and the divine.369

The relevance of the Black Madonna figure becomes clearer when we realize that she represented the
power of the feminine in her own terms. This is in marked contrast with the later white Madonna with
her blue and white gown, who was only an intercessor, an intermediary to the divine. In other words, the
Black Madonna represented not only the Great Mother archetype, but archetypal balance as well.
References that parallel this are found in the esoteric traditions.

Esotericism versus Exotericism

All major religions have had exoteric, as well as esoteric traditions.370 Exotericism refers to the official,
publicly available teachings; esotericism pertains instead to hidden knowledge, customarily available
only to initiates. The esoteric traditions include the Kabbalah in Judaism, Sufism in Islam, and Tantra in
both Hinduism and Tibetan Buddhism. In Christianity, the transmitters of such esoteric traditions included
the Augustinian, Benedictine, Cistercian, and Templar orders. All of these Christian esoteric traditions
had a different relationship with the feminine than that conveyed by the official exoteric message.

In the esoteric text of Gnostic origin, the Gospel According to the Hebrews, for instance, Jesus
explicitly called the Holy Spirit his Mother. Various mystical Christian traditions, including those of
Jakob Boehme, Meister Eckhart, Hildegard von Bingen, Mechtild of Magdeburg, Julian of Norwich, and
the Portuguese cult of the Holy Ghost, all make reference to the Motherhood of God.371 The Hebrew
tradition talks about the feminine Shekinah, the Indwelling of God. In Hinduism there are many
manifestations of the divine in feminine form. In the Sufi traditions she is called Lala (the night) and is
honored as the highest goal of the mystical quest.372

Author Jacques Bonvin notes: Only the Black Madonna was able to crystallize all the beliefs of Pagan
traditions within the Christian faith, without falsifying any of these beliefs. In this, the Black Madonna is
unique.373

Among the most prominent figures in Christendom to promote esoteric Christian teachings was Saint
Bernard (see insert).

Saint Bernard, Lover of the Black Madonna

Bernard of Clairvaux was a leading personality of the 12th century. He was born in Fontaines, near
Dijon, France, where the chapel had a Black Madonna. According to a 14th century legend, Bernard,
while still a young boy, was initiated into his vocation by three drops of the milk of the Black
Madonna. In esoteric tradition, three drops of virgin milk refer to the mysterious materia prima,
the raw material of the alchemists.
St. Bernard is credited with transforming the troubled Cistercian orderthen reduced to a handful
of monks in a single monastery at Citeaux, Franceinto a vast multinational enterprise of
civilization.374 This involved hundreds of monasteries from Russia to the Iberian Peninsula, every
one of which was dedicated to Our Lady.
The Cistercian order became deeply involved in esoteric research, with specialized scribes
translating Hebraic and Islamic alchemical texts, which Rome would certainly not have considered
as Catholic.375 St. Bernard himself wrote an astounding 200 sermons on Solomons Song of
Songs, the very poem that Jewish Kabbalists considered one of their most important texts. It begins,
I am black, but I am beautiful, O ye daughters of Jerusalem.376
St. Bernard also encouraged the pilgrimage to Santiago de Compostela in northern Spain, which is
replete with Cistercian and Templar sites.377 This pilgrimage was known as the path of the Black
Madonnas, as it connected the majority of the Black Madonna sanctuaries.
The founding charter for the famed Order of the Templars was authored by St. Bernard as well.
This charter, and all other official Templar documents, placed the name of Our Lady ahead of the
name of Christ, in stark contrast with contemporary Christian practice.
St. Bernard was not the only influential personality to have used the Black Madonna as his lifes
inspiration. St. Ignatius of Loyola, for example, gave his sword to the Black Madonna of Montserrat
when he founded the Jesuit order. Joan of Arc prayed to the Black Madonna, and her mother prayed
to the Black Madonna at Le Puy for her imprisoned daughter. Goethe used the Black Madonna as the
model for his eternal feminine in Faust.378

Political tension and occasional violence are not uncommon between the exoteric and esoteric
traditions within a particular religion. Such conflicts develop in part because esoteric knowledge tends to
extend beyond the confines of the traditional customs and doctrine of its own faith, embracing instead the
broader body of aligned teachings from other religions. The medieval boom of the Black Madonna and the
upsurge of rich, esoteric Christian traditions in Europe, coincided with the interrelated blossoming of the
Sufi traditions of Islam,379 the Kabbalah of Judaism,380 and a burgeoning interest in the practice of
alchemy.

Alchemy and the Blackness of the Madonna

What is the esoteric message of the Black Madonna and, in particular, her intentionally black color?

At the most literal level, the Black Madonna symbolizes Mother Earth, and, like the Earth, she is dark
in color. The child she holds in her arms represents humanityevery one of us. She refers back,
therefore, directly to the age-old worship of the Great Mother and to her nurturing relationship to
humanity.


At the more subtle level, the pitch-black color of the Black Madonna connects with alchemy. A
linguistic clue of that connection is revealed in the etymology of the word alchemy itself, which derives
from two Arabic words: Al, the general Arab particle; and Khemit, the Black Earth, the traditional
name for Egypt, the place where the alchemical art was reputed to have originated. The strikingly
abnormal color of the Black Madonna specified that She was not just representing Mother Earth, but the
black Earth of alchemy itself.381

Alchemy has become confused with its literal symbolism of transmuting the vilest metal (lead) into the
noblest one (gold). As is made clear in the warnings of alchemists of all ages, however, this is primarily a
philosophic or symbolic transmutation, a metaphor for a fundamental personal transformation. True
initiates of alchemy had only contempt for those who would mistakenly interpret alchemical textbooks
literally as some sort of technology to get rich materially. The true essence of alchemy as a guide for
personal evolution was encoded metaphorically. The riches that were sought after were not worldly
goods or gold, but rather the wealth of spiritual knowledge and wisdom.

The reason for disguising its transformative nature so elaborately was to protect the alchemist from
being labeled a heretic or worse, branded a sorcerer, an offense punishable by death at the stake. The
metallic transmutation was merely a ruse, a symbolic guise, a coded language. It was used by
practitioners, some of whom were well-known Benedictine monks, to protect that knowledge from being
misused by non-initiates.382 Such deception allowed true alchemists to continue their research and
extensive writings about that sulfurous topic, without inviting attention and disapproval from the Church.

Alchemy was, in fact, one of the main traditional Western esoteric paths for personal spiritual
evolution. Sir Isaac Newton attached more importance and wrote more pages about his research on
alchemy than on physics and optics combined. Another of alchemys many notable practitioners was Carl
Jung.383

Alchemy is a path towards spiritual evolution, through which ones consciousness transforms into
metaphysical gold, shining brightly like an inner sun. The mysterious materia primathe so-called lead
that gets transformed into goldis none other than the alchemist himself or herself. Jung referred to this
process as individuation, which comes as a result of the integration of the animus (the masculine
aspect, which is conscious in men and unconscious in women) with the anima (the feminine aspect, which
is unconscious in men and conscious in women).

The very first step in the alchemical process is known as the nigredo, literally the work in black,
described by Jung as the death of the ego, the dark night of the soul, or the garment of darkness.384
Medieval and renaissance scholars also referred to this process as melancholy (literally, black
humors). Saturnine melancholy was the difficult, unpleasant, but indispensable initial step required in
order to attain true inspiration and wholeness (see insert).385

Alchemy as a Symbolic Individuation Code386

Three key elements are involved in the alchemical process: sulfur, the yang or masculine principle,
associated symbolically with the sun, and fire; mercury, the yin or feminine principle, associated
with the moon, silver, and water; and salt, the symbol of the material body.


Alchemy aims at creating the legendary Philosophers Stone, (the integrated self, or Jungs
individuated human). This integration is realized by a mystical marriage of both the masculine and
the feminine dimension of the alchemist him or herself. As the alchemical handbook, Aurofontina
Chymica, states, This blackness doth manifest a Conjunction of the Male and Female.387

In his book Mammon and the Black Goddess, Robert Graves writes: The Black Goddess is so far
hardly more than a word of hopeShe promises a new pacific bond between man and womanShe will
lead man back to that sure instinct of love which he long ago forfeited by intellectual pride.388

MEDIEVAL ARCHETYPAL REPRESSION



A move toward ever-stronger authoritarian rule was established from the first half of the 13th century
onwards. Local autonomy was replaced by the centralization of power. This power shift preceded an
economic succession of events.

In 1265, a monopoly of yang royal coinage was instituted. The gradual elimination of local yin
currencies followed. The resulting monetary contraction was aggravated further by the debasement of
royal coinage by King Philip IV, around 1295. A powerful economic collapse then followed around 1300.

The downturn led to widespread epidemics and famines that continued to weaken the population for
several generations, and culminated in the outbreak of the deadly plague in 1347. The depression and
misery would persist for more than a century, until about 1470.

The power shift and economic events, though unquestionably destabilizing in their own right, should
nevertheless be understood as part of a more comprehensive breakdown that took hold. The archetypal
values that had been honored during the previous three centuries were systematically reversed. The
parting shot came by way of a brutal campaign unleashed by the increasingly powerful papal authority in
Rome.

The target of this papal campaign was the unorthodox Christians of southern France, collectively
referred to as the Albigensians (derived from Albigi, the ancient name of the southern French province of
Languedoc, where the sects were centered, and the region from which the literature of Courtly Love
originated). The Albigensian Crusade led to the first Inquisition by the Church (see insert).

The Cathars and the Albigensian Crusade

Conventional recounting tells of a specific Christian sect, the Cathars, whose heretical practices,
notably including gender equality, provoked Romes reaction during the 13th century. Recent findings
suggest a more complex account.
The Cathars were but one of many popular sects of the time, which included the Vaudois, Bguins,
Bogomils, and others. Particular teachings aside, these various sects harbored common concerns
regarding the mounting authoritarianism and materialism of Rome.
Until this period, the Pope was considered the Bishop of Rome; the first among bishops, but
ultimately only one of many important voices in the Christian community.389 Over the course of the
12th to 14th centuries, however, papal authority became enforced more and more in the context of
new doctrinal issues, such as clerical celibacy, the idea of purgatory, fixing the number of
sacraments, and other details of liturgy.390 This growing centralization of power within the Church,
combined with the increasingly lavish lifestyles of the upper clergy, provided the ferment against
Roman ascendancy.
Some of the Christian dissidents of the period came to be referred to as Cathars. This term was
first used in 1163 by the German monk, Eckbert of Schnau, as a derogatory play on two words: the
Greek katharos (the pure), and the more popular catier (sorcerers who adore cats, from the Latin
catus, cat).391 So-called Cathar sect members instead referred to themselves as les bonhommes
(the good people).
In 1209, Pope Innocent III ordered the Albigensian Crusade to counteract the rejection of Romes
authority. An agreement with the ruler of northern France, King Louis IX (later sanctified as Saint

Louis), recognized the Kings authority over the lands previously held by southern Languedoc
nobility.392 In turn, the King supported papal religous control.393 This alliance between the Pope and
King brought an end to the once brilliant Languedoc civilization.
One infamous episode that took place in the town of Bziers reveals the brutality of the
Albigensian Crusade. Only part of the towns population was considered to be heretical. But when
asked how soldiers could distinguish the Cathars from others, Arnaud Amaury, the official papal
emissary sent to oversee the attack, replied: Tuez les tous. Dieu reconnaitra les siens. (Kill
them all. God will recognize his own.)394
In spite of wholesale massacres, opposition to Roman authority persisted, prompting Pope
Gregory IX to institute the Dominican Order in 1231, assigning it the duty to carry out inquistions for
the apprehension and trial of heretics.

The Albigensian massacres and Inquisition were accompanied by a gradual erosion of womens rights,
both within the Church and throughout society. As Petra von Cronenburg explains:

The leadership role of women abbots in double monasteries was curtailed. Sacraments became
deliverable exclusively by male priestsWomen, who earlier were relatively free and could
become poets, medical doctors or heads of guilds, became gradually constrained to the role of object
of exchange in marriage, despised as demonic temptresses, and appreciated only for their capacity to
produce heirs.395

The Church condemned all Courtly Love literature, deeming it inspired by the devil. This triggered
strong resistance at first, even among the clergy. According to von Cronenburg:

When education for women was cut back, and when finally even nuns were restrained from teaching,
the movement of the Beguines took form, which refused to take religious vows so as to permit
them to continue educating women and girls. But in 1312, their properties were confiscated and their
rights curtailed, as the Inquisition moved against them as well.396

By the end of the 14th century, the once flourishing expression of feminine values in much of Western
Europe during the Central Middle Ages was practically eradicated.

The ensuing power shift is examined below from several viewpoints.

An Archetypal Ending

An archetypal perspective interprets the events that led to the demise of this age as part of an underlying
shift in consciousness, from a period of more or less balanced masculine and feminine values to that of
patriarchy. This included the formation of imperialist monarchies and the strong repression of the Great
Mother archetype and feminine roles in general.

The concept of an unquestionable heirarchical authority, embodied by a king or emperor, was directly
reinforced on the religious front by centralized papal authority and monotheism. This is exemplified by
the drawing below, in which the King of Sicily is crowned by the archetypal king, Christ himself.


A strictly monetary perspective does not mention, much less attempt to understand, other significant
changes that occurred at the time of this economic collapse. It does, for instance, take into account the
stunning reversal of womens roles in the workplace, and their renewed subjugation in society.

An archetypal perspective, in contrast, not only includes an explanation of the monetary changes that
occurred, but also provides a more encompassing context by which to understand other shifts and
reversals that accompanied the economic breakdown. Appreciation of the Great Mother archetype and her
repression offers us a framework to account for the simultaneous backlash against women, the end of
Courtly Love literature, the official de-emphasis of the Black Madonna movement (replaced from the 14th
century onwards by conventional white Madonnas), the Albigensian Crusade, and the centralization of
royal and papal power. This archetypal perspective also accounts for the subsequent predominance of
other traits associated with the dominant yang coherence.


The patriarchal backlash would only intensify over the next six centuries. The Inquisition by the Church
(which endured until 1784), sanctioned many forms of torture and, as previously mentioned, executed an
estimated six million women. Many of these women were burned to death as witches.

Paralleling the persecutions and killings, the possibilities of gainful work by women rapidly shrank to
the point that, by 1776, the French legislator Turgot would complain that women were being excluded
from virtually all commercial activities, Even those that are most appropriate for their sex, such as
embroidery.397 Until the middle of the 20th century, most women in the West could not even open their
own bank account without marital consent, a situation that Eleanor of Aquitaine would have likely found
absurd. The widely available local currencies were simply abandoned, and a monopoly of scarce, yangtype, conventional currencies was permanently established, further reinforcing the yang shadow
coherence, patriarchy, and women's dependency.

Zeitgeist of the Central Middle Ages



The monetary perspective offered earlier in this work, though important, does not take into consideration
the many changes that occured during the Central Middles Ages.

At the same time, it is also necessary to keep in mind that we do not claim that the archetypal
perspective is the product of a linear causality between feminine values, Black Madonna worship, and
complementary yin-yang currency systems. Rather, we see a mutual causality, a nonlinear coherence
among these phenomena, occurring as a probability wave: all these variables emerged at the same time
and then collapsed together as well. The Germans call this a Zeitgeist, a spirit of the times, when a
particular set of cultural values and traits arise simultaneously. The zeitgeist of the Central Middle Ages
included honoring the feminine, the appearance of complementary demurrage-charged yin currencies, and
a remarkable prosperity that benefited all people and which lasted for more than two centuries.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

The uniqueness of the Central Middle Ages and the circumstances related to the demise of this golden age
cannot be sufficiently explained soley by the monetary perspective offered earlier in this work. The
complementary currencies very likely contributed to the high standard of conditions of this epoch; their
elimination also helps shed light on the dramatic reversal that occurred in the late 1200s and 1300s. But
the monetary framework does not by itself adequately explain the coherence that was operational in
Western Europe at that time. Yin-yang currency systems were part of a constellation of phenomena that
took hold that also included reintegration of Great Mother archetypal energies, feminine values, Courtly
Love literature, Black Madonna worship and the like. The rise of each of these elements offers a more
thorough understanding of the zeitgeist of this age, which culminated in a remarkable prosperity that
benefited all levels of society, long-term thinking, community projects, and the advancements of women
during this period. In similar fashion, archetypal repression helps explain the simultaneous elimination of
the complemementary currencies, the reversals for women, rising authoritarianism, the Inquisition, and
other phenomena that occurred during the waning years of this golden epoch.

CHAPTER TWENTY SIX - Dynastic Egypt



The past has revealed to me the structure of the future.

~PIERRE TEILHARD DE CHARDIN

Another exceptional epoch marked by notable prosperity, long-term thinking, and other features found in
the Central Middle Ages occurred much earlier in history in Dynastic Egypt. One element that was
common to each society, and which helped to define them, was the existence of a dual-currency monetary
system. A major distinction with respect to its latter medieval counterpart is that Egypts golden age
lasted markedly longer, extending from as far back as the 2nd Millenium BCE to as late as 30 BCE (see
insert).

Egyptian Millennia398

Ancient Egypts civilization extends from at least the Old Kingdom (2575 BCE) to the Roman period
(30 BCE). To give some sense of the time expanse under consideration, consider that when
Alexander the Great conquered Egypt n 332 BCE, this civilization had already been in existance for
as long as Alexander is ancient to us. The timeframes given below are categorized according to
governance.
Late Predynastic Period (31002950 BCE)begins with the unification of Upper and Lower
Egypt. Earliest known hieroglyphic writings date to this period.
Dynastic Egypt (2950332 BCE)so named to denote the 31 hereditary lines (dynasties) of
Egyptian-born rulers. This vast epoch is subdivided into Early Dynastic Period (29502575 BCE),
Old Kingdom (25752150 BCE), Middle Kingdom (19751640 BCE), New Kingdom (15391075
BCE), the Late Period (715332 BCE), and three intermediate periods. The first pyramids are
believed to have appeared during the Early Dynastic Period.
Macedonian/Ptolemaic Period (33230 BCE)begins with Alexander the Greats arrival from
Macedonia. He and his descendants (which included Ptolemy I-XII) ruled over Egypt for the next
three centuries. This period ends in dramatic fashion with the famed suicide of Cleopatra VII
(herself a direct descendant of Alexander).
Roman Period (30 BCE395 CE)begins with the defeat of Antony and Cleopatra by Octavian,
which culminatied in Roman control over Egypt (30 BCE). Roman rule brought an end to the
Egyptian dual-currency system. In 395 CE, Egypt became part of the Byzantine Empire.

THE EGYPTIAN ECONOMY



As in the case of medieval Europe, no systematic statistical analyses were performed during these ancient
times. The economic landscape can, however, be inferred from a number of indirect indicators, such as
diets, working conditions, education, and archeological findings.

Food. Egypt has long and universally been considered the breadbasket of the ancient world. No less
than 15 different words were commonly used during the Old Kingdom to distinguish different types of
bread, which speak to a prosperous society. More than 40 words existed at the time of the New Kingdom
for bread and cakes.399 The advice offered by a scribe to his disciples suggests an affluent and fairminded society: Do not eat bread while another stands by, without offering your portion to him. Food is
always there. It is man who does not last.400

Besides bread, cheese, onions, melons, beans, and many vegetables, there was also a plentiful supply
of meat and fish. Diodorus Siculus, the famed Greek historian, reports, The Nile contains every variety
of fish and in numbers beyond belief; for it supplies all the natives not only with abundant subsistence
from the fish freshly caught, but it also yields an unfailing multitude of fish for salting.401

Egypts fertility in grain was the highest in the ancient world; average yield estimates ran as high as ten
times the norm. One sign that something special was taking place in food production was the fact that
Dynastic Egypt initiated the first historically-documented foreign aid program. Written records denote that
Egypt gave grains free of charge to the Athenian citizens when they suffered a famine in 445 BCE.402 The
bountiful food supply was matched by this societys taste and selection of beverages.

Drink. Both beer and wine were abundant and commonly consumed at all levels of society. The GreekEgyptian Athenaeus, one of the earliest-known wine critics, described Egyptian wines with a
sophistication that would rival todays connoisseurs:

Wine of the Mareotic region is excellent, white, pleasant, fragrant, easily assimilated, thin, not likely
to go to the head, and diuretic. The Taeniotic wine is better than the Mareotic, somewhat paler; it has
an oily quality, pleasant, aromatic, mildly astringent. And the wine of the Antylla province surpasses
all others.403

The substantial quantity of consumption led a Middle Kingdom Wisdom Text to advise to lend a hand to
an elder who drank too much beer, and to respect him as his children should.

Education. Formal instruction was not uncommon, particularly from the Middle Kingdom onwards.
Official day schools, known as Houses of Instruction, were established in association with the royal
residences and many temples. Quite simply, anyone who was anyone in Dynastic Egypt could read and
write.404 Not everybody knew the hieroglyphic form of writing, reserved as it was for sacred texts or
inscriptions on public monuments. Laundry lists, however, as well as dressmaking advice and other
household trivia indicate that even ordinary housekeepers and servants were able to read and write in the
common demotic script.

Workdays. Workdays were eight hours long and there were many holidays. According to records of the
time, only 18 of 50 consecutive days were working days for the entire labor crew.405

Archeological Confirmation. In addition to written accounts, there is mounting archeological evidence


of the generally high standards of conditions of the age. According to Mark Lehner, lead archaeologist of
the University of Chicago/Harvard University Giza Plateau Mapping Project:

Bones in the area [Giza] suggest that workers enjoyed quite a lot of prime beef. Previous
excavations have discovered that they also ate bread and fish, and drank beer. Analysis of human
remains suggests that workers apparently had access to medical treatment. Evidence has been found
of healed broken bones, amputated limbs, and even brain surgeries.406

For the sake of accuracy, it should be pointed out that though the majority of findings lend support to the
overall affluence of Egyptian society, archeological evidence is not uniformly consistent. One exception
is noted in the study of the skeletal remains in the Tell el-Amarna area (see insert).

The Exception of Tell el-Amarna

Tell el-Amarna was briefly the capital of ancient Egypt during the short reign of the pharaoh
Akhenaten 13791362 BCE. Recent excavations at this site show that, Anemia ran at 74 percent
among children and teenagers, and at 44 percent among adults. The average height of men was 159
cm [5 feet 2 inches] and 153 cm [just over 5 feet] among women. According to researcher Jerome
Rose, professor of anthropology at the University of Arkansas, Adult heights are used as a proxy for
overall standard of living. Short statures reflect a diet deficient in protein. People were not growing
to their full potential.407
The discrepancy between the archeological findings at Tell el-Amarna and others is partially
explained by some of the specifics of this period and site. The reigning pharaoh Akhenaten was
considered an unpopular heretic, and the conditions related to his experimental new city built in the
middle of the dessert does not reflect conditions in and around the Nile basin or the overall
economic reality of the millennia in question.408 In short, Tell el-Amarna can be considered an
exception to the general rule of Egyptian economic wellbeing, due to unusual times and place.

What then was the source of this ancient civilizations success?

Though the fertile black soil of Egypt was indeed exceptional, this gift of the Nile accounts for only
part of this societys abundance. Productive assets, such as their irrigation systems, which were
maintained at a quality envied by the rest of the ancient world, obviously contributed as well, as did their
apparent industriousness and the unique economic incentives that were then operational in Egypt. But
these and other elements, though distinctive and important, were themselves likely the by-product of yet
another ancient Egyptian peculiaritytheir monetary system.

THE EGYPTIAN DUAL-CURRENCY SYSTEM



Two currencies operated in parallel in ancient Egypt.

Long-distance currencies, in the form of standardized gold rings and silver bars, were used in
international exchanges with nations such as Mesopotamia and Nubia. These currencies were used for the
purchase of important items such as real estate, luxury items, and marriage contracts. They functioned as
both a medium of exchange and as a store of value.

Another type of currency was widely in use as well. It was demurrage-charged and linked to the
storage of food.

Egyptian Demurrage and Food Storage



The Egyptian demurrage-charged local currencies, like their medieval counterparts, appeared to function
purely as a medium of exchange for daily trade among Egyptians. A key difference was that the demurrage
fee in Egypt was based on the actual cost of the storage of food.409 Food storage was by no means a
unique feature of Egyptian society. Storing for a bad season and next years seedlings was an essential
practice common to all agricultural societies dating back to the beginning of the agricultural revolution
(10,000 BCE), and still in use to this day. The Egyptians, however, also used food storage as the basis for
a monetary system. This food-based monetary system provided great benefits not just to the privileged
classes but to all Egyptians, thus setting this society apart from others of its time.

The food-storage currency likely worked as follows:

Imagine yourself as an ancient Egyptian farmer who, after the harvest, has a surplus of ten bags of
wheat. You bring these bags to your local storage site and the scribe gives you a receipt specifying,
Received ten bags of wheat, followed by the officials name and the date of this transaction. Depending
on the period and locale, these wheat receipts were written on either papyri, a thick paper-like material,
or, we contend, on an ostrakon (plural: ostraka), a broken piece of pottery shard, millions of which have
been found throughout Egypt.410

The key to the wheat-currency system becomes clear when you return, perhaps a year later, to cash in
your ten-bag ostrakon. The scribe looks at your pottery-shard receipt and orders only nine bags returned
to you. The conversation might go as follows:

I brought you ten bags; why do you return to me only nine now?

Somewhat irritated, the scribe replies, Dont you see that was a year ago?

So?

Do you see that guard standing in front of the storage building? He eats, you know! So do I, for
that matter. Notwithstanding all our precautions, we also lose some wheat to rats and mice.

Yes, but what has that to do with my tenth bag?

This tenth bag is a demurrage charge equivalent to the cost of storing the wheat for one year. The
redemption value of these Egyptian ostraka receipts would age. For instance, had you returned six
months instead of one year later to recover your bags, you would have received 9.5 bags in return (a 0.5
bag demurrage charge, or one half of an annual demurrage fee for storage). In essence, the longer the food
was held in storage, the greater the cost that was incurred, similar to the fees of a parking meter. For this
reason, people would tend not to hoard such currencies, but would use them instead as a pure medium of
exchange; in as timely a manner as was practical and possible.

These wheat receipts served as a local currency, circulating in parallel with the long-distance money of
silver bars and gold rings.

Egyptian versus Medieval Demurrage



Though far more ancient, the Egyptian demurrage system was patently more sophisticated than its
medieval counterpart. This approach was not only fine-tuned to the month and even the day, but was also
tied to the real world of spoilage and costs of storage. The analogous medieval Renovatio Monetae
was instead a stop-and-go process performed every five or six years, or after the death of a lord.

The arbitrariness of both the frequency and level of taxation in the medieval demurrage resulted in
abuses. For instance, Duke Johann II of Saxony had his money reminted 86 times during his 18-year reign
(from 1350 to 1368). One ruler in Poland changed his coins systematically four times per year. Such
misuse ended up discrediting the entire practice.

The Egyptians seemed quite content with a monetary system that permitted even the most modest
farmers production to become money at the farmers choice. Often teased by the Greeks for their
mundane-looking local money, Egyptians in turn considered the Greek passion for gold and silver coins a
rather odd obsession, and viewed such precious-metal coins as a piece of local vanity, patriotism or
advertisement with no far-reaching importance.411 The Egyptians accepted foreign coins only for their
bullion contentas a simple raw materialas confirmed by Greek coins found in Egypt that had been cut
open just to verify their metal content.

The particulars of how or when this food-storage, demurrage-charged money was first implemented are
unknown. What is known is that during the Ptolemaic period (33230 BCE), the Egyptians considered the
demurrage-charged currency as the old money.


One intriguing hypothesis regarding this currencys origin is offered in the Bible (see insert).

Joseph and Demurrage

The biblical story of Joseph (ca. 1900-1600 BCE) may offer a clue to the origins of the demurrage
currency in Egypt. It is not, however, only what is written in the bible but also what is left
unexplained that is of interest.
Betrayed by his jealous brothers, Joseph was sold to the Ishmaelites for twenty pieces of silver,
and they brought him to Egypt, (Genesis 37:28). Once there, Joseph managed to interpret the
Pharaohs premonitory dream of seven fat and seven lean cows. Joseph recommended that food
reserves be stored during the seven fat years, to make them available for lean times. The Bible

claims that the pharaoh and others were so impressed with this solution that Joseph was named
General Superintendent, the second most powerful position in all of Egypt.
We know, however, that food storage was a typical component of ancient economies and dream
interpretation seems a flimsy reason for Josephs dramatic rise in power. Another explanation is
tempting.
Would it not be possible that Joseph may have helped either promote or invent a demurrage
currency system backed by food storage and was, thus, credited with saving the Egyptian economy?


These ostraka appear to have served as common currency for ordinary daily exchanges for at least
sixteen centuries and perhaps much longer still. The demurrage charge was built into all transactions
using the wheat standard and standards based on other similar storable food items (such as grains,
barley, and wine) as currencies. This monetary system may help explain some of the as yet unanswered
mysteries regarding the economic strength of Dynastic Egypt, unique in its time.

The Case for Ostraka



It must be stated here that though millions of ostraka wheat receipts have in fact been found in various
places in Egypt dating to the time periods in question, the generalized use of these pottery shards as fullyfledged demurrage-charged monetary system has yet to be directly confirmed.

The main study on demurrage currencies was conducted in 1910 by the German Greek-classics scholar,
Friedrich Preisigke, who focused exclusively on the Ptolemaic period from 332 BCE onwards.412 His
research was also limited to those paper-like currencies in the form of papyri found in the Imperial
Collection of Greek-language papyri from Egypt.

Almost completely ignored in this research, however, was the abundant and more ancient ostraka.413
No less than 1.6 million ostraka were found in one single dynastic village (at Medinet), a relatively wellpreserved and ancient region in the Egyptian desert.414

Preisigke himself certainly does not make the claim that the food-receipt system was invented or was
new during the period he describes. There were some additional banking functions added during the
Ptolemaic period, but receipts for food deposits with temples are abundant much earlier. Nor does he
state that money was used only in the form of papyri. Preisigke instead implicitly inferred that the papyri
and ostraka played the same function. He points out for example that he found papyri used in some areas
of the Delta, but in Memphis ostraka were used.415

Preisigke also makes astute points regarding the use of wheat in Egyptian accounting mechanisms:

There seems even to exist a clearing system between long-distance deposits through a state- run
accounting system. One could therefore receive a cheque drawn in wheat that was deposited in one
place, and withdraw that amount in another place, for a fee. Netting between transactions seem to
have taken place (if one needed 100 units of wheat transported from A to B; and 90 units from B to
A; they would only have to transport 10 units from A to B).416

Another observation made by Preisigke, that taxes were payable in ostraka, lends itself to the argument
that food receipts were commonly used as money. Preisigke observed that, Particularly in villages, some
taxes were payable in nature. A landlord would request to have the renter of a farm pay for him the taxes
in wheat owed by the landlord to that location, and that amount would be deducted from the renters
dues.417

Because of the limited time focus of Preisigkes work, some may conclude incorrectly that demurrage
currencies first appeared during the Ptolemaic period. It must be emphasized here that no study other than
Presigkes has ever been undertaken regarding such unconventional currencies. To our knowledge there
has not been much interest in yin-type currencies, be it of ancient Egypt or of the Central Middle Ages.
The zeitgeist of academia during the 19th and much of the 20th centuries simply did not lend themselves to
such investigations.

Though direct, irrefutable evidence in support of our monetary claims is still lacking, there is, however
a strong convergence of many indirect circumstantial claims that we believe support our claims that the
ostraka may be considered to be like modern day paper with many different uses, from informal notes to
formal contracts and the like. We claim that this would include their use as common money, similar to the

use of modern-day checks or paper money. What is an established fact is that countless numbers of ostraka
have been found all over Egypt with information indicating that they were receipts for storable food,
specifying the amount in weight of the commodity exchanged and its dates.

Again, further study on the yin-currencies of dynastic Egypt along with many other ancient societes is
certainly warranted.

A GRECO-ROMAN ENDING

That the monetary system may have been linked to the prosperity of Dynastic Egypt is also suggested by
the fact that the end of the good millennia in Egypt coincided with the demise of the dual-currency system
by the conquering Romans. The net results of the replacement of the demurrage-charged ostraka by a
monopoly of modern Roman currency with positive interest rateswith the interest tending to accrue to
Romewere significant and enduring. The Egyptian economy, which had enjoyed a distinctive prosperity
for well over 2000 years and was once the envy of the ancient world, eroded after only a few generations
under the new monetary regime. Egypt ended up degenerating to the status of a developing country, a
condition it retains to this very day.

General opinion, dating back to the Greek historian Plutarch in the first century CE, claims that ancient
Egypts abundance was merely a gift of the Nile. But an economy that functioned quite successfully for
millennia came to an end at the same time as the demise of the dual-currency system. The Nile, everpresent and ever-flowing, was there when the economy flourished and remained there after the economy
declined. We submit the hypothesis that at least some of the credit for the proverbial breadbasket of the
ancient world should be attributed to those funny-looking, demurrage-charged ostraka.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

The converging evidence from Dynastic Egypt offers testimony that using a dual-currency system
provided solutions and new possibilities that otherwise could not have existed. The Central Middle Ages
and Dynastic Egypt were two civilizations that enjoyed economies that were exceptionally prosperous
and stable, encouraging a more active participation of all social classes.

CHAPTER TWENTY SEVEN - Dynastic Egypt Revisited



The basic discovery about any people is the discovery

of the relationship between its men and its women.

~PEARL S. BUCK

Archetypes do not belong to any one culture or period of history; they are fundamental psychological
patters that belong to humanity, and transcend race, nationality, society, and time itself. What does
significantly differentiate one individual, community, culture, civilization, and epoch from another is the
degree to which archetypes are integrated or repressed and the type of money that is operational.

We repeat our claim that archetypal repression is inexorably linked to todays major issues and that the
lack of integration of the Great Mother archetype in particular has profoundly influenced our monetary
paradigm and its spread of skewed patriarchal values. With our own present-day interests in mind, we
continue our reexamination of another past society that used a dual-currency system and that honored
feminine as well as masculine values.

DYNASTIC EGYPTIAN ARCHETYPAL INTEGRATION



As previously noted, among the many important similarities between the Central Middle Ages and
Dynastic Egypt are: dual-currency systems, prosperous economies, and long-term thinking. Additionally, a
similar archetypal coherence was in play. In Dynastic Egypt, veneration of the Great Mother archetype
took the symbolic form of Isis.

The Isis Cult



Most of todays commonly held beliefs about Dynastic Egypt emanate from Western research dating back
to the 19th century and first half of the 20th century. Egyptologists of the period, likely influenced by their
own cultural biases, held that Egyptian culture was inherently patriarchal, with an all-powerful male
pharaoh at the top. More recent findings, however, paint a very different picture, with religious,
legislative, and social traditions that were clearly and predominantly matrifocal. At the center of this
tradition was the great Isis, the supreme goddess in Egypt, the almighty Great Mother, worshipped
uninterruptedly for more than three millennia, from well before 3200 BCE to at least 200 CE.

The relationship between Isis and temporal power is illustrated by the many representations of a
pharaoh suckling the breast of Isis to receive the divine nourishment of wisdom from her, thus giving the
pharaoh his right to rule. She was also the Seat of Wisdom, identified by her hieroglyph in the form of a
high-backed throne that rested on her head. This cathedra chair was her key distinguishing feature.418
The throne maketh the king, as many texts have said since the first dynasty.419 The lap of the Goddess
Isis became the royal throne of Egypt.

Isis was also the indispensable bridge between the land of the living and the realm of the departed.
Mythology holds her as the originator of the important ritual of mummification, and all the magical rituals
necessary for the transition to the hereafter.

The apparent Egyptian fixation with death centered on the belief that though mortality was inevitable, it
was not necessarily the end. By taking all the correct precautions it was possible to enjoy an afterlife in
the Field of Reeds, a land of pleasure and plenty.420 The elaborate mummifications and burial
arrangements were considered pragmatic undertakings necessary to ensure the continuation of the good
life, even after death. The Egyptians believed they could take their material possessions with them to the
afterlife, which is why they were buried with their most precious belongings.

Initially reserved for the pharaohs and their family members, such arrangements became accessible to
any men and women who could afford them, starting from the Middle Empire onwards. These customs
revealed an acceptance of death and preparation for it as a fact of life, an outlook quite consistent with
Great Mother cultures, which encompassed her key attributes of sex, death, and money.

The Isis myth provides abundant clues of the Egyptian reverence for the Great Mother archetype. In
contrast with Greek and other Indo-European mythologies, the feminine principle was not only honored,
but also systematically empowered. Osiris, the male God of the Afterlife and the God of the Nile
(including floodwaters and vegetation), is, comparatively speaking, almost a sidekick. He is the hapless
one whom Isis rescues time and again out of love (see insert).

Isis: the Feminine Savior

Isis was the first daughter of Nut, the overarching night sky who bore all the gods, and the little
Earth-God, Geb. Her Egyptian name was Au Set (Exalted Queen), which was later modified during
the Ptolemaic Period to the now familiar Isis by the colonizing Greeks.
According to popular legend, Isis lived with her brother and lover, Osiris, God of the Nile. Their
brother Seth, jealous and evil, killed Osiris, dismembering him into 13 parts. Thus began the long
saga whereby Isis recovered Osiris body parts, one by one, marking each location where a part was

found with a temple and sacred city. All parts were found but one, his sexual organ, which Isis
replaced with a golden phallus. She then invented the art of embalming and returned Osiris to life,
after performing a magical ritual on his body. Impregnated by his golden phallus, Isis bore a child,
Horus, the Golden Sun God.
In stark contrast to contemporary and subsequent patriarchal religions, it is the feminine principle
that embraces the heavenly, solar, male god. As Jungian psychologist Erich Neumann explains, The
daytime sky is the realm where the sun is born and dies, not, as later, the realm over which it
rules.421
Initially the Goddess of the Hearth and Home, Isis became universal in her powers. She became
known as the Lady of the Innumerable Names (myrionymos) and as Isis the All-Goddess, (Isis
Panthea).422 I am the Mother of All that is, Mistress of all elements, origin of all time, first among
all gods and goddessesI govern everything.423 She was the Queen of Heaven, the Mother of the
Sun, the Maker of Sunrise and Maker of Kings. She was the mourning wife, tender sister, and the
originator of all the arts and of all that makes life civilized, comfortable, and worthwhile. She was
the Lady of Joy and Abundance, Sochit (the grain field), and Hathor (the generous source of food),
giving humans their daily bread. As Destiny, she overcame Fate and caused righteousness to
prevail. As Isis Medica, she was the healer of all ills. Finally, She was in the fullest sense
Love.424 Isis was indeed Almighty.
From the beginning, Isis turned a kind eye to humans, teaching women to grind corn, spin flax,
weave cloth, and to calm men enough to live with them. Each living being was considered to be a
drop of her blood; and feminine values were as important as masculine values as revealed in the
conditions of women.

The Status of Women in Egyptian Society



Egyptology confirms that women were remarkably privileged in Egyptian society, especially when
compared to the relative conditions of women from other cultures of the time and down through history.

Legal Status

Historian Max Mueller claims that, No people ancient or modern has given women so high a legal
status as did the inhabitants of the Nile Valley.425 The legal status of Dynastic Egyptian women not only
surpassed other societies of the period, but compares favorably to the status in many nations today.

Egyptologist Janet H. Johnson writes:

From our earliest preserved records (Old Kingdom) the formal legal status of women (no matter if
they were unmarried, married, divorced, or widowed) was identical to that of Egyptian men.
Egyptian women, like Egyptian men, were legally responsible for their own actions and personally
accountable to both civil and criminal law. They were able to acquire, own and dispose of both real
estate and other personal property. They could enter into contracts in their own names; they could
initiate court cases and likewise be sued; they could serve as witnesses in court cases, they could sit
on juries; and they could witness legal documentsWomen had legal rights and were willing to fight
for them.426

Marriage

Marriage contracts dealt predominantly with financial matters and were, extremely advantageous to the
wifeEither party could divorce the other on any grounds, but the economic consequences of the annuity
contract made this a serious step for the husband.427 In the event of divorce, women also tended to have
custody rights of children. This was in stark contrast with, patriarchal Rome, where a pregnant widow
was obliged by law to offer her newborn baby to her dead husbands family; only if they had no use for
the child was she given the chance to raise her baby herself.428

Egyptian women could also choose who they wanted to marry independently of social classeven
slaves or foreigners. This too differed significant from the customary practices of other societies of the
time. During their rule over Egypt, the Romans would introduce complex inheritance regulations to
pressure Egyptians to marry only within their own social class.429

As in many of the comparatively favorable conditions enjoyed by Egyptian women, Isis played a
pivotal role, in this case, as the upholder of the marriage covenant. During a wedding, it was in Isis
name that the husband made a solemn contract to be obedient to his wife.430

Womens Work

Regarding careers and work, women were excluded from a number of positions, for example, city mayors
and royal scribes, and from certain crafts, such as sculptors, carpenters, and public gardeners.431 Then
again, men were similarly excluded from certain activities. For instance, women were the key producers
in the two principal industries in Egypt: food and textiles.432

The foremost industrial craft in Egypt was the manufacture of linen textiles. It was critical for both the
living and the deada single mummification could require as much as 1,000 square yards of linen
cloth.433 As in the medieval period, women participated in all aspects of linen manufacturing: harvesting
the flax, hackling, roving, spinning the fibers into threads, and the weaving process. Weaving frequently
included mass-production factories with many workers supervised by an overseer, who was usually a
woman. Women also reportedly accepted payment for finished cloth and bore the title Overseer of the
House of Weavers. It was only in the later part of the New Kingdom that some men were allowed to
enter the weaving industry.434

Many women held high positions in public administration and courtly functions. This included female
stewards for kings, queens, and princesses, seal bearers (treasurers), and chiefs of funerary priesthood.
This is well documented in the Old Kingdom.


Women Rulers

While women appeared equal or may even have been favored in some legal and private matters, the most
powerful position of allthe pharaohwas almost always, but not exclusively, held by men. Not
infrequently there existed female regents, i.e., a pharaohs who mother ruled on her sons behalf until he
matured. More significant still, between 3000 and 1000 BCE, four women officially assumed the
throne.435 It was during the regency of Ny-netjer of the Second Dynasty (27702649 BCE) that, It was
decided that women might hold the kingly office.436

While rarely actualized, the mere fact that there was no ideological or theological barrier for women to
rule in Egypt was a remarkable situation and indication of the ancient Egyptian mindset. Even today, many

nations, including such world-leading countries as the United States, China, Russia, France, and Japan,
have yet to elect a female president or prime minister.

Women and Poetry

Another parallel with the Central Middle Ages was the unusual appearance of love poetry in Egypt,
comparable in some respects to Courtly Love literature. In fact, Egyptians were the people known to
write love poetry.437 Much to the amazement of contemporary Greeks, Egyptian women often took the
initiative in courtship, addressing the man or proposing marriage in love poems and letters.438

Seen from a modern perspective, and in light of recent advancements in womens rights, Egypt was still
primarily a mans world. The unique status of women in Dynastic Egypt is more readily understood,
however, by comparison with conditions in other civilizations of that period (see insert).

Womens Status in Other Ancient Civilizations

A basis of comparison for womens status is offered by two civilizations with which Egypt had
extensive commercial and cultural contact: Mesopotamia and Greece. A small sampling of their
characteristic laws and customs are synthesized here.
Mesopotamias Hammurabic law (ca. 1750 BCE) considered it normal practice for a man unable
to repay his debts to give away his wife or children as slaves in compensation. The father, without
the involvement of either the mother or daughter herself, customarily arranged all marriages.439 In the
ancient Middle East it was customary that, Adultery is possible only on the side of the wife,
because she is the property of the husband.440
Historian and author Gerda Lerner writes:
Divorce was easily obtained for men, who merely had to make a public declaration of intent. It was
difficult for a wife to obtain a divorce and only those without blemish might attempt it because the
law states that: If [the woman] has not kept herself chaste but is given to going about out [of the
house], and so belittle her husband, they shall cast that woman into the water.441
Athens and other Greek city-states did not recognize a womans independent existence. Women
had no political rights and did not participate in any decision-making. Fathers or male relatives
arranged a womans marriage. Women could not own or inherit any property, nor enter into any
transaction involving more than the value of one bushel of grain.442
Greek women were also excluded from public life. Women were kept in seclusion in the
gyneceum, an isolated area in the back of the house, where no man could enter except close
relatives. Greek historian Xenophon (428354 BCE) proposed that, It is better for a woman to stay
inside the house, and not show herself at the door.443 The Greek playwright Menander (342292
BCE) wrote that, A decent woman must stay at home; the streets are for low women. The only
women accepted in public or permitted to be educated into literacy and the finer social arts, were
hetaira (prostitutes).444

Egyptologist Joyce Tyldesley states:

Egypt was undoubtedly the best place to have been born a woman in the whole of the Ancient World.
During the dynastic period, as the Greek historian Herodotus observed, Egyptian women enjoyed a
legal, social and sexual independence unrivaled by their Greek or Roman sistersThey could own
and trade property, work outside the home, marry foreigners and even live alone without the

protection of a male guardian.445



It is again Isis who is officially credited with having made, the power of women equal to that of
men.446

EGYPTIAN ARCHETYPAL REPRESSION



The medieval and dynastic golden ages both ended when a centralizing power took over. In Europe it took
the form of kings ruling by divine right. In Egypt instead, it occurred with the loss of sovereignty to
ancient Rome. But unlike the abrupt medieval demise, the Egyptian end came gradually, with cultural
erosion by foreign patriarchal influences, namely, Mesopotamian, Hittite, Persian, Hyksos, Greek, then
Roman followed by Christianization.

As in Europe, Egypts decline also coincided with replacement of its yin currency by a yang monetary
system, imposed by Rome. This monetary change was accompanied by an accelerated concentration of
wealth, typical of the Roman Empire. In Kerkereosiris, a Fayum village representative of the Roman
period, an estimated population of 1,500 families farmed some 3,000 acres, which averaged out to a mere
two acres per family. In stark contrast, one privileged family, the Apions, who had twice achieved the
position of praetorian prefect in public administration during the 6th century CE, controlled a whopping
75,000-acre estate.447

In Egypt as in medieval Europe, the constellation of yang shadows became increasingly dominant: a
monopoly of yang-type currencies prevailed, patriarchy was affirmed, and the repression of the Great
Mother archetype ensued. This repression increasingly activated the collective emotions of greed and fear
of scarcity, which became embedded in the culture through the monetary system.

Commonalities

Honoring the Great Mother archetype, demurrage-charged currencies, and abundance for the masses can
be all understood as imprints of the same archetypal coherence. The golden periods both in Egypt and
medieval Western Europe coincided with honoring both yin and yang values. The end of each period
coincided with renewed archetypal repression of the Great Mother.

Again, we do not claim a magical, direct causal effect between Great Mother veneration and the
choice of monetary systems. In both these periods when the Great Mother was honored, however, a yin
demurrage-charged currency was also adopted, which very likely contributed to the unusual abundance
and exceptional economic conditions of each civilization.

These two societies also had in common an archetypal coherence that differed markedly from the rest
of the world. And not only did each culture honor the Great Mother, but in many respects, the medieval
Black Madonna was none other than Isis herselfher titles and emblematic chair were merely
transferred. More surprising still, some of the Black Madonnas venerated in France were actually original
Egyptian statues of Isis (see insert).

The Black MadonnaEgyptian Connection

There are numerous connections between the medieval Black Madonna and the Egyptian Isis. Both
icons are seated in the same straight chairthe Cathedrathe symbol of her power and, not
coincidentally, the origin of the word cathedral. Other connections include the oriental
anecdotes in many Black Madonna legends, the esoteric Egyptian alchemical link, and the
identical and particular kinds of miracles performed in their legends. A few of the many other
associations are listed below.
Several Black Madonna statuesnamely, the Black Virgin of Boulogne in France and at the
Sablon in Brussels, Belgiumare reported to have arrived by river, standing on a boat with no sails
or crew, with a copy of the Gospels in an oriental script.448 This is an exact transposition of the
ritual along the Nile by which Isis arrived by boat in her sacred cities. Isis was traditionally invoked
as Star of the Sea, Seat of Wisdom, and Queen of Heaven, three titles by which St. Bernard
referred specifically to the Black Madonna a millennium later.
The literal and symbolic blackness of the Black Madonna also has deep associations with Isis.
Plutarch describes the famed Veil of Isis as black. Members of Isis main priestly groups were
known as the wearers of black because they specialized in mourning her.449 Isis brother and lover,
Osiris, was also called the Black One. The spells invoking Isis began with, Thy kingdom resides
in that which is utterly black.450
The famed pilgrimage to Santiago de Compostela derived its name from compostus stellae
(literally compost of stars in Latin). This pilgrimage was associated with the Black Madonna
sanctuaries. It was also called the Path of the Milky Way, a direct reference to Isis in her Hathor
form, and a name by which our own galaxy is known. Some of the Black Madonna statues were
popularly referred to as les Egyptiennes.451 Examples include the Black Madonna of Chartres in
Northern France, and in Southern France, the Black Madonna of that of Meymac, which dates back to
the 12th century.
In a number of cases, the connections are even more explicit. Several medieval statues revered as
the Black Madonna were actually antique statues of Isis that had been directly imported from Egypt.

A chronicle from 1255 mentions that upon the return of Louis IX from the Crusades, He left in the
country of Forez an image of Our Lady carved in black color that he had brought back from the
Levant. In actuality, this is an original Egyptian statue of Isis with Horus on her lap.
Another Egyptian Black Madonna statue, long preserved and honored in St. Germain des Prs (a
suburb of Paris), was removed and destroyed during the 16th century on orders of Bishop
Bretonneau, because he did not appreciate its pagan origins.452 The famous Black Madonna from
Le Puy and other such statues were also destroyed by French revolutionaries in 1793. Fortunately, a
scientist named Faujas de Saint-Fons had made three very detailed analyses and a scientific
description of that specific statue earlier in 1777. He determined the statue to be of Isis with Osiris
[sic], which had been modified into a Madonna.453 He even mentions hieroglyphic inscriptions
identical to those that he had found on the well-known archeological Table of Isis.454

CLOSING THOUGHTS

Both the Central Middle Ages and Dynastic Egypt offer testimony to the relationships between types of
money and our collective psyches and society. These past civilizations also provide a warning that is
relevant today. Medieval economist Guy Bois views the events that culminated in the Plague as
precedent[s] of a systemic crisis.455 It might be prudent to heed these lessons of the past and expand our
understanding of how monetary systems affect all of us, particularly in light of the ongoing instability of
our current global money system.

CHAPTER TWENTY EIGHT - The Balinese Exception



Life and livelihood ought not be separated but to flow from the same source, which is spirit. Spirit
means life, and both life and livelihood are about living in depth, living with a meaning, purpose, joy,
and sense of contributing to the greater community.

~MATTHEW FOX

The study of matrifocal societies offers insights about how an archetypal and monetary framework
different from our own might impact our lives and society. Such an investigation requires us to look to the
past as most indigenous peoples and matrifocal societies have by now either been destroyed, adapted
beyond recognition to the ways of invaders, or otherwise succumbed to the pressures of the modern
world.

Fortunately, there is at least one known exception. One unusual indigenous culture has managed to
endure and maintain much of its ancient cultural heritage and monetary system. Present-day Bali offers us
at least some sense of what honoring the Great Mother archetype and yin-yang values in society is actually
like.

EXCEPTIONAL BALI

Quilted rice paddies, volcanoes soaring up through the clouds, dense rain forests, blue-green seas,
religious statues and an almost endless array of colorful festivals are some of the images that greet the
millions of tourists who visit the island of Bali each year. Bali is part of the archipelago of Indonesia, a
mostly Islamic nation in which the Balinese are proud of preserving their particular Hindu culture.


Like many tropical islands, the Balinese economy derives part of its income from tourism. But Bali
differs from most other tourist meccas. A clue to this islands exceptional culture is noted by the literally
thousands of cultural and religious activities that take place in Bali annually. The vast majority of these
activities are performed not for foreigners, however, but for the Balinese themselves and for their deities.

It is still true today as it was when Swedish artist Tyra de Kleen observed in the 1920s that, At their
temple feasts [the Balinese] combine two good purposes, namely to please their gods and amuse
themselves.456 Out of the 5,000 dance groups listed with the provincial authorities in Bali a decade ago,
less than 200 were paid performances staged for tourists, while the other 4,800 performance groups
performed only for temple time.457

Temple groups play for foreigners in order to earn income for their instruments, costumes and such.
They do not, however, earn an income for their art. In comparison, practically all traditional dance groups
on other Pacific Islands today, like Hawaii, Fiji, and Tahiti, perform mainly for tourists.

The Balinese exception begs inquiry. What is the secret of their resilience? Why has this indigenous

culture survived when so many others have not? How can a people with a GNP per capita that is about
one tenth that of the United States find the money, time, and the resources for such extravaganzas and
activities? To answer such questions, we must look at some key features of this unusual society.

COMMUNITY: THE BANJAR



Community is an essential element of Balinese life and culture. Many important activities, such as rice
growing and the elaborate preparations for festivals and religious ceremonies, require the efforts and
cooperation of not only family members and friends, but on occasion, the participation of entire
communities.

The order and cooperation common to the Balinese society is realized by interrelated, local
organizational structures.458 The most significant of those structures, to which most Balinese still belong,
include:

Subak: for water irrigation cooperatives for rice production;
Pemaksan: for the coordination of religious rituals;
Banjar: the most important civic organization, which orders the social aspects of the community.
These organizations form an integrated structural fabric that strengthens each community and the culture
as a whole.

The Banjar is the principal civic organization in Bali. It operates in a decentralized, hyper-democratic,
and cooperative manner at a grassroots level. Written references to the Banjar date back to 914 CE (a
century prior to the advent of the Central Middle Ages).459 This systems longevity is in no small measure
related to its adaptability. Anthropologist and local resident Fred B. Eiseman explains, Even today,
among families who have spent several generations in an urban setting away from the rice fields, the
Banjar still plays an important role.460

The number of Banjars in an area varies from only one in a small village to several in larger towns.
Each Banjar has its own rulebook, the Awig-awig, all of which are based on the same general democratic
principles. The Banjar leader, the Klian Banjar, is elected by a majority vote of members and can be
dismissed at any time, though this is rarely done. He or she receives no remuneration for this function.
Anthropologists Clifford and Hildred Geertz describe the leader as More an agent than a ruler.461

Each family has one representative in the krama, the Banjar council, where every member is
considered equal and has one vote. No special status is granted to wealthier or higher caste members. At
monthly meetings, new activities are proposed and ongoing projects are discussed. The contributions of
time and money for each project are then decided upon, customarily by a majority vote. In short, the
Banjar functions as a community-based planning and implementation unit, which budgets all its activities.

Balinese leaders credit the Banjara system of mutual cooperationfor the resilience of Balinese
culture. Two Klian Banjars describe the benefits this way: Banjar is what holds the community, each
other, together.462 Banjar is the most fundamental organization that keeps the Balinese character
intact.463

But what holds the Banjar together?

A Complementary Currency System



A key to the Banjar is their dual-currency system.464 The rupiah is the conventional national Indonesian
currency. The Nayahan Banjar, or work for the common good of the Banjar, is a time-services currency
whose unit of account is a block of time equal to about three hours of work. The availability of both
currencies provides unusual flexibility in mobilizing local resources.

On average, a Banjar starts between seven and ten different projects every month, big and small. The
expected contributions of each family unit, in rupiah and in Nayahan, are estimated for a project. In poorer
Banjars, the rupiah monetary constraint is typically more binding, while in richer ones, the Nayahan time
commitment tends to be more challenging. In all cases, a mixture of rupiah and Nayahan currencies is
used, although the proportional mix varies widely by project and by Banjar.465

Community members consider the Nayahan Banjar money more critical than rupiah for keeping
cooperation strong. The importance of the time commitment to these projects is reflected by the main
penalty meted out. It is not a rupiah fine, but ostracism, the exclusion from the Banjar of someone who
refuses three times in a row to respect community decisions. Such bans can be devastating, as Clifford
and Hildred Geertz report: The Balinese still say today that to leave the krama [Banjar council] is to lie
down and die.466 A Klian Banjar explains the impact of such isolation: When they [ostracized Banjar
members] have an important family ceremony, like a cremation, marriages, or coming-of-age rituals, then
nobody will give time for helping them in the preparations. The rituals are sacrosanct and each requires
a communal effort. Depriving someone of time from the community is thus considered the ultimate
retribution.

It should be noted that use of the national rupiah, by both the Banjar and the Balinese people, only dates
back to Indonesian independence in the 1940s. Up until that time, the offical conventional currency was
the Dutch Guilder. While the Nayahan Banjar has been in use since before written records as a timebacked currency for public works, the principal medium of monetary exchange used by the Banjar was an
odd-looking coin, noted for a traditional square hole in its middle, called the Uang Kepeng, or Coin
Money.467 This currency was outlawed in the 1950s and finally went out of circulation in the 1970s.
Research by international currency expert, Stephen DeMeulenaere, has brought our attention to this
currency (see insert).

The Balinese Uang Kepeng

The Uang Kepeng has a long history. Its use in Bali can be officially traced back to the formation of
decentralized local governance in 914 CE, though its introduction to Bali is likely to have occurred
centuries earlier.468 It is, however, from the time that the Uang Kepeng became the official medium of
exchange of the Banjar and could be taxed, spent on public works projects, and circulated as a fullyfunctioning currency, that its significance to Balinese society was formalized, according to
DeMeulenaere.469


This coin money was minted in China and used as trading tokens, much in the same manner that
trading beads were used in North America with indigenous peoples.470 Chinese seafaring merchants
traded these tokens and other goods, such as ceramic objects, to obtain local Balinese spices.
Though the Balinese came into contact with, and were in fact governed by, other cultures
periodically during their long history, the only currency they formed a particular attachment to were
these odd-looking coins. Dutch anthropologist De Kat Angelino noted back in 1921 that the Balinese
preferred Uang Kepeng as a medium of exchange to Dutch, British, and Mexican money, which they
instead often melted to make into silver jewelry.471
It was only after the introduction of the Indonesian rupiah in the 1940s that the use of the Uang
Kepeng subsided, although its use as a ceremonial currency and for fines in some Banjars continues
to this day.
The Uang Kepeng are closely connected to the Balinese economics and mathematics. The Balinese
calculation system, similar to that of the abacus, was developed using these coins. Miguel
Covarrubias noted in the 1930s, The Balinese do not count in the present Dutch monetary system of
guilders and centsthe ringgit, big silver coins (worth two and a half guilders) are normally divided
[instead] into 1,200 Kepeng.472
The Uang Kepeng were typically strung together and carried in bundles of twenty-five coins each.
The Balinese word for 25 is selae, derived from se (one). The word ikat means to tie something
together in a bundle. The word for fifty is sekat, i.e. two bundles of selae that have been tied
together. The word for seventy-five, telung, means three bundles of selae that have been tied
together, and so on. When someone is broke, they say Sing Ada Pis, referring to the other name for
the Uang Kepeng, Pis Bolong or Pierced Piece.

The Uang Kepeng and Current Change



It was only when new national banking and currency laws were put into effect after Indonesia gained its
independence, that the Balinese were forced to accept the Indonesian rupiah in replacement of the Guilder
and the Uang Kepeng. According to many unofficial accounts however, the Uang Kepeng continued to be
used by the local Banjars as a medium of exchange up until the early 1970s.

It should be understood that the Uang Kepeng was the more popular form of currency. This
complementary currency and the rupiah were functionally different types of money. The replacement of the
local currency by the official legal tender was not a trivial matter; it changed the dynamics of the Balinese
monetary system. Though both currencies were interest-bearing, the interest was applied in very different
ways. With rupiah, like with all modern national currencies, interest is automatically assigned and
exacted. But in the case of the Uang Kepeng, the interest feature was less formal, more flexible, and did
not tend to accumulate over time. The interest might be paid back in Uang Kepeng or in goods or services,
such as assisting in a harvest or a religious ceremony. Additionally, there was no formal control over the
supply of this money. In fact, Uang Kepeng were readily available.

According to DeMeulenaere,

We might think that it would not be possible to manage a currency without being able to control its
supply, and that only a scarce currency is a strong currency, and by extension, that a currency lacking
scarcity would be weak. The Balinese, however, and other traditional societies that used an
abundant currency as a medium of exchange, developed unique means of keeping the circulating
supply low enough in order to maintain its value: they spent it on ceremonies or artistic displays of
their savings. In Bali, those with too much Uang Kepeng had statues of a goddess made out of the
coins, which were displayed prominently in their homes. The coins were also used in large
quantities during the ritual blessing of a new house, or for cremations and other religious and cultural
ceremonies. In these ways, demand for the currency and its value was maintained over the centuries.
As a readily available local means of exchange, Uang Kepeng encouraged the circulation of
locally-produced goods and services, supporting the agricultural economy, the local marketplace,
and the women who managed it all. Until the 1950s, Uang Kepeng protected the Balinese agricultural
economy and society from penetration and destruction by foreign money, trade and tourism, market
and currency fluctuations, or other adverse situations. Up until that time, the introduction of foreign
money did not affect the local economy or the behavior of the people, who could choose to
participate in both economies and not be forced to choose between the traditional economy of Uang
Kepeng and the new economy of Indonesian rupiah.
The decline of Uang Kepeng as a medium of exchange corresponds with a shift in economic
behavior towards earning the Indonesian rupiah. Although many significant elements of traditional
life remain vibrant in Bali, the monetary protection blanket they once had with Uang Kepeng has
been stripped away, leaving the Balinese people and society increasingly vulnerable to situations
beyond their control and subject to the same financial and consumption pressures faced by all of us
living in the modern world.473

Complementary currencies, especially the Uang Kepeng474 and Nayahan Banjar, have been a mainstay
of the Banjar system for more than a millennium. This dual-currency system keeps community spirit and
collective cultural expressions strong by enabling greater options in project choices and a diverse array

of activities. Banjars in poorer communities automatically favor projects that require time, such as the
great temple dance, the kecak, which traditionally involves much manpower. In contrast, more affluent
districts that are less concerned about financial costs are, therefore, more inclined to approve projects
that can be paid for in rupiah. For example, one single project in a wealthier Banjar had a budget of 1.2
billion Rupiah (equivalent to about $132,000) and proportionally much lower expenditures of time.475

The Banjar system extends beyond religious and cultural events to civic activities, such as support for
building primary schools or local roads, especially when the central government is unable to provide
funding. In short, local resources can be mobilized to support a fuller spectrum of undertakings, whatever
the community chooses to focus on.

The Great Mother Archetype



The repression of the Great Mother archetype has, as noted, cast its shadow upon much of our world.
Precious little is left of the once vibrant cultures in which everything was considered sacred, a belief
common to many so-called primitive societies. Some 5,000 years of an imbalanced patriarchal
supremacy has helped shape the modernist view that perpetuates a split between spirit and nature, mind
and matter, soul and body.

Bali, however, has managed to preserve key elements of its heritage that predate the Central Middle
Ages and endure in part to this day, despite seventeen centuries of invasions, foreign religious influences,
European colonization, integration into the predominantly Muslim nation-state of Indonesia, and terrorism.
This resilience forms part of a cultural coherence that we refer to as the Balinese exception.

Daily life in Bali integrates the mundane and the spiritual. This is evidence of the yin coherence, an
honoring of the more feminine aspects, such as the community cooperation found in a vast tapestry of
offerings, daily rituals, and festivals.

Offerings

A clue to understanding this culture is provided by the etymology of the word bali, meaning offering or
gift. It is a fitting name for a culture in which, with but one exception during the year, no day passes
without at least some form of offerings.

Authors Francine Brinkreve and David Stuart-Fox write:

They [the offerings] are found everywhere. Each day the lady of the house places little palm leaf
containers with beautiful flowers on a family shrine. A driver places a similar offering on the
dashboard of his car or truck. A family member graciously carries towers of fruits and cookies to a
temple on its festival day. Whole villages sometimes create enormous offerings several meters high.
And within offerings, such wondrous details as little rice dough figurines and delicate palm leaf
creations are almost hidden from view. The immense variety of form and color of the Balinese
offering is truly amazing.476

Festivals

Each of the many thousands of temples in Bali has its own odalan festival, a special feast that celebrates
the gods coming to the annual commemeration of the founding of their temple. The people renew their
ties with the gods and also reinforce their bonds with each other during the elaborate preparations and
ceremonies.477 Such festivals are filled with dances, some masculine and warrior-like, others feminine
and graceful.

There are procession rituals in which each family presents its offerings to its deities and ancestors.
These rituals are accompanied by prayers with the sprinkling of holy water and blessed rice on the
foreheads of participants, and carnivals, night-long drama dances, and trance dances in which participants
receive visitations from spirits. The more important festivals can go on for days and even weeks.

Death

Miguel Covarrubias, who first visited Bali in 1937, described the particular Balinese ritual response to
death:

Strange as it seems, it is in their cremation ceremonies that the Balinese have their greatest fun. A
cremation is an occasion for gaiety and not for mourning, since it represents the accomplishment of
their most sacred duty: the ceremonial burning of the corpses of the dead to liberate their souls, so
that they can thus attain the higher worlds and be free from reincarnation.478

Death is a cause for celebration: The grand send-off of the soul into heaven, in the form of a rich and
complete cremation, is the life-ambition of every Balinese.479

The material body is seen as the container of the soul. Death is but a passing from one form to another,
the beginning of another chapter, a normal part of lifes cycle, like a tree shedding its leaves. Life on this
Earth is considered by the Balinese as just an incident in the long process of the souls evolution. In short,
death is most certainly not a taboo in Balinese culture.

Cremations, religious ceremonies, and artistic activities permeate life and hold great meaning to the
Balinese, who participate with pride, intention, and craftsmanship. Many hours or even weeks of
preparations are required, along with the combined efforts of the entire community.

In every aspect of daily living there is a deep and abiding honoring of what is best described as the yin
expression of life, in which the spiritual and the mundane are seamlessly intertwined.

Balance and Trust



Together with its particular archetypal framework and dual-currency system, another characteristic that is
exceptional about Bali, and distinquishes this society from much of the rest of the world today, can be
described in a single wordtrust.

Returning to Dr. Bernice Hills Sacred Wounds of Money, we recall the difficulties often associated
with being financially well-off in our society: the burdens of expectation; a deep sense of isolation
accompanied by suspicions regarding relationships and friendships; a tendency toward dysfunctional
family dynamics; and having ones own sense of self brought into question. We noticed that each of these
wounds is characterized by a lack of trust at different levels of interaction. Though their particular objects
of concern may differ, lower and middle classes also suffer considerably from a lack of trust, with regard
to both fellow citizens and the abundance of the universe, in a society that uses only conventional
national currencies.

When poverty strikes and people are forced to live paycheck-to-paycheck without much in the way of
job security or savings, increasing attention is paid to concerns such as individual survival and caring for
ones own. In such a paradigm, one is continually confronted with scarcity, competitiveness, and the yangshadow coherence.

A very different set of dynamics emerges in a society in which a means of exchange is available to all,
whether it is in the form of money, time, or whatever each member of that society can contribute. A deeper
sense of security, belonging, and identity are reinforced, and the walls of separation are no longer
necessary. With a complementary currency system, the basic needs of even those at the lowest end of the
financial spectrum can more easily be met. There is, therefore, far less reason for the haves and have-nots
to mistrust or to envy.

Trust, pride, contentment, quality of life, and the values of a people are not easily measured from a
strictly conventional perspective. These phenomena, which permeate qualitatively different dimensions,
do not lend themselves well to quantifiable statistics, linear logic, or sound bites. As a result, the possible
implications inherent in Balinese archetypal integration are often overlooked. As we have seen, there is a
clear connection between the honoring of the Divine feminine, dual-currency systems, and a more
egalitarian society.

The Balinese reaction to recent tragedies offers some comparative sense of how a different perspective
and archetypal integration impact upon a culture.

BALIS 9/11

Bali became world news after the terrorist bomb attack in the town of Kuta on the night of October 12,
2002, in which more than 180 people were killed. Balis 9/11 occurred exactly one year, one month,
and one day after the attack on the World Trade Center in New York. Though the terrorist attack itself was
widely covered in the global media, the Balinese reaction to this horror was not given much notice.

Two reports follow. The first is by the police in the days immediately after the bombing:

Lt. Col. I Made Murda of the Bali police told us that, although hundreds of shops had their windows
blown out by the blast, not one single looting has been reported. Down in Legian there are all these
shops without windows and doors, all their wares there for the taking, but nobody has.
There were also fears that there could be an instant reaction against the Muslim population of
Bali, but no such thing has happened. What has happened is that there have been peace vigils and
prayer meetings all over the island, and Christians, Muslims, locals and foreigners working hand in
hand in the relief effort.480

The second report is from the Parum Samigita, the Think Tank for the Banjars located at the ground
zero area where the blast occurred (Kuta, Legian and Seminyak). Their spokesperson, Asana Viebeke,
delivered the following speech in English on Friday, October 25, 2002:

Now We Move Forward!

We Balinese have an essential concept of balance. Its the Tri Hita Karan, the concept of triple
harmonious balance. The balance between god and humanity; humanity with itself; and humanity with
the environment. This places us all in a universe of common understanding.
Who did this? This is not such an important question for us to discuss. Why this happenedmaybe
that is more worthy of thought. What can we do to create beauty from this tragedy and come to an
understanding where nobody feels the need to make such a statement again? That is important. That is
the basis from which we can embrace everyone as a brother, everyone as a sister.
It is a period of uncertainty, a period of change. It is also an opportunity for us to move together
into a better futurea future where we embrace all of humanity, in the knowledge that we all look
and smell the same when we are burnt.
The past is not significant. It is the future that is important. This is the time to bring our values, our
empathy, to society and the world at large. To care. To love
Why seek retribution from people who are acting as they see fit? These people are misguided from
our point of view. Obviously, from theirs, they feel justified and angry enough to make such a brutal
statement.
We would like to send a message to the world: embrace this misunderstanding between our
brothers and lets seek a peaceful answer to the problems that bring us to such tragedy. We embrace
all the beliefs, hopes and dreams of all the people in the world with love.
Do not bring malice to our world. What has happened has happened. Stop talking about the
theories of who did this, and why. It does not serve the spirit of our people. Words of hate will not
rebuild our shops and houses. They will not heal damaged skin. They will not bring back our dead.
Help us to create beauty out of this tragedy.
Everybody in the world is of one principal brotherhood. Tat Tvam AsiYou are me, and I am
you. These are the concepts by which we, as Balinese, live our lives.

If we hate our brothers and sisters we are lost in Kali Yuga (the Dark Age). If we can love all of
our brothers and sisters, we have already begun to move into Kertha Yuga. We have already won
The War Against Terrorism.
Thank you for all your compassion and love.

Asana L. Viebeke

Kuta Desa Adat481

In October 2005, another wave of terrorist attacks took place in Bali. The response was the same as
with the first bombing. Balinese culture, its dynamic balance of yin and yang, its archetypal integration, its
commitment to peaceful resolutions, and recognition of the sacred in everything in their world, leaves this
culture better prepared than most to deal with such events.482

There are, however, signs of change taking place. The nature of this shift and the likely reasons behind
it merit our attention.

RECENT CHANGES

On almost any given morning or late afternoon, the main roads of Bali today fill with traffic. Increasing
numbers of Balinese are working in manufacturing plants, import-export firms, hotels, new fast-food
chains, malls, and shops that cater to tourists. Street vendors, taxi cab drivers, and massage therapists
solicit passersby taking in the sights of Ubud, Kuta, and Sanur.

Balinese culture certainly endures. Religious icons and offerings are quite evident still, as are
traditional processions and festivals of one kind or another. But many of the familiar icons of
globalization are now commonplace as well and clash more than blend with time-honored customs. The
assertion made two decades ago that, Tourism is for Bali, not Bali for tourism, begs review. A more
complex reality is emerging.

Informal interviews with several dozen Balinese revealed that some ill-defined shift is occurring.
Television, tourism, and globalization are often cited as likely agents of added economic pressures and
cultural change. But, most Balinese are unaware of the impact that the supression of the dual-currency
system has had on their culture. Fortunately, a few Balinese nevertheless do very much appreciate the
impact and importance of a robust dual-currency system. This includes Prince Tjokorda Raka Kerthyasa,
head of the Bali Heritage Foundation, who is today working to reinstate the Uang Kepeng.483

A particular set of cultural values and traits arose simultaneously in Dynastic Egypt, the Central Middle
Ages, and Bali, and included integration of Great Mother archetype and a dual-currency system.
Moreover, a similar set of challenges that included changes to the monetary paradigm and repression of
yin values coincided with the fall of Dynastic Egypt and the Central Middle Ages and is currently
bringing pressures on the Balinese.

In concluding, we wish it understood that our review of past ages and Bali is not intended as a
recommendation of any one particular way of life, constellation of values, beliefs, or means of worship.
Furthermore, the specific measures and directions taken by each of these mostly homogeneous, agrarianbased societies are not necessarily applicable to todays multicultural, complex, global economy.

The relevance of these civilizations to ours today is the greater range of options and possibilities that
become available by means of integration of a fuller spectrum of archetypal values and by availing
ourselves of the greater potential of money. Given the many distinct advantages we enjoy today in
comparison to virtually any other known period of history, including that of a greater understanding than
ever before of money, it is reasonable to expect that we can achieve the best of what these former ages
were able to achieve, and far more still.

CLOSING THOUGHTS

The intricate and colorful fabric of Balinese culture bears homage to the often-neglected yin-aspects of
society. These are the invariably under-financed yet vitally critical areas of the arts, community-building,
and family life. As a direct consequence of a deficit of economic options, these major contributors to a
societys wellbeing are often found to be struggling and moribund among vast swaths of populations
around the world.

Bali has had a long history of a dual-currency monetary system, which has afforded this rich Hindu
culture a capacity to withstand the onslaught of foreign invasion right up to the 1970s, when one of their
yin currencies, the Uang Kepeng, was made illegal. Over the past four decades a slow erosion of core
Balinese culture and values has taken place. Phenomena such as mass media, massive tourism, and
globalization are often cited as the cause of this decline. The attrition of the balanced yin- yang monetary
structure, however, contributes to this process.

This monetary equilibrium can be readdressed and, in the case of Bali, is currently under
reconstruction, armed with a clear understanding of the functional dynamics of money and its deep
psychological and archetypical underpinnings.

CHAPTER TWENTY NINE - Invitation To A New World



Insanity: doing the same thing over and over again

and expecting different results.

~ALBERT EINSTEIN

In 1901, Georg Simmel observed in his book Philosophy of Money that, The debate about the future of
money is not about inflation or defla tion, fixed or flexible exchange rates, gold or paper standards; it is
about the kind of society in which money is to operate. In these final pages, we offer some parting
thoughts on monetary innovations and the kind of society we believe to be possible.

We will close with an invitation to you, the reader, to join us online, where our exploration of money
and societal transformation continues.

WHAT IS TRULY POSSIBLE



Our age is blessed with an epic opportunity. There now exists the real possibility of not only addressing
many of our most vital concerns, but ushering in an unparalleled age that can significantly enhance
conditions for all of humanity and the living systems of our precious planet. To this end, we reaffirm some
of the claims made in this book.

We can provide meaningful work for all. We can deal far more effectively and proactively with the
costly booms and busts of the business cycle. We can ensure the conditions necessary for free enterprise
and economic development to flourish, while simultaneously protecting the collective long-term interests
of society and the environment. We can bring about a world in which social concerns such as the
upbringing and education of our children and quality care for our elders are firmly addressed, and where
the diversity and sanctity of all life and the life-affirming aspects of what it is to be fully human are
supported and secured. We can achieve all this, and more.

These prospects are not only possible but achievable within the span of a single generation.
Furthermore, this transformation can be realized without conflict or hardship, and without the need to
raise taxes, redistribute wealth, or seek assistance from the federal government. The technologies, skills,
and means required for such a shift are known and are already being utilized in successful pilot programs
around the world, and are ready for widespread deployment.

We reaffirm that these and other claims made throughout this work are not conjecture, but are instead
supported by an ever-growing body of scholarship and by real-world experience, past and present.
Curitiba, Time Dollars, LETS, social currencies such as the Fureai Kippu and Saber, commercial
currencies such as the WIR, C3, and the Terra TRC; hard-earned lessons from the Great Depression;
millennia of history, the notable accomplishments of the Central Middle Ages, and so much moreall
offer testimony to what is possible, what is truly achievable through a greater understanding and
utilization of money.

Humanity has the knowledge and the means to bring about the greatest transformation in all of known
history. What we do not have is the luxury of unlimited time.

A TIME TO ACT

Many of the arguments offered in this work were, as previously noted, first presented more than a decade
ago in The Future of Money. Looking back, 1999 was perhaps an inconvenient year to make a case for the
urgent review and amendment of our centuries-old monopoly of national currencies. It will be recalled
that, despite concerns over Y2K, a general mood of optimism characterized the dawn of a new millenium.
The U.S. economy then boasted 4.5 percent unemployment and an inflation rate of 2.1 percent; gasoline
pump prices averaged $1.17 per gallon, Internet companies enjoyed unprecedented returns, as the DowJones soared to 11,750. Some economists of note, so buoyed by conditions and future prospects,
entertained the possibility that even the age-old business cycle had finally been tamed.

Optimism at the turn of the millenium spilled over to other areas, including confidence in our ability to
deal with looming issues such as unfunded liabilities and the environment. The baby-boomer generation
was, after all, then still more than a decade away from retirement. And though there was already a clear
consensus among the majority of the worlds leading scientists regarding greenhouse gases and climate
change, debate continued, and the twenty years estimated as necessary to birth a post-carbon economy
seemed a long time off given the context of our short-term culture.

In essence, there were many apparent indicators in 1999 to counter the call for monetary reform.

But the 999th year of the second millennium and the first decade of this third millennium came and
went. And not one of the megatrends cited in this book or its predecessor were addressed. Each of our
vital issues and the state of the world has instead only gotten worse.

Baby boomers, who will live longer than previous generations, are now beginning to retire. Yet, the
funds required to match their longevity and ensure their golden years are lacking. These and other social
issues have been made more problematic still by the global recession and overburdened public coffers.
Though the recession is at least officially considered at end, its root causes have not been addressed. The
supposed recovery of 2010 has come and gone as well, and 2011 saw continued economic instability,
austerity measures, and ongoing hardships for the small and medium-sized enterprises that comprise the
bulk of all private jobs. Official unemployment figures in the United States and elsewhere remain
stubbornly fixed at more than double the levels of a decade ago, with unofficial figures much higher still.
The concentration of wealth continues to increas as more and more middle-class citizens face uncertain
economic futures. The private sector remains locked in a singular pursuit of short-term objectives, while
traditional pre-recession neoliberal economic policies and unprecedented neo-Keynesian stimulus
packages have each demonstrated their inadequacies. And privatization, the supposed solution to allow
governments to meet their more-immediate fiscal concerns, will deprive our economies of the resilience
needed to ensure future stability and development. More ominous still, the first decade of the new
millennium is now officially established as the warmest on record. With precious little of note having
been achieved in this regard to date, and with ten of the twenty years estimated to bring about a postcarbon economy now behind us, we must seriously consider the options left us, and fast.

BACK TO MONEY

We reiterate that our ineffectiveness in the face of contemporary global challenges is not an expression of
the intractability of climate change, job losses, or other pressing concerns. The persistence of such issues
is instead related to our continued inability to identify and address the systemic root causes of these
concerns and, more specifically, to grasp their link to our industrial-age monetary paradigm.

No matter how sincere the desire or how determined our efforts, we simply cannot and must not expect
our difficulties to disappear until and unless we understand the functional dynamics of the current
monetary system and enact monetary amendments. To continue to think and act otherwise while expecting
revitalization to somehow magically take hold, is truly insane.

Money, Currency, and Great Change



In contemplating what kind of world is possible, we are reminded of the etymological roots of the words
money and currency. The term money, as noted, derives from Juno Moneta and is linked to a
constellation of perennial values vital to humanity and society. The term currency is linked to the
condition of flowing. (from Latin, currens, prp. of currere to run). As civilizations such as medieval
Western Europe and Dynastic Egypt reveal, some currencies are needed to function like a healthy
circulatory system; to flow and nurture each and every member of society to the betterment of all. The
restricted use of any one type of money, no matter how well designed, impedes the full expression of who
we are and what is truly possible.

We are in the midst of Great Change. It can either take the form of a breakdown on an unprecedented
scale, or a significant breakthrough for civilization. A positive shift will, however, not just happen on its
own accord. The kind of transformation that enhances life and allows us to overcome many present-day
concerns will require review and amendment of those very same systems that, notwithstanding their
contributions to the many remarkable accomplishments of our time, also fueled the myriad crises that are
now converging upon us. This is particularly true of the key information replicator of the Industrial Age
our centuries-old monopoly of national currencies.

The time for the democratization of money is now. With so much to gain and so little to lose, why delay
any longer?

AN INVITATION

Our journey in pursuit of monetary innovations and societal transformation continues online at our
companion websites:

www. newmoneyforanewworld.com

and

www.lietaer.com

CHAPTER THIRTY - The Dynamics of Transformation and Money



This chapter, regarding the changes now taking place to our economies and society at large, and the vital
role of monetary enhnacements, will be posted online on our companion websites:

www.newmoneyforanewworld.com

and

www.lietaer.com

ABOUT THE AUTHORS



Bernard Lietaer has studied and worked in the field of money for more than 30 years in an unusually
broad range of capacities including as a central banker, a fund manager, a university professor, and a
consultant to governments in numerous countries, multinational corporations, and community
organizations. He co-designed and implemented the convergence mechanism to the single European
currency system (the euro) and served as president of the Electronic Payment System at the National Bank
of Belgium (the Belgian Central Bank).

He co-founded and managed Gaia Corp, a top performing currency fund whose profits funded
investments in environmental projects. A former professor of International Finance at the University of
Louvain, he has also taught at Sonoma State University and Naropa University. He is currently a Research
Fellow at the Center for Sustainable Resources of the University of California at Berkeley. He is also a
member of the Club of Rome, a Fellow of the World Academy of Arts and Sciences, the World Business
Academy, and the European Academy of Sciences and Arts. Bernard Lietaer has written numerous books
and articles about money systems, including The Future of Money (translated into 18 languages), and New
Money for a New World (2011, Qiterra Press).

Stephen Belgin is the founder and President of Qiterra Press. He is a self-described passionate student of
systems thinking and what is truly possible. A near-death experience in the 1970s began a journey that
spanned much of the globe and a wide variety of disciplines, including medical research and
communications. Most recently, he spent a decade working with Bernard Lietaer to create New Money
For A New World, one of a number of upcoming books from Qiterra Press that speaks to societal
transformation and the solutions that are within our grasp.

ENDNOTES

CHAPTER ONE - A Tale of Two Cities



1 Information regarding Curitiba results from a field trip to the area in the late 1990s by Bernard Lietaer and by a follow-up interview in June
2007.


2 The Hammerville metaphor for our societys limiting use of money as a tool

CHAPTER TWO - Welcome to Moneyville




1. 3 John Maynard Keynes, A Treatise on Money (London, 1930), p. 13.

2. 4 Richard Wagner, interview by the authors (22 June 2004).

3. 5 Jacques Rueff, The Age of Inflation, translation by A. H. Meeus and F.G. Clarke

(Chicago: Henry Regnery Co., 1964).



4. 6 See: Peter Sloterdijk, Aus Herbstschrift I (Steierischer Herbst, 1990).

CHAPTER THREE - Megatrends and Money




1.

Ken Dychtwald, from a speech addressing the Academy of Criminal Justice


Sciences Meeting (San Francisco, 3 April 1999).

2.

Ken Dychtwald, from a speech addressing the Academy of Criminal Justice


Sciences Meeting (San Francisco, 3 April 1999).

3.

Ken Dychtwald, from a speech addressing the Academy of Criminal Justice


Sciences Meeting (San Francisco, 3 April 1999).

10 Jonathan Sacks, The Dignity of Difference: How to Avoid the Clash of Civilizations

(London, New York: Continuum International Publishing Group, 2003), p. 106. The
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), based in Paris, is an
association of the most developed countries in the world


1.

11

Peter G. Peterson, Gray Dawn: The Global Aging Crisis, Foreign Affairs
(January-February 1999).

2.

12

Peter G. Peterson, Gray Dawn: The Global Aging Crisis, Foreign Affairs
(January-February 1999).


3.

13 Source: <http://www.nchc.org/facts/cost.shtml>


4.

14

Source: <http://www.nchc.org/facts/cost.shtml> See also: Fidelity Investments,


Press Release (6 March 2006).

5.

15 Paul Eccleston, Ecological credit crunch potentially more damaging than financial

crisis, says WWF The Daily Telegraph (London, 29 October 2008), quoting WWFs
International Director, James Leape, and the WWF Living Planet Report.

6.

16 Paul Eccleston, Ecological credit crunch potentially more damaging than financial

crisis, says WWF The Daily Telegraph (London, 29 October 2008), quoting WWFs
International Director, James Leape, and the WWF Living Planet Report.

7.

17

Sigmar Garbriel, Biodiversity fundamental' to Economics, German Federal


Environment Minister (9 March 2007). <http://www.bbc.co.uk>

8.

18 Deforestation continues at an alarming rate, Press Release, Food and Agriculture

Organization of the United Nations (FAO), (Rome, 14 November 2005).



9.

19 As announced at the UN Climate Change Conference in Bali, Indonesia, by the

United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (December 2007).


<http://unfccc.int/meetings/cop_13/items/4094.php>

20 ASA GISS Surface Temperature (GISTEMP) Analysis, which provides a measure of the changing global surface temperature with
monthly resolution for the period since 1880, as reported by the Carbon Dioxide Information Analysis Center (CDIAC).
<http://www.cdiac.esd.ornl.gov>



1.

21 Remarks by Sigmar Gabriel, German Federal Minister for the Environment, Nature

Conservation and Nuclear Safety, based on The Economics of Ecosystems and


Biodiversity report by The European Union and German environment ministry-led
research, and presented at the UN Convention of Biological Diversity (Bonn, 19 May
2008).

2.

22

Economic Sector and Climate Change report by Munich Re (21 May 2008).
<http://www.munichre.com>

3.

23 Munich Re, press release (29 December 2005). <http://www.munichre.com>


4.

24 Jim Coleman, Cap and Trade - The Booster Shot Our Economy Needs, Terra

Rossa (20 February 2008). <http://www.terrarossa.com>



5.

25 Summary for Policymakers, Climate Change 2007: The Physical Science Basis.

Contribution of Working Group I to the Fourth Assessment Report of the


Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Intergovernmental Panel on Climate
Change
(2007).
<http://www.ipcc.ch/pdf/assessmentreport/ar4/wg1/ar4-wg1spm.pdf>

6.

26

The 2001 joint statement was signed by the scientific academies of Australia,
Belgium, Brazil, Canada, the Caribbean, China, France, Germany, India, Indonesia,
Ireland, Italy, Malaysia, New Zealand, Sweden, and the U.K. The 2005 statement
added Japan, Russia, and the United States. The 2007 statement added Mexico and
South Africa. Professional societies include: American Meteorological Society,
American Geophysical Union, American Institute of Physics, American Astronomical
Society, American Association for the Advancement of Science, Stratigraphy
Commission of the Geological Society of London, Geological Society of America,
American Chemical Society, and Engineers Australia. The Science Of Climate
Change (Royal Society, May 2001); Joint science academies' statement: Global
response
to
climate
change
(Royal
Society,
June
2005).
<http://royalsociety.org/displaypagedoc.asp?id=13619>; Joint science academies'
statement on growth and responsibility: sustainability, energy efficiency and climate
protection. <http://royalsociety.org/displaypagedoc.asp?id=20742>;
Potsdam Institute for Climate Impact Research, (May 2007)
<http://www.pik-potsdam.de/news/press-releases>

7.

27 John Thornhill, Income Inequality seen as the Great Divide, The Financial Times

(London, 19 May 2008).



8.

28 Sacks, The Dignity of Difference, p. 107.


9.

29 Edward N. Wolff, Recent Trends in Wealth Ownership, a paper for the conference: Benefits and Mechanisms for Spreading
Asset Ownership in the United States (New York University, 10-12 December 1998).


10.

30 Executive Pay Special Report, Business Week (9 April 2001).


11.

31 Center on Budget and Policy Priorities and the Economic Policy Institute (April 2008).


12.

32 David Boyle, The New Alchemists, Resurgence Magazine (January 1999).


13.

33 Sacks, The Dignity of Difference, p. 107.


14.

34 Stijn Claessens, Larry H.P. Lang, and Simeon Djankov, Who Controls East Asian

Corporations, Policy Research Working Papers, no. 2054 (Washington, D.C.: The
World Bank 1999).

15.

35 Stijn Claessens, Larry H.P. Lang, and Simeon Djankov, Who Controls East Asian

Corporations, Policy Research Working Papers, no. 2054 (Washington, D.C.: The
World Bank 1999).

16.

36

State of the World Population 2002: Useful Facts, Planetwire.


<http://www.planetwire.org>

17.

37 Anup Shah, Causes of Hunger are Related to Poverty (19 November 2005). <http://www.globalissues.org>


18.

38 Department of Labor Commissioner's Statement on the Employment Situation News Release: unemployment rose by 1.8 million in
the last four months of 2008.


19.

39

Tomoko A. Hosaka, Japan's exports tumble on global spending freeze, The


Associated Press, as reported by MSNBC (25 March 2009).

20.

40 Sharon

LaFraniere, 20 million migrant workers in China can't find jobs, The


International Herald Tribune (2 February 2009).

21.

41

World economy may lose 51 million jobs, International Labour Organization


(ILO), as reported by United Nations Radio (28 January 2009).

22.

42 Former UN Secretary General Kofi Annan addressing UN Economic and Social

Council (ECOSOC) annual session (3 July 2006).



23.

43 Paul

Craig Roberts, Forget Iran, Americans Should be Hysterical About This:


Nuking the Economy, Counterpunch (11-12 February 2006). Paul Craig Roberts
presents his argument as follows: The U.S. economy came up more than 7 million
jobs short of keeping up with population growth. U.S. manufacturing lost 2.9 million
jobs, almost 17 percent of the manufacturing work force. The knowledge jobs that
were supposed to take the place of lost manufacturing jobs in the globalized new
economy never appeared. The information sector lost 17 percent of its jobs, with the
telecommunications work force declining by 25 percent. Today there are 209,000
fewer managerial and supervisory jobs than 5 years ago.
<http://www.counterpunch.org>

24.

44 Floyd Norris, Off The Charts, New York Times (8 August 2009). For the decade,

there was a net gain of 121,000 private sector jobs, according to the survey of
employers conducted each month by the Bureau of Labor Statistics. In an economy
with 109 million such jobs, that indicated an annual growth rate for the 10 years of
0.01 percent.

25.

45 The U.S. Labor Department reported in February 2008 that average hourly earnings

increased 3.7 percent in 2007. As prices increased even more during that time, the
real earnings in terms of purchasing power actually decreased 0.8 percent. Average

earnings were $596, or $30,992 per year. (Note: This is the total earnings of all private
sector, non-farm, non-supervisory employees, full and part-time, divided by total
number of hours worked.) Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Real Earnings Report.

26.

46 Employees Put In More Hours, CNN.com (31 August 2001). <http://www.cnn.com>


27.

47

Barbara Killinger, Workaholics: The Respectable Addict (Toronto: Key Porter


Books, 1991), p. 7.

28.

48 Jacob Hacker, The Great Risk Shift (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2006).


29.

49

James Surowiecki, The Financial Page: Lifers, The New Yorker (16 January
2006), p. 29: The percentage of companies that offer health benefits has dropped
thirteen percent over the past five years, and even employees that are covered now
generally pay more of their own costs. With pensions the shift has been fundamental:
defined-benefit plans, in which companies guarantee a set payout to employees, have
been gradually replaced with defined-contributions plans like 401(k)s. With a
defined-benefit plan, the company assumes the risk of investing assets, absorbing the
impact of market downturns, but with a 401(k) it is entirely up to the employee to
prosper or plummetMeanwhile, the risk of exposure of anybody unfortunate
enough to lose a job has soared. People who are unemployed stay unemployed, on
average, about fifty percent longer than they did so in the seventies, and only about
half as many receive unemployment insurance as did in 1947. Furthermore the
explosion of health-care costs means that the consequences of forfeiting company
health insurance are graver than everSo, economists estimate that income volatility
is about twice what it was in the early seventies.

30.

50 United Nations Population Division, World Population Prospects: The 2004 Revision Population Database. <http://esa.un.org>


31.

51 William Greider, One World, Ready or Not: The Manic Logic of Global Capitalism

(New York: Simon and Schuster, 1997).



32.

52 Wassily Leontieff as quoted in Jeremy Rifkin, After Work, Utne Reader (May-

June 1995), p. 54.



33.

53 These numbers of monetary and banking crises are extracted from Gerard Caprio,

Jr. and Daniela Klingelbiel, Bank Insolvencies: Cross Country Experience, Policy
Research Working Papers, no.1620 (Washington D.C.: World Bank, Policy and
Research Department, 1996). Since then, an additional series of crises should be
added, including the Asian crisis in the late 1990s, and more recently, the Russian and
the Argentinian crises. See also: Jeffrey Frankel and Andrew Rose, Currency
Crashes in Emerging Markets: an Empirical Treatment, Journal of International

Economics 4 (1996), p. 351-66; Graciela Kaminsk and Carmen Reinhart, The Twin
Crisis: the Causes of Banking and Balance of Payment Problems, American
Economic Review 89, no. 3 (1999), p. 473-500; Carl-Johan Lindgren, Gillian Garcia,
and Matthew Saal, Bank Soundness and Macro-economic Policy (Washington D.C.:
IMF, 1996).

34.

54 Joseph Stiglitz, How to Reform the Global Financial System, Harvard Relations

Council International Review 25, no. 1 (Spring 2003), p. 54-9.



35.

55

Triennial Central Bank Survey of Foreign Exchange and Derivatives Market


Activity
in
2010

Final
results
(December
2010).
<http://www.bis.org/publ/rpfxf07t.htm>

36.

56 This number originates from the survey performed every three years by the Bank

of International Settlements (BIS)the central bank of the central banks located in


Basel, Switzerlandduring a normal day of trading. In addition to these traditional
foreign exchange transactions, the BIS counted in April 2004 a daily volume of $2.4
trillion in monetary derivatives in foreign exchange and interest rate related products,
including outright forwards and foreign exchange swapsGross market values more
than doubled, from $3.0 trillion to $6.4 trillion, in the three years to end-June 2004.
Bank of International Settlements (BIS), Triennial Central Bank Survey of Foreign
Exchange and Derivatives Market Activity 2004Final Results (Basel, Switzerland,
17 March 2005), p. 1.

37.

57 These statistics are derived from the total daily foreign exchange transactions as reported every three years by the BIS, and
compared to Global Annual Trade divided by the number of days.


38.

58

Russia blames U.S. for Global Financial Crisis, Reuters (7 June 2008).
<http://www.reuters.com/article/ousiv/idUSL0749277
620080607?sp=true>

39.

59 Catherine

Clifford, Household net worth sinks $11.2 trillion, CNNMoney (12


March 2009).

40.

60 Tami Luhby, Americans $1.7 trillion poorer, CNNMoney (5 June 2008).

CHAPTER FOUR - A Money Primer




1.

61

Geoffrey K. Ingham, Concepts Of Money: Interdisciplinary Perspectives From


Economics, Sociology. p. xi.

2.

62 The

Forum on Magic, held in Aaron Burr Hall, Princeton University (May 30,
2008). <http://www.princeton.edu/prok/issues/3-2/forum.xml>

3.

63 William Greider, The Secrets of the Temple (New York: Touchstone Books, 1987),

p. 240.

4.

64 Binyamin Appelbaum, Fed to Take a Step Out From Behind the Veil,New York

Times (25 March 2011).



5.

65

Edmund L. Andrews, Greenspan Concedes Error on Regulation, New York


Times (23 October 2008).

6.

66 Glyn Davies, A History of Money from Ancient Times to the Present Day (Cardiff:

University of Wales Press, 1994), p. 27.



7.

67 This definition has also been explored by Rabbi Nilton Bonder in his book, The

Kabbalah of Money: Jewish Insights on Giving, Owning, and Receiving (Boston:


Shambhala Books, 1996).

8.

68 Money Facts by the Subcommittee of Domestic Finance, Committee on Banking

and Currency, House of Representatives 88th Congress, 2nd Session (21 September
1964): Money is anything that people will accept in exchange for goods or services,
in the belief that they may, in turn, exchange it, now or later, for other goods or
services.

9.

69 Charles F. Durban, The Bank of Venice, Quarterly Journal of Economics 6, no. 3

(April 1892).

10.

70 Money Facts by the Subcommittee of Domestic Finance, Committee on Banking

and Currency, House of Representatives 88th Congress, 2nd Session (21 September
1964): Legal tender is any form of money that the U.S. Government declares good
for payment of taxes and both public and private debtsThis note is legal tender for
all debts public and private is written on every U.S. dollar bill. What this means in
practice is the following: if you owe someone money and he/she refuses your offer to
pay with dollar bills, you can walk away and simply declare the debt void. If needed,
the courts will back you in such a declaration.

11.

71 To be more accurate, while the Charter of the Bank of England dates from 1688, the monopoly of emission of paper money was
assigned by 1694, when an additional 1.2 million pounds were urgently needed to fight a war against the French. In the case of Sweden,
the power of emission had to be similarly transferred to the Bank of the Estates of the Realm when the crown needed urgent money to
fund a war against Denmark. While the introduction of paper money made the transfer of the power of emission of money from
sovereigns to banks possible, the proximate cause of that process was war.

12.

72 John Kenneth Galbraith, Money: Whence it Came, Where it Went (London: Andre

Deutsch, 1975).

73 Regulations specify that only 10 percent of a deposit need to be kept as a reserve in case the customer withdraws the funds. Therefore, up
to 90 percent is available to make new loans. Changing that percentage is one of the techniques whereby the Federal Reserve controls the
quantities of credit money the banks will be able to create. The exact percentages also vary with the kind of deposit made: the longer the term
of the deposit, the lower the percentage of reserves required. The 90 percent rule of this example, enabling a multiplier of about nine to
one, is an illustrative average.

CHAPTER FIVE - Money Is Not Value Neutral




1.

74 Charles Handy, The Empty Raincoat (London: Arrow Business Books, 1995), p.

108.

2.

75 A detailed description of this process is provided in Bernard Lietaer and Stefan

Brunnhuber, Money and Sustainability The Missing Link (2008).



3.

76 John

Jackson and Campbell R. McConnell, Economics (Sydney: McGraw Hill,

1988).

4.

77 Marc van de Mieroop, The Invention of Interest in William N. Goetzman and K.

Geert Rouwenhorst, The Origins of Value: The Financial Innovations that Created
Modern Capital Markets (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2005), p. 24.

5.

78 Source: <http://www.appropriate-economics.org/materials/Brief_History_of_interest.html>


6.

79 In Islam, for example see: Gillian Tett, Banks Create Muslim Windows as Islamic

Banking Expands its Niche, The Financial Times (2 June 2006), p. 6: The central
religious precept driving the Islamic finance industry is the idea that riba (a word that
can be translated either as interest or usury) is haram (forbidden or sinful)
At first glance, this appears to rule out most aspects of modern finance. But although
the Koran bans the creation of money, by money, it does allow money to be used for
trading tangible assets and businessesthat can generate a profitIronically, some
of [the] structures and techniques [of modern Islamic banking] echo those that
flourished in Christendom in Europe between the 12th and 15th centuries. The
Christian Council of Nicea (325 CE) banned the practice of usury among the clergy
and in 1140 this principle was extended to church members.

7.

80 Source: <http://www.sacred-texts.com/chr/ecf/002/0020342.htm>


8.

81 Source: <http://www.newadvent.org> (14 September 2006): The 12th canon of the

First Council of Carthage (345) and the 36th canon of the Council of Aix (789) have
declared it to be reprehensible even for laymen to make money by lending at interest.

The canonical laws of the Middle Ages absolutely forbade the practice. This
prohibition is contained in the Decree of Gratian and orders that the profit so
obtained to be restored; also the Third of the Lateran (1179) and the Second of Lyons
(1274) condemn usurers. In the Council of Vienne (1311) it was declared that if any
person obstinately maintained that there was no sin in the practice of demanding
interest, he should be punished as a heretic. It is a curious fact that for a long time
impunity in such matters was granted to Jews. The Fourth Council of the Lateran
(1215), canon 27, only forbids them to exact excessive interest.

9.

82 Estelle and Mario Carota, The Ignored Doctrine on Money (1986) in John H.

Hotson, The Comer Papers (Ontario, Canada: 1987), p. 1.



10.

83 Andrew Lowd, in his thesis, Alternative Currencies in Theory and Practice.


11.

84 Pierre Thuillier, Darwin Chez les Samourai, La Recherche, no. 181 (1986), p.

1276-80.

12.

85 Elisabet Sahtouris, Earth Dance: Living Systems in Evolution (Alameda: Metalog

Books, 1996).

13.

86 David Loye, personal email to Stephen Belgin (2005).


14.

87 David Loye, personal email to Stephen Belgin (2005).


15.

88 David Loye, personal email to Stephen Belgin (2005).


16.

89 Margrit Kennedy, et.al., Interest and Inflation Free Money: Creating an Exchange

Medium that Works for Everybody and Protects the Earth (Okemos: Sava
International, 1995), p. 26.

17.

90 Ian Dew-Becker and Robert J. Gordon, Where Did the Productivity Growth Go?

Inflation Dynamics and the Distribution of Income, paper presented at the 81st
meeting of the Brookings Panel on Economic Activity (Washington, D.C. 8-9
September 2005). <http://www.brookings.edu>

CHAPTER SIX - Back to the Future




1.

91

All three labels describing this period are quoted from Guy Bois, La Grande
Dpression Mdivale le XIVXVeme sicle: le Prcdent dune crise systmique
(Paris: PUF, 2000), p. 11.

2.

92

Eva Matthews Sanford, The Twelfth CenturyRenaissance or Proto-

Renaissance? Speculum 26 (1951), p. 635-42. See also: Warren Hollister, ed., The
Twelfth Century Renaissance (New York: John Wiley & Sons, 1969); Charles Young,
ed., The Twelfth Century Renaissance (Melbourne, FL: Krieger Publishing Company,
1977); Chris Ferguson, Europe in Transition: A Select, Annotated Bibliography of
the Twelfth-Century Renaissance (New York, London: Taylor & Francis, 1987);
Jacques Verger, La Renaissance du XIIe Sicle (Paris: Editions du Cerf, 1996).

3.

93 Robert Delort, La Vie au Moyen Age (Lausanne: Editta, 1982), p. 45.


4.

94 Bois, La Grande Dpression, p. 16.


5.

95 Marcel Bloch quoted in Bois, La Grande Dpression, p. 15.


96 Guy Fourquin, Histoire Economique de lOccident Medieval (Paris: Armand Collin,

1969), p. 215.


1.

97 Francois Icher, Les Oeuvriers des Cathdrales (Paris: Editions de la Martinire,

1998), p. 20.

2.

98 Bois, La Grande Dpression, p. 21.


3.

99 Bayard, La Tradition Cachee, p. 42.


100 Robert

L. Reynolds, Europe Emerges: Transition Toward an Industrial Worldwide


Society, 600-1750 (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1967), p.185-6


1.

101 R. Philippe, Lnergie au Moyen Age: LExemple des Pays dEntre Seine et Loire

de la fin du XIeme Sicle a la fin du XVeme Sicle (Paris: 1982).



2.

102 Frances and Joseph Gies, Cathedral, Forges and Waterwheel: Technology and

Invention in the Middle Ages (New York: Harper Perennial, 1995), p. 107.

3.

103 Robert Lacey and Danny Danzinger, The Year 1000: What life was like at the turn

of the first Millennium (London: Little Brown & Co., 1999), p. 87.

4.

104 Bois, La Grande Dpression, p. 52.


5.

105

Alex Werner, ed., London Bodies: The Changing Shape of Londoners from
Prehistoric Times to the Present Day (London: Museum of London, 1998), p. 108.
The sizes of the bodies are based on bone lengths and are therefore subject to error.

But where large samples are involved as here, the error is a constant that can be
ignored for the purposes of comparison.

6.

106 See for instance, Georges Duby, Europe des Cathdrales: 1140-1290 (Geneva:

Skira, 1966).

7.

107

Sacheverell Sitwell, The Gothick North: A Study of Medieval Life, Art, and
Thought (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1929).

8.

108 Delort, La vie au Moyen Age, p. 211-2.


9.

109 H. Kraus, A Prix dOr: le Financement des Cathdrales (Paris: Cerf, 1991). It

should be noted that abbeys do not fit into this general rule: they were built and
owned by the order that lived there. The bulk of the financing for the abbeys came
from donations of land or other endowments by nobility.

10.

110 Barbara Schock-Werner, Le Chantier de la Cathdrale de Strasbourg, Chantiers

Mdivaux (Editions du Zodiaque, DDB, 1995). The funding for each cathedral was
by a special legal and financially-independent institution, called la Maison de
lOeuvre Notre Dame. One of the most complete records relates to the cathedral of
Strasbourg in Alsace, France. In 1206, the Oeuvre Notre Dame at Strasbourg
consisted of a committee of citizens, including the local Bishop. However, from 1230
onwards the role of the Bishop and clergy dropped to the point that after 1262, the
Bishop was completely excluded from the committee. In 1290, LOeuvre Notre
Dame became an official municipal function. It has remained so to this day, with a
brief exception after the French Revolution (1789 to 1803), when it was controlled by
the French State (Rgie des Domaines).

11.

111 Bois, La Grande Dpression, p. 11.


12.

112 Fourquin, Histoire conomique de lOccident Mdival, p. 192.


13.

113 Henry S. Lucas, The Great European Famine of 1315-1316, Speculum 5, no. 4

(1930), p. 343-77

14.

114 Chronicle of Gilles Le Muisit, abbot of Saint-Martin de Tournai (1272-1352) in

Textes et documents dhistoire du Moyen Age, XIVe-XVe sicles, tome 1, S.E.D.E.S.


(Paris: 1970), p 8-9. See also: R. Fossier, Le Moyen Age, le temps des crises (12501520) (Paris, 1997). A. Colin and Jean Delumeau, Les malheurs des temps. Histoire
des flaux et des calamits en France (Paris: Larousse, 1987).

15.

115 Lucas, The Great European Famine of 1315-1316, Speculum 5, no. 4 (1930), p.

343-77.

16.

116 Daniel Power, ed., The Central Middle Ages (Oxford University Press, 2006), p.

60.

17.

117 Bois, La Grande Dpression, p. 93-4.

CHAPTER SEVEN - A Change of View




1.

118 The late medieval social order was constituted by Gods Three Estates, in which the Church, nobility, and masses were each to
serve one another to the benefit of all. According to historian Barbara Tuchman, The clergy was to pray for all men, the knights to
fight for them, and the commoner worked that all might eat. This plan derived from the early Christian notion of mankinds fall from an
original state of grace.


2.

119 The concentration of wealth took several centuries to be established and all its effects were not negative. For instance, patronage
by the elite gave birth to what became later known as the Renaissance.


3.

120 From the writings of early church father St. Augustine of Hippo.


4.

121 The French Philosopher Alexandre Koyr coined the term and definition of The

Scientific Revolution in 1939, which is often dated as having begun in 1543, the year
in which Nicolaus Copernicus published his De revolutionibus orbium coelestium
(On the Revolutions of the Heavenly Spheres), and Andreas Vesalius published his
De humani corporis fabrica (On the Fabric of the Human body). Although this
period is commonly dated to the 16th and 17th centuries, some see elements
contributing to this shift as early as the Middle Ages. See: Edward Grant, The
Foundations of Modern Science in the Middle Ages: Their Religious, Institutional,
and Intellectual Contexts (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996).

5.

122 See the Needham Research Institute website: <http://www.nri.org.uk/joseph.html>


6.

123 Source: <http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Scientific_revolution>


7.

124 Both Isaac Newton and Gottfried Wilhelm Leibniz are usually both credited with

the invention of calculus. Newton was the first to apply calculus to general physics
and Leibniz developed much of the notation used in calculus today. By Newton's
time, the fundamental theorem of calculus was known.

8.

125 Some historians differentiate between the Age of Reason in the 1600s and the Age of Enlightenment in the 1700s. For our
purposes, the Age of Enlightenment referred to in this book includes both these intellectual movements.


9.

126 Source: <http://www.riksbank.com> and <http://www.bankofengland.co.uk>

10.

127 To be more accurate, while the Charter of the Bank of England dates from 1688,

the monopoly of emission of paper money was assigned by King William of Orange
to that institution only in 1694, when he urgently needed an additional 1.2 Million
for a war against the French. See also: <http://www.bankofengland.co.uk>

11.

128

For
more
information
<http;//www.humanscience.wikia.com/wiki/Social_Development_Theory

see:


12.

129 Michael D. Bordo, The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. England adopted a

de facto gold standard in 1717 after the master of the mint, Sir Isaac Newton,
overvalued the guinea in terms of silver, and formally adopted the gold standard in
1819. <http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/GoldStandard.html>

13.

130 Voltaire, The Works of Voltaire, Vol. VII, Philosophical Dictionary Part 5 (1764).


14.

131 Personal communication with Alec Tsoucatos (June 15, 2005).


15.

132 For more information see: David Dugan and Alan Macfarlane , The Day the World

Took Off (University of Cambridge). <http://www.dspace.cam.ac.uk/handle1810/270>



16.

133 Alfred W. Crosby, The Measure of Reality: Quantification and Western Society

1250-1600 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998).



17.

134 This supposition is made because the success of the French experiment with local currencies seemed to have disappeared in the
mist of time.


18.

135 The Technocratic Materialistic Mechanistic (TMM) model is a term coined by Anne

Wilson Schaef, in Living in Process: Basic Truths for Living the Path of the Soul
(New York: Ballantine Wellspring, 1999).

CHAPTER EIGHT - Economic Myopia




1.

136 Eric Beinhocker, The Origins of Wealth Complexity, and the Radical Remaking of

Economics (Cambridge, Massachusettes: Harvard Business School Press, 2006).


Many earlier economists, such as Smith (and Bentham) regarded themselves as
philosophers rather than scientists, and the mathematics of the Classical periods is
generally limited to a few numerical examples and a bit of algebra, but nothing more
sophisticated.

2.

137 Eric Beinhocker, The Origins of Wealth Complexity, and the Radical Remaking of

Economics (Cambridge, Massachusettes: Harvard Business School Press, 2006).


Many earlier economists, such as Smith (and Bentham) regarded themselves as

philosophers rather than scientists, and the mathematics of the Classical periods is
generally limited to a few numerical examples and a bit of algebra, but nothing more
sophisticated, p. 67.

3.

138 Eric Beinhocker, The Origins of Wealth Complexity, and the Radical Remaking of

Economics (Cambridge, Massachusettes: Harvard Business School Press, 2006).


Many earlier economists, such as Smith (and Bentham) regarded themselves as
philosophers rather than scientists, and the mathematics of the Classical periods is
generally limited to a few numerical examples and a bit of algebra, but nothing more
sophisticated, p. 24. A more complete but more cumbersome definition for
Traditional Economics is: the set of concepts and theories articulated in
undergraduate and graduate-level textbooks. It also includes the concepts and
theories that peer-reviewed surveys claim, or assume, the field generally agrees on.

4.

139 Eric Beinhocker, The Origins of Wealth Complexity, and the Radical Remaking of

Economics (Cambridge, Massachusettes: Harvard Business School Press, 2006).


Many earlier economists, such as Smith (and Bentham) regarded themselves as
philosophers rather than scientists, and the mathematics of the Classical periods is
generally limited to a few numerical examples and a bit of algebra, but nothing more
sophisticated, p. 67.

5.

140 Eric Beinhocker, The Origins of Wealth Complexity, and the Radical Remaking of

Economics (Cambridge, Massachusettes: Harvard Business School Press, 2006).


Many earlier economists, such as Smith (and Bentham) regarded themselves as
philosophers rather than scientists, and the mathematics of the Classical periods is
generally limited to a few numerical examples and a bit of algebra, but nothing more
sophisticated, p. 67.

6.

141 Eric Beinhocker, The Origins of Wealth Complexity, and the Radical Remaking of

Economics (Cambridge, Massachusettes: Harvard Business School Press, 2006).


Many earlier economists, such as Smith (and Bentham) regarded themselves as
philosophers rather than scientists, and the mathematics of the Classical periods is
generally limited to a few numerical examples and a bit of algebra, but nothing more
sophisticated, p. 52-7.

7.

142 Eric Beinhocker, The Origins of Wealth Complexity, and the Radical Remaking of

Economics (Cambridge, Massachusettes: Harvard Business School Press, 2006).


Many earlier economists, such as Smith (and Bentham) regarded themselves as
philosophers rather than scientists, and the mathematics of the Classical periods is
generally limited to a few numerical examples and a bit of algebra, but nothing more
sophisticated, p. 33.


8.

143 GDP only includes goods; GNP does not include goods and services produced by

foreign producers, but does include goods and services produced by U.S. firms based
abroad. GDP replaced gross national product (GNP) as the primary measure of U.S.
production in 1991. <http://www.traderslog.com>

9.

144 The U.S. national median salary for a stay at home parent with one pre-school

child and another at school is $138,095. <http://swz.salary.com/momsalarywizard/>



10.

145

These figures, based on the median salary of the 25th percentile across four
different zip codes in the U.S. were calculated using data provided by:
<http://www.salary.com>

11.

146 Clifford

Cobb, Ted Halstead, and Jonathan Rowe, If the GDP is Up, Why is
America Down? Atlantic Monthly, 276 (4), October, p. 51-8. Cited from Sally
Goerner After the Clockwork Universe: The Emerging Science and Culture of
Integral Society (Edinburgh, Scotland: Floris Publishers, 1999), p. 331.

12.

147 Clifford

Cobb, Ted Halstead, and Jonathan Rowe, If the GDP is Up, Why is
America Down? Atlantic Monthly, 276 (4), October, p. 51-8. Cited from Sally
Goerner After the Clockwork Universe: The Emerging Science and Culture of
Integral Society (Edinburgh, Scotland: Floris Publishers, 1999), p. 331.Comments
made by Simon Kuznets appear in the first report to the U.S. Congress in 1934, as
reported by Measuring Progress: Annex.

148 Clifford Cobb, Ted Halstead, and Jonathan Rowe, If the GDP is Up, Why is America

Down? Atlantic Monthly, 276 (4), October, p. 51-8. Cited from Sally Goerner After the
Clockwork Universe: The Emerging Science and Culture of Integral Society (Edinburgh,
Scotland: Floris Publishers, 1999), p. 331.Comments made by Simon Kuznets appear in
the first report to the U.S. Congress in 1934, as reported by Measuring Progress: Annex.
As former World Bank economist Herman Daly puts it, the current national accounting
system treats planet Earth as a business in liquidation. Add pollution to the balance sheet
and we appear to be doing even better. Pollution shows up twice as gain: once when the
Chemical factory, say, produces it is a byproduct, then again when the nation spend
billions of dollars to clean it up in a toxic Superfund site. It shows up again as medical
bills rising as a result of dirty air.


1.

149 Robert Kennedy, Jr., from a lecture at a Friends of the Earth Rally (New York, 13 March 1963).


2.

150 Hazel Henderson, Jon Lickerman, and Patrice Flynn Calvert_Henderson Quality

of Life Indicators (Calvert Group, 2000). See also, Ethical Markets (White River

Junction, Vermont: Chelsea Green Publishing, 2006).



3.

151 Cobb, Halstead, and Rowe, If the GDP is Up, Why is America Down? p. 51-8.


4.

152 Cobb, Halstead, and Rowe, If the GDP is Up, Why is America Down? p. 51-8.


5.

153 Cobb, Halstead, and Rowe, If the GDP is Up, Why is America Down? p. 51-8.

CHAPTER NINE - Lessons from a Depression




1.

154

Paul Krugman, How Did Economists Get It So Wrong, New York Times (2
September, 2009). <http://www.nytimes.com/2009/09/06/magazine/06Economict.html>

2.

155

Paul Krugman, How Did Economists Get It So Wrong, New York Times (2
September, 2009). <http://www.nytimes.com/2009/09/06/magazine/06Economict.html>

3.

156 Saving

the System, The Panic, The Rescues and a Full Report on the World
Economy, The Economist (11 October 2008).

4.

157

Paul Krugman, The Third Depression, New York Times (27 June 2010).
<http://www.nytimes.com/2010/06/28/opinion/28krugman.html>

5.

158 The Economist (11 October 2008).


6.

159 Charles Kindleberger, Manias, Panics and Crashes ( New York: Wiley & Sons, 3d

ed. 1996), p. 1.

7.

160 Prior to the Weimar Republic (1919-1933), the German national currency was the

mark. In 1923, in order to counter inflation, the mark was replaced by the
rentenmark. One year later, when inflation slowed down, the reichsmark came
into being and remained Germanys national currency throughout the war years. It
was demonetized by a new currency law on June 20th 1948 and replaced by the
deutsche mark, which was finally replaced by the euro.

8.

161

Glyn Davies, A History of Money: From Ancient Times to the Present Day
(Cardiff: University of Wales, 1994), p. 572-4.

9.

162 In 1929, the Wra Tauschgesellschaft was founded by two Gesell followers, Hans Timm and Reinhard Rdiger. Claude Million,
Ph.D. dissertation, Nebenwhrungen gegen Absatzstockung und Beschftigungskrise Die amerikanischen Versuche mit scrip
whrend der Grossen Depression (Humboldt Universitt zu Berlin, April 1998).

10.

163 In 1929, the Wra Tauschgesellschaft was founded by two Gesell followers, Hans Timm and Reinhard Rdiger. Claude Million,
Ph.D. dissertation, Nebenwhrungen gegen Absatzstockung und Beschftigungskrise Die amerikanischen Versuche mit scrip
whrend der Grossen Depression (Humboldt Universitt zu Berlin, April 1998).


11.

164 In 1929, the Wra Tauschgesellschaft was founded by two Gesell followers, Hans Timm and Reinhard Rdiger. Claude Million,
Ph.D. dissertation, Nebenwhrungen gegen Absatzstockung und Beschftigungskrise Die amerikanischen Versuche mit scrip
whrend der Grossen Depression (Humboldt Universitt zu Berlin, April 1998). Letters specific to this case include the letter from the
Board of the Reichsbank (I 10513) to the Minister of Finance, dated 8/8/1931 (Bundesbank Archiv R 31.01/15345), p. 145.


12.

165 Margrit Kennedy, Interest and Inflation Free Money (Seva International, 1995):

During the Weimar Republic (1924-33), the central bank's president, Hjalmat
Schacht, had the desire to create an honest currency in Germany, whichin his
understandingmeant a return to the gold standard. Since he could not buy enough
gold on the world market adequate to the amount of money in circulation, he began
to reduce the latter. The shorter supply of money resulted in rising interest rates,
thereby reducing the incentives and possibilities for investment, forcing firms into
bankruptcy, and increasing unemployment, which led to the growth of radicalism and
finally helped Hitler to gain more and more power.

13.

166 Alex von Murat, The Wrgl Experiment with Depreciating Money (1934). Also,

see Fritz Schwartz, Das Experiment von Wrgl (Bern: Genossenschaft Verlag
Freiwirtschaftlicher Schriften, 1951), p. 14.

14.

167 Alex von Murat, The Wrgl Experiment with Depreciating Money (1934). Also,

see Fritz Schwartz, Das Experiment von Wrgl (Bern: Genossenschaft Verlag
Freiwirtschaftlicher Schriften, 1951), p. 14.

15.

168 Irving Fisher, Stamp Scrip (New York: Adelphi Co., 1933).


169 H.W. Brands, Traitor to His Class: The Privileged Life and Radical Presidency of

Franklin Delano Roosevelt (New York: Doubleday, 2008). Quoted in The Economist (1
November 2008), p. 83.


1.

170

See: <http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Currency_Act#Act_of_1764>. The Currency


Acts created tension between the colonies and the mother country, and were a
contributing factor in the coming of the American Revolution. In all of the colonies
except Delaware, the acts were considered to be a major grievance. When the First
Continental Congress met in 1774, it issued a Declaration of Rights, which outlined
colonial objections to certain acts of Parliament. Congress called on Parliament to
repeal the Currency Act of 1764, one of seven acts labeled "subversive of American
rights.

See also: Jack P. Greene, and Richard M. Jellison, The Currency Act of 1764 in
Imperial-Colonial Relations, 17641776, The William and Mary Quarterly, Third
Series, Vol. 18, No. 4 (October 1961), p. 517. John Phillip Reid, Constitutional
History of the American Revolution, III: The Authority to Legislate (Madison:
University of Wisconsin Press, 1991) p. 265.

CHAPTER TEN - The Blind Spot




1.

171 John Maynard Keynes, A Tract on Monetary Reform (1923).

CHAPTER ELEVEN - Great Change




1.

172 The National Center for Health Sciences, National Vital Statistics Report 47, no. 28,

Table 12. Estimated life expectancy at birth in years, by race and sex: deathregistration, United States, 1900-28, and 1929-97 (13 December 1999).
<http://www.cdc.gov/nchs>

2.

173 K. Bruce Newbold, Six billion plus: world population in the twenty-first century

(Lanham, Maryland: Rowman & Littlefield, 2007), p. 6. See also:


<http://www.thedailygreen.com/
environmental-news/latest/world-population-cartograms-47012201?click=main_sr>

3.

174 See: <http://www.worldmapper.org>


4.

175 Lily Nonomiya, Japan's Industrial Production Unexpectedly Declines Bloomberg

News (28 June 2007).



5.

176 Heather

Landym, Neil Irwin, Massive Shifts on Wall St. Troubled Investment


Bank To File for Bankruptcy, The Washington Post, p. A01 (15 September 2008).

6.

177 See: <http://www.efluxmedia.com/news_Financial_behemoth_Lehman_Brothers_largest_failure_in_US_24397.html>


7.

178 Barry

Ritholtz, Bernanke Bombshell: AIG Insurer Exposed to FP, 24 March


2009.
<http://www.ritholtz.com>.
See
also:
<http://ca.news.finance.yahoo.com/s/02032009/6/finance-aig-gets-new-aid-record-617-billion-loss.html>

8.

179 The salary boost just about matches the profit increase of 11 percent that Wall

Street analysts expect for the oil giant's 2008 profit, now pegged at just over $46
billion, according to a survey by FactSet Research. In 2009, analysts expect Exxon

Mobil's annual earnings to fall by about $8 billion to $34 billion as the energy boom
turned to bust. From Steve Gelsi, Exxon Mobil CEO Tillerson gets 10 percent
Raise, MarketWatch, The Wall Street Journal (3 December 2008).

9.

180 The Bank of England has now cut UK interest rates to an all-time low of 0.5

percent. From Christine Oliver, Interest Rates through the Ages: From Puritanism
to Prudence, The Guardian (5 March 2009). <http://www.guardian.co.uk>

10.

181 Adam Voiland, 2009: Second Warmest Year on Record; End of Warmest Decade,

NASA (28 January 2010). <http://www.nasa.gov/topics/earth/features/temp-analysis2009.html>



11.

182 Stephen Dinan, Obama signs massive stimulus bill, The Washington Times (17

February 2009).

12.

183 Sally Goerner, After the Clockwork Universe: The Emerging Science and Culture

of Integral Society. (Chapel Hill, NC: Triangle Center for Complex Systems, 1999).

184 Duane Elgin and Coleen LeDrew, Global Paradigm Change: Is a Shift Underway?

(San Francisco, CA: State of the World Forum, 2-6 October 1996).


1.

185 Thomas Griffith, This Turbulant World: People's Endless Struggles to Change

Their
Lives,
Time
(5
October
<http://www.time.com/time/magazine/article/0,9171,952063,00.html>

1983).


2.

186 The concept of Great Change was developed by the authors in collaboration with Dr. Sally Goerner (6 February 2006).


3.

187 Amy Maxmen, The Gut's Friendly Viruses Revealed, Nature, published online,

doi:10.1038/news.2010.353 (14 July 2010). It could be that viruses are the real
drivers of the system because of their ability to modify the bacteria that then modify
the human host.

4.

188 Jamshid Garajedaghi, Systems Methodology: A Holistic Language of Design and

Interaction Seeing through Chaos and Understanding Complexity.


<http://www.acasa.upenn.edu/JGsystems.pdf>

5.

189 Goerner, After the Clockwork Universe: The Emerging Science and Culture of

Integral Society.

6.

190 John Langone, Alternative Therapies Challenging the Mainstream, Time Special

Issue (Fall 1996), p. 40.


7.

191 John Langone, Alternative Therapies Challenging the Mainstream, Time Special

Issue (Fall 1996), p. 40.



8.

192 John A. Astin, Why Patients Use Alternative Medicine, Journal of the American

Medical Association, 279, no. 19 (1998), p. 1548-1553.



9.

193

James Robbins, Free market flawed, says survey, BBC News.


<http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/8347409.stm.>
See
also:
<http://www.bbc.co.uk/pressoffice/pressreleases/stories/2009/11_november/09/poll.shtm
Sharp Drop in American Enthusiasm for Free Market, Poll Shows GlobeScan (6
April 2011).
<http://www.globescan.com/news_archives/radar10w2_free_market/>

10.

194 Paul

Ray and Sherry Anderson, The Cultural Creatives (New York: Harmony
Books, 1999), with updates based on the original survey by Paul Ray, The Integral
Culture Survey: A Study of the Emergence of Transformational Value in America
(Research Monograph sponsored by the Fetzer Institute and the Institute of Noetic
Sciences, 1996).

11.

195

Duane Elgin and Coleen LeDrew, Global Paradigm Change: Is a Shift


Underway? (San Francisco, CA State of the World Forum, 2-6 October 1996).

12.

196

Duane Elgin and Coleen LeDrew, Global Paradigm Change: Is a Shift


Underway? (San Francisco, CA State of the World Forum, 2-6 October 1996).

13.

197 Paul Hawken, Blessed Unrest: How The Largest Movement in the World Came

Into Being and Why No One Saw It Coming (New York: Viking Press, 2007).

14.

198 Goerner, After the Clockwork Universe: The Emerging Science and Culture of

Integral Society.

15.

199 Astin, Why Patients Use Alternative Medicine.

CHAPTER TWELVE - Efficiency, Resilience, and Money




1.

200

Modern energy concepts and flow analyses were actually formally applied to
economics as early as 1951, by Nobel laureate Wassili Leontief with his input-output
analyses, modeling the flow of goods and value in economic systems. Ecologists then
applied these same flow concepts and analyses to ecosystems, only to have
economists later reapply these enhanced energy understandings to economics. Odum

(1971, 1984), Hannon (1973), and Costanza (1984), for example, have all used
thermodynamics and flow-network analysis as the basis for understanding the
activities in both economic and ecosystem networks; and Georgescu Roegen (1971)
developed an entire thermodynamic foundation for economics. Paul Samuelson
stated in 1965, in the Preface to Roegens Analytical Economics, that he considers
Roegen as A scholars scholar, and an economists economist. He added: I defy
any informed economist to remain complacent after meditating over this essay.
Nevertheless, complacency is what has greeted that book and its successor, Entropy
Law and the Economic Process.

2.

201 Predrag Cvitanovi, Introduction to Universality in Chaos (Bristol, UK: Adam

Hilger), p. 11.

3.

202

See: Robert Ulanowicz, Sally Goerner, Bernard Lietaer, and Rocio Gomez,
Quantifying Sustainability: Efficiency, Resiliency and the Return of Information
Theory, Journal of Ecological Complexity. The original paper is also available for
download on <http://www.lietaer.com>

4.

203 R.M. May, Will a large complex system be stable? Nature 238:413-414 (1972).


5.

204 C.S. Holling, Resiliency and the stability of ecological systems Annual Review of

Ecology and Systematics, 1973; and Brian H. Walker, John M. Anderies, Ann P.
Kinzig and Paul Ryan, Exploring Resiliency in Social-Ecological Systems:
Comparative Studies and Theory Development in a special issue of Ecology and
Society, 2006. Guest editors, Walker, Anderies, Kinzig, and Ryan, (Collingwood,
Victoria,
Australia:
CSIRO
Publishing).
Online
version:
<http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/viewissue.php?sf=22>

6.

205 Graphic was originally published in S. Goerner, R. Dyck, and D. Lagerroos, The

New Science of Sustainability: Building a Foundation for Great Change (Chapel


Hill, NC: Triangle Center for Complex Systems, distributed by Gabriel Island, BC,
Canada: New Society Publishers, 2008). Modified graphic in S. Goerner, B. Lietaer,
R. Ulanowicz, R. Quantifying economic sustainability: Implications for free
enterprise, theory, policy and practice. Ecological Economics 69 (1), p. 76-81.

7.

206 In the original literature this window is called a window of vitality given its

biological meaning in natural ecosystems. An ecosystem can support complex life


forms only within this range. See R.E. Ulanowicz, A Third Window: Natural
Foundations for Life (New York: Oxford University Press, 2008); and A.C. Zorach,
and R.E. Ulanowicz Quantifying the complexity of flow networks: How many roles
are there? Complexity 8(3): 68-76 (2003).

8.

207

On Aug. 14, 2003, more than 50 million North Americans find themselves
without power in the most widespread blackout in the history of electrical
civilization. <http://archives.cbc.ca/
science_technology/energy_production/clips/13545/>

9.

208

V.V. Gafiychuk, I.A. Lubashevsky, and R.E. Ulanowicz, Distributed selfregulation in ecological and economic systems, Complex Systems 11 (1997), p. 357372.

CHAPTER THIRTEEN - Sustainable Development




1.

209

See: Robert Ulanowicz, Sally J. Goerner, Bernard Lietaer, and Rocio Gomez,
Quantifying Sustainability: Resilience, efficiency and the return of information
theory, Ecological Complexity, 6(1), (27 March 2009), p. 36. Since sustainable
development requires a balance of efficiency and resilience, Ulanowicz (1980) used
configurations of flow pathways and magnitudes in natural ecosystems to develop a
measure of network efficiency called the Systemic Efficiency (SE or E), which
gauges overall system performance as well as its ability to pull more and more energy
into its sway, while reducing extraneous diversity/connectivity. The original paper is
also available for download on: <http://www.lietaer.com>. See also: Ulanowicz, A
hypothesis on the development of natural communities, Journal of Theoretical
Biology. 85 (1980), p. 223-245.

2.

210

See: Robert Ulanowicz, Sally J. Goerner, Bernard Lietaer, and Rocio Gomez,
Quantifying Sustainability: Resilience, efficiency and the return of information
theory, Ecological Complexity, 6(1), (27 March 2009), p. 36. Since sustainable
development requires a balance of efficiency and resilience, Ulanowicz (1980) used
configurations of flow pathways and magnitudes in natural ecosystems to develop a
measure of network efficiency called the Systemic Efficiency (SE or E), which
gauges overall system performance as well as its ability to pull more and more energy
into its sway, while reducing extraneous diversity/connectivity. The original paper is
also available for download on: <http://www.lietaer.com>. See also: Ulanowicz, A
hypothesis on the development of natural communities, Journal of Theoretical
Biology. 85 (1980), p. 223-245. See also: Robert E. Ulanowicz, C. Bondavalli, and
M.S. Egnotovich (1996). Network Analysis of Trophic Dynamics in South Florida
Ecosystems, FY 96: The Cypress Wetland Ecosystem, Annual Report to the United
States Geological Service Biological Resources Division (University of Miami, Coral
Gables, FL 33124: 1996).

3.

211

See: Robert Ulanowicz, Sally J. Goerner, Bernard Lietaer, and Rocio Gomez,

Quantifying Sustainability: Resilience, efficiency and the return of information


theory, Ecological Complexity, 6(1), (27 March 2009), p. 36. Since sustainable
development requires a balance of efficiency and resilience, Ulanowicz (1980) used
configurations of flow pathways and magnitudes in natural ecosystems to develop a
measure of network efficiency called the Systemic Efficiency (SE or E), which
gauges overall system performance as well as its ability to pull more and more energy
into its sway, while reducing extraneous diversity/connectivity. The original paper is
also available for download on: <http://www.lietaer.com>. See also: Ulanowicz, A
hypothesis on the development of natural communities, Journal of Theoretical
Biology. 85 (1980), p. 223-245. See also: Robert E. Ulanowicz, C. Bondavalli, and
M.S. Egnotovich (1996). Network Analysis of Trophic Dynamics in South Florida
Ecosystems, FY 96: The Cypress Wetland Ecosystem, Annual Report to the United
States Geological Service Biological Resources Division (University of Miami, Coral
Gables, FL 33124: 1996).

4.

212 E. Goldsmith, J. Mander, The Case Against the Global Economy and, For a Turn,

Towards the Local (Sierra Club Books, 1997) Cited in S. Goerner, B. Lietaer, R.
Ulanowicz, Quantifying economic sustainability: Implications for free enterprise,
theory, policy and practice, Ecological Economics, 69 (1), p. 78.

5.

213 Walmart: The High Cost of Low Prices (Brave New Films, 2005).


6.

214

Civic Economics, Austin Unchained (Austin,


<http://www.civiceconomics.com/Lamar_Retail_Analysis.pdf>

October

2003).


7.

215 The Economic Impact of Locally Owned Business vs Chains: A Case Study in Mid-coast Maine, New Rules Project, Institute for
Local Self-Reliance (ILSR) (Minneapolis, September 2003).


8.

216

Joseph Tainter, The Collapse of Complex Societies. (London: Cambridge


University Press, 1988).

9.

217 Joseph Stiglitz, Globalization and its Discontents (London, New York: Penguin

Books, 2002).

10.

218 Robert Pollin, Contours of Descent: U.S. Economic Fractures and the Landscape of Global Austerity. (London, New York: Verso,
2003).


11.

219 John Ralston Saul, The Collapse of Globalism and the Rebirth of Nationalism,

Harper's Magazine (March 2004), p. 33.



12.

220 Caprio and Klingelbiel, Bank Insolvencies: Cross Country Experience, Policy

Research Working Papers, no.1620 (Washington, DC: World Bank, Policy and
Research Department, 1996).


13.

221 For data on the growing disparity between rich and poor nations and individuals

see: Culpeper, Roy, 2005. Approaches to globalization and inequality within the
international system. In Overarching Concerns Programme Paper, no. 6 (Oct. 2005),
United Nations Research Institute for Social Development (UNRISD).

14.

222 Accompanied by jobless growth, meaning an increase in GDP growth that is

accompanied by a decrease in living-wage jobs. By 1995, for example, almost a third


of the worlds 2.8-billion person workforce was either jobless or working for such
low wages that they faced a life with little chance for advancement. For rates of
jobless growth see: Jeremy Rifkin, The End of Work: The Decline of the Global
Labor Force and the Dawn of the Post-Market Era (New York: Jeremy P. Tarcher,
1995).

15.

223 For details see: N. Klein, The Shock Doctrine: The Rise of Disaster Capitalism.

(New York: Holt and Company, 2008).



16.

224 Hazel Henderson, Paradigms in Progress: Life Beyond Economics (Indianapolis,

IN: Knowledge Systems, 1991); Creating Alternative Futures: the End of Economics
(West Hartford, CT: Kumarian Press 1966); and Ethical Markets: Growing a Green
Economy (White River Junction, Vermont: Chelsea Green Publishing, 2006).

17.

225 Paul Glover is the initiator of programs such as Ithaca HOURS, the Ithaca Health

Alliance, and Citizen Planners. He is author of Hometown Money: How to Enrich


Your Community with Local Currency (2005), and Recipe for Successful Local
Currency (2009)

18.

226

Thomas Greco, New Money for Healthy Communities (1994) ; Money:


Understanding and Creating Alternatives to Legal Tender (Chelsee Green, 2001);
The End of Money and the Future of Civilisation (White River Junction, Vermont:
Chelsea Green Publishing, 2009).

19.

227 Edgar S. Cahn, No More Throw Away People. (Washington, DC: Essential Books,

2004).

20.

228 Sergio Lub, creator of Friendly Favors. See: <http://www.favors.org/FF/>


21.

229 Susan Witt, was co-founder and Executive Director of the E. F. Schumacher Society, the predecessor of the New Economics
Institute, which launched the Berkshares currency and other initiatives.

CHAPTER FOURTEEN - LETS and Time Dollars



1.

230

It is particularly difficult to obtain up-to-date estimates of the number of


complementary currency systems operational worldwide. Such projects are by nature
local, and often people engaged in one type of complementary currency system
ignore what other types are operational, even in their own country. Furthermore, it
may even be harder to track when, for whatever reason, a system stops operating.
LETS systems are operating under its various names (Tauschring or Talent in
Germany, Green Dollars in Canada, SEL in France); the Timebanks in the UK; the
Regios in Germany; the Fureai Kippu in Japan, etc. The numbers for Japan, France,
Germany, Austria, Switzerland, and the Netherlands are the most recent and the best
quality. The corresponding sources are: For Japan, see Rui Izumi, The Development
and Future Challenges of the Community-Based Currencies in Japan, Keizaigaku
Ronshu (2006). For France, see: <http://selidaire.org/spip/rubrique.php3?
id_rubrique=211>. For Germany: there are 20 Regio systems in operation in
Germany, and another 33 in design process (see:<http://www.regiogeld.de/ ). In
addition, for the LETS type currencies, Simone Wagner from the University of
Konstanz simone.wagner@uni-konstanz.de has the most recently completed study
about Germany: Lokale Austauschnetzwerke - Entstehung, Stabilisierung und
sozialpolitische Bedeutung (forthcoming). See also: Susan Wagner, Diffusion of a
Social Movement: The Example of the German Local Exchange Systems ASA
Meeting
2007.
Also
see
websites:
<http://www.tauschringportal.de/Tauschringportal/index.htmlb>;
<http://www.tauschring.de/d0402add.htm>.
For
Austria:
<http://www.tauschkreise.at/>. There are also two Regio currencies operational in
Austria:
the
Waldviertler
and
the
Styrion.For
Switzerland:
<http://www.tauschnetz.ch/> and <http://www.tauschnetz.ch/orgliste.htm>. For the
Netherlands: <http://members.home.nl/letsdb/kaart.htm>. There exist also a number
of sources that are attempting to cover the global complementary currency scene.
Among the better ones, see: <http://www.complementarycurrency.org/>;
<http://www.cyberclass.net/turmel/urlsnat.htm>;
<http://www.lets-linkup.com/>;
<http://www.lets.org.au/>

2.

231 Michael Linton, interview


3.

232 James Taris, The LETSaholic Twist (Camberwell, Australia, 2005).


4.

233 All quotes from personal correspondence with Edgar Cahn, (8 July 2007).


5.

234 From Time Dollar website: <http://www.timedollar.org>


6.

235 R.

J. Sampson, S. W. Raudenbush; and F. Earls. Neighborhoods and violent


crime: A multilevel study of collective efficacy, Science 277 (15 Aug 1997), p. 918.


7.

236 Robert Wood Johnson Foundation: Service Credit Banking Project Site Summaries (University of Maryland Centre of Aging,
1990). This study shows the burn-out rate dropping from 40 percent to 3 percent thanks to the use of a Time Banking complementary
currency


8.

237 Time Dollars and Time Banking are gaining support from government officials. At a White House Conference on Aging,
Massachusetts and Wisconsin recommended using Time Dollars to work with the elderly. The British Secretary of Health has singled
out Time Banking as an effective mechanism to support informal healthcare.


9.

238 Time Banks USA, Time Bank Models: Youth at Risk, <http://www.timedollar.org> (15 September 2005).


10.

239 Time Banks USA, Time Bank Models: Youth at Risk, <http://www.timedollar.org> (15 September 2005).


11.

240 Time Banks USA, Time Bank Models: Youth at Risk, <http://www.timedollar.org> (15 September 2005).


12.

241 Time Banks USA, IRS Ruling, (23 February 2006). <http://www.timedollar.org>


13.

242 Linton Interview.


14.

243 Double coincidence of wants was coined by economist William Stanley Jevons.

See: W.S. Jevons, Money and the Mechanism of Exchange, (London: Macmillan,
1875), Chapter 1, paragraphs 5-6.

CHAPTER FIFTEEN - Social-Purpose Currencies



244 Toshiharu Kato, The New Model of Community Currency from Japan to the World: The Development of Eco-point Succeeding Ecomoney, (Aichi, Japan: World Exposition, February 2006).


245 Rui Izumi, The Development and Future Challenges of the Community-Based Currencies in Japan, Keizaigaku Ronshu (2006).


246 It is generally assumed that the first modern complementary currency system post-World War II is the LETS system started in Canada in
1982. In fact, the Japanese initiatives predate this by over a decade.


247 Mitsui Ichien, Report of Research on Desirable Models of Non-profit Welfare Activities for the Elderly (in Japanese), (Kansai: University
of Kansai: Research Institute of Ageless Society, 1991).


248 Yasuyuki (Miguel) Hirota, personal email message to Bernard Lietaer, (summer 2002).


249 Rui Izumi, Associate Professor at the School of Economics, Senshu University in Tokyo personal correspondence (July 2006): Major
factors that have contributed to the growth of local currencies: First, and perhaps surprisingly, was a program on national television in the late
1990s called Michael Ende's Last Message. This broadcast profiled complementary systems from the 1930s in Europe up (to) todays WIR,
LETS, and other popular systems. It touched a collective nerve. At that time, Japan was in deflationary depression after The East-Asian
Financial Crisis happened in 1997 and a bubble economic collapse in 1991, and these caused many Japanese people to wonder about
speculation and money. Second, Toshiharu Kato, a bureaucrat at Department of Trade and Industry, created the term Eco-money. Many
people felt an affinity with the term rather than the phrase community or complementary currency, and many books with the title containing the
term Eco-money were published.


250 For the developed countries belonging to the OECD, the number of people older than 65 has been growing from one out of 11 in 1965 to
one out of seven now. Over the next two decades, it could be as high as one out of four. The same is expected to happen in the developing
countries, one or two decades later. Peter G. Petersen, Gray Dawn: The Global Aging Crisis, Foreign Affairs (January-February 1999).


251 Rui Izumi, personal correspondence


252 As quoted in Makoto Maruyama, Local Currencies in New Zealand and Australia, in Junji Koizumi, ed., Dynamics of Cultures and
Systems in the Pacific Rim (Osaka: 2003), p. 183.


253 Dr. Gilson Schwartzs Creative Currencies project has a long history that dates back to 2003 when the City of Knowledge research
group, funded by the Presidency of Brazils Civil House Agency of Information Technology (ITI), developed mobile and complementary
currency pilot-projects in the beach resort of Pipa, in a Xavante village in Mato Grosso and in the midst of the jungle in Par (Abaetetuba).
Research into mobile technologies, innovative digital business models (such as crowdfunding) and cultural trends in the internet society over the
years led to the implementation of a second generation roadmap, leading to funding by the Ministry of Science and Technology, the Ministry of
Culture and the Brazilian Development Bank (Portuguese: Banco Nacional de Desenvolvimento Economico e Social, abbreviated: BNDES)
with the formal support of the central bank of Brazil.


254 Bernard Lietaer The Saber: An Education Currency for Brazil, The International Journal for Community Currency Research (27
February 2006). <http://www.uea.ac.uk/env/ijccr/abstracts/vol10(3)lietaer.html>


255 See: <http://www.cofc.edu/bellsandwhistles/research/retentionmodel.html>. See also: <http://www.know.org/>


256 F. Taddei, Training creative and collaborative Knowledge Builders: a major challenge for 21st century education (Paris: OECD, 2009).
Downloaded (15 June 2009) from: <http://q.liberation.fr/pdf/20090414/10901_telechargez-le-rapport.pdf>


257 Bernard Lietaer, Proposal for a Brazilian Education Complementary Currency, International Journal for Community Currency Research,
Vol. 10, pp. 18-23. <http://www.uea.ac.uk/env/ijccr/pdfs/IJCCR%20vol%2010%20(2006)%203%20Lietaer.pdf >


258 Thom Hartmann, Beyond ADD (Nevada City, California, Underwood Books, 1996).


259 See: H. Gardner, Frames of Mind: The Theory of Multiple Intelligences (Tufts University Press, 1993). See also: Thomas Armstrong,
Seven kinds of Smarts: Identifying and Developing your Multiple Intelligences (Plume Books, 1999)


260 Jeffrey Freed and Laurie Parsons Cantillo, Right-Brained Children in a Let-Brained World, Unlocking the Potential Of Your ADD Child
(New York: Simon and Schuster, 1997).


261 See: <http://visualspatial.org>


262 As reported to Stephen Belgin in a conversation with Jeffrey Freed and Laurie Parsons Cantillo (20 March 2011).


263 See: <http://visualspatial.org>


264 Marusa Vasconcelos Freire, Social Economy and Central Banks: Legal and Regulatory Issues On Social Currencies (Social Money) As
A Public Policy Instrument Consistent With Monetary Policy, International Journal Of Community Currency Research Vol 13 (2009) p. 76-94

CHAPTER SIXTEEN - Commercial-Purpose Currencies




1.

265 Webflyer Press Room edited by Randy Peterson. <http://www.webflyer.com>


2.

266

Bureau of Labor Statistics press release


<http://www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/empsit.pdf>

(11

March

2011).


3.

267 Jeannine

Aversa, Poll Finds Debt-Dogged Americans Stressed Out, (30 May


2010). <http://abcnews.go.com/Business/wireStory?id=10782052>


4.

268 AP-GfK Poll, Politics and Economy Topline (9 March 2010). <http://www.ap-

fkpoll.com/pdf/APGfK%20Poll%20March%202010%20Topline%20Release2%203.9.10.pdf>

5.

269 James Stodder, Complementary Credit Networks and Macro-Economic Stability:

Switzerlands Wirtschaftsring, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 72


(October 2009), p.7995; and , Reciprocal Exchange Networks: Implications for
Macroeconomic Stability, paper presented at the International Electronic and
Electrical Engineering (IEEE) Engineering Management Society (EMS) (Albuquerque,
NM, August 2000), p. 3.

6.

270

Tobias Studer, Le Systme WIR dans loptique dun chercheur Amrican


WirPlus (October 2000). <http://www.wir.ch>

7.

271 The system was ultimately credited with saving many of the businesses involved.


8.

272 WIR annual report 2006. See more details at: <http://www.wir.ch>

CHAPTER SEVENTEEN - The Terra, A Trade Reference Currency




1.

273 For those interested in acquiring a deeper understanding, please consult the White Paper available for download on web site.
<http://www.lietaer.com/2010/01/terra/>


2.

274 Such portfolio rebalancing can also be achieved through use of the futures markets in the relevant commodities, including the
possibility to take delivery of the commodity itself at maturity.


275 Shared by Paul Volcker with Bernard Lietaer personally.



1.

276 The overall discount rate to be applied to a project involves three components: the

interest rate on the currency, the risk of the project, and the cost of equity capital. The
demurrage fee is similar to a negative interest rate. Therefore, particularly for low risk
projects, the overall discount rate could be negative, making future cash flows more
valuable than those in the immediate future.

2.

277 In the year 1717, master of the Royal Mint Sir Isaac Newton established a new

mint ratio between silver and gold that had the effect of driving silver out of
circulation and putting Britain on a gold standard. However, only in 1821, following
the introduction of the gold sovereign coin by the new Royal Mint at Tower Hill in
the year 1816, was the United Kingdom formally put on a gold specie standard, the

first of the great industrial powers. Soon to follow was Canada in 1853,
Newfoundland in 1865, and the USA and Germany de jure in 1873. The USA used
the Eagle as their unit, and Germany introduced the new gold mark, while Canada
adopted a dual system based on both the American Gold Eagle and the British Gold
Sovereign. See: <http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Gold_standard>

CHAPTER EIGHTEEN - Two Worlds




1.

278 Paul Hawken,

Commencement Address to the Class of 2009 (University of


Portland, 3 May, 2009). <http://www.commondreams.org/view/2009/05/23-2>

2.

279 <http:data.worldbank.ort/indicator/FS.AST.PRVT.GD.ZS/countries /1W-US?display=graph>


3.

280 Betting the balance-sheet, Why managers loaded their companies with debt, A

special report on debt by The


<http://www.economist.com/node/16397174

Economist

(24

June,

2010).


4.

281 Adam Smith, Wealth of Nations, (1776), p. 929-30.


5.

282 Ludwig von Mises, Human Action, A Treatise on Economics (1949) 1st and 4th

editions. See online: <http://mises.org/resources/3250>



6.

283 Betting the balance-sheet, Why managers loaded their companies with debt, The

Economist (24 June 2010). <http://www.economist.com/node/16397174>



7.

284 The full list involves in alphabetical order: Abertis, Allen & Overy LLP, Barclays Capital, Carlyle Infrastructure Partners,
Chadbourne & Parke LLP, Citi Infrastructure Investors (CII), Credit Suisse, Debevoise & Plimpton, Freshfields Bruckhaus Deringer,
Fulbright & Jaworski, Mayer Brown, McKenna Long & Aldridge LLP, Merrill Lynch, Morgan Stanley, RBC Capital Markets, Scotia
Capital, and UBS. The document Benefits of private investment in infrastructure,was made public in January 2009.


8.

285 Euromoney (April 2010), p. 85.


9.

286 Nick Lord, The Road to Wiping Out the US Deficit, Euromoney (April 2010), p.

84-9.

10.

287 Nick Lord, The Road to Wiping Out the US Deficit, Euromoney (April 2010), p.

88.

11.

288

This includes several islands in the Venice lagoon, an ancient royal palace in
Palermo, and the Etruscan museum at Villa Giulia in Rome. John Follain, Hard-up
Italy sells islands and palaces Sunday Times (7 March 2010), p. 24.

12.

289 President Barack Obama, Presentation of the U.S. budget for 2010, (1 February 2010).

CHAPTER NINETEEN - Archetypes




1.

290 Gareth Cook, A Fish, a Gene, and a Source of Skin Color, The Boston Globe

(19 December 2005).



2.

291 The ancient Greeks considered the psyche to be the self, or soul, housed within

each individual, which is responsible for behavior. James Hillman, who developed
Archetypal Psychology, offers a more complex theory. Primarily, he notes that soul is
not a substance or entity that is located inside the brain or head of a person. Rather, it
is a perspective, a viewpoint towards things [it is] reflective; it mediates events
and makes differences (1975). Instead, Hillman sees human beings as in psyche.
The world, in turn, is the anima mundi, or the world ensouled. Hillman often quotes
a phrase coined by the Romantic poet John Keats: Call the world the vale of soulmaking. <http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Archetypal_psychology>

3.

292

Jacob Needleman, Money and the Meaning of Life (New York: Currency
Doubleday, 1991).

4.

293 The field of Archetypal Psychology was initiated by Carl Gustav Jung and further

developed by scholars such as Erich Neumann, Jolande Jacobi, Edward F. Edinger,


Christine Downing, and Jean Shinoda Bolen. James Hillman formally founded a
school of Archetypal Psychology.

5.

294

Elsewhere, Jung elaborates on this laconic statement: To the extent that the
archetypes intervene in the shaping of the conscious contents by regulating,
modifying, and motivating them, they act like instincts. Carl Gustav Jung, On the
Nature of the Psyche, Collected Works Volume 8: The Structure and Dynamics of
the Psyche (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1969), p. 408.

6.

295

Bernice Hill, Money and the Spiritual Warrior (Boulder: Five Centuries
Foundation, 2004), p. 17.

7.

296 Joseph Campbell, Myths to Live By, p.13.


8.

297 Eric Robertson Dodds, The Greeks and the Irrational (Berkeley: University of

California Press, 1951), p. 104.



9.

298 Carl Gustav Jung et al., Man and His Symbols (London: Picador, 1978), p. 101.

10.

299

Carl Gustav Jung, The Structure of the Psyche, (1927) in Collected Works
Volume 8, p. 342.

11.

300

Carl Gustav Jung, The Structure of the Psyche, (1927) in Collected Works
Volume 8, p. 342.

12.

301 Moore and Gillette developed their Quaternion map in five books, one for each

archetype, and one presenting a synthesis of their approach. They are: King, Warrior,
Magician, Lover (San Francisco: Harper Collins, 1991); The King Within (New York:
William Morrow, 1991); The Warrior Within (New York: William Morrow, 1992); The
Lover Within (New York: Avon Books, 1993); and The Magician Within (New York:
Avon Books, 1993). A number of modifications have been made to make these
archetypes more gender balanced and relevant to our purpose. For instance, the
Sovereign (Queen + King) is used instead of the King.

CHAPTER TWENTY - The Missing Archetype and Money




1.

302 Craig S. Barnes, The Great Goddess Debate, The Salt Journal: Reconstructing

Meaning 2, no. 3 (March-April 2000), p. 6.



2.

303 Marilyn Yalom, A History of the Breast (New York: Alfred Knopf, 1997), p. 9.


3.

304 Starhawk, The Spiral Dance: A Rebirth of the Ancient Religion of the Goddess

(San Francisco: Harper and Row, 1979).



4.

305 Marija Gimbutas, The Language of the Goddess: Unearthing the Hidden Symbols

of Western Civilization (San Francisco: Harper & Row, 1989), p. 321.



5.

306

This title is borrowed from the section on cattle currency in Glyn Davies, A
History of Money from Ancient Times to the Present Day (Cardiff: University of
Wales Press, 1994).

6.

307

Negley Farson, Behind Gods Back (London: Harcourt, Brace and Company,
1941), p. 264.

7.

308 From the same origin as the term capital punishment, referring to execution by severing the head.


8.

309 Georges Ifrah, Histoire Universelle des Chiffres (Paris: Robert Laffont, 1995), p.

180.

9.

310

Thorkild Jacobsen, The Treasures of Darkness: A History of Mesopotamian


Religion (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1976), p. 138.


10.

311 Demetra George, Mysteries

of the Dark Moon (San Francisco: Harper Collins,

1992), p. 162.

11.

312 Davies, A History of Money, p. 35.


12.

313 Davies, A History of Money, p. 35.


13.

314 Abb Breuil quoted in Jean Servier, Lhomme et linvisible (Paris, 1964), p. 37-8.


14.

315 Jean Chevalier and Alain Gheerbrant, Dictionnaire des Symboles (Paris: Robert

Laffont, 1982), p. 283.



15.

316 All her idols will be broken to pieces; all her temple gifts will be burned with fire;

I will destroy all her images. Since she gathered her gifts from the wages of
prostitutes, as the wages of prostitutes they will again be used. Holy Bible, Micah 6:8
NIV (Colorado Springs: International Bible Society, 1984).

16.

317

Patricia Monaghan, The Book of Goddesses and Heroines (St. Paul, MN:
Llewellyn Publications, 1990), p. 185.

17.

318

Patricia Monaghan, The Book of Goddesses and Heroines (St. Paul, MN:
Llewellyn Publications, 1990), p. 185.

CHAPTER TWENTY ONE - Repression of an Archetype




1.

319 James DeMeo, Saharasia: The 4000 BCE Origins of Child Abuse, Sex-repression,

Warfare and Social Violence in the Deserts of the Old World (Greensprings, OR:
Orgone Biophysical Research Lab, 1998).

2.

320 Philip Van Doren Stern, Prehistoric Europe, From Stone Age Men to the Early

Greeks (New York: W.W. Norton, 1969), p. 230, 302.



3.

321 For an architectural and archeological analysis of this process, see Vincent Scully,

The Earth, the Temple and the Gods: Greek Sacred Architecture (New Haven: Yale
University Press, 1979).

4.

322 Richard Tarnas, The Passions of the Western Mind: Understanding the Ideas that

Have Shaped Our World View (New York: Ballantine Books, 1991), p. 21.

5.

323

Aristotle, De Generatione Animalium II 3 (737a, 26-31) in The Works of


Aristotle, J.A. Smith and W.D. Ross, trans. (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1912).


6.

324 Aristotle, Politics, 1254b, p. 6-14.


7.

325

Sigmund Freud, Some Physical Consequences of the Anatomical Distinction


Between the Sexes (1925) in James Strachey, trans. and ed., The Standard Edition of
the Complete Psychological Works of Sigmund Freud (London: Hogarth Press, 19531974).

8.

326 Matthew 5:44-45 NIV.


9.

327 Jutta Voss, Frauenrequiem: Totenmesse fr alle Frauen die als Hexen ermordet

wurden (Stuttgart: Kreuz, 1989); Matilda Joslyn Gage, Women, Church, and State
(Watertown, MA: Persephone Press, 1980); Susan Griffin, Woman and Nature (New
York: Harper and Row, 1980), p. 17-8; Barbara Ehrenreich and Deirdre English,
Witches, Midwives and Nurses (New York: Feminist Press, 1973), p. 6-14; Gordon
Rattray Taylor, Sex in History (London: Thames & Hudson, 1953).

10.

328 In 1468, the Pope defined witchcraft as crimen exceptum, thereby eliminating any limits to the level of torture that could be
inflicted. The Dominican Order, initially created to combat the Cathar heresy, was now redirected to preach specifically against witches.
The Malleus Malleficiarum (Hammer to Kill Evils) was the official manual that prescribed the questions and correct answers, as well as
the tortures to be applied to obtain those answers. Armed with this document, Pope Innocent VIII officially started a holy war on
witches in 1488. This manual went through 29 editions over the next 300 years.

CHAPTER TWENTY TWO - Shadows




1.

329 Carl Gustav Jung, et. al., Man and his Symbols (London: Picador, 1978), p. 83.


2.

330 Another good definition of a shadow: A negative ego-personality that includes all

those qualities that we find painful or regrettable, from Carl Jung, Collected Works
Vol. 12: Psychology and Alchemy (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1980), p.
177 in footnote 178. Erich Neumann defines the shadow as the unknown side of the
personalityin the form of a dark, uncanny figure of evil to confront whom is
always a fateful experience for the individual. Erich Neumann, Depth Psychology
and a New Ethic (New York: G.P. Putnam and Sons, 1969), p. 137. Todays clinical
definition of shadow is an autonomous complex, often resulting from a childhood
trauma, of an aspect of ourselves that we do not accept.

3.

331 Translation of The Gospel of St. Thomas by Thomas O. Lambdin, B.P. Grenfell,

and A.S. Hunt, trans. <http://www.sacred-texts.com>


CHAPTER TWENTY THREE - Money and the Tao



1.

332 Jung developed this idea as the necessary integration of the animus (masculine

energy, which is conscious in men and unconscious in women) and anima (feminine
energy, which is conscious in women and unconscious in men). Human
individuation is defined as the full integration of both the animus and anima.

2.

333

Carl Gustav Jung, Collected Works Vol. 3, R.F.C. Hull, trans., (Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 1960), p. 203.

3.

334 Bernard Lietaer and Stephen Brunhubber, Money and SustainabilityThe Missing

Link: A report to the Club of Rome (2010).



4.

335

Lao-Tzu translated by Stephen Mitchell, Tao Te Ching (New York, Harper


Perennial, 1992).

5.

336 Humberto R. Maturana, The Organization of the Living: A Theory of the Living

Organization, Journal of Man-Machine Studies 7 (1975), p. 313-32 as quoted in


Riane Eisler, The Chalice and the Blade (New York: Harper Collins, 1987), p. 82.

CHAPTER TWENTY FOUR - Consequences of Repression




1.

337 James Hillman, Little Acorns: A Radical New Psychology, The Sun Magazine

(March 1998).

2.

338 What Matthew wrote in his gospel was that the love of money is the root of all

evil.

3.

339 Bono, Live Aid Concert (July 1985).


4.

340 Olusegun Obasanjo, comment on the G8 meeting (2000), <http://www.jubileeresearch.org>


5.

341 Soren Ambrose, Multilateral Debt: The Unbearable Burden (November 2001). <http://www.irc-online.org>


6.

342

Merriam-Webster, ed., Websters Third New International Dictionary of the


English Language, Unabridged (Springfield, MA: Merriam-Webster, 1993).

7.

343 Gustave Le Bon, The Crowd, A Study in the Popular Mind (London: T.F. Unwin,

1896, reprint 1921), p. 29.



8.

344 Wesley C. Mitchell, Analysis of Economic Theory, American Economic Review,

no. 15 (March 1925), p. 1-12.


345 Ondine Norman, Healing the Empty Self: Narcissism and the Cultural Shift from Dominance to Mutuality unpublished thesis (Pacifica
Graduate Institute, 1997), p. 8, 15.


346 Ondine Norman, Healing the Empty Self: Narcissism and the Cultural Shift from Dominance to Mutuality unpublished thesis (Pacifica
Graduate Institute, 1997), p. 38.



1.

347

Christopher Lasch, The Culture of Narcissism: American Life in an Age of


Diminishing Expectations (New York: Warner Books, 1979), p. 91.

2.

348 Mario Jacoby, Individuation and Narcissism: The Psychology of Self in Jung and

Kohut (New York: Routledge, 1990), p. 84.



3.

349 Stephen Donadio and Susan Davidson, eds., The New York Public Library Book of

Twentieth-Century American Quotations (New York: Warner Books, Inc., 1992).



4.

350 Jacoby, Individuation and Narcissism, p. 174.


5.

351 Susan Faludi, Stiffed: The Betrayal of the American Man (New York: William

Morrow, 1999), p. 9.

6.

352 Susan Faludi, Stiffed: The Betrayal of the American Man (New York: William

Morrow, 1999), p. 13.



7.

353 Bernice H. Hill, Money and the Spiritual Warrior (Boulder, CO: Five Centuries

Foundation, 2004), p. 56-9.



8.

354

Jacob Needleman, Money and the Meaning of Life (New York: Doubleday
Currency, 1994), p. 239.

CHAPTER TWENTY FIVE - The Central Middle Ages Revisited




1.

355 Erika Uitz, The Legend of Good Women: The Liberation of Women in Medieval

Cities (London, Wakefield: Myer Bell, 1994), p. 9.



2.

356 Joan Kelly-Gadol, Did Women Have a Renaissance? in Renate Bridenthal, Susan

Mosher Stuard, and Merry E. Wiesner (eds.), Becoming Visible: Women in European
History (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1977). This formally destroys Jacob Burckhardts
classic assessment of womens progress in The Civilization of the Renaissance in
Italy, Book Five, Chapter Five (New York: Harper, 1929).

3.

357 Uitz, The Legend of Good Women, p. 10.

4.

358 Rgine Pernoud, La Femme au Temps des Cathdrales (Paris: Stock, 1980), p. 84.


5.

359 Robert Lacey and Danny Danziger, The Year 1000: What Life was like at the Turn

of the First Millennium (London: Little Brown & Co, 1999), p. 164.

6.

360 Christine Fell, Women in Anglo-Saxon England (London: British Museum, 1984),

p. 109.

7.

361 Claude Marks, Pilgrims, Heretics and Lovers (New York: Macmillan, 1975).


8.

362 Pernoud, La Femme au Temps des Cathdrales, title of Chapter 7, p. 134.


9.

363 C.S. Lewis, The Allegory of Love (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1965),

p. 101.

10.

364 Meg Bogin, The Women Troubadours (New York, London: Norton & Co, 1980),

p. 12.

11.

365 Meg Bogin, The Women Troubadours (New York, London: Norton & Co, 1980),

p. 12.

12.

366 Denis de Rougemont, LAmour et lOccident (Paris: Union Gnrale dEditions,

1971).

13.

367 Ean Begg has been able to identify by name more than 500 such statues, but his

inventory is certainly incomplete given the large number of these statues that were
lost in fires, wars, or upheavals such as the French Revolution. See Ean Begg, The
Cult of the Black Virgin (London: Routledge, 1985). See also Pierre Gordon, Essais
sur les Vierges Noires (Neuilly sur Seine: Arma Artis, 1983).

14.

368

Petra von Cronenburg, Schwarze Madonnen: Das Mysterium einer Kultfigur


(Mnchen: Hugendubel Verlag, 1999), p. 172.

15.

369

Petra von Cronenburg, Schwarze Madonnen: Das Mysterium einer Kultfigur


(Mnchen: Hugendubel Verlag, 1999), p. 154.

16.

370 Pierre A. Riffard, Lsotrisme: Anthologie de lsotrisme Occidental (Paris:

Robert Laffont, 1990).



17.

371

See among others: Manuela Dunn Mascetti, Christian Mysticism (New York:
Hyperion, 1998).

18.

372

Malek Chebel, Dictionnaire des Symboles Musulmans: Rites, Mystique et

Civilization (Paris: Perrin, 1995); keywords: Sufisme, Nuit, Marie.



373 Jacques Bonvin, Vierges Noires: La Rponse vient de la Terre (Paris: Dervy Livres,

1988), p. 75.


1.

374 Begg, The Cult of the Black Virgin, p. 25-6.


2.

375

Louis Charpentier notes the surprise of the priest Vacandard on discovering,


between 1108 and 1115, a whole team of Hebraic scholars active in Citeaux, directly
under the supervision of Abbot Etienne Harding. See Louis Charpentier, Les Mystres
Templiers (Paris: Laffont, 1967), p. 15.

3.

376 Jacques Huynen, Lnigme des Vierges Noires (Paris: Robert Laffont, 1972), p.

116-7.

4.

377 At their height, it is estimated that 500,000 people traveled the pilgrimage routes

every year. See Claude Marks, Pilgrims, Heretics and Lovers (New York: Macmillan,
1975), p. 111.

378 Hans C. Binswanger, Geld und Magie: Deutung und Kritik der Modernen Wirtschaft

an hand von Goethes Faust (Stuttgart: Weinbrecht Verlag, 1985), p. 20-1.




1.

379 de Rougemont, LAmour et lOccident.


2.

380 The Kabbalah is reputed to have begun in Southern France and then spread to

Spain, where it flourished. See the article, Kabbale in Andr Vauchez, Dictionnaire
Encylcopdique du Moyen Age, Vol. 1 (Paris: Editions du Cerf, 1997), p. 8.

3.

381 Huynen, Lnigme des Vierges Noires. p. 145-9.


382 For instance, one of the classical dictionaries specializing in alchemy was written by

Don Pernety, a Benedictine monk from the abbey of Saint Maur, near Paris. See AntoineJoseph Pernety, Dictionnaire Alchimique and Les Fables Egyptiennes et Grecques
Dvoiles et Rduites au mme Principe (Paris: Delalain lAin, 1706).


1.

383

Carl Gustav Jung, Psychology and Alchemy, Bollingen Series, Volume XX


(Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1968).

2.

384

Carl Gustav Jung, Collected Works, Vol. XIV, Mysterium Conjunctionis


(Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1956), p. 44, note 72.

3.

385 See, for instance: Drers famous engraving entitled Melancholia. The Greek word melas means black.


4.

386 Jung, Psychology and Alchemy, Bollingen Series, Volume XX .


5.

387 Aurfontina Chymica (London: 1680), Alchemy on Line, <http://www.levity.com>


388 Robert Graves, Mammon and the Great Goddess (London: Cassells, 1964), p. 126.



1.

389 Until

the last third of the 11th century, one should really speak of Christian
Churches in the plural, rather than the singular. The Church of Rome tried to present
itself as a coordinator for Christianity, but before the 12th century the practice was
completely different. Giuseppe Sergi, LIde du Moyan Age: Entre Sens Commun et
Pratique Historique (Paris: Flammarion, 1999), p. 75-6.

2.

390 Robert Moore, La Perscution sa Formation en Europe, 950-1250 (Paris: Les

Belles-Lettres, 1991) and A la Naissance de la Socit Perscutrice: les Clercs, les


Cathares et la Formation en Europe, in La Perscution du Catharisme, XII-XIVe
sicle. Actes de la 6ieme Session dHistoire Mdivale (Carcassonne: Centre
dEtudes Cathares, 1996), p. 11-37.

3.

391 Anne Brenon, La Catharisme Mridional: Questions et Problmes, in Jacques

Berlioz, Le Pays Cathare: Les Religions Mdivales et Leurs Expressions


Mridionales (Paris: Editions du Seuil, 2000), p. 87.

4.

392 Until 1246, the king of France had no authority over any part of the southern half of France or any access to the Mediterranean
area. The Crusade against the Albigensians would give him both.


393 The

detailed texts of the Inquisitor Jacques Fournier have been preserved for the
period 1318 to 1325. The analysis by Jacques Berlioz reveals that the Inquisitors ultimate
purpose was not really about doctrinal issues, but aimed at crushing any local powers that
might oppose the centralizing power of either the king or the Pope, or the payment of
papal tax (la dime). Jacques Fournier was in fact working at the elimination of any local
forces who might limit the Kings power. See Berlioz, Le Pays Cathare, p. 62.


1.

394 Jacques Berlioz, Tuez-les Tous. Dieu Reconnatra les Siens. Le Massacre de Bzier

at la Croisade des Albigeois vus par Csaire de Heisterbach (Portet-sur-Garonne:


Loubatires, 1994).


2.

395 von Cronenburg, Schwarze Madonnen: Das Mysterium einer Kultfigur, p. 143-7.


3.

396 von Cronenburg, Schwarze Madonnen: Das Mysterium einer Kultfigur, p. 149.


4.

397 Jacques Turgot, ncient Guild Statutes of France (1776).

CHAPTER TWENTY SIX - Dynastic Egypt




1.

398 The dates are calculated from ancient lists, especially the Turin royal papyrus, and

from various other sources. The margin of error is from a decade or so in the 3rd
Intermediate Period and New Kingdom to perhaps 150 years for the 1st Dynasty;
dates for the 3rd Millennium are given for whole dynasties and are rounded, as are
numerous later dates. From the 12th Dynasty on, possible sequences of dates can be
calculated from astronomy; currently accepted sequences are used here. Dates from
664 BCE on are precise to within a year, <http://www.bbc.co.uk>. A more extensive
study of the Egyptian dual currency system andd its effects on society is available in
Chapter Six of Bernard Lietaer Mysterium Geld: Emotionale Bedeutung und
Wirkungsweise eines Tabus (Munich: Riemann Verlag, 2001)

2.

399 Moses I. Finley, The Ancient Economy, Sather Classical Lectures 43 (Berkeley:

University of California Press, 1985), p. 138



3.

400

Joyce Tyldesley, The Daughters of Isis: Women in Ancient Egypt (London:


Penguin Books, 1995), p. 104.

4.

401

Joyce Tyldesley, The Daughters of Isis: Women in Ancient Egypt (London:


Penguin Books, 1995), p. 106-7.

5.

402 Finley, The Ancient Economy, p. 166.


6.

403 Moses I. Finley, The Ancient Economy, Sather Classical Lectures 43 (Berkeley:

University of California Press, 1985), p. 112.



7.

404 Moses I. Finley, The Ancient Economy, Sather Classical Lectures 43 (Berkeley:

University of California Press, 1985), p. 155.



8.

405 Moses I. Finley, The Ancient Economy, Sather Classical Lectures 43 (Berkeley:

University of California Press, 1985), p. 138.



9.

406

Brian Handwerk, Pyramid Builders' Village Found in Egypt, National


Geographic
News
(Updated18
September
2002),

<http://news.nationalgeographic.com/news/2002/08/0805_020805_giza.html>. There are several possibilities for


the ill health of the workers, including that they were from a low caste of Egyptian
society and trying to start a new life in challenging, arid conditions. Additionally,
there could have been sabotage of the project given that Akhenaten broke away from
the priests and the doctrine of the time.

10.

407 Alaa Shahine, Study shows life was tough for ancient Egyptians, Reuters, U.K.

Edition (30 March 2008) <http://uk.reuters.com/article/2008/03/30/us-egyptarchaeology-study-idUKL2886575820080330>



11.

408 Pharaoh Akhenaten, who abandoned most of Egypt's old gods in favor of the Aten sun disk, built and lived in Tell el-Amarna in
central Egypt for 17 years. The city was largely abandoned shortly after his death and the ascendance of the famous boy king
Tutankhamen to the throne.


12.

409

Friedrich Preisigke, Girowesen im Griechischen gypten enthalted Korngiro,


Geldgiro, Girobanknotariat mit Einschlu des Archivwesens (Strasbourg: Verlag von
Schlesier and Schweikhardt, 1910; reprint, Hildesheim and New York: Georg Olms,
(1971), p. 13.

13.

410

Hugo Godschalk, Wurden die gyptischen Pyramiden mit einer DemurrageWhrung gebaut? Zeitschrift fr Sozialkonomie, no.149 (June 2006). The idea that
demurrage currencies were first initiated during the Ptolemaic period on the basis of
Preisigkes work would be similar to assuming on the basis of a book entitled 19th
Century Dutch Paintings that there were no paintings in Holland during the 16th,
17th, or 18th century.

14.

411 Finley, The Ancient Economy, p. 166.


15.

412

Friedrich Preisigke, Girowesen im Griechischen gypten enthalted Korngiro,


Geldgiro, Girobanknotariat mit Einschlu des Archivwesens (Strasbourg: Verlag von
Schlesier and Schweikhardt, 1910; reprint, Hildesheim and New York: Georg Olms,
(1971).

16.

413 No fewer that 1.6 million ostraka have been gathered in the dynastic village of Medinet, currently in the Egyptian desert. Almost all
remain untranslated to this day.


17.

414 Medinet was believed to be where the Ogdoadthe four pairs of first primeval godswere buried, and was also one of the
earliest places within the Theban region to be associated with the worship of Amun.


18.

415 Preisigke, Girowesen im Griechischen gypten, p. 13.


19.

416 Preisigke, Girowesen im Griechischen gypten, p. 101.


20.

417 Preisigke, Girowesen im Griechischen gypten, p. 75.

CHAPTER TWENTY SEVEN - Dynastic Egypt Revisited




1.

418 Anne

Baring and Jules Cashford, The Myth of the Goddess: Evolution of an


Image (London: Penguin Books, Arkana, 1993), p. 250.

2.

419 Isis was originally the throne personified. The throne made manifest a divine

power that changed every one of several princes into a king fit to rule. It is
interesting that this all-important throne symbolism of Isis was incorporated in the
medieval Black Madonna as the cathedra, one of her unique identifying
characteristics. Henri Frankfort, Ancient Egyptian Religion (New York: Harper and
Row, Torch Books, 1961), p. 17.

3.

420 These precautions were both precise and exacting. They included that the dead

remember a series of elaborate passwords at different stages of the journey in the


underworld (hence the Egyptian Book of the Dead which accompanied each burial,
and which provided a textbook reminder of those stages and the relevant magical
passwords for each) as well as the appropriate physical supports for the afterlife. The
Egyptians believed that what we call the human soul was made of three
components, respectively the Ka, the Ba, and what we might call the individual
consciousness. The Ka was destined to remain close to the corpse; the Ba was
represented as a human-headed bird that could leave the tomb but sometimes needed
to return; and finally, the consciousness would experience the journey into the
afterlife. All three needed to be taken care of, hence the need to preserve the body
forever through mummification, and the elaborate food, furniture, and other amulets
that would be necessary for a successful journey toward and life in the realm of
Osiris. If the transition failed for whatever reason, there would be a second and final
death. Therefore, to the Egyptians, the first physical death was inevitable but not
necessarily final. Hence the importance of taking all the right precautions to ensure a
pleasant afterlife, since, according to the Egyptians, you really had a chance to take it
all with you.

4.

421 Erich Neumann, The Great Mother, Bollington Series XLVII (Princeton: Princeton

University Press, 1955), p. 223.



5.

422

Myrionymos (whose names are innumerable) is significantly different from


polynomos (whose names are numerous). Several gods and goddesses were referred
to as having many names (e.g., Aphrodite, Apollo, Helios, Hermes, Artemis).
Reginald Eldred Witt, Isis in the Ancient World (Baltimore, London: The Johns
Hopkins University Press, 1971), p. 121: Isis, however, was the only divinity whose

epiclesis marked that the number of her names was not merely large but infinite. It
was in this endless diversity that her uniqueness rested. It was the source of her
strength, and her weakness. She alone claimed an infinity of divine titles and became
all things to all men. She could be chaste and yet raise the phallus. She could banish
lifes storms by her calm and yet become the Roman goddess of war. And, p. 138:
To many critics the picture may seem riddled with contradictions. But the evidence
that Isis is mutilated by the removal of any of these elements is irrefutable. In the
archetypal yin-yang framework, she perfectly embodies the yin capacity to hold
ambivalence.

6.

423 Georges Posener, Dictionnaire

de la Civilisation Egypytienne (Paris, 1959), p.

140.

7.

424 Witt, Isis in the Ancient World, p. 137.


8.

425 Robert

R. Briffault, The Mothers, Vol. 1 (New York: Charles Scribner's Sons,


1924), p. 384.

9.

426 Janet H. Johnson, The Legal Status of Women in Ancient Egypt, in Anne K.

Capel and Glenn E. Markoe, eds., Mistress of the House, Mistress of the Heavens:
Women in Ancient Egypt (New York: Hudson Hills Press, 1996), p. 175.

10.

427 Janet H. Johnson, The Legal Status of Women in Ancient Egypt, in Anne K.

Capel and Glenn E. Markoe, eds., Mistress of the House, Mistress of the Heavens:
Women in Ancient Egypt (New York: Hudson Hills Press, 1996), p. 183. The marriage
contract acted like annuity contracts since they were concerned predominately with
financial matters.

11.

428

Joyce Tyldesley, The Daughters of Isis: Women in Ancient Egypt, (London:


Penguin Books, 1995), p. 48.

12.

429

Joyce Tyldesley, The Daughters of Isis: Women in Ancient Egypt, (London:


Penguin Books, 1995), p. 58.

13.

430 Witt, Isis in the Ancient World, p. 41. Original quote from Diodorus Siculus in

Geography of Strabo Book I (Boston: Loeb Classical Library, Harvard University


Press), p. 27.

14.

431 Gay Robins, Women in Ancient Egypt (London: British Museum Press, 1993).


15.

432

When no other references are provided, the data from this section refers to
Catherine H. Roehrig, Womens Work: Some Occupations of Non-Royal Women as

Depicted in Ancient Egyptian Art, in Capel and Markoe, eds., Mistress of the House,
Mistress of the Heavens, p. 13-24.

16.

433 Herbert E. Winlock, Excavations at Deir el-Bahri 1911-1931 (New York: 1942),

p. 226.

17.

434 Henry Fischer, Administrative Titles of Women in the Old and Middle Kingdom,

in Egyptian Studies; William Ward, Non-Royal Women and their Occupations in the
Middle Kingdom, in Lesko, ed., Womens Earliest Records; Gay Robins, Women in
Ancient Egypt, p. 114-7.

18.

435 Four women ascended to the Egyptian throne: Nitokret (Dynasty 6), Sobeknefru (Dynasty 12), Hatshepsut (Dynasty 18) and
Tauseret (Dynasty 19).


19.

436 Quoted by Sir Alan Gardiner, Egypt of the Pharaohs (Oxford: Oxford University

Press, 1961), p. 431.



20.

437

Delightful translations of Egyptian love poetry can be found in Tor SveSderberg, Pharaohs and Mortals (New York: Bobbs Merrill, 1961), particularly the
chapter entitled, In the Shade of the Sycamores: of Perfumes and Love.

21.

438 Merlin Stone, When God was a Woman (San Diego: Harcourt Brace, 1976), p. 35-

8.

22.

439

Gerda Lerner, The Creation of Patriarchy (Oxford: Oxford University Press,


1986), p. 114.

23.

440 Louis M. Epstein, Sex Laws and Customs in Judaism (New York, 1948), p. 194.


24.

441 Lerner, The Creation of Patriarchy, p. 115-6.


25.

442 Peter B. Ellis, Celtic Women (Grand Rapids: William Eerdmans Publishing Co.,

1995), p. 99

26.

443 On Men and Women from Oikonomikos (ca. 370 BCE).


27.

444 The third class was known as the Hetaerae. The hetaerae, unlike the slaves and

the citizens, were much akin to the Geisha's of China. Hetaerae women were given an
education in reading, writing, and music, and were allowed into the Agora and other
structures, which were off limits to citizen and slave women. Most sources about the
Hetaerae indicate however, that their standing was at best at the level of prostitutes,
and the level of power they attained was only slightly significant. From: The
Women of Athens, Ancient Greek Civilizations (Minnesota State University).


28.

445 Tyldesley, The Daughters of Isis: Women in Ancient Egypt, back cover page.


29.

446 Witt, Isis in the Ancient World, p. 110.


30.

447 Moses I. Finley, The Ancient Economy, Sather Classical Lectures 43, (Berkeley:

University of California Press, 1985), p. 99.



31.

448 Jean Chevalier and Alain Gheerbrant, Dictionnaire des Symbols, (Paris: Laffont,

1983), p. 524.

32.

449 Fred Gustafson, The Black Madonna, (Boston: Sigo Press, 1990), p. 90.


450 Witt, Isis in the Ancient World, p. 193-4



1.

451 Black Madonna statues, like others, were burned during the French Revolution of

1793. In Chartres it was done under the cries A bas lEgyptienne, literally Down
with the Egyptian one!

2.

452

H. W. Mller, in Mnchener Jahrhundert Bild Kunst (1963), p. 35, cites the


original passage documenting this episode from Histoire Gnalogique de la Maison
des Brionnet (1620). Witt also mentions this same episode in Witt, Isis in the Ancient
World, p. 274. Dr. Witt conjectures that this Isis statue was also a Black Madonna.

3.

453

Faujas de Saint-Fons study entitled, Recherches sue les Volcans teints du


Vivarais et du Velay, is primarily a geological report, but it also contains the notes of
his investigations on the Black Madonna of Le Puy. See also: Bonvin, Vierges Noires:
La Rponse vient de la Terre, p. 205-12, and von Cronenburg, Schwarze Madonnen,
p. 35-8.

4.

454 The engraved Table of Isis (Mensa Isaica), dating back to the first century CE, was discovered in 1720 and exhibited in 1775 in
the Royal Archives at the Egyptian Museum of Turin. Faujas de Saint-Fons, in referring to this piece, may, therefore, have based his
findings not only on published records, but also on first-hand exposure to these hieroglyphs, making his testimony more valid.


5.

455 The subtitle of his book makes this explicit: Guy Bois, La Grande Dpression

Mdivale du XIVe et XVe Sicles: Le Prcdent dune Crise Systmique (Paris: PUF,
2000).

CHAPTER TWENTY EIGHT - The Balinese Exception



456 Tyra de Kleen, Bali: Its Dances and Customs, Sluyters Monthly 2 (1921), p. 129.


1.

457

Michel Picard, Bali: Cultural Tourism and Touristic Culture (Singapore:


Archipelago Press, 1996), p. 138.

2.

458

Clifford Geertz and Hildred Geertz, Kinship in Bali (Chicago: University of


Chicago Press, 1987) and Carol Warren, Adat and Dinas: Balinese Communities in
the Indonesian State (Kuala Lumpur: Oxford University Press, 1993).

3.

459

Agung and Purwita, Pemantapan Adat Dalam Menunjang Usaha-Usaha


Pembangunan (Denpasar: Majelis Pembina Lembaga Ada, 1983), p. 18.

4.

460

Fred B. Eiseman, Bali Sekala and Niskala: Essays on Society, Tradition and
Craft, Volume II (Berkeley: Periplus Editions, Inc., 1989), p. 74.

5.

461 Geertz and Geertz, Kinship in Bali.


6.

462 Pak Ketut Suartana, personal interview, Klian Banjar Sambahan, North Ubud Banjar, Ubud Kaja (30 July 2002).


463 Pak Wayan Suecha, personal interview, Klian Banjar KelodUbud (6 August 2002).



1.

464 The study of the Balinese dual-currency system was part of a four-month research

project performed by Bernard Lietaer and Stephen Demeulenaere in 2002 on the


economics of Banjars in the area of Ubud, the cultural capital of Bali. Any
quotations without specific references in this chapter come from field notes from
interviews during this research. For published results see: Bernard Lietaer and
Stephen Demeulenaere, Sustaining Cultural Vitality in a Globalizing World: the
Balinese Example, International Journal for Social Economics (September 2003).

2.

465 In most cases, enough people can be found to contribute the time needed to complete an activity. Therefore, such contributions do
not even have to be recorded. In those Banjars, however, whose members have less time available, or if complaints are logged about
the lack of contribution by others, time contributions are recorded by the Klian Banjar. Those who cannot contribute their share of time
are asked to send a substitute person, to whom they then owe a similar service. If neither option is possible, they must pay a charge
of between 5,000 and 10,000 Rupiah for each time block missed. Nevertheless, substitutions in Rupiah can only be partial and
conditional. They are not acceptable as a systematic way to avoid service to and personal participation in the Banjar.


3.

466 Geertz and Geertz, Kinship in Bali.


4.

467 Kepeng is etymologically related to the word chip or fragment. This is likely a

reference to the traditional square hole in the middle of each Uang Kepeng coin. See:
S. Hassan and J. Echols, Kamus Indonesia-Inggris (PT Gramedia, Jakarta, Indonesia,
2004).

468 Ida Bagus Sidemen, Nilai Historis Uang Kepeng (Historical Value of Uang Kepeng),

(Denpasar, Bali: Larasan-Sejarah, 2002). The oldest Uang Kepeng coins found in Bali
were minted by the Chinese Tang Dynasty (618-909 CE). Other types of trading coins and
brass gongs have been discovered in Bali, some of which originate from the Dong Son
culture of Vietnam in the 4th century CE.

469 Ida Bagus Sidemen, Nilai Historis Uang Kepeng (Historical Value of Uang Kepeng),

(Denpasar, Bali: Larasan-Sejarah, 2002). The oldest Uang Kepeng coins found in Bali
were minted by the Chinese Tang Dynasty (618-909 CE). Other types of trading coins and
brass gongs have been discovered in Bali, some of which originate from the Dong Son
culture of Vietnam in the 4th century CE

470 Ida Bagus Sidemen, Nilai Historis Uang Kepeng (Historical Value of Uang Kepeng),

(Denpasar, Bali: Larasan-Sejarah, 2002). The oldest Uang Kepeng coins found in Bali
were minted by the Chinese Tang Dynasty (618-909 CE). Other types of trading coins and
brass gongs have been discovered in Bali, some of which originate from the Dong Son
culture of Vietnam in the 4th century CE


1.

471 De Kat Angelino, Arnold Dirk Adriaan. (1930) Staatkundig beleid en bestuurszorg

in Nederlandsch-Indie. Gravenhage: Nijhoff.



2.

472

M.Covarrubias, Island of Bali, (First edition: New York: Knopff 1937),


(republished: Singapore: Periplus, 1998).

3.

473 Personal communication between Stephen DeMeulenaere and the authors (May 2007).


4.

474 Technically, the Uang Kepeng is still a yang currency, given that it was not created

by the Balinese themselves but imported into Bali from abroad (i.e. the Chinese
merchants). But it can be considered as a weak yang currency compared to
conventional national moneys such as the Rupiah, because of its lack of or weak
enforcement of the interest feature. Therefore, strictly speaking, what has happened
since the 1950s in Bali is the gradual replacement of the dual currency system of Uang
Kepeng and the Banjar time currency (a dual currency system consisting of a weak
yang complementing a strong yin) to a Rupiah and Banjar time currency (a dual
currency system consisting of a strong yang complementing strong yin). However,
such a shift seems to have had a sufficient effect to contribute to some changes in the
social behavior patterns among the Balinese. Obviously, we do not claim that the shift
towards a more yang currency by itself is the only cause for the gradual degradation
of the yin-yang balance in Balinese society. Other factors mentioned in the text, and
changes such as the introduction of commercial television in the local language, also
play contributing roles. As with all social changes, we are dealing with complex

mutually reinforcing processes, in which even subtle monetary changes can play a
non-negligible role.

5.

475 With Nyoman Bahuha, Klian Banjar of Banjar Kaja in Ubud (2 August 2002).


6.

476

Francine Brinkgreve and David Stuart-Fox, Offerings: The Ritual Art of Bali
(Singapore: Select Books, 1992), p. 199-219.

7.

477 Bali: A Travellers Companion (Singapore: Editions Didier Millet Pte Ltd., 1995),

p. 57.

8.

478 Miguel Covarrubias, Island of Bali (New York: Alfred Knopf, 1946), p. 359.


9.

479 Miguel Covarrubias, Island of Bali (New York: Alfred Knopf, 1946), p. 361.


480 Bernard Lietaer, A World in Balance, Reflections:

Journal of the Organizational

Learning Society (Summer 2003).




1.

481 Viebeke L. Asana, Now We Move Forward! See: <http://www.foothill.net>


2.

482 On 8 November 2008 three Islamist militants were sentenced to death and executed

in an Indonesian prison for their involvement in the 2002 bombing. Source:


<http://www.bbc.co.uk/news>

3.

483

Berfungsi Religius: Uang Kepeng Perlu Diproduksi Kembali (Religious


Function: Uang Kepeng Needs to be Produced Again), The Bali Post (23 December
2003). See: <http://www.balipost.co.id
/balipostcetak/2003/12/23/b4.htm>; also Keberadaan Pis Bolong di Bali: Dulu Uang Kartal,
Sekarang Sarana Budaya (The History of Pis Bolong [Uang Kepeng] in Bali,
Formerly a medium of Exchange, Today a Medium of Culture) The Bali Post 10
January 2004. <http://www.balipost.co.id/balipostcetak/2004/1/10/topik.html>

You might also like