United States Court of Appeals, Third Circuit
United States Court of Appeals, Third Circuit
United States Court of Appeals, Third Circuit
2d 1224
Petruzzi's IGA Supermarket, Inc. (Petruzzi's IGA), for itself and on behalf of
the class it represents, appeals from the district court's July 31, 1992 order
entering summary judgment in favor of defendants Darling-Delaware
Company, Inc. (Darling), The Standard Tallow Corp. (Standard), and Moyer
Packing Company (Moyer). Petruzzi's IGA does not appeal from an earlier
order of the district court dismissing a fourth defendant, Herman Isacs, Inc.,
pursuant to Fed.R.Civ.P. 12(b)(2) because of a lack of personal jurisdiction.
See 677 F.Supp. 289 (M.D.Pa.1987).1 In its complaint, Petruzzi's IGA alleged
that the defendants conspired to allocate customers in the fat and bone
rendering industry in violation of section 1 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1.
However, after considering the evidence put forward by Petruzzi's IGA in
response to the defendants' motions for summary judgment, the district court
concluded that Petruzzi's IGA failed to raise a genuine issue of material fact to
controvert the defendants' denial that there was a conspiracy among the
remaining defendants. District Court's Opinion (Opin.) at 65. Because we
disagree in part with the district court's view of the evidence and in part with its
application of the appropriate legal standards, we will reverse its July 31, 1992
order insofar as it granted summary judgment to Darling and Moyer. However,
because we agree that the evidence put forward does not tend to exclude the
possibility that Standard acted independently, see Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite
Serv. Corp., 465 U.S. 752, 764, 104 S.Ct. 1464, 1471, 79 L.Ed.2d 775 (1984),
we will affirm the district court's grant of summary judgment to Standard.2
I.
BACKGROUND
2
This case involves an allegation of a restraint of trade in the fat and bone
rendering industry. In this industry, rendering companies, such as the
defendants, purchase inedible fats, bones, suet, and meat trimmings (raw
materials) from suppliers, such as butcher shops, supermarkets, restaurants,
hotels, and government agencies. These companies then process the raw
materials into finished products such as tallow, grease, animal feed, and
fertilizer.
On March 14, 1986, Petruzzi's IGA filed a class action in the United States
District Court for the Middle District of Pennsylvania against Darling,
Standard, Moyer, and Herman Isacs, Inc., alleging that from as early as January
1, 1977, to at least December 31, 1985, the defendants conspired to allocate
existing raw material accounts in the fat and bone rendering industry in parts of
Pennsylvania, New Jersey, and Connecticut. According to the complaint, the
defendants violated section 1 of the Sherman Act by: (1) agreeing to refrain
On April 1, 1991, the three defendants remaining after the dismissal of Herman
Isacs, Inc., moved for summary judgment, citing an absence of evidence of
concerted action. In response to these motions, Petruzzi's IGA submitted a large
amount of evidence which it contended demonstrated the existence of an
agreement among the remaining defendants. Of significance, Petruzzi's IGA
submitted: (1) testimony from Howard Salisbury and Ralph Ebersole, two
former employees of Moyer; (2) secretly taped recordings of conversations
between principals of Ryder Rendering Company, a former competitor of the
defendants, and principals of Moyer (the Ryder tapes); (3) testimony of two
economists who concluded that the defendants conspired not to compete for
existing raw material accounts; (4) deposition testimony of representatives of
the defendants; (5) a memorandum prepared by Michele Ellerin, the former
wife of Lee Ryder, a co-owner of Ryder Rendering (the Ellerin memorandum);
(6) records of five past civil and criminal antitrust actions involving the
defendants and/or their employees; (7) phone records of the defendants and
their principals indicating numerous phone calls to each other over the years;
and (8) evidence of socializing by principals of the defendants. Petruzzi's IGA's
evidence describes the limited nature of competition for existing accounts and
several instances of retaliation against noncomplying rendering companies.
Despite this evidence, the district court granted the defendants summary
judgment because it determined that Petruzzi's IGA had not put forward
evidence which tended to exclude the possibility that the defendants acted
independently. Opin. at 65. In addition, the court stated that summary judgment
was appropriate because the defendants "have met plaintiff's evidence with
plausible business reasons justifying the conduct called into question." Opin. at
66. Petruzzi's IGA then appealed.
II.
DISCUSSION
6
As was the case here, at the summary judgment stage antitrust defendants often
maintain that the plaintiff has not offered sufficient proof that they acted in
concert and accordingly did not satisfy the first element of a section 1 claim.
See, e.g., Big Apple BMW, Inc. v. BMW of North America, Inc., 974 F.2d
1358, 1364 (3d Cir.1992), cert. denied, --- U.S. ----, 113 S.Ct. 1262, 122
L.Ed.2d 659 (1993). And, as noted above, the district court agreed with the
defendants. Petruzzi's IGA argues that the district court erred in this
determination because it proffered evidence sufficient to allow a reasonable
jury to conclude that the defendants acted in concert. Petruzzi's IGA asserts that
the district court not only improperly discounted evidence that supported an
inference of collusion, but also improperly compartmentalized the evidence
Petruzzi's IGA put forth.
F.2d at 1363. Rather, in all cases summary judgment should be granted if, after
drawing all reasonable inferences from the underlying facts in the light most
favorable to the nonmoving party, the court concludes that there is no genuine
issue of material fact to be resolved at trial and the moving party is entitled to
judgment as a matter of law. Where the movant has produced evidence in
support of its motion for summary judgment, the nonmovant cannot rest on the
allegations of pleadings and must do more than create some metaphysical
doubt.
9
However, at the summary judgment stage, a court is not to weigh the evidence
or make credibility determinations. Id. at 1363. Instead, these tasks are left for
the fact-finder. To raise a genuine issue of material fact, therefore, "the
[summary judgment] opponent need not match, item for item, each piece of
evidence proffered by the movant," but simply must exceed the "mere scintilla"
standard. Id. Additionally, a court should not tightly compartmentalize the
evidence put forward by the nonmovant, but instead should analyze it as a
whole to see if together it supports an inference of concerted action. Id. at 1364
(citing Continental Ore Co. v. Union Carbide & Carbon Corp., 370 U.S. 690,
699, 82 S.Ct. 1404, 1410, 8 L.Ed.2d 777 (1962)); In re Japanese Elec. Prods.
Antitrust Litig., 723 F.2d 238, 305 (3d Cir.1983), rev'd on other grounds sub
nom. Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 106
S.Ct. 1348, 89 L.Ed.2d 538 (1986).
10
11
The district court granted the defendants summary judgment. See 513 F.Supp.
1100 (E.D.Pa.1981). We then reversed in part, holding that the plaintiffs had
put forward sufficient evidence from which a conspiracy reasonably could be
inferred. See In re Japanese Elec. Prods., 723 F.2d at 303-16. On certiorari, the
Supreme Court reversed our decision. The Court stated that because the
plaintiffs' theory of conspiracy did not make sense from an economic
standpoint, the ambiguous evidence of a conspiracy they put forward was
insufficient to withstand summary judgment. Instead, in the circumstances, the
plaintiffs needed to provide "more persuasive evidence to support their claim
than would otherwise be necessary." 475 U.S. at 587, 106 S.Ct. at 1356. The
Court emphasized that evidence which is equally consistent with legal and
illegal conduct, standing alone, cannot support an inference of antitrust
conspiracy. Id. at 588, 106 S.Ct. at 1356 (citing Monsanto, 465 U.S. at 764, 104
S.Ct. at 1470).
13
In reaching its decision the Supreme Court first noted that the alleged predatory
pricing conspiracy was speculative at best because it required the defendants to
agree to forego profits that a free market would offer them. The Court then
stated that the only way such a conspiracy would make any sense was if the
defendants could recoup their losses in the future through monopoly profits.
475 U.S. at 588-89, 106 S.Ct. at 1357. The Court, however, looked at the
market and determined that there was no evidence that the defendants could
recoup such losses. Thus, the Court concluded that the defendants had no
motive to engage in the alleged conspiracy. Id. at 592-93, 106 S.Ct. at 1359.
The Court further recognized that the alleged unlawful behavior was equally
consistent with lawful behavior because "cutting prices in order to increase
business often is the very essence of competition." Id. at 594, 106 S.Ct. at 1360.
14
Importantly, however, in reaching its conclusion the Matsushita Court did not
hold that an antitrust defendant is entitled to summary judgment merely by
providing an economic theory to justify its behavior. See Eastman Kodak Co. v.
Image Technical Servs., Inc., --- U.S. ----, ----, 112 S.Ct. 2072, 2083, 119
L.Ed.2d 265 (1992) ("The [Matsushita ] Court did not hold that if the moving
party enunciates any economic theory supporting its behavior, regardless of its
accuracy in reflecting the actual market, it is entitled to summary judgment."
(emphasis in original)); In re Coordinated Pretrial Proceedings in Petroleum
Prods. Antitrust Litig., 906 F.2d 432, 439 (9th Cir.1990) ("Nor do we think that
Matsushita and Monsanto can be read as authorizing a court to award summary
judgment to antitrust defendants whenever the evidence is plausibly consistent
with both inferences of conspiracy and inferences of innocent conduct."), cert.
denied, --- U.S. ----, 111 S.Ct. 2274, 114 L.Ed.2d 725 (1991). Instead, the Court
simply stressed that to survive summary judgment in the absence of direct
evidence or strong circumstantial evidence of an agreement, a plaintiff must
assert a theory that is plausible. Matsushita, 475 U.S. at 593-94, 106 S.Ct. at
1359-60. In this respect, then, Matsushita did not invent a new requirement for
an antitrust plaintiff to meet, but merely articulated an established one, i.e., the
inferences drawn from the proffered evidence must be reasonable. See Eastman
Kodak Co., U.S. at ----, 112 S.Ct. at 2083. Therefore, contrary to the district
court's reasoning in our case, the defendants were not entitled to summary
judgment simply because they demonstrated a plausible rationale for their
behavior. Rather, the focus must remain on the evidence proffered by the
plaintiff and whether that evidence "tends to exclude the possibility that [the
defendants] were acting independently." Monsanto, 465 U.S. at 764, 104 S.Ct.
at 1471.
18
19
Nonetheless, the mere facts that a plaintiff alleges a plausible conspiracy and
that that allegation does not threaten to chill procompetitive behavior do not
mean that there are no restrictions on the inferences that can be drawn from the
evidence it puts forward. For example, the cases indicate that a plaintiff cannot
withstand a summary judgment motion by establishing only consciously
parallel behavior on the part of the defendants. See Theatre Enters., Inc. v.
Paramount Film Distrib. Corp., 346 U.S. 537, 541, 74 S.Ct. 257, 259-60, 98
L.Ed. 273 (1954); In re Japanese Elec. Prods., 723 F.2d at 304. Instead, in a
conscious parallelism case, a plaintiff also must demonstrate the existence of
certain "plus" factors, for only when these additional factors are present does
the evidence tend to exclude the possibility that the defendants acted
independently. See In re Japanese Elec. Prods., 723 F.2d at 304.
In its decision, the district court stated that if a plaintiff provided direct
evidence of a conspiracy, then the strictures of Matsushita did not apply. Opin.
Before detailing the evidence put forward by Petruzzi's IGA, we pause to stress
the nature of its allegations because it is important to keep it in mind when
considering the evidence. Although Petruzzi's IGA alleges that the defendants'
actions had an impact on prices, it does not contend that the defendants
conspired to fix prices per se. Also Petruzzi's IGA's ultimate goal is not to prove
that the defendants priced predatorily. Rather, it seeks to show only that the
defendants conspired to allocate customers so that once a renderer had won or
"loaded" an account, competition for that account effectively ceased. Thus,
with respect to the evidence relating to pricing, Petruzzi's IGA does not need to
show that prices across the industry were suspiciously similar, or that the
defendants priced predatorily. Rather, it need demonstrate only that the prices
paid by the defendants differed significantly between new and existing
accounts for such data would be consistent with its theory that competition was
restrained unlawfully only on existing accounts.
22
Industry 39, 42-44 (1968). Here, Petruzzi's IGA contends that the defendants
enforced their agreement by "targeting" the noncomplying companies, i.e.,
bidding on their accounts predatorily. Thus, to the extent that there is testimony
regarding the defendants pricing above market, it is relevant not to establish a
predatory pricing violation by a particular defendant, but to show the
enforcement mechanism used by the defendants to enforce their agreement.
Instances of predatory pricing, therefore, are circumstantial evidence that an
unlawful agreement exists.
23
With this background, we now turn to the evidence put forward by Petruzzi's
IGA. We consider this evidence as a whole and with the reasonable inferences
that we can draw from it. Such a consideration reveals that while a reasonable
jury could conclude that Darling and Moyer acted in concert, it could not find
that Standard took part in this conspiracy.
24
25
Howard Salisbury, a solicitor for Moyer during the early 1980s, testified that
Moyer followed a "code" in not soliciting the accounts of other renderers,
particularly Darling. Likewise, Ralph Ebersole testified that representatives of
Moyer and Darling discussed price-fixing and other customer problems while
at National Renderers Association (NRA) meetings. The district court
dismissed the significance of their testimony, however, stating that neither man
knew whether this adherence to the "code" flowed from conversations between
representatives of the defendants. Rather, the district court said that all that
could be inferred from these statements was that Moyer adhered to a code of
noninterference. Opin. at 23-24. Our reading of the record shows otherwise.
26
Salisbury signed a written statement stating, "I did not bother Darling accounts.
Mr. Sage [a high-level Moyer solicitor] told me on at least two occasions that
there was a mutual agreement and understanding with Darling, not to bother
their accounts." App. at 2228 (emphasis added). When discussing this
statement during his deposition, Salisbury stated that Sage told him: "there was
an understanding." App. at 2212. While Salisbury later testified that he was not
told of any understanding or agreement that Moyer had with any other
company, App. at 2216, he did not retract his statement as to Darling.8 In fact,
Salisbury testified:
I27told [Mr. Rubin and Mr. Keiser, lawyers for Petruzzi's IGA] that there was an
agreement or understanding. I also explained to Mr. Kaiser (sic) it has been going on
ever since I have been in the business. Ever since 1969. It was something that
everybody done (sic).
28
29
App. at 2224.
Like Salisbury, Ralph Ebersole also provided evidence of an agreement
between Moyer and Darling. Ralph Ebersole was the Director of Marketing for
Finished Products at Moyer from 1974 to 1979. He took this job after his
company sold out to Moyer, but he left to start his own company once his fiveyear contract with Moyer was up. Because he was not involved directly with
the purchase of raw materials, Ebesole's testimony relates mostly to the
meetings between other renderers at the NRA meetings which he attended.
30
31
Moreover, Ebersole's testimony suggests that Moyer did not limit its attempts to
conspire to Darling. Ebersole testified that a principal at Southern Tier, a
renderer which is not a party to this action, informed him that Sage approached
him about working out a relationship in which each company would stay away
from the other's customers. App. at 860.9 He further testified about overhearing
conversations between Sage and Ryder principals about not soliciting the
accounts of others. App. at 866-67. While neither Ryder nor Southern Tier are
defendants, this testimony does suggest that Moyer pursued a course of doing
business through agreements with its competitors, thereby supporting a
damaging interpretation of the other testimony put forward by Petruzzi's IGA.
32
In March 1983, Lee Ryder and his cousin Kent Ryder secretly taped four of
their conversations with John Hendricks and Curt Moyer of Moyer Packing.
Lee and Kent Ryder were co-owners of Ryder Rendering Co. before it sold out
to Darling. Ryder Rendering was having problems with Moyer and sought to
obtain evidence to give to the Justice Department for a possible antitrust action.
Although the Ryders hoped to gain evidence to use against Moyer, Lee Ryder
maintained in his deposition that he did not suspect collusion in the rendering
industry. App. at 1887-89. Similarly, Kent Ryder testified that the tapes were
made only with the intention of suing Moyer. App. at 1985. The Ryders
insisted that they made the tapes only because they suspected Moyer of pricing
predatorily. However, the Ryders' stated beliefs are not relevant for summary
judgment purposes. Rather, the words on the tapes can speak for themselves.
These words, like the testimony of Salisbury and Ebersole, suggest the
existence of an agreement in the industry of which Moyer was a part.
34
The district court considered these tapes, but ruled that they were insufficient to
establish the existence of a conspiracy. The district court dismissed the
significance of this testimony for primarily two reasons. First, it noted that the
Ryders were trying to trap the Moyer representatives into saying something
incriminating. Second, the court found that most of the statements revolved
around Ryder's solicitation of A & B Rendering of Allentown, with which
Moyer may have had a five-year contract.10 Opin. at 33-40. However, as
Petruzzi's IGA points out, while the conversations may have been inspired by
problems associated with A & B, the statements on the tapes are not limited to
problems with the A & B account.
35
For example, in a meeting on March 11, 1983, John Hendricks and Lee Ryder
began by discussing the problems with A & B. However, during this
conversation, Hendricks told Ryder:
36
Well--you
know the feeling of everybody. This isn't the first conversation we've had,
and it's not the first conversation you've had with anybody else about taking people's
accounts.
37
App. at 300. From this statement, a rational jury could conclude that Moyer
and other renderers had spoken to Ryder about taking existing accounts. In fact,
this conclusion is supported by other comments made by Hendricks. In a
40
Hendricks also told Lee Ryder: (1) "why don't you put your prices in line and
make money on what you have?" App. at 299; (2) "why don't you just operate
with what you have and not worry about what other people have," App. at 293;
(3) "[t]he only restrictions that you have on operating your business is; don't
take other people's accounts," App. at 298; and (4) "[y]eah, but you're
interfering with other people's businesses, that's the problem--that's the
problem," App. at 298 (emphasis added). From all of these statements, a jury
reasonably could conclude that Hendricks, acting on behalf of Moyer, was
attempting to get the Ryders to play by the industry rules and that Moyer was
part of an agreement among some renderers.
41
As noted, the district court discounted these statements because they related to
a particular problem with A & B. However, even the comments pertaining
directly to A & B suggest a more pervasive problem. For instance, in a March
9, 1983 conversation between Curt Moyer and Kent Ryder, Moyer told Kent
Ryder: "I certainly don't want to start anything; you know what I mean....
Pretty, pretty heavy. So I don't know, somebody, something got away from
somebody or just what happened, but that's what it is." App. at 282. Similarly,
Hendricks told Lee Ryder, "I put A & B out of the rendering business and I
loaded it." App. at 291; "[y]ou shouldn't solicit [A & B], that's right. I mean,
now, uh, you knew that for the last five years." App. at 292; and "[i]t's not an
auction. Is it?" App. at 306. Again, a reasonable inference is that Moyer was
attempting to get Ryder to play by the rules.
42
However, like the testimony of Salisbury and Ebersole, none of the statements
in the Ryder tapes implicates Standard. In fact, Hendricks made the only
reference to Standard in the tapes when he asked Lee Ryder why he was
bothering his accounts and not Darling's or Standard's accounts. App. at 293.
This statement in no way implicates Standard, for one cannot infer reasonably
that this statement indicates that Standard had an agreement with Moyer.
Petruzzi's IGA has argued that this statement shows that Moyer was aware of
what was going on at Standard. However, the record reveals that it was easy to
determine who had what account because the raw materials were placed in
containers that bore the servicing renderer's name. App. at 805-06. Moreover, it
is conceded that representatives from Moyer and Standard spoke. Thus, this
information could have been communicated during those conversations without
violating the Sherman Act.
3. The Expert Testimony
43
44
The experts noted that the homogeneity of the industry made it different from
industries in which the service or the product was differentiated because in
those industries it may make sense to offer a special introductory price so as to
introduce the customer to the special virtues of the soliciting company. For
example, a newspaper or magazine might offer a low introductory rate on its
product to obtain the consumer. A newspaper would be willing to accept this
initial, short-term loss because it realistically could expect to recoup the loss
once it has developed brand loyalty. By contrast, a rational gasoline station
would not offer customers discounts only on their initial purchases because
once its prices went up beyond the prices of its competitors, the customers
would go elsewhere. Cf. Matsushita, 475 U.S. at 589-93, 106 S.Ct. at 1357-59
(noting that it did not make sense for defendants to price below costs where
there was no opportunity to recoup this investment in future). Instead, we
would expect a particular gas station's prices to be constant no matter how
many times the customer had been in before unless, of course, it had an
agreement with its competitors not to service each other's cars.11
45
Although the two experts based their hypothesis on the other evidence
proffered by the plaintiff, they tested this hypothesis with multiple regression
analysis using the pricing data that the defendants turned over to Petruzzi's
IGA. From this study, they concluded that new accounts were paid roughly
39% more for raw materials than were existing accounts. App. at 730-31. Both
experts testified that this pricing pattern alone is sufficient to suggest
anticompetitive behavior for, as noted above, there is no logical reason for any
disparity in price in this homogeneous industry.
46
The district court dismissed the significance of this evidence for two reasons.
First, it ruled that the testimony could not be considered because it was
inadmissible under Federal Rule of Evidence 403. Second, it summarily stated
that even if the evidence were admissible, it was not sufficient to raise a
genuine issue of material fact because of weaknesses in the study. We consider
each of these rulings in turn, finding the evidence to be both admissible and
suggestive that Darling and Moyer acted in concert. However, because the
study did not contain a sufficient sample size from Standard, we conclude that
it is insufficient to implicate Standard.
a. Admissibility
47
48
The district court concluded that while the expert testimony could not be
excluded under Federal Rules of Evidence 702 and 703 based on the record
before it, the testimony should be excluded under Rule 403 because it was "not
more probative than prejudicial." Opin. at 55 (emphasis in original). Before
considering the admissibility of the expert testimony under each of these Rules,
we note that the district court applied the wrong test under Rule 403. For
testimony to be excluded under Rule 403, its probative value must be
"substantially outweighed" by the listed dangers, rather than simply "not more
probative than prejudicial."
49
50
51
52
The district court found, and the defendants do not contend otherwise, that the
proffered testimony passed the Rule 702 threshold. Thus, our discussion of
Rule 702 is rather limited because this ruling is not in dispute. Nevertheless, we
There are three intertwined bases for excluding testimony under Rule 702: (1)
if the testimony will not assist the trier of fact; (2) if scientific evidence is not
sufficiently reliable; and (3) if the particular expert does not have sufficient
specialized knowledge to assist the jurors. See 3 Jack B. Weinstein & Margaret
A. Berger, Weinstein's Evidence p 702 (1992) [hereinafter Weinstein's
Evidence ]; see also Hines v. Consolidated Rail Corp., 926 F.2d 262, 272-73
(3d Cir.1991) (noting two general reasons to exclude evidence under Rule 702:
unqualified witness and unreliable scientific technique (citing In re Paoli R.R.
Yard PCB Litig., 916 F.2d 829, 855 (3d Cir.1990), cert. denied, --- U.S. ----,
111 S.Ct. 1584, 113 L.Ed.2d 649 (1991))).
54
55
First, we note that the scientific method used by the economists, multiple
regression analysis, is reliable. Therefore, the results of such a study should be
accepted, assuming that it was done properly. Here, the only possible problem
is that the data set used by the experts was incomplete or inaccurate such that
an economist would not rely on it. However, no showing was made to this
effect by the defendants.
56
Second, and more importantly, the testimony clearly will assist the trier of fact
because it makes sense out of pricing data through the use of multiple
regression analysis. The data standing alone are meaningless to a lay person. In
fact, they are meaningless to an economist until a statistical study is run.
57
58
made by the defendants. Thus, while the defendants did try to poke holes in the
value of the study during the depositions, they have not supplied any experts
who testified that the study's methodology was fatally flawed. In fact, as in
DeLuca, here the experts' qualifications were unchallenged,13 the testimony
went to a crucial issue, and the analysis purported to be based on reasoning
accepted in the published literature. See DeLuca, 911 F.2d at 957. Therefore,
given these facts, we are "unwilling in the absence of countervailing evidence
or persuasive argument to conclude that [the expert] testimony would be
unhelpful under Rule 702." Id. Accordingly, the district court correctly
concluded that the evidence satisfied Rule 702.
59
60
The facts or data in the particular case upon which an expert bases an opinion
or inference may be those perceived by or made known to the expert at or
before the hearing. If of a type reasonably relied upon by experts in the
particular field in forming opinions or inferences upon the subject, the facts or
data need not be admissible in evidence.
61
The district court found that Rule 703 does not provide a basis to exclude the
expert testimony.14 Opin. at 55. While it is true that the experts based their
opinion in part on evidence that otherwise was not admissible, they also
concluded that the pricing data alone supported Petruzzi's IGA's allegations.
App. at 582, 739-40. The extra evidence simply reinforced their conclusion.
Therefore, even if the extra evidence was not the type reasonably relied upon
by experts in their field, the testimony still satisfied Rule 703 because there can
be no doubting that price data is of the type reasonably used by economists. See
In re Japanese Elec. Prods, 723 F.2d at 280. Moreover, there has been no
showing by the defendants that the other evidence upon which the economists
used is not of a type reasonably relied upon by economists. Thus, the district
court correctly found that the testimony would be admissible under Rule 703.
62
(iii) Rule 403. While Rule 403 can be used to exclude expert testimony before
trial, we have stated that if expert testimony survives the rigors of Rules 702
and 703, then Rule 403 becomes an unlikely basis for exclusion, especially in
the pretrial setting. See In re Paoli R.R. Yard PCB Litig., 916 F.2d 829, 859 (3d
Cir.1990), cert. denied, --- U.S. ----, 111 S.Ct. 1584, 113 L.Ed.2d 649 (1991);
DeLuca, 911 F.2d at 957. Moreover, as we have noted, Rule 702 incorporates
the danger of unfair prejudice, United States v. Downing, 753 F.2d 1224, 1242
(3d Cir.1985); therefore, if a court were to exclude expert testimony under Rule
403 it seemingly would have to be on some other basis, such as confusion of
the issues or waste of time. See id. at 1243. Nonetheless, the district court
excluded the testimony because the court thought it was unfairly prejudicial
and could mislead the jury.
63
As noted earlier, the court seemingly applied the wrong test under Rule 403,
and thus never made a determination that the unfair prejudice that would result
from the expert testimony would substantially outweigh the probative value.
For purposes of this discussion, however, we will assume that the court made
such a determination. Yet, in doing so, the court abused its discretion.
64
In assessing the experts' testimony, the court correctly noted that the
information regarding the pricing patterns was new. Opin. at 57. Nonetheless, it
held that this testimony was more prejudicial than helpful because there was no
factual basis for the experts' theory and because of problems in the data set.
Opin. at 62-64. However, both these conclusions are mistaken. First, basic
economic theory provides the linchpin for the experts' theory. As noted above,
in a homogeneous industry it does not make sense for a company to
differentiate in price between new and existing accounts.
65
Second, any problems with the underlying data should have been resolved
under Federal Rules of Evidence 702 or 703. However, as already noted, the
district court explicitly found that the study satisfied these requirements. In that
context, the court properly recognized:
66
Defendants
have not produced any expert reports to counter the opinions of
plaintiff's experts or challenge the data on which they rely. This court is not,
therefore, in a position, to undertake its own review of whether the data on which
the two economists rely is of the type relied upon by others in their field. Nor are we
in a position to challenge their methodology.
67
Opin. at 54-55. Thus, the court concluded that the exclusion of their testimony
under either Rule 702 or 703 would be improper without opinions from experts
for the defendants or an evidentiary hearing. But there were no such experts and
there was no evidentiary hearing.
68
However, a few pages later in its opinion, the court changed its approach,
holding that the testimony was prejudicial because there are questions about its
reliability and completeness. "An economic theory unsupported by factual data
adds nothing to the analysis," the district court concluded, "and does not raise
an issue of material fact where none existed." Opin. at 62. Thus, the court found
unfair prejudice because:[i]mbued as such testimony would be, with the aura of
economic expertise and couched in terms of economic theory and analysis there
is great danger that a jury of laymen, unfamiliar with economic antitrust theory
and analysis would accept unquestioningly the theories espoused by Drs.
Adams and Asher and defer to their opinions on the existence of a conspiracy,
the ultimate issue of this case.
69
Opin. at 63.
70
Similarly, while discussing Rules 702 and 703 the court stated, "We do not
question that their opinions are based on data of the type reasonably relied on
by experts in the field." Opin. at 54. Yet, the court in considering Rule 403 then
asserted that data which the experts used was unreliable: "we know nothing of
what was supplied or how it was used in determining that prices paid to
established accounts were lower than those paid to new accounts." Opin. at 59.
The court further added, "The deposition testimony of Drs. Adams and Asher is
equally vague and raises more questions about the reliability and completeness
of the data considered that it answers." Opin. at 59-60.
71
However, if the court were concerned about the accuracy of the data, then it
should have held an in limine hearing to assess the admissibility of the
testimony. Cf. In Re Paoli, 916 F.2d at 859 ("[A] court cannot fairly ascertain
the potential relevance of evidence for Rule 403 purposes until it has a full
record relevant to the putatively objectionable evidence."). Instead, without any
contrary expert testimony on which to rely and without holding an evidentiary
hearing, the court chose to make its own assessment of the study's value.
Clearly, this was inappropriate and reveals the court's error. See In re Japanese
Elec. Prods., 723 F.2d at 281 ("In making these exclusionary rulings the trial
judge made the same fundamental legal error which we noted earlier: he
assumed that the determining factor under Rule 703 was his view of what data
experts in a field ought to rely upon rather than making a factual inquiry and a
finding as to what data experts, in this case economists, deem reliable."). As we
have stated:
In sum, we hold that in order to exclude evidence under Rule 403 at the pretrial
stage, a court must have a record complete enough on the point at issue to be
considered a virtual surrogate for a trial record.
74
case, whatever else can be said about the completeness of the record, it is clear
that the record on the experts' price study was not sufficiently complete to be a
surrogate for trial.
75
In justifying its decision, the court also stated that because the evidence of prior
civil and criminal actions against defendants is not admissible and yet was
relied on by the experts, there would be a danger in allowing them to testify
when the jury cannot hear one of the key bases for their opinion. However, the
court ignored the experts' testimony that the pricing patterns alone provide
sufficient basis for their conclusion. In doing so, the court employed a process
similar to that which we criticized in In re Japanese Elec. Prods., regarding the
district court's Rule 702 analysis:
76 the court in effect did was to eliminate all parts of the report in which the
What
expert economist, after describing the conditions in the respective markets, the
opportunities for collusion, the evidence pointing to collusion, the terms of certain
undisputed agreements, and the market behavior, expressed the opinion that there
was concert of action.
77
723 F.2d at 280. Thus, there can be no doubt that the district court abused its
discretion by excluding the proffered expert testimony under Rule 403.
78
We also note that the court excluded the expert testimony based on a concern
about unfair prejudice. Unfair prejudice "means an undue tendency to suggest
decision on an improper basis, commonly, though not necessarily, an emotional
one." Fed.R.Evid. 403 Advisory Committee's Note. Thus, it is likely that the
court in using the term "unfair prejudice" simply meant that the evidence would
mislead the jury. Yet, "[v]igorous cross-examination, presentation of contrary
evidence, and careful instruction on the burden of proof are the traditional and
appropriate means of attacking shaky but admissible evidence." Daubert v.
Merrell Dow Pharm., Inc., --- U.S. ----, 113 S.Ct. 2786, 125 L.Ed.2d 469
(1993); see also In re Japanese Elec. Prods., 723 F.2d at 279 (" 'The jury is
intelligent enough, aided by counsel, to ignore what is unhelpful in its
deliberations.' " (quoting 3 Weinstein's Evidence p 702).
As noted, the district court stated that even if the expert economic testimony
were admissible, it still would grant the defendants summary judgment. In
particular, the court stated that based on the deficiencies in the underpinnings of
the expert testimony, no genuine issue of material fact would be raised. But it is
clear to us that in order to reach this decision, the court impermissibly weighed
To support its conclusion, the court stated, "The [expert opinion] add[ed]
nothing to the evidence." Opin. at 65. Yet, earlier the court itself recognized
that the testimony regarding the pricing patterns was new. Opin. at 57. The
results of the multiple regression analysis show a price differential between
new and existing accounts. As discussed above, there is no rational way to
explain this difference. To get around this study, the defendants and the district
court stressed potential flaws in the experts' study. However, the fact remains
that the defendants did not supply expert testimony undermining the validity of
the study or ask for a hearing on the study's validity. Thus, they have
established no valid basis for challenging the study's reliability.
82
While the study alone may not be enough to raise a jury issue, it certainly goes
a long way in helping Petruzzi's IGA to satisfy its burden of proof. More
importantly, this study, in conjunction with the testimony of Salisbury and
Ebersole and the Ryder tapes, "tends to exclude the possibility" that the market
as it exists today came about a result of independent action.
83
However, as the study relates to Standard, the district court's reading of the
testimony is correct. During his deposition, Dr. Asher testified that the study
used only one year of Standard's data, even though the experts had access to
more years. Instead, they extrapolated from the one year by using the same
pattern that existed with respect to Moyer. According to Asher, they used this
methodology because there were not sufficient new accounts for Standard to
create an adequate sample. App. at 749. Thus, as Dr. Asher admits, the data set
relating to Standard was insufficient to draw any definite conclusions. While
this data problem is not enough to exclude the price study generally, it does
serve to limit the inferences that can be drawn from it as it relates to Standard.
Therefore, because this is the only evidence implicating Standard, this evidence
standing alone is not sufficient to defeat summary judgment. See Daubert, --U.S. at ----, 113 S.Ct. at 2798 ("in the event the trial court concludes that the
scintilla of evidence presented supporting a position is insufficient to allow a
reasonable juror to conclude that the position more likely than not is true, the
court remains free to ... grant summary judgment"); Mid-State Fertilizer Co. v.
Exchange Nat'l Bank of Chicago, 877 F.2d 1333, 1339 (7th Cir.1989) (noting
that opinion not based on adequate facts supplies nothing to judicial process);
Town Sound & Custom Tops, Inc. v. Chrysler Motor Corp., 743 F.Supp. 353,
364 (E.D.Pa.1990) (granting summary judgment where expert opinion did not
add any evidence), aff'd, 959 F.2d 468 (3d Cir.1992), cert. denied, --- U.S. ----,
Finally, Petruzzi's IGA has put forward testimony that relatively few accounts
transferred among the defendants. This testimony also supports Petruzzi's IGA's
allegations for it is anecdotal evidence of the effects of the conspiracy. For
example, Salisbury testified that he did not lose any of his customers to
Standard or Darling. App. at 2223. Sage testified that during approximately 15
years at Moyer he lost less than 20 accounts for fat and bones to the other two
defendants. App. at 2179-80. Uriahs Shelly of Moyer testified that in
approximately 13 years he lost less than ten accounts to Darling out of roughly
1,500. App. at 2286. Finally, Earl Englemyer of Darling testified that during his
ten years, he did not lose any accounts to the competition. See App. at 1046-50.
While this anecdotal evidence by itself is certainly not enough to prove the
existence of a conspiracy, when considered in conjunction with the other
evidence, it makes an inference of concerted action more reasonable.
85
Yet, once again, this evidence does not implicate Standard. The record clearly
shows that Standard had capacity problems during the time of the alleged
conspiracy. Thus, its ability to process additional materials was limited
severely. Indeed, as Petruzzi's IGA's own experts testified, Standard had very
few new accounts during this period. Thus, the fact that Moyer and/or Darling
lost few accounts to Standard should be expected as for the most part Standard
was not bidding on anyone's accounts during this time.15
E. Conscious Parallelism
86
1280, 55 L.Ed.2d 791 (1978); Venzie Corp. v. United States Mineral Prods.
Co., 521 F.2d 1309, 1314 (3d Cir.1975); see also William C. Holmes, 1992
Antitrust Law Handbook 1.03, at 154 (noting that wide range of
circumstantial evidence can be used to establish needed plus factor, "[f]or
example, have they attended meetings or conducted discussions at which they
had the opportunity to conspire; have they acted against their own economic
best interests; have they engaged in parallel behavior that is economically
irrational unless an agreement exists; has at least one participant expressly
invited common action by the other ..."). In this respect, then conscious
parallelism cases "are merely illustrations of the more general proposition that
there are legal limitations upon the inferences which may be drawn from
circumstantial evidence." In re Japanese Elec. Prods., 723 F.2d at 304.
87
88
As Moyer and Darling implicitly have conceded, Petruzzi's IGA has put
forward evidence establishing that they acted similarly. While it may be true
that the defendants did not use the same prices or run their internal business
operations identically, the evidence shows that they acted similarly by
refraining from competing on existing accounts, while at the same time
competing actively for new accounts. See App. at 638-39, 641 (testimony of
Warren Alcock of Darling); App. at 1263-65 (testimony of Edward Harrigan of
Moyer); App. at 2088-89, 2124 (testimony of Robert Sage of Moyer); see also
Moyer's Brief at 32 (admitting that expert testimony showed that defendants
acted in parallel manner).
89
The record also shows that Moyer and Darling retaliated against those
App. at 2192.
92
App. at 2195; see also App. at 2204 (Salisbury's testimony relating to Moyer's
problems with Bear Creek) ("A: Yes, I did retaliate on a couple of their stops.;
Q: Did anybody tell you to retaliate?; A: Mr. Scarborough."); App. at 1178-81
(testimony of Robert Fry) (discussing Sage's conversations with him about
competitors who took his accounts); App. at 301 (Hendricks to Lee Ryder: "I'm
going to go out and cost you money, and you're going to go out and cost me
money, and if that's what you want, I guess that's what we're going to do. We'll
see who's got the most money."). Likewise, Ebersole also testified about Sage's
retaliatory efforts against Southern Tier and Fry Rendering, two noncomplying
competitors. See App. at 859-62. Moreover, Ebersole testified that Moyer
approached other renderers to help in their retaliation efforts. According to
Ebersole, Mr. Leidy, from Greencastle Products, was approached by Moyer to
help it solicit Ebersole's customers to help retaliate against him. App. at 918-19.
From this wealth of evidence, a reasonable jury could conclude that Moyer and
Darling acted similarly both by refraining from competing on existing accounts
and by retaliating against those renderers who went after their accounts.
2. Consciousness
98
Petruzzi's IGA also put forward evidence suggesting that the renderers were
aware of each other's policies. For example, as Moyer admits in its brief,
Hendricks's recorded statement "everybody does it [refrains from soliciting
other renderers' accounts]" proves "parallel conduct," i.e., at least Moyer was
aware that its behavior was consistent with its competitors. See App. at 294;
Brief at 20 n. 4. Similarly, Sage testified:
99 The main competition was always new openings with everybody. You are always
A:
competing hard on that.
.....
100
Q: Was there less activity for existing accounts as compared to new openings?
101
A: Yes.
102
103 App. at 2124; see also App. at 1192-93 (testimony of Robert Fry of Fry
Rendering) (stating that Fry did not solicit existing accounts, but only went after
them when he received calls from them and noting that this behavior was "a
way of doing business. You stayed in your own area. That was it.").
104 Similarly, there was evidence indicating that Darling knew of Moyer's
retaliatory efforts. For example, Lee Ryder testified that Mr. Schneider, a
Darling representative, tried to intervene and settle the price war between Ryder
and Moyer. App. at 1921-22. Darling may have taken this role because it saw
itself as a maintainer of order in the industry. However, whatever its reasons, it
shows that it was aware of the retaliatory behavior of Moyer.
3. "Plus" Factors
105 As noted above, mere consciously parallel behavior is not a sufficient basis
from which to infer concerted action. Instead, courts require "plus" factors
because otherwise the evidence is equally consistent with legal behavior. In his
treatise, Professor Areeda suggests the easiest "plus" factor to explain is
evidence implying a traditional conspiracy. See VI Phillip E. Areeda, Antitrust
Law: An Analysis of Antitrust Principles and Their Application p 1434b, at 214
(1986) [hereinafter Areeda, Antitrust Law ]. The testimony of Ebersole and
Salisbury, the Ryder tapes, and the economic data discussed above satisfies this
requirement.17
112 It is one thing for competitors all to charge the same price, as a perfectly
competitive market could lead them to do so. It is quite another for competitors
all to refrain from soliciting each other's accounts. See VI Areeda, Antitrust
Law p 1420d, at 123-24 (noting that refusal to bid in oligopoly situation is not
inevitable, but cannot be sustained without some enforcement mechanism). It is
still another for competitors to use the same enforcement mechanism.
Therefore, we hold that Petruzzi's IGA has put forward enough evidence to take
this case beyond the simple allegation of parallel behavior. It has supplied
evidence which indicates that Moyer and Darling had an actual agreement, and
it has provided evidence that Moyer and Darling acted against their self-interest
in ways not attributable to interdependence.
F. Evidence Properly Excluded
113 While we conclude that based on the evidence so far discussed, summary
judgment was improperly granted to Darling and Moyer, we nevertheless
address two additional pieces of evidence that the district court excluded from
consideration. We do so because one piece implicates Standard and because we
recognize that on remand Petruzzi's IGA may want to introduce this evidence.
1. The Ellerin Memorandum
114 Petruzzi's IGA produced a memorandum created in 1983 by Michelle Ellerin,
Lee Ryder's former wife, detailing Ryder's experiences in the rendering
industry. With hopes of getting the government to indict Moyer, Ellerin
prepared a memorandum providing a brief history of the rendering industry and
Ryder's experiences in it. The memorandum states, among other things, that
John Hendricks of Moyer Packing told Lee Ryder about the industry "rules";
i.e., no soliciting each other's existing accounts, new business is fair game, and
if there is a "mix up," then material must be traded to adjust for any inequities.
This memorandum also states that Darling and Standard worked together. Thus,
if admissible, the information contained in this memorandum might be
sufficient to defeat summary judgment as to all defendants. However, the
district court found that the information contained in this memorandum could
not be considered because it was based entirely on inadmissible hearsay that
could not be reduced to admissible form at trial. Opin. at 28-33; see J.F. Feeser,
Inc., 909 F.2d at 1542; Williams v. Borough of West Chester, Pa., 891 F.2d
458, 466 n. 12 (3d Cir.1989) (citing Celotex Corp. v. Catrett, 477 U.S. 317,
324-27, 106 S.Ct. 2548, 2553-55, 91 L.Ed.2d 265 (1986)).
115 Petruzzi's IGA argues that the district court erred in reaching this conclusion
because the information is capable of being admitted at trial. In particular, it
argues that Ellerin had personal knowledge of the events listed in the
memorandum. However, our review of her deposition reveals that the district
court correctly concluded that Ellerin derived her knowledge solely from
information from her husband or Kent Ryder. See, e.g., App. at 985
("Everything I knew about the industry and what the document speaks about
came primarily from Lee and from some degree from Kent."); App. at 998
("My direct knowledge comes only from Lee and Kent Ryder."). Moreover,
because Lee and Kent Ryder both testified during their depositions that they
had no reason to believe that there was any collusion in the industry, we agree
with the district court that the relevant information contained in the
memorandum could not be reduced to admissible form.
116 Petruzzi's IGA also argues that there are numerous exceptions to the hearsay
rule under which it could introduce the documents produced by Ellerin. Yet, it
does not suggest any particular rule under which we can conclude that the
information could be admitted. In the circumstances, we hold that for purposes
of this summary judgment motion this memorandum cannot be reduced to
admissible form.19
2. The Prior Antitrust Actions
117 Petruzzi's IGA also offered evidence of five prior antitrust actions brought
against the defendants and/or employees of the defendants. Petruzzi's IGA
claims that this evidence is admissible to prove the defendants' motive and
economic incentive to participate in the conspiracy. See Bogosian, 561 F.2d at
446 (requiring proof of these "plus" factors in conscious parallelism case). The
district court, however, refused to consider this evidence because none of the
five prior actions qualified for admissions under section 5(a) of the Clayton
Act, 15 U.S.C. 16(a), and their admissibility was barred by Federal Rules of
Evidence 408 and 410. Opin. at 44-45. After a careful review of this evidence
we have concluded that the district court's ruling was correct and that further
discussion regarding the bases for its conclusion is not necessary.
118 We do point out, however, that these prior actions are not relevant to the
defendants' motive. As noted above, the defendants' motive to enter into the
conspiracy is clear, and the existence of these earlier cases has no relevance to
proving that fact. Simply because the defendants were named in past antitrust
cases involving similar allegations does not make it more probable that the
defendants had a motive to carry out their conspiracy. See Fed.R.Evid. 401.
Petruzzi's IGA's argument is at best an attempt to end run the restrictions on
using past settlements and nolo pleas against defendants.20
III.
CONCLUSION
119 For the reasons stated above, we will reverse the district court's July 31, 1992
order inasmuch as it grants summary judgment to Darling and Moyer.
However, we will affirm the district court's grant of summary judgment to
Standard.
On July 31, 1992, the district court also issued a separate memorandum and
order denying the defendants' motion to revoke the conditional class
certification. 1992 WL 212230. The defendants have not cross-appealed from
that order
The district court did not discuss whether Petruzzi's IGA established a genuine
issue of material fact with respect to the other three elements of a section 1
claim. Likewise, the defendants have not argued to this court that Petruzzi's
IGA's evidence falls short with respect to these other elements. Accordingly,
we do not consider them in this appeal. Rather, we assess only whether
Petruzzi's IGA has put forth enough evidence regarding the defendants' alleged
concerted action to withstand the defendants' motions for summary judgment
The service provided by the renderers was homogeneous in that they all did the
same thing, pick up the materials. In this case, the materials sold by the
suppliers was for the most part homogeneous as well. Accordingly, the
renderers would have no reason to be concerned about who supplied them with
raw materials. The only exception is that Standard did not pick up suet and
meat trimmings, but only fat and bones, which the industry calls "ice cream."
7
10
11
12
Darling and Moyer obviously are not harmed by our use of the abuse of
discretion standard inasmuch as we surely would have come to the same result
regarding this evidence if we had exercised plenary review, i.e., the evidence
should not have been excluded. While in theory Petruzzi's IGA could be
prejudiced by the deferential review inasmuch as it is seeking to overturn the
district court's Rule 403 determination, in fact it is not because we rule the
evidence admissible as to all defendants, though as we shall explain, it is
inadequate to support Petruzzi's IGA's case against Standard
13
Perhaps facetiously, Darling states that the plaintiff's experts had expertise only
in economics, not as "cospiratologists [sic]." Darling's Brief at 25. But as we
have noted, "Characterizing the expert as an 'oath-help[er],' or a
'conspiracyologist,' is no substitute for recognition of the rule of law embodied
in Rule 702." In re Japanese Elec. Prods., 723 F.2d at 280
14
While the defendants do not concede that this ruling was correct, they do not
launch an all-out assault on it. See Darling's Brief at 25 n. 24; Standard's Brief
at 38 n. 28
15
16
For instance, most major banks raise or lower their prime rates when the
Federal Reserve lowers the rate it charges them. Banks are certainly aware of
the other banks decisions and are motivated, at least in part, by their
competitors' actions. Nonetheless, proof of only this behavior is not sufficient to
establish a section 1 violation. See In re Japanese Elec. Prods., 723 F.2d at 304
("While conscious parallel conduct has some tendency suggestive of concert of
action, the tendency is so slight that we have held that circumstance, standing
alone, to be legally insufficient.")
17
18
19
Petruzzi's IGA also argues that the documents were admissible because Lee
Ryder asserted the attorney-client privilege over them in his deposition.
However, our reading of the record does not reveal any such assertion by Lee
Ryder and the reference to the record in Petruzzi's IGA's Reply Brief at 13 to
Petruzzi's IGA also has suggested that the fact that the defendants' discussed the
prices of finished goods indicates that they acted in concert. The district court
rejected this conclusion, noting that the prices for finished goods were reported
in the trade reports and that any inference relating to the raw materials market
would be too speculative. Opin. at 47-48. We agree with the district court that
evidence of these discussions among the defendants in one context is
insufficient to draw an inference of conspiracy in another market