Alt Dis Mechanisms
Alt Dis Mechanisms
Alt Dis Mechanisms
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted
digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about
JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
The Harvard Law Review Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access
to Harvard Law Review
This content downloaded from 210.212.249.225 on Tue, 10 May 2016 14:34:08 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
COMMENTARY
ALTERNATIVE DISPUTE RESOLUTION: PANACEA OR
ANATHEMA?
Harry T. Edwards*
The Alternative Dispute Resolution (ADR) movement has seen an
extraordinary transformation in the last ten years. Little more than
a decade ago, only a handful of scholars and attorneys perceived the
need for alternatives to litigation. The ADR idea was seen as nothing
more than a hobbyhorse for a few offbeat scholars. Today, with the
rise of public complaints about the inefficiencies and injustices of our
traditional court systems, the ADR movement has attracted a bandwagon following of adherents. ADR is no longer shackled with the
reputation of a cult movement.
At worst, ADR is merely a highly fashionable idea, now viewed
as worthy of serious discussions among practitioners and scholars of
widely diverse backgrounds and professional interests. At best, the
ADR movement reflects a serious new effort to design workable and
fair alternatives to our traditional judicial systems. There can be no
doubt, however, that the ADR movement has drawn wide public
attention. During the past five years, there have been literally scores
of books, articles, conferences, bulletins, newsletters, and new course
offerings on ADR. Mechanisms for alternative dispute resolution are
now being established throughout the United States, with well over
one hundred and fifty minor dispute mediation centers in almost forty
Popularity and public interest are not sure signs of a quality endeavor. This is certainly true of ADR, because the movement is illdefined and the motives of some ADR adherents are questionable. It
appears that some people have joined the ADR bandwagon, without
regard for its purposes or consequences, because they see it as a fast
(and sometimes interesting) way to make a buck. It has also been
suggested that some of those people who promote ADR as a means
* Circuit Judge, United States Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia Circuit. Cornell
University, B.S., I962; University of Michigan, J.D., 1965. The author wishes to acknowledge
the research assistance given him by Charles Blanchard in the preparation of this Commentary.
1 Edelman, Institutionalizing Dispute Resolution Alternatives, 9 JUST. SYs. J. 134, 136
(i 984).
2 Sixteen states and ten federal district courts have authorized court-ordered arbitration
programs. See Background and Status, DISPUTE RESOLUTION F., Aug. 1985, at 4.
668
This content downloaded from 210.212.249.225 on Tue, 10 May 2016 14:34:08 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
3 By "alternative" dispute resolution I mean to focus on any ADR system that resolves
disputes pursuant to methods other than traditional litigation or government regulatory action.
Some alternatives - such as court-annexed arbitration - act as adjuncts to courts. Others,
however, use private fora not connected in any way to government institutions.
4 This Commentary will focus on the caseload problems of our judicial systems. However,
I recognize that ADR is also responding to other problems with the legal system. See Abel,
The Contradictions in Informal Justice, in THE POLITICS OF INFORMAL JUSTICE 31O (R. Abel
ed. I982); Edwards, Hopes and Fears for Alternative Dispute Resolution, 21 WILLAMETTE L.
REV. 425 (1985).
5 See, e.g., Edwards, The Rising Workload and Perceived "Bureaucracy" of the Federal
Courts: A Causation-Based Approach to the Search for Appropriate Remedies, 68 IowA L. REv.
871 (1983); Galanter, Reading the Landscape of Disputes: What We Know and Don't Know
(And Think We Know) About Our Allegedly Contentious and Litigious Society, 3I UCLA L.
REV. 4 (I983); Miller & Sarat, Grievances, Claims, and Disputes: Assessing the Adversary
Culture, I5 LAW & Soc'Y REV. 525 (I98I); Trubeck, Sarat, Felstiner, Kritzer & Grossman, The
Costs of Ordinary Litigation, 31 UCLA L. REv. 72 (1983).
This content downloaded from 210.212.249.225 on Tue, 10 May 2016 14:34:08 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
7 See id.
8 A study of cases in five federal district courts and at least one state court in each federal
district found that less than 8% of the cases went to trial. In 22.5% of the cases, the judge
either dismissed the case or rendered judgment on the merits summarily. The remainder were
resolved by settlement. See Trubeck, Sarat, Felstiner, Kritzer & Grossman, supra note 5, at
89.
9 See W. BRAZIL, SETTLING CIVIL SUITS i (i985). According to Brazil, "the process through
which the parties eventually reach agreement often is difficult to launch, then can be awkward,
expensive, time-consuming, and stressful. The route to resolution can be tortuously indirect
and travel over it can be obstructed by emotion, posturing, and interpersonal friction." Id. at
44.
This content downloaded from 210.212.249.225 on Tue, 10 May 2016 14:34:08 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Obviously, many disputes cannot be easily classified as solely private disputes that implicate no constitutional or public law. Many
commentators have tried to distinguish "public" and "private" disputes;
but, in my view, no one has been fully successful in this effort. The
problem is that hidden in many seemingly private disputes are often
difficult issues of public law. In this Commentary, I offer no easy
solution to the definitional problem of public/private disputes. I do
suggest, however, that there are a number of public law cases that
are easily identifiable as such. These include constitutional issues,
issues surrounding existing government regulation, and issues of great
public concern. The latter category might include, for example, the
development of a legal standard of strict liability in products liability
cases.11 Although less easily identifiable than constitutional and regulatory issues, such issues of great public concern can be accommo11 See, e.g., Escola v. Coca Cola Bottling Co., 24 Cal. 2d 453, 150 P.2d 436 (I944) (Traynor,
J., concurring).
This content downloaded from 210.212.249.225 on Tue, 10 May 2016 14:34:08 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
13 The recent Supreme Court decision in Thomas v. Union Carbide Agric. Prods. Co., 05
S. Ct. 3325 (I985), is not inconsistent with my central thesis that public law should not be
resolved by private ADR mechanisms. Thomas held that article III does not prohibit Congress
from selecting binding arbitration as the mechanism for resolving compensation disputes among
participants in the Federal Insecticide, Fungicide, and Rodenticide Act's pesticide registration
scheme. In Thomas, arbitration was chosen by Congress pursuant to standards that it set.
There was no danger that private parties would decide issues of public law.
using the distinction as developed in article III jurisprudence. This Commentary employs the
public/private distinction for an entirely different purpose. While article III is concerned about
the exercise of judicial power by the political branches of government, my concern is that public
law issues may be resolved by nongovernmental bodies. Nevertheless, the complexity of the
This content downloaded from 210.212.249.225 on Tue, 10 May 2016 14:34:08 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
court systems. ADR would not replace litigation, but instead would
be used to make our traditional court systems work more efficiently
and effectively. Because the vast majority of all court cases are settled
rather than adjudicated, many commentators believe that ADR has
an enormous potential for reducing caseloads by enhancing the effectiveness of settlement; at the same time, because ADR would be under
the careful supervision of courts, there is far less danger that ADR
would become a nefarious scheme for diminishing the rights of the
underprivileged in our society.
There are several ways in which the enormous settlement-enhancing potential of ADR can be tapped. Many lawyers insist that a
neutral, penetrating, and analytical assessment of a case greatly enhances the prospects of a successful negotiation by offering a realistic
view of what could transpire if a case goes to full-blown adjudica-
16 The first use of the mini-trial was a patent infringement action brought by Telecredit
against TRW. After three years of litigation, the two parties held a nonbinding arbitration
before executives of both corporations and former Judge James Davis of the Court of Claims.
Thirty minutes after the hearing, the parties settled. See Green, Recent Developments in
Alternative Forms of Dispute Resolutions, ioo F.R.D. 512, 5I4-I6 (I983). Judge Lambros has
introduced a "summary jury trial" modeled after the mini-trial. Lambros, The Summary Jury
Trial and Other Alternative Methods of Dispute Resolution, I03 F.R.D. 46I (I984).
17 The mini-trial has been successful in settling disputes of several major corporations including Control Data Corp., Burroughs Corp., Gillette Corp., and Texaco. See Green, supra
note i6, at 5I7.
This content downloaded from 210.212.249.225 on Tue, 10 May 2016 14:34:08 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
but a study of the Pittsburgh program did find that most participants
viewed arbitration outcomes as fair.21 Additionally, court-annexed
arbitration has many of the characteristics of adjudication - most
notably the application of rules of law by neutral decisionmakers.
Unfortunately, the success of arbitration programs has been less
than uniform. The seventh amendment right to a jury trial requires
that arbitrated settlements be nonbinding, unless the parties agree
otherwise.22 In cases seen to be very important to the litigants
whether for monetary reasons or otherwise - losing parties are rarely
willing to accept the result of arbitration as long as a trial de novo
remains available and they have so little to lose by resorting to fullblown litigation. Only if parties agree beforehand to waive their jury
rights can arbitration be fully effective.23
18 Obviously, some small tort and contract disputes can often present novel and important
public law issues. The danger of this occurring, however, is much less than that which would
occur if constitutional and regulatory cases were arbitrated. Furthermore, court-annexed arbitration ensures the parties eventual access to the courts, where novel public law issues can be
resolved.
19 See INSTITUTE FOR CIVIL JUSTICE, AN OVERVIEW OF THE FIRST FIVE PROGRAM YEARS
36 (I983).
20 See Shuart, Smith & Planet, Settling Cases in Detroit: An Examination of Wayne County's
"Mediation" Program, 8 JUST. SYs. J. 307, 315 (I983).
23 Over half of all arbitrated settlements in the Maryland Health Claims Arbitration System,
This content downloaded from 210.212.249.225 on Tue, 10 May 2016 14:34:08 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
for example, are refused by parties who demand a trial de novo. See MacAlister & Scanlan,
Health Claims Arbitration in Maryland: The Experiment Has Failed, I4 U. BALT. L. REv.
48I, 50I (I985). Similarly, about 6o% of the litigants studied in three federal district courts
refused arbitrated settlements in the court-annexed arbitration programs adopted by those courts.
See E. LIND & J. SHAPARD, EVALUATION OF COURT-ANNEXED ARBITRATION IN THREE FEDERAL DISTRICT COURTS 76 (I983).
24 A study of three federal district court programs found that, in two of the three districts
studied, the time from filing to disposition decreased as a result of arbitration. In most cases
this was because arbitration encouraged earlier settlements. See E. LIND & J. SHAPARD, supra
note 23, at 76-77.
In addition, some private groups have begun using agreements designed to prevent litigation
altogether. IBM and Hitachi, for example, have agreed, as part of a consent decree in a major
trade secret case, to resolve all future trade secrets disputes by negotiation and arbitration. See
S. GOLDBERG, E. GREEN & F. SANDER, DISPUTE RESOLUTION 545 (I985). Although not court-
annexed, this type of agreement between two private parties is not troubling because it is
unlikely to implicate public law issues.
This content downloaded from 210.212.249.225 on Tue, 10 May 2016 14:34:08 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
be examined without issue-obscuring procedural rules.27 Tens of thousands of cases are resolved this way each year by labor and commercial arbitration,28 and even more private disputes undoubtedly could
be better resolved through ADR than by adjudication.
However, if ADR is extended to resolve difficult issues of constitutional or public law - making use of nonlegal values to resolve
important social issues or allowing those the law seeks to regulate to
delimit public rights and duties - there is real reason for concern.
An oft-forgotten virtue of adjudication is that it ensures the proper
resolution and application of public values. In our rush to embrace
25 See J. AUERBACH, JUSTICE WITHOUT LAW? I38-47 (I983). However, even Auerbach
recognizes serious limitations on the use of local values in modern society, see, e.g., id. at I44
("[A]lternatives prevent the use of courts for redistributive purposes in the interest of equality,
by consigning the rights of disadvantaged citizens to institutions with minimal power to enforce
or protect them.").
26 Address by Chief Justice Warren E. Burger, in Minneapolis, Minnesota 4 (Aug. 2I, I985).
This content downloaded from 210.212.249.225 on Tue, 10 May 2016 14:34:08 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
The concern here is that ADR will replace the rule of law with
nonlegal values. J. Anthony Lucas' masterful study of Boston during
the busing crisis highlights the critical point that often our nation's
most basic values - such as equal justice under the law - conflict
with local nonlegal mores.30 This was true in Boston during the
school desegregation battle, and it was true in the South during the
civil rights battles of the sixties. This conflict, however, between
national public values reflected in rules of law and nonlegal values
that might be embraced in alternative dispute resolution, exists in
even more mundane public issues.
For example, many environmental disputes are now settled by
negotiation and mediation instead of adjudication. Indeed, as my
colleague Judge Wald recently observed, there is little hope that Superfund legislation can solve our nation's toxic waste problem unless
the vast bulk of toxic waste disputes are resolved through negotiation,
rather than litigation.31 Yet, as necessary as environmental negotiation may be, it is still troubling. When Congress or a government
agency has enacted strict environmental protection standards, negotiations that compromise these strict standards with weaker standards
result in the application of values that are simply inconsistent with
the rule of law. Furthermore, environmental mediation and negotiation present the danger that environmental standards will be set by
private groups without the democratic checks of governmental institutions. Professor Schoenbrod recently has written of an impressive
environmental mediation involving the settlement of disputes concerning the Hudson River. According to Schoenbrod, in that case private
parties bypassed federal and state agencies, reached an accommodation on environmental issues, and then presented the settlement to
governmental regulators. The alternative to approval of the settlement was continued litigation, which was already in its seventeenth
year, with no end in sight.32
The resulting agreement may have been laudable in bringing an
end to protracted litigation. But surely the mere resolution of a
29 Fiss, Against Settlement, 93 YALE L.J. I073, io85 (I984).
30 See J. LuKAS, COMMON GROUND: A TURBULENT DECADE IN THE LIVES OF THREE
AMERICAN FAMILIES I27 (I985); Lukas, Community and Equality in Conflict, N.Y. Times,
This content downloaded from 210.212.249.225 on Tue, 10 May 2016 14:34:08 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
dispute is not proof that the public interest has been served. This is
not to say that private settlements can never produce results that are
consistent with the public interest; rather, it is to say that private
settlements are troubling when we have no assurance that the legislative- or agency-mandated standards have been followed, and when
won't say they hated each other, but they were enemies. But in the
end, they were bringing up ideas about how they could work together. "34
This content downloaded from 210.212.249.225 on Tue, 10 May 2016 14:34:08 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
36 As Carol Lefcourt of the National Center on Women and Family Law explains:
This content downloaded from 210.212.249.225 on Tue, 10 May 2016 14:34:08 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Some forms of mediation, however, would protect the public values at stake. Professors Mnookin and Kornhauser suggest, for example, that divorce settlements can be be mediated successfully despite disparities in bargaining power by requiring court review of
outside the competence of arbitrators.39 So long as we restrict arbitrators to the application of clearly defined rules of law, and strictly
confine the articulation of public law to our courts, ADR can be an
effective means of reducing mushrooming caseloads. Employment
37 See Mnookin & Kornhauser, Bargaining in the Shadow of the Law: The Case of Divorce,
39 See, e.g., Devine v. White, 697 F.2d 421, 438-39 (D.C. Cir. i983) (suggesting that labor
arbitrators are just as q-alified to interpret statutes governing personnel relations as they are to
interpret labor contracts).
40 See Edwards, supra note 5, at 925-26, 930. But cf. Getman, Labor Arbitration and
This content downloaded from 210.212.249.225 on Tue, 10 May 2016 14:34:08 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
41 There has been a movement in state courts to protect even nonunionized employees from
unjust dismissals. See Note, Protecting Employees at Will Against Wrongful Discharge: The
Public Policy Exception, 96 HARV. L. REv. 193I, I931 (I983); Note, Protecting at Will Employees Against Wrongful Discharge: The Duty to Terminate Only in Good Faith, 93 HARV. L.
REV. i8i6 (I980).
42 See Katsoris, The Arbitration of a Public Securities Dispute, 53 FORDHAM L. REV. 279
(I984). In Wilko v. Swan, 346 U.S. 427 (I953), the Supreme Court held arbitration agreements
between investors and broker-dealers nonenforceable. Under SEC rule I5C2-2, such arbitration
agreements are illegal. Hence, in order for arbitration to be effective in the securities area,
either Congress must change the law to permit arbitration agreements or the procedures developed by the industry must be attractive to securities plaintiffs.
43 See Getman, supra note 40.
This content downloaded from 210.212.249.225 on Tue, 10 May 2016 14:34:08 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
in nonjudicial fora.
IV. OVERRIDING CONSIDERATIONS
47 See Janes, The Role of Legal Services Programs in Establishing and Operating Mediation
Programs for Poor People, i8 CLEARINGHOUSE REV. 520, 521 (1984).
48 In order to ensure that public law issues are not resolved in private fora, we must permit
litigants who raise issues of public or constitutional law to use courts even if private ADR
systems have already settled the dispute. Cf. Alexander v. Gardner-Denver Co., 415 U.S. 36
(1974) (holding that a title VII claimant does not waive his right to proceed in federal court by
virtue of an adverse decision in grievance-arbitration).
This content downloaded from 210.212.249.225 on Tue, 10 May 2016 14:34:08 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
50 I recognize that legal values may not be wholly absent from ADR mechanisms. See
Eisenberg, Private Ordering Through Negotiation, 89 HARV. L. REV. 637 (I976).
This content downloaded from 210.212.249.225 on Tue, 10 May 2016 14:34:08 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
51 Higginbotham, The Priority of Human Rights in Court Reform, 70 F.R.D. 134, 138 (1976).
This content downloaded from 210.212.249.225 on Tue, 10 May 2016 14:34:08 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms