Why Is The Chinese Saving Rate So High?: Guonan Ma and Wang Yi
Why Is The Chinese Saving Rate So High?: Guonan Ma and Wang Yi
Why Is The Chinese Saving Rate So High?: Guonan Ma and Wang Yi
Introduction
Chinas saving rate has been puzzlingly high. The nation saves half of
its GDP and its marginal propensity to save approached 60% during the
2000s, when its per capita GDP was only US$3,500 or one-tenth of the
OECD average (ADB 2009; IMF 2009; Zhou 2009). Such a saving rate
may have important implications both for Chinas own internal and external balance.
This article has three aims: to highlight the stylised facts of Chinese saving; to review the debate over factors shaping the saving dynamics, both
across sectors and over time; and to explore its medium-term outlook and
policy implications. Our critical review combines an international comparison of gross national saving and a breakdown of this aggregate by the
components of household, corporate and government saving. We hope to
take stock of the progress in understanding Chinese saving behaviour, put
the debate in perspective and shed new light on the trends in, and forces
behind, high Chinese saving.
The main findings of the article are as follows.
First, Chinas saving rate is high by historical experience, international
standards and model predictions, and has also been rising over time,
especially in the 2000s.
Guonan Ma is a senior
economist at the Representative
Office for Asia and the Pacific of
the Bank for International
Settlements (BIS)
Second, saving by each of the three sectors is also high but not exceptional. What sets China apart from the rest of the world is that it ranks
near the top globally across all three components.
Third, three major but underappreciated factors have been key: (i) major
institutional reforms including corporate restructuring, pension reform
and the spread of private home ownership; (ii) a marked Lewis-model
transformation process as labour left the subsistence sector where its
marginal product was less than its average wage; and (iii) a compressed
demographic transition, with a prospective rapid ageing process.
Fourth, our evidence questions the proposition that distortions and subsidies have been the principal causes of Chinas rising corporate profits
or high saving rate.
Fifth, adjusting for the effect of inflation and leverage alters the time
path and sectoral dynamics of Chinas corporate saving. Our inflationadjusted numbers suggest that most of the smaller increase in corporate
saving took place in the 2000s and not in the 1990s as appears from
the raw data.
While structural factors point to a likely peak in the Chinese saving
rate in the medium term, policy measures can contribute to the transition
to more balanced domestic demand. Nevertheless, much awaits further
exploration about the puzzle of high Chinese saving.
The article is organised as follows. The next section highlights the stylised facts about Chinas saving rate and provides a broader backdrop. After
that, we examine saving of the corporate, household and government
sectors respectively. We next outline three structural factors and several
policy measures shaping the medium-term outlook for the Chinese saving
rate, before the final section concludes.
2
1992
1995
2000
2005
2006
2007
2008
China
39.2
38.8
42.1
36.8
51.2
54.1
54.1
54.3
China
35.6
36.4
38.1
37.3
48.2
49.5
51.8
53.2
India
23.0
21.4
24.5
23.8
34.3
35.8
37.6
33.6
Japan
33.2
33.2
29.3
27.5
26.8
26.9
27.0
...
Korea
37.7
36.9
36.2
33.6
32.7
31.2
30.6
31.9
Mexico
23.6
18.6
21.1
23.8
23.3
25.5
...
...
Singapore
43.6
45.8
49.3
46.9
48.7
49.9
51.7
48.3
Australia
18.6
18.0
18.7
19.7
21.6
21.8
22.5
...
Canada
17.3
13.4
18.3
23.6
23.8
24.4
23.7
...
France
20.8
19.6
19.1
21.6
18.5
19.3
19.9
18.9
Germany
25.3
22.3
21.0
20.2
22.2
23.9
25.9
26.0
Italy
20.8
19.1
22.0
20.6
19.5
19.6
20.0
18.2
Switzerland
33.1
28.6
29.6
34.7
36.9
35.5
31.2
...
United
Kingdom
16.4
14.3
15.9
15.0
14.6
14.2
15.6
...
14.2
15.5
17.7
14.6
15.8
14.0
12.1
Notes
For China, the first row is gross national saving estimated using expenditure-based GDP, while the second row shows estimates using
production-based GDP. The latter one is consistent with the flow-of-funds statistics to be employed hereafter unless otherwise
specified.
Sources: Asian Development Bank (ADB); National Bureau of Statistics of China (NBS); OECD; authors own estimates
55
Expenditure-based
Production-based
50
45
35
40
25
35
0
Japan (195581)
Korea (197096)
China
India
45
15
1984
1988
1992
1996
2000
2004
2008
1982
1987
1992
1997
2002
2007
1 Gross national saving is estimated using production-based GDP, unless otherwise specified.
Sources: National Bureau of Statistics of China (NBS); authors own estimates.
Third, Chinese gross national saving is not only high but has also generally been rising over time, from 30% of GDP in the early 1980s to above
50% of GDP of late (Figure 1). Therefore, the marginal propensity to save
reached 54% over the period 19822008.
Fourth, Chinas saving rate has evolved in three distinct phases first, a
steady increase from 3035% of GDP to 4045% between 1982 and 1994,
then a decline to around 37% by 2000 and, finally, a resurgence thereafter
to reach over 50% (Figure 1). During this last phase, Chinas saving rate on
average went up 2 percentage points of GDP per year, implying a marginal
propensity to save of 60%.
Fifth, such a rapid rise in the saving rate is rare, but by no means unique
to China. Fast-growing Asian economies in their transition phases experienced similar upswings (Figure 1). Japans aggregate saving/GDP ratio rose
by 15percentage points during 195570, and Koreas increased from 16% to
40% between 1983 and 2000. Within one decade, Indias saving rate registered a rise of 10percentage points of GDP, reaching 38% by 2008.
Sixth, the Chinese household, corporate and government sectors each
have added to the rise in gross national saving. In terms of each individual
component, Chinas saving is high but not exceptional. As a share of
GDP, Chinas corporate saving at best rivals Japans, its household saving
is below Indias, and its government saving is less than Koreas (Figure
2). What distinguishes China from other countries is that its three saving
components have all ranked near their global tops, resulting in an exceptionally high aggregate saving rate.
4
Household
Corporate
Government
50
40
Household
Corporate
Government
50
40
30
30
20
20
10
10
0
92
94
96
98
00
02
04
06
08
US
TW
PH
FR
DE
JP
KR
IN
CN
Manufacturing
Construction
Services
Percentage of GDP
1980
1990
2000
2008
30.2
27.1
15.1
10.7
43.9
36.7
40.4
41.1
4.3
4.6
5.6
5.4
21.6
31.5
39.0
41.8
Agricultural
employment
Percentage
of total
employment
68.7
60.1
50.0
39.6
WorkingUrban
age
population
population
Percentage of total
population
19.4
26.4
36.2
45.7
59.7
66.7
68.4
74.3
low wage rate. It predicts a rising profit share in income, accelerated capital accumulation and faster economic growth during the transformation
process, therefore implying a higher saving rate. This process, while not
unique, could have been more accentuated in Chinas case because of
its compressed demographic transition and a larger pool of surplus rural
labour cumulated over the three decades prior to the early 1980s, thus in
part helping to explain its recent high saving rate.
Three key institutional factors
First, between 1995 and 2005, China went through its toughest corporate
restructuring, with large-scale labour retrenchment. The employment at
Figure 3: State employment and residential floor space in China
40
30
20
100
20
10
50
10
87
89
91
93
95
97
99
01
03
07
40
30
85 87 89 91 93 95 97 99 01 03 07 09
1 In millions of persons.
2 In square metres.
Sources: NBS; authors own estimates
6
state companies was halved (Figure 3). Such corporate restructuring tends
to directly boost corporate efficiency and reduce job security, lifting both
corporate and household saving.
Second, the 1997 pension reform transformed the previous pay-as-yougo system to a partially funded three-pillar scheme. The new scheme
reduced pension benefits, increased contributions and introduced prefunded individual pension accounts.1 This change may take place out of
concerns over rising pressure on public retirement schemes in anticipation
of rapid population ageing, and thus may have induced additional saving,
the so-called second demographic dividend. Therefore, reduced pension
wealth and anticipated acceleration of population ageing could both lift
the current saving rate in China.
The third institutional reform relates to private home ownership.
Starting from the late 1990s, state firms no longer provide housing for
employees, while the government introduced private home ownership
and real estate market, which interacted with the second demographic
dividend to provide additional incentives to build up pension assets.
Chinas home ownership exceeds 85% today, as Chinas physical assets
of residential housing per capita more than doubled during 19852008
(Figure 3). The implied housing investment is enormous. Thus surging
demand for housing assets has been another driver for both high economic
growth and high saving in China.
(1)
1 For Chinas pension system, see Feldstein (1998); Song and Yang (2010); and Herd, Hu and Cohen (2010).
where Y and S are gross national disposable income and gross national
saving, respectively; and subscripts e, h and g denote the corporate (enterprise), household or government sector, respectively. Equation (1) says
that the sector is contribution to the aggregate saving rate (Si/Y) depends
on two factors: its income share in the economy (Yi/Y) and its average propensity to save from its own income (Si/Yi). Our discussion will be based
on Chinas flow-of-funds statistics, which provide the breakdowns of gross
national income and saving by sector, but start only from 1992.
Three observations of Chinas saving composition are worth highlighting upfront (Table 3). First, the household sector is the largest saver in
China today, followed by the corporate sector. Second, firms and government have contributed the most to the rise in the aggregate saving rate
since 1992, accounting for more than four-fifths of the 17-percentage-point
rise in Chinas saving/GDP ratio. Third, the year 2000 appears to be a
turning point when aggregate Chinese saving as a share of GDP started
its relentless climb of 16 percentage points. Half of this hike so far in the
2000s has come from the government sector.
Corporate saving
Chinas corporate saving doubled from 12% of GDP in 1992 to a peak of
24% in 2004, but has since fallen back to 19% in 2008, when Chinas current account surplus surged (Table3). Over the 16-year period 19922008,
it contributed some 40% of the increase in Chinese aggregate saving, but
its role has diminished somewhat since the mid-2000s.
Following standard national income accounting, gross corporate saving
= depreciation + retained earnings = depreciation + net earnings dividend payouts. By convention, the corporate sectors average propensity
to save is 100% (i.e. Se = Ye). We discuss these three components in turn:
depreciation, dividend payout and corporate profits.
Depreciation as a share of GDP has probably risen during the 1990s
and 2000s because of a higher capital stock and newer vintages of capital.
Given the rapid paces of industrialisation and capital accumulation discussed previously, the capital stock per worker in the industrial sector at
least doubled during 200008. According to Bai, Hsieh and Qian (2006),
Chinas capital stock as a ratio to GDP rose from 130% to 170% between
the early 1990s and the mid-2000s.
8
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
Memo: changes
19922008
7.1
19921999
4.7
20002008
2.3
MPS: 9208 1.00
3.1
-2.7
5.9
0.41
Adjusted saving
Corporate
Household
Government
(3)
4.4
4.1
3.2
2.5
3.7
4.0
3.3
2.6
3.3
4.2
5.1
7.0
4.6
6.4
8.9
10.8
11.0
Total
(1)+(2)+(3)
36.4
38.0
39.4
38.1
37.1
38.4
37.7
37.1
37.3
38.2
40.3
43.6
46.6
48.2
49.5
51.8
53.2
15.6
21.4
21.1
21.0
16.9
14.8
13.4
14.1
16.6
18.1
18.5
18.9
24.9
21.7
19.8
20.0
21.0
16.4
12.5
15.1
14.6
16.5
19.6
20.9
20.4
17.4
15.9
16.8
17.7
17.0
20.2
20.8
21.0
20.4
6.6
-1.1
7.7
0.46
16.8
0.9
15.9
0.54
5.9
1.1
4.4
1.00
4.3
1.0
3.0
0.40
Notes
The adjusted corporate saving is corporate saving allowing for the erosion in real corporate debt arising from inflation, which is approximated as a product of expected inflation and net corporate debt. Expected inflation is measured by the two-year moving average
of the GDP deflator. Net corporate debt is estimated as corporate loans less the sum of corporate deposits and half of the currency
in circulation. Corporate loans are taken as the sum of short-, medium- and long-term loans minus loans to the households. The
household loans before 2000 are computed backwards by the 2000 outstanding level and the flow-of-funds statistics. The adjusted
household saving is calculated on the assumption that adjustments in corporate saving are fully accommodated by household saving.
MPS stands for marginal propensity to save.
Sources: NBS; authors own estimates
More controversial have been the various theories about the retained
corporate earnings (net earnings minus dividend payout). For a given
level of corporate profits, low dividend payments by Chinese firms could
help lift help earning retained at firms and can be attributable to two pos-
Cash/sales (lhs)
Cash/assets (lhs)
Cash/GDP (rhs)
22.5
20.0
15.0
12.5
1
02
03
04
05
06
07
08
200
Profit/GDP (lhs)
Profit/sales (lhs)
Sales/GDP (rhs)
4 9
17.5
10.0
12
150
100
50
0 0
99
00
01
02 03
04 05
06 07 08
1 Based on a sample of 1333 Chinese companies listed in China and Hong Kong SAR; in per cent.
2 Profit and sales of industrial enterprises with annual sales of above RMB5 million from the principal business.
Sources: Credit Suisse; NBS; authors own estimates
10
government (the ultimate owner) and thus is retained within the corporate sector.
An even more controversial issue is the apparently higher corporate
profits (Figure 4). Many explanations have been advanced (Bai et al. 2006;
Dollar & Wei 2006; Hofman & Kuijs 2008). We first group these arguments under two broad hypotheses, then review their pros and cons, and
finally examine in particular the roles of exchange rate and interest rate.
One hypothesis argues that high Chinese corporate saving, and indeed
fast economic growth, is mostly the consequence of government distortions designed to subsidise the corporate sector in order to promote growth
and exports. Two particular arguments are advanced under this hypothesis
(Tyers & Lu 2008; ADB 2009; Jha et al. 2009). First, monopolies boost the
corporate profits of many state firms. Second, subsidies and factor price
distortions (such as financial repression, subsidies for energy inputs and
cheap land) inflate corporate earnings, again benefiting state firms. In
short, Chinas rapid economic growth and high saving rate are principally
a function of distortions and subsidies.
An alternative hypothesis emphasises the broader structural forces and
institutional reforms examined above as the more important factors boosting corporate saving. First, efficiency gains from corporate restructuring
and an expanding indigenous private sector have intensified competition,
raised productivity and helped drive fast economic growth, deliver cost
saving and lift corporate profits. Second, accentuated by a compressed
demographic transition and a large pool of surplus rural labour, the prolonged Chinese ruralurban labour migration has capped wage growth,
thus also boosting corporate profits.2
These two hypotheses are not mutually exclusive and may well coexist.
While the truth probably lies somewhere in between, a more interesting
question is which set of forces matters more in shaping Chinese corporate
saving, whether the identified distortions have become more significant
over time so as to help explain the higher corporate saving rate, and if the
evidence confirms the main predictions of these two hypotheses.
A central prediction of the distortion-and-subsidy hypothesis is that, as
the principal beneficiary, state companies should be the major driver of
the higher corporate profits, because they are more likely to enjoy greater
2 For details of the debate over whether China reaches a so-called Lewis turning point, whereby the pool of
surplus labour starts drying up, see Garnaut (2006), Cai(2007), and Zhang, Yang and Wang (2010).
11
Industrial turnover
200
State controlled1
Foreign-invested2
Other3
10
8
120
80
40
2
0
State controlled1
Foreign-invested2
Other3
160
99
00
01
02
03
04
05
06
07
08
99
00
01
02
03
04
05
06
07
08
1 State-controlled enterprises.
2 Foreign, Chinese Taipei or Hong Kong SAR invested and controlled enterprises operating in China.
3 All the rest, including non-state controlled joint shareholding companies, collectives, private companies and other joint ventures.
Sources: NBS; authors own estimates
market power, receive more government subsidies and gain from easier
access to cheaper credit. Yet, in reality, it has been Chinas less advantaged
local non-state firms that have been gaining both market and profit shares
(Figure 5). The share of local private firms in Chinas industrial profits
more than doubled from 20% to 43% during the 2000s, despite facing
more restricted access to external finance and higher funding cost (Ma &
Wang 2010). This casts doubt on the distortion-and-subsidy hypothesis,
and favours the hypothesis of efficiency gains.3 Since most privatised state
firms were initially loss-making, tend to achieve some cost saving and
have added to market competition, an expanding private sector, either out
of greenfield investment or privatisation, generally enhances corporate
efficiency.
The other evidence on the two hypotheses in interpreting Chinas
higher corporate saving seems mixed and indicates varying magnitudes of
influence on both corporate and national saving.
The effect of energy subsidies or resource taxes on Chinas overall corporate profitability is ambiguous. Given China as a growing net energy
importer, energy subsidies may indeed weaken the countrys current
3 Song, Storesletten and Fzilibotti (2009) suggest that the high-productivity and credit-constrained firms finance
investment by internal saving and thus tend to generate high corporate saving while maintaining high return to capital
by attracting more resources to themselves. This interesting insight differs importantly from the proposition that high
corporate profit and saving come mostly from state-sponsored subsidies and distortions.
12
13
60
120
40
100
20
80
94
96
98
00
02
04
China
Other emerging economies3
06
08
60
94 95 96 97 98 99 01 02 03 04 05 07 08 09
1 19942008 = 100.
2 As a percentage of GDP.
3 Simple average of the real effective exchange rates of ten major emerging economies (Argentina, Brazil, Chile, India, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico,
Thailand and Turkey).
Sources: NBS; BIS; authors own estimates
porate sector more than halved as a share of GDP, singlehandedly contributing to 30% of the rise in corporate saving (Figure 7). While one may
attribute this mostly to financial repression that depresses funding costs of,
and subsidises to, Chinese (state) firms, we think that corporate deleveraging and inflation volatility could be greater forces behind the declining net
corporate interest payments (Figure 7).
First, the net corporate debts the difference between corporate loans
and deposits as a share of GDP more than halved between 1992 and
2008, reducing net corporate interest payments at any given interest rate.
Second, as argued by Modigliani and Cohn (1979), in times of high inflation, a large part of the interest payments represents inflation premium
Figure 7: Inflation, interest payment and corporate saving in China
30
As a percentage of GDP
In per cent
20
25
20
4 40
12
15
3 30
10
2 20
1 10
92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08
93
95
97
99
01
03
05
07
16
09
1 The difference between corporate loans on the one hand and corporate deposit and cash held by the corporate sector on the other.
2 Two-year moving average of GDP deflator.
Sources: NBS; Peoples Bank of China (PBC); authors own estimates
14
compensating creditors for the reduction of their real debt claims, and thus
should be considered repayments of the loan principal. Hence corporate
profits may be understated in high-inflation years, and vice versa in times
of deflation. China swung from double-digit inflation in the early 1990s to
outright deflation in the late 1990s, giving rise to a big gap between the
economic and reported accounting profits. Our preliminary estimation of
this gap shows that corporate profits are understated in the high-inflation
years of 199296 and overstated in the deflationary years of 19982000
(Table 3).
In sum, it is no easy task to identify the precise roles of the aforementioned factors in driving high corporate saving. While distortions and subsidies might inflate earnings at state companies and for some industries,
they were unlikely to have been the primary factor lifting Chinas gross
corporate saving. On balance, we tend to think that corporate restructuring, privatisation, slower wage growth owing to a large pool of surplus rural
labour and big swings in inflation are more important factors influencing
the evolving corporate saving during this episode.
Household saving
The household sector is the largest saver in China, but its saving fell from
20% of GDP in 1992 to a low of 16% in 2001 before staging a marked
comeback to 23% by 2008 (see Table 3 and Figure 2). During the 1992
2008 period, the household sector contributed only 3 percentage points of
the 17-percentage point rise in the nations aggregate saving rate.
This modest contribution has been the consequence of two competing
influences: a 10-percentage-point decline in the household share in gross
national disposable income and a 10-percentage-point rise in the average
propensity to save from household disposable income (Table4). Both have
weighed down Chinas private consumption share in GDP (Aziz & Cui
2007; Guo & NDiaye 2010). We discuss these two forces in turn.
The big drop in the household share in gross national disposable income
over the 19922008 period can be attributable to a fall in the labour share
in national income, and a decline in both investment income and net
income transfers for the household sector.
It is, first and foremost, the consequence of a declining labour share in the
economy, as the decline in the labour share accounts for some 60% of the
observed decline in the household income share between 1992 and 2007.
15
The sluggish Chinese wage growth until the late 2000s may have been the
combined outcome of the aforementioned structural and institutional forces
along the Lewis dualism transition, as well as other factors such as a lagging
service sector and difficult financing conditions for small firms.
Net interest income as a share of GDP halved during 19922007,
accounting for a quarter of the decline in the household income share.
As the household sector is a net creditor, much of the high net interest
income in the mid-1990s is simply the inflation premium required to
compensate the household depositors for the real depreciation of their
bank deposits. Hence household disposable income is overstated for highinflation years and understated for deflation years. Another reason for the
falling net interest income is the rising household debt in the past decade,
to be discussed below.
A third factor is reduced net transfers, mostly because of the increased
contributions required to fund the large future pension benefits and
other welfare obligations related to the expected population ageing (see
above). Social welfare contributions made by the household sector tripled
between 1992 and 2007, from 1.4% of GDP to 4.2%.
Despite this drop in household income share, household saving still
managed to rise as a share of GDP, owing to the much higher personal
saving propensity, which rose by 10 percentage points, mostly during the
2000s (Table 4). The high and rising household saving propensity has
been a subject of intense research, grouped here in four broad sets of
interpretation.
First, as life-cycle, permanent-income and habit-formation hypotheses
suggest, interactions among economic growth, income level and demographic changes may influence the personal saving rate. As mentioned
previously, a sharp decline in the Chinese youth dependency rate and
the expected rapid ageing of population might have interacted with high
growth and saving/consumption habit persistence, contributing to a higher
personal saving propensity. A related factor is the much flatter earning
profile over the life cycle in recent years, which in part helps explain a
high average household saving rate that displays a U-shaped pattern across
cohorts.4 Nevertheless, these forces by themselves can explain only part of
the high household saving rate in the 2000s.
4 For more details, see Modigliani and Cao (2004), Horioka and Wan (2008), Chamon and Prasad (2008), Wei
and Zhang (2009), Ma and Zhou (2009), and Songand Yang (2010).
16
Household
Adjusted
Government
corporate
Adjusted
household
Household
Adjusted
household
Government
1992
11.7
68.3
20.0
15.5
64.5
29.5
25.4
22.0
1993
15.7
64.6
19.7
21.4
59.0
28.1
21.2
21.0
1994
14.5
67.0
18.5
21.1
60.4
32.4
25.0
17.1
1995
16.0
67.2
16.5
21.3
62.1
29.6
23.8
15.5
1996
13.5
68.4
17.9
17.1
65.0
29.4
25.7
20.7
1997
13.0
68.6
18.3
14.9
66.8
31.4
29.6
21.9
1998
13.3
68.4
18.1
13.6
68.3
31.2
31.1
18.3
1999
14.6
67.2
18.1
14.2
67.7
29.8
30.3
14.7
2000
16.5
64.2
19.2
16.7
64.1
27.5
27.3
17.2
2001
17.4
62.0
20.5
18.3
61.2
27.0
26.1
20.8
2002
18.0
61.0
21.0
18.5
60.5
28.3
27.7
24.2
2003
18.3
59.8
22.0
18.8
59.2
30.4
29.8
31.4
2004
23.5
57.8
18.9
24.7
56.4
31.6
29.9
24.0
2005
20.4
59.4
20.5
21.3
58.1
35.6
34.2
30.4
2006
18.8
58.7
22.8
19.5
57.8
36.4
35.4
38.6
2007
18.8
57.5
24.1
19.7
56.3
37.9
36.6
44.2
2008
18.8
57.6
23.9
20.6
55.5
39.9
36.1
45.3
17
14
3,000
12
10
2,000
8
1,000
0
6
00
01
02
03
04
05
06
07
08 4
Household debt
As a percentage of:
GDP
25
Household disposable income
Household net worth
20
30
15
10
5
0 00
01
02
03
04
05
06
07
08
1 In billions of renminbi.
Sources: Credit Suisse; NBS; PBC; authors own estimates
18
20.0
20.0
17.5
17.5
15.0
15.0
12.5
12.5
10.0
94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08
10.0
Government expenditures1
Government consumption2
93 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08
1 Based on the fiscal and budgetary statistics, including both budgetary and extra-budgetary revenues and expenditure.
2 Based on the flow-of-funds statistics.
Sources: NBS; authors own estimates
19
12.5
10.0
7.5
5.0
2.5
0.0
KR
CN
MY
TH
IN
SG
PH
HK
ID
01
02
03
04
05
06
07
08
09
1 Only covers the net assets directly managed by the central government.
2 Balances pooled and managed at both the national and provincial levels in China.
Sources: IMF; NBS; the National Social Welfare Fund of China
20
21
22
Conclusion
This paper critically surveys the stylised facts and explanations about
Chinas gross national saving, and its corporate, household and government components. All three sectors have added substantially to Chinas
high and rising saving rate, especially during the 2000s. What distinguishes
China from the rest of the world is its combination of three high savers,
making Chinas aggregate saving rate exceptionally high. Moreover, over
the past three decades, Chinese saving has experienced at least three distinct phases. As such, no single theory or model can elegantly decipher the
puzzle of high Chinese saving.
Acknowledgements
The views expressed here are those of the authors only and do not necessarily reflect those of the BIS or the PBC. We wish to thank many, particularly Claudio Borio, Ben Cohen, Andy Filardo, Robert McCauley, Thomas
Rawski and Philip Turner for their comments, and Lillie Lam for her able
assistance. Any errors are ours.
References
Asian Development Bank (2009) Asian Development Outlook 2009: Rebalancing Asias
Growth. Manila: Asian Development Bank.
Aziz, J. & Cui, L. (2007) Explaining Chinas low consumption: the neglected role of
household income. IMF working paper WP/07/181. Washington, DC: IMF.
Bai, C. & Qian, Z. (2009) Factor income share in China: the story behind the
statistics. Economic Research, 3, pp. 2740.
Bai, C., Hsieh, C. & Qian, Y. (2006) Return to capital in China. NBER working paper
12755.
Bayoumi, T., Tong, H. & Wei, S. (2009) Chinas corporate savings is not a key driver
for its current account surplus: a cross-country firm-level comparative perspective.
Draft paper presented at the HKMA conference: Financial reform, macro policy and
currency internationalisation: the case of China. Hong Kong.
23
24
25
26