Samir Amin, Contemporary Imperialism
Samir Amin, Contemporary Imperialism
Samir Amin, Contemporary Imperialism
monthlyreview.org /2015/07/01/contemporary-imperialism/
Samir Amin
Samir Amin is director of the Third World Forum in Dakar, Senegal. His books published by Monthly Review Press
include The Liberal Virus, The World We Wish to See, The Law of Worldwide Value, The Implosion of Contemporary
Capitalism, and Three Essays on Marxs Value Theory .
1/9
chose rapid industrialization and armament (and this choice was not without some connection to the rise of fascism).
Collectivization was the price of that choice. Here again we must beware of judging too quickly: all socialists of that
period (and even more the capitalists) shared Kautskys analyses on this point and were persuaded that the future
belonged to large-scale agriculture.3 The break in the worker-peasant alliance that this choice implied lay behind the
abandonment of revolutionary democracy and the autocratic turn.
In my opinion, Trotsky would certainly not have done better. His attitude towards the rebellion of the Kronstadt
sailors and his later equivocations demonstrate that he was no dierent than the other Bolshevik leaders in
government. But, after 1927, living in exile and no longer having responsibility for managing the Soviet state, he
could delight in endlessly repeating the sacred principles of socialism. He became like many academic Marxists who
have the luxury of asserting their attachment to principles without having to be concerned about eectiveness in
transforming reality.4
The Chinese communists appeared later on the revolutionary stage. Mao was able to learn from Bolshevik
equivocations. China was confronted with the same problems as Soviet Russia: revolution in a backward country,
the necessity of including the peasantry in revolutionary transformation, and the hostility of the imperialist powers.
But Mao was able to see more clearly than Lenin, Bukharin, and Stalin. Yes, the Chinese revolution was antiimperialist and peasant (anti-feudal). But it was not bourgeois democratic; it was popular democratic. The dierence
is important: the latter type of revolution requires maintaining the worker-peasant alliance over a long period. China
was thus able to avoid the fatal error of forced collectivization and invent another way: make all agricultural land
state property, give the peasantry equal access to use of this land, and renovate family agriculture.5
The two revolutions had diculty in achieving stability because they were forced to reconcile support for a socialist
outlook and concessions to capitalism. Which of these two tendencies would prevail? These revolutions only
achieved stability after their Thermidor, to use Trotskys term. But when was the Thermidor in Russia? Was it in
1930, as Trotsky said? Or was it in the 1920s, with the NEP? Or was it the ice age of the Brezhnev period? And in
China, did Mao choose Thermidor beginning in 1950? Or do we have to wait until Deng Xiaoping to speak of the
Thermidor of 1980?
It is not by chance that reference is made to lessons of the French Revolution. The three great revolutions of modern
times (the French, Russian, and Chinese) are great precisely because they looked forward beyond the immediate
requirements of the moment. With the rise of the Mountain, led by Robespierre, in the National Convention, the
French Revolution was consolidated as both popular and bourgeois and, just like the Russian and Chinese
Revolutionswhich strove to go all the way to communism even if it were not on the agenda due to the necessity of
averting defeatretained the prospect of going much further later. Thermidor is not the Restoration. The latter
occurred in France, not with Napoleon, but only beginning in 1815. Still it should be remembered that the
Restoration could not completely do away with the gigantic social transformation caused by the Revolution. In
Russia, the restoration occurred even later in its revolutionary history, with Gorbachev and Yeltsin. It should be
noted that this restoration remains fragile, as can be seen in the challenges Putin must still confront. In China, there
has not been (or not yet!) a restoration.6
2/9
In the meantime, there is a two-fold challenge confronting the peoples and states of the South: (1) the lumpen
development that contemporary capitalism forces on all peripheries of the system has nothing to oer three-quarters
of humanity; in particular, it leads to the rapid destruction of peasant societies in Asia and Africa, and consequently
the response given to the peasant question will largely govern the nature of future changes;7 (2) the aggressive
geostrategy of the imperialist powers, which is opposed to any attempt by the peoples and states of the periphery to
get out of the impasse, forces the peoples concerned to defeat the military control of the world by the United States
and its subaltern European and Japanese allies.
The rst long systemic crisis of capitalism got underway in the 1870s. The version of historic capitalisms extension
over the long span that I have put forward suggests a succession of three epochs: ten centuries of incubation from
the year 1000 in China to the eighteenth-century revolutions in England and France, a short century of triumphal
ourishing (the nineteenth century), probably a long decline comprising in itself the rst long crisis (18751945) and
then the second (begun in 1975 and still ongoing). In each of those two long crises, capital responds to the challenge
by the same triple formula: concentration of capitals control, deepening of uneven globalization, nancialization of
the systems management.8 Two major thinkers (Hobson and Hilferding) immediately grasped the enormous
importance of capitalisms transformation into monopoly capitalism. But it was Lenin and Bukharin who drew the
political conclusion from this transformation, a transformation that initiated the decline of capitalism and thus moved
the socialist revolution onto the agenda.9
The primary formation of monopoly capitalism thus goes back to the end of the nineteenth century, but in the United
States it really established itself as a system only from the 1920s, to conquer next the Western Europe and Japan of
the thirty glorious years following the Second World War. The concept of surplus, put forth by Baran and Sweezy in
the 19501960 decade, allows a grasp of what is essential in the transformation of capitalism. Convinced at the
moment of its publication by that work of enrichment to the Marxist critique of capitalism, I undertook as soon as the
1970s its reformulation which required, in my opinion, the transformation of the rst (19201970) monopoly
capitalism into generalized-monopoly capitalism, analyzed as a qualitatively new phase of the system.
In the previous forms of competition among rms producing the same use valuenumerous then, and independent
of each otherdecisions were made by the capitalist owners of those rms on the basis of a recognized market
price which imposed itself as an external datum. Baran and Sweezy observed that the new monopolies act
dierently: they set their prices simultaneously with the nature and volume of their outputs. So it is an end to fair and
open competition, which remains, quite contrary to reality, at the heart of conventional economics rhetoric! The
abolition of competitionthe radical transformation of that terms meaning, of its functioning and of its results
detaches the price system from its basis, the system of values, and in that very way hides from sight the referential
framework which used to dene capitalisms rationality. Although use values used to constitute to a great extent
autonomous realities, they become, in monopoly capitalism, the object of actual fabrications produced systematically
through aggressive and particularized sales strategies (advertising, brands, etc.). In monopoly capitalism, a coherent
reproduction of the productive system is no longer possible merely by mutual adjustment of the two departments
discussed in the second volume of Capital: it is thenceforward necessary to take into account a Department III,
conceived by Baran and Sweezy. This allows for added surplus absorption promoted by the statebeyond
Department I (private investment) and beyond the portion of Department II (private consumption) devoted to
capitalist consumption. The classic example of Department III spending is military expenditure. However, the notion
of Department III can be expanded to cover the wider array of socially unreproductive expenditures promoted by
generalized-monopoly capitalism.10
The excrescence of Department III, in turn, favors in fact the erasure of the distinction made by Marx between
productive (of surplus-value) labor and unproductive labor. All forms of wage labor canand dobecome sources
of possible prots. A hairdresser sells his services to a customer who pays him out of his income. But if that
hairdresser becomes the employee of a beauty parlor, the business must realize a prot for its owner. If the country
at issue puts ten million wage workers to work in Departments I, II, and III, providing the equivalent of twelve million
years of abstract labor, and if the wages received by those workers allow them to buy goods and services requiring
3/9
merely six million years of abstract labor, the rate of exploitation for all of them, productive and unproductive
confounded, is the same 100 percent. But the six million years of abstract labor that the workers do not receive
cannot all be invested in the purchase of producer goods destined to expand Departments I and II; part of them will
be put toward the expansion of Department III.
Financialization of Accumulation
The new nancialization of economic life crowns this transformation in capitals power. In place of strategies set out
by real owners of fragmented capital are those of the managers of ownership titles over capital. What is vulgarly
called ctitious capital (the estimated value of ownership certicates) is nothing but the expression of this
displacement, this disconnect between the virtual and real worlds.
By its very nature capitalist accumulation has always been synonymous with disorder, in the sense that Marx gave to
that term: a system moving from disequilibrium to disequilibrium (driven by class struggles and conicts among the
powers) without ever tending toward an equilibrium. But this disorder resulting from competition among fragmented
capitals was kept within reasonable limits through management of the credit system carried out under the control of
4/9
the national state. With contemporary nancialized and globalized capitalism those frontiers disappear; the violence
of the movements from disequilibrium to disequilibrium is reinforced. The successor of disorder is chaos.
Domination by the capital of the generalized monopolies is exercised on the world scale through global integration of
the monetary and nancial market, based henceforward on the principle of exible exchange rates, and giving up
national controls over the ow of capital. Nevertheless, this domination is called into question, to varying degrees, by
state policies of the emerging countries. The conict between these latter policies and the strategic objectives of the
triads collective imperialism becomes by that fact one of the central axes for possibly putting generalized-monopoly
capitalism once more on trial.13
5/9
Another important consequence of this qualitative transformation of contemporary capitalism is the emergence of the
collective imperialism of the triad, which takes the place of the historical national imperialisms (of the United States,
Great Britain, Japan, Germany, France, and a few others). Collective imperialism nds its raison dtre in the
awareness by the bourgeoisies in the triad nations of the necessity for their joint management of the world and
particularly of the subjected, and yet to be subjected, societies of the peripheries.
Some draw two correlates from the thesis of the emergence of a globalized production system: the emergence of a
globalized bourgeoisie and the emergence of a globalized state, both of which would nd their objective foundation
in this new production system. My interpretation of the current changes and crises leads me to reject these two
correlates.
There is no globalized bourgeoisie (or dominant class) in the process of being formed, either on the world scale or in
the countries of the imperialist triad. I am led to emphasize the fact that the centralization of control over the capital of
the monopolies takes place within the nation-states of the triad (United States, each member of the European Union,
Japan) much more than it does in the relations between the partners of the triad, or even between members of the
European Union. The bourgeoisies (or oligopolistic groups) are in competition within nations (and the national state
manages this competition, in part at least) and between nations. Thus the German oligopolies (and the German
state) took on the leadership of European aairs, not for the equal benet of everyone, but rst of all for their own
benet. At the level of the triad, it is obviously the bourgeoisie of the United States that leads the alliance, once again
with an unequal distribution of the benets. The idea that the objective causethe emergence of the globalized
production systementails ipso facto the emergence of a globalized dominant class is based on the underlying
hypothesis that the system must be coherent. In reality, it is possible for it not to be coherent. In fact, it is not
coherent and hence this chaotic system is not viable.
In the peripheries, the globalization of the production system occurs in conjunction with the replacement of the
hegemonic blocs of earlier eras by a new hegemonic bloc dominated by the new comprador bourgeoisies, which are
not constitutive elements of a globalized bourgeoisie, but only subaltern allies of the bourgeoisies of the dominant
triad. Just like there is no globalized bourgeoisie in the process of formation, there is also no globalized state on the
horizon. The major reason for this is that the current globalized system does not attenuate, but actually accentuates
conict (already visible or potential) between the societies of the triad and those of the rest of the world. I do indeed
mean conict between societies and, consequently, potentially conict between states. The advantage derived from
the triads dominant position (imperialist rent) allows the hegemonic bloc formed around the generalized monopolies
to benet from a legitimacy that is expressed, in turn, by the convergence of all major electoral parties, right and left,
and their equal commitment to neoliberal economic policies and continual intervention in the aairs of the
peripheries. On the other hand, the neo-comprador bourgeoisies of the peripheries are neither legitimate nor
credible in the eyes of their own people (because the policies they serve do not make it possible to catch up, and
most often lead to the impasse of lumpen-development). Instability of the current governments is thus the rule in this
context.
Just as there is no globalized bourgeoisie even at the level of the triad or that of the European Union, there is also no
globalized state at these levels. Instead, there is only an alliance of states. These states, in turn, willingly accept the
hierarchy that allows that alliance to function: general leadership is taken on by Washington, and leadership in
Europe by Berlin. The national state remains in place to serve globalization as it is.
There is an idea circulating in postmodernist currents that contemporary capitalism no longer needs the state to
manage the world economy and thus that the state system is in the process of withering away to the benet of the
emergence of civil society. I will not go back over the arguments that I have developed elsewhere against this naive
thesis, one moreover that is propagated by the dominant governments and the media clergy in their service. There
is no capitalism without the state. Capitalist globalization could not be pursued without the interventions of the United
States armed forces and the management of the dollar. Clearly, the armed forces and money are instruments of the
state, not of the market.
6/9
But since there is no world state, the United States intends to fulll this function. The societies of the triad consider
this function to be legitimate; other societies do not. But what does that matter? The self-proclaimed international
community, i.e., the G7 plus Saudi Arabia, which has surely become a democratic republic, does not recognize the
legitimacy of the opinion of 85 percent of the worlds population!
There is thus an asymmetry between the functions of the state in the dominant imperialist centers and those of the
state in the subject, or yet to be subjected, peripheries. The state in the compradorized peripheries is inherently
unstable and, consequently, a potential enemy, when it is not already one.
There are enemies with which the dominant imperialist powers have been forced to coexistat least up until now.
This is the case with China because it has rejected (up until now) the neo-comprador option and is pursuing its
sovereign project of integrated and coherent national development. Russia became an enemy as soon as Putin
refused to align politically with the triad and wanted to block the expansionist ambitions of the latter in Ukraine, even
if he does not envision (or not yet?) leaving the rut of economic liberalism. The great majority of comprador states in
the South (that is, states in the service of their comprador bourgeoisies) are allies, not enemiesas long as each of
these comprador states gives the appearance of being in charge of its country. But leaders in Washington, London,
Berlin, and Paris know that these states are fragile. As soon as a popular movement of revoltwith or without a
viable alternative strategythreatens one of these states, the triad arrogates to itself the right to intervene.
Intervention can even lead to contemplating the destruction of these states and, beyond them, of the societies
concerned. This strategy is currently at work in Iraq, Syria, and elsewhere. The raison dtre of the strategy for
military control of the world by the triad led by Washington is located entirely in this realist vision, which is in direct
counterpoint to the naive view la Negriof a globalized state in the process of formation.14
7/9
moving away, as much as possible, from the liberal recipe and the electoral masquerade associated with it, which
claims to give legitimacy to regressive social policies. I would suggest setting up in its place a brand of new state
capitalism with a social dimension (I say social, not socialist). That system would open the road to eventual
advances toward a socialization of the management of the economy and therefore authentic new advances toward
an invention of democracy responding to the challenges of a modern economy.
Russian state power remaining within the strict limits of the neoliberal recipe annihilates the chances of success of
an independent foreign policy and the chances of Russia becoming a really emerging country acting as an important
international actor. Neoliberalism can produce for Russia only a tragic economic and social regression, a pattern of
lumpen development, and a growing subordinate status in the global imperialist order. Russia would provide the
triad with oil, gas, and some other natural resources; its industries would be reduced to the status of sub-contracting
for the benet of Western nancial monopolies. In such a position, which is not very far from that of Russia today in
the global system, attempts to act independently in the international area will remain extremely fragile, threatened by
sanctions which will strengthen the disastrous alignment of the ruling economic oligarchy to the demands of
dominant monopolies of the triad. The current outow of Russian capital associated with the Ukraine crisis
illustrates the danger. Reestablishing state control over the movements of capital is the only eective response to
that danger.
Outside of China, which is implementing a national project of modern industrial development in connection with the
renovation of family agriculture, the other so-called emergent countries of the South (the BRICS) still walk only on
one leg: they are opposed to the depredations of militarized globalization, but remain imprisoned in the straightjacket
of neoliberalism.18
Notes
1. In this article, I am limiting myself to examining the experiences of Russia and China, with no intention of
ignoring the other twentieth-century socialist revolutions (North Korea, Vietnam, Cuba).
2. Before the Second World War, Stalin had desperately, and unsuccessfully, sought an alliance with the
Western democracies against Nazism. After the war, Washington chose to pursue the Cold War, while Stalin
sought to extend friendship with the Western powers, again without success. See Georey Roberts,Stalins
Wars: From World War to Cold War, 19391953(New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 2007). See the
important preface by Annie Lacroix Riz to the French edition:Les guerres de Staline: De la guerre mondiale
la guerre froide (Paris: ditions Delga, 2014).
3. I am alluding here to Kautskys theses inThe Agrarian Question, 2 vols. (London: Pluto Press, 1988; rst
edition, 1899).
4. There are pleasant exceptions among Marxist intellectuals who, without having had responsibilities in the
leadership of revolutionary parties or, still less, of revolutionary states, have nonetheless remained attentive to
the challenges confronted by state socialisms (I am thinking here of Baran, Sweezy, Hobsbawn, and others).
5. See Samir Amin, China 2013,Monthly Review 64, no. 10 (March 2013): 1433, in particular for analyses
concerning Maoisms treatment of the agrarian question.
6. See Eric J. Hobsbawn,Echoes of the Marseillaise: Two Centuries Look Back on the French Revolution
(London: Verso, 1990); also see the works of Florence Gauthier. These authors do not assimilate Thermidor to
restoration, as the Trotskyist simplication suggests.
7. Concerning the destruction of the Asian and African peasantry currently underway, see Samir Amin,
Contemporary Imperialism and the Agrarian Question,Agrarian South: Journal of Political Economy 1, no. 1
(April 2012): 1126, http://ags.sagepub.com.
8. I discuss here only some of the major consequences of the move to generalized monopolies
(nancialization, decline of democracy). As for ecological questions, I refer to the remarkable works of John
8/9
Bellamy Foster.
9. Nicolai Bukharin, Imperialism and the World Economy (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1973; written in
1915); V. I. Lenin,Imperialism, The Highest Stage of Capitalism (New York: International Publishers, 1969;
written in 1916).
10. For further discussions of the Department III analysis and its relation to Baran and Sweezys theory of
surplus absorption see Samir Amin, Three Essays on Marxs Value Theory (New York: Monthly Review Press,
2013), 6776; and John Bellamy Foster, Marxian Crisis Theory and the State, in John Bellamy Foster and
Henryk Szlajfer, eds., The Faltering Economy (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1984), 32549.
11. Andre Gunder Frank and Samir Amin, Lets Not Wait for 1984, in Frank, Reections on the World
Economic Crisis (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1981).
12. Samir Amin, Empire of Chaos (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1992).
13. Concerning the challenge to nancial globalization, see Samir Amin, From Bandung (1955) to 2015: New
and Old Challenges for the Peoples and States of the South, paper presented at the World Social Forum,
Tunis, March 2015, and The Chinese Yuan, published in Chinese, 2013.
14. Contra Hardt and Negri,Monthly Review 66, no. 6 (November 2014): 2536.
15. The choice to delink is inevitable. The extreme centralization of the surplus at the world level in the form of
imperialist rent for the monopolies of the imperialist powers is unsupportable by all societies in the periphery.
It is necessary to deconstruct this system with the prospect of reconstructing it later in another form of
globalization compatible with communism understood as a more advanced stage of universal civilization. I
have suggested, in this context, a comparison with the necessary destruction of the centralization of the
Roman Empire, which opened the way to feudal decentralization.
16. Yash Tandon,Trade is War (New York: OR Books, forthcoming).
17. Samir Amin, Russia in the World System, chapter 7 in Global History: A View from the South(London:
Pambazuka Press, 2010), The Return of Fascism in Contemporary Capitalism,Monthly Review 66, no. 4
(September 2014): 112.
18. Concerning the inadequate responses of India and Brazil, see Samir Amin, The Implosion of Capitalism
(New York: Monthly Review Press, 2013), chapter 2, and Latin America Confronts the Challenge of
Globalization,Monthly Review 66, no. 7 (December 2014): 16.
9/9