Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

Samir Amin, Contemporary Imperialism

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 9
At a glance
Powered by AI
The key takeaways are that historical capitalism has always been imperialist in nature, and that the USSR faced many challenges in balancing industrialization, collectivization, and maintaining the worker-peasant alliance.

The author questions Lenin and Bukharin's thesis that imperialism is a new stage of capitalism associated with monopolies, arguing that capitalism has always led to polarization between centers and peripheries. Their hope that revolution would spread to Germany was also misguided.

They implemented the New Economic Plan to make concessions to the market and respect newly acquired peasant property, aiming to slowly progress towards socialism. However, this alliance was threatened by industrialization policies.

Contemporary Imperialism

monthlyreview.org /2015/07/01/contemporary-imperialism/
Samir Amin
Samir Amin is director of the Third World Forum in Dakar, Senegal. His books published by Monthly Review Press
include The Liberal Virus, The World We Wish to See, The Law of Worldwide Value, The Implosion of Contemporary
Capitalism, and Three Essays on Marxs Value Theory .

Lessons from the Twentieth Century


Lenin, Bukharin, Stalin, and Trotsky in Russia, as well as Mao, Zhou Enlai, and Den Xiaoping in China, shaped the
history of the two great revolutions of the twentieth century.1 As leaders of revolutionary communist parties and then
later as leaders of revolutionary states, they were confronted with the problems faced by a triumphant revolution in
countries of peripheral capitalism and forced to revise (I deliberately use this term, considered sacrilegious by
many) the theses inherited from the historical Marxism of the Second International. Lenin and Bukharin went much
further than Hobson and Hilferding in their analyses of monopoly capitalism and imperialism and drew this major
political conclusion: the imperialist war of 19141918 (they were among the few, if not the only ones, to anticipate it)
made necessary and possible a revolution led by the proletariat.
With the benet of hindsight, I will indicate here the limitations of their analyses. Lenin and Bukharin considered
imperialism to be a new stage (the highest) of capitalism associated with the development of monopolies. I
question this thesis and contend that historical capitalism has always been imperialist, in the sense that it has led to
a polarization between centers and peripheries since its origin (the sixteenth century), which has only increased over
the course of its later globalized development. The nineteenth-century pre-monopolist system was not less
imperialist. Great Britain maintained its hegemony precisely because of its colonial domination of India. Lenin and
Bukharin thought that the revolution, begun in Russia (the weak link), would continue in the centers (Germany in
particular). Their hope was based on an underestimate of the eects of imperialist polarization, which destroyed
revolutionary prospects in the centers.
Nevertheless, Lenin, and even more Bukharin, quickly learned the necessary historical lesson. The revolution, made
in the name of socialism (and communism), was, in fact, something else: mainly a peasant revolution. So what to
do? How can the peasantry be linked with the construction of socialism? By making concessions to the market and
by respecting newly acquired peasant property; hence by progressing slowly towards socialism? The New
Economic Plan (NEP) implemented this strategy.
Yes, but. Lenin, Bukharin, and Stalin also understood that the imperialist powers would never accept the
Revolution or even the NEP. After the hot wars of intervention, the cold war was to become permanent, from 1920 to
1990.2 Soviet Russia, even though it was far from being able to construct socialism, was able to free itself from the
straightjacket that imperialism always strives to impose on all peripheries of the world system that it dominates. In
eect, Soviet Russia delinked. So what to do now? Attempt to push for peaceful coexistence, by making
concessions if necessary and refraining from intervening too actively on the international stage? But at the same
time, it was necessary to be armed to face new and unavoidable attacks. And that implied rapid industrialization,
which, in turn, came into conict with the interests of the peasantry and thus threatened to break the worker-peasant
alliance, the foundation of the revolutionary state.
It is possible, then, to understand the equivocations of Lenin, Bukharin, and Stalin. In theoretical terms, there were
U-turns from one extreme to the other. Sometimes a determinist attitude inspired by the phased approach inherited
from earlier Marxism (rst the bourgeois democratic revolution, then the socialist one) predominated, sometimes a
voluntarist approach (political action would make it possible to leap over stages). Finally, from 19301933, Stalin

1/9

chose rapid industrialization and armament (and this choice was not without some connection to the rise of fascism).
Collectivization was the price of that choice. Here again we must beware of judging too quickly: all socialists of that
period (and even more the capitalists) shared Kautskys analyses on this point and were persuaded that the future
belonged to large-scale agriculture.3 The break in the worker-peasant alliance that this choice implied lay behind the
abandonment of revolutionary democracy and the autocratic turn.
In my opinion, Trotsky would certainly not have done better. His attitude towards the rebellion of the Kronstadt
sailors and his later equivocations demonstrate that he was no dierent than the other Bolshevik leaders in
government. But, after 1927, living in exile and no longer having responsibility for managing the Soviet state, he
could delight in endlessly repeating the sacred principles of socialism. He became like many academic Marxists who
have the luxury of asserting their attachment to principles without having to be concerned about eectiveness in
transforming reality.4
The Chinese communists appeared later on the revolutionary stage. Mao was able to learn from Bolshevik
equivocations. China was confronted with the same problems as Soviet Russia: revolution in a backward country,
the necessity of including the peasantry in revolutionary transformation, and the hostility of the imperialist powers.
But Mao was able to see more clearly than Lenin, Bukharin, and Stalin. Yes, the Chinese revolution was antiimperialist and peasant (anti-feudal). But it was not bourgeois democratic; it was popular democratic. The dierence
is important: the latter type of revolution requires maintaining the worker-peasant alliance over a long period. China
was thus able to avoid the fatal error of forced collectivization and invent another way: make all agricultural land
state property, give the peasantry equal access to use of this land, and renovate family agriculture.5
The two revolutions had diculty in achieving stability because they were forced to reconcile support for a socialist
outlook and concessions to capitalism. Which of these two tendencies would prevail? These revolutions only
achieved stability after their Thermidor, to use Trotskys term. But when was the Thermidor in Russia? Was it in
1930, as Trotsky said? Or was it in the 1920s, with the NEP? Or was it the ice age of the Brezhnev period? And in
China, did Mao choose Thermidor beginning in 1950? Or do we have to wait until Deng Xiaoping to speak of the
Thermidor of 1980?
It is not by chance that reference is made to lessons of the French Revolution. The three great revolutions of modern
times (the French, Russian, and Chinese) are great precisely because they looked forward beyond the immediate
requirements of the moment. With the rise of the Mountain, led by Robespierre, in the National Convention, the
French Revolution was consolidated as both popular and bourgeois and, just like the Russian and Chinese
Revolutionswhich strove to go all the way to communism even if it were not on the agenda due to the necessity of
averting defeatretained the prospect of going much further later. Thermidor is not the Restoration. The latter
occurred in France, not with Napoleon, but only beginning in 1815. Still it should be remembered that the
Restoration could not completely do away with the gigantic social transformation caused by the Revolution. In
Russia, the restoration occurred even later in its revolutionary history, with Gorbachev and Yeltsin. It should be
noted that this restoration remains fragile, as can be seen in the challenges Putin must still confront. In China, there
has not been (or not yet!) a restoration.6

A New Stage of Monopoly Capital


The contemporary world is still confronted with the same challenges encountered by the revolutions of the twentieth
century. The continued deepening of the center/periphery contrast, characteristic of the spread of globalized
capitalism, still leads to the same major political consequence: transformation of the world begins with antiimperialist, national, popularand potentially anti-capitalistrevolutions, which are the only ones on the agenda for
the foreseeable future. But this transformation will only be able to go beyond the rst steps and proceed on the path
to socialism later if and when the peoples of the centers, in turn, begin the struggle for communism, viewed as a
higher stage of universal human civilization. The systemic crisis of capitalism in the centers gives a chance for this
possibility to be translated into reality.

2/9

In the meantime, there is a two-fold challenge confronting the peoples and states of the South: (1) the lumpen
development that contemporary capitalism forces on all peripheries of the system has nothing to oer three-quarters
of humanity; in particular, it leads to the rapid destruction of peasant societies in Asia and Africa, and consequently
the response given to the peasant question will largely govern the nature of future changes;7 (2) the aggressive
geostrategy of the imperialist powers, which is opposed to any attempt by the peoples and states of the periphery to
get out of the impasse, forces the peoples concerned to defeat the military control of the world by the United States
and its subaltern European and Japanese allies.
The rst long systemic crisis of capitalism got underway in the 1870s. The version of historic capitalisms extension
over the long span that I have put forward suggests a succession of three epochs: ten centuries of incubation from
the year 1000 in China to the eighteenth-century revolutions in England and France, a short century of triumphal
ourishing (the nineteenth century), probably a long decline comprising in itself the rst long crisis (18751945) and
then the second (begun in 1975 and still ongoing). In each of those two long crises, capital responds to the challenge
by the same triple formula: concentration of capitals control, deepening of uneven globalization, nancialization of
the systems management.8 Two major thinkers (Hobson and Hilferding) immediately grasped the enormous
importance of capitalisms transformation into monopoly capitalism. But it was Lenin and Bukharin who drew the
political conclusion from this transformation, a transformation that initiated the decline of capitalism and thus moved
the socialist revolution onto the agenda.9
The primary formation of monopoly capitalism thus goes back to the end of the nineteenth century, but in the United
States it really established itself as a system only from the 1920s, to conquer next the Western Europe and Japan of
the thirty glorious years following the Second World War. The concept of surplus, put forth by Baran and Sweezy in
the 19501960 decade, allows a grasp of what is essential in the transformation of capitalism. Convinced at the
moment of its publication by that work of enrichment to the Marxist critique of capitalism, I undertook as soon as the
1970s its reformulation which required, in my opinion, the transformation of the rst (19201970) monopoly
capitalism into generalized-monopoly capitalism, analyzed as a qualitatively new phase of the system.
In the previous forms of competition among rms producing the same use valuenumerous then, and independent
of each otherdecisions were made by the capitalist owners of those rms on the basis of a recognized market
price which imposed itself as an external datum. Baran and Sweezy observed that the new monopolies act
dierently: they set their prices simultaneously with the nature and volume of their outputs. So it is an end to fair and
open competition, which remains, quite contrary to reality, at the heart of conventional economics rhetoric! The
abolition of competitionthe radical transformation of that terms meaning, of its functioning and of its results
detaches the price system from its basis, the system of values, and in that very way hides from sight the referential
framework which used to dene capitalisms rationality. Although use values used to constitute to a great extent
autonomous realities, they become, in monopoly capitalism, the object of actual fabrications produced systematically
through aggressive and particularized sales strategies (advertising, brands, etc.). In monopoly capitalism, a coherent
reproduction of the productive system is no longer possible merely by mutual adjustment of the two departments
discussed in the second volume of Capital: it is thenceforward necessary to take into account a Department III,
conceived by Baran and Sweezy. This allows for added surplus absorption promoted by the statebeyond
Department I (private investment) and beyond the portion of Department II (private consumption) devoted to
capitalist consumption. The classic example of Department III spending is military expenditure. However, the notion
of Department III can be expanded to cover the wider array of socially unreproductive expenditures promoted by
generalized-monopoly capitalism.10
The excrescence of Department III, in turn, favors in fact the erasure of the distinction made by Marx between
productive (of surplus-value) labor and unproductive labor. All forms of wage labor canand dobecome sources
of possible prots. A hairdresser sells his services to a customer who pays him out of his income. But if that
hairdresser becomes the employee of a beauty parlor, the business must realize a prot for its owner. If the country
at issue puts ten million wage workers to work in Departments I, II, and III, providing the equivalent of twelve million
years of abstract labor, and if the wages received by those workers allow them to buy goods and services requiring

3/9

merely six million years of abstract labor, the rate of exploitation for all of them, productive and unproductive
confounded, is the same 100 percent. But the six million years of abstract labor that the workers do not receive
cannot all be invested in the purchase of producer goods destined to expand Departments I and II; part of them will
be put toward the expansion of Department III.

Generalized-Monopoly Capitalism (Since 1975)


Passage from the initial monopoly capitalism to its current form (generalized-monopoly capitalism) was
accomplished in a short time (between 1975 and 2000) in response to the second long crisis of declining capitalism.
In fteen years, monopoly powers centralization and its capacity for control over the entire productive system
reached summits incomparable with what had until then been the case.
My rst formulation of generalized-monopoly capitalism dates from 1978, when I put forward an interpretation of
capitals responses to the challenge of its long systemic crisis, which opened starting from 19711975. In that
interpretation I accentuated the three directions of this expected reply, then barely under way: strengthened
centralization of control over the economy by the monopolies, deepening of globalization (and the outsourcing of the
manufacturing industry to the peripheries), and nancialization. The work that Andr Gunder Frank and I published
together in 1978 drew no notice probably because our theses were ahead of their time. But today the three
characteristics at issue have become blindingly obvious to everybody.11
A name had to be given to this new phase of monopoly capitalism. The adjective generalized species what is new:
the monopolies are thenceforward in a position that gives them the capability of reducing all (or nearly all) economic
activities to subcontractor status. The example of family farming in the capitalist centers provides the nest example
of this. These farmers are controlled upstream by the monopolies that provide their inputs and nancing, and
downstream by the marketing chains, to the point that the price structures forced on them wipe out the income from
their labor. Farmers survive only thanks to public subsidies paid for by the taxpayers. This extraction is thus at the
origin of the monopolies prots! As likewise has been observed with bank failures, the new principal of economic
management is summed up in a phrase: privatization of the monopolies prots, socialization of their losses! To go
on talking of fair and open competition and of truth of the prices revealed by the marketsthat belongs in a farce.
The fragmented, and by that fact concrete, economic power of proprietary bourgeois families gives way to a
centralized power exercised by the directors of the monopolies and their cohort of salaried servitors. For
generalized-monopoly capitalism involves not the concentration of property, which on the contrary is more dispersed
than ever, but of the power to manage it. That is why it is deceptive to attach the adjective patrimonial to
contemporary capitalism. It is only in appearance that shareholders rule. Absolute monarchs, the top executives of
the monopolies, decide everything in their name. Moreover, the deepening globalization of the system wipes out the
holistic (i.e., simultaneously economic, political, and social) logic of national systems without putting in its place any
global logic whatsoever. This is the empire of chaosthe title of one of my works, published in 1991 and
subsequently taken up by others: in fact international political violence takes the place of economic competition.12

Financialization of Accumulation
The new nancialization of economic life crowns this transformation in capitals power. In place of strategies set out
by real owners of fragmented capital are those of the managers of ownership titles over capital. What is vulgarly
called ctitious capital (the estimated value of ownership certicates) is nothing but the expression of this
displacement, this disconnect between the virtual and real worlds.
By its very nature capitalist accumulation has always been synonymous with disorder, in the sense that Marx gave to
that term: a system moving from disequilibrium to disequilibrium (driven by class struggles and conicts among the
powers) without ever tending toward an equilibrium. But this disorder resulting from competition among fragmented
capitals was kept within reasonable limits through management of the credit system carried out under the control of

4/9

the national state. With contemporary nancialized and globalized capitalism those frontiers disappear; the violence
of the movements from disequilibrium to disequilibrium is reinforced. The successor of disorder is chaos.
Domination by the capital of the generalized monopolies is exercised on the world scale through global integration of
the monetary and nancial market, based henceforward on the principle of exible exchange rates, and giving up
national controls over the ow of capital. Nevertheless, this domination is called into question, to varying degrees, by
state policies of the emerging countries. The conict between these latter policies and the strategic objectives of the
triads collective imperialism becomes by that fact one of the central axes for possibly putting generalized-monopoly
capitalism once more on trial.13

The Decline of Democracy


In the systems centers, generalized-monopoly capitalism has brought with it generalization of the wage-form. Upper
managers are thenceforward employees who do not participate in the formation of surplus-value, of which they have
become consumers. At the other social pole, the generalized proletarianization that the wage-form suggests is
accompanied by multiplication in forms of segmentation of the labor force. In other words, the proletariat (in its
forms as known in the past) disappears at the very moment when proletarianization becomes generalized. In the
peripheries, the eects of domination by generalized-monopoly capital are no less visible. Above an already diverse
social structure made up of local ruling classes and the subordinate classes and status groups there is placed a
dominant superclass emerging in the wake of globalization. This superclass is sometimes that of neo-comprador
insiders, sometimes that of the governing political class (or class-state-party), or a mixture of the two.
Far from being synonyms, market and democracy are, on the contrary, antonyms. In the centers a new political
consensus-culture (only seeming, perhaps, but nevertheless active) synonymous with depolitization, has taken the
place of the former political culture based on the right-left confrontation that used to give signicance to bourgeois
democracy and the contradictory inscription of class struggles within its framework. In the peripheries, the monopoly
of power captured by the dominant local superclass likewise involves the negation of democracy. The rise of political
Islam provides an example of such a regression.

The Aggressive Geostrategy of Contemporary Imperialism


The Collective Imperialism of the Triad; the State in Contemporary Capitalism
In the 1970s, Sweezy, Magdo, and I had already advanced this thesis, formulated by Andr Gunder Frank and me
in a work published in 1978. We said that monopoly capitalism was entering a new age, characterized by the
gradualbut rapiddismantling of national production systems. The production of a growing number of market
goods can no longer be dened by the label made in France (or the Soviet Union or the United States), but
becomes made in the world, because its manufacture is now broken into segments, located here and there
throughout the whole world.
Recognizing this fact, now a commonplace, does not imply that there is only one explanation of the major cause for
the transformation in question. For my part, I explain it by the leap forward in the degree of centralization in the
control of capital by the monopolies, which I have described as the move from the capitalism of monopolies to the
capitalism of generalized monopolies. The information revolution, among other factors, provides the means that
make possible the management of this globally dispersed production system. But for me, these means are only
implemented in response to a new objective need created by the leap forward in the centralized control of capital.
The emergence of this globalized production system eliminates coherent national development policies (diverse
and unequally eective), but it does not substitute a new coherence, which would be that of the globalized system.
The reason for that is the absence of a globalized bourgeoisie and globalized state, which I will examine later.
Consequently, the globalized production system is incoherent by nature.

5/9

Another important consequence of this qualitative transformation of contemporary capitalism is the emergence of the
collective imperialism of the triad, which takes the place of the historical national imperialisms (of the United States,
Great Britain, Japan, Germany, France, and a few others). Collective imperialism nds its raison dtre in the
awareness by the bourgeoisies in the triad nations of the necessity for their joint management of the world and
particularly of the subjected, and yet to be subjected, societies of the peripheries.
Some draw two correlates from the thesis of the emergence of a globalized production system: the emergence of a
globalized bourgeoisie and the emergence of a globalized state, both of which would nd their objective foundation
in this new production system. My interpretation of the current changes and crises leads me to reject these two
correlates.
There is no globalized bourgeoisie (or dominant class) in the process of being formed, either on the world scale or in
the countries of the imperialist triad. I am led to emphasize the fact that the centralization of control over the capital of
the monopolies takes place within the nation-states of the triad (United States, each member of the European Union,
Japan) much more than it does in the relations between the partners of the triad, or even between members of the
European Union. The bourgeoisies (or oligopolistic groups) are in competition within nations (and the national state
manages this competition, in part at least) and between nations. Thus the German oligopolies (and the German
state) took on the leadership of European aairs, not for the equal benet of everyone, but rst of all for their own
benet. At the level of the triad, it is obviously the bourgeoisie of the United States that leads the alliance, once again
with an unequal distribution of the benets. The idea that the objective causethe emergence of the globalized
production systementails ipso facto the emergence of a globalized dominant class is based on the underlying
hypothesis that the system must be coherent. In reality, it is possible for it not to be coherent. In fact, it is not
coherent and hence this chaotic system is not viable.
In the peripheries, the globalization of the production system occurs in conjunction with the replacement of the
hegemonic blocs of earlier eras by a new hegemonic bloc dominated by the new comprador bourgeoisies, which are
not constitutive elements of a globalized bourgeoisie, but only subaltern allies of the bourgeoisies of the dominant
triad. Just like there is no globalized bourgeoisie in the process of formation, there is also no globalized state on the
horizon. The major reason for this is that the current globalized system does not attenuate, but actually accentuates
conict (already visible or potential) between the societies of the triad and those of the rest of the world. I do indeed
mean conict between societies and, consequently, potentially conict between states. The advantage derived from
the triads dominant position (imperialist rent) allows the hegemonic bloc formed around the generalized monopolies
to benet from a legitimacy that is expressed, in turn, by the convergence of all major electoral parties, right and left,
and their equal commitment to neoliberal economic policies and continual intervention in the aairs of the
peripheries. On the other hand, the neo-comprador bourgeoisies of the peripheries are neither legitimate nor
credible in the eyes of their own people (because the policies they serve do not make it possible to catch up, and
most often lead to the impasse of lumpen-development). Instability of the current governments is thus the rule in this
context.
Just as there is no globalized bourgeoisie even at the level of the triad or that of the European Union, there is also no
globalized state at these levels. Instead, there is only an alliance of states. These states, in turn, willingly accept the
hierarchy that allows that alliance to function: general leadership is taken on by Washington, and leadership in
Europe by Berlin. The national state remains in place to serve globalization as it is.
There is an idea circulating in postmodernist currents that contemporary capitalism no longer needs the state to
manage the world economy and thus that the state system is in the process of withering away to the benet of the
emergence of civil society. I will not go back over the arguments that I have developed elsewhere against this naive
thesis, one moreover that is propagated by the dominant governments and the media clergy in their service. There
is no capitalism without the state. Capitalist globalization could not be pursued without the interventions of the United
States armed forces and the management of the dollar. Clearly, the armed forces and money are instruments of the
state, not of the market.

6/9

But since there is no world state, the United States intends to fulll this function. The societies of the triad consider
this function to be legitimate; other societies do not. But what does that matter? The self-proclaimed international
community, i.e., the G7 plus Saudi Arabia, which has surely become a democratic republic, does not recognize the
legitimacy of the opinion of 85 percent of the worlds population!
There is thus an asymmetry between the functions of the state in the dominant imperialist centers and those of the
state in the subject, or yet to be subjected, peripheries. The state in the compradorized peripheries is inherently
unstable and, consequently, a potential enemy, when it is not already one.
There are enemies with which the dominant imperialist powers have been forced to coexistat least up until now.
This is the case with China because it has rejected (up until now) the neo-comprador option and is pursuing its
sovereign project of integrated and coherent national development. Russia became an enemy as soon as Putin
refused to align politically with the triad and wanted to block the expansionist ambitions of the latter in Ukraine, even
if he does not envision (or not yet?) leaving the rut of economic liberalism. The great majority of comprador states in
the South (that is, states in the service of their comprador bourgeoisies) are allies, not enemiesas long as each of
these comprador states gives the appearance of being in charge of its country. But leaders in Washington, London,
Berlin, and Paris know that these states are fragile. As soon as a popular movement of revoltwith or without a
viable alternative strategythreatens one of these states, the triad arrogates to itself the right to intervene.
Intervention can even lead to contemplating the destruction of these states and, beyond them, of the societies
concerned. This strategy is currently at work in Iraq, Syria, and elsewhere. The raison dtre of the strategy for
military control of the world by the triad led by Washington is located entirely in this realist vision, which is in direct
counterpoint to the naive view la Negriof a globalized state in the process of formation.14

Responses of the Peoples and States of the South


The ongoing oensive of United States/Europe/Japan collective imperialism against all the peoples of the South
walks on two legs: the economic legglobalized neoliberalism forced as the exclusive possible economic policy;
and the political legcontinuous interventions including preemptive wars against those who reject imperialist
interventions. In response, some countries of the South, such as the BRICS, at best walk on only one leg: they reject
the geopolitics of imperialism but accept economic neoliberalism. They remain, for that reason, vulnerable, as the
current case of Russia shows.15 Yes, they have to understand that trade is war, as Yash Tandon wrote.16
All countries of the world outside the triad are enemies or potential enemies, except those who accept complete
submission to its economic and political strategy. In that frame Russia is an enemy.17 Whatever might be our
assessment of what the Soviet Union was, the triad fought it simply because it was an attempt to develop
independently of dominant capitalism/imperialism. After the breakdown of the Soviet system, some people (in Russia
in particular) thought that the West would not antagonize a capitalist Russiajust as Germany and Japan had
lost the war but won the peace. They forgot that the Western powers supported the reconstruction of the former
fascist countries precisely to face the challenge of the independent policies of the Soviet Union. Now, this challenge
having disappeared, the target of the triad is complete submission, to destroy the capacity of Russia to resist. The
current development of the Ukraine tragedy illustrates the reality of the strategic target of the triad. The triad
organized in Kiev what ought to be called a Euro/Nazi putsch. The rhetoric of the Western medias, claiming that the
policies of the Triad aim at promoting democracy, is simply a lie. Eastern Europe has been integrated in the
European Union not as equal partners, but as semi-colonies of major Western and Central European
capitalist/imperialist powers. The relation between West and East in the European system is in some degree similar
to that which rules the relations between the United States and Latin America!
Therefore the policy of Russia to resist the project of colonization of Ukraine must be supported. But this positive
Russian international policy is bound to fail if it is not supported by the Russian people. And this support cannot be
won on the exclusive basis of nationalism. The support can be won only if the internal economic and social policy
pursued promotes the interests of the majority of the working people. A people-oriented policy implies therefore

7/9

moving away, as much as possible, from the liberal recipe and the electoral masquerade associated with it, which
claims to give legitimacy to regressive social policies. I would suggest setting up in its place a brand of new state
capitalism with a social dimension (I say social, not socialist). That system would open the road to eventual
advances toward a socialization of the management of the economy and therefore authentic new advances toward
an invention of democracy responding to the challenges of a modern economy.
Russian state power remaining within the strict limits of the neoliberal recipe annihilates the chances of success of
an independent foreign policy and the chances of Russia becoming a really emerging country acting as an important
international actor. Neoliberalism can produce for Russia only a tragic economic and social regression, a pattern of
lumpen development, and a growing subordinate status in the global imperialist order. Russia would provide the
triad with oil, gas, and some other natural resources; its industries would be reduced to the status of sub-contracting
for the benet of Western nancial monopolies. In such a position, which is not very far from that of Russia today in
the global system, attempts to act independently in the international area will remain extremely fragile, threatened by
sanctions which will strengthen the disastrous alignment of the ruling economic oligarchy to the demands of
dominant monopolies of the triad. The current outow of Russian capital associated with the Ukraine crisis
illustrates the danger. Reestablishing state control over the movements of capital is the only eective response to
that danger.
Outside of China, which is implementing a national project of modern industrial development in connection with the
renovation of family agriculture, the other so-called emergent countries of the South (the BRICS) still walk only on
one leg: they are opposed to the depredations of militarized globalization, but remain imprisoned in the straightjacket
of neoliberalism.18

Notes
1. In this article, I am limiting myself to examining the experiences of Russia and China, with no intention of
ignoring the other twentieth-century socialist revolutions (North Korea, Vietnam, Cuba).
2. Before the Second World War, Stalin had desperately, and unsuccessfully, sought an alliance with the
Western democracies against Nazism. After the war, Washington chose to pursue the Cold War, while Stalin
sought to extend friendship with the Western powers, again without success. See Georey Roberts,Stalins
Wars: From World War to Cold War, 19391953(New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 2007). See the
important preface by Annie Lacroix Riz to the French edition:Les guerres de Staline: De la guerre mondiale
la guerre froide (Paris: ditions Delga, 2014).
3. I am alluding here to Kautskys theses inThe Agrarian Question, 2 vols. (London: Pluto Press, 1988; rst
edition, 1899).
4. There are pleasant exceptions among Marxist intellectuals who, without having had responsibilities in the
leadership of revolutionary parties or, still less, of revolutionary states, have nonetheless remained attentive to
the challenges confronted by state socialisms (I am thinking here of Baran, Sweezy, Hobsbawn, and others).
5. See Samir Amin, China 2013,Monthly Review 64, no. 10 (March 2013): 1433, in particular for analyses
concerning Maoisms treatment of the agrarian question.
6. See Eric J. Hobsbawn,Echoes of the Marseillaise: Two Centuries Look Back on the French Revolution
(London: Verso, 1990); also see the works of Florence Gauthier. These authors do not assimilate Thermidor to
restoration, as the Trotskyist simplication suggests.
7. Concerning the destruction of the Asian and African peasantry currently underway, see Samir Amin,
Contemporary Imperialism and the Agrarian Question,Agrarian South: Journal of Political Economy 1, no. 1
(April 2012): 1126, http://ags.sagepub.com.
8. I discuss here only some of the major consequences of the move to generalized monopolies
(nancialization, decline of democracy). As for ecological questions, I refer to the remarkable works of John

8/9

Bellamy Foster.
9. Nicolai Bukharin, Imperialism and the World Economy (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1973; written in
1915); V. I. Lenin,Imperialism, The Highest Stage of Capitalism (New York: International Publishers, 1969;
written in 1916).
10. For further discussions of the Department III analysis and its relation to Baran and Sweezys theory of
surplus absorption see Samir Amin, Three Essays on Marxs Value Theory (New York: Monthly Review Press,
2013), 6776; and John Bellamy Foster, Marxian Crisis Theory and the State, in John Bellamy Foster and
Henryk Szlajfer, eds., The Faltering Economy (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1984), 32549.
11. Andre Gunder Frank and Samir Amin, Lets Not Wait for 1984, in Frank, Reections on the World
Economic Crisis (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1981).
12. Samir Amin, Empire of Chaos (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1992).
13. Concerning the challenge to nancial globalization, see Samir Amin, From Bandung (1955) to 2015: New
and Old Challenges for the Peoples and States of the South, paper presented at the World Social Forum,
Tunis, March 2015, and The Chinese Yuan, published in Chinese, 2013.
14. Contra Hardt and Negri,Monthly Review 66, no. 6 (November 2014): 2536.
15. The choice to delink is inevitable. The extreme centralization of the surplus at the world level in the form of
imperialist rent for the monopolies of the imperialist powers is unsupportable by all societies in the periphery.
It is necessary to deconstruct this system with the prospect of reconstructing it later in another form of
globalization compatible with communism understood as a more advanced stage of universal civilization. I
have suggested, in this context, a comparison with the necessary destruction of the centralization of the
Roman Empire, which opened the way to feudal decentralization.
16. Yash Tandon,Trade is War (New York: OR Books, forthcoming).
17. Samir Amin, Russia in the World System, chapter 7 in Global History: A View from the South(London:
Pambazuka Press, 2010), The Return of Fascism in Contemporary Capitalism,Monthly Review 66, no. 4
(September 2014): 112.
18. Concerning the inadequate responses of India and Brazil, see Samir Amin, The Implosion of Capitalism
(New York: Monthly Review Press, 2013), chapter 2, and Latin America Confronts the Challenge of
Globalization,Monthly Review 66, no. 7 (December 2014): 16.

9/9

You might also like