The Fiscal Challenges Facing Medicare: Entitlement Spending and Medicare
The Fiscal Challenges Facing Medicare: Entitlement Spending and Medicare
The Fiscal Challenges Facing Medicare: Entitlement Spending and Medicare
85
groups. Workers and their spouses are entitled to receive Social Security and
Medicare benefits if they make sufficient payroll contributions while working,
and citizens and qualified aliens are entitled to Medicaid benefits if they meet
certain income and other demographic criteria.
Chart 4-1 shows spending on Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid in
2006 as a percent of the total Federal budget. The $549 billion in Federal
spending on Social Security benefits was 21 percent of total Federal outlays.
The $330 billion in federal spending on Medicare benefits was 12 percent of
outlays. The $191 billion in federal spending on Medicaid was 7 percent
of outlays. Because Medicaid is jointly funded by the Federal and State
governments, State governments also spent about $139 billion on Medicaid.
For those not covered by Medicare or Medicaid, the federal government
also helps with the purchase of private health insurance coverage in a variety
of ways, including the exclusion of employer contributions towards health
insurance premiums from personal income taxes. These tax expenditures are
included in the Federal budget and are estimated to equal $133 billion in
2006. The President’s 2008 budget includes a proposal to replace the existing
exclusion for employer-provided health insurance with a flat standard deduc-
tion to all families who purchase health insurance that meets minimum
requirements for catastrophic coverage, in order to improve the efficiency and
equity of these tax expenditures. The President’s policy proposal is described
in Box 4-1.
Chapter 4 | 87
Box 4-1 — continued
Chapter 4 | 89
Box 4-2 — continued
The 1997 Balanced Budget Act eliminated the direct link between
plan payment rates and local fee-for-service expenditures and sought to
expand the types of plans available to beneficiaries beyond the urban
areas where they had generally been available. The 1997 Balanced
Budget Act also mandated the use of risk adjustment to vary the
payments to insurers based upon the health status of its enrollees by
2000. As a result, incentives to engage in wasteful competition for rela-
tively healthier enrollees were mitigated so that insurers would instead
engage in competition to provide higher value care at a lower cost for
all enrollees. Because of some of the limits on the growth in payments
in the 1997 Balanced Budget Act, many private insurers withdrew from
the Medicare market. Enrollment declined by about 25 percent from
1999 to 2003.
The 2003 Medicare Modernization Act expanded the Medicare
Advantage program in two important ways (in addition to changing the
name from “Medicare+Choice” to “Medicare Advantage”). First, the 2003
Medicare Modernization Act increased the payment levels to the plans to
encourage participation across all Medicare Advantage plans. Second,
the 2003 Medicare Modernization Act created new regional preferred
provider organizations that offer a uniform deductible and an upper limit
on out-of-pocket spending to increase both the number of choices avail-
able to Medicare beneficiaries (especially in rural areas) and special
needs plans to target certain beneficiaries (such as those with dual
eligibility, those with chronic conditions, and the institutionalized).
Chapter 4 | 91
event of an uninsured loss, they may have an incentive to forego buying
insurance. This precommitment problem, sometimes called the “Samaritan’s
Dilemma,” has been demonstrated to be alleviated by the direct provision of
health insurance rather than a direct transfer of wealth. This economic argu-
ment, however, justifies the subsidization of, or requirement for, insurance
but does not justify a government-run plan.
Chapter 4 | 93
Box 4-3: Long-Term Care
Chapter 4 | 95
The next section of this chapter examines the reasons behind this projected
growth in Medicare spending. The average annual growth rate of Medicare
spending is projected to be 2.8 percentage points higher than GDP growth
per year between 2006 and 2040. Part of this increase in spending is due to
growth in the number of Medicare beneficiaries, and part of this increase in
spending is due to growth in real (inflation adjusted) Medicare spending
per beneficiary.
Chapter 4 | 97
it is not clear that this relationship is causal, an estimate of the value of these
added health benefits is about $70,000, far in excess of the added costs.
Economists have suggested that an increase in medical spending over time
is not necessarily problematic, in and of itself, so long as the marginal bene-
fits exceed the marginal costs. A simple cross-national comparison of the
fraction of GDP devoted to health care spending suggests that the United
States is a high-expense outlier relative to other developed countries.
However, it is plausible that the marginal benefits of improved health are
dependent on income, so that as a country’s GDP increases, it may be rational
for that country to devote a relatively higher share of its GDP to health care.
This perspective suggests that it may make sense for the United States to
spend more than other countries because it has higher per capita income and
health care can be a valued use of those higher resources.
Chapter 4 | 99
the incentives for health care providers and insurers to provide high-quality
care. A second way to improve the efficiency of Medicare spending is to
discourage the use of ineffective care that is currently overconsumed. Policies
to achieve this goal should aim to improve the incentives that Medicare bene-
ficiaries face regarding their consumption of care. More detail on these
policies is provided in the next two sections.
Chapter 4 | 101
Better Incentives for Medicare Beneficiaries
In addition to the competition induced by the new Part D benefit, its
pricing structure and associated subsidy for premiums provide good incen-
tives for Medicare beneficiaries to obtain relatively more efficient forms of
insurance coverage. Because the Federal subsidy toward the prescription drug
plan is generally a fixed proportion of the average premium bid each year,
beneficiaries receive the additional benefits of choosing plans that are less
generous than the average benchmark plan. Thus, beneficiaries appropriately
receive the full marginal benefits from either a higher amount of cost sharing
or a more restrictive list of covered medicines. This mechanism for having
Medicare beneficiaries pay lower amounts for less generous coverage therefore
improves the incentives for insurers to design more optimal products.
A potential downside to this mechanism for determining beneficiary
premiums, however, is that it could lead to relatively higher premiums for
people with higher expected expenses due to chronic health conditions if
these high-risk people gravitate toward plans with relatively more generous
benefits. As a result, these plans’ higher premiums would reflect a relatively
sicker pool of people covered by the plan, in addition to the underlying value
of more generous benefits. However, these potential problems can be allevi-
ated by the use of risk-adjusted payments to plans, as described in Box 4-2.
This mechanism for determining the premium contribution toward
different plans, currently in place for Part D, could potentially be applied to
the entire Medicare program. Providing beneficiaries with a choice of compre-
hensive plans and having the premium contribution for each plan vary in
relation to a benchmark plan has potential for improving the efficiency of
overall Medicare spending. A key difference between Medicare Part D and the
entire Medicare program, however, is the combination of the government-run
fee-for-service and Medicare Advantage components of the latter. This bench-
mark mechanism is likely to be successful only if the same premium
contribution is made toward both the fee-for-service component of Medicare
and the private Medicare Advantage plans, putting them on equal footing.
Just as described above, this mechanism for determining premium contribu-
tions would cause beneficiaries to receive the appropriate marginal benefits
when choosing plans with levels of coverage that are less generous than the
benchmark plan. It could therefore help to allow beneficiaries to determine
the optimal forms of out-of-pocket cost sharing and the optimal adoption of
new technologies over time. These two specific issues are explored below.
Chapter 4 | 103
Conclusion
Medicare has significant long-term unfunded obligations. Although Social
Security spending is currently much greater than Medicare spending, the
unfunded obligation for Medicare is much greater than that for Social Security.
Eliminating the projected 75-year actuarial deficit for Medicare Part A would
require an immediate 3.51 percent increase in the HI payroll tax or a reduc-
tion in projected Medicare expenditures by 51 percent. Projected increases in
Medicare Supplementary Medical Insurance (SMI) funding may appear less
transparent because they are funded out of general revenues, but the economic
significance of these obligations for Medicare SMI is just as great.
Policymakers face the challenge of reducing the growth of Medicare
spending while preserving access to life-saving health care and the important
financial protections that Medicare provides, and they cannot do so without
ensuring that Medicare funds are spent more efficiently. Increases in Medicare
spending over time are driven by an increasing population of aged Americans
and increasing per-beneficiary spending on health care. While much of the
increase in medical spending over time is driven by valuable new technologies,
there also appear to be significant inefficiencies in the system. Therefore,
future policies to control the growth in Medicare spending should target the
sources of inefficient spending but not discourage the use medical care that is
costly but delivers greater health benefits. This tension is the primary
dilemma that policymakers face.
Policymakers may want to consider restructuring Medicare so that the
direct spending by Medicare beneficiaries, in the form of premium contribu-
tions and out-of-pocket spending for medical care, yields a more efficient
allocation of resources. Revising the Medicare fee-for-service program and the
Medicare Advantage program to be more like Part D with a fixed-dollar
subsidy provided toward the premium, has the potential for improving incen-
tives for Medicare beneficiaries to consume optimal levels of care. When
individuals receive the full benefits of selecting less expensive coverage, they
will be more likely to select plans with optimal arrangements that balance
both financial protection and technological adoption.