Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

Jensen 2003 PDF

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 28
At a glance
Powered by AI
The key takeaways are that using budgets or targets in performance measurement and compensation systems causes people to lie, game the system, and destroy value. This behavior is widespread but costly, and can be addressed by changing how organizations pay people.

Two main negative effects are that both superiors and subordinates lie in the formulation of budgets, gutting the budgeting process of unbiased information needed to coordinate activities. They also game the realization of budgets and targets, destroying value for their organizations.

Paying people based on budgets or targets provides incentives for them to lie in the formulation of budgets, withhold and distort information, and game the system to meet the budgets or targets. This destroys value for the organizations.

European Financial Management, Vol. 9, No.

3, 2003, 379406

Professional Forum
Paying People to Lie: the Truth about
the Budgeting Process
Michael C. Jensen*
The Monitor Group and Harvard Business School
e-mail: MJensen@hbs.edu

Abstract
This paper analyzes the counterproductive effects associated with using budgets or
targets in an organisations performance measurement and compensation systems.
Paying people on the basis of how their performance relates to a budget or target
causes people to game the system and in doing so to destroy value in two main ways:
(a) both superiors and subordinates lie in the formulation of budgets and, therefore, gut
the budgeting process of the critical unbiased information that is required to coordinate
the activities of disparate parts of an organisation, and (b) they game the realisation of
the budgets or targets and in doing so destroy value for their organisations. Although
most managers and analysts understand that budget gaming is widespread, few
understand the huge costs it imposes on organisations and how to lower them.
My purpose in this paper is to explain exactly how this happens and how managers and
firms can stop this counter-productive cycle. The key lies not in destroying the budgeting
systems, but in changing the way organisations pay people. In particular to stop this
highly counter-productive behaviour we must stop using budgets or targets in the
compensation formulas and promotion systems for employees and managers. This
means taking all kinks, discontinuities and non-linearities out of the pay-for-performance
profile of each employee and manager. Such purely linear compensation formulas
provide no incentives to lie, or to withhold and distort information, or to game the system.
While the evidence on the costs of these systems is not extensive, I believe that solving
the problems could easily result in large productivity and value increases sometimes as
much as 50100% improvements in productivity. I believe the less intensive reliance
on such budget/target systems is an important cause of the increased productivity of

* Thanks to Joe Fuller, Nancy Nichols, Jennifer Lacks-Kaplan, Pat Meredith, Roger Marten,
Shibanee Verma, and Susanne Greenberg from Monitor, the editors of the Harvard Business
Review, and Michael Gibbs and Edwin Locke for their contributions to this piece. An executive
summary of this paper entitled Corporate budgeting is broken lets fix it was published in the
Harvard Business Review, November 2001. An early version of this paper was given at the EFMA
Meetings in Athens, Greece in June 2001 before the wave of corporate scandals including Enron,
Worldcom and others. Because the paper is fully consistent with these later events I found little
reason to update it to include these more notorious examples of the phenomena.

# Michael C. Jensen, 2003. Published by Blackwell Publishing Ltd., 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA
02148, USA.
380 Professional Forum

entrepreneurial and LBO firms. Moreover, eliminating budget/target-induced gaming


from the management system will eliminate one of the major forces leading to the
general loss of integrity in organisations. People are taught to lie in these pervasive
budgeting systems because if they tell the truth they often get punished and if they lie
they get rewarded. Once taught to lie in this system people generally cannot help but
extend that behaviour to all sorts of other relationships in the organisation.

Keywords: budgeting; budgets; compensation; performance measurement; gaming;


lying; loss of integrity; truthfulness; sandbagging; motivation; productivity; incentives;
control systems; accounting irregularities; fraud; goldbricking; channel stuffing;
cooking the books; managing earnings; managing the numbers.

1. Introduction

Budgeting systems are ubiquitous. Long considered a necessary tool in managing a


company, the budgeting process frequently consumes six months of management time
in negotiations, planning, and target-setting. Such systems are intended to coordinate
the activities of the units and motivate managers. They are used in simple organisa-
tions and in vast and complex enterprises.
And yet, the reality is that almost every company in the world uses a budget or target-
setting system that rewards people for ignoring or destroying valuable information
and punishes them for taking actions that benefit the company. These budget-based
systems reward people for lying, and for lying about their lying, and punish them for
telling the truth. These systems reward gaming while obfuscating the facts they are
meant to summon: facts that are necessary to help managers make the necessary trade-
offs in allocating resources between projects, departments and initiatives.
Most line managers realise that these processes are a joke. They go to a lot of
meetings, scope the extent of their problems, submit budgets they know will be
unacceptable, then scramble to redo budgets to reflect the new level of earnings
stipulated by senior management who are, in turn, driven by the earnings game they
are involved in with Wall Street analysts. Senior executives, knowing that they do not
have enough specific information about their markets and their customers to actually
argue on the merits of the case, instead use their position and negotiating power to
simply insist on higher and higher targets in an effort to meet the analysts expectations.
The example in Table 1 illustrates how this process plays out in many companies.
What is more, everyone at every level is so wrapped up in their budget systems that
even though most dislike the budgeting process and perceive the damaging effects of
the behaviour it encourages, they cannot conceive of managing a company in any
other way. Indeed companies that do without such budgeting systems run the risk of
being considered poorly managed. The key to resolving these issues is not necessarily
to throw out the budgeting process (although some would argue this is desirable),1 but

1
See Hope and Fraser (1997, 1999a, b, 2000), Kersnar (1999), Lester (2000) and Thomas (2000)
which summarise the experiences of a number of mostly Scandinavian companies including
Svenska Handelsbanken (Swedens largest bank which abandoned budgets in 1970), Air
Liquide, SKF, Ericsson, Skania, Schlumberger, Skandia, Swedish Post, Tetrapak, Diageo,
Borealis, Volvo Cars, IKEA, and Fokus Bank which have abandoned budgets or are in the
process of doing so. The Consortium for Advanced Manufacturing International (CAM-I) has
established a Beyond Budgeting Roundtable to understand and report on these developments.

# Michael C. Jensen, 2003


Professional Forum 381

Table 1
Let the games begin: one companys budget process.
Gaming, wasted time, and poor decisions are rampant in most budget processes at most companies.

Mid-May: The annual budgeting process begins. The chief financial officer and the chief
strategy officer establish the overall after-tax net income target by working backwards from
Wall Street analysts estimates and adjusting for known (but not disclosed) circumstances which
would impact the coming year. This target is then reviewed with the CEO who informs the
SBUs of the overall target.
Early June: The head of each SBU prepares a preliminary forecast for the coming year with
input from their business unit heads. The SBU challenge is to present a forecast that is not so
ridiculous as to infuriate the CEO, but nevertheless has a high probability of being achieved.
Late June: Not surprisingly, the sum of the SBU forecasts do not come close to the overall
target and the SBUs spend the next month defending their forecasts and explaining why it is
impossible to produce a higher net income.
Early July: Patience wears thin and the CEO and SBU presidents begin to negotiate the
allocation of the gap between the forecast and the overall target. This year, like every year,
the SBU president who is the better negotiator is awarded a much smaller piece of the gap than
the president who is not as good a negotiator.
Late July: Once the SBU targets have been agreed upon, a similar process to set targets for the
business units within the SBUs begins. After another month of presentations defending initial
forecasts, the President mandates the allocation of the overall SBU target. The business units then
spend the summer trying to figure out how to meet their targets. Much time is spent arguing over
internal allocations since in many business units as much as 60% of expenses come from other
departments. Again, this year there is more to be gained from beating down a colleague or from
changing the method of allocation than from focusing on how to grow revenues or reduce those
expenses under your control a fact that is not lost on the participants, acrimony and politicking
flourishes.
Early September: In this environment it is, as usual, virtually impossible to agree on the funding
of cross-organisational projects. One result is the creation of 14 different e-mail systems, none
of which are compatible. The eventual cost to connect these systems so that the company can
co-ordinate its services is a substantial portion of the $100 million project to connect the
companys business units.
In September: the final negotiations begin. The SBUs present their business plan for the coming
year to the senior management group (the CEO, CFO, CIO, CSO, HR, Legal, Risk). Each
major business within the SBU presents the highlights of their business plan, (focusing on the
reasons that they might not be able to meet the plan). The more convincing a business unit is,
the more likely its plan would be adjusted downwards.
From a business unit perspective the strongest lever in the negotiations is the deferral
or cancellation of so called strategic projects for which expenses are heavily loaded to the
near term and benefits are loaded to the sometimes distant future. Many of these strategic
projects are, however, essential if the firm is to remain in the business over the longer term.
For example, since the mid-1990s one SBU had known that for security reasons and to
comply with international standards it had to re-engineer one of its products before 31
December 1999. For five years this strategic project was put forward as a reason for reducing
the divisions target and rejected, and thus never initiated. In 1998, the division incurred $30
million in fraud costs, about one-half of which could have been avoided, if it had implemented
the project.

# Michael C. Jensen, 2003


382 Professional Forum

Table 1
Continued.

In November: Top management presents the coming years budget to the Board of Directors and
it is approved.
The End Game: A comparison of five years of actual earnings versus planned earnings showed
that the only number the company ever achieved was the net income number. Revenues and
expenses were at least 10% over or under. Most often revenues did not meet targets and
spending (usually R&D and investment spending) was cut to ensure that net income targets
were met. Bonuses, however, were paid because they were directly linked to meeting the net
income target.

to change the way we measure performance and the way we reward and punish
people.
Budget systems are based on the premise that managers should be rewarded for
achieving their targets for the period and punished for missing them.2 What every
manager knows, but most fail to pay attention to, is the effect that such systems have
on incentives. Tell a manager that he or she will get a bonus when targets are realised
and two things are sure to happen. First, managers will attempt to set targets that are
easily reachable, and once the targets are set, they will do their best to see that the
targets are met even if it damages the company to do so.
Consider this example: managers at a heavy equipment manufacturer were so set on
making their budget targets and assuring their bonuses that they shipped their
unfinished industrial products from their plant in England all the way to the Nether-
lands (so they could realise the sales revenues early). At great cost and inconvenience,
they finished assembling them in a warehouse close to their customer. By doing so,
they booked the sale in the necessary quarter, made their bonus, but lowered their
companys profit overall. The budget had been met, the bonuses were assured, but the
company was worse off for the effort. Examples like this are legion.
Such gaming, however, is considered part of business life, so much so that it often
takes on a life of its own. As in the example above, managers game the realisation of
the targets. They also game the setting of targets in the first place. Both result in
substantial damage to the company and lower its profits and value. How does this
happen and what can we do about it?

2. Gaming the realization of targets

A manager promised a $100,000 bonus for reaching this years target will go to great
lengths to achieve it. Managers who run the risk of just missing the budget target will
accelerate shipments and revenues from next year into this year and move expenses
from this year to next year even though by doing so overall profits are reduced in the
two years. Take the case where the manager loads the distribution channel with more

2
See Locke (2001), for an excellent review of goal setting and budgeting. Locke discusses the
counter productive effects of paying people for meeting goals and suggests three solutions to
these problems. I return to them below. Locke and Latham (1990) provide an excellent analysis
of the theory and evidence on goal setting.

# Michael C. Jensen, 2003


Professional Forum 383

product than it can handle because shipping the product allows realisation of the profit
this year. Managers do this even though they expect the product will be returned next
year, and even though they know it makes it even harder to make next years profit target.
And it is not unusual for the gaming to turn fraudulent. In one case managers
shipped fruit baskets that weighed exactly the same amount as their product and
booked them as sales. In another case, Informix, an internet software company, and
its auditor paid $142 million to settle lawsuits resulting from SEC charges for
fraudulently increasing earnings by $295 million in the 19941997 period. In its
complaint the SEC charged that managers and sales personnel attempting to meet
or exceed the companys internal revenue and earnings goals:

1. moved revenues from one quarter to the previous quarter by backdating sales
agreements;
2. entered into secret side agreements granting rights to refunds and other conces-
sions such as paying fictitious consulting or other fees to customers to refund
their software license fees;
3. recognised revenue on transactions with reseller customers that were not credit-
worthy,
4. recognised amounts due under software maintenance agreements as software
licensing revenues; and
5. recognised revenue on disputed claims against customers.3
Similarly Sabratek, a developer and seller of remote healthcare equipment has been
sued for revenue enhancing fraud including the alleged sale of products to entities that
had not ordered them, inventory parking arrangements, and widespread stuffing of
the distribution channel.4 In another case the Wall Street Journal reported on 9 April
20015 that PricewaterhouseCoopers found that the Korean unit of Lernout & Hauspie
Speech Products NV was found to have reported fictitious sales equal to 70% of its
nearly $160 million in sales between September 1999 and June 2000. In an effort to
clinch rich bonuses tied to sales targets, the Korean units managers used highly
sophisticated schemes to fool L&Hs new management. One especially egregious
method involved funneling bank loans through third parties to make it look as though
customers had paid when in fact they hadnt. One of the executives involved earned
$25 million in sales target bonuses before being fired. L&H one of Europes high-tech
stars, filed for bankruptcy protection . . . after admitting to widespread accounting
irregularities. And the news media6 has recently reported on questions of accounting

3
See In the matter of Informix Corporation, SEC Release No. 337788, 11 January 2000,
http://www.sec.gov/litigation/admin/34-42326.htm.
4
See P. Larson (TMF Parlay), Sabratek saga cliff notes FOOL PLATE SPECIAL: an
investment opinion, August 26, 1999 http://www.fool.com/news/1999/foolplate990826.
htm?ref newreg, (23 April 2001), and Herb Greenberg, *update* amended lawsuit alleges
accounting irregularities at Sabratek, 15 June 1999, http://www.thestreet.com/comment/
herbonthestreet/756299.html (23 April 2001).
5
J. Carreyrou, Lernout unit booked fictitious sales, says probe, Wall Street Journal, 9 April
2001, p. B2, and J. Carreyrou and M. Maremont, Lernout unit engaged in massive fraud to
fool auditors, new inquiry concludes, Wall Street Journal, 6 April 2001, p. A3.
6
Reuters Corporate accounting woes puts fund managers on alert, 13 February 2001 http://
www.forbes.com/newswire/2001/02/13/rtr184059.html (23 April 2001).

# Michael C. Jensen, 2003


384 Professional Forum

irregularities (a common manifestation of this gaming problem) in many well-known


firms7 including Bankers Trust, Cendant,8 W. R. Grace, Livent, Sunbeam, Waste
Management, Rent-Way9 Xerox10, Compaq,11 CISCO,12 Gillette,13 Kroger,14 Rite
Aid,15 Computer Associates,16 and Lucent.17 The Wall Street Journal reports that
about 40 of the SECs accounting-fraud investigations involve companies in the
Fortune 500. Indeed, the SECs enforcement chief, Richard Walker, commenting on
the magnitude of the problems said recently: If we had nothing else to do, the
accounting investigations alone could keep us busy for the next five or ten years.
The size and magnitude are crushing (Schroeder, 2001).

7
See C. J. Loomis, Lies, damned lies, and managed earnings, Fortune, 2 August 1999.
Accounting: book cookers, beware! Audits are improving, Fortune, 16 April 2000.
8
See Cendant case scorecard: government 3; book-cookers 0, Fortune, 10 July 2000.
9
See Queena Sook Kim, Rent-way details improper bookkeeping: expenses were artificially cut
by $127 million, report says, Wall Street Journal, 8 June 2001, p. C1.
10
See Xerox Press Release, Xerox releases details from independent investigation of Mexico
accounting issues, 1 February 2001, http://biz.yahoo.com/bw/010201/ct_xerox.html (23 April
2001). J. Bandler and J. Hechinger, Xerox executive challenges its accounting and is fired
query into Mexican units books snowballs, Asian Wall Street Journal, 7 February 2001.
Reuters Update 1-Xerox accounting woes resurface, shares tumble, 3 April 2001, http://
www.forbes.com/newswire/2001/04/03/rtr227376.html (23 April 2001). Reuters Xerox hit with
shareholder lawsuit, 21 February 2001 http://www.forbes.com/newswire/2001/02/21/
rtr189312.html (23 April 2001).
11
G. Kelly and J. Ticehurst, Compaq denies channel stuffing claim, 12 December 2000,
http://www.vnunet.com/News/1115296 (23 April 2001).
12
See A. Bary, Half-point rate cut is worth 10% to the NASDAQ, Barrons Online, 23 April
2001.
13
See D. Golden, Gillette Co. misses estimates, citing excess inventories, Wall Street Journal,
19 April 2001. Chief financial officer Charles Cramb acknowledged that the company
oversupplied batteries and older razor systems to retailers during the year-end holiday season
and misread its market share, leaving it with trade inventory backlogs in excess of three weeks.
14
See Kroger Co. to restate results after finding improper accounting, Wall Street Journal,
6 March 2001, p. B10. Gary Rhodes, a spokesman for Kroger, said the restatements stem from
accounting entries that were made to manage Ralphs earnings. In quarters for which actual
results exceeded budget expectations, he said, some executives of Ralphs would inappropriately
record the extra money in a variety of accounts instead of reporting it as income. . . . All of the
executives who were directly involved in the questionable bookkeeping have left Ralphs in the
past year, Mr. Rhodes added, and Kroger has reported the matter to the SEC.
15
See M. Maremont, Lawsuit details Rite Aids accounting woes, Wall Street Journal,
28 February 2001, p. C1.
16
See A. Berneson, A software company runs out of tricks, NY Times, 29 April 2001, section
3, p. 1, and A. Berneson, Computer associate officials defend accounting methods, NY Times,
1 May 2001, section C, p. 1.
17
See D. J. Berman and R. Blumenstein, Behind Lucents woes: push to meet high revenue
goal, Wall Street Journal, 29 March 2001. S. N. Mehta, Lessons from the Lucent debacle,
Fortune, 5 February 2001. T. Murphy, SEC continues Lucent probe, 19 February 2001, http://
www.electronicnews.com/issue/RegisteredIssues/2001/02192001/z8f-1.asp, (23 April 2001).
Reuters, Chronology: key events in Lucents recent trouble, 24 April 2001, http://
www.forbes.com/newswire/2001/04/24/rtr242259.html (24 April 2001).

# Michael C. Jensen, 2003


Professional Forum 385

Years ago I witnessed top management of a durable goods manufacturing company


with target-based bonuses struggling to reach their bonus targets before the year-end
close of the books. In September they announced to their board and customers that
product prices would increase 10% effective as of 2 January of the next year. Now it
may well be that a price increase was the right action at this time for this firm. But it
was not in line with competition at the time, nor was it very likely that 2 January, of
all possible dates, was the optimal time for the increase. But, announcing an effective
date of 2 January of course, would motivate the firms customers to order product in
advance of their normal order cycle to avoid the price increase. This would thereby
aid management in reaching the bonus level for the year but at the expense of next
years profits. Moreover, when it became clear in November that the firm would not
reach the bonus targets management announced the largest quarterly loss in the
history of the company. This is consistent with the notion that managers realising
they will not meet this years targets, move revenues to next year and expenses from
future years to the current year (write-offs) because it costs them nothing to do so in
this years bonus and it makes it easier to reach targets in future years.

3. Gaming the setting of targets

Managers have information that is important in setting their budget targets for next
year. However, once a budget-target reward system is in place managers have no
interest in seeing such information accurately incorporated in budget targets. Indeed,
as Ichak Adizes so accurately summarised it in his 1989 book: The more people lie
about how much they cannot do, the more they are rewarded. Being aware of this,
superiors are then led to lie about how much their subordinates can do to counter-
balance this bias. But now no one in the system has incentives to accurately estimate
what the budgets should be, and at all levels information critical to the budget-setting
process is hidden, destroyed or polluted. There are two major effects of this on
companies.
A. Budgets play a critical role in coordinating disparate parts of a company so that
their actions lead to harmonious interactions, high output, low cost, high quality,
low inventories and satisfied customers. But, once we establish a budget-targeting
process that hides and destroys critical information regarding what various parts
of the organisation can do and how they will do it, this critical coordinating role of
budgets is severely hampered. Uncoordinated, chaotic actions that lead to high
cost, low quality, missed opportunities, and dissatisfied customers are the result.
B. Honesty and integrity are eroded throughout the organisation because once man-
agers are taught that they must lie and conceal information to succeed in the
budget-target game they soon begin to extend such out-of-integrity behaviour to
all parts of an organisations management system and even its relationship to
outside parties. The budget game inevitably gets extended to the firms relationship
with the capital markets as the CEO and CFO become enmeshed in a game with
financial analysts over meeting financial targets. Managing the numbers as it is
often called, is commonly considered part of every top managers job18 along

18
For excellent discussions of this phenomenon, see (Collingwood, 2001; DeGeorge et al.,
1999).

# Michael C. Jensen, 2003


386 Professional Forum

with denying that this dishonest behaviour is going on. It shows up at the board of
directors level as management misleads the board, as the board endorses mislead-
ing reports to shareholders and other outside constituents, and as managers
mislead customers, suppliers and employees about all sorts of important informa-
tion about the state of the company.

4. Stopping the vicious cycle and restoring integrity

I believe that almost no one in this system consciously believes he or she is lying or
behaving without integrity. Indeed, in most corporate cultures much of this behaviour
has become expected of responsible managers and board members. It is also undis-
cussable. To stop the gaming of budgets and targets and restore integrity to the
planning and management process we must begin not by telling managers to stop
lying, nor by eliminating the use of budgets, but by eliminating the use of budgets and
targets in compensation formulas and promotion systems.
Eliminating the use of targets or budgets in compensation systems solves the
problem because if your bonus or promotion is a function of what you accomplish,
not whether you meet or exceed a budget or target, you have no monetary incentive to
hide information or lie in the budget/target-setting process. Budgets can be used for
planning and coordinating as they were intended, and a major cause of the erosion of
integrity in organizations is eliminated.

A. Analysis of the fundamental sources of the incentives to game the system


To see why this behavioural problem is a problem with the compensation system, not
the budgeting system, let us structure the analysis a little more. We start by defining a
pay-for-performance profile which plots the total compensation of an individual vs.
his or her performance. Consider the fairly standard pay-for-performance profile
in Figure 1.

Fig. 1. Typical pay-for-performance profile of an executive compensation scheme.

# Michael C. Jensen, 2003


Professional Forum 387

Figure 1 illustrates the common practice in which a managers salary plus bonus
is constant until a minimum hurdle performance is reached commonly 80% of the
targeted or budgeted performance level. For our purposes we need not specify what
the measure of performance is, but it might be profits, sales, quantity of output or
any number of other things including the growth rate of some measure. At about 80%
of the budgeted performance the manager receives a bonus for making the hurdle
target. This bonus can often be substantial, and as performance increases above this
hurdle the bonus increases until it is capped at some maximum (120% of the budget or
target is common). Performance above this upper limit generates no additional bonus.
Consider managers incentives when they are struggling to reach the minimum
hurdle. In this situation as long as they believe they can make the minimum, managers
will engage in actions to increase the performance measure, and this can be done by
legitimate or illegitimate means. When the measure is profits, or some variation of
profits, managers have incentives to increase this years profits at the expense of future
years profits by moving expenses from this year to the future (by delaying purchases,
for example) or by moving revenues from future years into this year by booking
orders early (as we described above by announcing future price increases, or by giving
special discounts this year, or guaranteeing to repurchase goods in the future, and so
on). When these actions simply move profits from one year to another the adverse
impact on firm value is probably small. But, it can pay managers today, to engage in
actions that reduce the total value of firm cash flows by moving profits to the current
period even when future profits are dramatically reduced. Obviously policies that
encourage long-term employment in a managers current job tend to reduce (but not
eliminate) the incentives to beggar the future to boost the present-year bonus.
When managers conclude that they cannot make the minimum hurdle, their incen-
tives shift dramatically. Now they have incentives to do the opposite of what we just
described, that is to move profits (if that is the performance measure) from the present
to the future. They will do this by moving expenses from the future to the present
period (by prepaying expenses, taking write-offs for restructuring, etc.), and by
moving revenues from the present to the future.19 This is the big bath theory.
As we can see from Figure 1 if the manager is going to miss the bonus this year
anyway, there is no further reduction in compensation from performance that is even
farther away from the lower hurdle amount (subject always to the condition that the
manager is not fired). But moving future expenses to the present and current revenues
to the future will increase the likelihood of a bonus in future years and increase the
bonus amount at that time if they are in the payoff range. Thus, it pays managers to
take what would be a small loss now and turn it into a big loss now so as to advance
their future bonus interests. This undoubtedly plays a role in exaggerating the appar-
ent decline in profits during times of recession as company after company decides to
take huge write-offs to their earnings. We can bet that much of this behaviour over-
states the current losses while setting the stage for higher measured performance in the
future. In times like the present this behaviour can become so pervasive that it affects
macroeconomic statistics and even public policy. Similarly we can predict that during
boom times the fortunes of firms will be overstated as managers stretch to live up to

19
For an excellent analysis and empirical study of the effects of bonus schemes on managers
choice of accounting polices see: Healy (1985).

# Michael C. Jensen, 2003


388 Professional Forum

unrealistically high expectations of analysts and other participants in the financial


markets.
Finally, managers who are within reach of the bonus cap have incentives to not
exceed the maximum because they get no rewards beyond that point (and these
perverse incentives are even stronger if this, years performance is used in setting
next years targets). In this situation managers have incentives to move expenses from
the future to the present and revenues from the present to the future to increase
bonuses in future years. And again, they have incentives to do this even if it imposes
real losses on the company to do so.

B. The source of the gaming problems

Thus, we see that the source of the gaming problems and the costs they create in
organizations is not the budgeting system itself, but the way in which we pay people.
The source of the problem is in the relation between the compensation of people and
the budget. In general, we see that any time managers are within shooting distance of
a kink (or in general any nonlinear segment) in the pay-for-performance function, the
firm is rewarding them for taking actions that are harmful. As long as the kinks are
present there is no way around these incentives except direct monitoring. But such
direct monitoring is often difficult because the specific knowledge required to observe
it lies with the managers, not their monitors.20 If managers in a particular firm have
few if any opportunities to make decisions that can shift results to conform to the
kinks, there is little cost. But in most cases managers, as the examples given above

20
For example in the Lernout & Hauspie Speech Products NV (L&H) case mentioned earlier,
John Carreyrou in the Wall Street Journal reported:
L&Hs new chief executive, Philippe Bodson, said that upon learning of Pricewaterhouses
findings he was very impressed by the level of sophistication of the fraud and the amount of
imagination that went into it. Speaking at a news conference in Brussels Friday, Mr. Bodson
said the fraud at L&H Korea should become a case study in business schools. . . .
To fool auditors, L&H Korea used two types of schemes, Pricewaterhouses sleuths found.
The first involved factoring unpaid receivables to banks to obtain cash up front. Side letters that
were concealed from KPMG gave the banks the right to take the money back if they could not
collect from L&H Koreas customers. Hence, the factoring agreements amounted to little more
than loans.
The second, more creative scheme was set in motion after auditors questioned why L&H
Korea was not collecting more of its overdue bills from customers. L&H Korea told many
customers to transfer their contracts to third parties. The third parties then took out bank
loans, for which L&H Korea provided collateral, and then paid the overdue bills to L&H
Korea using the borrowed money, Pricewaterhouse found.
The upshot is that L&H Korea was paying itself. When the contracts were later cancelled,
L&H Korea paid penalties to the customers and the third parties to compensate them for the
inconvenience of dealing with the auditors, the Pricewaterhouse report said.
The probe also found that the bulk of L&H Koreas sales came from contracts signed at the
end of quarters, so managers could meet ambitious quarterly sales targets and receive multi-
million-dollar bonuses. For instance, 90% of the revenue recorded by L&H Korea in last years
second quarter was booked in 30 deals signed in the final nine days of the quarter. But L&H
Korea was forced to subsequently cancel 21 of those contracts because the customers most of
them tiny start-ups did not have the means to pay. (Carreyrou, 2001).

# Michael C. Jensen, 2003


Professional Forum 389

illustrate, have many opportunities to do these things, and they are often very difficult
to observe from above and therefore to monitor.

C. The solution to budget gaming problems


Figure 2 shows graphically how to solve the budget gaming problems. If we make the
pay-for-performance function a straight line, the actual bonus that a manager receives
is independent of where the budget target is set. To see this, note that if the budget is
set at Target #1 and actual performance is as noted, the bonus paid to the manager is
exactly the same as it would be if the budget target were set at Target #2. Thus, the
linear bonus schedule rewards people for what they actually do, and not what they do
relative to what they say they can do.21
Let me be clear at this point how linearising the pay-for-performance schedule will
change the incentive to lie and game the system. Once the system is linearised there is
no incentive for a manager to lie about what he or she can do in the budget-setting
process. Once lower level managers really believe it, this means that top-level

Fig. 2. The solution to the budget gaming problem: remove all kinks, discontinuities and
curvilinearity from the pay-for-performance function. Straight-line pay-for-performance
functions eliminate the incentives for managers to game the budget-setting process. Note that
the bonus for actual performance at the denoted Actual Outcome in the figure (the Actual
Bonus) is the same whether the budget target was set at #1 or at the higher #2 level. Therefore,
managers have no incentive to lie about what they can or cannot do in the budget setting
process.

21
Locke (2001, pp. 5253 ), suggests similarly that two solutions to this behaviour are to
Motivate by goals but reward by performance, and to use multiple goal and reward levels.
Recent work by (Schweitzer et al., 2001) indicates that the psychological rewards associated
with meeting preset goals are sufficient to induce the gaming behaviour we are discussion even
in the absence of monetary rewards. See the discussion in Section 5 below. The latter tiering of
rewards can reduce but not eliminate this behaviour.

# Michael C. Jensen, 2003


390 Professional Forum

management will be getting unbiased measures of what can be done in the future, and
the quality of planning and coordination can go up considerably.
The benefits associated with eliminating the costs associated with ineffective
planning and coordination can be considerable. In one case a large beverage company
ran out of its core product in one of the largest regions in the country for an important
holiday season because of gaming by one of its managers. In gaming the bonus system
the VP of sales in that region dramatically underpredicted market demand for the
quarter (so he could easily exceed it) and insisted the estimate was accurate. But the
price for his little white lie was extremely high: when the operations people took his
word for it the entire region ran out of product for the holiday selling season.
Moreover, as we can see from Figure 2 there is no undue incentive to make value-
destroying tradeoffs in the performance measure through time. Since there are no
kinks or other non-linearities or discontinuities the only incentive a manager has to
move things around in time is his or her time rate of preference or the interest rate.
Since pay will still go up as performance improves, dishonest managers may still try
to lie about their numbers in order to increase their bonus. That, of course, is a risk
that companies have always had to watch out for. A linear bonus schedule does not
reduce the need for good control systems and attentive executives. As long as man-
agers think they will not be caught or that the penalties for such lying will be small it
will pay them to take actions that will overstate their actual performance. There is no
solution to this problem other than having good control systems that get the measures
right, and high penalties for those who get caught taking such actions.

D. The costs of budget gaming activity


I believe the total costs imposed on companies and the economic system by the misuse
of budgets and targets in reward systems is very large. To my knowledge there are no
high quality aggregate estimates of these costs. The best example of estimated costs
due to this gaming activity is that by Donald Roy in his article, Goldbricking in a
machine shop (1952). Roy worked in a machine shop, for almost a year, that used a
piece rate incentive system for lathe operators that (with the exception of the hurdle
bonus) was close to that portrayed in Figure 1. Roy surreptitiously kept records of his
own and co-workers behaviour and output, and describes their gaming behaviour
vividly and carefully. Based on his records, Roy estimates that eliminating the
goldbricking due to the target-based reward system with caps in his shop would
increase productivity from 33% to 150%. (See Roy, 1952, pp. 441442). Since
programmes like these are common even today to measure and motivate employees,
including production line workers, sales forces, managers and top level executives,
I believe the costs to the economy are huge. If Roys estimates of losses are approxi-
mately correct, and I believe they are, by solving these problems we could generate
increases in productivity approximating 50100% in the places where they exist.

E. Stretch goals and the role of top managers in motivating lies

But the incentive and pressure to manipulate the system to attain some stretch goal
comes not only from the desire of lower level managers to realise their bonuses but also
from top managers collaboration with the gaming. This occurs when top managers
pressure lower-level managers to make the plan at any cost, and refuse to be realistic
about whether it is even feasible to make the goal. The result can be another strong source
# Michael C. Jensen, 2003
Professional Forum 391

of incentives to lie, manipulate, and game the system, at the expense of the organisations
integrity. And the cost of attempting to call attention to and stop this behaviour can
be extremely high as evidenced by claims in recent lawsuits against Lucent and Xerox.
Nina Aversano, a former Lucent vice president who ran North American sales,
claims in her lawsuit that Rich McGinn, the CEO of Lucent, forced her to retire in the
fall of 2000. She further claims that this happened after she warned McGinn that
growth projections were too high and presented material showing that 2001 sales in
her region would fall short of growth targets, in part because of discounts promised to
customers in December of 1999 to make purchases they might otherwise have
postponed until a quarter later. (Mehta, 2001, pp. 146, 148)
In his wrongful termination lawsuit against Xerox James F. Bingham, former
Assistant Treasurer of Xerox claims he was fired in retaliation for his efforts to
rectify (Xeroxs) fraudulent accounting and financial reporting practices (Bandler
and Hechinger, 2001). As assistant treasurer, he was one of the finance managers the
company called on to help guide it through tough economic times. To bolster
deteriorating results, he says he practiced creative accounting with gusto, even invent-
ing a few new twists. I fed the beast, he says. But eventually Mr. Bingham balked,
because he believed it was his responsibility to speak out at Xerox because we were
driving ourselves into bankruptcy with bad business decisions based on faulty
accounting. He thought the logic of my arguments and the correctness of my data
were so strong that top Xerox executives would change course. Maybe I was a little
bit na ve. (Bandler and Maremont, 2001)
Xerox had been faced with declining business results. Inside Xeroxs finance depart-
ment, there was growing pressure to compensate for the poor results with accounting
gimmickry, Mr. Bingham told SEC investigators last December. Xerox executives
frequently assigned accountants numerical goals to produce profits through account-
ing actions, he said, according to a transcript of his testimony. It just became
standard operating procedure that, you know, you look to the accountants to find
income. At first, Mr. Bingham was an enthusiastic participant in these intricate
accounting maneuvers, saying he enjoyed them because they were intellectually challen-
ging. According to his 1999 annual performance review, he took the lead role in a
series of transactions with banks in which Xerox packaged short-term rental agreements
for copiers in Brazil and elsewhere as if they were long-term deals, which are generally
treated for accounting purposes as sales. This enabled Xerox to book immediately
much of the future rental revenue (Bandler and Hechinger, 2001)
Last month [Jan 2001] Mr. Bingham finally received some vindication. After
months of calling his claims baseless, Xerox restated its results for the past three
years and acknowledged that it had misapplied accounting rules in a variety of
ways, including improperly using a $100 million reserve to offset unrelated expenses
precisely one of Mr. Binghams criticisms. To correct the reserve error, Xerox cut its
1998 and 1999 pretax profits by $100 million, while adding $6 million to 2000s pretax
figure. Xerox also gave credence to Mr. Binghams main claim, that it had used
aggressive accounting to secretly bolster results in the late 1990s. In the footnotes of
an SEC filing, the company revealed for the first time that its pretax profits in 1998,
1999 and 2000 had been boosted by a total of $845 million through a series of
one-time transactions and changes in accounting estimates. That was a hefty
chunk of the $2.1 billion in pretax profits reported for the three years. Xerox
maintains its accounting for these items was appropriate, and no steps to adjust for
the transactions were included in the restatement (Bandler and Hechinger, 2001).
# Michael C. Jensen, 2003
392 Professional Forum

F. Curvilinear bonus schemes provide unproductive incentives as well

Figure 3 provides the basis of an analysis of a bonus scheme in which the pay-
for-performance curve increases at an increasing rate. The argument behind this is
that an organisation may want to reward its managers for improved performance at
an increasingly higher rate. Unfortunately, by application of Jensens inequality, this
scheme too provides managers with an incentive to take counterproductive actions.
I have found in dealing with managers on these issues that inevitably when I fail to
discuss this issue (because I originally thought it was too technical and esoteric and,
therefore, unnecessary to cover), it comes up as a favoured policy option in the new
compensation system.
Consider the case in which a manager could indeed meet the targeted budget each
year. Doing so would yield the manager a bonus of $12,000 every year. But if he could
at no cost move things around so that the performance would fluctuate from 80% of
budget in one year to 120% of budget in the next year he would be better off.
In the low 80% year he would receive a bonus of $10,000 and in the 120% year his
bonus would be $20,000. The total for the two years would be $30,000 and the
average, $15,000. He thus has incentive to artificially increase the variability of
performance under this compensation scheme. Moreover, he has incentives to do so
even if the costs of doing it reduced overall performance in both years. As I alluded to
above, it is easy for managers or analysts to mistakenly believe that these effects will
be small and unimportant. It was exactly this type of compensation plan that Chrysler
introduced to motivate its dealers in January of 2001, and that caused Chrysler to
experience an 18% decline in sales in April 2001. Section 6.1 provides a detailed
discussion of the Chrysler situation.

Fig. 3. Curvilinear pay-for-performance functions encourage managers to increase


the variability of year-to-year performance measures if they provide for larger
increases in bonus for a given increase in performance at higher levels of performance
(i.e., convex as they are in this example), and to decrease the year-to-year variability if they
are concave.

# Michael C. Jensen, 2003


Professional Forum 393

The opposite, of course, would be true if the curve were concave rather than
convex. In this case the manager would have incentives to artificially reduce the
variability of outcomes to increase his average bonus payment.

G. In summary
If every element of a managers compensation (including bonuses and promotions) is
independent of the budget or target, then he or she has no monetary incentive to game
it and to lie or omit information in constructing it. The result: organisational integrity
can be restored and budgets can be constructed and used not for gaming, but for
making the tradeoffs that lie at the heart of management coordination of enterprise
activities. This means that the relation between pay and performance has to be a
straight line. When there are no kinks, no non-linearities, and no discontinuities in the
relation between pay and performance the bonus does not depend on the target in any
way. Therefore, managers have no monetary incentive to lie or hide information. This
also means promotions or other means of rewards cannot be a function of the target
or budget. While this is conceptually easy to do, it is tough to implement in systems
where managers cannot imagine another way to manage. Competitiveness will be
enhanced as we change such managerial mindsets.

5. The hidden costs of stretch goals

Many managers will react to my proposal in the following way: while a linear bonus
schedule would remove the incentive to game the target-setting system, it will also
remove the incentive effects of stretch goals. Indeed, Locke (2001, p. 48) in his
summary of goal setting concludes that the empirical evidence strongly indicates
that goal setting increases performance:

There have been more than 500 studies of goal setting on work tasks. It has been
studied in at least eight countries. Goals have been set for many different types of
outcomes, including sales, R&D, cost control, productivity, quality, and efficiency.
The time spans studied have ranged from 1 minute to 25 years. It works in both
laboratory and organizational settings and with both individuals and groups. About
90% of goal-setting studies have achieved positive results. One survey revealed that
the average performance improvement attained by goal-setting studies in real
organizations was 16%, although in some cases the improvement was over 50%.

Let us assume that these studies accurately measure the effects of stretch goal
setting. I believe it is very difficult and in some cases impossible to estimate the
costs of gaming that accompanies such goal setting procedures. It is especially difficult
to measure the costs of gaming in a laboratory setting where the amounts at issue are
small, the time involved is too short for people to figure out the multitudes of clever
ways to game the system, and the costs of gaming would usually be difficult to
measure because the long run effects would be unobserved. And unless it was
explicitly designed into the experiments the costs of poor information in the planning
and coordination process would be difficult if not impossible to observe because of
the artificiality and incompleteness of the laboratory environment.
Indeed, in the large and robust literature on goal-setting I have found only one
study that attempts to measure the effects of goals on unethical behaviour. In their as
# Michael C. Jensen, 2003
394 Professional Forum

yet unpublished paper, Schweitzer et al. (2001, 2002, forthcoming) find in their labora-
tory study that subjects regularly lied about their performance. For example, in their
clever study, the authors find that even in situations where there was no monetary
reward for meeting a goal, merely setting such a goal that subjects accepted resulted in
subjects lying about their performance 34.8% of the time when they were otherwise
close to meeting it. This compared to instances of lying of 14.8% in similar circum-
stances when subjects were not given a goal but only asked to do your best and 48%
when they were being rewarded for meeting the goal. These results imply that even if we
linearise the compensation plan but still use targets to motivate people as Locke
suggests (see footnote 21) we are still going to observe gaming in the system. Even in
the absence of monetary rewards for meeting a goal it appears that the psychological
rewards for doing so are enough to cause people to lie about making the goal.
Those who argue for the effectiveness of stretch goals must believe that the gaming
costs associated with these systems are less than the benefits. This means that the costs
due to the loss of critical information in the planning and coordination process
(imagine an entire region running out of a companys major product during the
major holiday selling season), and the damage caused by the gaming aimed at
realising the goals once set must be less than the increased output that results from
the stretch goals. Table 2 presents one CEOs experience with stretch goals that is
inconsistent with the effectiveness argument of stretch goals.
More formally, let P be the amount of performance that would come from a purely
linear pay-for-performance system such as that in Figure 1, and P* > P be the higher
level of performance under the stretch goal system without taking the costs of gaming
into account. Let G be the costs associated with the degradation of the planning and
coordination function resulting from the gaming involved in setting the targets and in
the costs of gaming involved in the realization of the targets of the goal system. If the
stretch goal system is to generate positive value, the present value of P*  G must be
greater than P. I do not believe we have good formal statistical evidence on this
question, but we will have it in the future as managers and management scientists
begin to look at the costs and benefits of these systems more carefully. As I indicated
above, my guess is that we will find that the costs of these systems far outweigh
their benefits in most cases. And I emphasise again that in considering these costs we
must take explicit account of the effects of precedents set in the budgeting/target
setting and compensation system on the loss of integrity in the rest of an organiza-
tions systems.

6. Three things to get right in a linear compensation plan

In moving to a non-target-based compensation system it is important to get it close to


right in the first year, and this is not easy. There are three things a company has to get
right in moving to a new linear compensation plan:
1. The measure of performance,
2. The intercept of the bonus line,
3. The slope of the bonus line.

Together these three factors define the payoffs for the plan and the incentive effects
of the plan.
# Michael C. Jensen, 2003
Professional Forum 395

Table 2
Stretch goals and kinked compensation: a hard lesson learned.

The newly appointed CEO of a large and prominent multinational corporation was furious with
the degree to which sales and profit growth was slowing due to what he saw as the unwillingness
of his executives to set stretching goals. In fact, he felt they were becoming expert at setting
goals low enough to ensure making.

Like most firms, budgets played a key role in the life of his firm. Managers earned
significant bonuses for achieving budget, none for missing budget and little, if any, addi-
tional bonus for exceeding budget. Each year a long and involved process of budget setting
ensued.

The new CEO liked the budget system because it ensured strict accountability something
he held near and dear to his heart. However, he did not like the way that managers set low
budget goals and managed accordingly. He blamed two factors. First, he saw the cultural
tradition of the firm as not aggressive enough in pushing for stretch targets. Second, he saw
the existing organisational structure as being too complex, and this blurred the lines of
accountability, allowing managers to avoid taking personal responsibility for success or
failure.
As a consequence, he attacked these two problems. First, he embarked on the biggest and most
wide-ranging reorganisation in the long history of the firm. Almost every manager in the firm
was affected by the changes. All of the existing budgets needed to be rearranged and redis-
tributed. Second, he made it clear in his own management style that he was going to insist on
stretch goals, stretch targets, stretch attitudes.
He left the critical features of the compensation scheme largely untouched. Budget achievement
was still the critical performance measurement. There remained a pronounced kink at achieve-
ment of budget. A nuance that changed was that managers were allowed to give out gifts of
stock to employees seen to have gone above and beyond the call of duty.
The result? Disaster almost immediately. Since achieving budget was the critical element in
performance measurement, managers spent much of the first year lobbying to have the reallo-
cation of budget targets to them minimised as far as possible in order to ensure meeting budget.
Those that were unable to get a favourable target, complained vociferously that they had been
treated unfairly in the reallocation process and they should be given relief. In addition,
managers sought to have their actions seen as exemplary whether they were or not in
order to earn special share awards.

Within months, everyone realised that the new stretch budgets imposed upon them in the
reallocation were not going to be met. Managers then gave up, let the year fall into the tank
and waited to have expectations reset to a lower level for the following years budgets. However,
this reality was obscured from the CEO until the last minute, causing him enormous capital
market embarrassment resulting in his dismissal. He learned the lesson the hard way that
maintaining a compensation curve kinked around the budget while pushing harder for stretch
will not produce more stretch but rather more dishonesty.

1. The measure of performance

There are many interesting and important things to be weighed in the choice of
performance measure including, among others, the time interval over which measures
are made, the entity that is being measured, the number of measures, and the nature
of the measure itself. We limit our brief discussion here to these.
# Michael C. Jensen, 2003
396 Professional Forum

First, as we reduce the time interval over which the measures are made they become
more relevant to ongoing decision-making. Imagine waiting 10 years for a perform-
ance measure. However, as we make the time interval shorter it becomes easier
for managers to game the system by moving results from one period to another.
Consider the ease of postponing vehicle sales from one month to the next as Chrysler
found out recently when it introduced a new incentive programme for its dealers.
Chryslers programme paid the dealers a bonus depending on how many cars they
sell relative to a monthly sales target. The function was an increasing piece-wise linear
function with a bowl shape like that portrayed in Figure 3. Under the plan, Chrysler
gives dealers cash based on the percent of a vehicle sales target they meet. If they sell
fewer than 75% of the sales target, they get nothing. If they sell from 75.1% to 99%,
they get $150 for each vehicle sold: 100% to 109.9%, is $250 and anything more than
110% nets $500 per vehicle (Suhr, 2001). Begun in January, 2001 the programme
backfired in April 2001 when dealers saw they were not hitting the sales target early in
the month and cut back on sales and inventory. It is a good bet that as Chrysler
dealers saw they were unlikely to earn the $500 per car payments in April (when
industry sales as a whole were down 10%) they took actions to delay sales from April
to May (undoubtedly losing some in the process) to increase the total bonus payments
they received for the two months taken together.22
The result (according to a NY Times article, Incentive plan hurts Chrysler): A
Chrysler program intended to reward dealers who meet sales goals backfired in April,
as dealers worried about missing the goals ordered fewer vehicles, Chryslers chief
executive said today. Chryslers sales fell 18%, 80% worse than the industry average
and the CEO announced that it was due to complication(s) in understanding how the
new sales reward program works (New York Times, 2001, p. 5.)
Chrysler revised the programme in May to give dealers two more months to make up
for any missed sales target for a given month. The underlying cause of the problem,
which cost Chrysler dearly, is the non-linear reward function that (as explained in
Section 4.F above) pays managers for increasing the variability of performance even
if it reduces overall performance. Moving to a 90-day interval will help Chrysler reduce
the problem because it is easier to push the sales of vehicles around 30 days or so than it
is to move them 90 days, but it will not eliminate the problem.
Second, if you wish to encourage cooperation between people, use group measures
of performance (such as for an entire team), not purely individual measures of
performance. It will be desirable to do this when one persons actions significantly
affect the productivity of others and those effects are not easy to measure and
incorporate in the persons performance measure. This would make it more desirable
to measure performance for the team as a whole and compensate members of the team
on the performance of the whole. This, of course, will encourage free riding of
individual team members, but this can be controlled if the size of the team is small
or we can induce self-monitoring by the team.
Third, we must decide how much subjectivity will be involved in each performance
measure. In considering this we must recognise that every performance measurement

22
(Hyde, 2001) Dick Withnell, a Dodge dealer in Salem, OR, said when sales started to fall off
in early April below targets, dealers started cutting back on orders. Not very many guys hit it
(the sales goal) in April, he said. When the guys arent hitting it they start being conservative
with inventory. It becomes a self-fulfilling prophecy.

# Michael C. Jensen, 2003


Professional Forum 397

system in a firm must involve an important amount of subjectivity. The reason, as my


colleague George Baker has pointed out, is that any activity whose performance can
be perfectly measured objectively does not belong inside the firm. If its performance
can be adequately measured objectively, it can be spun out of the firm and contracted
for in a market transaction.23 Thus, one of the most important jobs of managers,
complementing objective measures of performance with managerial subjective evalua-
tion of subtle interdependencies and other factors, is exactly what most managers
would like to avoid. Indeed, it is this factor along with efficient risk bearing that is at
the heart of what gives managers and firms an advantage over markets.
Fourth, do not give people or units multiple performance measures without
specifying the tradeoffs between them. Doing so leaves managers with no purposeful
way to choose an action. For example, suppose we tell a manager to both increase
profits next year and increase market share. If the world is such that after some point
market share can only be increased by decreasing price and, therefore, decreasing
profits, the manager has no purposeful way to decide what to do.24
Fifth, in general it is counterproductive to measure performance with a ratio. My
rule of thumb is: If it is a performance measure and it is a ratio, it is wrong. I have never
found a counter-example. The problem with using a ratio as a performance measure is
that those who are attempting to maximise it can do two things. They can increase the
numerator or decrease the denominator. Firms that use ratios as performance
measures generally implicitly assume that managers will increase (or decrease) the
numerator. But that of course is not true, and the results can be truly perverse. Two
simple examples will suffice here.
If we measure someones performance by the sales margin, measured as a per-
centage of sales (a ratio), the individual in maximising this measure can cut back
production or sales (the denominator) to sell only those units with the highest margin
rather than increasing the margin on the units currently being sold. The result: total
dollars of profit and value will fall.
The same is true if we measure people by percentage return measures say return
on assets (ROA). We want people to continue to maximise the return on each asset
and to invest in assets until the profit on the investment in the last asset is zero, and
this will be when the return on the marginal asset is equal to the cost of capital.
But someone rewarded for increasing the ROA measure will have incentives to
invest in only the highest returning asset. If the cost of capital is 10% a 40% ROA on
an asset which costs $1,000 yields an economic profit of $400  $100 $300. How-
ever, a 20% return on an asset that costs $10,000 with the same 10% cost of capital,
yields a much greater economic profit of $2,000  $1,000 $1,000. If the two return
streams are perpetuities the first asset has a value of $3,000 300/0.1 in excess of its
cost, and the second asset has a value of $10,000 1,000/0.1 in excess of its cost. It is
obvious that the best investment if the two are mutually exclusive is the latter, and if
they can both be taken the best decision is to take them both. But doing either of these
actions will result in a reduction of the ROA measure and a destruction of value. Yet
that is what we are rewarding managers for doing when we measure their performance
by ROA or ROE.

23
For an excellent discussion of closely related issues, see (Baker et al., 1997).
24
For a detailed analysis of this issue and how it relates to stakeholder theory as well as a
critical failing in the balanced scorecard, see Jensen (2001).

# Michael C. Jensen, 2003


398 Professional Forum

There is usually a way to constrain decision rights in each situation to make a ratio
measure work, but most firms do not do this. In the ROA example it could be made to
work if we fix the level of investment at $10,400. But this solution, of course, assumes
away one of the reasons why we have a manager in this job in the first place to
determine the optimal level of investment. It also presumes that the specific knowl-
edge necessary to make the total investment decision lies higher in the hierarchy, and
that we have that higher-level managers performance measured properly.
My favourite period-to-period measure of performance is economic profit or what
Stern Stewart calls Economic Value Added (EVATM). It is not a ratio, and therefore
has none of the problems of ratio measures. It is a flow measure, however, and thus
not perfect. Using economic profit as a measure of period to period performance we
still have to figure out how to motivate managers to make those value creating
decisions that will generate negative economic profit in the early years while returning
large positive economic profit in later years. What we ideally want is a stock measure
of total value added over the life of the investment, but there is no simple mechanical
way to measure this. It must be estimated and checked against the evolution of value
over time.

2. The intercept of the bonus line

The intercept determines the location of the bonus line and works in conjunction with
the slope of the bonus line to determine the total bonus for any given level of
performance. Increasing the intercept increases the difficulty of achieving any given
level of bonus. There is a strong tendency of organisations and managers to be short
run oriented in their setting of the intercepts of the bonus line. Summarised succinctly
the theory goes as follows: let us take away the benefits of exceptional effort this year
by using this years performance as the base for next years bonus.
This reduces the risk that managers will be overcompensated for overly conserva-
tive projections of performance (high bonuses in one year make it harder to get high
bonuses the next year), but it also reduces incentives for increasing performance and
reintroduces gaming into the system. It does so by making the intercept and/or slope
of the compensation function depend on last years performance. Understand that
when we do this we then introduce a kink or non-linearity in the compensation
function as managers recognise that next years compensation for any degree of
performance will be lower when this years performance is higher. Managers and
other employees quickly learn to take this into account in limiting the performance
reported this year so as not to set benchmarks for the future that are too high.
Suppose, for example, that in order to increase performance a manager can exert
more effort to increase performance by 10% over the current level, and that it takes
considerable effort every period in the future to maintain that increase in perform-
ance. In this case managers will perceive that it takes effort every single period to
maintain the one time increase in performance but they are rewarded only in the first
year for the improvement. Unless the current years bonus is very substantial most
managers will think twice before engaging in this effort. In effect this policy estab-
lishes a discontinuity/kink in the future compensation function at the level of this
years performance. And since this shift in the future compensation line depends on the
managers actions today it therefore will affect managers decisions to take those
actions. A better way is to look further out, setting bonus lines for a number of
# Michael C. Jensen, 2003
Professional Forum 399

years out based on longer-term growth and profitability projections. This is harder to
do, but it reduces the potential for gaming.
On the other side, low performance this year that reduces the level of performance
required to earn any given payoff next year will be factored in to managers decisions
to take large baths this year in the event of otherwise poor performance. Taking a
bath this year makes next years bonuses higher for any given level of true perform-
ance. In a truly linear pay system this would not induce gaming, but it will if, as is
often true, the large writeoffs are not included in this years performance measures or
there are lower bounds on compensation that limit negative bonuses.
Figure 4 gives an illustration of how the linear compensation lines can be shifted out
to meet, for example, some growth estimate for a number of years. This is obviously a
more challenging plan than one that does not adjust for some future growth. Many
managers want to do this to avoid overpaying in the future. As long as it is all put in
place at the beginning and does not make the shifts a function of present or future
performance such shifts in the intercept will not generate gaming behaviour. Unfortu-
nately, while this is easy to say it is not easy to do. I think realistically there is no perfect
solution to this problem of adjusting the bonus lines over time to take into account
competitive conditions and changes in the growth of the market. Equity compensation
does not shift the difficulty over time. It pays managers for what happens, and except
for the kink at the point of bankruptcy induces few gaming problems.

Fig. 4. Example of how compensation lines can be set to change at initiation according to a
fixed formula. If the formula does not depend on future performance it will not have
adverse affects on incentives by causing gaming. (Source: Adapted from client work of
Jennifer Lacks-Kaplan)

# Michael C. Jensen, 2003


400 Professional Forum

3. The slope of the budget line

The slope of the bonus line must be high enough to reward managers for taking risks
and to reward them for the extra effort and creativity to produce incremental perform-
ance. There is no simple rule that will tell us what the slope should be. Choosing a
slope involves assessing the benefits that come from higher rewards for outstanding
performance from managers and employees versus the costs of doing so. The more
risk averse managers and employees are the lower the slope will have to be.
Given a trial value of the intercept and slope of the bonus line a firm must estimate
through simulation the bonus payoffs to its managers and employees for all relevant
levels of performance and make sure that it is comfortable that the economics of the
system work. We cannot create a system that turns all a firms cash over to its
managers and employees without destroying the ability of the firm to invest and
raise capital. And if we create a system that does not reward employees enough for
outstanding performance we will lose them to competing firms.
Finally it is obvious but worth saying anyway, that it is important to think through
all aspects of compensation, including the effects of promotion and non-pecuniary
reward systems to make sure that non-linearity and target-based rewards and punish-
ments have not crept back into the system.

7. The difficulties of managing without targets

A. Good managers always set targets and reward those who meet them and punish those
who dont

It will not be easy for most firms to switch to a linear compensation system. These
target-based systems are so ingrained in the minds of managers and in the managerial
code of most organisations that even those managers who wish to change them will
find it very difficult to do so. People have to learn to think in a fundamentally
different way about these systems. Getting managers to give up target-based bonuses
is hard, but then getting them to give up promotions or reputational rewards for
meeting or beating budgets is even harder. And once managers become intellectually
convinced of the desirability of these steps, they often wish (unwittingly) to reintroduce
the problem by putting upward kinks or non-linearity in the system by increasing the
bonuses more rapidly after the targets are met as in Figure 3. The psychological mindset
seems to be that both managers and employees feel unrewarded unless they get some-
thing more after they have achieved budget, and this easily leads to increasing the piece
rate in the linear compensation system and reintroducing all of the attendant problems
of non-linear compensation profiles discussed in the context of Figure 3.

B. Strong allegiance to minimum and maximum limits on compensation


It is sometimes difficult for an organisation to present its managers and employees
with fully linear pay-for-performance schedules because of employee cash constraints.
Employee financial commitments such as mortgages, college tuition and so on make it
valuable for people to have a limited downside, and some companies may be forced by
market conditions to impose lower limits on the downside. But as long as we can keep
the lower limits (or upper limits) out of the relevant range of likely outcomes the
incentive effects should be small.
# Michael C. Jensen, 2003
Professional Forum 401

One way to help move the lower limit out of the relevant range is to follow Bennett
Stewarts suggestion to institute a bonus bank in which managers are not paid their
entire bonus in the year earned (Stewart, 1990). One example is to pay it out over
3 years with the balance held in a virtual bank, paid interest, and available for payout
in future years. But if the next years bonus is negative (that is below the lower limit of
salary plus bonus) it would be charged to the bonus bank and would reduce future
bonus bank payouts.
There are other strong forces that limit the ability of organisations to truly make
compensation linear. It is difficult for organisations and the human beings that make
them up to manage without maximum limits on compensation. People have a strong
tendency to attribute large positive outcomes to good luck, and there is a strong
tendency for managers to wish to limit the payoffs from such luck. But luck is often
extremely difficult to distinguish from talent and a few critical choices that managers
can make or not make. Jealousy plays a role in this, and so does pride, two of the least
desirable qualities of human beings.
Running a linear compensation system with no maximum limits means that up and
down the hierarchy managers have to be willing to see some employees and/or
managers that report to them getting bonuses that are much larger than their own.
How many CEOs can tolerate paying a salesperson or technical expert more than they
get themselves? Wise ones are both willing and able to do this and willing to
encourage managers under themselves to do it. But because the pay-for-performance
system will give levels of total compensation in any given year that do not rise linearly
as we go up the hierarchy, ego and jealousy play important roles in undoing the
system and putting kinks back into it.
I recently witnessed a large technical firm that wished to revise its compensation
system to cause its stock price to double in 3 years reimpose maximum payoffs on the
system. This change, of course, was directly inconsistent with their desire to release
unlimited upside incentives on the part of their managers to bring about extraordinary
organisational performance.
One of the benefits of entrepreneurial organisations is that the equity ownership is
close to the decision-making power and managers stand or fall on the stock price
performance of the company. Such systems are often associated with intense energy
and commitment, and can reward or penalise intensively on both the upside and the
downside. Note that as long as a company is out of range of bankruptcy, equity gives
its managers a linear pay-for-performance system with no upside limits. And it is
more difficult to take back the equity gains than it is when all that is necessary is a
revision of the bonus formula.

C. The fear of turnover vs. the benefits of new blood


When moving to a linear system managers will worry whether the intercept and slopes
of their compensation lines are correct. Are they too rich and will they pay off too
much to insiders and leave too little to shareholders? Are they too risky for managers
and employees?
In addition, because of the power of self selection, organisations must recognise that
moving from a typical low sensitive pay-for-performance system with lower bounds and
caps, kinks, and gaming, to a linear system such as that suggested here will create
turnover among their employees and managers. Although this will generally be a good
thing in the long run, it can be very disturbing in the short run because those people
# Michael C. Jensen, 2003
402 Professional Forum

who are unhappy with the risks and promised rewards in the new system will not leave
without first making life uncomfortable for many others. In addition, ex ante, it will
generally be difficult to see how they will be replaced, and the fear among top managers
and board members will be that the firm will lose so much specific knowledge with the
turnover that the firms operations will be threatened. This is a legitimate concern, but
such costs are often overemphasised. My general impression is that the unexamined
alternatives (to current managers) are almost always substantially undervalued.
If the changes are well designed, the long-term self-selection benefits can be valu-
able to the firm as poorer performing employees voluntarily leave the company. In
addition, a firm that has too little turnover does not benefit from the new ideas and
ways of thinking that can be brought in by new hires that are not yet captured by the
firms culture and standard ways of thinking. Because new blood brings benefits the
optimal turnover rate is not zero.
Figure 5 shows a simple example of how a change from a purely bureaucratic
no-pay-for-performance system to a steep pay-for-performance system will cause
low talented, less risk taking employees and managers to go to competitors with
no-pay-for-performance systems and for highly motivated risk taking people to be
attracted to our firm. Or put another way, Figure 5 shows that when we opt for no
pay-for-performance we are putting into place systems that tend to attract and keep
in our employment people who are less talented, more risk averse and less productive
than the average in the market.

D. The dynamics of the system over time


A company must deal with how the system will change over time, and here we face
another set of difficult challenges because, as I point out in section 6, we cannot make

Fig. 5. The shape of the compensation plan affects how hard a person works and what they
work on. The shape also creates self-selection into or out of a company. All those employees
and managers in Company B in the lower end of the performance dimension who expect to
earn more in Company A with the bureaucratic no-pay-for-performance system will migrate to
Company A. Those at the higher end of the spectrum will stay or be recruited into Company B.

# Michael C. Jensen, 2003


Professional Forum 403

the location or slope of future bonus lines depend on this years performance without
indirectly introducing non-linearities and kinks back into the system. And we must be
careful to avoid making what will seem to be arbitrary changes in the system as we go
forward in the future. If we do this we can gut the system of its incentive effects.
If managers and employees come to believe that we will revise the system downward
to avoid or take back large bonuses paid in the current year they will correctly
conclude that the system has kinks in it, even though they are informal and not
explicit. They will estimate where those kinks are and hold back effort to restrict
future performance so they are not triggered. See Roy (1952) for some powerful
examples of this behaviour that are all too common today as well.
This means we also have to resist the strong pressures from managers and employ-
ees to abandon the bonus system when its payoff is low because of poor performance.
The threat of strikes or resignations by managers and employees in periods of hard
times can be very difficult to resist. But, if a company is to gain the benefits of self-
selection discussed above its top managers must be willing and able to endure the
turnover that will result. This may be one of the most difficult tasks for many
companies to accomplish successfully.

E. The importance of education

Any company making substantial changes in its compensation system will have to
devote considerable resources to educating its managers and employees about exactly
how the new systems will work and why. If people cannot understand what drives the
payoffs in a new system they will not be properly motivated even if it is well designed
system. This education will take time and effort and will have to overcome the natural
tendency of human beings to resist change. Compensation is a fundamental element in
each persons life, and any compensation change programme must recognise two facts
about human behaviour: (1) almost everyone believes that they are experts on com-
pensation and (2) almost everything that they believe about compensation is wrong.
Thus, getting the new system right and getting over the change period to a point
where people are fully adjusted to and comfortable with the new system is a major
managerial challenge. And we must not be surprised when we find that even people
who will benefit in the new system will end up opposing it (at least initially) for a
variety of these reasons.

F. Lead from the top

Given the complexity of designing a new pay system, as well as the controversy it
inevitably sets off, CEOs will feel a natural desire to hand off leadership for the effort
to the human resources (HR) department. That would be a mistake, and probably a
fatal one. HR has neither the standing, the influence, nor the decision rights to make a
fundamental business change that will have a profound impact on the business
decisions of line managers. And that is exactly the kind of change that I am talking
about: everyone in the organisation will have to shift their thinking about the role and
use of both budgets and incentives. Performance measures will have to be changed,
and the functional form of bonuses will have to be revised. Since these issues are as
politically charged as any within a company, strong CEO leadership is essential. Only
the CEO has the credibility to make the business case for the changes and to rally the
troops behind them.
# Michael C. Jensen, 2003
404 Professional Forum

The CEO should recognise that the new plan will meet with intense resistance,
even at the highest reaches of the organisation. HR cannot be expected to be an
enthusiastic supporter of the new system because almost nothing in the new system
will make the HR departments job easier. To the contrary, life in HR will be tougher
in the new system. The firm will face higher turnover throughout as more risk averse
and less qualified people fight the changes and eventually leave. There are risks to be
taken in redesigning the system and the HR department will not see great payoffs
from rocking the boat.
Some of the strongest objections, I have found, tend to come from the CFO and his
or her team. Finance executives naturally fear that reducing the importance of budget
targets in motivating line managers will make it more difficult to control results and
avoid surprises. It will be up to the CEO to make sure the CFO, not to mention Wall
Street analysts, understands that the new approach will improve the quality of both
the information provided by the line and the incentives provided to managers. And
better information and better incentives will lead to better results. Yes, there may be
greater uncertainty in quarter-to-quarter results as there will no longer be the
incentives to set artificially low targets and then do everything possible to meet
them but the long-run profits will be superior. In effect giving up the illusion of
control that comes from quarterly and annual budget targets will effectively increase
managerial control.
In addition, every major line manager will have to understand the new system and
the theory behind it and be prepared to explain it and defend it against opposition and
opportunism from the ranks. There are no shortcuts through the education process.
Organisations do not change overnight, particularly when the very frame through
which we see the business is involved. Remember, it has taken many years to weave
lying and deceit into the fabric of our businesses; cleansing the fabric will take time
as well.

G. Do not abandon traditional controls completely


Finally, companies should be careful not to put too much emphasis on the new bonus
system. People are incredibly creative and given time and incentives they will find
innovative ways to operate within any new system to make themselves better off. We
must plan for the mistakes we will inevitably make in designing a new system and
leave room to adjust it, and we must have other controls in place to ensure that we do
not inadvertently run off the tracks because we forgot to attend to one or another
detail. Incentives, as powerful as they are, cannot do everything.

8. Restoring reality; restoring integrity

The effects of gaming are pervasive in organisations. They extend well beyond the
internal setting of goals and move towards demeaning the whole organisation. As I
mentioned above, the budget game inevitably gets extended to the firms relationship
with the capital markets as the CEO and CFO become enmeshed in a similar game
with financial analysts over meeting financial targets.25 This is a game that managers
can only lose in the long run and a game that reinforces and exacerbates the internal

25
See for example, Loomis (2001).

# Michael C. Jensen, 2003


Professional Forum 405

managerial budget-target games. Managers can take actions that make it appear that
the company is meeting its targets and analysts expectations, just as they can in their
internal systems. Thus they are almost universally drawn into a short-run game with
the analysts in which they manipulate the numbers to satisfy the markets. This
strategy must fail in the end because every company faces a certain amount of
uncertainty that cannot be controlled. Like a balloon, if you push it down here, it
pops up somewhere else eventually.
The cost of such gaming cannot be measured in numbers alone. As I have pointed
out above, this gaming ultimately erodes the integrity of the entire organisation.
Consistent with the recent lawsuits against Lucent and Xerox by Aversano and
Bingham discussed in Section 4.E, above, Barbara Toffler (1991) describes the issue
well in her excellent article When the signal Is move it or lose it. She quotes an
unnamed executive who describes the move it philosophy as when the boss tells a
subordinate to move it just get it done, meet the deadline, dont ask for more money,
time or people, just do it and so it goes on down the line. That . . . is the heart of
unethical practice in business. Toffler comments: An insidious twist in the move-it
demand is that it allows no challenge. Saying that a command is unrealistic or
impossible is likely to trigger a retort like: Youre paid to get it done, so do it, or
If you cant do it well find somebody who can. Indeed, a decision to stand ones
ground may be tantamount to putting ones job on the line. It should be no surprise
that unethical behaviour creeps in. Most cases of unethical management practice
I have seen occur when basically decent people get caught in the move-it grind . . . For
American companies, this peril from within is as serious as outside threats from
competitors.
Everyone can benefit by bringing this game to an end, and I believe it starts by
eliminating the use of targets in compensation systems, and in particular by eliminat-
ing the use of budgets as targets in compensation systems. Simply put this means
creating linear pay-for-performance compensation systems.

References

Adizes, I. Corporate Lifecycles (Englewood Cliffs, NY: Prentice Hall, 1989, p. 9091).
Baker, G. P., Gibbons, R. S. and Murphy, K. J., Relational contracts and the theory of the
firm. unpublished manuscript (Harvard University, December, 1997).
Bandler, J. and Hechinger, J., Xerox executive challenges its accounting and is fired-query into
Mexican units books snowballs, Asian Wall Street Journal, 6 February 2001.
Bandler, J. and Maremont, M. Seeing red: how ex-accountant added up to trouble for humbled
Xerox, Wall Street Journal, 28 June 2001, p. A1.
Carreyrou, J., Lernout unit booked fictitious sales, says probe, Wall Street Journal, 9 April
2001, p. B2.
Collingwood, H., The earnings game: everyone plays, nobody wins, Harvard Business Review,
2001, pp. 6574.
DeGeorge, F., Patel, J. and Zeckhauser, R., Earnings management to exceed thresholds,
Journal of Business, Vol. 72, no. 1, 1999.
Healy, P. M., The effect of bonus schemes on accounting decisions, Journal of Accounting and
Economics, Vol. 7, 1985, pp. 85107.
Hope, J. and Fraser, R., Beyond budgeting: breaking through the barrier to The Third
wave , Management Accounting, December, 1997.
Hope, J. and Fraser, R., Beyond budgeting white paper, beyond budgeting round table.
(Fraser Hope Associates, CAM-I Consortium for Advanced Manufacturing, International,
1999a).

# Michael C. Jensen, 2003


406 Professional Forum

Hope, J. and Fraser, R., Beyond budgeting: building a new management model for the
information age, Management AccountingLondon 16, 1999b.
Hope, J. and Fraser, R., Beyond budgeting, Strategic Finance, Vol. 30, 1 October 2000.
Hyde, J., Chryslers reward program backfires. The Globe and Mail, 1 May 2001, p. B14.
Jensen, M. C., Value maximization, stakeholder theory, and the corporate objective function,
European Financial Management, Vol. 7, no. 3, September 2001, pp. 297317. In Business
Ethics Quarterly, Vol. 12, no.1, January 2001, and the Journal of Applied Corporate Finance,
Fall 2001. Available from the Social Science Research Network eLibrary at: http://
papers.ssrn.com/paper 220671. An earlier version of this paper appears in Breaking the
Code of Change, Michael Beer and Nithan Norhia, eds, Harvard Business School Press,
2000.
Kersnar, J., Re-inventing the budget, CFO Asia, July/August 1999.
Lester, T., Monday management: managers count blessings as budgets begin to lose currency
some firms long for freedom from the burden of budgeting, Irish Times, 2000.
Locke, E. A., Motivation by goal setting, in R. T. Golembiewski (ed.), Handbook of Organiza-
tional Behavior (New York: Marcel Dekker, 2001).
Locke, E. A. and Latham, G., A Theory of Goal Setting and Task Performance (Englewood
Cliffs NJ: Prentice Hall, 1990).
Loomis, C. J., The 15% delusion, Fortune, 5 February 2001.
Mehta, S. N., Lessons from the Lucent debacle, Fortune, 5 February 2001.
New York Times, Incentive plan hurts Chrysler, 1 May 2001, p. 5.
Roy, D., Goldbricking in a machine shop, American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 57, 1952,
pp. 427442.
Schroeder, M., SEC list of accounting-fraud probes grows, Wall Street Journal, 6 July 2001,
p. C1.
Schweitzer, M., Ordonez, L. and Douma, B., The dark side of goal setting: the role of goals in
motivating behavior, Working Paper (Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania.
Philadelphia, PA, 2001).
Schweitzer, M., Ordonez, L. and Douma, B., The Dark Side of Goal Setting: The Role of
Goals in Motivating Unethical Decision Making. Academy of Management Proceedings, 2002.
Schweitzer, M., Ordonez, L. and Douma, B., The Role of Goal Setting in Motivating Unethi-
cal Behavior. Forthcoming.
Stewart, G. B., Remaking the corporation from within, Harvard Business Review Vol. 68, no. 4,
1990, pp. 126137.
Suhr, J., Chrysler revises dealer quotas, AP Online, 7 May 2001.
Thomas, T., Toss your budget out the window, Business Review Weekly, 8 September 2000.
Toffler, B., When the signal is move it or lose it, New York Times, 17 November 1991.

# Michael C. Jensen, 2003

You might also like