Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation Poole Pract Act
Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation Poole Pract Act
Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation Poole Pract Act
244
an d
Nigel Poole
Market Participation
Smallholder Agriculture
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Smallholder Agriculture
and Market Participation
Praise for this book
Poole swims against the tide of meta-analysis, thematic review and non-
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Market Participation
Nigel Poole
Published by
Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations
and Practical Action Publishing 2017
Practical Action Publishing Ltd
The Schumacher Centre, Bourton on Dunsmore, Rugby, Warwickshire, CV23 9QZ, UK
www.practicalactionpublishing.org
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
FAO, 2017
The authors have asserted their rights under the Copyright Designs and Patents Act 1988 to be
identified as authors of this work. Such assertions shall not be construed as constituting a waiver of
the privileges or immunities of FAO.
All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be commercially reprinted or reproduced or
utilized in any form or by any electronic, mechanical, or other means, now known or hereafter
invented, or in any information storage or retrieval system, without the written permission
of the publishers.
Product or corporate names may be trademarks or registered trademarks, and are used only for
identification and explanation without intent to infringe.
A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library.
A catalogue record for this book has been requested from the Library of Congress.
ISBN 978-1-85339-941-1 Paperback
ISBN 978-1-85339-940-4 Hardback
ISBN 978-1-78044-941-8 ebook
ISBN 978-1-78044-940-1 Library pdf
Citation: Poole, N. (2017) Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation, Rugby, UK: Practical
Action Publishing, <http://dx.doi.org/10.3362/9781780449401>
Since 1974, Practical Action Publishing has published and disseminated books andinformation in
support of international development work throughout the world. Practical Action Publishing is a
trading name of Practical Action Publishing Ltd (CompanyReg. No. 1159018), the wholly owned
publishing company of Practical Action. Practical Action Publishing trades only in support of its
parent charity objectives andany profits are covenanted back to Practical Action (Charity Reg.
No.247257, Group VAT Registration No.880 9924 76).
FAO encourages the use, reproduction and dissemination of material in this information product.
Except where otherwise indicated, material may be copied, downloaded and printed for private
study, research and teaching purposes, or for use in non-commercial products or services, provided
that appropriate acknowledgement of FAO as the source and copyright holder is given and that
FAOs endorsement of users views, products or services isnot implied in any way.
All requests for translation and adaptation rights, and for resale and other commercial use rights
should be addressed to www.fao.org/contact-us/licence-request or to copyright@fao.org.
FAO information products are available on the FAO website (www.fao.org/publications) andcan be
purchased through publications-sales@fao.org
FAO ISBN 978-92-5-109939-1
The designations employed and the presentation of material in this information product do not imply
the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of the Food and Agriculture Organization of
the United Nations (FAO) concerning the legal or development status of any country, territory, city or
area or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its frontiers or boundaries. The mention
of specific companies or products of manufacturers, whether or not these have been patented, does
not imply that these have been endorsed or recommended by FAO in preference to others of a similar
nature that are not mentioned. The views expressed in this information product are those of the
author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of FAO, or of Practical Action Publishing
Ltd or its parent charity Practical Action. Reasonable efforts have been made to publish reliable data
and information, but the authors and publisher cannot assume responsibility for the validity of all
materials or for the consequences of their use.
Contents
About the author ix
Part I
The potential and challenges of smallholder agriculture 1
http://dx.doi.org/10.3362/9781780449401.000
vi Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
Part II
Case studies of smallholder agriculture 115
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Index 193
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
PART I
ofsmallholder agriculture
The potential and challenges
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
CHAPTER 1
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
http://dx.doi.org/10.3362/9781780449401.001
4 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
Economy: Out of the 2.5 billion people in poor countries living directly from the food
and agriculture sector, 1.5 billion people live in smallholder households. Many of those
households are extremely poor: overall, the highest incidence of workers living with their
families below the poverty line is associated with employment in agriculture.
Social: Women comprise an average of 43 per cent of the agricultural labour force of
developing countries up to almost 50 per cent in East and Southeast Asia and sub-Saharan
Africa. Should women farmers have the same access to productive resources as men, they
could increase yields on their farms by 2030 per cent, lifting 100150 million people
out of hunger. Women are the quiet drivers of change towards more sustainable production
systems and a more varied and healthier diet.
Governance: Smallholders provide up to 80 per cent of the food supply in Asia and
sub-Saharan Africa. Their economic viability and contribution to diversified landscape
and culture are threatened by competitive pressure from globalization and integration
into common economic areas; their fate is either to disappear and become purely
self-subsistence producers, or to grow into larger units that can compete with large,
industrialized farms.
Source: summarized from FAO (2012).
Box 1.1 explores some dimensions of the type of farming we are considering.
Smallholder agriculture is most important of all for its contribution to the
food security, nutrition, and health of many poor people:
Small-scale agriculture is the main source of food in the developing
world, producing up to 80 percent of the food consumed in many
developing countries, notably in sub-Saharan Africa and Asia. With poor
rural households making up two-thirds of the global population earning
less than $1.25 per day, smallholder agriculture is also an important
source of income underpinning the livelihoods of vast numbers of poor
people. Smallholders and small family farms are therefore central to an
inclusive development process and their contribution is crucial to food
security (Arias et al., 2013: 6).
The significance of agriculture and the rural economy to poverty reduction
can be illustrated with statistics from the World Banks World Development
Indicators. In developing countries and regions, the rural population is
relatively high, and agriculture accounts for a relatively large but declining
6 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
Table 1.2 Food production and productivity indicators major regions of the world
Food production index Agricultural productivity
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Table 1.3 to be disaggregated by age and gender, the under-fives and adolescent
girls would register significantly.
Digging a little deeper into the data in Table 1.3, it is evident that the
Oceania region including many Small Island Developing States (SIDS)
registers high levels of stunting among children, comparable to the levels
in Africa. It is more surprising to observe the high rates of adult obesity in
the Caribbean and Oceania, which encompass most of the SIDS. These are
comparable to the levels of obesity in many wealthy countries in developed
regions of the world. These data illustrate the phenomenon of the double-
burden of malnutrition, which is under- and over-nutrition. The co-existence
of stunting, micronutrient deficiencies, and adult obesity creates major
challenges for local and global food systems. The linkages between agriculture
and nutrition are currently high on the international research agenda: for
example, in the UK Government-funded research programme Leveraging
Agriculture for Nutrition in South Asia (LANSA, undated). Recent publica-
tions taking a value perspective on the linkages are Devaux et al. (2016) and
Maestre et al. (2017).
Because of its contribution to food supplies and nutrition, smallholder
agriculture is also an important factor supporting social and political stability.
For example, high onion prices in India in 1998 led to the fall of the BJP
government, and continue to act as a bellwether of political tension. Rising
food prices are implicated, among other factors, in fomenting the Arab Spring
(Breisinger et al., 2012). In all countries, food price rises make a significant
contribution to the rate of inflation, to which poor people are most sensitive.
8 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
societies, justice,
5. Achieve gender
accountability
15. Protect, restore, and equality
8. Promote
promote sustainable use of 6. Ensure
economic growth,
terrestrial ecosystems water and
employment
sanitation
1. End poverty
2. End hunger, achieve food security and improved
nutrition, promote sustainable agriculture
3. Ensure healthy lives
Breeding and Market access Intra-household
varietal development distribution
Box 1.2 Livelihoods and ecology in the Sahel region of West Africa
A survey approach was used to examine the contribution to rural livelihoods in Burkina
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Faso of major tree products, derived from baobab (Adansonia digitata), shea (Vitellaria
paradoxa) and nr (Parkia biglobosa). While home-produced cereals constitute the major
part of the peoples diets, tree products make a significant contribution to food security
during the dry soudure season when cereal granaries are empty and the new harvest is
pending. Tree products also served as a mechanism for managing household strategies for
exchange of goods, marketing of products, and managing food consumption through the
seasons. Understanding of the agroecological importance of trees and tree management
was reinforced.
Households were not all the same: rural heterogeneity down to intra-household level is
an important feature of tree product utilization, with variations in tree management and
product utilization depending on human and economic relationships as well as natural
resource endowments.
The complexity of and variation in human relationships was evident at multiple levels
of the Burkinab society: at the community level, where local authorities exercise a degree
of control over natural resources; within the typical compound of households; among men
and women and children within and between the constituent households.
One of the principal implications of this research for enhancing the contribution of trees
to sustainable livelihoods in the Sahel is that conservation and enhancement initiatives
must be tailored to the local context. Implementation must be negotiated according to the
important agroecological, human, and tree specificities, land tenure and fragmentation,
particularly in the more fragile northern part of the country, and, at the same time, address
the gender and age roles of different householders and authority figures, thus exploiting
the potential for sustainable enterprise and greater productivity.
Source: adapted from Poole et al. (2016a)
resources grow and are reallocated among livelihood activities within peoples
households. Recent research in West Africa has emphasized how the people
of the Sahel and their skills are a resource that can be used to manage the
competing claims of sustainable management of a fragile environment and
secure rural livelihoods (Box 1.2).
The changes accompanying these processes involve shifts between
productive sectors and spatial contexts, driven by the initiatives of entre-
preneurs, augmented by external support, and facilitated by incentives from
an external environment which is conducive to productive investment and
returns. Within this broad context, both theory and practice are persuasive
about the role of increasing rural peoples access to remunerative markets for
their products as a mechanism of agricultural development.
and food security (at a local and regional scale), for increasing incomes of
farmers and employees, for enabling and stimulating the supply of agricul-
tural services and goods to rural areas, and for the secondary (agro-industrial)
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Changing contexts
Two recent international reports highlight the immediate and longer-term
challenges. Rural Development Report 2016: Fostering Inclusive Rural
Transformation by the United Nations International Fund for Agricultural
Development (IFAD) draws attention to the rapidly changing global context:
the global economy, rates of urbanization and increasing food demand,
climate change, erratic energy supplies, conflict, and increasing inequality
(IFAD, 2016).
14 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
new market entrants. Moreover, most new entrants lack the skills they need to enter
firms operating at higher levels of productivity and wages. As a result, the overwhelming
majority of young people are destined for employment on farms, rural enterprises or in
the informal sector
Successful adaptation by smallholder farmers could dramatically reduce the risks
posed by climate change. Innovations in water management and irrigation, drought-
resistant seed strains, soil conservation, and new tillage and climate-resilient cropping
patterns could all make a difference. Africas farmers need help from their governments
and the international community in scaling up adaptation
Unlocking the productive potential of Africas farmers would strengthen economic
recovery. It would raise incomes, create jobs, create new markets, open new opportunities
for investment, and link the farm and the rural non-farm economy with other growth
centres.
Source: Africa Progress Panel (2012)
A people perspective
A particular challenge in many contexts is to engage a new generation of
people in agriculture. In Samoa, for example, farming is said to be among the
least valuable of the employment or career opportunities for a young villager,
coming behind migration, trade, and fishing (Angelucci et al., undated).
Theage profile of smallholder farmers is steadily rising in many countries and
Introducing smallholder agriculture 15
regions because young people are leaving rural areas to seek opportunities
elsewhere. Farming can become an attractive profession if smallholder farms
can be transformed into modern businesses. For this, at least three things are
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Commercializing agriculture
Understanding smallholder market participation
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Pure subsistence is very rare, and cash needs for household expenditures
are an almost universal reality. Diversification in patterns of economic
production and capital accumulation are fundamental livelihood strategies
for economic well-being. Thus, almost all people, including smallholder
farmers and the poorest, are linked to markets in the wider non-agricultural
economy. In the first instance, these are markets for consumer goods,
including food. In rural areas, many farmers will source agricultural inputs
such as seeds, implements, and fertilizers from local suppliers, or rent other
agricultural services. Many people in rural contexts are also linked to labour
markets. At the very least, some members of farming households often work
as farm labourers or in secondary enterprises, or migrate out of rural areas to
urban areas or further afield.
A decade ago, the World Banks Development Report on agriculture set the
agenda for commercialization and explored opportunities and weaknesses in
the smallholder context (World Bank, 2007). National governments, inter-
national donors, and non-governmental organizations have adopted the
commercialization narrative. Typical of public statements is the following:
What data are available will be related to the monitoring and evaluation
activities of specific interventions and are generally not easy to find.
Monitoring markets reveals important dynamic patterns in production
and consumption. For example, diets in many countries are shifting towards
higher-value livestock products, fruits, and vegetables. Specific foods are
often perceived to have significant health or other prized attributes. As some
people grow in wealth and learn about nutrition and new products, demand
expands and prices rise, offering new supply opportunities to farmers for
commercial sales. At the same time, food is diverted from poorer consumers
and poorer rural people who are net consumers who can no longer afford
the product. Rural people who cannot produce enough food for their own
Introducing smallholder agriculture 19
Box 1.5 Market dynamics and new opportunities: The case of Ethiopia
Ethiopiais one of the worlds poorest countries, well-known for its precariousfoodsecurity
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
situation. But it is also the native home of teff, a highly nutritious ancient grain increas-
ingly finding its way into health-food shops and supermarkets in Europe and America.
Grown by an estimated6.3 million farmers, fields of the crop cover more than 20%
of all land under cultivation As Western consumers acquire a taste for teff, how to
ensure that Ethiopia and its farmers benefit from new global markets is a critical question.
Growing demand for so-called ancient grains has not always been a straightforward win for
poor communities. InBolivia and Peru, reports of rising incomes owing to the now-global
quinoa trade have come alongside those of malnutritionand conflicts over land as farmers
sell their entire crop to meet western demand.
Ethiopias growing middle class is also pushing up demand for teff,and rising domestic
pricesover the past decade have put the grain out of reach of the poorest. Today, most
small farmers sell the bulk of what they grow to consumers in the city.
This may have helped boost incomes in some rural areas but it has had nutritional
consequences, says the government, as teffis the most nutritionally valuable grain in the
country. Estimates suggest that while those in urban areas eat up to61 kg of teff a year,
in rural areas, the figure is 20 kg. The type consumed differs too: the wealthy almost
exclusively eat the more expensive magna and white teff varieties; less well-off consumers
tend to eat less-valuable red and mixed teff, and more than half combine it with cheaper
cereals such as sorghum and maize.
The governments agricultural transformation agency aims to boost yields by developing
improved varieties of the grain, along with new planting techniques and tools to reduce
post-harvest losses.
David Hallam, former Director of the Trade and Markets Division at the UNs Food
and Agriculture Organization, says that while there is money to be made from new global
markets for traditional crops, governments have to support small-scale producers to ensure
they share the benefits of increased trade.
Typically, these products are going to go through many hands before they reach the
shelves of Sainsburys or wherever. There are [profit] margins at every step, and small
farmers are not necessarily well placed to bargain with the bigger traders, says Hallam,
who sees quinoas popularity as a cautionary tale of how export opportunities can be a
mixed blessing for poor countries.
Regassa Feyissa, an Ethiopian agricultural scientist and former head of the national
Institute for Biodiversity, warns that without careful planning, increased teff production
for export may displace other important crops for farmers. And efforts to boost production
could benefit business interests at the expense of small farmers.
Source: Provost and Jobson (2014)
subsistence and can no longer afford to buy may have to leave the land,
and farming becomes consolidated among less numerous but larger-scale
producers.
Teff (or tef), the staple grain of Ethiopia, is one such health food. A report
by Minten et al. (2013) comments on the changing market characteristics in
Ethiopia. Interventions in such situations can boost the rural economy, and
sometimes even support the struggling smaller farmers. Theauthors outline
ways in which to boost the potential for the teff economy by improving
inputs, technology, and product marketing. Box 1.5 summarizes the new
opportunities in such agricultural markets.
20 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
A wide range of factors affects the extent to which smallholder farmers can
integrate production with commercial markets, as can be seen in Box 1.6.
Household heterogeneity
Due recognition has recently been given to the differences between households,
and warning against development approaches that fail to differentiate
adequately between different household types. The World Banks adoption
of a commercialization narrative for smallholder agriculture in Africa has a
big picture approach to rural policy formulation. This tends to gloss over
inter-household heterogeneity, to say nothing of intra-household heteroge-
neity, that is, the differences within households among men and women,
Introducing smallholder agriculture 21
old and young, high and low status. Rural heterogeneity is understood best
within the small picture of rural household characteristics (Poole et al.,
2013b). Theimportance of analysing the small picture detail, disaggregation,
contextual locality, and particularity is highlighted by Poole et al.
In its seminal World Development Report (WDR) on agriculture, the World
Bank noted that heterogeneity defines the rural world (World Bank, 2007: 5).
Box 1.7 contests this view.
It is not a new thing to stress the importance of disaggregating the
differentcharacteristics of large populations and recognizing diversity.
Barrett (2008) comments on diversity in African smallholder agriculture.
As already noted, most smallholder farm production is for subsistence, but
even households which sell staple grains typically soon after harvest are
net consumers over the year, relying on income from the sale of cash crops
or labour. Nevertheless, there is considerable differentiation and inequality
among smallholder farmers. It is common for there to be a high level of seller
concentration in staple-food product markets which tend to be dominated by
the farmers who are better-endowed in terms of productive assets, technology,
22 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
limited and reductionist. It glosses over the development losers, whose limited assets
and capabilities consign them to exit from agriculture and often from rural life into
probably the lowest echelons of an urban-industrial society. Exit from agriculture
can mean unemployment, social disruption, and urban deprivation within a context of
burgeoning populations, climate change, and resource scarcities.
Thus, the levels of differentiation commonly used are not very local or particular,
reflecting the methodologies of meta-analytical approaches and the growing influence
of thematic reviews. They do not get deep into the hearts and minds of rural household
members. Differentiation and customization are conceived only within the overarching
imperative of commercializing agriculture.
Source: Poole et al. (2013b)
The smallholder households access to, and the productivity of, assets,
including natural resources, labour, and capital, vis--vis their subsistence
needs will determine both their ability and their willingness to increase
production for sale in markets.
The connectivity of smallholders to different markets, which can
be considered in terms of remoteness (defined broadly to include
geographical proximity, knowledge asymmetries, power relationships,
and the costs of commerce, or transaction costs), will modify the
incentives that they receive.
The functionality of these markets. Many local food markets are volatile
because of the low volumes transacted and their limited integration
with regional or international markets, which limits the markets ability
to modify demand- and/or supply-side shocks. Volatility can affect the
level and riskiness of returns to the producer. Where markets are not
well integrated, returns to increased output can diminish quickly as
prices plummet, significantly affecting incentives for market partici-
pation and, consequently, for productivity-enhancing technology
adoption.
Introducing smallholder agriculture 23
While extolling the rates of development in the global South, the United
Nations Human Development Report also draws a distinction between
economic growth and human development progress. The middle class in
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
That people should be central to the processes affecting their lives now
seems obvious. Nevertheless, policymakers too easily make statements that
abstract from the complications of reality. For example, the Government of
Uganda signalled the importance of arable agriculture in promoting the food
security of the pastoralist Karamojong people.
Karamoja has for a long time been buying food from her neighbours,
this is the time to change the trend so that Karamojas neighbours
can rely on her for food, said the [Karamoja Affairs] Minister after
she was impressed by the manyacresof different foods grown
[TheMinister] commended this work saying that if many families
embraced farming on a large scale, Karamoja would get to the desired
level of development. She saluted the families who have tirelessly
worked in the fields to grow food to feed their families and urged them
Introducing smallholder agriculture 25
to produce more so that they can remain food secure throughout the
year and even have surplus for sale (ChimpReports, 2013).
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
However, the plan to make every household cultivate arable crops in a garden
has been criticized by many development authorities for failing to consider
the social, economic, and agroecological contexts and involving the people
themselves in determining their livelihood strategies (IRIN, 2014).
Thus, voice and choice both matter in identifying and prioritizing
problems, and in the planning and implementation of agricultural
development and market participation policies. Credence has to be given
to the complexities of household management: smallholders will not
respond automatically to initiatives to promote agricultural commerciali
zation. Aswell as policy incentives, the local context, individual characte
ristics, and the opportunities and threats of the external environment
affect smallholder choices:
objective per se, and may contribute to higher-level objectives such as poverty
reduction. The needs of the poorest smallholders are probably best met by
creating jobs, building their assets, improving their health and education, and
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
in providing social protection. Market links will not provide multiple wins
(Wiggins and Keats, 2013: ix).
The complexity and interrelatedness of the new SDGs has been referred
to already: the potential synergies and conflicts between the goals will create
numerous policy dilemmas and require careful examination of the outcomes
of interventions across sectors in ways to which development specialists are
not accustomed. For example, boosting agricultural growth may adversely
affect resource management and climate change; promoting female partici-
pation in the agricultural economy may adversely affect girls education and
household caring practices. Many other conflicts and trade-offs are plausible,
giving rise to considerable governance challenges (Waage et al., 2015).
What then are the scope and limitations of improving smallholders access
to markets, of agricultural development? What also are the necessary accom-
panying approaches? What we have is a tension between two propositions.
First, we agree that there are multiplier effects of agricultural development on
broader processes; one strategy can have wide impacts, as shown in Figure 1.3
which makes explicit the connections between agricultural development and
wider development processes.
Second, we face the reality that addressing even one high-level goal requires
multiple approaches. Agricultural development depends on a range of other
factors (Figure 1.4).
If addressing such goals requires multiple and integrated strategies,
aspirations for what can be achieved by increasing smallholder participation
in agricultural market development must be limited, rather than resolving
all development problems. Thus, the impact of specific and focused actions
to improve smallholders market access should not be judged by the wider
impact on overall poverty reduction and other SDGs.
Incomes and
employment
Sustainable
Agricultural
resources
development
management
Exports
Economic
restructuring
Figure 1.3 Agricultures contribution to other sectors, activities, and policies
Introducing smallholder agriculture 27
Health and
education policies
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Agricultural
input supplies
Knowledge Agricultural
management development
Trade and
market policies
Environment and
natural resources
Figure 1.4 Agricultures dependence on other sectors, activities, and policies
A note on terminology
We have noted that there are goals, trade-offs, conflicts, constraints, and
priorities in the political processes that affect the expectations and achieve-
ments of policies and approaches to improving market access. A common
understanding of these concepts will help the subsequent analyses and
discussions. This is how these terms will be used:
Objective. A desired state that can be, inter alia, human, natural,
economic, or technological and can range within a hierarchy from the
low level, specific, and small scale to high level, large in scale and
scope.
Goal. A high-level objective, usually long term in nature and large in
scale and scope.
Target. A low- or intermediate-level objective that may be short to
medium term and which contributes to achieving a goal.
Indicator. A measurable phenomenon enabling assessment of progress
towards reaching a target.
Policy. A defined and coherent programme formulated to achieve an
objective, usually medium to long term, with a set of specified actions
and activities.
Approach. The conceptual development and empirical experience which
together constitute a theory of change and the evidence base for a
particular policy formulation.
Intervention. A project, action, or activity of an agency (public, private,
third sector) external to the targeted beneficiaries, undertaken as part of
a policy formulated to achieve an objective.
Initiative. A project, action, or activity which arises from within or
among beneficiary organizations and individuals.
Instrument. The specific mechanism, means, and methods whereby an
intervention or initiative is implemented.
through which the upwards escalation of impacts and effects are, or should
be, mediated are usually not clearly articulated. It is important to make these
connections in order to understand how escalation of local development
outcomes may (fail to) contribute to higher level objectives.
References
Africa Progress Panel (2012). Jobs, Justice and Equity: Seizing opportunities in
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
times of global change. Africa Progress Report 2012. Retrieved 28 March 2017,
fromhttp://www.africaprogresspanel.org/publications/policy-papers/africa-
progress-report-2012/.
Amrouk, E.M., Poole, N.D., Mudungwe, N. and Muzvondiwa, E. (2013).
TheImpact of Commodity Development Projects on Smallholders Market Access
in Developing Countries: Case studies of FAO/CFC Projects. Rome, United
Nations Food and Agriculture Organization. Retrieved 28 March 2017,
from http://www.fao.org/docrep/017/aq290e/aq290e.pdf.
Angelucci, F., Cafiero, C. and Malua, M. (undated). A Supply Chain Finance
and Risk Management Scheme for Addressing Financial Needs and Constraints
to Smallholders Participation in Samoan Fruits and Vegetables Value Chains.
Rome, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations.
Arias, P., Hallam, D., Krivonos, E. and Morrison, J. (2013). Smallholder Integration
in Changing Food Markets. Rome, Food and Agriculture Organization of
the United Nations. Retrieved 28 March 2017, from http://www.fao.org/
docrep/018/i3292e/i3292e.pdf.
Barrett, C.B. (2008). Smallholder market participation: concepts and evidence
from eastern and southern Africa. Food Policy 33(4): 299317 <http://dx.doi.
org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2007.10.005>.
Berdegu, J.A. and Fuentealba, R. (2011). Latin America: The state of
smallholders in agriculture. IFAD Conference on New Directions for
Smallholder Agriculture. Rome, International Fund for Agricultural
Development.
Breisinger, C., Ecker, O., Al Riffai, P. and Yu, B. (2012). Beyond the Arab
Awakening: Policies and investments for poverty reduction and food security.
Washington, DC, International Food Policy Research Institute. Retrieved
28 March 2017, from http://www.ifpri.org/sites/default/files/publications/
pr25.pdf.
ChimpReports (2013). Janet moves to reverse Karamojas worsening
hunger. Retrieved 22 May 2017, from http://www.chimpreports.com/
14024-janet-moves-to-reverse-karamojas-worsening-hunger/.
Devaux, A., Torero, M., Donovan, J. and Horton, D., eds, (2016). Innovation
for Inclusive Value Chain Development: Successes and challenges. Washington,
DC, International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI).
FAO (2012). Smallholders and Family Farmers. Retrieved 28 March 2017, from
http://www.fao.org/fileadmin/templates/nr/sustainability_pathways/docs/
Factsheet_SMALLHOLDERS.pdf.
FAO (2013). The State of Food and Agriculture 2013: Food systems for better
nutrition. Rome, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United
Nations. Retrieved 28 March 2017, from http://www.fao.org/publications/
sofa/2013/en/.
FAO (2016). The State of Food and Agriculture 2016: Climate change, agriculture
and food Security. Rome, FAO. Retrieved 02 November 2016, from http://
www.fao.org/3/a-i6030e.pdf.
FAO (undated). All ACP Agricultural Commodities Programme. Retrieved
27April 2017, from http://www.fao.org/economic/EST/AAACP/en/.
32 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
agriculture and nutrition policies and practice: evidence from Afghanistan. LANSA
Working Paper Number 9. Chennai, India, Leveraging Agriculture for
Nutrition in South Asia (LANSA), MS Swaminathan Research Foundation.
Retrieved 07 April 2017, from https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/
media/5963972ee5274a0a59000157/Mapping_stakeholder_perceptions__
Afghanistan_on_template_0.pdf.
Pritchard, B., Rammohan, A., Sekher, M., Parasuraman, S. and Choitani, C.
(2014). Feeding India: Livelihoods, entitlement and capabilities. Abingdon, UK,
Routledge.
Provost, C. and Jobson, E. (2014). Move over quinoa, Ethiopias teff poised
to be next big super grain. The Guardian. Retrieved 28 March 2017, from
http://www.theguardian.com/global-development/2014/jan/23/quinoa-
ethiopia-teff-super-grain.
Rogers, T.S., Morrison, J.A. and Bammann, H. (2010). Agriculture for Growth:
Learning from experience in the Pacific. Summary results of five country studies in
Fiji, Samoa, Solomon Islands, Tonga and Vanuatu. EU-AAACP Paper. Rome, Food
and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations. Retrieved 28March
2017, from http://www.fao.org/docrep/013/am011e/am011e00.pdf.
Rosset, P.M. and Martnez-Torres, M.E. (2012). Rural social movements and
agroecology: context, theory, and process. Ecology and Society 17(3): C717
<http://dx.doi.org/10.5751/ES-05000-170317>.
Sen, A. (1981). Poverty and Famines: An essay on entitlements and deprivation.
Oxford, UK, Clarendon.
Sutherland, P.D. (2013). Migration is development: how migration matters
to the post-2015 debate. Migration and Development 2(2): 151156 <http://
dx.doi.org/10.1080/21632324.2013.817763>.
United Nations (2013). Human Development Report 2013. The Rise of the South:
Human progress in a diverse world. New York, United Nations Development
Programme. Retrieved 28 March 2017, from http://hdr.undp.org/
en/2013-report.
UN-DESA (undated). UN Sustainable Development Knowledge Platform.
United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs. Retrieved
27 April 2017 from https://sustainabledevelopment.un.org/index.php?
menu=1300.
United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs (undated). UN
Sustainable Development Knowledge Platform. Retrieved 27 April 2017
from https://sustainabledevelopment.un.org/index.php?menu=1300.
Waage, J. and Yap, C., eds, (2015). Thinking Beyond Sectors for Sustainable
Development. London, Ubiquity Press.
Waage, J., Dangour, A.D., Hawkesworth, S., Johnston, D., Lock, K., Poole,
N.D., Rushton, J. and Uauy, R. (2011). Understanding and Improving the
Relationship between Agriculture and Health. A review commissioned as part
of the UK Governments Foresight Project on Global Food and Farming
Futures. London, The Government Office for Science. Retrieved 22 January
2016, from http://www.lcirah.ac.uk/_assets/Foresight%20Report%20
Agriculture%20and%20Health%20review.PDF.
34 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
Waage, J., Yap, C., Bell, S., Levy, C., Mace, G., Pegram, T., Unterhalter, E.,
Dasandi, N., Hudson, D., Kock, R., Mayhew, S., Marx, C. and Poole, N.
(2015). Governing Sustainable Development Goals: interactions, infra-
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Policy approaches
and theoretical considerations
This chapter discusses the evolution of policies and approaches to agricultural
development in recent decades. We introduce theory and literature relevant to
smallholder farming; understanding how households and individuals behave is key to
stimulating peoples own initiatives and in designing and implementing development
policies to improve livelihoods. The costs and benefits of engaging in markets to
boost development are an important determinant of behaviour, as are the assets
and attributes that each individual and household can make use of. The chapter
closes by introducing the concept of the value chain as a development paradigm
for promoting markets and development, and the particular implications for partici-
pation of smallholder farmers.
http://dx.doi.org/10.3362/9781780449401.002
36 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
Market liberalization
The period of structural adjustment through fiscal austerity, privatization,
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
institutional structures and conduct, poor people will be able to benefit from
engagement in such markets.
In diagnosing market imperfection and designing potential interven-
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
tions, the M4P analysis is highly applied, and the intervention approach is
somewhat mechanistic, inasmuch as the actual characterization and selection
of target groups (diagnosis of the poor and their context) is rudimentary
(see Box 2.1): market rather than household- or people-focused. It suggests
a range of tools socio-economic studies, census data, poverty assessments,
livelihoods analysis, investment climate surveys, competitiveness analysis,
drivers of change (The Springfield Centre, 2008: 28) but does not use the
range of disciplinary approaches necessary to understand peoples attitudes,
aspirations, and vulnerabilities.
While M4P envisages commercial interventions and is pro-competitive
structures, it is weak in the policy dimension and draws back from
advocating innovative public-policy interventions and radical restructuring
Systemic constraints
Farmers are most likely to turn to retailers for information as they are most widespread
and accessible
Retailers tend to push products to maximize their own modest income; they do not see
themselves as a source of information
Retailers buy their supplies from large-input suppliers, who also provide them with
information and support, but only about their own products
Input suppliers have the capacity and incentive to support retailers to become more
effective sources of information: satisfied farmers are good for business
Intervention focus
Institutional innovation
Agreeing with Barretts view that The primary theme in the literature on
smallholder market participation is the importance of transactions costs
(2008: 310), Poole and de Frece (2010) suggest that often it is small-scale
institutional innovations in local market organization that serve best to
stimulate smallholder participation in input and output markets: institu
tional innovation is needed in respect of new rules of the game and
also new types of organization, i.e. new players in the game. So, too, are
specific investments in human and social capital, and business and market
organization: new ways of organizing both people and markets to work for
the poor.
It is interesting that, after decades of underperformance, there is a resurgence
of interest in farmer organizations. Box 2.2 outlines the arguments in favour
of collective organizations.
Challenged by the Millennium Development Goals, policymakers turned
to value chain approaches, the delivery of specific business services, and the
facilitation of wider enabling environments that might make market systems
and chains work better for the poorest (Poole, 2010). Value chains will still
POLICY APPROACHES AND THEORETICAL CONSIDERATIONS 41
Box 2.2 Collective organization: Can it contribute to more equitable and efficient markets?
There are theoretical explanations of the failures of collective organisation but, at
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
the same time, the fundamental reasons for collaborating hold true: the potential for
exploiting production and managerial economies of scale, overcoming market entry
barriers, reducing transaction costs, and cultivating supply chain relationships. Collective
decision making may be cumbersome, and top-down decision making may be undesirable.
But new forms of collective enterprise illustrate that innovative business models can
work: new generation cooperatives may provide solutions to some of the historical
andstructural problems of cooperatives. There are alternative management structuresand
financial resources either philanthropic support; or external equity investment with a
capacity to exert leverage through management building; or invitations to bondholders
with a financial stake but without governance rights. These strategies offer the possibility
of external capitalisation without diluting membership control.
Despite a history of operational failure, statutory arrangements such as levies and
marketing boards are also mechanisms with potential to overcome market failures and the
provision of public goods
The approach of external supporting organisations must be patient and realistic.
Collective enterprise may not always work because usually there are threshold levels of
asset requirements and of external support for successful group formation and operation.
It is clear that collective enterprises are organic: they learn and grow, sometimes fail,
and sometimes need to rise from the ashes of incompetence and corruption. The path
to maturity is usually long, and needs supportive investment through a range of planned
and sequenced business services, with an exit strategy emplaced to ensure progress
towards sustainability. And there is no one size-fits all, and no guarantee that individual
successes can be upscaled and replicated
Modelling insights
In the theoretical understanding of household behaviour, there is firstly a
unitarymodel whereby the household is considered to be a single decision-
making unit led by a dominant and sometimes benevolent male(Becker, 1976).
This is associated with the work of Becker and Mincer in the 1960s and 1970s,
is consistent with the concept of a single welfare function, and gave rise
to the New Home Economics. In the unitary model, economic efficiency
concerns revolve around maximizing benefits for the household overall, by
making investments with the best returns. Equity issues are those which affect,
for example, distribution of benefits among children: First, parents may be
interested in ensuring that all children are equally well off. Alternatively, they
may have preferences for particular children; for example, boys over girls,
firstborn over latter born, their own children over those whom they raise as
foster children (Haddad et al., 1997: 4).
POLICY APPROACHES AND THEORETICAL CONSIDERATIONS 43
male household head, vis--vis the adult women in the household. In termsof
negotiating power, aranking of adult women, or more specifically of wives
ofthe male household head, can be expected to affect distributional outcomes
for sub-households (lemnage) concerning access to and quality of land for
agriculture (principally staple grain production), and rights to the grain store
of the male household head.
Within the Sahel, different household endowments in terms of social and
human capital, notably labour, land quantity and quality, and rainfall, are
likely to give rise to different patterns of entitlements and decision making.
The influences arising from the external environment are likely to be highly
significant. The following changes are likely to impact rural household
management dynamics:
differences already mentioned generate transaction and other costs, plus risk,
such that idiosyncratic obstacles are superimposed on the systemic challenges
of accessing markets.
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Transaction costs
The role of institutions and transaction costs
A digression on institutions and transaction costs is important here. Theintro-
duction to economics of the study of transactions is attributed to the US
political economist John R. Commons. In the tradition of the American
Institutionalists analysing collective action, Commons was searching for an
economic theory of the part played by collective action in the control of
individual action. The three constituents of collective action were, hebelieved,
conflict, dependence, and order. The unit of investigation that would encompass
these three constituents was the transaction: so I made the transaction the
ultimate unit of economic investigation, a unit of transfer of legal control
(Commons, 1934: 4).
46 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
most aspects of the emerging neoclassical school and, above all, the behavioural
assumptions associated with the notion of Rational Economic Man.
The fundamentals of OIE concern the organization and control of the
economic system. The forces governing economic outcomes were regarded as
mediated not first and foremost through the price mechanism, but through
power relations, legal rights, and the role of the polity. The operation of
theprice mechanism was not disputed but institutions were held to supersede
prices in importance: It is simply not true that scarce resources are allocated
among alternative uses by the market The real determinant of whatever
allocation occurs in any society is the organizational structure of that
society in short, its institutions (Ayres, 1957: 26). Ayres, among others,
was negative about the allocative role of institutions in economic activity,
whereas Commons was more positive: institutions could promote economic
development and well-being. In the aftermath of the Second World War, insti-
tutionalism gave way before the neoclassical renaissance which became the
mainstream paradigm.
Nevertheless, the significance of institutions in influencing markets
persisted, not least in Coases influential 1937 and 1960 papers (Coase, 1937,
1960). Coase was primarily interested in the organization of the firm, but
his comments on marketing costs gave rise to the notion of transaction
costs in addition to production costs of doing business. Arising out of this
work, New Institutional Economics (NIE) and particularly the Transaction
Cost Economics (TCE) branch was concerned with the organization and
development of economic activity, of contractual arrangements between firms.
Although Williamson traced the origins of TCE to the 1930s (Williamson, 1975),
NIE derives its concern with transaction costs, and little else, from the OIE of
Commons et al. Seminal contributions have been made to the development of
NIE by many other writers.
Williamsons definition of the transaction serves as a first approximation:
a transaction occurs when a good or service is transferred across a technologi-
cally separable interface. One stage of activity terminates and another begins
(Williamson, 1985: 1). Marion identifies four transaction elements (Marion
and NC117 Committee, 1986):
making the deal;
transfer of ownership;
establishing a price;
physical delivery of the product to the buyer.
Farmers costs
We have much more to learn about transaction costs. For example, Zanello
et al. (2014) analysed transaction costs in farmers market decision making
in Ghana using a distinction between different types of transaction costs
introduced by Key et al. (2000) and Bellemare and Barrett (2006):
Proportional transaction costs are transaction costs that vary with the
quantity traded. Often they are associated with the unit transport costs or
the time required to make a sale. Fixed transaction costs are independent
of the quantity traded and include the costs of seeking information on
prices, costs of setting up a sale transaction and monitoring costs (that is,
costs to ensure that the conditions of an exchange are met, for example
enforcing the payment schedule) (Zanello et al., 2014: 1227).
of access to market with transaction costs. Admittedly, Coase (1937) did not
use the term transaction costs, but marketing costs but it is unhelpful
when Barrett writes that The transactions costs that have attracted most
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
attention by analysts are those associated with transport (Barrett, 2008: 310).
Ownership, or lack, of a means of transport to market donkey cart, bicycle,
motorbike, pickup truck is an important determinant of the ease of doing
business, but is conceptually distinct from managing the uncertainty that
is the root of transaction costs. In Norths terms, transport costs are trans-
formation costs or more commonly production costs rather than
transaction costs, and must be addressed by quite different sorts of inter-
vention and initiatives.
Overall, reducing transaction costs is a key focus for policy intervention.
Inaddition, interventions have been aimed at:
Farm level:
Market level:
Livelihoods assets
Natural assets:
Human assets:
Social assets:
Physical assets:
access to credit;
income benefit from product sales;
access to longer-term investments.
At the simplest level, it could be the switch from subsistence food production
to commercial production. What is the opportunity cost of the project
activity? How has the relationship between subsistence/food prices and
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
prices of the new commercial products evolved? The demand for labour is
animportant element in the shift towards more intensive production of
higher-value products. Similarly, the increased cost of inputs and technology
for higher-value production will affect borrowing requirements, cash flows,
and other household spending decisions. There is a generational perspective
to the trade-offs: for example, children can be asked or compelled to work
in order to bring in immediate financial assets, or sent to school to enhance
long-term social capital.
Convertibility. Guyer (1997) also points out that assets are multifaceted; that is,
they can be put to more than one use. In addition, assets are also convertible,
financial assets being the most fungible: quickly convertible, for example, into
physical capital (equipment and housing), natural capital (land and livestock),
social capital (gifts and prestige goods), and more slowly convertible into human
capital through education. But financial assets are also the most vulnerable to
rapid depletion (loss of cash, loss of access to credit).
Asset erosion. It is possible that small producers are left impoverished from
shocks. Vulnerability and risk are critical factors which can lead to asset erosion.
Apart from household affairs like illness, accidents, and death, there are natural
disasters like floods and drought that can impact severely on thehousehold
economy. It maybe through individual misjudgements or unwise development
initiatives that farmers take credit that they cannot repay; maybe the market
collapses and the investments made in new opportunities become sunk costs,
i.e. costs that cannot be recovered. Investment by farmers in crop insurance is a
mechanism for avoiding massive losses by making relatively small expenditures
that in the best circumstances will not be recovered at least financially
but will reduce household vulnerability. Specific culture in the ethnographic
sense can be conceived of as an asset that confers stability and coherence, as
for example in ethnic-minority communities (Poole et al., 2013a). Cultural
change can erodesuch cultural capital. But cultural change can also build other
assets: adecline in traditional mores may erode social stability and investment
in female seclusion and consequent investment in marriage, butalso offer
new forms of investment, for example through girls education and female
employment even engagement in agribusiness marketing.
organizations such as cooperatives are likely to take longer, say five years
or more, and therefore is not likely to be observable. Economic or business
sustainability will be significantly dependent on the external environment
over which smallholders have no control.
Upgrading
Market functions
Primary
Actor assets,
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
supply
capabilities and
empowerment
External
environment
Institutions and
regulations
public, NGO
Chain governance and private
Lead firms sectors
Intra-chain Incentives and
Market power linkages constraints
Entry conditions
Distribution of
risks and rewards
a value chain comprises the linkages between actors and the flows of
products, services, resources and information among economic actors:
households, firms and other organizations such as cooperatives
Key features of value chain research are analyses of:
dimension.
Setting systems boundaries for value chain research has been necessary
to limit analysis to tractable questions and feasible empirics, and, conse-
quently, analyses have commonly been case studies, centred on business
dyads rather than whole chains. Thus, whole chain analyses have been
few. The study reported in IFPRI (2010) may be theacme of value chain
analyses, but employed a level of resources that would be unimaginable to
most researchers.
outcomes for the poor and the rich, the underfed and overfed,
developing and advanced economies, and cross-cutting contexts where
all these dimensions may coexist.
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Chains are pathways through more general and enduring market systems.
They may come and go but rarely stay the same, and dynamic analyses are also
necessary, especially in fast-evolving consumer markets. Much research and
value chain analyses are no exception adopts a static case-study approach.
Research needs to capture the dynamic nature of markets: not just inter-
vention impacts over months, but changing supply and demand conditions
over years.
Returning to themes that are central to this book, on upgrading and
inclusion, three initial considerations must be made explicit: firstly, is partici-
pation in commercial markets always a desirable objective? Secondly, can
upgrading have the perverse effect of raising entry barriers and excluding the
poor whose improvement is being targeted? Questions of equality and gender
underlie this preoccupation. And thirdly, note that a given chain may be less
important to the actors themselves than to the keen researchers; peoples
livelihoods are diverse, and thus a given chain may be only one in a portfolio
of activities. Livelihood context matters.
This book follows two recent value chain publications and, it is hoped,
adds helpfully to the growing literature rather than duplicates existing efforts.
In their recent volume, Coles and Mitchell (2011: 15) set out an immodest
agenda: This book seeks to address one of the most intractable contemporary
development challenges what can the billion poorest people do to improve
their livelihoods and join the trend of rising prosperity in the developing
world? The answer given is, upgrading their position in a range of natural
resource-based value chains.
The other book is a synthesis, edited by the Overseas Development
Institute, London, of research that has emerged from a programme of the
International Development Research Centre, Canada, that aimed to integrate
poverty, gender, and environmental concerns into value chain research and
increase incomes for the rural poor in a sustainable manner. The research was
undertaken between 2007 and 2009, in South and East Asia (India, Nepal,
Vietnam, and the Philippines) and sub-Saharan Africa (Mali, Tanzania, and
Senegal), drawing on the experiences of farmers, development workers, and
policymakers from the South.
58 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
Upgrading
Different types of upgrading are commonly recognized: horizontal and vertical
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
The concluding chapter claims that our approach has been intensely
practical this book examines research-based evidence for the effectiveness of
upgrading interventions (Coles et al., 2011: pp. 2367). Itadds usefullytothe
theoretical literature on value chain analysis, but less on experiences of value
chain interventions. Perhaps the cases are little more than typical market
development interventions. One might have expected more on thecritical
role of human capacity building and on empowerment, which ismentioned
in a couple of places but tangentially, or apparently as an afterthought on
gender, but not as a fundamental element of the framework.
market alternatives, lack of finance, and small scale. Donors and NGOs may
intervene through narrowly defined projects at specific points in the value
chain but often ignore these wider partnership constraints. Second, having
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
achieved some measure of improved participation, the authors note that the
literature pays surprisingly little attention to issues of upscaling (Helmsing
and Vellema, 2011: 16).
Developing an integrative framework, rather than using a singular
(economic) conception of what a value chain is, allows diverse researchers
to reveal the different meanings and incentives found in local communities.
Aligning the incentives arising from alternative understandings is necessary to
formulate favourable conditions of participation for vulnerable groups and
hence poverty reduction.
Much literature on value chains has not moved beyond case studies. In its
conceptualization, this book does. The multidisciplinary approach has yielded
important insights (something that this author has signalled elsewhere; Poole
et al., 2013b). Measured against the framework introduced above, there is
much work still to be done, and that is as it should be.
References
Abebe, G.K., Bijman, J., Kemp, R., Omta, O. and Tsegaye, A. (2013).
Contract farming configuration: smallholders preferences for contract
design attributes. Food Policy 40: 1424 <http://doi.org/10.1016/
j.foodpol.2013.01.002>.
Ayres, C.E. (1957). Institutional economics: discussion. American Economic
Review 47: 2627.
Barrett, C.B. (2008). Smallholder market participation: concepts and evidence
from eastern and southern Africa. Food Policy 33(4): 299317 <http://doi.
org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2007.10.005>.
Bayudan-Dacuycuy, C. (2013). The influence of living with parents on
womens decision-making participation in the household: evidence from
the Southern Philippines. Journal of Development Studies 49(5): 641656
<http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00220388.2012.682987>.
Bebbington, A. (1999). Capitals and capabilities: a framework for analyzing
peasant viability, rural livelihoods and poverty. World Development 27(12):
20212044 <https://doi.org/10.1016/S0305-750X(99)00104-7>.
Becker, G.S. (1976). Altruism, egoism, and genetic fitness: economics and
sociobiology. Journal of Economic Literature 14(3): 817826.
Bellemare, M. and Barrett, C.B. (2006). An ordered tobit model of market partici-
pation: evidence from Kenya and Ethiopia. American Journal of Agricultural
Economics 88: 324337 <http://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8276.2006.00861.x>.
POLICY APPROACHES AND THEORETICAL CONSIDERATIONS 61
Dorward, A.R. and Poole, N.D. (2004). Functioning of Markets and the Livelihoods
of the Poor. Making Markets Work Better for the Poor. Proceedings of the
Inception Workshop, November 2003. Hanoi, Asian Development Bank.
Doss, C. (2013). Intrahousehold bargaining and resource allocation in
developing countries. World Bank Research Observer 28(1): 5278.
Gereffi, G. and Korzeniewicz, M., eds (1994). Commodity Chains and Global
Capitalism. Westport, CT, Greenwood Press.
Gibbon, P. (2001). Upgrading primary production: a global commodity chain
approach. World Development 29(2): 345363 <https://doi.org/10.1016/
S0305-750X(00)00093-0>.
Gibbon, P. (2003). The African Growth and Opportunity Act and the global
commodity chain for clothing. World Development 31(1): 18091827
<https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2003.06.002>.
Griffon, M., ed. (1989). Economie des filires en rgions chaudes. Formation des
prix et changes agricoles. Actes du Xeme sminaire dconomie et de sociologie,
1115 septembre. Montpellier, France, CIRAD.
Grossbard, S. (2010). Independent Individual Decision-Makers in Household
Models and the New Home Economics. IZA Discussion Paper No. 5138. Bonn,
Germany.
Guyer, J.L. (1997). Endowments and assets: the anthropology of wealth and
the economics of intrahousehold allocation, in L. Haddad, J. Hoddinott
and H. Alderman, eds, Intrahousehold Resource Allocation in Developing
Countries: Models, methods, and policy, pp. 112125. Baltimore and London,
Johns Hopkins University Press.
Haddad, L., Hoddinott, J. and Alderman, H., eds (1997). Intrahousehold Resource
Allocation in Developing Countries: Models, methods, and policy. Baltimore and
London, Johns Hopkins University Press.
Hall, P.A. and Soskice, D. (2001). Varieties of Capitalism: the institutional
foundations of comparative advantage. Oxford, OUP.
Harper, M., Belt, J. and Roy, R., eds (2015). Commercial and Inclusive Value
Chains. Rugby, UK, Practical Action Publishing.
Hawkes, C. (2009). Identifying innovative interventions to promote healthy
eating using consumption-oriented food supply chain analysis. Journal
of Hunger & Environmental Nutrition 4(3/4): 336356 <http://dx.doi.org/
10.1080/19320240903321243>.
Helmsing, A.H.J. and Vellema, S., eds (2011). Value Chains, Social Inclusion and
Economic Development: Contrasting theories and realities. London, Routledge.
Humphrey, J. (2005). Shaping Value Chains for Development: Global value chains
in agribusiness. Eschborn, Germany, GTZ.
IFAD (2016). Rural Development Report 2016: Fostering inclusive rural
Transformation. Rome, United Nations International Fund for Agricultural
Development. Retrieved 28 March 2017, from https://www.ifad.org/
ruraldevelopmentreport.
IFPRI (2010). Pulses Value Chain in Ethiopia: Constraints and opportunities for
enhancing exports. Working Paper. Washington DC, International Food
Policy Research Institute (IFPRI).
POLICY APPROACHES AND THEORETICAL CONSIDERATIONS 63
Kaplinsky, R. (2000). Spreading the gains from globalisation: what can be learned
from value chain analysis. IDS Working Paper No. 10. Brighton, Institute of
Development Studies.
Key, N., Sadoulet, E. and de Janvry, A. (2000). Transactions costs and agricul-
tural household supply response. American Journal of Agricultural Economics
82: 245259 <https://doi.org/10.1111/0002-9092.00022>.
Li, L. and Wu, X. (2011). Gender of children, bargaining power, and intra-
household resource allocation in China. Journal of Human Resources 46(2):
295316 <http://dx.doi.org/10.3368/jhr.46.2.295>.
Lundberg, S., Romich, J.L. and Tsang, K.P. (2009). Decision-making by children.
Review of Economics of the Household 7(1): 130 <http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/
s11150-008-9045-2>.
Marion, B.W. and NC117 Committee (1986). The Organization and Performance
of the US Food System. Lexington, MA, Lexington Books.
Morrison, J.A. (2010). Brief guide prepared in support of capacity development
workshops on the implementation and use of value chain studies approaches for
policy analysis. Rome, UN Food and Agriculture Organization.
North, D.C. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance.
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Poole, N.D. (2010). From marketing systems to value chains: what havewe
learnt since the post-colonial era and where do we go? In H. van Trijp and
P. Ingenbleek, eds, Markets, Marketing and Developing Countries: Where we
stand and where we are heading, pp 1822. Wageningen, the Netherlands,
Wageningen Academic Publishers.
Poole, N.D. (2013). Value chain perspectives and literature: a review. Food
Chain 3(3): 199211 <https://doi.org/10.3362/2046-1887.2013.019>.
Poole, N.D. and de Frece, A. (2010). A Review of Existing Organisational Forms of
Smallholder Farmers Associations and their Contractual Relationships with other
Market Participants in the East and Southern African ACP Region. EU-AAACP
Paper Series. No. 11. Rome, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United
Nations. Retrieved 28 March 2017, from http://www.fao.org/fileadmin/
templates/est/AAACP/eastafrica/FAO_AAACP_Paper_Series_No_11_1_.pdf.
Poole, N.D. and Donovan, J. (2014). Building cooperative capacity: the
speciality coffee sector in Nicaragua. Journal of Agribusiness in Developing
and Emerging Economies 4(2): 133156 <http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/
JADEE-01-2013-0002>.
Poole, N.D., Alvarez, F., Vazquez, R. and Penagos, N. (2013a). Education for
all and for what? Life-skills and livelihoods in rural communities. Journal
of Agribusiness in Developing and Emerging Economies 3(1): 6478 <http://
dx.doi.org/10.1108/20440831311321656>.
Poole, N.D., Chitundu, M. and Msoni, R. (2013b). Commercialisation: a
meta-approach for agricultural development among smallholder farmers
in Africa? Food Policy 41(August): 155165 <https://doi.org/10.1016/
j.foodpol.2013.05.010>.
Porter, M.E. (1985). Competitive Advantage: Creating and sustaining superior
performance. New York, Macmillan.
64 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
Porter, M.E. (1990). The Competitive Advantage of Nations. New York, Macmillan.
Raikes, P., Jensen, M.F. and Ponte, S. (2000). Global commodity chain analysis
and the French filire approach: comparison and critique. Economy and
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Financial services
for agricultural smallholders
This chapter discusses finance, which is one of the biggest barriers for smallholder
farmers wishing to engage in markets. On the one hand, farmers can easily fall into
debt; on the other, it is difficult for farmers to access financial capital to expand
production and marketing. The chapter reviews diverse and innovative forms of
financing that can improve services in many circumstances.
The transaction costs introduced in Chapter 2 are found to be significant in the
delivery of financial services. We deepen the discussion of the behavioural features
of financial markets at the heart of which are informational problems: lack of good
information increases financial risks. The chapter concludes with a discussion of
agricultural development strategies that can link credit provision with the delivery
ofother forms of market development support in ways that reduce risks for lenders and
stimulate agricultural production and marketing. A final caveat is that implanting
sustainable models of integrated agricultural development services can take years.
Background
The role of finance
Looking back to the early post-colonial era of the 1950s and 1960s, many inter-
national organizations and governments in developed and developing countries
considered that the prevailing markets for agricultural finance were a constraint
to boosting the productivity of the rural sector and to fostering the adoption
by farmers of new technologies and inputs. Traditional, and often long-
standing, systems of finance were considered to be exploitative and inefficient.
Theprovision of credit would help to overcome the key constraints.
Views about market performance in those days owed more to preconcep-
tions than evidence at least on the output side (Southworthetal.,1979;
Holtzman, 1989). Nevertheless, research did identify practices that damaged
agricultural development. For example, Crows study of the rice trade in
Bangladesh uncovered complex market structures and interrelationships
between growers and traders who were often moneylenders (Crow, 1989). Crow
considered credit to be pivotal to understanding the operations ofthe rice
market. Interest rates were largely implicit but very high into thehundreds
of per cent and commissions had to be paid by farmers before credit could
http://dx.doi.org/10.3362/9781780449401.003
66 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
returns and hence alter the incentives to increase production for the market
and so promote national food security. Thesystem of dadon forward sales
as a means of financing production by farmers provided `bonded suppliers
for the market participant, thereby securing rice supply sources at favourable
terms, and assisted in creating personal andlong-term market relationships.
Crow found that millers also enjoyed a high degree of market power, to the
extent that they could even hold up government rice policy until it changed
in their favour; that is, until the government, in the interests of somehow
getting supplies moving through the system to assist national food security,
was forced to alter its buying policy in favour of the millers.
Officials were found to actually collude in the circumvention of government
policy by diverting public rice supplies to private markets. According to Crow
(1989: 217), any policy which tends to stabilize prices may be expected to
reduce returns to a section of the trading community. Hence it was in the
millers interests to undermine the success of the formal supply channel.
Thehidden vertical relationships concentrated market power among a
merchant elite who definitely were not price takers, but who exerted consid-
erable market power through interlocked markets the power of merchants
and landlords as the main suppliers of credit (Crow, 1989; 222).
Such analyses, critical of often informal and potentially exploitative
financial markets for smallholder production, raised many questions about
how credit relations affected poor farmers and food-security objectives.
Accordingly, many governments addressed market failures by intervening
in credit provision by limiting interest rates, allocating lending quotas for
poor farmers to formal finance institutions, launching and providing capital
to agricultural banks and other rural credit institutions such as coopera-
tives with specific responsibilities to lend to farmers, providing the lending
incentive of credit guarantees against loan defaults, and softening terms in
cases of agroecological or economic shocks. Finally, attempts were made to
make illegal the sort of informal moneylending practices identified by Crow
in Bangladesh.
But farmers need for finance was more complex than could be solved by
a cheap loan and benign regulation. The wider financial environment and
the delivery systems for credit were also found to be complex. Government
intervention in credit, like that in many other markets, was often costly and
ineffective. Lending was often politicized and went to the less-poor farmers.
Two important structural issues associated with credit arrangements were
that lending was often linked to technology that was inappropriate for the
poorest, and provision of credit was not accompanied by the provision of
other financial services necessary to meet the complex needs of smallholders.
Funds lent to farmers were often diverted to other uses, and poor loan-
repayment rates contributed to the financial failures and withdrawal of state
FINANCIAL SERVICES FOR SMALLHOLDERS 67
Increasing formality
Informal Formal
Member-based NGOs
organizations financial
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
organizations
and individuals institutions
market characteristics than another. Moral hazard is the first, for which a
definition (derived from Investopedia, undated) is: the risk borne by one party to
a transaction that another party to the transaction has not entered into the contract
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
in good faith, and/or has provided misleading information about its assets, liabilities
or credit capacity, and therefore may take unusual risks in an attempt to earn a profit.
In a lending context, moral hazard refers to a tendency by borrowers who
have secured finance to fail to protect themselves against risk, trusting rather
in the services and possible payouts than prudent risk-reducing behaviour.
Similar phenomena are commonly observed in an insurance context.
A second, related phenomenon is adverse selection, which occurs where
there is a tendency for one party to a transaction, usually the buyer of goods
or services, to be among those people who engage in less prudent behaviour.
Asymmetric information is implicated again, where one party usually has a
greater awareness and understanding of the goods or services being bought and sold,
and can exploit the other party. For example, those seeking financial services
may be those potential borrowers who do not take sensible precautions against
risks or the suppliers of poor-quality goods and services where the quality
cannot be easily verified, at least until after the transaction is completed.
Thus, these problems where one party to the transaction has better
knowledge about the goods, services and likely reactions of market participants,
can be considered information failures, and give rise to behaviouralproblems,
essentially of cheating. Transaction-cost economics focuses on these problemsof
information, uncertainty, and behavioural patterns in markets.
Principal-agent terminology can also illuminate contractual difficulties.
Information and behavioural problems afflict the less well-informed partner,
who is often the principal, in seeking reliable buyers and sellers, trustworthy
recipients, and sustainable businesses (i.e. agents). Assessing creditworthiness,
monitoring financial relationships, ensuring compliance with rules, mediating
and sanctioning cases of failure and default are all costly business activities
in terms of time, management worry, and actual financial expenditure.
Thus, firms incur transaction costs of mitigating the uncertainty created by
information and behavioural problems, which eat away at a firms profitability.
The total of normal costs of production or service provision plus transaction
costs can be so high, as is often the case when transacting with many
small-scale enterprises, that transactions do not happen. This is market failure.
Institutional economics, of which transaction-cost economics is a branch,
attaches importance to the provision of information and the formulation of
rules and norms of behaviour or institutions which reduce incentives for
behavioural problems and so lower transaction costs.
The informational problems in markets that apply clearly to the provision
of financial services have the following implications:
At some high level of uncertainty, total costs rise to a level too high for
transactions to take place and the market fails.
The provision of information and development of market institutions
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Market failure b
Successful transactions
d
Sale price
Provision of
Margin Profit information and
Total market institu-
Transaction costs tions reduces
costs transaction
costs
Cost of
production a c
Increasing uncertainty
as financial services to members, and finally the need for more sophisti-
cated forms of business governance often participatory and executive
management.
Leveraging equity. Pretes (2002) work is not so new, but he publicized the Village
Enterprise Fund, a US NGO in East Africa, using equity-based microfinance to
support small business start-ups and facilitate the growth stage of the business.
He showed how start-up grants and equity finance are useful and appropriate
additions to the more common loan-based approaches.
Finance and risk management. Angelucci and Conforti (2010) show how finance
is more than credit: financial management also involves identification and
management of risk. They showed how the provision of necessary insurance
can be hindered by a lack of credit and underinvestment in productivity
improvements. Also, market context matters: for Small Island Developing
States (SIDS) lack of demand due to small farming populations constrains
the development of appropriate insurance products work to which we will
return shortly.
Value chain links. Financing through supply chain contracts and the growing
focus on value chain management has opened new possibilities. As illustrated
by Miller and Jones (2010), value chain financing can be focused on chain
activities and linkages and complement conventional lending by being
embedded within other services, reflecting stakeholder participation in
terms of shared risks and returns. Since 2008 the United Nations World
Food Programme (WFP) Purchase for Progress (P4P) initiative has aimed to
provide a guaranteed market to smallholder farmers and at the same time
tolink farmers with commercial organizations that can provide the necessary
supports and services, including information technologies, to develop viable
agribusinesses (World Food Programme, 2016). Forward delivery contracts
from WFP reduce the risks to farmers who might otherwise avoid engagement
with markets. Governments often participate by creating a conducive business
74 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
environment. WFP build and coordinate strategic partnerships with all value
chain partners, including firms and other organizations such as AGRA, Bayer,
GrowAfrica, the International Finance Corporation, Rabobank, Syngenta,
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
of default. The latter allocates a sum ofmoney to the scheme and lends to
interestedsmall-scale finance institutions who may have better information
about borrowers but still cannot absorb the risk of default.
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
and ways to address hurdles that go beyond the capacity of the financial
institution to resolve can improve the results of the value chain partners
and those who finance them (Miller and Jones, 2010: 155).
New financing initiatives are needed, and new opportunities are continuing
to open up. In AAACP reports on the Zambian cassava sector, Poole identified
the diverse challenges (Poole, 2010; Poole et al., 2010):
The need for new forms of financial delivery and the lack of interest
from the private sector so far suggests that the conditions of market
failure are present to justify carefully designed intervention and financial
innovation. There is scope for further research in delivery mechanisms
for this level of microfinance: new knowledge and evidence is needed
to design appropriate financing mechanism, particularly for delivery
of small-scale funds to grassroots organizations: micro-funding may
be up to $10000 for infrastructure for an individual processing plant.
Private-sector business-service firms (such as accountants) can be
invited by national banks and international financial organizations to
design and implement models of competitive tendering and challenge
FINANCIAL SERVICES FOR SMALLHOLDERS 77
References
Angelucci, F. and Conforti, P. (2009). Risk Assessment and Finance in the Fruit
and Vegetable Value Chain. Evidence from Small Island Developing States in
the Caribbean and the Pacific. EU-AAACP Paper Series. No. 6. Rome, Food
and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations. Retrieved 28 March
2017, from http://www.fao.org/fileadmin/templates/est/AAACP/pacific/
FAO_AAACP_Paper_Series_No_6_1_.pdf.
Angelucci, F. and Conforti, P. (2010). Risk management and finance along
value chains of Small Island Developing States: evidence from the Caribbean
and the Pacific. Food Policy 35(6): 565575 <https://doi.org/10.1016/
j.foodpol.2010.07.001>.
British Business Bank (undated). Understanding the Enterprise Finance
Guarantee. Retrieved 9 May 2017 from http://british-business-bank.co.uk/
ourpartners/supporting-business-loans-enterprise-finance-guarantee/
understanding-enterprise-finance-guarantee/.
Crow, B. (1989). Plain tales from the rice trade: indications of vertical
integration in foodgrain markets in Bangladesh. Journal of Peasant Studies
16(2): 198229 <http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/03066158908438390>.
Donovan, J. and Poole, N.D. (2014). Changing asset endowments and
smallholder participation in higher value markets: evidence from certied
coffee producers in Nicaragua. Food Policy 44: 113 <http://dx.doi.org/
10.1016/j.foodpol.2013.09.010>.
Hardaker, J.B., Huirne, R.B.M., Anderson, J.R. and Lien, G. (2004). Coping with
Risk in Agriculture. Wallingford, UK, CAB International.
Helms, B. (2006). Access For All: Building inclusive financial systems. Washington
DC, Consultative Group to Assist the Poor, World Bank. Retrieved 09July
2014, from http://www.cgap.org/sites/default/files/CGAP-Access-for-All-
Jan-2006.pdf.
Holtzman, J.S. (1989). Maddening myths of agricultural marketing in
developing countries. Journal of International Food and Agribusiness Marketing
1(2): 5562 <http://dx.doi.org/10.1300/J047v01n02_05>.
Investopedia (undated). Moral hazard. Retrieved 9 May 2017, from http://
www.investopedia.com/terms/m/moralhazard.asp.
Kent, R., Bakaweri, C. and Poole, N.D. (2014). Facilitating entry into shea
processing: a study of two interventions in northern Ghana. Food Chain
4(3): 209224 <http://dx.doi.org/10.3362/2046-1887.2014.022>.
McMahon, J. and Harrison, T. (2014). Collaborating for Smallholder Finance:
How is Stanbic closing the loop? Inclusive Business in Practice Case
studies from the Business Innovation Facility portfolio, Inclusive
Business Hub Team. Retrieved 28 March 2017, from http://api.ning.
com/files/poTC6m2b82oCVTyU-6XyzAWFttZzcEg98SWPbveUwwcfxHM-
Z4PVVjZNXnvHiyl3V4OfC4BYYLNMy80mcNyB7dEGItSoC73O/Deepdive_
Stanbic_HUB.pdf.
78 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
Miller, C. and Jones, L. (2010). Agricultural Value Chain Finance: Tools and
methods. Rome and Rugby, UK, FAO and Practical Action Publishing.
North, D.C. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance.
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Veit, R. (2009). Assessing the Viability of Collection Centres for Fruit and Vegetables
in Fiji: A value chain approach. EU-AAACP Paper Series. No. 7. Rome, Food
and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations. Retrieved 28 March
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Risk management
for agricultural smallholders
Agribusiness involves risk. This chapter explores the concept of risk and considers
howagricultural smallholders manage in practice the different kinds of risks in
production and marketing, and how they cope with price variation. Contracts are one of
the most important mechanisms for reducing risk, but the terms of contracts will often
depend on the negotiating power of the stronger contracting party. We make the case
for governments to be involved in risk management in order to enhance the functioning
of markets. The provision of insurance is a common way of supporting businesses, and
is increasingly feasible in small-scale agricultural enterprise and marketing. Finally,
we comment on risk management challenges in different agricultural sectors.
Introduction
The evolution of the food chain from a competitive industry charac-
terised by many participants at all levels to an increasingly integrated
system provides a unique risk management opportunity to those who
have market power. In the absence of effective intervention by public
institutions, highly integrated firms are able to transfer the majority
of unacceptable risk to the ends of the chain; in particular, to farmers,
ranchers and retail consumers While public policy intervention may
partially mitigate risk through a variety of programmes and regulations
designed to address risk symptoms, past and current policies have
generally failed to address a primary cause of the inequity in risk transfer
by not ensuring an adequate level of competition throughout the food
chain (Swenson, 2000: 657).
To begin this chapter with a quotation that criticizes the unfair balance
of risk in food chains makes a strong statement about where responsibilities
lie for the management of smallholder farmers problems. The discussion
of agricultural value chains has often touched questions related to the
risks involved in the transition to a new organization of the agricultural
production and distribution sectors. But with the notable exception of Jaffee
et al. (2008), few contributions to the literature have been explicitly devoted
to the issue of risk management within developing countries rural agricul-
tural and food chains. Given the adoption of closer forms of value chain
http://dx.doi.org/10.3362/9781780449401.004
82 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
developing countries. More market engagement means that other events are
becoming more relevant in determining the overall levels and types of risk
to which developing countries agricultural producers are exposed. These are
problems such as contract breaches by a contractual counterpart, disruptions
in transportation logistics, unpredictable changes in final demand due to
safety concerns of consumers, and the introduction of new standards required
to access rich consumer markets.
Some of the initiatives described at the end of the last chapter illustrate
how close contractual arrangements can facilitate the entry of farmers into
markets. How these arrangements work depends on how they are designed in
relation to sharing and reducing the risks that farmers are assume when they
engage in markets.
Siegel and Jaffee (2008) have made a valuable contribution to the analysis
of the problems of risk assessment and risk management in agri-food chains,
with the aim of developing an operational framework to analyse and manage
supply-chain risk. They borrowed extensively from the existing literature
onsupply-chain risk management (SCRM) and on the strand of development
literature that has been concerned with the concept of vulnerability.
SCRM sees the value chain as an economic framework or entity within
which firms and individuals interact in order to extract a premium over
production costs from the sale of a given product. The objective of SCRM
analysis is to identify and mitigate the major events that hinder the
objective of bringing the right products (quantity and quality), in theright
amounts,to the right place, at the right time, and at a competitive cost (Jaffee
et al.,2008: 5). The concept of vulnerability underlies risk. Vulnerability is
defined as the combined result of the probability of an event occurring and
of the economic damage that may derive from such an event. In SCRM,
vulnerability is not an individual or household characteristic but is taken
to be the vulnerability of the chain itself; that is, the possibility that the
chain might fail to bring the right product in the right quantities to the right
place at the right time and at a competitive cost. The management of risk in the
chain is seen from the perspective of a fully vertically integrated enterprise,
concerned with the risk of the disruption of the chain, with limited or no
attention to the distribution of risk among chain participants.
The issues discussed in this chapter are the same ones that inform SCRM,
but less at the level of the chain as a whole than at the level of chain partici-
pants. The questions are: how to define and identify the risks that are relevant to
small-scale farmers and entrepreneurs, how to analyse the available or potential
risk management tools, and how to suggest possible policy responses. First, the
focus here will be on price or market risk for agricultural producers, making
only passing reference, when deemed necessary, to the problem of managing
production risk, which has been more extensively covered in the literature.
Risk management for agricultural smallholders 83
Here we will consider how risks can be identified and managed in rural
value chains, and who is affected in chains such as those for farm products.
The chapter draws substantially on the AAACP papers by Cafiero (2008) and
Conforti (2009).
they are responsible. Mapping also highlights the chain mechanisms that
link thevarious functions, and associates the chain functions to the links
wherethe risk is first likely to have an impact.
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Risk assessment
Risk assessment implies identification of the possible risk-generating events,
quantification of the impact that each will have in terms of financial losses,
and association of a probability value to each of them. Even though precise
quantification of the extent of losses and the probability of the risk occurring is
virtually impossible, to have even a rough idea of their range can be extremely
important in defining the optimal risk management strategy.
One informative practice, common in financial investment and risk
management, is the process of risk layering, in which a probability distribution
of potential losses is formed. When the only dimension being considered is
the entity of the financial loss, irrespective of the event that might cause it,
the distribution will have the shape depicted in Figure 4.1. It can be seen that a
proportion of the risks involves smaller financial losses with a high probability
of occurring; usually these losses are absorbed by the person or firm affected.
This is the layer of retained risk, or the retention layer. Other layers of risk
are identified by choosing the levels of financial losses that separate the risk-
retention layer from the risk-transfer layer and this latter from the so-called
tail risk. This practice is useful in informing theprocess of risk management
through insurance, in that it allows for the identification and handling of
different types of risk:
Probability
of loss
Retention layer
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Insurance layer
losses large enough to
disrupt normal business
Tail risk
practices, but can be
pooled in an insurance unlikely but catastrophic
product and/or covariate events
that insurers are
unwilling to cover
Scale of loss
Figure 4.1 Risk layering
Source: author
the tail risk of unlikely but catastrophic losses which is the part that will
not be covered through formal insurance.
elements which can affect the size of each layer. The distribution of the
layers is primarily determined by the specific risks of each environment;
however, the market for services used by farmers and government policies
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
alsocontribute.
The retention layer. As retention-layer losses are frequent and of limited size,
in most rural contexts they are normally addressed through household
income diversification and consumption smoothing. Production variability
tends to offer a natural hedge to farmers, given the inverse relation observed
between prices and yields. Other key elements shaping theability of farmers
to retain losses individually are individuals access tothe agricultural services
market,such as credit and finance, storage andtransport facilities, and other
services, such as extension and technical assistance.
Through unintended consequences, policies also play a major part in
shaping the ability of farmers to retain risks. Price controls reduce the automatic
hedging offered by the inverse relation with quantities, and redistribute risk
rather than reduce volatility. However, where agriculture is widely supported
by public resources, as is the case in OECD countries, the risk-retention layer
will likely become large, as subsidies and protection will increase farmers
ability and willingness to retain individual risks directly. Indeveloping
countries, public support to agriculture is usually more limited, and this tends
to reduce the size of the retention layer, and to increase the need to resort to
informal mitigation and smoothing mechanisms.
because of their covariate nature and the magnitude of the associated losses.
Lack of information reduces the willingness of farmers to insure against
unlikely catastrophic events. Hence tail risks usually call for the establishment
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Risk management
Once the extent of risk exposure has been assessed, the next step is to consider
what actions can be taken to reduce the losses associated with risk exposure.
Discussions start with the special nature of agricultural production, with
its strong dependence on biological processes and a high vulnerability to
natural phenomena such as weather and pests, as we have noted. Thefocus
is usually on yield or production risk. This approach has several short-
comings, such as neglect of the possibility of a natural hedge or compen-
sation, such as when prices and production are negatively correlated: a low
level of agricultural production often signifies high market prices and vice
versa. Therefore, through increases in prices, producers might in part be
able to compensate for a reduction in production. In such circumstances,
producers total incomes are somewhat equilibrated and welfare losses are
limited, given that what ultimately matters is incomes, not simply the level
of production.
88 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
Coping strategies
If the physical characteristics of production and the institutional context
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
on whether they make their impact within the farm gate or beyond it.
Thiscorresponds to the traditional distinction made between production
(oryield) risk and market (or price) risk. Through decisions on the amount
being sold or on the timing of sales, the producer can directly affect the price
(s)he receives, and therefore production and marketing decisions themselves
can be considered mechanisms for risk management.
The timing of marketing decisions is constrained by the need for income
for household costs and for working finance. Farmers require credit or
savings even to bridge the time between sowing and harvests; hence
purchasing inputs, even in the absence of unexpected market or environ-
mental swings, requires finance. Crop and plot diversification, savings,
storage, and purchase of financial assets, where they are accessible, are
common practices that serve the purpose of managing the expected price
variability. In the absence of any other source of credit, produce must
besold so-called distress sales to meet immediate financial needs.
Andsuch sales often occur at a time when market prices are low, because the
timing coincides with harvest, and/or because other people are in the same
situation, needing to make sales at the same time.
The extent to which the level of production and the price received by
the producer are negatively correlated depends on the relative scale of the
producer and the size of the market. Usually, for small producers, changes
in individual output and product sales are not capable of affecting prices,
and in such cases it makes sense to analyse and manage yield risk indepen-
dently of the price received. The smaller and more local the market, the
higher the possibility that the natural hedge can be effective, as quantities
and prices arelikely to experience greater fluctuations. But even if individual
producers have little scope for affecting the price level through management
of the quantity marketed, such that production shocks are correlated across
producers, individual production and total production will be correlated,
andtherefore some scope for a natural hedge may exist.
However, local markets may be integrated with larger markets, even
international markets, and therefore prices may fluctuate with supply and
demandacross a wider economic region. In this case, local supply and demand
conditions will not change prices in what is, in effect, a much larger market.
Inshort, selling prices will be independent of local supplies, the natural link
between low production and high prices is lost, and there will be no natural
hedge: farmers may have to sell their limited supplies at prices kept low by
the supply and demand conditions in the wider market. Under such circum-
stances, the production and market risks can both be severe.
Furthermore, in some circumstances, producers as a group might exploit the
ability to increase the price they receive by reducing the quantity theymarket.
This is the rationale for the practice of product withdrawal. When demand
90 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
isinelastic, even a slight decrease in the quantity sold can raise the price and
increase overall revenue. For such a strategy to be effective, however, coordi-
nation among all producers that supply their product to a given market is
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
MC
AC
p
MR
D
q q Quantity q q q Quantity
Figure 4.2 The cartel
Source: author
Risk management for agricultural smallholders 91
of cheating: sellers try to coordinate output to raise prices, but find that some members of
the group choose to increase sales to take advantage of the high prices.
In the left-hand diagram in Figure 4.2 the whole-industry demand curve and
marginal revenue curve are D and MR, respectively. The initial market equilibrium occurs
at output and price pq. For the representative firm or farmer in the right hand
diagramoutput is set at q, receiving price p, just covering average costs. Nowsuppose:
Source: author
an issue for producers, and any activity directed towards reducing the cost of
storage (which comprises both physical and financial components) will always
have very strong implications for producers ability to cope with price risk.
One other aspect that complicates the analysis of price in the presence
of storage is active government intervention. Usually, public programmes
intended to achieve price stabilization in developing countries are justified
as a means to protect consumers. Consumers are numerous and often more
politically active, able to bring pressure on governments, in urban areas. Thus,
mechanisms such as buffer stocks and export restrictions are put in place for
domestically produced foodstuffs with the aim of preventing food prices from
rising above a ceiling level. From the producers perspective, unpredictable
changes in policies that directly and indirectly affect commodity markets are
perhaps the most relevant source of price risk independent of producers own
market behaviour. In this respect, government lobbying by producer interest
groups can be seen as a mechanism for price-risk management. Such advocacy
is another potential focus of collective action by producers, and is a form of
long-term risk management.
would be that of entering into a contractual agreement directly with the final
consumers, who will have the exact opposite stand in terms of price, and
therefore would provide the most effective price-risk sharing opportunity.
Inmost cases this is impractical, given the physical and economic separation
that exists between producers and consumers. Nevertheless, there are other
hedging mechanisms that could be exploited by agricultural producers, which
include forward-sale contracts to be stipulated with an intermediary buyer
of the product, and price-contingent contracts to be traded on organized
exchanges. The possibility of effectively exploiting the hedging potential of
formal contracts traded on local or international exchanges depends largely
on the institutional settings that allow for their enforcement, and these are
limited for developing country producers.
Two aspects of forward contracting deserve to be highlighted. First, in
agricultural produce markets, it tends to be that many small producers deal
with few economically larger traders, who may exploit local buying power
in formulating the terms of the contract: on quantities, quality, delivery and
timeliness, and, above all, the price. Second, when a share of local production
is sold through forward contracts, the concept of a spot market price loses
some of its significance as the link between the wholesale price that forms
at the level of final consumption and the farm-gate price is broken. While
this might protect producers from the consequences of market events that
may occur beyond the farm gate after the contract has been signed, it usually
comes at the price of forgoing the benefits of any rises in price.
One other aspect to be considered is that the signing of a forward contract
introduces a new type of risk for the producers, namely the possibility that
thebuyer or client will default on the terms of the contract and fail totake
delivery of the product at the specified conditions. It is precisely this risk
that increases as smallholder producers enter into new types of contractual
arrangement through more sophisticated mechanisms of market coordi-
nation. The extent of this client risk depends strongly on the institutions
thatsupport exchange, including the prevailing legal system and the
abilitythat producers have to call upon impartial courts to enforce contracts.
Inshort, the levelofinstitutional development influences the transaction
costs and the level of risk, as discussed in Chapter 3 and as clearly explained
by North, among others (North, 1987, 1990, 1994).
For export commodities, traders of exports originating in developing
countries might find opportunities to hedge their selling-price risk exposure
through contracts traded on international exchanges. The possibilities for
local producers in developing economies depend, once again, on the existence
of either formal or informal contractual agreements between producers and
traders, on their relative market power, and the complexity of institutional
development.
Risk management for agricultural smallholders 93
Quotes like the one reported at the beginning of this chapter might
convey the impression that the ability to extract rents associated with market
power can also be exploited to transfer more than the fair share of risk.
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
People of the same trade seldom meet together, even for merriment and
diversion, but the conversation ends in a conspiracy against the public,
or in some contrivance to raise prices. It is impossible indeed to prevent
such meetings, by any law which either could be executed, or would be
consistent with liberty and justice. But though the law cannot hinder
people of the same trade from sometimes assembling together, it ought
to do nothing to facilitate such assemblies, much less to render them
necessary (Smith, 1776: 232).
Box 4.2 Formal contracts: Risk sharing between farmers and traders in Spain and Ghana
Can the introduction of standard sellerbuyer contracts facilitate producers marketing
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
decisions and reduce uncertainty, thereby lowering transaction costs for Spanish mandarin
and orange producers? Research showed how producer behaviour was found to vary and how
producers could be grouped according to their different production and marketing orienta-
tions. Regarding sales decisions, marketing factors in addition to the negotiated price were
found to be important determinants of the terms of the transaction. Most of all, uncertainty
about payment was a major preoccupation of small-scale producers, more so than prices,
and contracts were considered to be one way to mitigate this form of market risk.
Marketing institutions are less developed in sub-Saharan Africa: producers often
experience weak bargaining relationships with traders because they do not have access to
information on prices, demand conditions, or alternative marketing channels. Most of all,
farmers lack the ability to enforce verbally agreed terms of exchange with traders. Farmers
may also renege on agreements, to the detriment of small traders. Such contractual ineffi-
ciencies reduce the performance of the market system, with multiple consequences: there
are unexploited market opportunities, in-field and post-harvest losses, seasonal gluts of
produce, poor quality control, inequitable returns to producers, unsatisfied consumer
demand, and reduced multiplier effects in the rest of the local economy.
A study of vegetable marketing in Ghana offered ideas for how the development
of contractual institutions could enhance market coordination: closer coordination
mechanisms to mitigate uncertainty and enhance the building of a clientele, for example
through formal contracts, have potential to overcome the pervasive mistrust between
farmers and traders and reduce transaction costs.
Written agreements such as standard-form contracts offer three advantages over verbal
agreements. First, written specifications establish criteria by which performance can be
measured in terms of important variables such as product price; quantity traded; product
quality; place of delivery; ownership of packaging materials; and payment date. Changes
to these terms will be transparent, and, in the event of unavoidable conflict, resolution
mechanisms can be specified.
Second, adoption of written agreements may boost the informal rules of business
attitudes and ethics. Moral obligation rather than the force of law may, in time, come to
prevail, creating trust between buyers and sellers.
Third, the law is there to help, but expectations of formal legal remedies should not be
exaggerated. It may be preferable that unwritten norms and customary laws operate through
negotiation rather than the expensive remedial use of contract law through formal legal
procedures. Hence the importance of developing moral obligation within the trading culture.
Source: summarized from Poole et al. (1998, 2003) and Poole (2000)
the overall merit of such policies. With reference to prices, and linked to our
discussion of price risk, one accepted conclusion should be that price stabili-
zation per se is not a desirable policy objective. Everything else being equal, an
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
who pay receive cover; those who dont pay are excluded. Asinsurance cover
is not a public good, the role of the government in theinsurance market
should be limited to regulation: that is, providing the legal framework for
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
the risk to other institutions or organizations who are better able to bear the
risk or who are less risk-averse; and by pooling risks across space, crop sectors,
andother economic sectors (Hazell et al., 1986: 2). Idiosyncratic and individual
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Types of insurance
Hopes some years ago that the smallholder insurance industry might take off
have been disappointed (Hazell, 1992). However, efforts to develop appropriate
insurance products for the covariate risks of developing country agriculture
have continued such as risk securitization in Nicaragua (Miranda and
Vedenov, 2001). Over the last few years, there has been an increasing interest
in hedging against weather-related events, following the increasing likelihood
of extreme phenomena related to global environmental issues such as climate
change. Public intervention in this area is now growing, with governments
looking with interest towards market-based tools to hedge financial positions
in case of adverse events. Newer and promising products, at both micro and
macro levels, are indexed insurances. These are based on indemnities tied
to predetermined indicators for a common geographical area, unlike the
assessment of losses sustained by individual enterprises which are examined
in the field. Indirect-index insurance, also called weather derivatives, falls in
this category (Schaffnit-Chatterjee, 2010: 234). Mahul and Stutley (2010) cite
China, India, and Mexico as countries where provision of weather insurance
has expanded. Differences between indemnity and index-based agricultural
insurance products are summarized in Table 4.1.
At the micro level also, insurance is considered to be a promising area for
promoting agriculture in poor developing countries, as well as for managing
safetynets and disaster management, as shown by the increasing number
ofprojects, pilots, experiments, and even policy schemes which are being
undertaken that entail some sort of agricultural insurance (Mahul and
The success of microcredit worldwide has shown that people with low
incomes are a proven market for financial services and are effective
consumers if given appropriate products, processes, and knowledge.
Inthe insurance field, microinsurance can provide the specialised
insurance products demanded by under-served low income markets
(Lloyds Micro Insurance Centre, undated: 3).
risk management knowledge, and on the other are subject to systemic hazards
for which there is under-provision by the private sector. Using predefined
statistical indices of events, such as the natural disasters to which agriculture
is prone, to trigger payouts speeds response to disaster and reduces the costs of
administration and individual loss adjustment (Box 4.3).
and which greatly determine the degree of market power that producers
may achieve;
the degree of processing, or the extent to which the bulk product is used
also as an input for other industries, which may condition the charac-
teristics above.
level of complexity/integration;
extent of control operated by the various agents;
locus of price formation;
major production risks, other than price variation, to which the producer
is exposed.
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
External
Policy risk Supply risk Distribution risk
Box 4.4 Risk management through aligning private and public objectives
Warehouse receipt systems allow agricultural producers to access credit by borrowing
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
against receipts issued for goods stored in independently controlled warehouses. These
systems enable producers to delay the sale of their products until after harvest, to a
moment when prices are generally more favourable. Warehouse receipt systems can
therefore mobilize credit for the agricultural sector and improve agricultural trade.
Warehouse receipt systems bring other benefits to the agricultural sector. For example,
the provision of good handling and storage by warehouses licensed and controlled according
to mandatory standards can help reduce post-harvest losses and improve product quality.
The increased storage of agricultural commodities after the harvest season may in turn
contribute to stabilizing commodity price volatility. With respect to the management of
national food security and strategic reserves, an effective warehouse system provides
government authorities with timely and accurate information about the aggregate stock of
stored agricultural commodities in the country
In recent years, many countries around the world have begun to introduce or reform
legislation of their warehouse receipt system. Various objectives motivated the reforms,
from mobilizing credit for the agricultural sector after market liberalization to adapting an
existing system to the requirements of electronic commerce, or enhancing the income of
smallholder producers.
Asreported above, traders may have to procure and pay for the product
through advance contracts, thus bearing most of the risk associated with
product deterioration and other risks, which may be particularly high in many
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
price variations, and they may then transfer part of the benefits to farmers in
terms of more stable prices.
One other change that is occurring in the supply chains of traditional
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
bulk commodities such as coffee, cocoa, and tea, is the attempt to colonize
new market niches, resulting in a wave of diversification into speciality
commodities, up to the point of causing the switch to a distinctly different
commodity chain organization.
For some standard fruits, such as bananas and pineapples, the dominant
configuration in global trade in the past has been vertical integration, with
trading companies taking direct control of production through ownership
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Farmers retained most of the production risk, with the additional dimension of quality
risk: the contract specified that the firm would only pay for product that fulfils the
quality norms set in advance.
Because it is in the interest of the firm to maintain adequate supply, Lecofruit SA
provided technical assistance and training, in addition to monitoring and supervision
of the contracted areas.
Potential alternative market outlets for producers created incentives for Lecofruit SA to
offer a price premium to attract and retain farmers and to ensure enforcement.
Contracts proved to be self-enforcing, necessarily so given the poorly developed legal
institution and the relatively high transaction costs for formal enforcement, compared
with the small amount involved in any individual contract.
Contracts appeared to be robust even under conditions of high inflation and therefore
price risk.
Conclusions
The fast-growing interest that has formed around the concept of value chains
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
information sharing;
competition;
contract enforcement.
Risk management for agricultural smallholders 111
Indeed, the prevailing view of the role of the state goes beyond these
potential roles to create an environment in which agribusiness can operate
fairly and efficiently, all the time balancing the need for specific interventions
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
with the need to create a climate that enables farmers and firms to unleash
their own business initiatives:
References
Barrett, C.B. (2008). Smallholder market participation: concepts and evidence
from eastern and southern Africa. Food Policy 33(4): 299317 <https://doi.org/
10.1016/j.foodpol.2007.10.005>.
Borzoni, M. and Poole, N.D. (2011). Sourcing strategies in the Italian coffee
industry. Food Chain 1(1): 7186 <http://dx.doi.org/10.3362/2046-
1887.2011.006>.
Cadilhon, J.-J., Moustier, P., Poole, N.D., Giac Tam, P.T. and Fearne, A. (2006).
Traditional vs. modern food systems? Insights from vegetable supply chains
to Ho Chi Minh City (Vietnam). Development Policy Review 24(1): 3149
<http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-7679.2006.00312.x>.
Cafiero, C. (2008). Agricultural Producer Risk Management in a Value Chain
Context: Implications for Developing Countries Agriculture. EU-AAACP Paper
Series. No. 4. Rome, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United
Nations. Retrieved 28 March 2017, from http://www.fao.org/fileadmin/
templates/est/AAACP/inter-regional/FAO_AAACP_Paper_Series_
No_4_1_.pdf.
Conforti, P. (2009). Agricultural Insurances as Market Based Tools for Risk
Management and Agricultural Development. EU-AAACP Paper Series. No. 5.
Rome, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations. Retrieved
28 March 2017, from http://www.fao.org/fileadmin/templates/est/AAACP/
inter-regional/FAO_AAACP_Paper_Series_No_5_1_.pdf
112 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
Cramer, C., Johnston, D., Mueller, B., Oya, C. and Sender, J. (2016). Fairtrade
and labour markets in Ethiopia and Uganda. Journal of Development Studies:
116 <http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00220388.2016.1208175>.
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Dercon, S., ed. (2005). Insurance Against Poverty. Oxford, Oxford Scholarship
Online.
Donovan, J. and Poole, N.D. (2014a). Partnerships in fairtrade coffee: aclose-up
look at how buyers and NGOs build supply capacity in Nicaragua. Food
Chain 4(1): 3448 <http://dx.doi.org/10.3362/2046-1887.2014.004>.
Donovan, J. and Poole, N.D. (2014b). Changing asset endowments and
smallholder participation in higher value markets: evidence from certied
coffee producers in Nicaragua. Food Policy 44: 113 <http://dx.doi.org/
10.1016/j.foodpol.2013.09.010>.
Dorward, A. (2009). Integrating contested aspirations, processes and
policy: development as hanging in, stepping up and stepping out.
Development Policy Review 27(2): 131146 <http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/
j.1467-7679.2009.00439.x>.
Fafchamps, M. and Minten, B. (1999). Relationships and traders in
Madagascar. Journal of Development Studies 35(6): 135 <http://dx.doi.
org/10.1080/00220389908422600>.
FEWS NET (undated). Home page. Retrieved 9 May 2017, from http://www.
fews.net/
Garca Martnez, M. and Poole, N.D. (2008). The development of private fresh
produce safety standards: Implications for developing Mediterranean exporting
countries. Fresh Perspectives 26. agrifoodstandards.net. Retrieved 28 March
2017, from https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/media/57a08b96e5274
a31e0000c4a/60506-fp26.pdf.
Hazell, P.B.R. (1992). The appropriate role of agricultural insurance in
developing countries. Journal of International Development 4(6): 567581
<http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/jid.3380040602>.
Hazell, P., Pomareda, C. and Valds, A., eds (1986). Crop Insurance for
Agricultural Development: Issues and experience. Baltimore, MD, Johns
Hopkins University Press.
International Finance Corporation (2016). Global Index Insurance Facility.
Retrieved 28 March 2017, from http://www.ifc.org/wps/wcm/connect/
industry_ext_content/ifc_external_corporate_site/financial+institutions/
priorities/access_essential+financial+services/global+index+insurance+
facility.
Jaffee, S., Siegel, P. and Andrews, C. (2008). Rapid Agricultural Supply Chain
Risk Assessment: Conceptual framework and guidelines for application.
Commodity Risk Management Group, Agricultural and Rural Development
Department. Washington, DC, World Bank. Retrieved 28 March 2017,
from http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTCOMRISMAN/Resources/
RapidAgriculturalSupplyChainRiskAssessmentConceptualFramework.pdf.
Jayne, T.S., Sturgess, C., Kopicki, R. and Sitko, N. (2014). Agricultural
Commodity Exchanges and the Development of Grain Markets and Trade in
Africa: A review of recent experience. Working Paper 88. Lusaka, Zambia,
Indaba Agricultural Policy Research Institute (IAPRI). Retrieved 28March
2017, from http://ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/188568/2/wp88.
pdf.
Risk management for agricultural smallholders 113
<https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2006.05.004>.
Pritchard, B., Rammohan, A., Sekher, M., Parasuraman, S. and Choitani, C.
(2014). Feeding India: Livelihoods, entitlement and capabilities. Abingdon, UK,
Routledge.
Reardon, T., Barrett, C.B., Berdegu, J.A. and Swinnen, J.F.M. (2009).
Agrifood industry transformation and small farmers in developing
countries. World Development 37(11): 17171727 <https://doi.org/10.1016/
j.worlddev.2008.08.023>.
Schaffnit-Chatterjee, C. (2010). Risk Management in Agriculture: Towards
Market Solutions in the EU. Frankfurt am Main, Deutsche Bank Research.
Retrieved 11 November 2016, from http://www.dbresearch.com/PROD/
DBR_INTERNET_EN-PROD/PROD0000000000262553.PDF.
Singh, I., Squire, L. and Strauss, J., eds (1986). Agricultural Household Models:
Extensions, applications, and policy. Baltimore, MD, Johns Hopkins
University Press.
Sitko, N.J. and Jayne, T.S. (2012). Why are African commodity exchanges
languishing? A case study of the Zambian Agricultural Commodity
Exchange. Food Policy 37(3): 275282 <https://doi.org/10.1016/
j.foodpol.2012.02.015>.
Smith, A. (1776). The Wealth of Nations (Penguin Classics edition 1970).
Harmondsworth, UK, Penguin.
Swenson, L. (2000). Income risk management: the perspective of United States
farmers, in Income Risk Management in Agriculture, pp. 657. Paris, OECD.
Retrieved 11 November 2016, from http://www.oecd.org/agriculture/
agricultural-policies/42750750.pdf.
Wehling, P. and Garthwaite, B. (2015). Designing Warehouse Receipt Legislation:
Regulatory options and recent trends. Rome, UN Food and Agriculture
Organization. Retrieved 10 November 2016, from http://www.fao.org/3/
a-i4318e.pdf.
World Bank (2007). World Development Report 2008: Agriculture for Development.
Washington, DC, World Bank. Retrieved 28 March 2017, from http://
siteresources.worldbank.org/INTWDR2008/Resources/WDR_00_book.pdf.
World Bank (2017). Enabling the Business of Agriculture 2017. Washington,
DC, World Bank. Retrieved 28 March 2017, from http://eba.worldbank.
org/~/media/WBG/AgriBusiness/Documents/Reports/2017/EBA2017-
Report17.pdf.
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
PART II
Case studies of smallholder agriculture
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
CHAPTER 5
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Introduction
The principal theme of this book is to understand the constraints affecting
smallholder farmer participation in agri-food markets and point to ways to
help farmers take better advantage of market opportunities. In the earlier
chapters we considered some of the constraints in theory and in practice.
Inthe last chapter we considered risk and how to manage it. InPart 2
we report on four interventions, in different contexts, which aimed to
increase farmers commercial opportunities, and present simple analyses of
the impacts of the projects. Risk is one of the factors that is highlighted.
Chapters 610 draw substantially on papers by Amrouk et al. (2013) and
Mudungwe et al. (2012).
Market-participation projects can be considered from two angles: first,
and commonly, projects are designed by third-party organizations such as
government bodies, international organizations, and non-governmental
organizations. Whether or not these projects are designed and implemented
in a participative manner, they can be considered as interventions by organi-
zations that are inherently outside the agri-food value chain, as defined at the
end of Chapter 1:
http://dx.doi.org/10.3362/9781780449401.005
118 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
Second, access to markets can come about through strategies and activities
among participants within the value chain, and can be described better as
initiatives, independent of outside interventions:
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Harper et al. (2015) argue that most business happens within commercial
value chains that are not the object of project interventions. Their volume of
case studies illustrates how farming smallholders and other poor people can
profitably integrate their livelihood activities with modern value chains. And,
they argue, projects are not needed because there are benefits for all value
chain partners and it simply makes good business sense.
Nevertheless, we have seen that there are many reasons why smallholder
farmers cannot easily access markets. The four interventions introduced
here and reported in Chapters 69 were designed to overcome these diffi-
culties. Four projects on vegetables, milk, sisal, and henequen were
selected for analysis, and lessons about how these projects have succeeded
inenabling better market participation by the smallholder farmers were
drawn. Ultimately, the objective was to develop guidelines for best practices
to be pursued in designing and implementing future commodity projects:
to draw lessons on the determinants of successes and failures of projects
assisting smallholder farmers to enhance their participation in agricultural
value chains (Amrouk et al., 2013).
Cases
The Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO) and the
Common Fund for Commodities (CFC) have been implementing commodity-
specific development projects for over 20 years in the context of the development
plans agreed by the FAO Intergovernmental Groups (IGGs). Nearly 70 per cent of
the projects have been located in least-developed countries. These projects mostly
aimed to provide smallholder farmers with knowledge, skills, and servicesto
increase agricultural productivity and household incomes. Project inputs
tofarming systems included dissemination of improved varieties, provision of
fertilizers and pesticides, training on effective crop-management systems, and
transmission of information on market trends and prices. In some instances,
support to build market infrastructure, such as pack-houses for processing fruits
and vegetables, greenhouses, and funding for the establishment of institutions
such as farmers cooperatives and associations, was also provided.
Since the scope to increase income through area expansion remains limited
in many contexts, productivity growth through the adoption of new technol-
ogies and practices is required to enable smallholders to achieve higher
returns. Higher productivity can therefore generate surpluses of marketable
crops and livestock products, enabling better access to market opportu-
nities for more consistent supplies of higher-quality and -quantity products.
IMPACT OF COMMODITY DEVELOPMENT PROJECTS 119
The direct beneficiaries of the project were the smallholder dairy farmers,
butalso milk processors and consumers who benefited from increased local
milk supplies and better-quality milk. Specifically, the project set out to
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
in practice. It traces how the (short-term) project activities and outputs will
cause (short- to mid-term) outcomes and how these will lead in turn to
(longer-term) social and economic impacts. This approach, as used here, is
shown in Figure 5.1, which illustrates the pathway from the inputs made, in
these cases, by external interventions which are expected to overcome market-
entry barriers, not least by enriching the asset status of the beneficiaries.
Leveraging these livelihood assets leads to a series of positive economic and
other outcomes. Sustainability is achieved through the impact of immediate
outcomes on the long-term enhancement of livelihood assets.
The development of quantitative indicators was guided by the causal
linkages identified in Figure 5.1. Broadly, there were two groups of indicators:
livelihood indicators of the participating farmers, and market indicators.
Thefour case studies concerned commodities from four different groups, namely
export vegetables, milk, sisal, and oleaginous plants. A set of specific indicators
was adapted and analysed for each project.
Inputs Outcomes
Interventions by the Incomes:
state, external
donors, and NGOs growth, stability, and
distribution among
beneficiaries
Sales:
Assets quantities and quality of
Finance Human products marketed
Training Social through new value chains
Technology Physical compared with alternative
Institutions Financial markets
Natural Prices:
returns for products
marketed through new
chains compared with
alternative markets
Initiatives by
commercial value Changes in assets
chain partners
human, social, physical,
Inputs financial, natural
Figure 5.1 Theory of change approach: intervention inputs, assets, and outcomes
Source:author
IMPACT OF COMMODITY DEVELOPMENT PROJECTS 123
2013, 2014).
The following key asset indicators were analysed for the four projects:
Human assets:
Social assets:
Physical assets:
Financial assets:
access to credit;
income benefit from product sales.
Natural assets:
Market-related indicators
The second set of indicators relate to market participation by the
smallholderfarmers:
Incomes:
Sales:
Prices:
Innovation:
Methodology
Data requirements
The assessment entailed the following key steps:
Ethiopia 23 8 31
Peru 29 10 39
Tanzania 40 14 54
Zambia 40 16 56
Total 132 48 180
Field methods
Field visits were made to each project site during 2012. The participatory
techniques involved qualitative data collection through close collabo-
ration between the evaluation team and project funders, supervisory bodies,
executing agencies, and a sample of project beneficiaries. Discussions were
held with market-chain actors such as private-enterprise executives from
trading and processing firms, cooperative leaders and members, individual
farmers and project participants; and with key informants such as project
managers, andpublic-sector stakeholders.
Data analysis
There was both qualitative and quantitative analysis of data collected for
theassessment.
Content analysis was used in analysing qualitative data from interviews and
focus groups, and consisted of identifying themes, issues, trends, and thematic
interrelationships. The technique involves looking at documents, text, or
speech to see what themes emerge, or what people talk about the most.
Descriptive statistics were used to describe relationships between variables
and to suggest any causal relationships between variables being analysed.
Frequency tables, where statistics such as simple percentages are used to
compare before and after situations, were used.
Summary quantitative analysis using regression techniques was also
undertaken. Findings have been incorporated into the conclusions below.
References
Amrouk, El. M., Poole, N.D., Mudungwe, N. and Muzvondiwa, E. (2013).
TheImpact of Commodity Development Projects on Smallholders Market Access
in Developing Countries: Case studies of FAO/CFC projects. Rome, United
Nations Food and Agriculture Organization. Retrieved 28 March 2017,
from http://www.fao.org/docrep/017/aq290e/aq290e.pdf.
Donovan, J. and Poole, N.D. (2013). Asset building in response to value chain
development: lessons from taro producers in Nicaragua. International
Journal of Agricultural Sustainability 11(1): 2337 <http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/
14735903.2012.673076>.
Donovan, J. and Poole, N.D. (2014). Changing asset endowments and
smallholder participation in higher value markets: evidence from certied
coffee producers in Nicaragua. Food Policy 44: 113 <http://dx.doi.org/
10.1016/j.foodpol.2013.09.010>.
128 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
Harper, M., Belt, J. and Roy, R., eds (2015). Commercial and Inclusive Value
Chains. Rugby, UK, Practical Action Publishing.
Mudungwe, N., Muzvondiwa, E., Musarurwa, G. and Solange Sevilla, S.
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Project context
Programme design and implementation
Europe has long been seen as a potential market for exports of fresh produce
from sub-Saharan Africa, although the challenges facing suppliers, particu-
larly in terms of value chain organization and quality control, have long been
evident (Jaffee, 2003). Evidence from a range of regions and countries shows
the potential and constraints of smallholder participation (Blandon et al.,
2009; Barrett et al., 2012). In Ethiopia, the participation of smallholder farmers
in marketing cooperatives has been found to be likely to reduce rural poverty
and increase agricultural commercialization (Francesconi and Heerink, 2011),
although welfare impacts on the poorest of agricultural exports are not always
as expected (Cramer et al., 2016).
The programme analysed here was designed to strengthen the export
capacity of vegetable farmers in Ethiopia and Sudan through the removal
of critical supply-side constraints and weaknesses in relation to technical,
infrastructural, and market factors. The project was implemented over three
years from May 2007 to April 2010. There was a further no-cost extension
phase from May 2010 to July 2011.
Here, only project implementation in Ethiopia is considered, and we
focus on four main components. The major outputs/activities of the project
intervention were:
http://dx.doi.org/10.3362/9781780449401.006
130 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
Questionnaire sample
A total of 23 farmers were interviewed. All were male, and all were
heads offamily with the exception of one who was the son of the head
of family. All households considered themselves to be middle-income.
Relevant personal and project participation data are presented in Table 6.1.
More than half of the farmers included in the sample were over the age
of30, and four over 50 years. Almost half had high-school or diploma-level
education. Halfof the sample had been with the project for three years, and
half for only oneyear.
Findings
Household asset building
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Access to land
Land tenure was a complicated issue, involving own land, rented land, and
share-cropping arrangements. These details were not investigated. The mean
land area devoted to agricultural production initially was 3.3 hectares, rising to
4.1 hectares at the end of the project. There was considerable variation in scale
of agricultural production, but many households were able to increase the
scale of production during the course of the project. None of the respondents
had grown green beans before the project, and the area under green beans was
a small proportion of the total under agricultural production.
Project services
All respondents acknowledged receiving services of agricultural extension,
training, and access to inputs by means of the revolving loan fund. When
asked about the adequacy of these particular services, results were positive:
almost all responses were that services were either adequate or very adequate.
A paired t-test comparing the responses inadequate with adequate/very
adequate showed a difference that was very highly significant.
Responses related to the specific content of production services received were
also generally positive but there were more responses affirming inadequacy.
Nevertheless, a paired t-test comparing the responses inadequate with adequate/
very adequate showed a difference that was highly significant (p = 0.0038).
These results were supported by qualitative data from a smallholder respondent:
We got knowledge on proper use of inputs, and my income has increased.
One key informant commented: The project success was on the production
side given the right skills, small farmers can produce (Ministry of
Agriculture respondent).
The project design addressed satisfactorily the issues of productive
capacity inputs and technical issues and the productive skills of the
growers. From being non-growers to successful growers and exporters of
green beans within three years (in some cases within one year) was a consid-
erable achievement: Training received from the project helped us to use
resources wisely and in a timely fashion (smallholder farmer). The inter-
vention was appropriate it did build capacity for farmers (farm manager,
commercial producer/exporter).
In contrast, very few respondents considered any of the marketing services
to be very adequate, and a considerable number considered the services to
be inadequate, notably in respect of market information, new markets,
and market linkages (Table 6.3). A paired t-test comparing the responses
inadequate with adequate/very adequate showed a difference that was not
significant at the 90 per cent level (p = 0.1319):
VEGETABLE EXPORT PROGRAMME IN ETHIOPIA 133
Quality of produce 2 14 2
Market information 7 10 0
New markets 9 7 0
Linkages 8 9 0
Supply consistency 3 13 1
Transport costs 3 10 3
Contract enforcement 2 10 4
Prices 5 13 3
Storage facilities 0 0 0
Suitable transport 3 13 2
Note: * Difference of means between inadequate and adequate/very adequate not significant
at the 90 per cent level (p = 0.1319)
Financial assets
Questions about savings and actual income gains were too complex to
gain useful information because of translation and conceptual problems.
Nevertheless, the positive changes in income and assets noted were
attributed to the impact of the project. Qualitative data were more helpful
than the quantitative data. A smallholder respondent said: Theproject
linked us to market and we got higher prices and therefore increased our
incomes.
In addition, in respect of new income-earning opportunities, qualitative
responses stated that the building of the pack-houses created additional
temporary employment opportunities in construction and also seasonal
work (which proved to be temporary because of the demise of the market).
Also, there was a growth of the market for transport through use of
donkeycarts.
Downstream activities
However, there were major weaknesses in the project. Most importantly, the
export of green beans was stopped by the commercial producer/exporter after
the three-year project finished, and therefore the project failed completely
to integrate smallholders into the export market in a sustainable manner.
Farmers were left with no export market and there never had been a domestic
market for green beans.
There was evident dissatisfaction with downstream activities: The supply
chain should be addressed in an integrated manner (production, harvesting,
grading, cold chain management, packing) (key informant from project-
executing agency).
134 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
Thus, the project badly failed to address marketing issues. This dissatisfaction
was highlighted in interviews with smallholders, many of whom commented
to the effect that:
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Sustainability
As the commercial producer/exporter stopped trading green beans at the end
of the project, the sustainable integration of the smallholders was unsuc-
cessful. Asone key informant commented: Farmers in Ethiopia are no
longer producing green beans because the exporter they were linked to is
no longer commercializing green beans (project-executing agency).
The negative comments are in response to the closure of the market at
the end of the project, even if the marketing during the project had been
considered successful:
Costs of quality
Another issue of direct relevance that surfaced in discussions was the high-cost
and demanding quality-assurance criteria for the European market. Much is
known of the challenges this poses to exporters in developing countries. For
smallholder cooperatives to gain and maintain access to European markets
without the intermediary services of a major commercial exporter requires a
different level of investment in capacity building and financial operation. The
conclusion drawn from the focus group discussions was that: There is a need
for continuous training on production, packing and market information.
And, from a key informant: The high cost of the certification is seen as
challenge for small farmers realization of quality-assurance certification
(project-executing agency).
VEGETABLE EXPORT PROGRAMME IN ETHIOPIA 135
Targeting
Another significant issue was the targeting of smallholders. All those
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
2. The project envisaged trying three crops, and possibilities need not
necessarily have been confined to these. Green beans and okra were
selected for the initial phase of the project, with possible additional crops
136 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
It is evident that risk was increased by the exclusive focus on the export
market, on one single crop, and on one single export organization in the
value chain. Moreover, risk was magnified through an inadequate counterpart
contribution which enabled the exporter to cease trading at the end of the
project without the incurring the penalty of sunk costs, leaving producers with
no market outlet. We can speculate likewise that the lack of competitiveness
in the new value chain can be attributed to the close relationship between the
project-executing agency and the commercial producer/exporter.
Conclusions
Project beneficiaries acknowledged that there had been income and livelihood
improvements which they attributed to the project, that they were able to
increase the scale of agricultural production overall, and in most cases tobuild
assets. Capacity building among farmers was a success: significant skills in
production were gained. However, the risks of asset switching into green
beans were high, and at least some of the assets have become redundant;
smallholders who invested in assets specific to green-bean production and
exporting will have incurred significant sunk costs. Therefore, some growers
may actually have been impoverished by participating in the project.
VEGETABLE EXPORT PROGRAMME IN ETHIOPIA 137
The demand for agricultural labour increased to meet the need for careful
picking of green beans, and there was a new demand for labour in the
construction and operation of the pack-houses. The acquisition of carts by
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Note
The 1,000 birr heuristic used to distinguish between minor and major
investments is a matter of judgement, and it is arguable that a cart and a
water pump, for example, should not be classified as minor investments but
as significant productive assets (U$1 = 23 birr on 24 May 2017).
References
Barrett, C.B., Bachke, M.E., Bellemare, M.F., Michelson, H.C., Narayanan, S.
and Walker, T.F. (2012). Smallholder participation in contract farming:
comparative evidence from five countries. World Development 40(4):
715730 <http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2011.09.006>.
Blandon, J., Henson, S. and Cranfield, J. (2009). Small-scale farmer partici-
pation in new agri-food supply chains: case of the supermarket supply chain
for fruit and vegetables in Honduras. Journal of International Development
21(7): 971984 <http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/jid.1490>.
Cramer, C., Johnston, D., Mueller, B., Oya, C. and Sender, J. (2016). Fairtrade
and labour markets in Ethiopia and Uganda. Journal of Development Studies
53(6): 841856 <http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00220388.2016.1208175>.
Francesconi, G.N. and Heerink, N. (2011). Ethiopian agricultural cooperatives
in an era of global commodity exchange: does organisational form matter?
Journal of African Economies 20(1): 153177 <https://doi.org/10.1093/jae/
ejq036>.
Jaffee, S. (2003). From Challenge to Opportunity: Transforming Kenyas fresh
vegetable trade in the context of emerging food safety and other standards in
Europe. Washington, DC, World Bank.
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
CHAPTER 7
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Project context
Programme design and implementation
The development of the oilseed sector in general, and of jatropha in particular,
offers opportunities for smallholder participation in the bioenergy industry
(Brittaine and Lutaladio, 2010). Nevertheless, linking smallholders into such
markets requires investment into more than production and marketing:
significant research requirements and interaction with public energy policies
presuppose coordination with the state and private enterprises, plus patient
capital investment. Mixed experiences mean that it is no longer considered to
be a miracle crop (Degail and Chantry, 2013).
The project in Peru and Honduras started in 2007 and was due to finish
in 2013. Working with small-scale agricultural cooperatives, it was designed
to reduce poverty and to improve the quality of the lives of the farmersby
improving the supply of and demand for rapeseed and Jatropha curcas.
Theprojects aim was to provide biodiesel as an alternative to conven-
tional fuels in Peru. The seeds would also be processed for the production of
vegetable oils as a substitute for diesel fuel in public transportation. Relevant
government institutions were part of several inception meetings to promote
the planting and marketing of jatropha.
The project was complex and, to some extent, experimental, with five
components and outputs. Essentially it was a privatepublic partnership between
donors, smallholder farmer groups, and small-scale companies in Peru and
http://dx.doi.org/10.3362/9781780449401.007
140 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
Demographic details
The project was implemented in four regions of Peru, and this study was
undertaken in districts of the Lambayeque region of the maritime north.
Twenty-nine (29) farmers were interviewed. The project was dominated by
men, with only three women as participants, reflecting the prevailing socio-
economic organization which has low participation of women in decision-
making positions for agricultural production and marketing.
The majority of farmers interviewed were aged 30 to 50 years and most of
them had completed secondary-school education. All but two were headsof
household. Details are shown in Table 7.1. The high level of education ofsome
of the participants (seven with tertiary education) was notable. Most farmers
were well-established in the area, with decades of residence and up to five
years of cooperative membership.
Findings
Not all quantitative data were complete, and data such as distance to market
were not informative, giving only a partial insight into the implementation
Project services
All respondents acknowledged receiving services of training, agricultural
extension, and access to inputs. When asked about the adequacy of these
particular services, results were positive: almost all responses rated them as
either adequate or very adequate (Table 7.2).
Despite these positive responses, many farmers commented about
constraints to productive capacity and the limits to information.
Productive capacity
Farmers noted that irrigation systems were crucial for increasing productive
capacity. However, in some of the project areas they faced acute shortages of
irrigation water. There were failures in the first plantations of jatropha that
were not irrigated and were inadequately fertilized owing to a lack of technical
information. Some had water reserves in wells approximately 80 metres deep
but problems were compounded because they did not have adequate pumping
facilities to extract the water from such deep wells.
Jatropha achieves optimum production in its sixth year, and this is the
period when farmers start to recover their investment. Most of the crop
inthe project area was in its fourth and fifth year, and yields were still low,
themaximum benefits having not yet been realized.
The seed production has dropped due to lack of water, we got an electric
water pump but we need help to install it.
We get little seed from the project; we need more seed to increase
production to be profitable.
The price at which we sell the jatropha does not represent all the work
required and the money spent to make it grow.
At the time of the research, it was evident that a small percentage of farmers
were likely to pull out of the project if support were not forthcoming for
necessary infrastructure, irrigation, fertilizers, harvesting, and market access.
PRODUCTION AND COMMERCIALIZATION OF OILSEEDS IN PERU 143
Sustainability
Since it takes five to six years for jatropha to be ready to harvest, it is necessary
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Public support
Farmers also criticized the lack of institutional development in terms of
overarching government strategy and post-harvest development activities for
the sector:
There is need to investigate how to detoxify the cake of jatropha for use
as stock-feed for cattle.
Impacts
Strengths
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Weaknesses
For farmers, jatropha is one element among other livelihood activities
such as food production and other income generation and is undertaken
within an institutional environment which needs a higher level of broad-
based sectoral support: competitive markets, accompanying technological
PRODUCTION AND COMMERCIALIZATION OF OILSEEDS IN PERU 145
Conclusions
These findings were endorsed in a final project report (GIZ 2013). The report
acknowledged that it was a risky venture characterized by high uncertainties
and lack of knowledge about important issues, especially the development of
the energy markets and the suitability of the jatropha plant as an economic
viable alternative for small farmers (GIZ, 2013: 3). The desire to provide partic-
ipation opportunities to smallholder farmers in renewable-energy markets was
admirable but the experimental nature of the project made the design and
implementation imperfect.
The political and environmental objectives of the project have not been
evaluated here. For all the complexities of the project, it is unsurprising
that the sustainability of the value chain model was not in any way assured
atthe time of the analyses. The report acknowledges that the many local
constraints to smallholder participation and small-enterprise development
were too serious to be overcome by the project intervention; similarly the
146 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
References
Brittaine, R. and Lutaladio, N. (2010). Jatropha: A Smallholder Bioenergy Crop.
The Potential for Pro-Poor Development. Integrated Crop Management Vol. 8,
International Fund for Agricultural Development/Food and Agriculture
Organization of the United Nations.
Degail, A.-C. and Chantry, J. (2013). Developing jatropha projects with
smallholder farmers: conditions for a sustainable win-win situation for
farmers and the project developer. Field Actions Science Reports [Online]
(Special Issue 7). Retrieved 23 May 2017, from https://factsreports.revues.
org/2182.
PRODUCTION AND COMMERCIALIZATION OF OILSEEDS IN PERU 147
Donovan, J., Blare, T. and Poole, N. (2017). Stuck in a rut: emerging cocoa
cooperatives in Peru and the factors that influence their performance.
International Journal of Agricultural Sustainability 15(2): 169184 <http://
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
dx.doi.org/10.1080/14735903.2017.1286831>.
GIZ (2013). Production of Oleaginous Plants and Commercializatiion of Natural
Vegetable Oils as Substitutes for Diesel Fuel for Public Transportation in Peru
and Honduras (CFC/FIGOOF/26). Retrieved 18 November 2016, from
http://common-fund.org/fileadmin/user_upload/Projects/FIGOOF/
FIGOOF_26/1.Technical_Report_Project_FIGOOF_26.pdf.
Poole, N.D. (2010). Zambia Cassava Sector Policy: Recommendations in support
of strategy implementation. EU-AAACP Paper Series. No. 16. Rome, Food and
Agriculture Organization of the United Nations. Retrieved 21 February 2017,
from http://www.fao.org/fileadmin/templates/est/AAACP/pacific/07_FAO_
AAACP_Paper_Series16_Recommendations_Zambia_Cassava_Strat.pdf.
Poole, N.D., Chitundu, M., Msoni, R. and Tembo, I. (2010). Constraints to
Smallholder Participation in Cassava Value Chain Development in Zambia.
EU-AAACP Paper Series. No. 15. Rome, Food and Agriculture Organization
of the United Nations. Retrieved 21 February 2017, from http://www.fao.
org/fileadmin/templates/est/AAACP/eastafrica/FAO_AAACP_Paper_Series_
No_15_Constraints_to_smallholder_participa%C3%83__1_.pdf.
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
CHAPTER 8
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Project context
Programme design and implementation
Sisal (Agave sisalana) is a robust plant which can grow under adverse environ-
mental conditions and produces a fibre for transformation into products such
as rope, twine, carpets, yarn, and newer products such as paper. The case for
there being market potential for a sustainable, renewable natural resource is
strong (Shamte, undated). The production of sisal in Tanzania dates back to
the era of German East Africa in the 19th century. Historically a plantation
crop, there have been efforts to increase participation by smallholders since
the early 1960s and the potential contribution of sisal to smallholder farming
and wider economic development has been recognized (FAO Committee on
Commodity Problems, 2013).
The project was designed to develop new sisal and henequen productsand
build the market for these products. The project had a multi-pronged and
integrated value chain development approach, embracing both agricultural
improvement and industrial product-development, both of which were
supported by appropriate research efforts.
Project activities were implemented in Tanzania and Kenya during the
period January 1997 to December 2005. Both countries have large smallholder
farmer sectors and long-standing aspirations to encourage farmers to engage
in commercial markets and contribute to wider sectoral development in order
to escape the trap of the subsistence economy. The analysis here is based only
on the research undertaken in Tanzania.
http://dx.doi.org/10.3362/9781780449401.008
150 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
In the 1960s, Tanzania was the largest producer of sisal in the world, but the
industry suffered declines in output in subsequent decades. The potential for
this endemic crop remains, and the industry weaknesses of inadequate research
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Findings
Questionnaire sample
A total of 40 farmers from Korongwe District in Tanga region were interviewed,
20 each from two commercial estates. Respondent categories and numbers
are shown in Table 8.1.
All the farmers interviewed were heads of family except one female who was
a spouse. Thirty-four households considered themselves to be middle-income.
Three households considered themselves poor and the other three households
very poor. Other beneficiary characteristics are presented in Table 8.2,
illustrating the relatively advanced age of participants, relatively low levels of
education, and long-standing presence in the region. Most respondents lived
within five miles of a road and the produce collection point and a service
centre. The most distant lived 1518 kilometres away.
Household assets
Respondents were asked to indicate significant assets they had before and after
the project. In assessing the magnitude of change in household assets, the
responses were classified as follows:
Agricultural assets
In assessing agricultural assets, respondents were asked to indicate what
significant agricultural assets they had before and after the project. Responses
were classified as follows: no change, minor, moderate, or major upgrades:
harvesting my sisal.
Access to land
Most households reported an increase of agricultural land under cultivation
during the projects. The mean land area devoted to agricultural production
initially was 2.3 hectares, rising to 12.4 hectares.
The yields were mostly less than 2 tonnes per hectare, much lower
thanpotential yields, which were estimated to be 4 tonnes per hectare.
Onekey informant, a plant protection specialist from an agricultural research
institute, commented: Current yields for smallholder farmers are low. With
good husbandry practices (good planting material, preparation of nurseries
and not planting suckers), smallholder farmers can achieve the potential
yield of 4 tonnes per hectare.
Project services
A total of 25 farmers (63 per cent) indicated that they had received training,
35 (88 per cent) had received extension support, and 17 (43 per cent)
received planting material from the project. Respondents were asked about
the adequacy of the services provided by the project. The majority of the
responses were negative: 61 per cent of the farmers rated the adequacy of
thetraining offered by the project as inadequate; 60 per cent rated extension
as inadequate; and 88 per cent rated the provision of inputs (planting
material)as inadequate. No participants indicated that the level of services
provision was very adequate. These findings were supported by qualitative
information from the smallholder farmers:
The project should have put more emphasis on technology for planting
material of sisal and equipment. Currently, we are using sisal suckers
instead of using pure materials.
The project did not have sufficient funding to support training, inputs
and extension to the smallholder farmers (executive director, agro-
processing firm and former national project officer).
Leaf spot disease (korogwe) is still a problem which has not been
addressed and this affects the quality of sisal fibre. There is need for
SISAL PRODUCT AND MARKET DEVELOPMENT IN TANZANIA 153
All the respondents indicated that pests and diseases were a major constraint
(particularly the korogwe leaf spot) and were inadequately addressed by the
project. Access to credit was also viewed as one of the most inadequately
addressed issues; 84 per cent of the farmers who responded to the question rated
it inadequate: The project should have provided loans to assist land preparation,
planting, and harvesting and Credit to meet farmers farming operations
(field maintenance and purchase of inputs) should have been addressed.
One key informant commented: Lack of credit is a major constraint
affecting both the sisal production and productivity in the smallholder sector
(sisal plant protection specialist, agricultural research institute).
The training on post-harvest handling skills was rated only inadequate or
adequate. Actual post-harvest handling, for storage and for the decorticator/
brushing facilities, was generally perceived to be adequate as this wereprovided
by a private agro-processing firm.
Other constraints that were highlighted during interviews were the high
production and processing costs, and the competition for labour with other
sectors, which contributed to the high costs.
Adequacy of marketing
Farmers did not perceive price formation to be straightforward. The small-
holders produced and marketed leaf sisal but the price paid to the farmers was
based on the fibre content. The processing of the leaf into fibre was undertaken
by a private agro-processor which was responsible for most marketing
functions. From the qualitative information collected, respondents indicated
that the issues of product prices received by farmers and the costs of transport
needed to be addressed. Farmers should be represented in the marketing and
setting of prices so that they can receive a fair price.
One key informant commented about the unrealized opportunity for
smallholders to add value: Farmers could get a better price if they were selling
fibre as opposed to the leaf. Processing costs take 60 per cent and the farmer
gets the remaining 40 per cent (official, Sisal Farmers Association/Tanzania
Sisal Board).
On transport, farmers felt that the leaf transportation service should be
improved by the private agro-processor, because there were not enough vehicles:
Leaf transportation should be improved, there are not enough vehicles/
tractors to meet demand of farmers.
Financial assets
Data on actual income gained were incomplete. However, respondents were
asked whether there was income gain as a result of the project. A total of
22farmers out of the 32 farmers who responded to the question were positive.
154 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
Five farmers indicated there was no change in their income. The reasons
given were that the area under sisal was still small while input costs were
high and therefore they were only able to break even. One key informant
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
also commented: Major constraints that have limited production are the high
input costs relating to clearing land, high cost of labour and lack of access to
credit to fund sisal-farming operations (group manager, agro-processor).
Social assets
A total of 38 of the 40 farmers interviewed indicated that they had joined
the smallholder producer organizations. Some farmers in Mwelya Estate
indicated that they were members of the Savings and Credit Union. One
smallholder farmer commented: My income has increased. I can now make
savings with the Savings and Credit Union.
Conclusions
The project facilitated smallholder farmers to participate in commercially
oriented sisal production activities. Sisal has increased some smallholder
earnings in the drought-prone areas.
While the project design addressed partially the issue of access to land,
other production aspects (inputs, technical issues) were not satisfactorily
addressed. Training in sisal husbandry was inadequate, extension support
was weak, and there was lack of access to credit. These factors have had an
impact on the production and productivity of sisal by smallholder farmers.
Securing adequate land-tenancy arrangements, as opposed to land access,
was incomplete because farmers did not have title deeds to the land for use
as collateral for lending. This constrained their access to credit. One key
informant commented: A major constraint that limits farmers participation
in the market is that farmers do not have title deeds to the land and this
has limited their access to credit (official, Sisal Farmers Association/Tanzania
Sisal Board).
Human asset formation was inadequate: the project did not adequately
address farmers production and post-harvest skills. Provision of servicesto
farmers was also deficient: there was a perceived lack of adequate transport
to take produce from the farm to the processing facility. Not only was
the weakness in the value chain link between producers and processor
responsible for insufficient services and inputs, but inefficiencies also
impaired product quality at both production and processing stages:
The issue of targeting is also significant in this case study. Project benefi-
ciaries were selected on a voluntary basis. There was an advertisement and
SISAL PRODUCT AND MARKET DEVELOPMENT IN TANZANIA 155
anybody was free to apply. Personal data collected reflect that some partici-
pants were formally employed elsewhere and some had university degrees but
there were also some low-income smallholder farmers. The question of who
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
failed to create competition in the market for services delivery and product
sales. Greater foresight concerning wider market structures and the implica-
tions of economic power for benefit distribution could have led to more equal
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
References
FAO Committee on Commodity Problems (2013). Potential Constraints to
Smallholder Integration into the Developing Sisal Value Chain in Tanzania.
CCP:HF/JU 13/3. Rome, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United
Nations.
Kimaro, D., Msanya, B.M. and Takamura, Y. (1994). Review of sisal production
and research in Tanzania. African Study Monographs 15(4): 227242.
Shamte, S. (undated). Overview of the Sisal and Henequen Industry: A Producers
Perspective. FAO Corporate Document Repository. Rome, Food and Agriculture
Organization of the United Nations. Retrieved 28 March 2017, from http://
www.fao.org/docrep/004/Y1873E/y1873e05.htm.
CHAPTER 9
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Project context
The project analysed here was implemented in Lesotho and Zambia over a
four year period up to 2012, and was aimed at improving the productivity and
http://dx.doi.org/10.3362/9781780449401.009
158 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
The direct beneficiaries of the project were the smallholder dairy farmers.
Secondary beneficiaries were considered to be the milk processors and also
consumers who benefited from increased local milk supplies and better-
quality milk.
Thirty-nine farmers (25 male and 14 female) from seven districts, mainly
in the southern provinces of Zambia, were interviewed. Respondent numbers
are shown in Table 9.1.
The majority of the farmers interviewed were male heads of families
(31 of the39 households were headed by men). Most of the farmers were over
50years of age and the level of education was very high; most had completed
secondary education and had also attained a tertiary qualification in the form
of a certificate or a diploma. Further, the majority of these farmers had lived
in these districts for more than 10 years (Table 9.2).
The mean distances of the respondents from the main road and the milk-
collection point were both just over 5 kilometres, a relatively small distance
for transport given adequate facilities, and the mean distance to the major
service centre was about 18 kilometres.
membership
2530 12 Primary 7 None 13 Pre-2000 2 <10 3
3050 1 High school 32 Certificate 17 200007 35 1030 21
>50 25 Diploma 8 Post-2008 1 3050 8
Degree 1 >50 6
Findings
Household and agricultural assets
Respondents were asked to indicate significant household assets owned
before and after the project. Asset accumulation was indicated by increases in
ownership of bicycles, radio, and television sets after the project (Table 9.3).
Land utilization by respondents also increased from a mean of 10.2 hectares
to 13.9 hectares, attributed by farmers to the need for more land to grow feed
for the dairy cows. There was considerable variation among respondents.
Project services
A total of 37 of the sample of 39 farmers indicated having received training,
33 received extension support, 32 received feed-planting material, and
29 received information from the project. The majority of respondents
considered the services provision to be adequate and only 19 per cent considered
the services inadequate. Inputs and information provision scored very low
(Table 9.4).
Responses concerning the issues identified by participants as constraints
to the production of milk in the various districts varied. For example only
six farmers considered the distributed inputs to be inadequate, compared
with 20 who considered that the provision of credit was inadequate. A small
160 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
Inadequate 4 14 10 2
Adequate 22 15 12 11
Very adequate 10 7 4 2
No response 2 3 13 24
primary producers.
The increased price range and the enhanced value chain linkages
were seen as sustainable, resulting in net returns to farmers of more than
US$0.25per litre, making smallholder dairy a sustainable source of daily
disposable income. It must be noted that the improved participation of
dairy farmers cannot solely be attributed to this project, as a number of
projects had been implemented in the past and some even overlapped with
this project.
Productivity measures
An increase in the survival rate of calves was attributed by most respondents to
the activities of the project, which helped to enhance animal husbandry.
Milk production per cow rose significantly from a mean of 4.1 litres to
8.4litres per day. With increased cow numbers and increased productivity,
participating farmers saw total milk output per day rise from an average of
29.8litres to 81.3 litres.
Milk losses were eliminated through the installation of generators by the
project: the mean loss of 30 per cent fell to zero per cent.
Conclusions
The project facilitated farmers penetration into the commercial milk-production
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
valuable price premiums. The value chain was strengthened through effective
collective organization which facilitated processing and marketing. In terms
of physical capital, significant investment was evidently attributable to the
project. Investment in farmers human assets was more limited.
References
Flores-Martinez, A., Zanello, G., Shankar, B. and Poole, N. (2016). Reducing
anemia prevalence in Afghanistan: socioeconomic correlates and the
particular role of agricultural assets. PLoS One 11(6): e0156878 <https://doi.
org/10.1371/journal.pone.0156878>.
Hoddinott, J., Headey, D. and Dereje, M. (2015). Cows, missing milk markets,
and nutrition in rural Ethiopia. Journal of Development Studies 51(8): 958975
<http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00220388.2015.1018903>.
Jodlowski, M., Winter-Nelson, A., Baylis, K. and Goldsmith, P.D. (2016).
Milk in the data: food security impacts from a livestock field experiment
in Zambia. World Development 77: 99114 <https://doi.org/10.1016/
j.worlddev.2015.08.009>.
Maestre, M., Poole, N. and Henson, S. (2017). Assessing food value chain
pathways, linkages and impacts for better nutrition of vulnerable groups.
Food Policy 68: 3139 <http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2016.12.007>.
Rawlins, R., Pimkina, S., Barrett, C.B., Pedersen, S. and Wydick, B. (2014). Got
milk? The impact of Heifer Internationals livestock donation programs in
Rwanda on nutritional outcomes. Food Policy 44: 202213 <https://doi.org/
10.1016/j.foodpol.2013.12.003>.
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
CHAPTER 10
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
http://dx.doi.org/10.3362/9781780449401.010
166 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
Lessons learned
Overall results
Overall, project activities had a positive impact on market participation.
Inorder to assess empirically how changes in asset indicators influenced
market participation, a logit regression analysis was applied to the entire
set of survey data. The selected independent variables covered the asset
indicators from the livelihood assessment approach as described in Table 10.1.
This shows summary and comparative results for all cases broken down into
the five livelihood assets: natural, human, social, physical, and financial.
Household and farm characteristics contributing significantly to the model
were added on the basis of the resulting goodness of fit measured by the log
likelihood chi-square. Also, variables with multicollinearity were identified
and droppedfrom the model.
The variables education, wealth, farm size, district, and age of the household
were found to improve the explanatory power of the model. The resulting
odds ratios and standard errors are shown in Table 10.2. The likelihood ratio
chi-square of 46.4 with a p-value less than 0.05 shows that the resulting
model as a whole fits significantly better than a model with no independent
variables. This means that the explanatory variables included contribute
jointly towards explaining smallholders market participation patterns. Access
to extension services and training, expansion in private productive agricultural
assets, access to credit, district, farm size, age of the household, and wealth had
significant influence on market access. All these variables were significant at
the 10 per cent level, except for the variables access to credit and district, which
were significant at the 5 percent level.
PROJECT IMPACT: SYNTHESIS AND CONCLUSIONS 167
Table 10.3 Probability changes in market access for changes in explanatory variables
Change in variable Probability Change in probability of market access
Access to extension
Inadequate to adequate 0.2800.865 +0.585
Access to credit
Inadequate to adequate 0.3480.924 +0.576
Wealth
Poor to middle-income 0.1210.729 +0.601
The result from the logit regression also showed that the likelihood of
an improvement in market access increased with the geographic location,
or district. Smallholders located in districts with a tradition of commer-
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
project. Milk quality increased, allowing for longer shelf life and improved
product safety. From a mean loss of 30 per cent, milk losses were eliminated as
a result of the installation of generators for cooling milk funded by the project.
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
adequate. However, when aggregating the results across all four projects, 50per
cent of the surveyed smallholders felt that the issue of lack of credit was not
adequately addressed through project activities.
On the other hand, access to extension services and technology was
considered adequate (Tables 10.6 and 10.7). On aggregate, improved access to
technology was associated with better market integration for 67 per cent of
the survey respondents. The impact of technology adoption can be assessed
by looking at changes in productivity levels. For example, Table 10.8 compares
yields for green beans before and after project implementation in Ethiopia.
It shows that yields were relatively higher following the project, and the
difference between yield levels was statistically significant at the 5 per cent
level. Similarly, in Zambia, milk production per cow increased by more than
100 per cent. About 82 per cent of the respondents attributed this change to
the project (Table 10.9).
Table 10.8 Paired t-test on green beans yields, before and after project
Variable obs Mean Std err. Std dev. [95% Conf. interval]
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Note: a90: green bean yields (tonnes/ha) before project; a91: green bean yields (tonnes/ha)
after project
Table 10.9 Percentage changes in milk output per cow (litres), before and after project
Before the project After the project Percentage change
Mean 4.1 8.4 104
Minimum 0.2 1.4 600
Maximum 14 20 42
8.5 per cent and 2.3 per cent considered themselves as poor andvery poor,
respectively. This implies that project activities effectively targeted the better-
endowed smallholders. As noted in the conclusions, this feature of targeting
may or may not be an intentional objective of smallholder market-access
projects.
Table 10.11 illustrates this targeting phenomenon, showing that 112 out
of 128 (87.5 per cent) of smallholders were middle-income households with
an average landholding of 5.3 hectares, which is 208 per cent more than
households classified as poor. Middle-income smallholders also had a higher
level of education (Table 10.12) and reported, on average, having more
household assets prior to the project than poor households.
Second, the field survey revealed weaknesses in the design and imple-
mentation of the marketing component of the projects, which should have
included activities specifically designed to build sustainable value chain
linkages. Participating smallholders generally felt that their skills in marketing
174 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
Very poor 0 0 3
Poor 1.7 2.15 11
Middle income 5.3 11.47 112
Rich 1 1.41 2
Total 4.8 10.83 128
Capacity development
Participatory approaches and training are necessary to increase smallholder
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Conclusions
As noted at the end of Chapter 1, this book addresses two sets of issues:
based on literature and field experiences it promised to indicate the strengths
and weaknesses of interventions and initiatives formulated to improve
smallholder market access; and evaluate improving market access as an
approach which contributes to bigger development goals. The purpose of the
empirical Chapters 69 in Part 2 was to present evidence and draw lessons
from the determinants of successes and failures of selected CFC/FAO projects
in assisting smallholder farmers to participate (and/or participate on more
favourable terms) in agricultural markets/value chains.
The results summarized here are consistent with the evidence from the
literature on the importance of stimulating the market-participation capacity
of smallholders. Without an enabling environment that enhances their
natural, human, social, physical, and financial assets, smallholders do not
have the appropriate incentives or opportunities to participate in markets.
The results of the field surveys conducted in the four countries showed that
project activities targeting the five market-participation capacity indicators
described in the methodology section, did contribute to strengthening market
access and linkages.
On the basis of the four country case studies, and using both qualitative
andquantitative methods, a series of lessons and best practices in designing
PROJECT IMPACT: SYNTHESIS AND CONCLUSIONS 179
logical conditions. Only a few poor and very poor smallholders were selected as
participants in the projects. This bias towards the better-endowed smallholders
generates the best economic returns to the intervention, but it implies that the
most marginal and poorest rural people were likely to be excluded as benefi-
ciaries although some benefits may have accrued to them through second-
order effects, mostly in terms of increased opportunities in local labour markets.
Smallholders are a heterogeneous group facing different types of constraints to
market access and, as such, the initial objective of a commodity-development
project should be to articulate clearly the nature of those constraints relevant
to each category of smallholders, so that project execution is well-focused and
likely to benefit the intended beneficiaries.
The analysis of the field survey data suggested that project activities
addressing all five market participation capacity indicators contributed to
strengthening market linkages. Further, improvements in smallholder market
participation were associated with project activities that focused on extension,
training and demonstrations, and support in building up productive agricul-
tural assets. Gains in market participation were also correlated with the initial
condition related to household and farm characteristics such as wealth, land
size, asset ownership, and a favourable agroecological environment. Access to
credit was found to significantly influence access to markets, highlighting the
positive role of credit-support activities which constituted, in several instances,
a core component of CFC/FAO projects. Favourable institutional and market
environments were also factors predisposing towards project success.
The study surveys showed that technology adoption had a significant
impact on smallholders. Yields per hectare were improved significantly in
the case of projects involving crop activities (Ethiopia, Tanzania, and Peru),
while milk yield per cow was increased twofold on average in Zambia.
Project-specific activities were a factor behind the increases in produc-
tivity. These involved providing training to smallholders on good crop and
livestock production practices, and provision of planting materials, market
information, and subsidized fertilizers. In the case of Ethiopia, the project
instituted a revolving loan fund to be used by the smallholders cooperative
for the purchase of inputs. As a result, smallholders managed to success-
fully grow and export green beans, at least for the lifetime of the project.
Inthe case of the jatropha project in Peru, farmers learned new production
techniques, including pruning, use of organic manure, bioinsecticide
use, and utilization of bees to pollinate crops. Increases in earnings from
commercial farming triggered additional incentives to generate production
surpluses, notably during the initial years following the implementation of
project activities.
Given the existing bias in the selection of participating smallholders,
project activities and policy recommendations need to be specific to the
180 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
References
Amrouk, El M., Poole, N.D., Mudungwe, N. and Muzvondiwa, E. (2013).
TheImpact of Commodity Development Projects on Smallholders Market Access
in Developing Countries: Case Studies of FAO/CFC Projects. Rome, United
Nations Food and Agriculture Organization. Retrieved 28 March 2017,
from http://www.fao.org/docrep/017/aq290e/aq290e.pdf.
World Bank (2017). Enabling the Business of Agriculture 2017. Washington, DC,
World Bank.
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
CHAPTER 11
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
http://dx.doi.org/10.3362/9781780449401.011
184 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
of lessons for upscaling good practice, but this argument comes with a
warning. It constitutes a plea or pronouncement, or even a provocation as
a corrective to the conclusion that market-access experiences can necessarily
be replicated and upscaled into policy. It is a framework for action, or a
manifesto, to scale down policymaking from the macro to the micro, meaning
that policymaking should be downscaled to the local level, building on local
knowledge and understanding of specific people and contexts. Actually, itis
not a question of either upscaling or downscaling, but of rebalancing the
onus of responsibility for development policy, programmes, and projects
towards the local context and away from the central axes of development
decision making.
A macro perspective
The Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs) provide the current framework
forunderstanding and formulating strategies. But strategies are only the
basisfor policies which then have to be operationalized through programmes,
projects, and local processes. As we move from the outer ring of Figure 1.1,
embracing the macro issues of development, towards the inner ring, which
includes the livelihoods of poor agricultural smallholders who are our focus, in
a geographical sense we downscale from the global to continental, tonational,
to regional, to district, to local micro issues.
Food quantity
There are huge challenges in feeding the world. While innovative food sources
such as insects, bacteria, and seaweed, among others, will be developed and
may become acceptable to consumers over the 21st century, there is still a
need to increase areas of production, increase productivity, and change food
sources and diets. There are limited areas for the expansion of food production,
but those there are lie largely in developing regions. Thedata reviewed in
Chapter 1 illustrated the productivity gap between advanced-country agricul-
tural systems and these developing regions, offering considerable opportunity
for increasing food supplies.
Many developing regions are characterized by fragile ecosystems:
poorersoils than the productive temperate regions, extreme temperature
regimes, and suboptimal rainfall patterns. Meteorological extremes are
already increasing; this is likely a consequence of climate change and, so
far, international agreements have not been effective in halting the rate of
global warming. While there isneed for large-scale investments to exploit
the constrained potential of theserelatively unproductive lands, they
are precisely where smallholder agriculture also is an important mode of
production.
186 Smallholder Agriculture and Market Participation
Sustainability
The Sustainable Development Goals, concerning the many issues challenging
all nations, have attracted the attention of the global community. Among
other things, agriculture and downstream sectors make a large direct contri-
butionto the problems as well as potential solutions, not least to global
warming through direct and indirect greenhouse-gas emissions. For agriculture
and rural activities in general, sustainability implies proper management of
the natural resources base: water, soils, biodiversity, pastures, woodland and
forests, and air. Increasing utilization of more sophisticated technologies must
be consistent with indeed, supportive of sustainable intensification.
For development practitioners, difficult questions surround these challenges:
how much will these changed practices happen autonomously, guided by the
invisible hand of markets? How much will they require a policy response from
governments and supranational organizations to address market failures?
How much collective will to make an effective policy response is there in
the international community? We will see by 2030 whether the SDGs have
been the right ones and how successfully policies have been operationalized.
It will become evident how much progress has been achieved in orienting
agriculture towards the quality and quantity of food delivered to consumers
that will be needed to meet the 2030 Goals.
A sectoral perspective
Health and food quality
Market participation is not an end in itself, but for most smallholders
is a means towards the end of earning a living and overcoming poverty
challenges. We noted above the importance of production which sustains
the natural environment. Besides this stewardship function, agriculture
can directly address major health challenges. Agriculture can make a direct
contribution towards reducing the undernutrition that causes costly and
distressing human, social, and economic underdevelopment. Agricultures
contribution as an input to the local and global food industries is also linked
GOING LOCAL WITH DEVELOPMENT POLICIES 187
The global food system is a major driver of the demand for specific crops and
livestock products, the overconsumption of which is implicated in the rise in
non-communicable diseases attributed to processed meats and dairy products,
sugar, and palm oil among other foodstuffs. This suggests that smallholder
agriculture should be not only efficient and profitable but also sensitive
to consumers nutritional requirements, particularly in respect of micro-
nutrients. There are theoretical reasons, and plenty of evidence, to expect
smallholders to be able, efficiently and sustainably, to supply value chains
for high-nutrient quality foods such as fruits and vegetables. Smallholders
can exploit potential competitive advantages in supplying local marketswith
foods of high nutrient quality, whose consumption in many developing
regions needs to rise to meet nutritional quality objectives.
power and roads and bridges; market supply and demand for all sorts of goods
and services depend on timely and accurate information using hard telecom-
munications and soft knowledge. The growing body of evidence that access
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
practitioners who know the localities better than national policymakers and
international donors and experts based in the capital. Decentralizing respon-
sibilities does not only require a governance structure but is also conditional
upon having the appropriate human capacity at the regional, provincial, and
district levels. While insecurity persists, staffing remote areas is problematic.
In Afghanistan, peace-building is an absolute necessity but, given greater
security and stability, downscaling development responsibilities to the local
context is an approach that could respond to the plea made in this postscript.
Coordination betweenprovinces also offers an approach to the territorial
nature of the development context.
Transnational territorial approaches to apparently intractable local
development challenges may seem idealistic and improbable, but other
approaches have failed to make an impact. However, there is a governance
principle of subsidiarity to which we can appeal for support: adopting
theprinciple of subsidiarity enables decision making and intervention to
be undertaken at a level as close as possible to the citizen or stakeholder,
i.e.as little centralized as can be made to work competently.
The approach proposed here suggests the following three methods to
downscale actions for market development and other broader responsibilities,
which may find echoes in other contexts:
The final question is where to start downscaling? By all means, let national
governments re-envision policy processes by adopting decentralized and
territorial approaches to development. But a significant first move is needed
by policy and decision makers, and researchers within the architecture
GOING LOCAL WITH DEVELOPMENT POLICIES 191
Reference
Poole, N., Echavez, C. and Rowland, D. (2016). Stakeholder Perceptions of
Agriculture and Nutrition Policies and Practice: Evidence from Afghanistan.
LANSA Working Paper Number 9. Chennai, India, Leveraging Agriculture for
Nutrition in South Asia (LANSA), MS Swaminathan Research Foundation.
Retrieved 24 May 2017, from http://ims.ids.ac.uk/sites/ims.ids.ac.uk/
files/documents/Mapping%20stakeholder%20perceptions%20%20
Afghanistan%20on%20template_0.pdf.
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244
Index
Page numbers in italics refer to boxes and tables.
World Development 56
Garca-Martnez, M. and Poole, N.D. 107 individual and collective decision making
gender see households; women models 43
Ghana 47, 74 inequality and opportunity, market
formal contracts 95 exclusion and inclusion 235
Global Index Insurance Facility (GIIF) information
99100, 101 finance services 6871
governance 190 knowledge management 190
government roles and interventions risk management 96, 97
finance 667 infrastructure 1878
insurance 87, 97, 99, 1001 innovation 15, 20
price stabilization 91 financial services/insurance 67, 737, 97,
public-private sector partnerships 745, 1001
767, 87 institutional 401
risk management 957, 111 livestock feeding technologies 121, 158,
staple foods for domestic consumption 1701
1045 as market-related indicator 124
green beans risk management 110
from Madagascar 109 institutions
see also Ethiopia: diversification innovation 401
programme for vegetable export role and transaction costs 457
development insurance
group lending 67 for agricultural development 97101,
Guyer, J.L. 50, 51, 52, 53 978
compulsory crop 74
Haddad, L. et al. 42, 43 government provision 1001
Hardaker, J.B. et al. 72 government regulation and legislation
Harper, M. et al. 37, 118 97, 99
health risk layering 845, 867
and food quality 1867 types 98100
nutrition-related indicators 7, 8 interactions and trade-offs 512
Helmsing, A.H.J. and Vellema, S. 24, 44, 58, international commodity agreements
5960 67, 90
heterogeneity 13, 179, 184, 188 international fresh produce markets 1089
Afghanistan 189 international fresh produce-chains 1024
households 203 International Research Centre, Canada 57
households internationally traded commodities 1067
economic decisions 42, 434 internationally traded speciality
heterogeneity 203 commodities 1078
and livelihoods 4853 interventions
management decisions 434 case studies 12930, 146, 1556, 157, 162
market decisions 445 impact of projects 11718, 122, 1267,
modelling 423 169, 1767, 17880
human assets 49, 123, 167 see also development policies; government
Human Development Report 24 roles and interventions
investment 51
IFAD 15, 50 in local government 190
impacts see commodity
developmentprojects Jaffee, S. 129
index-based insurance 101 et al. 812
and indemnity, differences between 98 Siegel, P. and 82, 83
India 23 Jatropha see Peru: oilseed production
indicators 28 for biofuel
development goals 89
health and nutrition-related 7, 8 Karamojong people, Uganda 245
impact of projects 1659, 1789 Karembu, M. 15
livelihood asset 1223 knowledge management 190
196 SMALLHOLDER AGRICULTURE AND MARKET PARTICIPATION
production costs 46, 47, 48, 82, 143, Siegel, P. and Jaffee, S. 82, 83
150, 184 sisal see Tanzania: sisal product and
productivity 1617 marketdevelopment
http://www.developmentbookshelf.com/doi/book/10.3362/9781780449401 - Friday, December 01, 2017 1:35:47 PM - IP Address:98.22.180.244