Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

Defense Economics: Achievements and Challenges: January 2007

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 15

See

discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/23697524

Defense economics: Achievements and


challenges

Article · January 2007


DOI: 10.15355/2.1.45 · Source: RePEc

CITATIONS READS

6 4,134

1 author:

Keith Hartley
The University of York
224 PUBLICATIONS 2,413 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Economics of Arms Industries View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Keith Hartley on 03 June 2014.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Proceedings of the 10th Annual International Conference on Economics and Security

Defence Economics: Achievements and Challenges1

Keith Hartley

Centre for Defence Economics, University of York, York, YO 10 5DD, UK,


e-mail: kh2@york.ac.uk

1. Introduction
Defence economics is a relatively new part of the discipline of economics. One of
the first specialist contributions in the field was by Hitch and McKean, The
Economics of Defense in the Nuclear Age (1960). This article presents an
overview of the achievements and challenges for defence economics. The
achievements are based on a review of papers published in the journal Defence
and Peace Economics, especially publications and progress since the tenth
anniversary issue. The focus is on coverage of topics, including Special Issues.
Major gaps in coverage are identified.

The choice of topics for challenges facing defence economics represents a


personal view. These include the defence economics problems; UK nuclear
weapons policy; project case studies based on the example of the Eurofighter
Typhoon; the military production function and the role of military outsourcing;
and some data problems illustrated with reference to the costs of conflict and the
Iraq war.

2. Achievements
2.1.Definitions

The definition of defence economics has evolved to reflect new threats and new
policy developments. During the Cold War and in its immediate aftermath,
defence economics was defined as the economic study of defence, disarmament,
conversion and peace. In the post-Cold War environment, the focus has been on
1
This paper is reproduced from The Economics of Peace and Security Journal with kind
permission of the Editors.

1
Proceedings of the 10th Annual International Conference on Economics and Security

the economics of war and peace. Modern definitions embrace the study of wars
and conflicts both conventional and non-conventional conflict. Examples include
the economic study of civil wars, revolutions and terrorism (e.g. Brauer, 2003;
Barros and Sandler, 2003; Hartley, 2007; Hegre and Sandler, 2002).

Some of the pioneering contributions in the field were dominated by US


economists (US economists are less dominant today). These included:

i) Models of arms races (e.g. Richardson (1960); Intriligator and Brito


(1989; Schelling (1966)))

ii) Economic theories of alliances (e.g. Olson and Zeckhauser (1966);


Sandler (1988)).

iii) The demand for military expenditure (e.g. R. Smith (1980))

iv) Defence, growth and development (e.g. Benoit (1973))

v) The economics of military personnel, especially an all-volunteer force


(Hansen and Weisbrod (1967); Oi (1967)). Here, it is interesting to
compare UK and US experience. The UK introduced an all-volunteer
force earlier than the USA, but compared with America, UK economists
were not actively involved in the policy debate.

vi) Procurement and contracting (e.g. Peck and Scherer (1962)).2

Since the end of the Cold War and in the post-Cold War world, there have been
some new developments in defence economics. These reflected the end of the
Cold War, globalisation and new security threats in the form of international
terrorism (e.g. 9/11 attacks on the USA: see Sandler and Hartley, 2007). These
new developments include:

i) Economic studies of disarmament and the peace dividend (e.g. Hartley,


K., et al, 1993). Here, a novel contribution was the analysis of
disarmament as an investment process.

ii) The arms trade (e.g. Levine, Sen and Smith, 2000)

iii) Terrorism (e.g. Sandler, 1992)

iv) Economic studies of conflict (Hartley and Sandler, 2003). Compare


market analysis with conflict. Markets are characterised by voluntary
trade and exchange based on the price mechanism; by markets in
equilibrium; and by the growth of output (creative power). In complete
2
A detailed reference list for these pioneering contributions is provided in Sandler and Hartley
(1995).

2
Proceedings of the 10th Annual International Conference on Economics and Security

contrast, conflict uses military force to achieve a re-allocation of


resources; markets are in disequilibrium (chaos); conflict destroys
markets; and conflict focuses on destructive power rather than creative
power (i.e. it involves the destruction of physical and human capital).

v) Economics of peace-keeping (e.g. Solomon and Berkok, 2006).

2.2. The journal: Defence and Peace Economics

2.2.1. Background

The journal provides an indicator of the development of defence economics and


its establishment as a reputable sub-discipline of economics (c.f. health
economics). The journal was launched in 1990 with the title Defence Economics
and was published four times a year. There was a UK Managing Editor, a North
American Editor dealing with North American papers reflecting the presence of a
substantial number of US defence economists, together with an international
Editorial Board. In 1995, it was renamed Defence and Peace Economics to reflect
the post-Cold War security changes and the increasing focus on disarmament,
conversion and peace issues. In 2000, publication was increased to six issues per
year which is a further reflection of the growing academic interest in the field. In
late 2006, the typical lag between acceptance of a paper and its publication was
about 12 months.

2.2.2. Features of the journal

Whilst the journal focuses on economics papers, it accepts good quality


contributions from other related disciplines as well as articles written by policy-
makers, industrialists and practitioners. Two distinctive features are its Country
Survey Series and its Special Issues. To date, there have been some 20 Country
Surveys, each designed to provide data, analysis and evaluation of a country’s
defence economy (e.g. data on defence expenditure; armed forces; demand for
defence spending; and any defence industrial base). There remains scope for
more Country Surveys of both major defence spending nations (e.g. USA) and
nations which are less well-known (e.g. China; India; Iran; Iraq; Pakistan; new
NATO members; North Korea).

There have been numerous Special Issues. These include special, topical and
under-researched themes (e.g. terrorism; arms exports; defence R&D), tributes to
leading defence economists (e.g. Jack Hirshleifer), conference papers focusing on
a common theme as well as Issues designed to promote defence economics in a
specific country (e.g. Canada; Greece; Spain; Turkey). Each Special Issue
requires a Guest Editor who is responsible for the content of the Issue and the
quality of the articles. Proposals for Special Issues are made to the Editors who
will then commission the Issue, or the Editors might approach someone to take the
lead and develop a Special Issue.

3
Proceedings of the 10th Annual International Conference on Economics and Security

2.2.3. The tenth anniversary issue, 2000

The tenth anniversary of the journal was commemorated with a Special


Anniversary Issue (Hartley and Sandler, 2000). This contained an article
reviewing the coverage of the journal to that date. There were also articles on
concepts of defence economics, arms races, conflict and exchange, defence and
aid, manpower economics and disarmament.

This section summarises the main findings of the review of coverage from 1990 to
2000. The top 10 topics covered were (figures in brackets show number of
articles):

1) Defence expenditure studies (29)


2) Procurement processes and policies (21)
3) Economics of alliances (18)
4) Conversion (17)
5) Defence industries and industrial base (16)
6) Military manpower (14)
7) Country surveys (11)
8) Terrorism, guerrilla warfare and insurgencies (11)
9) Defence and growth (9)
10) Public choice and defence (8)

In contrast, areas with relatively little coverage included articles on arms races,
the arms trade, disarmament and arms control, the military production function,
the nature of defence economics and defence budgets. In view of their importance
and topicality, the small number of articles on arms races and the arms trade was
surprising.

In 2000, various gaps in coverage were identified. These included game theoretic
analysis of defence; peace economic studies, including peacekeeping missions,
regional arms races and conflict resolution; contributions from related disciplines;
and good quality case studies of defence industries, projects and of conversion
(both successful and unsuccessful conversions).

2.2.4. Progress since year 2000

The record of publications since the 10th Anniversary Issue enables an assessment
of the changing trends in defence economics. Since the 2000 Anniversary Issue
(2000/1), there have been 41 issues of the journal with 221 articles to end-2006
(2006/6). Table 1 shows the topics with the greatest coverage over this period.
In aggregate, these topics accounted for 87% of all topics published over the
period. Inevitably, there are problems of classification, especially with defence-
growth and defence expenditure studies as well as with personnel and military
production function articles. Nonetheless, compared with the 1990 – 2000
period, there are some new topics in the top list. These include conflict, arms

4
Proceedings of the 10th Annual International Conference on Economics and Security

races, terrorism, the military production function, peacekeeping, defence R&D


and the arms trade.

Table 1. Coverage from 2000 to 2006

Topics Number of articles


Defence –growth 23
Conflict 22
Defence industrial base 20
Arms races and arms control 17
Terrorism 16
Military production function 15
Defence expenditure 14
Peace and peacekeeping 12
Debt issues 10
Defence R&D 10
Alliances 9
Manpower economics 9
Arms trade 8
Country surveys 8

Equally interesting are the topics which have received little coverage. These
included European defence policy, disarmament, conversion, security policy,
defence budget trade-offs, procurement, regional issues, public choice and the
nature of defence economics. The list of Special Issues is a further indicator of
developments in defence economics. Since 2000, there have been 16 Special
Issues reflecting new topics, new themes, conference proceedings and efforts to
promote defence economics in specific countries, namely, Canada, Greece, Spain
and Turkey. Table 2 shows the coverage of Special Issues since the Anniversary
Issue.

Table 2. Special Issues, 2000 – 2006

Arms exports Economics of Conflict, Civil War and


Defence in Greece and Turkey Peace- Historical Perspectives
Economics of Defence: Perspectives Symposium on Defence Economics
from Spain Deficit, Debt and Defence
Civil Wars Future of the Defence Firm
Defence and Economic Development in Canadian Perspectives on Defence
the Balkans Economics
Economic Analysis for Defence Defence R&D
Decision-Makers Peacekeeping
Internal and External Threats Essays in Honour of Jack Hirshleifer

5
Proceedings of the 10th Annual International Conference on Economics and Security

Major gaps remain, some of which were identified in the Anniversary Issue.
There is a need for good quality analytical and critical case studies of conflict,
defence industries, projects and conversion (both successful and failed
conversions). Examples include the Iraq war and experience with major weapons
projects such as aircraft carriers, combat aircraft (e.g. F-22; JSF; Typhoon) and
submarines. There is also scope for more articles from policy-makers, the armed
forces and from industry.

Other opportunities exist in procurement and contracting and analysis of the


efficiency of the armed forces and the military production function. The history
of economic thought in war, defence and peace is another gap. Finally,
globalisation issues need to be addressed, embracing global threats, global
defence industries and global military solutions (e.g. peacekeeping; ad hoc
military alliance such as ‘coalitions of the willing’).

3. Challenges
3.1. The Defence Economics Problem

This is the standard economics problem of choice under uncertainty. It reflects


two trends. First, for most nations, defence budgets in real terms have been either
broadly constant or falling. Second, input costs for equipment and military
personnel have been rising. Unit equipment costs have doubled every decade
leading to smaller numbers of equipment ordered from defence industries and
smaller numbers for the armed forces (e.g. a long-run downward trend in the
numbers of combat aircraft, tanks and warships in the armed forces). Also, for
military personnel, the costs of an all-volunteer force have to rise faster than wage
increases in the civilian sector (i.e. to compensate for the net disadvantages of the
military employment contract: discipline; mobility; danger; long and unsociable
hours on operations; and the probability of injury and death). The result of these
trends is the need for difficult defence choices. Whilst higher defence spending
will ‘solve’ some of these problems, it shifts the choice problem from defence to
social welfare spending and taxation levels (i.e. ‘guns v butter’ choices).

Interestingly, the end of the Cold War has made no difference to unit cost
escalation: it has continued. For example, the UK cannot afford a successor to
Typhoon combat aircraft; attack helicopters are becoming unaffordable so that
there is a future for main battle tanks; and by the time UAVs are as capable as
manned aircraft, they will be equally as expensive and hence just as unaffordable
(Pugh, 2007).

There is a further dimension which affects the defence economic problem.


Evidence shows that there is a positive relationship between annual defence R&D
spending some 10 – 25 years earlier and military equipment capability (or years of
advantage). This relationship is subject to diminishing returns. It shows that the
USA is the world leader and that it is some 5-6 years ahead of the UK and

6
Proceedings of the 10th Annual International Conference on Economics and Security

France, some 8 years ahead of Germany and about 12 years ahead of Sweden.
The result is that the US defence industry has an international competitive
advantage reflected in its defence export performance. But the US advantage
comes at a price. Its lead over the UK involves an annual defence R&D budget
which is five times that of the UK (Middleton, et al, 2006).

There are a variety of responses to the defence economics problem. These include
‘equal misery’ affecting all the armed forces and involving less training, fewer
attrition buys, some project cancellations and delays in delivering new equipment
(i.e. shifting the new equipment programme to the right). Alternatively, there
could be a defence review involving a major shift in a nation’s defence
commitments (e.g. abandoning some capabilities; role specialisation); or nations
could seek to improve efficiency in procurement through competitive purchasing
and military outsourcing. For European nations, an EU defence policy is a further
option.

Economic theory also offers some policy guidelines and principles for formulating
defence policy. First, the principle of final outputs. This requires a focus on the
final outputs of defence in terms of peace, security and protection or more
realistically in terms of defence capabilities. For example, it might be that a
nation’s defence budget provides the capability to be involved in a major conflict
as part of an international coalition (e.g. UK in Iraq and Afghanistan) or to be
involved in, say, three small to medium scale operations (e.g. peacekeeping).
Such an approach shows the limitations of focusing on inputs. Typically, debates
about defence policy focus on the implication of budget cuts for the size of the
army, navy and air force (e.g. cuts in the numbers of infantry regiments, tanks,
warships and combat aircraft squadrons). This is the wrong focus. Instead, the
key question is what contribution do these inputs of soldiers, warships and aircraft
make to the final outputs of peace and security and what would be the impact of
marginal changes in these inputs (e.g. reducing the size of the navy by 5% and
increasing the size of the army by 5%)?

The second economic principle is that of substitution. This recognises that there
are alternative means of achieving protection. For example, there are substitution
possibilities between civilians and military personnel; between reserves and
regulars; between attack helicopters and tanks; between cruise missiles/UCAVs
and manned combat aircraft; between air power and land forces; and between
nuclear and conventional forces. Some of these substitution possibilities affect the
traditional monopoly property rights of the armed forces. It might mean cruise
missiles operated by the army and navy replacing manned combat aircraft
operated by the air force.

The third economic principle is that of competition as a mechanism for achieving


efficiency. Here, there are opportunities for introducing or extending competition
to the purchase of defence equipment (e.g. buying from overseas rather than from
a national defence industrial base) and to military outsourcing. Typically, the
armed forces operate a monopoly of services provided by ‘in-house’ units. Such

7
Proceedings of the 10th Annual International Conference on Economics and Security

activities could be opened-up to competition by allowing private firms to bid for


this work (e.g. catering; training; transport; managing military bases and training
ranges).

3.2. UK Nuclear Weapons Policy

Interestingly, the first specialist defence economics text book was entitled The
Economics of Defense in the Nuclear Age (Hitch and McKean, 1960). Some 45
years later, the UK is considering whether to replace its Trident strategic nuclear
force. This decision will be controversial involving political, military and moral
issues. But economics cannot be ignored since costs are involved.

Economists assess a Trident replacement decision by starting with a conceptual


framework. The policy options need to be identified embracing submarine, air
and land-based alternatives for a strategic deterrent (including the option of
running-on Trident for longer than its original planned service life). The options
then need to be assessed using a cost-benefit framework. Costs include
acquisition, life-cycle and disposal costs. Benefits embrace the military
effectiveness of the options in relation to the military requirement. There are also
wider economic and industrial benefits to be included in the evaluation. These
include such factors as security of supply, the retention of industrial capabilities
and the impact on jobs, technology and any exports.

Opportunity costs cannot be ignored. One estimate suggests replacement costs of


£15-20 billion over 20 years (based on building a new Vanguard/Trident force at
2006 prices); but the estimate might be double that figure or considerably less.
No official figures are yet available. An expenditure of £15-20 billion could be
used for alternative defence spending on conventional equipment. For example,
£15-20 billion might buy 30-40 Type 45 destroyers; or 2 aircraft carriers plus their
JSF aircraft and helicopters; or 230-310 Typhoon combat aircraft (these are
illustrative examples based on acquisition costs only). Alternatively, there are
Trident versus social welfare trade-offs. Alternative civil spending is available in
the form of 100 – 130 new hospitals (capital costs only over 20 years) instead of a
Trident replacement. A Trident replacement also affects the future of the UK
submarine industrial base (UK SIB). Without a submarine replacement for the
UK’s nuclear deterrent force, it will be difficult and costly to maintain a UK SIB.
But a submarine replacement will require contract negotiations with a UK
monopoly supplier (BAE Systems) and the associated problems of determining
prices and profits on non-competitive contracts and providing efficiency
incentives whilst avoiding ‘excessive’ profits. As always, there are no costless
options.

8
Proceedings of the 10th Annual International Conference on Economics and Security

3.3. Project Case Studies: Typhoon

Typhoon illustrates the opportunities for in-depth case studies of major equipment
projects and for the economic evaluation of such programmes. Economic theory
suggests guidelines for an efficient defence industrial policy in an alliance and
these can be used to assess the efficiency of the Typhoon programme. Efficient
programmes are characterised by gains from trade based on specialisation by
comparative advantage; by gains from economies of scale and learning; and by
reduced duplication of costly R&D. Typhoon fails on gains from trade since its
work-sharing arrangements are not based on comparative advantage between
partner nations. Instead, work is allocated on the basis of juste retour reflecting
the size of national orders and the desire of each nation for a share of the high
technology on the programme and for national final assembly lines. However,
Typhoon scores more highly on gains from scale and learning through combining
all national orders into one large-scale order; but it loses some economies of
learning through duplicate final assembly lines (but final assembly is 3-5% of
production cots). Finally, there are some gains for Typhoon from reduced
duplication of costly R&D programmes (e.g. four nations choosing one R&D
programme).

The large-scale public expenditure on Typhoon of over Euros 54 billion (2004


prices for development and production) has attracted considerable public scrutiny
by national Parliaments. Criticism has also been made of the continued relevance
of Typhoon in the new post-Cold War security environment, the high and rising
costs of the project, its considerable delays, the inefficiencies of its industrial
arrangements and the bureaucracies of the customer governments. However,
there has been little information on the economic benefits of Typhoon. What are
its benefits in terms of jobs, technology spin-offs and balance of payments
(exports and import-savings)? Such economic and industrial benefits are part of a
complete cost-benefit economic evaluation of Typhoon (Hartley, 2006).

3.3.1. Economic benefits

Typhoon supports some 100,000-105,000 jobs directly and indirectly in over 400
European companies. In 2006, these jobs were distributed: Germany and Italy
with 20,000 each; Spain with 25,000; and the UK with 40,000 jobs. Many of these
are highly-skilled and high wage jobs in development, production and support.
Many of Typhoon’s labour skills are highly transferable (e.g. to motor car and
electronic industries; and to Airbus 380 work).

There is an impressive list of technology benefits and spin-offs from Typhoon.


Examples include carbon fibre technology, flight control systems and aero-engine
technology. There are spin-offs to civil aircraft, to motor car industries (including
Formula 1 racing cars in Italy and the UK) and further spin-offs to supply chains
(including the application of modern business practices).

9
Proceedings of the 10th Annual International Conference on Economics and Security

Typhoon offers export and import-savings benefits which further contribute to


providing jobs and to maintaining the European defence industrial base which
represents an alternative source of supply to the USA. In late 2006, there were
export orders for 90 aircraft valued at Euros 9.5 billion. Also, the import-saving
contribution of Typhoon was estimated at Euros 33.5 – 54 billion (acquisition
costs only: the higher estimate assumed that Typhoon was the least-cost solution
and the lower estimate assumed a mixed buy of US F-15E and F-18E/F aircraft).
On this basis, the total balance of payments contribution of Typhoon is some
Euros 43 – 63.5 billion.

3.3.2. A critique

The economic benefits of Typhoon need to be evaluated critically. The


opportunity cost question cannot be avoided. Would the resources used on
Typhoon make a greater contribution to national output if they were used
elsewhere in the economy?

Similarly, examples of technology spin-offs appear impressive but they are


qualitative and not quantitative: there are lots of examples and case studies, but
little evidence on their valuation. What is the market value of these spin-offs and
what is their transmission mechanism? One estimate based on the Netherlands
experience with its planned JSF purchase suggested that Typhoon technology
spin-offs might be valued at Euros 7.2 billion (2004 prices) but this is likely to be
a lower-bound estimate (Hartley, 2006, pp17-18). Some of the mechanisms
whereby technology from Typhoon is ‘spun-out’ to other sectors of the economy
have been identified. These included labour turnover with skills transferred
elsewhere either within a company or to other firms (e.g. the motor car industry
in Germany); through staff on Typhoon acting as consultants (e.g. to Formula 1
racing car industry); through the supply chains; and through links with
universities (Hartley, 2006, p17).

There is a more fundamental critique of the economic benefits of Typhoon


concerning their market failure dimension. Do arguments about jobs, technology
and exports reflect genuine market failures justifying state intervention; is state
intervention likely to be worthwhile; and are defence projects such as Typhoon,
the most efficient form of intervention to correct market failures? In relation to
jobs and exports, it is likely that labour and foreign exchange markets are working
reasonably well; but spin-offs are a beneficial externality suggesting failure in
technology (R&D) markets.

Finally, collaboration inefficiencies on Typhoon cannot be ignored. These


embrace development and production and are reflected in the work-share
arrangements, the industrial organisation and the customer governments of the
partner nations all of which have led to cost increases and delays. For example,
the Typhoon programme lacks a single lead company as prime contractor with

10
Proceedings of the 10th Annual International Conference on Economics and Security

management authority and financial responsibility and also it lacks a single


customer. Governments are subject to changing requirements, national agendas,
industry lobbying and different budgetary pressures (national projects are not
immune from such features). Overall, the Eurofighter company recognises that
about one third of the 54 month delay was due to the company and its
management organisation, with the rest of the delay attributed to the partner
governments, their budget problems and to changes following the end of the Cold
War.

The Typhoon programme offers some lessons for future collaborations. First,
work-shares need to be based on efficiency and competitiveness criteria rather
than political bargaining and equity between the partner nations. Second,
collaboration needs a single prime contractor subject to the risks of a fixed price
or target cost incentive contract. Despite its recent problems, Airbus is an
example of a successful collaboration.

4. Conclusion: Further challenges


4.1. Challenges for the Armed Forces

Private industry makes continuous change due to changing consumer preferences,


new technology and the emergence of lower cost rivals at home and overseas.
The Armed Forces cannot avoid the need to change. The drivers for change come
from budget cuts, new technology, new threats and new conflicts and some times
from government through a new, innovative defence minister (e.g. McNamara).

The need for change in the Armed Forces means that they have to address radical
solutions and depart from the traditional ways of doing business. For example,
the substitution principle with, say, a greater use of reserve forces and more
military outsourcing has to be addressed in an era of defence budget constraints
and a preference for social welfare spending. But the search for efficiency
improvements in the Armed Forces is limited by their lack of private market
incentives in the form of competition, the profit motive and the policing role of
capital markets (i.e. threats of takeovers and bankruptcy).

4.2. Challenges for defence economics

There remains a massive research agenda based on traditional and new topics.
Traditional areas include the scope for further analytical and empirical work on
the military production function and the efficiency with which the Armed Forces
convert inputs into military outputs. Here, there is scope for the international
comparison of labour-capital relationships in such forms as the numbers of
military personnel per warship, tank unit and combat aircraft squadron. Military
outsourcing also provides a check on the internal efficiency of various activities of

11
Proceedings of the 10th Annual International Conference on Economics and Security

the Armed Forces and questions arise about the optimal extent of such
outsourcing (e.g. combat units).

Data problems remain, but the collection of reliable data provides a public good
subject to free-riding and this is not an attractive route to fast promotion in the
economics profession! Two examples illustrate the challenges. First, there is a
need for more data on the defence industrial base for each nation in the world.
China is an obvious data gap. Also, there is a lack of data on defence R&D,
especially its inputs of scarce scientists and engineers. Second, new studies of
the economics of conflict require data on the costs of conflict. Such data are
difficult to obtain. There are military costs and civilian costs to be considered.
Ideally, data are needed on the planned military costs and final outcomes,
including the impact of conflict on all participating nations. Even the apparently
simple task of obtaining data on the military costs of the conflict and peace-
keeping phases of operations in Afghanistan and Iraq are fraught with difficulties.
There remains scope for a proper costing of the conflicts in Iraq and Afghanistan.

12
Proceedings of the 10th Annual International Conference on Economics and Security

References
Brauer, J. (ed) (2003) Economics of conflict, war and peace in historical
perspective. Defence and Peace Economics, Special Issue, 14(3), pp.151 – 236,
June.

Barros, C.P. and Sandler, T. (eds) (2003) Internal and external threats: Defence
economic analysis. Defence and Peace Economics, Special Issue, 14(6), pp.385 –
474, December.

Hartley, K, et al, (1993) Economic Aspects of Disarmament: Disarmament as an


investment process. UNIDIR, New York.

Hartley, K. and Sandler, T (eds) (2000) Special Anniversary Issue of defence and
peace economics. Defence and Peace Economics, 11(1), pp.1 – 126.

Hartley, K. and Sandler, T (eds) (2003) The Economics of Conflict.


The International Library of Critical Writings in Economics 168, vols 1-3,
Cheltenham.

Hartley, K. (2006) The Industrial and Economic Benefits of Eurofighter


Typhoon. Report for Eurofighter, Munich, June.

Hartley, K. (2007) Defence economics, in Durlauf, S. and Blume, L. (eds), New


Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. 2nd edition, Macmillan, London, forthcoming.

Hegre, H. and Sandler, T. (eds) (2002) Economic analysis of civil wars. Defence
and Peace Economics, Special Issue, 13(6), pp.429 – 496, December.

Hitch, C. J. and McKean, R. (1960) The Economics of Defense in the Nuclear


Age. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, USA

Levine, P., Sen, S. and Smith, R (eds) (2000) Arms exports, controls and
production. Defence and Peace Economics, Special Issue, 11(5), pp. 443 - 548

Middleton, A and Bowns, S with Hartley, K and Reid, J (2006) The effect of
defence R&D on military equipment quality. Defence and Peace Economics,
17(2), pp.117 – 139.

Pugh, P. (2007) Retrospect and prospect: Trends in cost and their implications for
UK aerospace. Defence and Peace Economics, forthcoming.

Sandler, T. (ed). (1992) Terrorism, guerrilla warfare and insurrections. Defence


Economics, Special Issue, 3(4), pp. 259 – 358.

Sandler, T and Hartley, K. (1995) The Economics of Defense. Cambridge Surveys


of Economic Literature, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, England.

13
Proceedings of the 10th Annual International Conference on Economics and Security

Sandler, T. and Hartley, K. (eds) (2007) Handbook of Defense Economics.


Volume 2, Elsevier, Amsterdam.

Solomon, B. and Berkok, U. G. (eds) (2006) Canadian perspectives on


peacekeeping. Defence and Peace Economics, Special Issue, 17(5), pp. 393 – 485.

14

View publication stats

You might also like