Youth Unemployment in Advanced Europe: Okun's Law and Beyond
Youth Unemployment in Advanced Europe: Okun's Law and Beyond
Youth Unemployment in Advanced Europe: Okun's Law and Beyond
European Department
January 2015
This Working Paper should not be reported as representing the views of the IMF.
The views expressed in this Working Paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily
represent those of the IMF or IMF policy. Working Papers describe research in progress by the
author(s) and are published to elicit comments and to further debate.
Abstract
The crisis has intensified what was previously a chronic unemployment problem in Europe;
youth unemployment is now at unprecedented highs in some European countries. This paper
assesses the main drivers of youth unemployment in Europe. It finds that much of the
increase in youth unemployment rates during the crisis can be explained by output dynamics
and the greater sensitivity of youth unemployment to economic activity than adult
unemployment. Labor market institutions also play a significant role in explaining the
persistently high levels of youth unemployment, especially the tax wedge, minimum wages
relative to the median wage, spending on active labor market policies, the opportunity cost of
working (measured by the unemployment benefits), vocational training, and labor market
duality. This suggests that policies to address youth unemployment should be comprehensive
and country-specific, focused on reviving growth and advancing labor market reforms.
Keywords: Youth employment, youth unemployment, Okun’s law, business cycle, labor
market factors
Contents Page
I. Introduction ............................................................................................................................4
V. Conclusions .........................................................................................................................22
Tables
Figures
Box
References ................................................................................................................................24
4
I. INTRODUCTION1
Youth unemployment has surged in Europe during the global crisis, and is at historic highs in
many countries. Several papers have highlighted the deleterious consequences of high youth
unemployment. These include the impact of “scarring” that leads to a lower probability of
future employment and/or lower wages, which has been found to be persistent (Dao and
Loungani, 2010; Ellwood, 1982; Gregg and Tominey, 2005; Kahn, 2010; Oreopoulos et al.,
2012). High levels of youth unemployment have been shown to erode social cohesion and
institutions (Giuliano and Spilimbergo, 2009; Altindag and Mocan, 2010; ILO, 2013), and
foster crime (Fougère et al., 2009; Carmichael and Ward, 2001). In addition, young
unemployed workers may have a higher propensity to relocate abroad because of lower
“sunk costs” and greater potential for education and, subsequently, work abroad.2 The
outward migration of the youth combined with the general ageing of the population may
lower the potential output of the euro area since a significant share of the outward migration
is to countries outside the euro area (OECD, 2013a). High youth unemployment and an
outward migration of younger members of the workforce could also undermine the
sustainability of spending on social safety nets in euro area countries, which is of particular
concern given their demographic challenges.
In response, specific policies have been formulated at both the European Union (European
Commission, 2012 and 2013a) and national levels to deal with youth unemployment. The
most notable examples are the EU’s Youth Guarantee Scheme, aimed at ensuring that all
young people get a job offer within four months of leaving formal education or becoming
unemployed, and the Youth Employment Imitative, aimed at supporting active labor market
policies for young people not in education, employment or training in regions with high
youth unemployment. Policies at the national level include, for instance, Italy’s July 2013
measures to support youth unemployment, including tax breaks for employers hiring
under-30s on permanent contracts, and the increase in training, apprenticeship and internship
schemes. Such policies aim to smooth the job-searching process and promote youth
employment.
But what drives youth unemployment? Despite the focus on the harmful effects of pervasive
youth unemployment and policies to address the problem, studies devoted to understanding
the main drivers of youth unemployment are relatively limited. The large literature on labor
1
We are grateful to Petya Koeva Brooks for her guidance on the project. We would also like to thank Shekhar
Aiyar, Céline Allard, Larry Ball, Helge Berger, Olivier Blanchard, Rodolphe Blavy, John Bluedorn, Jӧrg
Decressin, Prakash Loungani, Paulo Medas, Mahmood Pradhan, and other IMF colleagues, and seminar
participants at the European Commission and the European Central Bank for their insightful comments. We are
grateful to Xiaobo Shao and Katherine Cincotta for their excellent assistance with research and document
preparation respectively.
2
For example, there is evidence that Latvian emigrants during the crisis were slightly younger and slightly more
educated than the average population (Hazans, 2011, Blanchard et al., 2013). Arpaia et al. (2014) show that a
quarter of immigrants are in the age group of 15–24 years old, and 40 percent are in the age group of
15-29 years old.
5
markets usually examines overall unemployment, which has also been an important concern
during the global crisis.
The few papers that do investigate youth unemployment and employment in advanced
economies all point to the important role of economic activity and labor market institutions.
Some find significant effects from multiple factors—including labor market reforms,
economic freedom, education, part-time employment, and active labor market policies
(Choudhry et al., 2012a). Others highlight the role of individual labor market institutions
such as the union involvement in wage setting (Jimeno and Rodriguez-Palenzuela, 2002;
Bertola et al., 2007), labor market flexibility (Bernal-Verdugo et al., 2012a), or employment
protection legislation (Bassanini and Duval, 2006) for youth labor market outcomes.
Our paper examines the main cyclical and structural explanatory factors behind the youth
unemployment dynamics during the global crisis. It covers 22 advanced European
countries—18 in the euro area, as well as Denmark, Sweden, Norway and the United
Kingdom, but the discussion places a special emphasis on the euro area. The sample period is
from 1980 to 2012, with the actual size subject to data availability, in particular for labor
market features.
The paper makes several contributions to the empirical literature. First, our analysis
compares and contrasts the effects of various factors on both youth and adult unemployment,
and the changes and levels of the unemployment rate. Second, our methodology allows us to
take fuller account of output fluctuations on youth unemployment. Like many other studies
on similar issues, we also utilize panel data to control for unobserved time-specific or
country-specific characteristics. However, unlike these studies which assume that output
fluctuations have a common effect across countries, we estimate the country-specific
sensitivity of unemployment to output fluctuations and also control for such country-specific
output-sensitivity when studying the role of labor market institutions. There is evidence that
the sensitivity of unemployment to output varies significantly across countries (e.g., Ball et
al., 2013).
Moreover, this paper investigates examines whether labor market factors amplify or dampen
the sensitivity of unemployment to output fluctuations in each country. In the context of the
current crisis, a few papers have studied how financial crises affect youth and how labor
market institutions affect the reaction of youth unemployment to crisis (e.g., Choudhry et al.,
2012b). However, they mainly focus on recessions (rather than output fluctuations in general)
and only incorporate select labor market factors into the analysis (e.g., labor market
flexibility in Bernal-Verdugo et al., 2012b, and employment protection legislation,
O’Higgins, 2012). Our paper covers a broad range of labor market institutions that affect
both labor demand and supply. Also, it looks at how each of a broad set of labor market
factors affect the sensitivity of youth unemployment rates to the output gap, including during
6
The results suggest that youth unemployment rates are more sensitive to output fluctuations
than adult unemployment, and the significant increase in youth unemployment during the
crisis, especially in vulnerable euro area economies, was largely due to the decline in
economic activity. In addition, the persistently high levels of youth unemployment could be
also explained by a host of labor market institutions, including: the opportunity cost of
working (measured by the unemployment benefits), labor costs (measured by the tax wedge
and minimum wage relative to the median wage), spending on active labor market policies
(ALMPs), vocational training, and labor market duality. Finally, labor market features do not
generally affect the sensitivity of youth unemployment to output gaps.
The remainder of the paper is structured as follows: Section II documents stylized facts about
labor market dynamics in advanced European countries. Section III describes empirical
methodology and data. Section IV summarizes the empirical results, and, finally, Section V
concludes.
The crisis has left a sizable dent in euro area output and investment, which dropped by 2 and
19 percent respectively since their pre-crisis peak. The hardest hit sectors were construction,
retail and wholesale sectors, and manufacturing, with sectoral output lower than their
pre-crisis peaks by 20 percent, 5 percent, and 4 percent, respectively.
Labor market outcomes have been dismal: about 4 million jobs were lost across the advanced
Europe during this time period, with 25
Euro Area: Unemployment Rates and NEET
unemployment rates—youth unemployment in 23 (Percent)
3
particular—rising to unprecedented levels. The Youth
21
crisis has reversed a decade-long trend of modest Adult
19 Youth NEET
declines in youth unemployment—the youth
17
unemployment rate in the euro area remains
15
elevated at 24 percent in mid-2014, well above
13
the 15 percent rate in 2007. The adult
11
unemployment rate has also risen significantly,
9
but less so than youth unemployment
7
(10¼ percent in mid-2014, from 6½ percent in
2007). The higher youth unemployment rate 5
2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013
only partly reflects the fact that the youth labor Source: Eurostat
force is typically smaller than the adult labor
3
Henceforth, youth refers to individuals aged 15–24 years, and adults refer to individuals aged 25–64 years.
Unemployment refers to the unemployment rate.
7
force; the gap between youth and adult unemployment rates has increased significantly after
the crisis.4 The NEET rate, defined as the share of the youth population that is not employed
or involved in further education or training, is less influenced by measurement biases
inherent in determining the size of the youth labor force. Even the NEET rates show that the
mild improvements that had started before the crisis have now been reversed.
Across the euro area, there are large cross-country differences in the level and change in
youth unemployment, and these differences have increased during the crisis. The current
unemployment situation reflects a complex mix of developments during the crisis, combined
with a variety of pre-crisis unemployment rates. Taking these differences into account, euro
area countries can be placed into four buckets: (i) those that witnessed large increases in the
youth unemployment during the crisis from relatively low pre-crisis levels (Ireland, Cyprus);
(ii) those with above-average unemployment rates before the crisis, but small increases since
the crisis (Belgium, France, Finland and Sweden); (iii) those with the worst of both of the
above categories—large increases in youth unemployment after the crisis, but relatively high
rates to begin with (Greece, Spain, and Italy); and, (iv) those with the best of both worlds
(Austria, Netherlands, Germany), with small increases in unemployment (or even a decline in
the case of Germany) on top of low pre-crisis unemployment rates to begin with.
Youth employment conditions are fragile, tenuous and concentrated. The young are far more
likely to be hired on temporary contracts than adults in all countries, but particularly in
Spain, Italy and Portugal, countries which 80
experienced some of the largest increases Share of temporary employment, 2013, percent
70
in youth unemployment during the crisis. Youth Adult
60
Youth employment is also concentrated in
sectors which tend to be more sensitive to 50
the business cycle: manufacturing, 40
wholesale and retail trade, and hotels and
30
restaurants. Before the crisis, these sectors
comprised 65–75 percent of youth 20
GRC
DNK
DEU
EST
ITA
FIN
LUX
SVK
SVN
SWE
IRL
CYP
FRA
BEL
PRT
AUT
LVA
MLT
GBR
NLD
NOR
4
The youth labor force tends to be smaller than that for other age cohorts because young individuals may
choose to pursue full-time education, although participation in education does not necessarily exclude
participation in the labor force (e.g., part-time work or apprenticeships). The youth labor market is also
characterized by frequent search and matching as individuals look for better jobs, using intermediate stages for
accumulating experience (and perhaps, occasionally, dropping out of the labor force).
8
youth and 40 percent of adults. As of 2013, wholesale and retail trade was the dominant
sector for youth employment, followed by manufacturing and accommodation and food
services.5
100 60
Youth Employment By Sector, Share of employment in top 3 areas of economic
90 2000-07, percent activity, 2013, percent
Construction, Real Estate Manufacturing 55
80 Youth Adult
Wholesale, Retail Trade Hotels and Restaurants
70 50
60
45
50
40 40
30
35
20
10
30
SVK
SVN
IRL
CYP
BEL
AUT
PRT
LVA
FRA
GRC
MLT
GBR
DNK
ESP
ITA
EST
DEU
NLD
NOR
LUX
FIN
SWE
0
CYP ESP GRE IRE ITA POR
Source: Eurostat
Measure. In line with the literature, this paper uses the unemployment rate as a main measure
of youth and adult unemployment. This enables us to exploit existing theoretical frameworks
for our analysis, and allows easier comparison with the literature. Some have argued that the
unemployment rate is not informative and is a biased measure of the incidence of
unemployment given the smaller and more volatile size of the youth labor force. But other
measures also come with their own challenges.
5
Top areas of economic activity for adults vary more by country. The dominant ones are human health and
social work activities, wholesale and retail trade as well as manufacturing.
6
The unemployment ratio is defined as the unemployed as a share of total population.
7
The NEET referred to in this paper is the definition adopted in most European countries (Eurofound, 2012). In
the United Kingdom (Coles et al., 2002; McGregor et al., 2006) and in New Zealand (Hill, 2003), the NEET
mainly capture teenagers. The Japanese definition of NEET refers to people aged 15–34 years old who are not
in the labor force, not attending school and not housekeeping (OECD, 2008a), while in Korea NEET refers to
(continued…)
9
Measurement of labor market factors. For robustness, a number of different measures are
used for each of the following categories of labor market features— labor costs; the
opportunity cost of working; collective bargaining; labor market duality; education and
training; and spending on ALMPs. In each category, the analysis relied on several indicators
and different sources (see Table 1 for definitions). For instance, labor costs were measured
by the tax wedge and the ratio of the minimum wage to the median wage under the
assumption that the former was most relevant for the youth. Several countries in the euro area
do not have minimum wages and this ratio was set to zero in the data base. Similarly, the
opportunity costs of employment are measured by gross benefit replacements rates, net
replacement rates (benefit replacement rates net of taxes) and “the inactivity trap” which
arises when tax and benefit systems interact to reduce the financial incentive of individuals
who qualify for social protection benefits to work.
Data challenges. There are several constraints. Some arise from the challenges inherent in
capturing the structural characteristics of labor markets in a manner that captures
country-specific institutional context. Others arise from the need to measure labor market
factors consistently across a broad range of countries and over a long period of time to
maximize the sample size.
Sample size. Data on the selected labor market institutions is usually not available for the
full sample period, and is especially limited for new entrants to the euro area. The smaller
sample size implies that country-by-country empirical analysis combining the
institutional variables and measures of the business cycle together would not yield robust
results. For instance, the data series for some variables (e.g., ALMPs) starts from late
1990s for most countries, and even later for smaller countries; some variables (e.g.,
OECD’s index for employment protection legislation) are missing in some countries, and
other series (e.g., tax wedge) only start from early 2000’s for all countries. This cuts the
total sample size significantly, and in some cases, we have to use fewer variables than
preferred.
people aged 15-34 years who have left school, are not preparing to enter a company, do not have a job, do not
have family responsibilities (or children) and are not married (OECD, 2008b).
10
Duration of the analysis. Given the long lags in data availability, it is difficult to extend
the analysis beyond 2012 at this juncture since only a subset of the labor market variables
is available. Thus, labor market reforms since the crisis are not fully captured in the
dataset, e.g., Spain’s major labor market reforms of 2012 (Ley 3/2012 de medidas
urgentes para la reforma del Mercado laboral) which included reforms to collective
bargaining, opt-outs and firm level internal flexibility regarding working conditions
(wages, hours), and dismissals (conditions, costs).
Measurement and relevance. The analysis had to use data series that were available for a
large set of countries over a long period of time. But some of these variables are not
always relevant for the young
unemployed (e.g., the unemployment 90
Reason for Temporary Work Contract Among
benefit system), nor do they capture the 80 Youth, percent of unemployed, 2012
country-specific institutional context that 70
Slow moving. Finally, by their very nature to some extent, structural variables change
very slowly from year to year, which makes it difficult to study the impact of reforms on
8
The OECD’s Product Market Reform indicator is only available every five years. We therefore focus on the
Goods Market Efficiency: Competition sub-indicator compiled from the Global Competitiveness Report and the
cost of starting a business from the World Bank Doing Business Indicators.
11
labor market dynamics. Also, labor and product market features have remained relatively
unchanged since 2000 for many of the countries in the sample (Figure 1) because of lack
of major reforms in several countries, regardless of which indicator is used. In general,
these indicators seem to have remained broadly the same or even deteriorated in countries
that have witnessed the highest levels and the biggest increases in youth unemployment.
Germany and the Scandinavian countries are among the few that have registered
improvements.
B. Methodology
There were several methodological constraints. These limitations arose as a result of the data
challenges discussed in the previous section and the uncertainties involved in estimating
equilibrium values of potential output and unemployment. As a result, the specifications
considered below did not take into account non-linear and lagged effects of output and labor
market indicators. In addition, significant simplifying assumptions had to be made about the
country-specific effects of labor market features.
The Okun’s Law, proposed by Arthur Okun in 1962, is the empirical regularity that changes
in unemployment rates and output growth are negatively related.9 Many studies confirm this
relationship for overall unemployment but research on youth unemployment is less common.
Some authors highlight the higher sensitivity of youth unemployment to the business cycle
(OECD, 2006; Scarpetta, 1996; Scarpetta et al., 2010; and European Commission, 2013b).
Standard specification. The Okun’s coefficient for individual countries is estimated on the
basis of the following specification, where is the estimated value of the Okun’s
coefficient for country i (Table 2):
− is the dummy variable for country i (other than for country 1 to avoid perfect
collinearity)
9
See Ball et al. (2013) for an extensive discussion on this topic and theoretical derivation of the reduced form
relationships in (1) and (1a).
12
Alternative specification. We also consider an alternative specification using the output gap
and deviation from natural rates of unemployment , respectively, as
independent and dependent variables. is the Okun’s coefficient in this model (with
estimates provided in Table 2):
Ball et al. (2013) argue in favor of the specification (1a) on the grounds that specification
(1) is only theoretically valid if one is willing to assume a constant equilibrium
unemployment rate as well as constant potential growth. However, estimating the output gap
and deviation from structural unemployment in specification (1a) is difficult. We use output
gap estimates from the IMF’s World Economic Outlook database and apply the HP filter
(with a smoothing parameter of 100) to get the natural rate of unemployment. The HP filter
suffers from the well-known problems of unreliability at the end of the sample, and using
output gap measurement from WEO allows us to sidestep this problem somewhat for
potential output, but not for the natural rates of unemployment. Therefore, the specification
in differences in equation (1) is our referred method for estimating the Okun’s coefficient.
Disaggregation. The idea of disaggregating the Okun’s Law specification into the impact of
various expenditure components was proposed in Anderton et al. (2014), which, however,
did not differentiate between youth and adult unemployment. We apply this methodology as
well to see which component of growth—consumption, investment and exports—has the
largest effect on unemployment. For practical purposes, this involves replacing
growth of various expenditure components (namely, growth in
consumption, investment and exports). The results are listed in Table 3.
Due to the previously discussed data challenges, it is not feasible to estimate country-specific
effects of several labor market factors simultaneously, while also allowing for individual
country effects of the business cycle (measured by the output gap). As a result, this paper
considers two model specifications.
Multivariate approach. This specification considers the effect of several labor market
features (and output gap) simultaneously, but restricts their impact to be the same across
countries, while allowing the impact of the business cycle to vary across countries. More
formally, the specification for the multivariate approach is given by the following model with
the estimates provided in Table 4:
13
Univariate approach with interaction term. The trade-off between maximizing the sample
size and incorporating variable effects of labor market factors in each country also motivates
our second univariate approach.
This approach also considers the impact of one labor market feature at a time but allows its
impact to vary across countries via its interaction with the business cycle. We consider the
following specification, with the same notations as in (2):
This specification includes one additional term—the interaction of the labor market variable
institutional variable, output gap, and the country dummy. It is based on the assumption that
(i) labor market features may affect the way unemployment rates responds to the business
cycle, and this impact may vary across countries; and the simplifying assumption that (ii) the
effect of the labor market factor remains the same across countries, except indirectly via its
impact on the business cycle.
From equation (3), the marginal impact of the change in labor market feature on the level
of unemployment is given by the partial derivative:
),
Thus, the impact of a change in any labor market feature differs across countries. Crucially,
the marginal effects of a unit change in variable labor market factor will then depend on the
value of the output gap at which they are evaluated. This point is calculated at the
14
country-specific average output gap during the sample period. The standard errors for the
marginal effects are computed using the delta method. The results of this approach are
summarized in Figure 2.
Robustness check. A variety of additional specifications were considered, e.g., using the total
unemployment rate and employment rates for different age groups as dependent variables. In
addition, we have considered models with changes in labor market institutions as
independent variables and output growth instead of the output gap as the independent
variable, to mimic the standard Okun’s law formulation in (1) more closely.
Levels versus changes. Our preference ultimately lies with models that feature levels (not
changes) of unemployment rate as dependent variables. A number of theoretical models of
unemployment are consistent with using unemployment rate in levels as dependent variable
in reduced-form equations. For example, Nickell and Layard (1999) develop a wage
bargaining model with numerous identical firms, showing that equilibrium level of
unemployment rate will be decreasing in any exogenous factor that increases job separation
rate (represented in our case by the output gap), increases the search effectiveness of the
unemployed (represented by ALMPs), lowers the benefit replacement ratio, lowers the
strength of the workers in the wage bargain (union density) or raises the elasticity of product
demand facing the firm. The latter argument even suggests some scope for including
variables associated with product market regulation into unemployment equations. Other
examples of similar models include Scarpetta (1996) and Bassanini and Duval (2006), who
estimate a specification very similar to ours.10
This section discusses the main results from the various specifications described in Section
III. Some of these results need to be interpreted with caution given the methodological and
data constraints already discussed. Moreover, it would be important to remember that these
results do not measure the impact of the reforms undertaken in countries after the crisis as
they fall outside the sample period. Some results are counterintuitive and difficult to explain
without additional granular information about other relevant and country-specific factors.
10
Bassanini and Duval (2006) estimate a reduced-form equation consistent with a variety of theoretical models
of labor market equilibrium (job search, wage setting), where
unemployment is regressed on a series of structural variables (in vector X), an output gap measure (G), as well
as country and time fixed effects. We depart from this specification by including interaction terms and
excluding time fixed effects (equation 2).
15
Standard Okun’s coefficient. We find unambiguous evidence validating the Okun’s law
across a wide range of countries. This is true regardless of how output fluctuations are
measured—by real GDP growth or the output gap. In equations (1) and (1a), cyclical factors
explain around 50 percent of the
0.2
variation in the changes in youth Euro Area: Okun's Law Coefficients /1
0.0
unemployment rates and around
-0.2
60 percent for adult unemployment rates
-0.4
across all advanced European countries,
-0.6
as measured by the R-squared (Table 2). -0.8
Youth unemployment is more sensitive -1.0
than adult unemployment in every -1.2
country, reflecting their relatively fragile -1.4
unemployment conditions. -1.6
-1.8
Youth Adults
Disaggregated Okun’s coefficient. In -2.0
order to find out which component of
NOR
ESP
EST
NLD
DEU
LUX
ITA
SVK
AUT
IRL
BEL
MLT
CYP
SVN
PRT
DNK
GBR
FIN
FRA
LVA
GRC
SWE
growth relates most to youth and adult
unemployment, the Okun’s law regression 1/ Shaded bars and circles reflect estimations that are not
significant.
(1) was generalized and estimated by using
growth rates of consumption, investment and exports as independent variables. The results
indicate that, for most countries in the sample, youth and adult unemployment rates are most
sensitive to consumption growth but much less sensitive to export growth in many countries
0.5 0.5
Elasticity of Youth Unemployment to GDP Components Elasticity of Adult Unemployment to GDP Components
0 0
-0.5 -0.5
-1 -1
-1.5 -1.5
-2 -2
SVK
SVN
IRL
BEL
CYP
AUT
FRA
LVA
PRT
MLT
GRC
ESP
GBR
DNK
DEU
EST
ITA
NLD
NOR
FIN
LUX
SWE
SVK
SVN
IRL
CYP
BEL
FRA
PRT
AUT
LVA
ESP
GBR
MLT
GRC
DNK
NLD
DEU
ITA
EST
NOR
FIN
LUX
SWE
Sources: Eurostat; WEO; authors' estimates. Unfilled shapes indicate statisticially insignificant conefficients.
Sources: Eurostate WEO; authors’ estimates. Unfilled shapes indicate statistically insignificant coefficients.
(Table 3). This is broadly consistent with the findings by Anderton et al. (2014), which
argues that “this reflects the highly labor-intensive nature of the services that represent the
bulk of consumers’ expenditure, while the higher productivity manufacturing-related content
of exports tends to be less labor intensive.”
16
Greater sensitivity of youth. All estimates of the Okun’s coefficient suggest that youth
unemployment is much more sensitive to the business cycle than adult unemployment. In
every country, the estimated Okun’s coefficient is, on average, two to three times as large for
the youth than for adults. It is partly because a smaller labor force means youth
unemployment rates necessarily react more sharply than adult unemployment rates to a
change in the GDP growth or output gap. However, it could also be explained by the greater
concentration of youth employment in cyclically sensitive industries and perhaps in small-
and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) (Box 1).
SVK
CYP
BEL
SVN
DNK
GBR
LVA
ESP
NOR
EST
SWE
NLD
DEU
LUX
ITA
AUT
IRL
PRT
MLT
FRA
GRC
FIN
financial constraints than larger firms.1
Greater financial constraints are associated Sources: European Commission; authors' calcuations
with higher youth unemployment.
Controlling for country-specific fixed effects and output gap, an additional percentage point of firms
reporting financial constraints is associated with higher youth unemployment rates by 0.3 and 0.4
percentage points (for industrial and services sector respectively). The effect on adult unemployment rates
is smaller (0.2 percentage points).
A 10-percentage-point increase in the average employment share in SMEs (or the SME share of value
added) lowers the Okun’s coefficient by 0.1, making unemployment more pro-cyclical.
1
There are data limitations. The average share of SME up to 2008 is used for each country because the data is available
only from 2008 and stays broadly constant. The percentage of firms reporting financial constraints is small (often zero)
and relatively unchanged, e.g., before the financial crisis only 2 percent of industrial firms reported financial constraints,
on average, compared to 2012–2013 when the average was 9.3 percent.
Cross-country variation. The Okun’s coefficient, i.e., the sensitivity of unemployment rates
to output fluctuations, varies across countries. Estimates range from not significantly
11
SMEs are defined as firms with less than 250 employees, turnover of less than 50 million euro or a balance
sheet less than 43 million euro.
17
different from zero (e.g., Austria, Germany12) to -1.9 in Spain, i.e., a one-percentage-point
reduction in growth increases youth unemployment rates by almost 2 percentage points. The
ranking in the size of the Okun’s coefficient of the countries is consistent with the estimates
reported in Ball et al. (2013), who document the largest coefficient for Spain and the smallest
one for Austria.13
Intercept. The intercept in the Okun’s law equations (1) and (1a) also has an interesting
interpretation, which is sometimes overlooked. The intercept (including the fixed effect
component) would equal the change in unemployment rate when economic growth is zero.
Ball et al. (2013) point out that under the assumption of constant potential growth, the
intercept equals the product of minus the implied potential growth rate and the estimated
Okun’s law coefficient. In other words,
in equation (1)
Because the Okun’s law coefficient is empirically expected to be negative, this suggests that
the intercept in equation (1) should always be positive. The estimates in Table 2 confirm that
this is indeed the case. Intuitively, a positive intercept implies that if actual growth is zero,
while potential growth is positive, the unemployment rate is expected to increase because of
a wider output gap. High values of the intercept terms suggest greater difficulties in
sustainably reducing unemployment, or, put differently, a stronger growth is required to
prevent unemployment rates from rising. Spain has the highest Okun’s law intercept for
youth unemployment exceeding 5 percentage points, with intercepts for Cyprus, Estonia,
Greece, Ireland, Latvia, Portugal, Slovakia, and Sweden exceeding 2 percentage points. Only
for Austria, Germany, Netherlands, and Norway are intercepts not significantly different
from zero. On the other hand, the intercepts in equation (1a) (also including fixed effects) are
almost all insignificant with the exception of Latvia. This is also consistent with economic
theory—when output gap is zero, the deviation of unemployment rate from its natural level
should be zero as well.
Business cycle effects across specifications. How does the impact of the business cycle or the
output gap differ across specifications, i.e. between equation 1(a) which excludes the effect
of labor market factors, and (2) and (3) that includes labor market factors? The estimations
are not comparable because of very different sample sizes. The estimates of the Okun’s
coefficient according to equation 1(a) are based on 565 observations (Table 2). The output
gap coefficients in equation 2, on the other hand, are based on samples sizes that range from
99−160 observations (Table 4); these results are less robust and have therefore not been
reported in this paper to avoid confusion. It is therefore not meaningful to compare the results
12
Even in those cases, some studies have found that the Okun’s law holds for measures of hours worked. For
instance, instead of layoffs, German companies resorted to a decrease in average hours worked per worker
(Reisenbichler and Morgan, 2012).
13
Not surprisingly, the magnitudes differ somewhat from Ball et al. (2013) because our analysis focuses on
specific age groups of the unemployed.
18
across specifications to derive the additional explanatory power from the inclusion of labor
market factors in the estimations, all the more so because of the simplifying assumption that
labor market factors have the same effect across all countries.
Output changes, on average, explain about 50 percent of the increase in youth unemployment
rates during the crisis, as shown in Table 2. Drawing on the labor market literature, this
section examines the role of other possible explanatory factors, in particular the structural
features of the labor market.
Empirical results. Changes in labor market variables were found to not be significant
explanatory factors for the increase in youth unemployment rates. The lack of a robust
relationship between labor market factors and changes in the unemployment rate could
simply reflect the empirical, specification and data challenges that have already been
discussed as well as the inability of the chosen labor market variables to capture country-
specific institutional details that may also be relevant in individual countries.
However, the results of the multivariate approach (equation (2)) suggest that a number of
labor market features are significantly associated with the levels of youth unemployment rate
(Table 4). In particular, lower labor costs (measured by the tax wedge and minimum wages
relative to the median wage) and higher spending on ALMPs, especially for training, are
associated with lower unemployment. Higher opportunity costs of working (measured by
gross and net benefit replacement rates) and stronger labor market duality (indicated by
higher shares of temporary workers and lower employment protection of temporary workers)
tend to raise unemployment, whereas collective bargaining (proxied by union density) has
mixed effects which are not robust.
Robustness. The above results are, by and large, confirmed by the univariate approaches as
well. However, there is a wide divergence in the range of estimates in part due to different
sample sizes used for the different estimations because of data constraints. Considering one
variable at a time allows the utilization of the whole sample for which data is available for
the regressor variable whereas in a multivariate specification the length of the sample is
determined by the sample size of the variable for which the data is least available. Thus, the
sample size can generally be much larger for the univariate estimations than for the
multivariate estimations. However, an important caveat to the results of the univariate
regressions is that they may be prone to omitted variable bias when there are significant
correlations among different labor market features which affect unemployment. Subsequent
references to the estimation of the impact of labor market features generally refer to the
multivariate specifications reported in Table 4, unless otherwise specified.
Greater hiring costs are associated with higher unemployment rates in the literature. Taxes
on employers and employees, together with high statutory minimum wage rates increase
19
labor costs and reduce labor demand. Our results indicate that a one-percentage-point
increase in the tax wedge is associated with an increase in youth unemployment rates by
0.3-1.3 percentage points. The size of the correlation with adult unemployment is smaller
(around 0.4–0.5 percentage points). A one-percentage-point increase in minimum wages
(relative to median wages) is associated with an increase in youth unemployment by
0.4-1.2 percentage points, while the magnitude is smaller for adults. This is consistent with
the finding of OECD (2012) that since 2007 the young have on average been at a big
disadvantage in countries where the minimum wage is relatively high as a share of median
pay.14
An inactivity trap can arise through the interaction of tax and benefit systems. High social
protection benefits can reduce financial incentives to work because the combined effects of
increased tax payments and withdrawn income-tested benefits offset the potential gain in
disposable incomes from increased earnings. Higher inactivity trap is not significantly related
to unemployment when other labor market features are controlled for (Table 4), but is
associated with higher unemployment when investigated alone (Table 5).
14
See also Bernal-Verdugo (2012a).
15
Young workers may not be entitled to full unemployment benefits given their short employment histories.
However, OECD (2006) finds a negative impact of generous unemployment benefits on youth employment that
is comparable in magnitude to other age cohorts.
16
We rely on the OECD gross replacement rate measure due to its availability for a longer period of time
(1983-2011, on a biannual basis).
17
These results are in line with some recent studies—labor market duality has been associated with lower youth
employment rate in a sample of 17 OECD countries over 1960–1996 (Bertola et al., 2007), and flexible labor
market is found to help improve youth labor market outcomes (OECD, 2006, and Choudhury et al., 2012a).
20
Overall, the role of higher union density is found to be unclear and not robust. A
one-percentage-point increase in union density could be associated with lower youth
unemployment rates by 0.2–0.6 percentage points under some specifications.19 However, this
finding is not robust to alternative specifications, including using different control variables
or allowing country-specific interactions. The results from specifications with employment as
dependent variable20 suggest that higher union density may be associated with an altered
employment composition, perhaps because employers prefer to hire the non-unionized youth
instead of the unionized adults in order to preserve the flexibility to adjust the work force as
needed, leading to higher employment for the youth and lower employment for adults.
Most empirical studies using macro-level data have found that ALMP spending, especially on
training, reduces total unemployment (OECD, 2006). We find that higher spending on
ALMPs, especially on training, is associated with reductions in both youth and adult
unemployment rates. An additional thousand euros per unemployed increase in ALMPs
spending is associated with lower youth and adult unemployment rates by around 0.3 and 0.1
percentage points respectively.21
18
The rating is on a scale from 1 (least protection) to 6.
19
This result is based on the OECD’s indicator on union density which measures the incidence of unionization
among the employed, but does not measure the degree of centralization.
20
Not reported in this paper, but available upon request.
21
However, micro-level studies find that the effectiveness of ALMPs varies, and that programs similar at
appearance can yield very different outcomes (e.g., Card, et al., 2010; Kluve, 2010). ALMPs need to be
designed and monitored properly as analysis of such programs shows that the impact and cost-effectiveness of
ALMPs vary significantly based on their design. Studies also show that ALMPs that target young people are not
(continued…)
21
Impact on sensitivity to business cycle. Allowing for interactions between labor market
features and output fluctuations, as specified in equation (3), reveals significant cross-country
differences in the role of labor market features. The coefficient before the interaction term of
the output gap and the labor market variable would indicate the direction and magnitude of
such effect. Given that the Okun’s coefficient is negative, a negative (positive) coefficient
would imply that a particular labor market variable amplifies (dampens) the impact of the
business cycle on unemployment (Table 6). Our analysis, for the most part, finds only limited
evidence that labor market features change how youth unemployment responds to output
fluctuations. For instance, a higher tax wedge is found to amplify the impact of the business
cycle for Finland, Greece, Ireland, Slovakia and Spain, and dampen the impact for Denmark,
Sweden and the United Kingdom (column 5, Table 6). Similarly, total ALMP spending is
found to dampen the business cycle effect in Ireland, Slovakia, and Spain, but amplify the
impact in Finland, France, and Malta. Some of these results may seem counterintuitive and
cannot be properly explained without a detailed assessment of country-specific factors that
may be influencing the results but are not adequately captured in the model specification.
Some authors have suggested that insufficient progress in other structural reforms—e.g.,
product market liberalization—is also an obstacle to facilitating greater youth employment
(see e.g. Nicoletti and Scarpetta, 2001). Picking the appropriate indicator for cross-country
comparison in this dimension was not easy (see Section III), and the chosen measure of
product market reform has important limitations. Thus, it is not surprising that we did not
find conclusive evidence of the link between these indicators and youth unemployment. For
the indicator “goods market efficiency” the estimated coefficient generally have the correct
signs, but the results are only significant in a few countries. The strongest effects are on adult
employment where higher goods market efficiency is associated with higher employment.
The results from using the “cost of doing business indicator” are counterintuitive, perhaps
because many countries have done reforms aimed at reducing the cost of starting a business
in the aftermath of the crisis, suggesting substantial endogeneity.
However, these results should not be construed as evidence against the importance of product
market reforms to facilitate entrepreneurship, but rather of data limitations. A suitable
indicator for measuring the ease of entrepreneurial activity on a cross-country basis is
needed, especially with regard to the ease of starting a new business.
very effective regardless of the type of the program. See “Youth Unemployment in Advanced Economies in
Europe: Searching for solutions,” IMF SDN14/11, Box 1.
22
1.0 1.5
Ireland. Interaction Coefficients Italy. Interaction Coefficients
1.0
0.5
0.5
0.0
0.0
-0.5
-0.5 -1.0
-1.5
-1.0
-2.0
-2.5
-1.5
-3.0
Significant. Insignificant. Significant. Insignificant.
-2.0 -3.5
EPRT
TPROB
GRR
ITRAP
UDENSITY
LOWEDUC
EPRT
GRR
TPROB
NRR
TWEDGE
ITRAP
UDENSITY
MIN2MED
LOWEDUC
ALMPTOT
MIN2MED
NRR
TWEDGE
ALMPTRAIN
ALMPTOT
TSHARE
ALMPTRAIN
TSHARE
1.0 4.0
Greece. Interaction Coefficients Spain. Interaction Coefficients
0.8
3.0
0.6
0.4 2.0
0.2
1.0
0.0
-0.2 0.0
-0.4
-1.0
Significant Insignificant
-0.6
Significant. Insignificant.
-0.8 -2.0
EPRT
TPROB
GRR
ITRAP
UDENSITY
LOWEDUC
NRR
TWEDGE
MIN2MED
TPROB
ALMPTOT
GRR
UDENSITY
EPRT
LOWEDUC
ITRAP
ALMPTRAIN
NRR
TWEDGE
TSHARE
MIN2MED
ALMPTOT
TSHARE
ALMPTRAIN
Note: The data refers to the coefficients for the interaction between labor market features and the output gap.
Source: Authors’ estimates.
V. CONCLUSIONS
This paper documents labor market dynamics in advanced European countries, contrasting
developments in youth and adult labor markets. The analysis investigates the roles of growth
and labor market features in influencing both youth and adult unemployment rates. There is
considerable heterogeneity across countries in the levels and dynamics of youth
unemployment, labor market features and the responsiveness of the labor market to the
business cycle. Nevertheless, a few significant conclusions emerge.
Youth unemployment is more sensitive to economic growth than adult unemployment, and
the drop in economic activity during the global financial crisis explains the increase in
unemployment since 2007 to a large extent, especially in countries that experienced the
highest unemployment. The persistently high levels of unemployment across countries are
explained by both the output gap and a number of labor market features, such as the tax
23
wedge, minimum wages relative to the median, spending on ALMP, and the generosity of
unemployment benefit systems, the availability of vocational training and the incidence of
labor market duality. As the economic recovery takes hold and unemployment rates return
closer to their historical averages, labor market institutions may play an increasingly large
role in influencing labor market dynamics.
The analytical approaches adopted in this paper have been limited by the availability of
comparable data across countries for a variety of structural reform indicators as well as
uncertainties regarding estimations of the output gap and the equilibrium rate of
unemployment. The results therefore may not reflect sufficient country-specific information,
nor do they include the non-linear and lagged effects of the explanatory variables; all this
could have a material effect on the unemployment outcome in a given country. Overcoming
these methodological and data limitations could be a productive avenue for future research.
Nevertheless, the cross-country evidence presented here can highlight systematic patterns of
cross-country divergence and serve as motivation for country-specific analysis. Achieving a
sustainable reduction in unemployment rates in a number of advanced European countries
will be an enormous challenge, suggesting that more analysis will continue to be required in
the future for these countries.
24
REFERENCES
Altindag, D., and Mocan, N., 2010, “Joblessness and Perceptions About the Effectiveness of
Democracy”, Journal of Labor Research, 31 (2), pp. 99 – 123.
Anderton, R., Aranki, T., Bonthius, B., and Jarvis, V., 2014, “Disaggregating Okun’s Law:
Decomposing the Impact of the Expenditure Components of GDP on Euro Area
Unemployment”, forthcoming ECB Working Paper.
Arpaia, A., Kiss, Á., Pálvölgyi, B., and Turrini, A., 2014, “Labour Mobility and Labour
Market Adjustment in the EU”, European Commission, Directorate-General for
Economic and Financial Affairs, Economic Papers, forthcoming.
Ball, L., Leigh, D. and Loungani, P., 2013, “Okun’s Law: Fit at Fifty?” Working Paper
18668, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Bassanini, A. and Duval, R., 2006, “The Determinants of Unemployment Across OECD
Countries: Reassessing the Role of Policies and Institutions”, OECD Economic
Studies 42.
Bernal-Verdugo, L. E., Furceri, D., and Guillaume, D., 2012a, “Labor Market Flexibility and
Unemployment: New Empirical Evidence of Static and Dynamic Effects”,
Comparative Economic Studies 54, (251 – 273).
____________, Furceri, D., and Guillaume, D., 2012b, “Crises, Labor Market Policy, and
Unemployment”, IMF Working Paper no. 12/65.
Bertola, G., Blau F.D., and Kahn, L. M., 2007, “Labor Market Institutions and Demographic
Employment Patterns”, Journal of Population Economics, 20 (4), pp. 833 – 867.
Blanchard, O., Griffiths, M., and Gruss, B., 2013a. “Boom, Bust, Recovery: Forensics of the
Latvia Crisis.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (Fall).
Card, D., Kluve, J., and Weber, A., 2010, “Active Labor Market Policy Evaluations: A Meta-
Analysis”, The Economic Journal, 120 (548), pp. F452–F477.
Carmichael, F. and R. Ward, 2001, “Male Unemployment and Crime in England and Wales”,
Economics Letters 73 (2001) 111–115.
Choudhry, M., Marelli, E., and Signorelli, M., 2012a, “Youth and Total Unemployment Rate:
the Impact of Policies and Institutions”, mimeo, Available at
http://www.eco.unibs.it/~emarelli/CMS_unemp_instit.pdf
25
____________, Marelli, E., and Signorelli, M., 2012b, “Youth Unemployment and the
Impact of Financial Crises”, International Journal of Manpower 33(1): 76–95.
Coles, B., Hutton S., Bradshaw, J., Craig, G., Godfrey, C. and Johnson, J., 2002, Literature
Review of the Costs of Being ‘Not in Education, Employment or Training’ at Age 16-
18, Research Report, 347, Department of Education and Skills, Nottingham.
Dao, M., and Loungani, P., 2010, “The Human Cost of Recessions: Assessing It, Reducing
It”, IMF Staff Position Note, SPN/10/17.
European Commission, 2012, “Moving Youth into Employment”, Communication from the
Commission to the European Parliament, the Council, the European Economic and
Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions, 727.
____________, 2013a, “Working Together for Europe’s Young People: A Call to Action on
Youth Unemployment”, Communication from the Commission to the European
Parliament, the Council, the European Economic and Social Committee and the
Committee of the Regions, 447.
Fougère, D., Kramarz, F., and Pouget, J., 2009, "Youth Unemployment and Crime in
France", Journal of the European Economic Association, 7 (5), pp. 909 – 938.
Giuliano, P., and Spilimbergo, A., 2009, “Growing Up in a Recession: Beliefs and the
Macroeconomy”, NBER Working Paper No. 15321.
Gregg, P., and Tominey, E., 2005, “The Wage Scar from Male Youth Unemployment”,
Labor Economics, Volume 12, Issue 4, August 2005, Pages 487.
Hill, J., 2003, Young People Not in Education, Training or Employment: Key Indicators,
Ministry of Social Development, Wellington, New Zealand.
International Monetary Fund, 2014, “Youth Unemployment in Europe: Okun’s Law and
Beyond,” IMF Country Report No. 14/199. International Monetary Fund, Washington
DC.
____________, 2014, “Youth Unemployment in Advanced Economies in Europe: Searching
for Solutions,” IMF Staff Discussion Note 14/11. International Monetary Fund,
Washington DC.
Jimeno, J. F., and Rodriguez-Palenzuela, D., 2002, “Youth Unemployment in the OECD:
Demographic Shifts, Labor Market Institutions, and Macroeconomic Shocks”, ECB
Working paper no. 155, June.
Kahn, L. B., 2010, “The Long-Term Labor Market Consequences of Graduating from
College in a Bad Economy”, Labor Economics 17, pp. 303 – 316.
Kluve, J., 2010, “The Effectiveness of European Active Labor Market Programs”, Labor
Economics 17 pp. 904 – 918.
McGregor, A., Clelland, D. and Reid, J., 2006, “Evaluation of Measurement Options for
Those Aged 16–19 Not in Employment, Education or Training (NEET)”, Scottish
Executive, Edinburgh.
Nickell, S. and Layard R., 1999, “Labor Market Institutions and Economic Performance”, in
O. Ashenfelter and D. Card (eds.) Handbook of Labor Economics. Vol. 3C, North-
Holland, Amsterdam.
____________, 2006, “Boosting Jobs and Growth,” OECD Employment Outlook, Chapters 3
and 7, OECD Publishing.
Oreopoulos, P., von Wachter, T., and Heisz A., 2012, “The Short- and Long-Term Career
Effects of Graduating in a Recession”, American Economic Journal: Applied
Economics 4(1): 1-29.
O’Higgins, N., 2012, “This Time It’s Different? Youth Labor Markets During ‘The Great
Recession’ ”, Comparative Economic Studies, 3.
Reisenbichler, A. and Morgan, K. J., 2012, “From “Sick Man” to “Miracle”: Explaining the
Robustness of the German Labor Market During and After the Financial Crisis 2008-
09”, Politics & Society 2012 40: 549 DOI: 10.1177/0032329212461616.
Scarpetta, S., 1996, “Assessing the Role of Labour Market Policies and Institutional Settings
on Unemployment: A Cross-Country Study,” OECD Economic Studies No. 26,
1996/1.
____________, S., Sonnet A., and Manfredi T., 2010, “Rising Youth Unemployment During
The Crisis: How to Prevent Negative Long-term Consequences on a Generation?”,
OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers, No. 106, OECD
Publishing doi:10.1787/5kmh79zb2mmv-en.
Table 1. Data Definitions
Variable Definition Source
Output gap (Real GDP - Real potential GDP) as a percent of real potential GDP WEO (estimates as of Feb. 2014)
GDP growth Year-on-year growth of GDP, constant price WEO
Unemployment rate Unemployed population as a percent of labor force in corresponding age cohort. Eurostat
Net replacement rate Net benefits replacement rate is defined as the ratio of net income while out of work (mainly unemployment benefits if European Comission Tax and
unemployed, or means-tested benefits, if on social assistance) divided by net income while in work. A lower net Benefits Indicators Database
replacement rate is associated with greater incentive to search for and take up a job when unemployed.
Gross replacement rate Average of the gross unemployment benefit replacement rates for two earnings levels, three family situations and three OECD
durations of unemployment.
Inactivity trap The inactivity trap - or the implicit tax on retuning to work for inactive persons - measures the part of additional gross European Comission Tax and
wage that is taxed away when an inactive person (not entitled to receive unemployment benefits but eligible for income- Benefits Indicators Database
tested social assistance) takes up a job. In other words, this indicator measures the financial incentives to move from
inactivity and social assistance to employment.
Minimum wage/Median wage Minimum wage relative to median wage for full-time workers. This ratio is set to be zero for countries without a national OECD
minimum wage.
Protection of temporary workers Strictness of employment protection for tempororary contracts. OECD
Share of temporary workers Temporary employees as percentage of the total number of employees. Eurostat
Tax wedge (EC) The tax wedge is defined as the proportional difference between the costs of a worker to their employer (wage and European Comission Tax and
social security contributions, i.e. the total labour cost) and the amount of net earnings that the worker receives (wages Benefits Indicators Database
minus personal income tax and social security contributions, plus any available family benefits). Tax wedge measures
both incentives to work (labour supply side) and to hire persons (labour demand side).
Union density Trade union density corresponds to the ratio of wage and salary earners that are trade union members, divided by the OECD
total number of wage and salary earners (OECD Labour Force Statistics). Density is calculated using survey data,
28
wherever possible, and administrative data adjusted for non-active and self-employed members otherwise.
Adjusted bargaining power Employees covered by wage bargaining agreements as a percentage of all wage and salary earners in employment with The QOG (Quality of
the right to bargaining, adjusted for the possibility that some sectors or occupations are excluded from the right to Government) Institute,
bargain (removing such groups from the employment count before dividing the number of covered employees over the University of Gothenburg
total number of dependent workers in employment).
Share of temporary workers on probation Proportion of total temporary workers on probation (other reasons for being on temporary contracts include "could not Eurostat
find a permanent job", "did not find a permanent job", "in education or training").
Share of low-educated workers Persons with lower secondary education attainment. Eurostat
ALMP total spending per unemployed Active labor market policies are programs that intervene in the market to address unemployment, via increasing Eurostat
employment opportunities for job seekers and improving balance between jobs available and qualified job seekers. Total
spending per unemployed includes spending on labor market services, training, hiring incentives for firms, supported
employment and direct jobs (for the public/nonprofit sector), and start-up incentives for self-employment.
ALMP spending per unemployed on training Active labor market policy: spending on training per unemployed. This is a sub-component of the total ALMP spending Eurostat
defined above. Spending on training is among the largest components of ALMP spending in most countries.
29
31
Share of low-educated workers 0.01 0.08 0.07 -0.13*** -0.12*** -0.12**
(0.10) (0.08) (0.08) (0.04) (0.04) (0.05)
ALMP total spending per unemployed -0.36*** -0.32*** -0.21*** -0.23*** -0.27*** -0.21*** -0.13*** -0.14*** -0.07*** -0.10*** -0.08*** -0.10***
(0.06) (0.04) (0.07) (0.07) (0.06) (0.07) (0.03) (0.02) (0.02) (0.03) (0.02) (0.02)
Country-specific output gap coefficient Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country fixed effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Number of Observations 144 151 104 160 99 106 144 151 107 160 101 114
Adjusted R-squared 0.93 0.94 0.96 0.93 0.96 0.96 0.93 0.93 0.95 0.91 0.95 0.95
Hiring cost
Minimum wage/Median wage 0.18* 0.01 0.62*** 0.56*** -0.42*** -0.51***
(0.11) (0.06) (0.16) (0.17) (0.09) (0.08)
Tax wedge (EC) 0.72** 0.39*** 0.86** 1.04*** -0.30** -0.41***
(0.28) (0.11) (0.36) (0.35) (0.15) (0.08)
Collective bargaining
Union density -0.01 0.10*** 0.34*** 0.43*** 0.29*** -0.49***
(0.04) (0.03) (0.10) (0.14) (0.06) (0.04)
Adjusted bargaining power 0.16*** 0.00 -0.66*** -1.11*** 0.19*** 0.00
(0.05) (0.03) (0.24) (0.19) (0.07) (0.05)
Duality
Protection of temporary workers 2.26 1.05 3.35 2.91 1.35 -0.51
(1.78) (0.77) (2.58) (2.18) (1.05) (0.56)
Share of temporary workers 0.06** 0.06 -0.10* 0.38* -0.17*** 0.58***
(0.03) (0.05) (0.06) (0.22) (0.04) (0.08)
Education/Training
Share of temporary workers due to probation -0.14 0.02** -0.09 0.03 0.15 -0.08***
(0.08) (0.01) (0.09) (0.05) (0.10) (0.01)
Share of low-educated workers -0.12*** -0.00 0.25*** 0.36*** 0.18*** -0.30***
(0.04) (0.02) (0.05) (0.06) (0.04) (0.01)
Country fixed effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year fixed effect No No No No No No No
Observations 471 239 239 507 258 498 313
Adjusted R-squared 0.77 0.83 0.84 0.78 0.86 0.77 0.76
34
40 60
50
30
40
20 30
20
10
10
0 0
ESP
DEU
NLD
GRC
IRL
SVK
LUX
DNK
FRA
ITA
NOR
BEL
FIN
PRT
AUT
SWE
GBR
MLT
NLD
NOR
LUX
BEL
SWE
FRA
CYP
LVA
AUT
PRT
GBR
ITA
ESP
GRC
EST
FIN
DEU
DNK
SVN
IRL
SVK
60
Tax Wedge, percent 0.8
Ratio of Minimum to Median Wage
50 2001 2013 2013 Average 0.7
2001 2012 2012 Average
0.6
40
0.5
30
0.4
20 0.3
10 0.2
0.1
0
POR
NET
LTV
NOR
LUX
MAL
GER
DEN
GRE
CYP
FRA
SWE
BEL
UK
AUT
ESP
ITA
EST
FIN
IRE
SVK
SVN
ESP
EST
GRC
IRL
NLD
LUX
SVN
SVK
BEL
LVA
FRA
PRT
GBR
Notes Latest data for Cyprus is 2007, Latvia and Malta,
2012.
90 80
Union Density, percent Share of temporary employment, 2013, percent
80 70 Youth Adult
2001
70
60
2010-11
60
2011 Average 50
50
40
40
30
30
20
20
10 10
0 0
SVN
SVK
IRL
BEL
CYP
AUT
FRA
LVA
PRT
MLT
GRC
GBR
ESP
DNK
ITA
EST
NLD
DEU
NOR
ESP
LUX
FIN
EST
DEU
SWE
GRC
NLD
IRL
SVN
SVK
LUX
DNK
FRA
BEL
NOR
ITA
FIN
PRT
AUT
SWE
GBR
36
50
3
40
30 2
20
1
10
0 0
ESP
GRC
DNK
DEU
ITA
FIN
IRL
SWE
BEL
FRA
AUT
PRT
GBR
NLD
NOR
SVK
SVN
IRL
BEL
CYP
AUT
FRA
LVA
PRT
MLT
GBR
GRC
ESP
DNK
NLD
ITA
EST
DEU
NOR
LUX
FIN
SWE
70 25
Total ALMP spending per unemployed, Spending on ALMP measures per unemployed,
Thousands
(thousand euros) (thousand euros)
60
2006 2006
20 2011
50 2011
2011 Average
2011 Average
15
40
30 10
20
5
10
0
0
GRC
ESP
DNK
EST
ITA
DEU
FIN
LUX
SVK
SVN
SWE
IRL
BEL
CYP
AUT
FRA
LVA
PRT
MLT
GBR
NLD
NOR
SVK
SVN
IRL
BEL
CYP
AUT
FRA
LVA
PRT
GRC
MLT
GBR
ESP
DNK
DEU
NLD
EST
ITA
NOR
FIN
LUX
SWE
6.0 35.0
Goods Market Efficiency: Competition(rating) Cost of starting a business,
percent of income per capita
2006 2013 2013 Average 30.0
5.5 2004
25.0 2014
2014 Average
5.0
20.0
4.5 15.0
10.0
4.0
5.0
3.5 0.0
GRC
ESP
DNK
EST
ITA
DEU
FIN
LUX
SVK
SVN
SWE
IRL
CYP
BEL
AUT
FRA
LVA
PRT
MLT
GBR
NLD
NOR
GRC
ESP
DNK
EST
ITA
DEU
FIN
LUX
SVK
IRL
SVN
SWE
BEL
CYP
AUT
FRA
LVA
PRT
MLT
GBR
NLD
NOR
Source: Eurostat, European Commission, OECD, World Economic Forum, World Bank Doing Business Report,
authors’ calculations
37
SVK
IRL
SVN
BEL
AUT
CYP
FRA
LVA
PRT
ESP
GBR
MLT
GRC
DNK
ITA
NLD
EST
DEU
NOR
FIN
LUX
SWE
-0.3
GRC
ESP
DNK
DEU
ITA
FIN
LUX
SVK
IRL
SWE
BEL
AUT
FRA
PRT
GBR
NLD
NOR
Inactivity Trap Minimum to Median Wage Ratio
2.0 0.7
Significant (Youth)
0.6
1.5 Insignificant (Youth)
0.5
1.0 Significant (Adult)
0.4
Insignificant (Adult)
0.5 0.3
0.2
0.0
0.1
-0.5 0.0
-1.0 -0.1
Significant (Youth) Insignificant (Youth)
Significant (Adult) Insignificant (Adult) -0.2
-1.5
SVK
SVN
IRL
BEL
CYP
AUT
FRA
LVA
PRT
GRC
ESP
GBR
DNK
DEU
NLD
ITA
NOR
EST
FIN
LUX
SWE
SVK
SVN
IRL
BEL
CYP
AUT
FRA
LVA
PRT
GBR
ESP
MLT
GRC
DNK
DEU
NLD
EST
ITA
NOR
FIN
LUX
SWE
1.3 0.2
1.0 0.1
0.0
0.8
-0.1
0.5
-0.2
0.3
-0.3
0.0 Significant (Youth)
-0.4 Insignificant (Youth)
-0.3
-0.5 Significant (Adult)
Significant (Youth) Insignificant (Youth)
-0.5 Insignificant (Adult)
Significant (Adult) Insignificant (Adult) -0.6
-0.8
SVK
IRL
SVN
BEL
AUT
FRA
PRT
ESP
GRC
GBR
DNK
ITA
NLD
EST
DEU
NOR
FIN
LUX
SWE
SVK
IRL
SVN
BEL
AUT
CYP
FRA
LVA
PRT
ESP
GBR
MLT
GRC
DNK
ITA
NLD
EST
DEU
NOR
FIN
LUX
SWE
38
DNK
GRC
DEU
ESP
ITA
DNK
EST
DEU
EST
ITA
FIN
LUX
SVK
SVN
FIN
LUX
IRL
SWE
SVK
SVN
SWE
BEL
AUT
FRA
IRL
BEL
CYP
LVA
PRT
AUT
FRA
LVA
PRT
GBR
MLT
GBR
NLD
NOR
NLD
NOR
Share of Temporary Workers Share of Low Educated Workers
0.5 0.2
0.3 0.1
0.0 0.0
-0.3 -0.1
-0.2
-0.5
-0.3 Significant (Youth)
-0.8 Significant (Youth)
-0.4 Insignificant (Youth)
-1.0 Insignificant (Youth)
Significant (Adult) -0.5 Significant (Adult)
-1.3
Insignificant (Adult) -0.6 Insignificant (Adult)
-1.5
-0.7
-1.8
SVK
SVN
IRL
CYP
AUT
BEL
FRA
LVA
PRT
MLT
GBR
ESP
GRC
DNK
DEU
NLD
EST
ITA
NOR
FIN
LUX
SWE
IRL
CYP
BEL
FRA
AUT
LVA
PRT
GBR
ESP
GRC
MLT
DNK
DEU
NLD
EST
ITA
FIN
LUX
SLV
SWE
FRA
LVA
PRT
MLT
GBR
GRC
ESP
DNK
DEU
NLD
EST
ITA
NOR
FIN
LUX
SWE
GRC
ESP
DNK
DEU
ITA
EST
FIN
LUX
SVK
SVN
IRL
SWE
BEL
CYP
AUT
FRA
LVA
PRT
MLT
GBR
NLD
NOR