Will Information Technology Reshape The North-South Asymmetry of Power in The Global Political Economy?
Will Information Technology Reshape The North-South Asymmetry of Power in The Global Political Economy?
Will Information Technology Reshape The North-South Asymmetry of Power in The Global Political Economy?
Steve Weber is director of the Institute of International Studies and professor of political science at
the University of California, Berkeley. His most recent book, The Success Open Source, was
published in April 2004 by Harvard University Press.
Jennifer Bussell is a doctoral candidate in political science at the University of California, Berkeley.
Her research is on the political determinants of information and communication technology access
in developing countries.
Studies in Comparative International Development, Summer 2005, Vol. 40, No. 2, pp. 62-84.
disruptive to current ways of doing things to call into question assumptions about
the "inevitability" or "natural state" of many economic processes and
Weber and Bussell 63
It's now approximately 35 years since Robert Noyce and Gordon Moore offered to
the world Intel's first microprocessor. A little more than a decade later, IBM and
Apple introduced the notion of a "personal" computer. Another decade brought
widespread diffusion of the Internet, connecting all those computers together, and
a bit later came the World Wide Web, a system for linking together documents
located pretty much anywhere in the network. Roughly another decade brings us
to the present, where the Internet has gone wireless and is on the verge of becoming
ubiquitous. Processing power is now just about so inexpensive and connectivity so
widespread that the vision of "smart objects"—that is, sensory capabilities and
intelligence embedded in just about every physical object that people use—is
becoming a reality.
Big deal. From a global macro-perspective, the international political economy
has changed little. The United States is still rich and Africa is still poor. Most
developing countries still export raw materials and low-cost manufactured goods
and are thus more vulnerable to economic shocks and creeping commoditization
64 Studies in Comparative International Development / Summer 2005
than are developed countries. And the supposed "end of geography" effect has been
anything but: look at a map of Internet bandwidth and notice the thickness of the
lines that converge on North America relative to the extraordinarily thin coverage
in the global South. I An email from Rwanda to Ethiopia most likely travels through
New York or London in order to reach its destination. The geography of
telecommunications is almost painfully reminiscent of colonial railroads that ran
toward export ports but systematically avoided direct inter-colonial connections.
Surely the biggest shift in global development over the last 25 years is the
emergence of China but that story began prior to the digital revolution. And
although new technologies have certainly facilitated the effective insertion of
China into global production networks, the Chinese development story really has
been driven principally by other factors.
It might have become fashionable, particularly in the wake of the late-1990s
equity-market burst, to extend the Solow paradox ("computers show up
everywhere except in the productivity statistics") to an argument about economic
development overall. The overblown hype of the late 1990s positively invites this
kind of reaction. But it's an overreaction. In fact, the Solow paradox (if it was ever
really as paradoxical as it sounded) has begun to unravel, at least in the way
American productivity statistics held up during the most recent recession and
recovery. More sober voices of organizational theory reminded everyone of
another "law" that goes along with Moore's Law, that for every $1 that a successful
company spends on technology, it spends $10 on investment in reorganization in
order to be able to effectively use that technology (Brynjolfsson and Hitt, 2000).
And Carlota Perez, in Technological Revolutions and Financial Capital, put
forward a simple five-phase model of technology revolutions that is strikingly
isomorphic across at least four modern historical episodes: the first industrial
revolution in Britain, the age of steam and railways, the age of steel and heavy
engineering, and the age of oil, the automobile, and mass production (Perez, 2003:
18).
The expectations that Perez's arguments create for digital technology are pretty
clear. In the 1980s we probably passed through what Perez calls the "irruption
phase," where new technologies emerge and show hints of their future potential
across a broad range of industries. The 1990s gave us her "frenzy phase," where
financial capital gets ahead of everything else and creates a market bubble of
overinvestment, which tends to overshadow the very significant buildup of new
infrastructure and technological capabilities that will provide a foundation for
widespread economic change. The frenzy phase, of course, ends in a "turning
point" brought on by the recession that follows the collapse of the financial bubble.
It's during the turning point that institutions broadly begin to adjust in significant
ways to take advantage of the new technologies. Government regulations change,
people experiment with distinctive ways of organizing production, markets are
remade—the "fetters on the mode of production" are released. What follows is a
"synergy phase" in which the rules and the organizations are aligned to facilitate a
full flourishing of what the technology makes possible. The cycle ends with a
"maturity phase" in which the productive extensions of the new technology are on
Weber and Bussell 65
Transaction Costs
presumably would like to communicate with each other not only to exchange
information but also offer each other support. But the transaction costs these
individuals faced in finding each other around the world were prohibitively high
until now. In this kind of discourse, the failure of a community to take shape
because of high transaction costs is just as much a market failure as is the inability
of a widget owner to find a buyer and negotiate a widget-exchange contract that
would benefit both sides. The perfection of markets and the realization of potential
communities are theoretically parallel.
The vision of a low—transaction cost economy and society was in fact rather
radical. The re-engineering of production processes and community organization
set off by this reduction in transaction costs toward an asymptote of zero would be
broad, massive, and—most importantly for our discussion here global. It would
have seemed very strange and inconsistent (as well as unfashionably pessimistic)
to imagine a world where barriers and boundaries were being knocked down by
technology just as soon as someone leaned on them, and at the same time posit the
firm maintenance of the North-South, core-periphery, or similar distinction. And
so "edevelopment" became a new slogan, describing a digitally enabled optimism
for reengineering the place of developing countries in global economic flows.
The G-8 Digital Opportunity Task Force (DOT Force) a joint venture of United
Nations specialized agencies, the Markle Foundation, and Accenture Consulting,
among others—was a powerful symbol of this kind of thinking. Bridging the
"digital divide" was the goal, which meant empowering developing countries to
participate effectively in the emerging global economy. So-called e-readyness was
the prerequisite. And although each recommendation was hedged with the
obligatory caveat that technology was no silver bullet for development, the clear
message coming from the DOT Force and numerous similar groups was this: Make
yourself ready for Internet technology—related direct investment, liberalize your
telecommunications sector, release restrictions on information flow, play by the
rules set by the newly relevant standards bodies (the Internet Corporation for
Assigned Names and Numbers, for example), and the new global economy will
more or less come to you. And that will be a good thing for development.
Of course it was not that simple; even the mega-optimists were not so naive as
that. Bill Gates spoke up to remind people that Microsoft (or at least the Bill and
Melinda Gates Foundation) understood perfectly well that many poor countries
need clean water and access to affordable pharmaceuticals a great deal more than
they need gigabyte ethernet. Some observers pointed out that transaction costs
were in many cases the bread and butter of rent-seeking regimes, and that people
in power very well might not want to reduce the market inefficiencies that enabled
very lucrative corruption. Others pressed more deeply into assumptions about the
terms of trade in a digital global economy: Was exporting data-entry work, low-
level coding, or for that matter cheaply assembled computer hardware really more
advantageous to developing economies than exporting textiles or copper or shoes?
Was the investment and upgrade path to higher value-added products and services
really that much clearer in digital goods than in manufactures? In an unpublished
paper, Weber explored the implications of digitally enabled international trade for
Weber and Bussell 67
commercial liberalism arguments: Does trading in bits and bytes rather than steel
and autos disincentivize countries to go to war?2
These were all good, and in some cases researchable, questions (see Saxenian,
2005). On the whole, they helped to embed the "digital divide" idea in a (usefully)
broader discussion, by reminding everyone that fundamental disparities in access
to and the ability to use new technologies reflect long-standing divides of poverty,
education, and freedom to make choices. That perspective led to a (defensible)
concern that digital technologies might exacerbate global inequality rather than
reduce it. In fact, it is remarkably easy to write a "lock-out" scenario in which
developing economies risk falling further behind the leading edge of a digitizing
world economy. The combination of Moore's Law (rapid increases in processing
power at declining prices) and Metcalfe's Law (positive network externalities,
meaning that the value of the network increases disproportionately as it grows)
suggests that markets could grow intensively and dramatically within the
developed world without necessarily having to expand geographically at the same
pace. After all, it is not a law of nature that trade grows faster than GDP; there is
significant room for within-network growth without creating market links to
developing economies.
As developed economies build networked purchasing and production systems
that depend on advanced digital technologies, countries that are not connected on
favorable terms (and firms within those countries) are deeply disadvantaged. While
these markets may eventually become saturated, in the meantime the effect on
developing countries' economies will be significant. International organizations
and non-governmental organizations are increasingly computer-enabled as well,
which means that they will favor interaction with countries and organizations in
the developing world that are similarly enabled and can interact effectively with
their information systems.
The point is that sophisticated information-technology (IT) capabilities are
becoming a prerequisite to effective interaction with much of the world economy.
And while the prerequisites have grown, so have the potential downsides of lacking
them. The industrial economy may have had inherent limits to growth, implying
that exclusion of much of the world's population was actually necessary in some
sense (it is impossible to imagine a functioning global economy in which every
family in China burns gasoline in an internal combustion engine). There are no
such inherent limits to the information economy, at least not that we can now see.
While the physical infrastructures of the information economy are not trivial, they
are quite a lot cheaper to start, they scale in ways that engines don't, and although
they do require some energy to run, they are really not very petroleum-dependent.
Bittwiddlers produce very little greenhouse gas per unit of value creation, and
many ideas are infinitely customizable for use in difTerent contexts. From an
efficiency perspective, the possible exclusion of four billion people from the next
era of wealth creation makes no sense. From an ethical standpoint, it is even more
problematic than was the exclusion of previous eras, because there is no intrinsic
environmental or resource-base reason for it.
All this simply from a reduction in transaction costs? Not entirely. Changes in
transactions costs, like any other costs, are phenomena that occur at the margin (in
68 Studies in Comparative International Development / Summer 2005
the economic, not pejorative, sense). The important point is that transaction costs
are only one ingredient of the Coase equilibrium; the other ingredient, of course,
is secure and well-defined property rights. It took a little longer to see it, but digital
technologies also empower people and organizations to experiment in new ways
with the rules and norms that make up a property-rights regime. And if Ronald
Coase, Douglass North, and Hernando de Soto could agree on one thing, it would
be that shifting property rights can and will destabilize the foundations of existing
cooperative arrangements, institutions, and power dynamics including the
NorthSouth divide—and probably in more radical ways than do changing
transaction costs.
back to the community fully and without any restriction. It is almost as if the
concept of fair use a provision allowing for the free reproduction of copyrighted
works under certain limited circumstances—was extended without boundaries,
along with a guarantee that no individual 's fair use will be permitted to constrain
subsequent fair use by any other individual, for any purpose.
Open source is profoundly remaking the economics of the IT sector in advanced
countries. It is already a major part of the mainstream IT economy, and it
increasingly dominates aspects of that economy which will likely be the leading
edge (in technological and market terms) over the next decade. There exist
thousands of open-source projects, ranging from small utilities and device drivers
to office suites like OpenOffice, database systems like MySQL, and operating
systems like Linux. The Linux operating system and the Apache Web server attract
the most public attention. Apache simply dominates the Web-server market: over
65% of all active Web sites use Apache. 4 Nearly 400 0 of large American
companies use Linux in some form; it is the operating system for more than a third
of active Web servers and holds a significant and increasing proportion of the
server market overall. 5 If you use Google to search the Web, you use a cluster of
thousands of computers running Linux. Examples of other open-source projects in
wide use abound. Sendmail is an open-source email transfer and management
program that powers about 80% of the world's mail servers. BIND is an open-
source program that acts as the major addressing system for the Internet. Yahoo
runs its directory services on FreeBSD, another open-source operating system. If
you saw the movies Titanic or Lord ofthe Rings, you were watching special effects
rendered on Linux machines that are running at companies like Disney,
Dreamworks, and Pixar. Increasingly, open-source software is running major
enterprise applications for large and small corporations alike. Amazon, E* trade,
Reuters, and Merrill Lynch are examples of companies that have recently switched
backend computer systems to Linux. Large parts of the United States government,
including the Defense Department, the Department of Energy, and the National
Security Agency, work with open-source software (Weber, 2004). Microsoft cites
open-source alternatives as its major business threat in several of the market sectors
the company dominates (Hellweg, 2004). IBM has essentially bet its future on a
strategy built around open-source platforms (Galli, 2005). And open-source
software is a major factor in fast-evolving markets for embedded code that runs
"smart" devices, a sector that many foresee as the major source of growth in the IT
economy over the next decade.
Open source is not a marginal phenomenon that can be dismissed as the quixotic
activity of software enthusiasts and code hobbyists. It is mainstream and central to
the IT economy. Innovation is being fostered and promoted in dispersed networks
of collaborators who are not held together under a corporate, state, university, or
other authoritative organization. And as a result, software is becoming a tool, and
even more so a commodity in some of the most important applications and markets.
Value and profits are being redistributed to people and companies that provide
services, customization, integration, design, and in some cases (ironically)
hardware.
70 Studies in Comparative International Development / Summer 2005
From a global economic perspective, the success of open source is doing two
very important things. First, it is removing raw software code—which arguably is
to the next era of economic growth what petroleum as it comes out of a well was
to an earlier era from the control of any company or government and turning it into
something like a commons, albeit a commons that is uniquely valuable because it
cannot be depleted by overuse. Second, it is creating a large and growing body of
code that can be studied, manipulated, customized, and recombined into new
configurations by anyone who has the training and experience to work with it.
Weber argues in The Success of Open Source (2004) that this will deeply
accelerate the rate of innovation in information technology overall, since software
is by any reasonable measure the rate-limiting step in the information economy.
For developing economies in particular, Weber (2004) argues that the
implications could be very significant. Assume, again, the simple notion that
software is a tool for manipulating information. If the tool is essentially free to
anyone who wants to use it, and freely modifiable to make it useful in whatever
way the user can manage, then lots of people will grab the tool and experiment
with it. The opensource community has been international from the start and
remains so; it transcends national boundaries in a profound way because its
interests (as well as its product) are not tied to or dependent on any government.
This observation is more than simply the fact that open-source developers live in
countries all over the world. It is important that developers in China, Indonesia,
and other developing countries contribute to open source software, but what is
more important is that they all have access to the tool, and on equal terms. We
consider the implications of this access for the South in greater detail below.
A more expansive and speculative argument sees digital ICTs—and, as we
discuss below, the success of the open-source software process—as driving
changes in ideas about ownership, property, and control—the way in which people
order economies in the broadest sense of that term. In Institutions, Institutional
Change, and Economic Performance (1990), Douglass North labels these kinds of
ideas as institutions, "humanly devised constraints that shape human interaction."
By creating patterns of incentives and constraints for individuals to act and to
organize for joint action, institutions establish self-reinforcing and (more or less)
locked-in paths of economic development (North, 1990). If you accept North's
simple model, then the potential leverage on development paths comes not from
technology itself per se, but from the broad organizational changes that technology
will drive via its impact on institutions. And there is no institution more central to
market-exchange systems than property rights. A production process that
challenges existing property rights has the potential to undermine the stability of
low-performance but otherwise selfreinforcing equilibrium conditions. After all,
importing a new property-rights regime is at least as much "shock therapy" as
importing someone else's currency and price regime.
In this way ICTs, and particularly open source, may challenge or transform
global systems of property rights. What are the implications for global
development, and particularly the North-South divide? While the story is yet to be
written, we lay out two scenarios below with very different implications for the
global division of wealth and power.
Weber and Bussell 71
global. What is distinctive about digital technologies is that they make it possible
to imagine a shared global infrastructure that is far less expensive than a similarly
global and shared infrastructure would necessarily have been in a physical
environment (think railroads, or even container shipping). Open source can be seen
as the software piece of this infrastructure; add to that the profusion of physical
transmission through fiber and increasingly through extensive wireless capabilities,
along with terminals at the endpoints whose capabilities double every 1 8 months
or so by Moore's Law, and you have something that (probably for the first time in
human history) could approach a truly global infrastructure. Whether or not this
will happen in practice is an open question.
Two proto-scenarios of how the development of such an infrastructure might
play out are on the horizon. These scenarios are rooted in distinct concepts of how
property-rights battles evolve, and they can be used to generate differing sketches
of a global economic environment for development. In each of these scenarios
there is a differing outcome of these property-rights battles, which occur over both
the ownership of code, standards, and other knowledge-based factors in the global
economy, and the digital infrastructure itself, the physical wires and transmitters
on which this knowledge flows. Like any infrastructure, this would become a
platform on which people, economies, and societies would build (and potentially
share) their own "applications." Whether or not this infrastructure becomes
globally linked and shared among countries is a key difference between the
scenarios we propose. There are opportunities for a developmental upside to this
picture, but it is not a simple picture to construct, even as a scenario. The critical
uncertainties lie in the architecture of this technological infrastructure and,
following from that, what behavior(s) it would facilitate or support. In Code and
Other Laws of Cyberspace (1999), Lawrence Lessig reminds everyone that no
architecture (economic or political) is featureless and equally facilitative of all
action by all players. Networks have nodes; code instantiates rules; information
wants to be neither free nor very expensive. Put simply, a global digital
infrastructure is not predisposed to become the foundation of a power-free world,
any more so than any other kind of infrastructure would be. Where power lies, in
turn, depends on who provides what pieces of the infrastructure, and how it is
owned, distributed, taken care of, maintained, and upgraded over time.
This is a partly familiar and partly unfamiliar problem. The familiar part
resembles a multiplayer battle of the sexes—type game, where the issue is not
whether we all prefer to agree on a standard, but rather is over which standard we
prefer to agree upon. Put differently, everyone might desire coordination on a
global digital infrastructure, but the battle is joined over the differential distribution
of costs and benefits within particular manifestations of that outcome. A simple
version of the dilemma looks like this: Two neighbors desire a new streetlight on
their block (Varian, 1998). The light is worth $400 to each but costs $700 to build.
A contractor may be able to solve this problem (but not always, depending on other
aspects of the neighbors' preferences) in the first instance by soliciting increasing
bids from each neighbor until she is offered more than $700 total. But that does
not solve the maintenance problem, or for that matter other aspects of the
distributional problem, such as where on the street the lamp will be built. Scaled
Weber and Bussell 73
up to multiple players, this part of the problem may not change shape in principle,
but in practice it gets enormously more complicated.
The less familiar part of the problem emerges when the game stretches out over
time. A global digital infrastructure can be a kind of commons. The less familiar
problem is that we are not just trying to manage the provision of a commons, which
then has to be governed so as to make certain that it does not get degraded by
overuse; we are trying in addition to do something a bit harder, the maintenance
and care-taking and particularly the upgrading of that commons over time, since
infrastructures, whether of steel-reinforced road bed or computer code, require
modification for evolving applications and in any case deteriorate with use and
over time. And we would necessarily be doing it all outside the boundaries of
authoritative, state-organized politics, since the state's role as a key provider of
shared infrastructure is declining generally and has always been of lesser
importance in the digital world than elsewhere.
The economics here are about sustained, multi-dimensional, dynamic sharing,
rather than just iterated cooperation. A priori, our expectation is that power takes
on new and perhaps distinctive dimensions in this kind of problem, and that the
actors will discover at least some of these dimensions over time rather than plan
for or strategize around them from the start. For example, the politics of
distributing Internet addresses—which once seemed to be a pure coordination
problem without significant consequences—have become remarkably contentious
as "name-space" emerged to be a scarce and valuable resource for the World Wide
Web (Bach, 2004). For a speculative example, consider that in a (future) world of
far more open financial networks, central banks ' ability to control short-term
interest rates may be a significantly less powerful regulator of economic activity
than the ability to control access to bandwidth. Uncertainty about this future may
act as a salutary veil of ignorance behind which new and reasonably well-
functioning institutions get built to manage digital standards. But it may also
generate anticipatory strategic behavior to gain power over infrastructure and
standards, which will make it very hard to build much of anything that can be
shared among diverse actors.
The scenarios we lay out below address two distinct potential outcomes of these
debates. Neither is a best- or worst-case scenario; there are potential benefits and
threats to both the North and South in each. But they derive from quite different
actions on the part of powerful international actors. They would also have diverse
and significant effects on the character of North-South political economic relations.
The purpose of drawing out scenarios is decidedly not to predict the future but
rather to exaggerate the most important and most uncertain elements of a future,
elements that are most easily seen and debated when they are placed in sharp
Property-Rights Imperialism
The first scenario we call "the imperialism of property rights." The imperial
strategies of 1800s European powers were in one sense simple: Go out into the
world and find more of the critical factors of production (and consumption) for the
74 Studies in Comparative International Development / Summer 2005
industrial economy than you have at home. Organize them in ways that allow easy
insertion into your production systems. Integrate them smoothly so that your
factories and markets expand apace. Use power—peaceful forms if you can, but
more violent forms if you must—to resist any significant challenge. The critical
factors of production for this phase of economic growth were land and people, and
the strategy was called colonialism. Although Britain led, other countries were of
course pressed into a competitive race to enclose what they saw as dwindling
supplies of factors into their production systems, so that Britain could not deny it
to them. Two obvious consequences were a set of conflicts between colonial
powers at the boundaries of their respective holdings, particularly as the windows
of opportunity to grab a place in the sun were seen to be closing down; and anti-
colonial struggles emerging from the people whose resources were being pressed
into forms of property that benefited the colonial power's production systems.
A major thrust of contemporary U.S. foreign economic policy is closely
analogous, with the difference being that knowledge and information are now the
factors of production to be organized. The Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual
Property Rights Agreement (TRIPS), and even more aggressively the TRIPS-Plus
provisions that the U.S. has negotiated into a series of bilateral trade accords, are
emblematic. U.S. trade negotiators describe "piracy" of intellectual property both
as an economic phenomenon and as an ideological, almost moral, affront to
modern behavior. For example, A New York Times Magazine article of January
2005 quoted an un-named administration official arguing that China's lax
enforcement of (American) intellectual property rules were the equivalent of
nuclear threats from the SoViet Union during the Cold War. The imperialism of
property rights is often advertised as protecting markets, but keep in mind that most
of the people who purchase pirated CDs in China would not have bought the real
item simply because they could not afford to do so—and thus most piracy in
developing countries does not represent lost sales. In software markets, there is
actually a clear logic that favors allowing sub rosa piracy in developing countries
in order to "hook" users into particular platforms that they must later pay to service
and upgrade as GDP rises.
What piracy does represent, importantly, is an institutional challenge to a set of
beliefs about what ownership means and why it is configured as it is. The
intellectual-property "incumbents" from industries like music, software,
pharmaceuticals, and others argue that almost any crack in the firmament of
property rights creates a slippery slope toward a black hole for innovation. If they
(sometimes) acknowledge that patent and copyright regimes are in practice
imperfect, they hardly acknowledge any theoretical alternatives. They also claim
that any significant experiments with alternative incentives for innovation and
investment will fail and, in the process of failing, destroy existing systems of
creativity. As Steve Ballmer, CEO of Microsoft puts it, open source is a "cancer"
on the intellectual-property regimes that incentivize innovation. 7
Some targets of this strategy simply do not care and prefer to free-ride on
whatever intellectual property they can access. Many of the targets of this strategy
understand the arguments perfectly well, but simply do not accept their claims of
exclusive truth. And so there is a reaction to the incumbents' arguments that takes
Weber and Bussell 75
on the tone of an anti-imperialist thrust. China did not simply pirate Viagra; the
Chinese State Intellectual Property Office went through a formal process of
invalidating the patent. It will likely do the same at some point soon with
cholesterollowering statin drugs, as the emerging Chinese middle class finds itself
suffering from diseases of modernity (such as coronary artery disease) without the
Western middle-class income or insurance schemes to pay for these drugs.
As isolated "revolts," these are more significant to Pfizer than they are to the
United States economy or to the global economy as a whole; a few invalidated
patents does not a revolution make. The more significant risk to intellectual-
property colonialism comes when target countries unite to define their own
alternative (and autonomous) regimes. Watch for the developing-world consortium
that links an Indian generics manufacturer with a Chinese research lab to produce
and sell low-cost anti-hypertensives in Brazil and Russia. Whether or not a Frantz
Fanon equivalent emerges to give eloquent voice to this kind of initiative, it will
in fact represent a significant anti-imperial repositioning to which the United States,
in turn, will have to decide how to respond.
There's one powerful objection to this scenario in some American circles; and
although it is comforting to those who worry about impending struggles over
intellectual property, it is almost certainly wrong, at least in its strong articulation.
This view rests on the proposition that convergence onto American notions of
intellectual property, and the best ways to "protect" what is valuable within it, is
inevitable. This assumption underpins the claim that as China and other emerging
economies increasingly generate fundamental innovations, they will become
staunch defenders of copyright and something very much like the United States
patent system.
This is possible, but not nearly inevitable. Patent and copyright are pragmatic
compromises between competing values; their terms have changed over time at
least as much in response to the power of economic interests as in response to
economic logic. It is hard to find an economist or lawyer who believes that the
current American intellectual-property regime is anything like a unique or optimal
solution to the underlying problem set it is meant to solve.
To go from that toward a convergence claim strikes us as a naive application of
a latter-day modernization logic, reasoning that today's developing economies will
transition toward the same kinds of market structures that last century's developers
did, because that is the optimal or only equilibrium path. It seems to us far more
likely that today's developers will find other ways of protecting what is valuable
and other ways of extracting rents from different parts of a value chain. Greenfield
experiments in open source—style property systems should be expected in sectors
like music, entertainment, software, pharmaceuticals and others that happen to be
major global strengths for the U.S. economy. To dismiss these challenges as
quixotic, idealistic, and unworkable because they are challenging to the business
models of globally competitive incumbents (many of whom are based in the U.S.),
is to underestimate the creative minds of emerging market entrepreneurs arrayed
against the very different market conditions that they face, and overestimates the
power ofAmerican rules of the game. Some of the larger players, particularly China,
have begun to subtly and in some cases aggressively challenge American/European
76 Studies in Comparative International Development / Summer 2005
on these issues are open questions. The drivers of decisions on this shared model
could indeed be the developing countries themselves. Argentina, Brazil, and
thirteen other southern countries are pressuring the World Intellectual Property
Organization to become a real alternative institutional base of support for
developing countries' intellectual-property agendas. This effort comes in response
to the current dominance of the TRIPs agreement, and highlights the significance
of these international bodies as locations for these debates. 9 Individual countries
also play an important role, for instance, in recent efforts by the Brazilian
government to support open source—based management of Top Level Domain
registries in African countries. These examples represent an increasingly common
coordination between southern actors to support open standards (Wanjiku, 2005).
There are significant advantages to this model of a unified, extensible, and
shared global digital infrastructure. Countries in both the North and the South
would benefit from as-yet unrealized network externalities that increase their
access to both knowledge and global markets. For countries in the South in
particular, there could be significant benefits to an open property-rights system.
The early evidence of this can be seen in the enthusiastic response of developing
countries to the open-source software movement. With the combination of lower
up-front costs to access code, less-onerous intellectual-property restrictions on
customization and redistribution, and the relative lack of legacy systems in many
places, it is no surprise that developing-world markets have become a hotbed of
enthusiasm for open-source deployments. China's Linux sales grew 20 0 0 in 2004
and are expected to continue double-digit growth for the foreseeable future. Latin
Americans are increasingly adopting Linux on the desktop. Government
procurement policies are particularly important in the developing world, where
governments are often lead users in a technical sense as well as a major market
presence. The Brazilian government now requires companies and research
institutes that receive government financing for the purpose of developing software,
to then license it as open source (Benson, 2005).
In 2003, the Chinese government declared Linux the "operating system of choice"
for new installations. Venezuela's national IT institute has said that it expects more
than half the country's public agencies to be using open-source platforms by 2007.
South Korea's government plans to replace a significant proportion of its desktop
installations with open-source packages in the next two years, as do the Israeli and
South African governments. 10 These are, of course, anecdotes, and a series of
anecdotes is not a substitute for comprehensive data. But in the absence of
satisfactory data, these anecdotes at least demonstrate a pattern of proliferating
open-source initiatives. Certainly Microsoft's increasingly aggressive campaigns
to compete with and undermine open-source alternatives in developing-country
markets signal that Microsoft perceives a significant pattern. I l
The degree to which a software tool can be utilized and expanded is limited in
practice. Open-source software, however, is limited only by the knowledge and
learning of the potential users, not by exclusionary property rights, prices, or the
power of rich countries and corporations. It is important to be cautious in thinking
about what this means: knowledge and learning are real constraints (albeit a
different kind of constraint than are exclusionary rights and power). The free
78 Studies in Comparative International Development / Summer 2005
diffusion of tools will not create a profound leveling phenomenon. Even when
everyone has equal access to tools, some people can and will use those tools to
create and add more value than others. Consider an analogy to an imaginary world
where everyone had access to as many steam engines as they wanted, all at the
same time, at nearly no cost, and with an open ability to disassemble, customize,
and reassemble the components. It is still the case that economic development in
the industrial era would have been uneven, but it very well might have been less
drastically uneven than it is today.
If extrapolating this analogy to the information economy sounds outlandish
even as a hypothesis, take a step backward toward more familiar discussions about
the question of "appropriate technology" for poor countries. For most of the second
half of the 20th century it was rich-country governments, and the international
development institutions dominated by them, that made the most important
decisions about what was appropriate technology to transfer to developing
countries. Developing countries themselves had little say in these processes. Open-
source software shifts the decision-making prerogative into the hands of people in
the developing countries. In one sense, the provision of a freely available
technological infrastructure still represents by itself a form of wealth transfer to
poor countries, but it is a wealth transfer that developing countries can maneuver
to their particular advantage. To provide real products and services on top of the
infrastructure requires an investment of local labor to start. India, China, and many
other developing countries have a surplus of inexpensive technical manpower.
Combining surplus manpower with free software tools creates the possibility of an
interesting kind of comparative advantage that will certainly matter in local
markets and in some cases might become important on global markets, as well.
One of the advantages of opensource licensing is that it then prevents a
dysfunctional enclosure of mobilized "southern" resources into "northern"
properties protected by patents that are offered for resale to the "South" at
exploitative prices, a depressingly common pattern for knowledge-intensive
products as diverse as music, plant varieties, and pharmaceuticals.
The promise inherent in this argument is that software innovations can and should
come from everywhere. Emerging markets are not implicitly stuck relying on
commoditized, hand-me-down innovation from the developed world. They can
have their own lead users who pull technology development toward applications
that fit specifically the indigenous needs and demands of emerging markets (Von
Hippel, 2005). Indeed, because information technology often has great plasticity
and is more easily customized than were many industrial-era technologies, the
opportunity for autonomous lead users in emerging markets to deeply influence
the direction of technology development is considerable. Open-source software
helps to tap this potential. Our hypothesis here is that many of the "killer apps"
for developing economies (more modestly, the applications that find widespread
acceptance and drive technology and infrastructure deployment forward) will
almost certainly come from within those economies. This would be accentuated in
the context of a shared global digital infrastructure. In other words, user-centered
design principles developed in the United States and for American users will not
be directly transferable to much of the rest of the world. The same is true of the
Weber and Bussell 79
We quote at length because this statement demonstrates vividly that the issue is
more than saving costs. There is nationalist ideology behind these initiatives, but
also concrete interests. It is no surprise to industrial organization theorists that
governments (like any customer in a market) want to avoid locking themselves into
a single private provider for crucial tools. And it is no surprise to international-
relations theorists that states want to avoid becoming dependent on software whose
export is under U.S. legal jurisdiction and whose development and licensing is
controlled by America's dominant software industry. Communications networks,
e-government applications, and of course just about everything that makes up a
modern military force increasingly run on sophisticated software. No national
government, if it had alternatives, would have chosen during the 20th century to
accept dependence for steel or petroleum on a single supplier or a small number of
suppliers based in a potential rival nation. And so it is unsurprising that the Chinese
government in particular has supported the development of Red Flag Linux and
other open-source packages as a distinct alternative to proprietary software in part
as a development tool, and in part as a lever to reduce potential dependence on a
company that just happens to be based in Redmond, Washington, USA.
80 Studies in Comparative International Development / Summer 2005
globalizing economy, but also to the trade opportunities of actors in the South who
are excluded from these networks, and who will consequently be increasingly
disadvantaged. In addition, while the members of a global religious trade network
may link across NorthSouth economic boundaries, there is no reason to believe
that the power dynamics in networks would differ from those that currently exist
between the North and South. Thus, this vision is not particularly hopeful for
global politics, or for any sense of enhanced solidarity between developing and
developed countries.
to a couple of years (by modest reformulations or testing for safety in children) are
the norm. And the strategic behavior of firms does not reflect a vibrant culture of
discovery that the intellectual-property regime was supposed to incentivize:
clinical trial data are "massaged" by sponsors. "Land grabs" of the human genome
by companies that file for low-quality patents make it likely that almost any
interesting new molecule can be held up in litigation. Putting together a patent
portfolio to pursue the development of particular chemical compounds involves a
huge amount of legal and business wrangling. The deadweight costs are passed on
to consumers. Overall, the perceived legitimacy of the pharmaceutical industry and
its implied license to operate is at real risk, at least in part because the intellectual-
property regime is not working.
The international politics of pharmaceuticals are yet more fragile. To a citizen
of South Africa, the cost of anti-retroviral treatment for AIDS is like a weapon of
mass destruction. The debate over pricing and availability of drugs in poor
countries takes place in the shadow of predictions that 100 million people may die
in Africa from a disease that can now be treated as a chronic condition in the United
States. Indian manufacturers will, in the course of 2005, be brought under WTO
restrictions on exporting generic formulations of patented drugs to other
developing countries. And the Chinese challenge to U.S. drug patents, as we
mentioned earlier, looms large.
There are parallels to each of these concerns in the software sector and most
other knowledge-intensive industries. If the pharmaceutical industry is distinctive,
it is probably because the arguments are further advanced and because the stakes
are more immediately tangible. What happens as the battles over property rights in
the pharmaceutical industry are joined in the next few years will yield early signals
for other industries that development thinkers should watch with great interest.
Conclusion
The potential futures we present here reflect two different sets of consequences
that might follow a simple cause: the staggering increase in availability of digital
technologies, which has forced reconsideration of both the inevitability of
transaction costs and the "predetermined" nature of intellectual property regimes.
We have focused on potential shifts in property rights to highlight looming debates
that may have significant implications for the global economy. It may indeed be
that the North-South power dynamics of 2050 look very similar to those of today,
but it is clear from examining these scenarios that if that turns out to be the case,
actors in the South will have, at the very least, made significant attempts to
influence that trajectory.
Our discussion probably focuses more heavily on the potential downsides of the
two scenarios. This was a conscious choice. While there are important potential
benefits to actors in the South in either case, and particularly within the shared
global digital infrastructure, it is necessary to highlight areas of concern that might
not be immediately obvious otherwise. Movement toward a single model of
property rights may backfire if the assumptions of that system do not meet the
requirements of increasingly more powerful actors in the international arena.
84 Studies in Comparative International Development / Summer 2005
Pressure instead for an open and shared system of infrastructure and standards
promises greater benefits to all, but is limited by the potential rise of value-laden
barriers to exchange. In each of these scenarios, the breaking down of some barriers,
be they economic or technological, could be met with the formation of new barriers
driven by the economic interests of powerful states or the culturally rooted
preferences of individual actors.
This is not to say that new barriers to exchange are predetermined. As we argued
earlier, the two scenarios we have developed here merely set out some central
concerns and opportunities for international development in a digitally enabled
world. The implications of the digital revolution for the South are mixed, which
seems unsurprising given the results of previous development efforts. The digital
revolution is not necessarily more likely to eradicate the North-South divide than
the industrial revolution did. But these technologies do create new spaces for
debate within which developing-country actors can experiment and innovate in an
effort to shape outcomes. Thus, while the answer to the somewhat audacious
question in our title is likely to reflect a compromise between the alternatives we
have sketched, what is certain is that development in a digital era will be
powerfully shaped by the answers to the questions raised here.
Notes
1. For example, see <http://www.telegeography.com/products/map_internet/index.php?
PHPSESSID=8a5368ca2835ec7f301 b9fafebbOOc8c>. Accessed 1 7 April 2005.
2. The argument on this point was that to the extent that breaking up difficult-to-replace supply
chains was a disincentive to conflict, commercial liberal driving forces that press against war
would likely be weaker in a digital economy than in a physical one—simply put, because the
digital economy requires less-fixed and non-redeployable investment. It is easier and less
expensive to relocate software engineering (which you can buy in pieces) than it is to relocate
an FDIfunded physical factory. General Motors has more to lose from a Sino-American conflict
than does Microsoft, at least on the production side of the equation.
3. For a detailed explanation of open-source development processes and characteristics, see Weber
(2004).
4. http://www.netcraft.com/survey/.
5. Precise estimates on this point vary, depending on the metrics. The research firm IDC estimates
that Linux ran on 23% of new servers shipped in 2002 and projects an increase to 32% by 2007.
Gartner puts the numbers at 7% and 16.4%. Most analysts agree that the rate of growth is
somewhere in the range of 20% per year. See for example "The Linux Uprising," Business Week
3 March 2003; the IDC study is available at www.osdl.org/docs/linux_market_overview.pdf.
6. Creative Commons: www.creativecommons.org/about/licenses.
7. http://news.com.com/Why+Microsoft+is+wary+of+open+source/2100-1001 3-268520.html.
8. A lossy image is one in which the image after compression is different from the original image
due to lost information.
9 See http://www.cptech.org/ip/wipo/da.html and http://www.wipo.int/documents/en/document/
govbody/wo_gb_ga/pdf/wo_ga_31 _ I I .pdf.
10. These initiatives are reported in Steve Hamm, "Linux Moves In On the Desktop," Business Week
23 Feb 2004; Ken Spencer Brown, "IBM, Others Pushing Linux onto the Desktop" Investor's
Business Daily 22 Dec 2003; CNet News.com, "Oracle, Red Hat Set Up Linux Center in
Singapore," 23 June 2004; Business News Americas, "Open Source in 50% of Public Entities by
2007," March 9 2005.
Weber and Bussell 85
References
Bach, David. 2004. "Varieties of Cooperation: Regulating Transnational Markets for Information
Goods." Doctoral dissertation, Department of Political Science, University of California, Ber-
Benson, Todd. 2005. "Brazil: Free Software's Biggest and Best Friend." New York Times 29 March.
Brynjolfsson, Erik, and Lorin M. Hitt. 2000. "Beyond Computation: Information Technology,
Organizational Transformation and Business Performance." Journal of Economic Perspectives
14(4):
Galli, Peter. 2005. "IBM gives 500 patents to open-source developers." eWeek I I January.
Hellweg, Eric. 2004. "Microsoft IS worried about Linux." <www.CNNMoney.com>, accessed 9
September 2004.
Kuznets, Simon. 1973[1971]. "Nobel Lecture." In Kuznets, Simon, Population, Capital and Growth:
Selected Essays New York: WW Norton and Company.
Lessig, Lawrence. 1999. Code and Other Laws QfCyberspace. New York: Basic Books.
Liu, Bob. 2002. "China to be Stronghold for Open Source." Developer 5 Nov; at http://
www.internetnews.com/dev-news/article.php/1494881. Accessed 10 May 2005.
North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Perez, Carlota. 2003. Technological Revolutions and Financial Capital. Cheltenham, UK: Edward
Elgar Publishing.
Saxenian, AnnaLee. 2005. "From Brain Drain to Brain Circulation: Transnational Communities and
Regional Upgrading in India and China." Studies in Comparative International Development
40, No. 2: 35-61.
Varian, Hal. 1998. "Markets for Information Goods." Unpublished paper available at http://
hubcap.clemson.edu/—sauerr/classes/425/cases/varian_info%20goods.pdf. Accessed 10 May
2005.
Von Hippel, Eric. 2005. Democratizing Innovation. Cambridge, MIT Press.
Wanjiku, Rebecca. 2005. "Brazil Opens its Arms to Africa." Highway Africa News Agency.
<www.highwayafrica.ru.ac.za/hana/textviewer.asp?item_id=339>. Accessed 5 April 2005.
Weber, Steven. 2004. The Success ofOpen Source. Cambridge, MA, and London: Harvard University
Press.
Weber, Steven, David Bach, and Abraham Newman. 2005. "Price Isn't Everything" in Across the
Board, Mar/Apr.