Market Failure: Market Failure Government Failure Information Economics Environmental Economics Agricultural Economics
Market Failure: Market Failure Government Failure Information Economics Environmental Economics Agricultural Economics
Market Failure: Market Failure Government Failure Information Economics Environmental Economics Agricultural Economics
Main articles: Market failure, Government failure, Information economics, Environmental economics,
and Agricultural economics
Pollution can be a simple example of market failure. If costs of production are not borne by producers but are
by the environment, accident victims or others, then prices are distorted.
The term "market failure" encompasses several problems which may undermine standard economic
assumptions. Although economists categorize market failures differently, the following categories
emerge in the main texts.[b]
Information asymmetries and incomplete markets may result in economic inefficiency but also a
possibility of improving efficiency through market, legal, and regulatory remedies, as discussed
above.
Natural monopoly, or the overlapping concepts of "practical" and "technical" monopoly, is an extreme
case of failure of competition as a restraint on producers. Extreme economies of scale are one
possible cause.
Public goods are goods which are undersupplied in a typical market. The defining features are that
people can consume public goods without having to pay for them and that more than one person
can consume the good at the same time.
Externalities occur where there are significant social costs or benefits from production or
consumption that are not reflected in market prices. For example, air pollution may generate a
negative externality, and education may generate a positive externality (less crime, etc.).
Governments often tax and otherwise restrict the sale of goods that have negative externalities and
subsidize or otherwise promote the purchase of goods that have positive externalities in an effort to
correct the price distortions caused by these externalities.[58] Elementary demand-and-supply theory
predicts equilibrium but not the speed of adjustment for changes of equilibrium due to a shift in
demand or supply.[59]
In many areas, some form of price stickiness is postulated to account for quantities, rather than
prices, adjusting in the short run to changes on the demand side or the supply side. This includes
standard analysis of the business cycle in macroeconomics. Analysis often revolves around causes
of such price stickiness and their implications for reaching a hypothesized long-run equilibrium.
Examples of such price stickiness in particular markets include wage rates in labour markets and
posted prices in markets deviating from perfect competition.
Environmental scientist sampling water
Some specialized fields of economics deal in market failure more than others. The economics of the
public sector is one example. Much environmental economics concerns externalities or "public
bads".
Policy options include regulations that reflect cost-benefit analysis or market solutions that change
incentives, such as emission fees or redefinition of property rights.[60]
Public sector
Main articles: Economics of the public sector and Public finance
See also: Welfare economics
Public finance is the field of economics that deals with budgeting the revenues and expenditures of
a public sectorentity, usually government. The subject addresses such matters as tax incidence (who
really pays a particular tax), cost-benefit analysis of government programmes, effects on economic
efficiency and income distribution of different kinds of spending and taxes, and fiscal politics. The
latter, an aspect of public choice theory, models public-sector behaviour analogously to
microeconomics, involving interactions of self-interested voters, politicians, and bureaucrats. [61]
Much of economics is positive, seeking to describe and predict economic phenomena. Normative
economicsseeks to identify what economies ought to be like.
Welfare economics is a normative branch of economics that uses microeconomic techniques to
simultaneously determine the allocative efficiency within an economy and the
income distribution associated with it. It attempts to measure social welfare by examining the
economic activities of the individuals that comprise society. [62]