Central Banks in The Age of Euro
Central Banks in The Age of Euro
Central Banks in The Age of Euro
Edited by
Kenneth Dyson and Martin Marcussen
1
3
Great Clarendon Street, Oxford ox2 6dp
Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford.
It furthers the University’s objective of excellence in research, scholarship,
and education by publishing worldwide in
Oxford New York
Auckland Cape Town Dar es Salaam Hong Kong Karachi
Kuala Lumpur Madrid Melbourne Mexico City Nairobi
New Delhi Shanghai Taipei Toronto
With offices in
Argentina Austria Brazil Chile Czech Republic France Greece
Guatemala Hungary Italy Japan Poland Portugal Singapore
South Korea Switzerland Thailand Turkey Ukraine Vietnam
Oxford is a registered trade mark of Oxford University Press
in the UK and in certain other countries
Published in the United States
by Oxford University Press Inc., New York
# The several contributors 2009
The moral rights of the authors have been asserted
Database right Oxford University Press (maker)
First published 2009
All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced,
stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means,
without the prior permission in writing of Oxford University Press,
or as expressly permitted by law, or under terms agreed with the appropriate
reprographics rights organization. Enquiries concerning reproduction
outside the scope of the above should be sent to the Rights Department,
Oxford University Press, at the address above
You must not circulate this book in any other binding or cover
and you must impose the same condition on any acquirer
British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data
Data available
Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data
Data available
Library of Congress Control Number: 2009924588
Typeset by SPI Publisher Services, Pondicherry, India
Printed in Great Britain
on acid-free paper by the
MPG Books Group
ISBN 978–0–19–921823–3
1 3 5 7 9 10 8 6 4 2
Acknowledgements and Preface
v
Acknowledgements and Preface
The book’s distinctive character derives from the focus, questions, and ap-
proaches typical of political science in addressing comparative political econ-
omy. It deals with Europeanization, power, and convergence in institutions and
policy processes. It focuses on ideas, institutions, discourse, and strategies in
central banking; asks questions about how they mediate the effects of the euro
on states (Europeanization) and about what they tell us about power and
convergence. At the same time a key theme is the limits of Europeanization as
a concept for capturing processes of change in central banking and differences
in reform trajectories.
The book benefited from two major opportunities to bring together contri-
butors in research workshops. The EU-CONSENT Network of Excellence sup-
ported a first workshop in Cardiff University in May 2007. Special thanks are
due to the British Academy for co-funding a second research workshop in
November 2007 with the EU-CONSENT Network. These workshops provided
invaluable opportunities for authors to present drafts of their chapters for
discussion. In particular, Angela Pusey at the British Academy displayed great
courtesy, patience, and efficiency in ensuring the smooth running of the British
Academy workshop.
In addition, the final revision of chapters benefited greatly from the com-
ments of all contributors, who served as discussants on each other’s papers at
the two workshops. Particular debts of gratitude are owed to Professor Charles
Goodhart (LSE) and to Professor Ivo Maes (Catholic University of Louvain) for
their trenchant advice.
Dominic Byatt and his team at Oxford University Press have offered unfailing
encouragement and support at every stage. Through their commitment, will-
ingness to work as a team, and patience with our efforts at guidance, the
contributors have made our task pleasant and rewarding in personal as well as
in academic terms. The combination of OUP’s professionalism with the dedi-
cation of contributors lightened the editorial load. Nevertheless, as ever, any
shortcomings in the final product remain the responsibility of the editors.
Finally, a few words are needed about the immediate context of the book. It
was written as the dramatic events associated with the financial crisis of 2007–8
began to unfold. The US sub-prime mortgage crisis and the crisis in the inter-
bank money markets had occurred. However, the US rescues of the mortgage
financing giants Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac and the insurance giant AIG, the
bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers, and the spread of bank solvency crises to the
EU and Euro Area lay ahead. By September 2008, the three Benelux govern-
ments were rescuing Fortis bank; the German government and Bundesbank
were bailing out Hypo Real Estate; a number of German states were rescuing
their state banks; whilst EU governments were offering guarantees for bank
deposits in an ad hoc, initially uncoordinated manner. Central banks were
drawn into liquidity support operations and into bank rescue operations on a
massive scale, rediscovering their role as banker to the banks; huge public stakes
vi
Acknowledgements and Preface
were taken in banking systems, not least in the United States and Britain, the
homes of archetypal ‘Anglo-American free market capitalism’; the regulation
and supervision of financial markets became a high-profile political issue;
whilst monetary policy stood uneasily poised between the challenge of infla-
tion and threats from the financial crisis to the real economy of output and
jobs. The economic and political world of central banking was in transform-
ation: A favourable tailwind for monetary policy had been replaced by strong,
volatile headwinds. Clearly, this book does not have the benefits of being able
to look back on this crisis and assess its historical scale and long-term effects on
central banking, an exercise that will be possible in a few years time, though
some points are fairly safe to establish even at this early stage. We can only take
note of events up to spring 2008. This problem is not, however, central to the
book. The first chapter recognizes that since 1999 the age of the euro has been
embedded in a political economy of (in historical terms) good times. This era is
closing. Central banks, financial markets, politicians, and officials will be mak-
ing history in a very different context of hard times. Just how different that
context will be, and what effects their actions will have, we do not yet fully
know.
Kenneth Dyson
Cardiff University, Wales
Martin Marcussen
Copenhagen University, Denmark
June 2008
vii
This page intentionally left blank
Contents
List of Figures xi
List of Tables xiii
Abbreviations xv
Notes on Contributors xix
ix
Contents
References 407
Index 435
x
List of Figures
xi
This page intentionally left blank
List of Tables
xiii
This page intentionally left blank
Abbreviations
xv
Abbreviations
xvi
Abbreviations
xvii
This page intentionally left blank
Notes on Contributors
xix
Notes on Contributors
xx
Notes on Contributors
the co-editor of the Review of International Political Economy and has published
numerous articles and book chapters on post-communist political economy
and identity politics. She has served as both a Research Fellow in Foreign Policy
Studies at the Brookings Institution (1995–6) and the A. John Bittson National
Fellow at the Hoover Institution (2001–2). She is currently finishing a book
entitled Priests of Prosperity: The Transnational Central Banking Community and
Post-Communist Transformation. She received her PhD in Politics from Princeton
University in 1997.
Huw Macartney is an ESRC Postdoctoral Fellow at Nottingham University.
He has recently completed his PhD, Transnational Social Forces, Variegated
Neo-liberalism and Financial Market Integration in the EU, at the University of
Manchester and has a forthcoming article in the British Journal of Politics and
International Relations.
Ivo Maes is a Deputy Head of the Research Department of the National Bank of
Belgium and holds the Robert Triffin Chair at the Institut d’études Européennes
of the Université Catholique de Louvain. His current research focuses on the
history of central banking and European monetary and financial integration.
His recent publications comprise Economic Thought and the Making of European
Monetary Union (Edward Elgar 2002); The Bank, the Franc and the Euro, A History
of the National Bank of Belgium (Lannoo 2005, co-author); and Half a Century of
European Financial Integration. From the Rome Treaty to the 21st Century (Merca-
torfonds 2007). He has been a visiting professor at Duke University (USA) and at
the Université de Paris-Sorbonne.
Martin Marcussen is an Associate Professor of Politics at the University of
Copenhagen. He specializes in global governance, European integration, and
the role of ideas in public policy. He is the author of Ideas and Elites: The Social
Construction of Economic and Monetary Union (Aalborg University Press 2000).
Michael Moran is WJM Mackenzie Professor of Government at Manchester
University and a Fellow of the British Academy. His most recent book is The
British Regulatory State: High Modernism and Hyper-Innovation (Oxford University
Press, 2nd edn, 2007).
George Pagoulatos is an Associate Professor of Politics at the Department of
International and European Economic Studies, Athens University of Economics
and Business, and Visiting Professor at the College of Europe in Bruges. He was a
member of the Greek government’s Council of Economic Advisors (2002–4). He
has published extensively in journals such as West European Politics; Journal of
Common Market Studies; Journal of Public Policy; Public Administration; and European
Journal of Political Research. His book Greece’s New Political Economy: State, Finance
and Growth from Post-war to EMU (Oxford St. Antony’s Series, Palgrave Macmillan
2003) received the Academy of Athens award for best book in economics.
xxi
Notes on Contributors
Amy Verdun is a Professor of Political Science, Jean Monnet Chair and Director
of the Jean Monnet Centre of Excellence at the University of Victoria, Canada.
She is the author or editor of nine books and has served as guest editor of five
special issues of peer-reviewed journals. She has published in peer-reviewed
journals such as British Journal of Politics and International Relations; Journal of
Common Market Studies; Journal of European Public Policy; Journal of Public Policy;
and Review of International Political Economy.
Wolfgang Wessels holds the Jean Monnet Chair for Political Science at the
University of Cologne. In 2007, he received the European Award ‘Jean Monnet’
in Gold. He is chair of the Executive Board of the Institut für Europäische Politik
(Berlin) and of the Trans European Policy Studies Association (Brussels), as well
as coordinator of the EU-CONSENT Network of Excellence. Recent publications
include Economic Government of the EU. A Balance Sheet of New Modes of Policy
Coordination (ed. Ingo Linsenmann and Christoph O. Meyer, 2007).
xxii
1
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
Europeanization, Convergence, and
Power in Central Banking
Kenneth Dyson
The coming of the age of the euro, signalled by the establishment of the
European Central Bank (ECB) in 1998, represented a bold novelty in the history
of central banking. It involved the birth of a small, untested, supra-national
central bank, which was cast directly into the role of the second most powerful
in the world, only half a decade after the European Exchange-Rate Mechanism
(ERM) had been convulsed by crises in 1992–3 (on which Dyson 1994). The
unprepossessing context was an institutionally weak European polity, without
independent fiscal competence, not least to bail out cross-nationally active
banks, and without a centralized European banking supervisory structure
(Dyson 2008b). A lonely ‘institution-in-the-making’, the ECB was responsible
for managing a new single currency, the euro, for over 300 million Europeans
in, initially, 11 of 15 European Union (EU) member states. As one of its first
Executive Board members noted, its youth, its distinctive institutional loneli-
ness, and its lack of the attributes of a fully integrated central bank—notably in
banking supervision—left it exposed (Padoa-Schioppa 2000, 2005). Second, the
age of the euro involved a core grouping of European states, which incorporated
a mosaic of historically formed identities, voluntarily merging their currencies
in a time of peace. In consequence, the ECB was formed in elite consensus but
had weak resources of European identity and solidarity on which to draw.
Unsurprisingly, given these two aspects of its context, its first Chief Econo-
mist, Otmar Issing (2008) stresses the scepticism that prevailed initially, not
just amongst characteristically cautious central bankers but also in the financial
markets and amongst financial journalists (cf. Woolley’s chapter on the US Fed
in this volume). Structural rigidities, not least in financial, services, and labour
markets, suggested the danger of persisting and economically and politically
1
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
The idea of the age of the euro as a structural break was blunted by the reality of
its smooth birth. The ECB’s early success owed much to its careful, meticulous
technical preparation by EU central bankers in the decade before its launch.
More specifically, it derived from ‘borrowing credibility’ by its institutional
modelling on the foremost and most-admired EU central bank, the German
Bundesbank. In particular, from 1 January 1994 the new European Monetary
Institute (EMI), composed of EU central bankers, prepared this final stage
three of Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) (on which Dyson 2000;
Dyson and Featherstone 1999). This period offered an opportunity to build a
team approach to monetary policy and for many national central banks to
begin upgrading their analytical capacity to contribute to this process. In fact,
the post-1979 ERM had served as an even longer training ground in monetary
policy coordination and in learning through crisis management, on which
many of the founding central banks could draw (Dyson 2000).
The EMI period also clarified the centrality of the principle of decentraliza-
tion in the design of the Eurosystem. Its justification depended on the role of
the national central banks in cultivating public confidence by maintaining the
quality of banknotes in circulation. It also recognized the historically different
functions of national central banks in their own societies (on which see pp. 19–28
below). Finally, given the association of national central banks with a state-
based EU, they were essential for communicating monetary policy to different
domestic audiences. At the same time, the EMI period manifested a concern of
2
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
3
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
On the other hand, the ECB lacks the traditional central banking advantage
of being able to take shelter, as a technocratic entity, beneath the protective
umbrella of a unified political authority that supports its mandate. It lacks
the supportive political context of a federal European fiscal stabilizing mech-
anism to cushion and smooth adjustment to asymmetric economic shocks.
Perhaps more ominously, in light of the traditional function of central banking
in safeguarding financial stability, the ECB cannot confidently rely on a federal
‘bail-out’ mechanism in case of contagious, systemic cross-national banking
and financial crisis. The EU-level Memorandum of Understanding in April 2008
represented progress in organizing cross-national ‘stability groups’ of super-
visors for some 20 to 30 cross-border banks. Nevertheless, the Euro Area had a
weakly developed and, up to the 2008 financial crisis, untested institutional
capacity for cross-national crisis management and is deficient in traditional
symbols of collective solidarity in dealing with future configurations of the
political economy of ‘hard times’ (Dyson 2008a). The ECB is a ‘stateless’,
isolated central bank in an ‘institutionally fuzzy’ polity (on which Dyson
2008b).
The age of the euro combines sharply defined central bank independence in
monetary policy with institutional ‘fuzziness’ in the key functions of financial
stability and fiscal compensation. It represents a form of hybrid central bank-
ing. The Euro Area is both located ‘beyond the state’ in monetary policy and yet
constrained by member states’ willingness to ‘own’ the euro in their domestic
fiscal, economic reform, and banking and financial market supervisory policies
and in coordinating nationally organized bank bail outs. At the same time, in
involving the most radical Europeanization of its member states through dele-
gation of sovereignty in monetary policy, the age of the euro highlights even
further the domestic distinctiveness of the constituent national central banks
of the Eurosystem. These national central banks are the most ‘Europeanized’ of
domestic institutions. In consequence, they are particularly interesting cases for
Europeanization research.
This institutionally lonely and exposed position of the ECB and of the
national central banks of the Eurosystem induces tension. In this context the
striking, even radical accentuation of the principle of central bank independ-
ence is functional. It acts as collective insurance for a new untried currency
against the heightened risks to credibility from its political dependence on
problematic domestic ‘ownership’ and loyalty by member-state political and
economic elites. It relies on them to expedite reforms to make adjustment
processes more speedy and efficient and to lower the costs of disinflation. In
this paradox, we encounter the elusiveness of Eurosystem central bank power in
the age of the euro: the combination of strong institutional profiling and
discursive confidence in monetary policy with problematic domestic political
ownership in fiscal and economic reform policies and weak institutional cap-
acity in cross-national financial market crisis management and bank bail outs.
4
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
5
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
Key Questions
6
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
era and the post-1945 ‘US-dollar-backed’ Bretton Woods era till 1973. They
provided a set of international rules in which central banks were embedded.
Correspondingly, the contexts and experiences of globalization differed across
these ages of central banking, in ways that profoundly affected their functions
and organizational cultures.
What do these changes consequent on European monetary integration reveal about
the power of central banks?
There are two senses of power: ‘power over’ and ‘power to’ (cf. Morriss 2002).
In its first, most frequently used sense, the power of central banks rests in their
power over other actors, in its being asymmetric. This power describes their
capacity to make others comply with their distinctive preferences: for instance,
to gain or retain functions and legal competences; to align market and political
expectations with their mandate for price stability; to increase their monetary
income in the Eurosystem; or to gain longer periods of exercising voting rights
in reform of the ECB Governing Council. Perhaps most strikingly in this
respect, the age of the euro disempowered the Bundesbank and empowered
other central banks in monetary policy.
Conventionally, this perspective sees power in ‘relational’ terms. It imputes to
central banks self-interested motives of ‘bureau’ expansion of functions, career
opportunities, and budgets: for instance, in developing and managing euro
payment and settlement systems, in centralizing banking supervision, or in
maximizing their monetary income. The question is whether in practice they
make effective use of the various resources of power on which they can draw to
enhance their relative power at domestic, European, and international levels.
These resources include their legal authority to act; professional expertise and
ideas; experience and reputation; information about markets and probable effects
of policy actions; the scale of the economy (defined by GDP size and financial
assets); and the weight of the currency in international markets and in central
bank reserves. Because of varying resources, some central banks are relatively
more powerful (at least potentially) than others, the US Fed internationally and
traditionally the Bundesbank in Europe. In reallocating these resources of power
EMU has transformed relative power in European central banking.
‘Power over’ also has a structural element, which expresses itself in the two
less visible dimensions of central bank power: the power to frame and shape
how other actors define their economic interests (what is seen as appropriate
behaviour), and the power of agenda setting in economic policy (including
keeping certain issues off the agenda) (cf. Lukes 2005). Seen in these terms,
EMU ‘uploaded’ to the Euro Area the structural power of the Bundesbank and its
distinctive Ordo-liberal ideas as well as ratified a more general international
structural shift to ‘stability-oriented’ policies (see Dyson’s chapter). By this
mechanism of ‘Europeanization as Germanization’ it reframed domestic
debates about macro-economic policy interests across the Euro Area towards
7
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
8
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
fiscal discipline, rooted in the less visible structural dimensions of central bank
power, can mask the highly contingent nature of this trust, the problematic
relationship of instruments to goals, and a vulnerability to market complexity,
opacity, and volatility. In addition, it highlighted the continuing openness of
structural power in banking and financial markets to political contest, espe-
cially once banking ‘originate-and-distribute’ business models proved reckless,
reward structures were vulnerable to charges of being iniquitous, and the state
was drawn into multiple bank rescues and sought to impose new regulatory
conditions. As we see below, persisting national variability in political constel-
lations of ideologies and interests, in ‘path dependence’ and in state traditions
of thought define the varying limits of central bank power to frame how
interests are conceived and to keep certain issues off the agenda.
In banking supervisory policies and financial stability the relationship of
instruments to goals is more problematic and vulnerability to markets most
acute. Analytical models are less robust in the face of the fast pace of financial
market innovation and multiple hidden potential sources of shocks, rules fail to
give strong backbone to supervisors, regulatory self-confidence is more brittle,
and central bank policy instruments are less clearly fit for purpose. Examples
were plentiful in 2007–8 with the manifest failures to regulate the ‘shadow’
banking system, the ongoing uncertainties about who owned securitized loans
and about what they were worth, the muddled rescues of Bear Stearns and of
Northern Rock, the systemic aftershocks of the collapse of Lehman, the massive
governmental interventions to recapitalize banks, buy up toxic assets and
guarantee credits, and central bank engagements in providing liquidity to
credit-starved banks. Policy was torn between the poles of avoidance of ‘moral
hazard’ associated with banking bail outs (thereby giving an incentive to reck-
less lending) and preventing systemic crisis, which feeds into the ‘real’ econ-
omy of output and jobs. The central, blunt central bank policy instrument of
interest-rate changes cannot alone deliver both price and financial stability
(Draghi 2008). The use of interest-rate hikes to prick specific asset price ‘bub-
bles’, say in housing, risks broad damage to macro-economic growth and
employment. Conversely, problems of locking in price stability have been
historically linked to asset ‘bubbles’: note the United States in 1929, Japan in
the 1990s, Asia in 1997–8, and sub-prime mortgages in 2007–8. By mid-2008
the international central bank community had yet to devise simple, transparent
supervisory rules that would enable supervisors to play a credible counter-
cyclical role in moderating excessive bank lending and accumulating bank
capital reserves during booms (cf. Goodhart and Persaud 2008). In their
absence, there was a plausible case for making greater use of monetary policy
for macro-prudential purposes (cf. Bank for International Settlements 2008).
A number of hypotheses about central bank power seem well supported
by the evidence in this volume. First, a complex combination of European
with domestic and international factors has strengthened central bank
9
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
power. In particular, their structural power has grown in the form of a cross-
national convergence in general political support for price stability, central
bank independence, tighter internal management efficiency, and strengthened
accountability and transparency.
Second, this strengthening of central bank power has been dwarfed by the
growth of the structural power of the global financial markets, in relation to
which central banks have been spectators rather than independently active
regulatory players. In consequence, central banks sought to play a difficult
balancing game. On the one hand, they attempted to work with the markets
to ensure their continuing efficiency, creativity, and dynamism in providing
liquidity. Central banks had also to recognize that financial and asset markets
were of increasing importance for monetary policy transmission, making finan-
cial stability of growing importance in monetary policy formation (Weber
2008). On the other hand, central banks have to ensure that they are not
captured by the markets, that they exercise independent professional judge-
ment, and take a system-wide independent perspective. Consistent with this
view, they distrust signals of readiness to bail out troubled banks as creating
potential moral hazard, providing incentives to reckless risk taking, and jeop-
ardizing financial stability and their own professional reputation. The acute
difficulties of this balancing game came to the fore in the credit crunch and
financial crisis of 2007–8.
Third, the growth of the power of the global financial markets simultaneously
empowers and threatens to disempower central banks. They are empowered as
political elites come to rely on central banks as professional ‘gate keepers’ to
complex, volatile, interconnected, and opaque markets. Central bank inde-
pendence and the appointment of ‘hawkish’ central bankers act as a form of
political insurance. Conversely, the sheer scale, creativity, and proneness of the
global markets to excess threaten to disempower central banks through new
sources of systemic risk and crisis. Once, as in 2008, financial crisis spills over
into acute threat to the ‘real’ economy, the issue of confidence shifts from
financial markets and central banks to governments, which became massively
active on a scale designed to ward off risks of any repeat of the Great Depression
of the 1930s. Keynesian ideas of counter-cyclical, government-led fiscal policies
enjoyed an intellectual renaissance that suggested a shift in structural power
away from central banks towards elected governments.
Fourth, at least in the period till the financial crisis of 2008, EMU had served
to shore up the structural power of European central banking via an ‘ECB-
centric’ Euro Area and by EU accession and Maastricht conditionality criteria
for Euro Area accession. At the same time EMU led to divergent changes in the
relative power of different European central banks. In the case of Euro-insiders,
the Bundesbank was the big net loser; others, especially the central banks of
smaller states, were net gainers. Diminished relative power in Europe for
the Bundesbank translates into new domestic weakness and vulnerability.
10
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Conversely, increased relative power in Europe for many small state central
banks creates potentially enhanced domestic leverage over policy, a more
authoritative role in domestic policy debate, and—as in Greece—new exposure
as a focal point in domestic political opposition to a ‘neo-liberal’ agenda of
reform. Domestic leverage is increased when national central banks retain
a wide range of national functions that predate the Eurosystem (e.g. the
National Bank of Belgium). However, this outcome does not hold when these
functions—like protecting a weak domestic banking sector in the case of the
Bank of Italy—involve ‘misfit’ with EMU and EU templates.
Fifth, for euro-outsiders the international sources of a strengthening of
structural power of central banking remain similar, notably in the impacts of
global financial markets and of ascendant trans-national policy ideas that
privilege stability-oriented policies and a set of shared understandings about
their institutional, procedural, and policy preconditions. However, in these
cases domestic variegation in Europeanization is even more pronounced. This
variegation reflects contrasts in attitudes to monetary ‘sovereignty’ and how it
relates to national identity; the timing of central bank development in rela-
tion to international financial market liberalization; the character of the
economic and financial structures in which central banks are embedded;
how domestic political parties use the processes of granting central bank
independence and of appointments to top posts; and whether, in conse-
quence, central bank governors are seen to be personally politically independ-
ent and thus reliable authoritative professional figures. These factors are
explored in the volume.
To what extent, and in what ways, is EMU producing convergence across these
various dimensions and across functions?
‘Europeanization’ begs the question of whether it is associated with conver-
gence, with central banks coming to resemble each other. This resemblance can
take different forms: resemblance in agenda stemming from increasingly shared
pressures; in ideas and functions; in instruments and structures; in cultures; and
in outcomes. Hence convergence is a multi-dimensional concept. The question
produces, in consequence, differentiated answers depending on precisely what
we are talking about.
Convergence exhibits functional specificity. Patterns of convergence/
divergence vary across monetary policy, transparency and accountability,
financial market supervision, and research. In this volume, Marcussen outlines
a convergence around a new age of the ‘scientization’ of central banking,
exemplified in the new prestige to research and ‘knowledge-based’ policies in
legitimating their power. Macartney and Moran identify simultaneous epi-
stemic convergence and institutional divergence even within the same func-
tional area of financial market supervision: whilst Jabko points out that policies
on transparency are very different in financial market supervision from mone-
tary policy. Begg sees an international process of convergence in monetary
11
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
policy strategy towards inflation targeting, though one in which the ECB
remains an outsider.
However, convergence in central banking is often superficial. On closer
examination it turns out to be more variegated and to involve multiple
equilibria. The dynamic nature of convergence highlights, in part, the ‘path-
dependent’ specificities of historical and institutional contexts. These specifi-
cities shape the differential reception of ideas (Hay 2000). However, they also
illustrate the sheer randomness in market and political developments. The
incidence and particularities of crises in central banking vary and have the
potential to shift central banks off their trajectory of development. These crises
become in turn embedded in different institutional memories, for instance
about the dangers of exchange-rate fixing in the Bank of England and of
‘hyper-inflation’ in the Bundesbank.
In consequence, convergence displays not just functional specificity but also
temporality. It exhibits historical contingency. The preparatory phase of the age
of the euro was associated with convergence in inflation rates. Since European
monetary union, however, differences in inflation have proved persistent. This
persistence threatens longer-term strains through consequent loss of competi-
tiveness and serious protracted adjustment problems that could lead to diver-
gences in wider macro-economic performance, especially output growth and
employment. Outcomes can, in short, move in different directions over time,
again reflecting contingency. Similarly, the national banking systems in which
European central banks are embedded display strong historical path depend-
ence so that institutional arrangements for supervision are resistant to conver-
gence. As we see below, ‘New Public Management’ ideas have also been adopted
variably: amongst euro insiders more by the Bundesbank than the Banque de
France, and amongst outsiders more by the Swedish than the Danish central
bank.
In addressing these questions about Europeanization, power, and conver-
gence, the volume retains a strong sense of varying historical, international,
and domestic contexts. Weighing these contextual factors raises perennially
problematic issues of scholarly judgement about the appropriate ‘level of
analysis’. The editors have not sought to ‘resolve’ these issues. In fact, we have
encouraged pluralism by juxtaposing European country case studies with Euro
Area-level chapters, functionally specific chapters, and non-European ‘control’
cases.
12
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
13
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
The questions that animate this volume, and its core organizing concepts and
approaches, reflect its intellectual origins in comparative political economy,
notably the study of the institutional basis of macro-economic policies. ‘Euro-
peanization’, ‘power’, and ‘convergence’ offer a cluster of interrelated concepts
with which to examine change in central banking.
Europeanization
Europeanization refers to the domestic effects of European integration on
policies, polities, and politics and characteristically focuses on mechanisms
and the qualitative aspects of time (Dyson and Goetz 2003; Featherstone and
Radaelli 2003). This volume examines the effects of the creation of the Euro
Area on national central banks: their competences, their structures and func-
tioning, and how they relate to their political and policy contexts. We are
interested in how they respond to European-level requirements and in how
they make strategic use of the creation of the Euro Area. In the first sense,
Europeanization functions as a ‘top–down’ mechanism. It provides strongly
14
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Power
Europeanization of central banks and banking is bound up with power. Power
remains a complex and elusive concept with many facets. It sources are varied:
moral authority, legal competence, position in domestic economic governance,
expertise, financial resources, performance, even personal attributes of central
bankers. Central bank power is relative to, and contingent on, possession of
these various resources, which are distributed unevenly across space and over
time. It is, in consequence, fragile and mutates.
15
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
16
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
17
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
financial shock of 2008 gathered pace, especially as the scale of their national
commercial banks potentially eclipsed the domestic capacity to bail them out.
The varied sources, different manifestations, and discrepancies between
potential and actual power underline the continuing difficulty of pinning
down power, not just in the Eurosystem, but even in the financial markets.
At least up to the financial crisis of 2008, financial institutions seemed to exude
vast power. However, much of this power depended on their creativity in
inventing new complex products, like various forms of derivative, and more
problematically on their capacity to retain market confidence in these products.
Moreover, these ideas were hard to patent, could be easily copied, and soon
became low-margin widely available products. Hence they were in practice
vulnerable to rapid loss of competitive advantage. The result was an enormous
incentive to permanent creativity that briefly marked out certain key individ-
uals and companies as powerful. In short, creativity took its place, alongside
capital and financial leverage, as a key source of market power. Financial market
players, as well as central bankers, proved acutely vulnerable to the complexity
and opacity that followed from this creativity and the ‘herd’ instincts in search
of higher yield, as the crisis of 2008 revealed. The paradox of central bank power
was that, in successful delivering low real interest rates and in neglecting the
mundane world of financial stability for the intellectually exciting world of
monetary policy strategy, they increased incentives to the markets to be more
creative and take higher risks in search of yield.
The complexities and paradoxes of central bank power are highlighted in part
by the above focus on the political criterion of their capacity to make a difference
to outcomes. They also surface in the use of the moral criterion of praise or blame
in evaluating the responsibility of central bankers for outcomes. Here a tension
opens between ‘power to’ and ‘power over’. Providing central bankers with the
‘power to’ deliver outcomes, whether to entrench low inflation or promote
financial stability, is a matter of endowing them with appropriate instruments.
However, the possession and, above all, use of these instruments open central
bankers to the moral paradox of praise for delivering socially desired outcomes
like price stability and blame for exercising excessive power over others (dom-
ination) without sufficient democratic accountability and transparency. This
moral conundrum bedevils the debate about central bank power.
Convergence
The creation of the Euro Area was notable in both expressing and reinforcing a
broader international and historical trend to enhanced central bank power in
macro-economic policy. In other words, Europeanization is bound up with
international convergence, especially in common pressures. Central banks
look more alike—even if not exactly the same—on such dimensions as their
independence, collective internal decision-making structures, monetary policy
18
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
On both the international and the European levels, central banks perform
broadly similar core functions in delivering price and financial stability. They
are embedded interdependently in international and interconnected financial
markets, characterized by complex opaque forms of intermediation, and hence
have a common vulnerability to contagious financial crises. In the face of a
market context driven by greed and fear, central bankers share common profes-
sional attributes, ranging from an ingrained caution and risk aversion, through a
‘stability-oriented’ conception of macro-economic policy, to a focus on capacity
to communicate in suitably coded terms with financial markets. Not least,
central banks interact cross-nationally to an unusual extent in a variety of
international forums. In consequence, they represent an ‘epistemic community’
with a high degree of readiness to engage in cross-national policy coordination
(cf. Haas 1992). Central bankers’ professional beliefs also dispose them to seek to
build effective cross-national policy coordination on the solid foundations of
credible domestic commitment and capability to build stability ‘at home’. In
short, their attitudes to international coordination tend to be similarly condi-
tional. These factors suggest a potentially relatively high level of convergence
amongst central banks in professional beliefs, in functions, and in pressures.
19
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
20
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
In certain cases central banks acquire a heroic role, as with the Baltic
State central banks in the post-1991 process of independence from the Soviet
Union. Intimate association with independence means that they, and the
currencies that they manage, become bound up in images of national identity
and state sovereignty. This factor distinguishes the central banks in the Baltic
States—where there is substantial public (though not elite) reluctance to give up
national currencies—from that in Hungary (cf. Greskovits chapter). They are
key arbiters of national economic policy debate and enjoy high levels of trust.
In other cases, like France and the German Second Reich (1871–1918), central
banks had a more ‘humdrum’ role in national debates. Although part of state
building, they were not so intimately linked to national independence, com-
pared for instance to the government bureaucracy and the army.
An aspect of ‘path dependence’ is the timing of state and nation building—
and hence central bank formation—in relation to the development of the
international political economy. Notably, the east central European central
banks were reconstituted after the end of the Cold War in an international
context of consensus about freedom of capital movement, central bank inde-
pendence, and ‘stability-oriented’ policies (cf. Epstein and Johnson chapter).
This timing empowered them domestically as ‘liberalizers’ and ‘modernizers’
and powerfully shaped their identity.
In addition to ‘path dependence’, state traditions of thought about the role of
public authority in economic development matter (Armstrong 1973; Dyson
1980). Association with state building highlights the particularities of state
traditions in economic development, which in turn help forge role conceptions
of central banks and leave their own distinct genetic footprints. The French
central bank, for instance, retains an image and style of ‘interventionism’, of
embodying certain state purposes. This style was evident in a ‘developmental’
role in the early post-1945 period in implementing economic priorities in
national plans through its credit policies; in its role with government in seeking
consolidation of the French banking sector (e.g. the BNP, Paribas, and the
Societe Generale in 1999); or, since 2006, in assuming a ‘social’ role in personal
debt management (cf. Howarth’s chapter). The image of the Bank of England is
bound up in a very different relationship of state building to the economy. Its
traditional ‘hands-off’ approach centred on supporting the international role of
the City of London. The Bank was embedded in the ‘club-like’ social networks
of the City that were premised on a gentlemanly code of trust and informally
held together government, central banks, and finance, at least till the 1980s
(Kynaston 2002; Roberts and Kynaston 1995).
In Belgium, the Netherlands, and Sweden, by contrast, the imprints of social
partnership find their expression in a role in supporting ‘concertation’ amongst
employers and trade unions. In reaction to the cataclysm of the collapse of the
Weimar Republic and the Third Reich, the Bundesbank embodies the post-war
Ordo-liberal conception of a new German state bound by clear principles and
21
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
firm rules to safeguard long-term stability. Hence it espoused a ‘public trustee’ role
on behalf of price stability that made it more distant from the ‘short-termism’ of
financial markets (than the Bank of England), government (than the French
central bank), and the social partners (than the Belgian or Dutch central banks).
‘Path dependence’ in state building also deeply shaped notions of institu-
tional legitimacy in central banking, especially conceptions of accountability.
The chapter by Eichbaum on Australasian central bank illustrates the back-
ground role of the British Westminster political model in the development of
ideas on central bank independence and inflation targeting. This constitutional
model, which focuses on ministerial responsibility to Parliament, has a ‘misfit’
with ideas of ‘goal’ independence (as opposed to ‘instrument’ independence) in
central banking. Conversely, it fits with the idea of political determination of
the inflation target and central bank accountability for meeting this target.
However, as the chapters on the US Fed and the ECB and Jabko’s chapter
show, these ideas flow less easily into different constitutional frameworks. The
US separation of powers model involves more complex accountability relation-
ships to Congress and the federal executive. In the Euro Area context two
different constitutional models have competed, though very asymmetric in
terms of their power over central bank design. The French republican model
focuses on accountability to the nation, whose will is delegated to the sovereign
political institutions of the Republic. Hence it fits badly with ‘goal’ independ-
ence in central banking and advocates European-level ‘economic government’,
to which the ECB should be accountable and which should coordinate eco-
nomic and monetary policies (see Howarth’s chapters). Far more powerful in
shaping the institutional design of independence and accountability of the ECB
have been German Ordo-liberal ideas of trusteeship (see Dyson’s chapter on the
Bundesbank; also Dyson and Featherstone 1999 for the reasons). These ideas
focus on a strong institution with a narrowly defined mandate for price stabil-
ity, on behalf of which the central bank acts as public trustee.
22
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
‘Weak’ states lack the unity of purpose amongst domestic veto players to
pursue consistent economic policies and suffer from a plethora of veto points
on change. In short, they lack institutional capacity to deliver their preferences.
These veto points are to be found in party system fragmentation and party
factionalism, in ministerial ‘fiefdoms’ within coalition governments, in poten-
tially competing legislative majorities in lower and upper houses, in various
organized groups, and in structures of territorial interest. As the Italian case
demonstrates, they can be associated with (relatively) ‘strong’ central banks,
providing an opportunity to carve out a niche of power: a case of a ‘strong’
central bank in a ‘weak’ state. Conversely, ‘weak’ states do not guarantee central
bank power: the Greek central bank was a ‘weak’ central bank in a ‘weak’ state.
‘Weak’ states can erode the authority of central banks, whether by enmeshing
them in clientele relationships for rewarding supporters or by politically
motivated processes of partisan advantage through appointments to top
posts. In consequence, their authority is eroded (see Greskovits’ chapter on
east central Europe). If state capacity to act matters for central banks, so too does
whether state actors share or subvert their core purposes.
Conversely, ‘strong’ states embody a greater unity of purpose that enables
coordinated action amongst various veto players. Again, there is no single
pattern. Where state capacity to deliver is linked to a shared social purpose
with the central banks, a ‘strong’ state is consistent with a ‘strong’ central bank.
An example is Sweden, where the central bank has been supported by the
capacity of the state to deliver a context for neo-corporatist forms of respon-
sible, macro-economic–focused collective bargaining. The Bank of England has
similarly benefited from the capacity of the British state to deliver on fiscal
discipline and market liberalization (when governments are so inclined). In
contrast, the French central bank has been a ‘weak’ central bank in a ‘strong’
state. In this case, domestic political ideology has proved less supportive of fiscal
consolidation and structural reforms to liberalize markets.
In consequence, there are cross-national variations in the institutional capacity
of states to support central banks by delivering domestic stability-oriented fiscal
policies and wage bargaining. There are also variations in the vulnerability of
central banks to the political use of the appointments process to their top posts,
notably in undermining their reputation for objectivity (see Greskovits’s chapter).
23
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
The ‘output’ legitimacy of the Bundesbank made it the model for the design
of the ECB. In gaining ‘output’ legitimacy in its first decade the relative power of
the ECB within the Eurosystem was strengthened. However, this legitimacy is
contingent on performance.
The Eurosystem provided a new challenge of ‘output’ legitimacy for constituent
national central banks: their capacity to pursue internal efficiency-oriented
reforms, like tighter strategic control, ‘de-layering’ of structures, ‘outsourcing’,
and performance measurement. Here again contrasting trajectories of reform
were evident, with different emphases in individual cases (cf. Pollitt and
Bouckaert 2000). The French and the Greek central banks adapted to maintain
the status quo. Rationalizing measures were introduced without recourse to the
legitimating discourse of the New Public Management. ‘Outsourcing’ initiatives
were limited. Strong internal trade-union presence proved a key constraint. Thus
in 2008 the union’s forceful demonstration led to an exemption of Bank of Greece
staff from the pension system reform. In the Banque de France internal vested
interests blocked major strengthening of macro-economic research capacity.
A different emphasis was apparent in the Danish central bank, which also
eschewed a pace-setting role in public-sector reforms. A key reason was that
it experienced little external pressure for reform because of the continuity in
making monetary policy from the ‘old’ ERM to the ‘new’ ERM II.
More characteristic of Eurosystem central banks was modernization through
transformation of existing structures. These central banks sought to be paceset-
ters in domestic public-sector reform and included Germany and the Nether-
lands. The ‘outsider’ Swedish central bank became a key benchmark. In these
cases the New Public Management was a legitimating discourse. The third
reform trajectory—‘marketizing’ central banks by introducing private-sector
practices—was pursued much more cautiously and characteristically in the
function of cash management.
24
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
In addition, though there may be broad general shifts in central banking and
evidence of epistemic convergence, there is room for differences of view on a
range of issues. For instance, views on how random and unpredictable are finan-
cial markets feed into different assessments of the value of formal macro-
economic modelling in monetary policy and of how much reliance to place in
an individual ‘anchor’ like money supply growth, exchange-rate targeting, or
inflation targeting. The view that markets are random and unpredictable trans-
lates into the belief in the primacy of expertise in the form of tacit knowledge,
grounded in the value of long experience of managing crises, in the cultivation of
a certain mystique in central banking, and in personal trust as vital to the transfer
of this tacit knowledge (cf. Collins 2007). There are also differences of view on
whether central banks should ignore asset prices and deal only with the eco-
nomic consequences of an asset price bust the ‘mop-up-after’ policy (cf. Green-
span 2007) or be more proactive and ‘lean against the wind’ (e.g. the Bank for
International Settlements 2008; Bordo 2007; Draghi 2008; Weber 2008). Simi-
larly, transparency can be regarded as potentially subversive, to be conceded in
response to demands from political institutions (see Woolley’s chapter on the US
Fed), or as an instrument for making monetary policy more effective and hence to
be embraced pro-actively (see Marcussen’s chapter on Sweden).
Central banker preferences are typically linked to domestic state traditions.
In accountability, for example, two positions can be identified. Central banks
can be seen as embedded in principal/agency relations, in which the governing
majority delegates and in turn demands accountability. This notion fits closely
with states that emphasize Parliamentary sovereignty (as in the ‘Westminster’
model) and with inflation targeting as a device for holding central banks to
account. Conversely, central banks can be seen as ‘disinterested’ trustees for a
specific public interest. This notion is very strong in the post-war German
tradition and has been uploaded into the ECB. The ECB is accountable to the
public of the Euro Area to deliver its Treaty mandate of price stability.
Within the shared context of the Eurosystem, these four factors—alongside
the international strength of the domestic financial sector—provide different
opportunity structures and constraints for central banks. They account for
persisting variations in their potential to project and exercise power. The pres-
ence and effect of these factors is even more evident outside the Eurosystem.
Persisting national preferences in key areas like accountability and transparency
keep the Bank of England and the Swedish Riksbank at an intellectual distance
from the Eurosystem.
The age of the euro suggests an inversion of the historic relationship bet-
ween central banks and the state. The mechanisms are twofold: a collective
25
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
26
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
role included the central banks of France, Italy, Prussia, and Spain. This
interventionist historical context of much continental European central bank-
ing contrasts with the market-based financial system into which the age of the
euro was born.
Despite these marked historical contrasts in the European state system and in
relations between states and markets, central banks bear the imprint of this
past. In their origins central banks served to augment the power of European
states. They attained, in consequence, as we saw above, a status of dignity and
high social prestige. This status expressed either the ethic of public service,
which was imputed to a social class that embodied the civic virtues (character-
istic of the Bank of England), or their embodiment of the authority of the state
and its purposes (as in the German Reichsbank). Equally, central banks reflected
the historical variability in state- and nation-building experiences and—in the
case of the Bundesbank—historical ruptures.
This historical context means that central banks articulated the financial and
monetary dimensions of sovereignty. Just as it had armed forces and police to
protect its subjects and its borders, so the state had its own money. The central
bank was there to safeguard the value of the national currency. It had, accord-
ingly, a symbolic power. It represented the nation. Central banks were bound
up with nation building as well as state building. In the process their individual
definitions of their common functions took on the attributes of distinct con-
ceptions of statehood and nationhood.
This role of central banks in state and in nation building was articulated in
their architecture, characteristically austere, classical, dignified, and imposing,
and in the formality of their rituals and traditions. The imposing edifices of the
Bank of England and the Bank of France convey powerful images of historic
grandeur and solemnity. In contrast, the German Bundesbank’s modernist
architecture symbolizes a ruptured tradition after 1933–45, a new central
bank for a new state, and a redefined nation. Even so, the traditional central
bank images remain: calm solemnity and the ‘private’ government of public
money.
The striking feature of the age of the euro is the historic attenuation of this
association of European central banking with state, sovereignty, and national
identity. Architecturally, it is the post-modern age of central banking, symbol-
izing a hybrid of European cross-national identity building with national par-
ticularities. The futuristic design of the ECB tower in Frankfurt expresses this
spirit. Socially and culturally, the ECB brings together seconded officials from
national central banks with permanent officials from a range of European
states. Their commonality resides in shared central banking professionalism,
in cultivating a Euro Area identity in policy formation that is non-national, and
in the exclusive use of the English language. In short, the ECB represents a
highly cosmopolitan expert elite, a trans-national ‘epistemic community’
united by shared beliefs and policy projects (on which Haas 1992).
27
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
In contrast to the internal European processes leading to its birth and evolution,
the age of the euro is defined in substance by the larger spatial and historical
framework of the international political economy.
28
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
The big international central banking story of the first part of the twentieth
century was the protracted power shift from the Bank of England, the putative
fulcrum of the classical Gold Standard, to the US Fed. The ‘gold-backed’ age of
globalization witnessed even higher levels of trade and financial integration
than in the ‘US-dollar-backed’ Bretton Woods age of globalization. It rested on
the credible commitment of the Bank of England to convertibility of the pound
sterling to gold. Given this external discipline and the associated notion of
‘automaticity’ in adjustment, there was little incentive to develop national
central banking. Its emergence in the period 1870s–1914 owed more to a new
and growing emphasis on ‘monetary sovereignty’ associated with newly emer-
gent ‘nation’ states, a process that gathered pace in the interwar period. The
shift to the post-1945 ‘US-dollar-backed’ age of globalization reflected a rebal-
ancing of financial and economic power within the North Atlantic–centred
world economy away from London to New York and a new willingness of the
United States, not apparent in the 1930s, to assume the leadership role in
international stabilization.
Central banking in the age of the euro reflected this legacy of international
economic history. Historical legacy, notably associated ‘agglomeration’ effects,
along with its favourable location between international time zones, meant
that London remained the core European financial centre. This comparative
advantage was reinforced by the pioneering role of the British government in
deregulating the financial sector in the 1980s and in benefiting from the
financial services revolution; it was seen again in October 2008 in the model
character of the British banking bail out for the EU. The City was the main
global centre for international business. Hence a further distinctive feature of the
age of the euro has been the separation of ‘financial’ Europe (centred on
London and firmly global and US-centric in outlook) and ‘monetary’ Europe
(focused on the ECB in Frankfurt). In consequence, the Euro Area lacks the core
European financial centre.
More fundamentally, however, the post-1945 period has been characterized
by the financial and monetary ascendancy of the United States, represented by
New York and Chicago, the US Fed, and the US dollar. Despite recurrent and
often sharp volatility, the US dollar remains the core international currency in
foreign-exchange trading, the main denominator in world trade, the main
‘anchor’ currency for states pursuing explicit exchange-rate policies (leading
to talk of an informal ‘Bretton Woods II’), and the dominant reserve currency
for other central banks. Financial and monetary crises transmit more forcefully
outwards from the United States than into the United States. Post-1973, the
leadership role of the US Fed survived the end of the Bretton Woods system,
which had been in effect a US dollar-based international exchange-rate system,
and the tribulations of the US dollar in the late 1970s and beyond. Drawing
on memories of the disruptive effects of US-based market excesses and
benign neglect of international responsibilities, the age of the euro was in
29
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
part designed to better insulate Europe in this new era of market-led globaliza-
tion. Although this aim could in part be realized in terms of the reduced
external trade dependence of a large currency union, global financial market
integration continued to provide powerful transmission mechanisms through
which US power was manifested.
In this context of a ‘financial’ Europe centred on London and of US-centred
global financial and monetary power, the ECB had limited scope to carve out an
international role. This constraint offered an extra incentive to focus on estab-
lishing credibility through fulfilling its Treaty mandate of price stability
and through encouragement of member-state governments to increase the
output growth potential of the Euro Area by domestic economic reforms.
Performance—‘output’ legitimacy—was the key to international credibility
but ran into the paradox and uncertainties outlined at the outset of this chapter.
30
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
New Keynesian models were seen as weak in spotting asset price developments,
notably ‘bubbles’, through longer-term analysis of money and credit and too
prone to ‘real-time’ data problems and estimation errors that could lead to
destabilizing effects from monetary policy (Weber 2006b). The Bundesbank
saw its views on the importance of money and credit analysis as confirmed
and strengthened by the 2007–8 financial crisis and as the indispensable sta-
bilizing element in a more symmetric long-term monetary policy across the
financial cycle that could dampen fluctuations (Weber 2008).
At the same time the Bundesbank accepted that New Keynesian models were
useful in highlighting the concept of ‘staggered’ prices and the role of ‘friction’
in the real, imperfect world of wage and price adjustment and in picking up
cost-push factors like productivity growth, regulatory and competition policies,
wage indexation formulas, labour-force developments, fiscal policy shifts, and
tax structure (classically Woodford 2003). The real-world problems of insuffi-
ciently rapid adjustment of wages and prices, compared to the United States
(notably in services), meant that New Keynesian models retained a strong
appeal to EU central bankers. In consequence, the ECB sought to reconcile
New Keynesianism and German ‘money growth’ models in its two-pillar mon-
etary policy strategy, though in the process retaining a critical distancing from
the US-centred, New Keynesian consensus.
In particular, within the consensus on stability-oriented monetary policies,
contest focused on asset price ‘bubbles’ like the bursting of the Internet bubble
in 2000 and of the credit and house price bubble that burst in 2007. Given two
key problems—that bubbles can be hard to identify until they burst and hard to
prick without collateral damage to other activities, there were differences of
view about whether monetary policy could, and should be used to counter
them or whether it was better to rely on regulation of capital requirements and
lending standards. Recurrent bubbles prevailed over regulatory quality and,
above all in 2008, exposed an Achilles heel of central banking. In the wake of
the credit crisis of 2007–8 the Bank for International Settlements (2008) stressed
the need for greater use of monetary policy for macro-prudential purposes. The
frequency and severity of crises could be reduced by a more symmetrical use of
monetary policy: by tightening it when credit growth soars and asset prices
explode, even if it temporarily reduces inflation below target levels. This assess-
ment rested on the attribution of a sizeable portion of blame for the 2007–8
crisis to the central banks, led by the US Fed, for tolerating a long period of easy
money and rapid asset price inflation.
Academic monetary economists were in general powerful advocates of rules,
though their advocacy varied from money supply growth, exchange-rate target-
ing, to direct inflation targeting. Central bankers were also attracted to rules as
insurance to protect against political incursions on their independence and,
not least, as an anchor to entrench market expectations of inflation consistent
with their objectives. However, they were most directly exposed to the volatility
31
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
32
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
33
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
34
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
learnt from painful experience that they were acutely vulnerable to the massive
size, global scale, speed, and random behaviour—in short, power—of highly
complex, interconnected and opaque financial markets. European monetary
union provided collective insurance, above all to small and medium-sized
states, by safeguarding the trade and investment gains of the post-war European
integration process, not least the single European market. In addition, it offered
higher trade and investment gains through the elimination of exchange-rate
risks and reduction of transaction costs.
The age of the euro helped to speed and consolidate the macro-economic
power of central banking in Europe by overcoming vestigial domestic resistance
to the idea and practices of central bank independence. This resistance reflected
an enduring political incentive to try to control the business cycle for political
reasons, not least by relaxing policies to gain electoral support. It was strength-
ened in 2008 as financial crisis in money and other markets and implosion of
leading banks threatened recession. Bank bail outs were associated with a new
loosening of fiscal rules in favour of counter-cyclical action. The political and
intellectual context of central banks changed.
Incentives to control the political business cycle were stronger under two
conditions. First, where domestic institutional rules established fixed electoral
terms, as in France and Germany, governments lacked the discretion to time
elections during a favourable period of economic expansion or in order to pre-
empt a pending economic downturn. Hence they had a stronger incentive to
manipulate the economy (Kayser 2005). Second, where governments were
locked into long cycles of economic stagnation and weak wage growth (as in
Germany in 1993–2005 and in Italy), they had an incentive to seek to manipu-
late economic conditions to favour re-election, irrespective of whether they
had fixed or discretionary electoral terms. Deprived of monetary policy, the
emphasis shifted to fiscal policies. In turn, politically opportunistic fiscal
policies—and the credibility of the Stability and Growth Pact—became a
major source of uncertainty and vulnerability to the ECB (Issing 2008).
In addition, many European states had an historic legacy of ideas favouring
political intervention in the economy. These ideas were variously rooted in
Catholic social teaching, social democratic ideas, ‘realist’ views of the state and
markets, and not least dominant domestic political memories where they
associated financial market power with unemployment. French dirigisme rests
on the idea that elected governments, not least the President under the Fifth
Republic, embody the superior republican legitimacy of the will of the nation.
In Hungary and Poland, strongly entrenched ideas of social solidarity underpin
a distrust of independent central bankers. In Italy, the state functions in a way
that offers political elites scope to reward and protect their clienteles, not least
subverting domestic structural reforms. Hence, central banking is exposed to
varying European attitudes to the legitimacy of technocratic power in eco-
nomic policy.
35
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
The paradox of the age of the euro was that, in a project constructed
around Franco-German political leadership in European integration, French
and German ideas about the relationship of central banks to the state were
least easy to reconcile. Although the Treaty was firm on central bank independ-
ence, the ECB remained politically exposed to this paradox. Its capacity to
endure this exposure reflected in part the tough Treaty provisions and high
hurdles to amendment (unanimity in domestic ratification) and in part firm
German support for central bank independence, grounded in bitter historical
memories of interwar and post-war hyperinflation. The motto that ‘the euro
must be at least as strong as the D-Mark’ overshadowed German policy towards
the ECB.
Other than Germany, European states had two main incentives to renounce
their residual sovereign powers over monetary policy, as well as the symbol-
ism of their national currencies for identity: removing the capacity of the
financial markets to directly punish and humiliate elected governments
through exchange-rate crisis; and neutralizing German power over European
monetary policies. A single currency and a single monetary policy eliminated
a key international vulnerability of post-war European states and were con-
sistent with an enduring post-war motive of power balancing, notably against
Germany, in the European integration process. These incentives were espe-
cially strong for the smaller European states. They stood to gain dispropor-
tionately from the end of exchange-rate risk and the reduction of transaction
costs in both trade and investment and from having formally equal ‘voice’ in
monetary policy.
In the process, however, the axis of vulnerability for European states in the age
of the euro shifted from the exchange-rate crisis to contagious cross-national
banking and financial crisis. Although this vulnerability was increased by
strengthened incentives to trans-national European banking with the euro, it
was more deeply rooted in the interconnectedness and opacity of global finan-
cial markets. Even if US-centred, the 2007–8 liquidity and solvency crisis high-
lighted the ongoing vulnerability of European states to excesses in financial
market risk taking and the deficiencies of fragmented European regulatory
systems in an age of interconnected financial markets. The age of the euro,
and the financial crisis of 2008, challenged European central banks to refocus
priorities around the financial stability function. The issues extended beyond
their involvement in macro-level financial market risk analysis and stress test-
ing; through the problem of their frequent exclusion from the micro-level,
operational aspects of banking and financial market supervision; to questions
36
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
37
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
Additionally, the ECB had to cope with new vulnerability in monetary policy
from two shocks: international energy and commodity price shocks and
imported inflation from emerging markets; and the deflationary effects
from the credit crunch and financial crisis of 2008. The ECB benefited in its
early years (1999–2005) from the historical accident of a relatively ‘good
birth’. The international political economy offered a context of ‘good times’
for monetary policy. The global economy grew at an unprecedented rate,
even if the Euro Area economy exhibited symptoms of anaemic overall GDP
growth, productivity growth and high structural unemployment, largely
consequent on the weak performance of its core former ‘D-Mark-Zone’ econ-
omies. Its locomotives lay outside Europe in US consumer-led growth and in
the powerful entry of China and India into the international economy as
exporters of cheap manufactures (with by 2007 China accounting for just
over 25% of world economic growth at purchasing power parity). Above all,
‘globalization’ became associated for a period with the magic reconciliation
of the so-called ‘Great Moderation’ in low inflation, low short-term real
interest rates, and high growth (christened by the governor of the Bank of
England the ‘NICE’ decade of ‘non-accelerating inflation and continuous
expansion’). In this benign context, like other central banks, the ECB was
able to pursue an ‘accommodative’ monetary policy without endangering its
strict price stability mandate, which it redefined in 2003 as ‘below but close
to’ 2 per cent. Above all, it succeeded in locking in long-term market expect-
ations of inflation broadly consistent with this definition at historically low
real interest rates. The age of the euro benefited from this historical accident
of a good birth.
In contrast to the greater complacency about inflationary pressures exhibited
by some other leading central banks, from 2005 this ‘accommodative’ ECB
monetary policy was gradually reduced. Its ‘monetary’ pillar identified mount-
ing inflationary risks in the context of continuing low output growth potential.
Even so, by late 2007, Euro Area inflation was accelerating well above target.
‘Globalization’ had ceased to function as a one-way inflation dampener. Food,
commodity, and energy prices rose sharply, reflecting partly supply problems
and partly new demand from rapidly growing economies like China and India;
38
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
subsequent falling real wages meant falling disposable income; whilst financial
crisis intensified as the effects of the US sub-prime debacle spread across markets
and, through tightening credit policies, into the real economy. Even if the
threat of ‘second-round’ effects in wage settlements on the 1970s pattern was
ameliorated by subsequent product, trade, and labour-market deregulations, as
well as higher immigration, a global inflationary process threatened.
Hence, the ECB faced new challenges in monetary policy. The accommoda-
tion of new threats to the real economy of growth and employment from
financial crisis proved more difficult to reconcile with the threats to the price
stability mandate from imported global inflation. These ‘globalization’ chal-
lenges opened up new political space for tensions and conflicts about ‘winners’
and ‘losers’ and between supra-national central bankers, loyal to the Treaty
mandate of price stability, and European governments, anxious about their
electorates’ tolerance for cuts in real incomes and determined to protect their
national banks and depositors from banking failures. This changing environ-
ment offered new incentives to form coalitions of ‘losers’, altering the axis of
political debate about globalization, financial markets, and central banks.
The potential for tension and conflict was already apparent in that the age of
the euro had provided stark domestic challenges of economic and institutional
reforms in Euro Area member states. In the process, it made more transparent
both the weaknesses and failures of domestic political leadership and the deeper
institutional, political, and cultural problems of managing economic change in
the political and the corporate spheres. Euro Area member states had lost two
traditional core mechanisms to speed adjustment to asymmetric shocks: the
exchange rate, notably devaluation to regain lost competitiveness (in short,
exporting adjustment problems to others); and the interest rate.
The age of the euro meant a ‘one-size-fits-all’ monetary policy that, in some
cases, fuelled credit booms notably in residential investment through low, even
negative real interest rates (as in Ireland and Spain up to 2007) and, in others,
acted as a constraint through higher real interest rates (as in Germany till 2005–
6). In consequence, there was a divergence in credit cycles between Germany
and these states. Moreover, persisting inflation differentials and differentials in
productivity growth led to changes in relative unit labour costs and ‘real’
exchange-rate changes inside the Euro Area. Firms in some states, notably
Ireland, Portugal, Greece, Spain, and Italy, became less competitive and their
current account deficits widened. In contrast, Germany, Austria, Finland, and
Belgium gained competitiveness. In order to deal with asymmetric shocks in
this altered policy framework, Euro Area states had to rely more on regaining
budgetary room for manoeuvre through sound sustainable fiscal policies, on
disciplined wage policies to enhance competitiveness, and on labour-market,
employment, and product and service market policies to encourage flexibility.
Domestic reform pressures mounted and were articulated not least by national
central banks. In the process they were drawn into domestic political contest.
39
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
At the level of process the age of the euro was above all a European affair, bound
up in the economic and political dynamics of European integration. It was part
and parcel of various pro-integration arguments: about completing the ‘logic’ of
European customs union and the single market (‘one market, one money’);
about trade and investment gains from eliminating exchange-rate risk and
reducing transaction costs; and about making European integration, in German
Chancellor Helmut Kohl’s words, ‘irreversible’ and ensuring no future wars in
Europe. Historical memory of catastrophic twentieth-century European wars
40
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
and the failure of traditional faith in the ‘balance of power’ hung heavily over
the politics of the process (Dyson and Featherstone 1999).
The euro raised in a highly focused manner the question of the relationship of
European integration to state power. At its heart was a trade-off that invited
different political choices based on contrasting domestic structures of preference.
On the one hand, loss of state power was implicit in the formal renunciation of
‘monetary sovereignty’, both in its symbolic trappings especially of ‘identity’ and
in the nominal form of the interest rate and the exchange rate as domestic policy
instruments for cushioning asymmetric shocks. Domestic contests were shar-
pened: over implications for different national economic and social models, for
who wins and who loses, and for whether ‘real’ convergence in living standards
represented by GDP per capita was being sacrificed to ‘nominal’ convergence.
On the other hand, euro entry offered the gains of currency and monetary
union. These gains in state power included the elimination of increased vul-
nerability to domestic exchange-rate crises in the post-Bretton Woods age of
floating exchange rates and volatile global financial markets; sharing in Euro-
pean monetary policy rather than being a passive ‘policy taker’ from the
Bundesbank in the Exchange-Rate Mechanism (ERM); as well as increasing
growth and employment through trade effects from reduced transaction costs
and reducing risk through access to much larger, more liquid financial markets
The complex trade-offs were evaluated differently by domestic elites.
Amongst the ‘old’ 15 EU member states in 1998–9 Britain, Denmark, and
Sweden chose to remain ‘outsiders’; whilst newer EU member states divided
between ‘leaders’ and ‘laggards’ on euro entry and shifted their positions on this
spectrum (on which Dyson 2006, 2008).
Above all, the age of the euro represented the most advanced example of
differentiated European integration. In contrast to full integration of all EU
member states, it produced a radical restructuring of European central banking
into the ‘Eurosystem’ and ‘outsiders’. The Eurosystem comprised the ECB and
the national central banks of those EU member states whose currency was the
euro. In this new context, the formal conditionality attached to EU accession,
and later to entry into monetary union, acted as powerful, top–down, European-
level pressures for convergence around a clear, specific and detailed insti-
tutional template of central bank independence, prohibition of monetary
financing of deficits, and strengthened incentives to pursue disinflation and
fiscal discipline.
At the same time, as this volume shows, in the context of contrasting political
choices, and not least underlying economic structures, national central
banks behaved differently. The Bank of England, an ‘outsider’, focused very
41
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
More generally, the NCBs in the Eurosystem sought to occupy different special-
ized niches in the new more competitive environment of ideas. This pursuit of
specialization within the Eurosystem was visible in contributing ideas to mon-
etary policy, financial stability, new research networks, the euro payment and
settlement system, the agenda of the New Public Management, and EU/Euro
Area enlargement and transition economies. NCBs were forced to consider their
comparative advantage and build their own niches as the basis for leadership
roles in pooling services through specialized cooperation activities in the Euro-
system. How they developed specialization, and responded to wider Eurosystem
pressures, reflected the historical accidents of their competences and strengths;
the constraints of their size; and their geographical location. In competences,
for instance, the Belgian and French central banks had traditionally strong roles
in national accounting and in collecting data about firms, giving statistics a
strong profile in their work. The Belgian and Dutch central banks had particular
strengths in developing collateral central bank management systems that they
could transfer to the Eurosystem. In general, smaller NCBs had a greater incen-
tive to seek out cooperation. For instance, two systems of cooperative pooling of
the operational management of the ECB’s foreign reserve assets were established
in 2007: between the Luxembourg and Slovenian central banks; and between
the Cypriot, Greek, Irish, and Maltese central banks. Although small NCBs had a
new incentive to engage in monetary policy analysis, they could not hope to
match the ECB. In contrast, as a large central bank with an eminent reputation
in monetary policy performance, the Bundesbank had a strong incentive to
42
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
maintain both its traditional role in this policy area through its advocacy of a
principles-based approach and its high international profile in various Eurosys-
tem cooperative ventures to provide technical advice to states outside the EU,
including Russia, the Gulf Cooperation Council, and the western Balkans.
Geographic location led the Austrian and Finnish central banks to focus,
respectively, on the Balkans and the Baltic States.
Contest emerged about different forms of cooperation, part of a larger debate
about operating modalities in the Eurosystem, on which the Governing Council
set up a Task Force. Examples of ‘bottom–up’ cooperation included the leading
role of the Belgian National Bank in developing harmonized, efficient, and
secure IT-based management of cash flows with the cash single shared platform
(Cash SSP in 2006) as the model for a future Single Euro Cash Area; and, building
on their geographic locations, the Austrian and the Finnish national banks in
fostering privileged relations with post-communist transition economies in Euro
Area enlargement. A more ‘top–down’ cooperation, negotiated in the ECB Gen-
eral Council, was the German Bundesbank, the Banque de France, and the Banca
d’Italia leadership in the shared computer platform for the TARGET 2 electronic
euro payment and settlement system. This leadership group was extended to the
Spanish central bank in developing the proposal for TARGET2-Securities (T2S)
for settlement of securities transactions using this shared platform. On issues like
cross-border collateral management and statistics a tussle was apparent over the
form that cooperation was to take. The new Collateral Central Bank Manage-
ment (CCBM2)—endorsed by the ECB Governing Council in 2007—was mod-
elled on the Belgian and Dutch central banks, but participation remained
voluntary pending consultation on its further development.
The less central a function was to monetary policy, the greater was the scope
to develop flexible, ‘bottom–up’ cooperation. Alongside the Cash SSP in cash
management (by 2008 the Belgian, Dutch, Luxembourg, and Finnish central
banks), an example of ‘bottom–up’ cooperation in banking supervision was the
2003 Memorandum of Understanding on the exchange of data in national
central registers. This cooperation allowed better evaluation of credit risk in
cross-border lending and involved a consortium of the central banks in Austria,
Belgium, France, Germany, Italy, Portugal, and Spain. Membership was neces-
sarily limited to those states with national credit registers and—given the focus
of banking supervision on the EU level—not in principle limited to Eurosystem
central banks.
43
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
agendas of change. First, NCBs were under increased pressure to stake out
leadership in promoting internal efficiency through the techniques of ‘New
Public Management’. This pressure derived from their vulnerability to two
arguments: that with centralized monetary policy making they were ‘over-
staffed’ in relation to functions, bloated self-serving bureaucracies; and that
they were hypocritical in calling for structural reforms when they were unwill-
ing to bear the pain of reform themselves in the face of major structural change.
Here the main model was a Eurosystem ‘outsider’, the Swedish central bank.
Under Axel Weber the Bundesbank sought to carve out a leadership role on New
Public Management; whereas the Banque de France, caught up in more difficult
public-sector trade union problems, proved a laggard. The New Public Manage-
ment was attractive to the new ECB because it combined an association with
‘modernization’ with centralizing implications and legitimated transformation
in central banking.
Second, NCBs were under pressure to upgrade their applied research, conse-
quent on the need to mount persuasive arguments in a new context in which
they were no longer ‘monopolists’. Quality of analysis was exposed when they
had to share in debates in a large number of Eurosystem committees and
working groups and, above all, to ensure that their governors were well-briefed
for Governing Council meetings on both monetary and non-monetary matters.
The Bundesbank’s focus on developing its niche in the ‘monetary analysis’
pillar of ECB monetary policy strategy represented an attempt to directly
shape centralized policy and to give more analytical clout to its traditional
‘principles-based’ approach. Similarly, building on its advantage in competence
in banking supervision, the Dutch National Bank sought out a niche in the
financial stability function. Overall, however, even for the top performers in
quality research performance like the Dutch and Finnish central banks, it
proved difficult to match the growing scale of research capacity in the ECB. In
the three Eurosystem research networks—on monetary transmission (1999–
2002), inflation persistence, and wage dynamics (2006–8)—ECB researchers
played key roles. In cooperation with NCB research directors, the ECB also
developed benchmarks for assessing research quality, ranking key policy-
oriented academic journals. This new, intensifying benchmarking process in
turn increased internal pressures to invest in research, as well as controversy
about the appropriateness of benchmarking English-language journals when
NCBs should be communicating more actively with domestic audiences.
Above all, the age of the euro witnessed the evolution of a body of principles,
rules, and practices of cooperation and teamwork within the Eurosystem. In
addition to the intense benchmarking described above, the Eurosystem
spawned a body of binding rules. At the heart of this evolution was the search
to marry common goals with the principle of decentralization that had been
established in the preparatory work of the EMI. Centralization was in principle
confined to monetary policy making; though its implementation was a matter
44
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
for the NCBs. Nevertheless, the monetary policy function spawned the need to
extend binding rules to ensure both consistent implementation and that
related functions, like payment and settlement systems, were supportive.
This body of binding rules can be accessed elsewhere (see Dyson and Quaglia
2009). They include the following:
. Treaty articles, notably 4, 105, and 106
. The Statute of the European System of Central Banks (ESCB), especially
articles 3, 12, 17–20
. The ECB regulation on the application of minimum reserves, December
1998 and subsequent amendments
. The ECB decision of 1998 (and subsequent amendments) on the key to
subscriptions of NCBs to the capital of the ECB
. The decision on the rules of procedure of the ECB, February 2004
. The ECB monetary policy rules as laid down in October 1998 and ‘clarified’
in May 2003
. The ECB guidelines on monetary policy instruments and procedures of the
Eurosystem, with various amendments
. The evolution from a two-tier to a single list in the collateral framework
. The correspondent central banking model
. The Council regulation of May 2000 on further calls of foreign reserve
assets by the ECB
. The ECB guidelines of October 2003 on the management of foreign
exchange reserves and operations
. The standards in the EU securities settlement systems
. The Council regulation of November 1998 on collection of statistical
information and the ECB guidelines of November 2000 on statistical report-
ing requirements by the NCBs
Binding rules went along with the evolution of a body of principles about the
organization of cooperation, which reflected the practices that had grown up in
the various committees and working groups of the Eurosystem. They were
articulated in the Eurosystem Mission Statement of 2005. The focus in the
Mission Statement was on ensuring the effectiveness of the Eurosystem as a
‘team of central banks’, able to ‘speak with one voice’ and ‘exploit synergies’.
Prima facie the age of the euro suggests a ‘structural break’ in European central
banking. The arrival of the euro as the second world currency after the US dollar
45
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
46
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
47
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
48
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
49
The Age of the Euro: A Structural Break?
European contest. Central bank power is vulnerable to the potential for political
mobilization of collective action on behalf of losers (putative or real) and to
the association of central bank power with ‘neo-liberal’ Europeanization and
globalization (and their conflation). Its Ordo-liberal variant is also subject to the
contesting legitimacies of the republican and (should the UK ever enter) the
Westminster models of institutional legitimacy and accountability.
Continuing broad political support for the high collective action capacity of
central banks in safeguarding price and financial stability depends on their
dissociation from the ‘excesses’ of financial market power and their avoidance
of ‘moral hazard’. The banking excesses revealed in the 2007–8 financial crisis
and the systemic bail outs of the banking sector brought home this point.
‘Working with the market’ could be reconstructed as ‘being captured by the
market’, as being over-accommodating to reckless risk taking and unjust private
gains at huge cost to the public interest. Broadly held social norms of what
constitutes appropriate behaviour in markets and in central banks are them-
selves a form of structural power that constrain central banks. Central banks
have to be seen to be ensuring compliance with these socially valued norms,
not just facilitating narrower standards of utility maximization by financial
market actors. In this respect, public opinion, as mediated by political elites
and given voice in the media, continues to matter in central banking. Central
banks cannot rely for power on their institutional independence, their close-
ness to and understanding of the markets, or their macro-economic expertise.
As the events of 2007–8 highlighted, they are caught up in larger political
processes of (re)definition of norms of acceptable behaviour, whose neglect—
benign or not—can only undermine popular support for central bank power.
50
Part I
The Changing Context of
Central Banking
This page intentionally left blank
2
Differentiation in the European System
of Central Banks: Circles, Core, and
Directoire
Gaby Umbach and Wolfgang Wessels
53
Differentiation in the European System of Central Banks
This section is based on the analysis of the two most relevant dimensions of
differentiation of the ESCB, institutional and functional. With reference to
institutional differentiation, the two groups of ‘insiders’ and ‘outsiders’ form
the main point of reference. The second section of this part of the chapter
analyses the functional dimension of ESCB differentiation.
54
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Willing
Yes No
Core insiders
(France, Germany, Italy, Spain) Semi-permanent
1 3
Normal insiders outsiders with and
(Maastricht Convergence Criteria)
Temporary outsiders
keen to join
(Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Estonia,
No Romania)
2
Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland,
Candidate countries as
(potential) future outsiders
(Croatia, Turkey, Former Yugoslav
Republic of Macedonia)
4
Figure 2.1. Groups of ESCB membership
Source: Own design.
which is responsible for governing the Eurosystem through the ECB’s Govern-
ing Council and its Executive Board. The 2004–7 EU enlargement boosted a
further sub-division of this first formal group as it created the new informal
(conceptual) sub-group of ‘new insiders’.
‘Core insiders’. The first informal (conceptual) sub-group of ‘core insiders’ is
made up of (old and large) EU Member States (Germany, France, Italy, Spain)
that are powerful enough to seek some kind of political leadership within EMU
and the ESCB and, thus, to construct some sort of de facto differentiation
amongst the ‘insiders’ (see chapters by Dyson, Howarth, and Quaglia). This
sub-group could be eager to advance as a possible directoire (cf. below) of the
‘core’ Europe group of ‘insiders’. ‘Core insiders’ long for a more stable and
permanent institutional representation and influence within Eurosystem insti-
tutions and the ESCB in general, ‘hoisting their national flags’ within the ECB’s
Executive Board in terms of continuing occupancy of seats. During the first
decade, France, Germany, Italy, and Spain are examples for ‘core insiders’.
Treaty provisions on the governing bodies of the ESCB seem to support this
development as they provide opportunity structures for differentiation. ‘Core
insiders’ might use these treaty provisions on the functions of the ESCB accord-
ing to their national interests and monetary policy priorities to steer the ESCB.
55
Differentiation in the European System of Central Banks
56
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
adoption of the euro have been self-set to 2012 onwards (European Com-
mission 2007).
‘Temporary outsiders keen to join’ still have to adapt to the ESCB’s institu-
tional architecture. Moreover, they need to put noticeable efforts into domestic
reforms to stabilize national economic performance in order to meet the Maas-
tricht criteria and to become ‘insiders’.
‘Semi-permanent Outsiders Without a Treaty-based Opt Out’ (Matrix: Box 3). This
informal (conceptual) sub-group comprises EU Member States that are not
Exchange Rate Mechanism II (ERM II) members, are not attempting to fulfil
the Maastricht criteria, have not obtained any derogation in the treaties, and are
not pushed towards Eurosystem membership by the EU. Currently, Sweden
alone forms this sub-group that de facto does not have to fulfil the Maastricht
criteria. Yet, in case of tedious and problematic accession processes amongst
‘temporary outsiders’ to the Eurosystem, this sub-group could serve to pool
those frustrated with accession preparation.
‘Semi-permanent Outsiders With a Treaty-based Opt Out’ (Matrix: Box 3). This
last informal (conceptual) sub-group is made up of EU Member States, like
Denmark (ERM II member) and the United Kingdom (non-ERM II member)
that are not required to join the Eurosystem and that have officially negoti-
ated Treaty opt outs (see chapters by Marcussen and Goodhart). So, de jure,
members of this sub-group do not have to fulfil the Maastricht convergence
criteria. Accession to the Eurosystem strongly depends on domestic political
constellations and priorities. Due to their strong economic performance, these
EU Member States potentially act as role models for non-Eurosystem member-
ship, establishing feasible reasons for ‘temporary outsiders’ to remain ‘semi-
permanent outsiders without a treaty-based opt out’, that is, following the
example of Sweden.
Additionally, two more informal (conceptual) sub-groups of ‘outsiders’ can be
identified. They will, however, not form focus of the analysis in this chapter.
These two sub-groups are constituted by states that are neither EU nor ESCB or
Eurosystem members. They, nevertheless, have institutional links to the ESCB
and are affected by Eurosystem and ESCB decisions as, for example, they are
candidate states to become EU members or partners of international economic
interaction, such as global economic players or international economic and
financial fora.
‘Candidate Countries as (Potential) Future Outsiders’ (Matrix: Box 2). This infor-
mal (conceptual) sub-group consists of states that officially applied for EU
membership like Croatia, Turkey, and the Former Yugoslav Republic of Mace-
donia. They are or might be on their way to (sooner or later) becoming EU
members and are, hence, also affected by Eurosystem and ESCB decisions as
well as by the Maastricht convergence criteria. Additionally, they have to adapt
their national political and economic systems to become ESCB members by the
57
Differentiation in the European System of Central Banks
date of their (potential) accession to the EU. Thus they have to adapt ex ante to
the ESCB’s institutional architecture and functional particularities.
‘Global Players’. Global economic players, such as Brazil, China, India, Japan,
and the United States (including international fora such as G7/8, G8þ, and
the IMF), which have a substantial impact on global economic development,
make up this final informal (conceptual) sub-group (see chapter by Woolley).
They also affect and are affected by a strong/weak euro as part of the global
economy and, thus, also by Eurosystem and ESCB decisions strengthening or
weakening the euro. Their relation to the Eurosystem especially influences
foreign-exchange operations and the external representation of the EU on the
international arena.
58
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Insiders
Core insiders
Normal insiders
New insiders
Figure 2.2. The ESCB—‘Europe of concentric circles’ led by a ‘core Europe of the able’
with traces of a ‘directoire of the powerful’
Source: Own design.
Protocol No. 18 TEC) Above, this pattern was further elaborated by the defi-
nition of different informal sub-groups of ‘insiders’ and ‘outsiders’. A differen-
tiation in terms of power and influence follows. At the same time, the
boundaries of the ‘insider’ and ‘outsider’ groups are ‘permeable’ through EU
accession and the adoption of the entire EU acquis by acceding states.
Within the treaties, this differentiation is formally enshrined in the separ-
ation between ‘Member States without a derogation’ and ‘Member States with a
derogation’ (Art. 122 TEC). The provisions of the Lisbon Treaty were designed to
make more visible the treaty-based opportunity structure for a Europe of concen-
tric circles, that is, differentiation between ‘insiders’ and ‘outsiders’, by explicit
legal provisions. It differentiates explicitly between ‘countries whose currency
is the euro’ (‘insiders’) and those ‘Member States with a derogation’ (‘outsiders’).
It will insert new articles on both country groups into the treaties to ensure the
proper functioning of EMU (Art. 136–138 TFEU). The Treaty amendments
related to ‘countries whose currency is the euro’ refer to the Stability and
Growth Pact (SGP), the Broad Economic Policy Guidelines (BEPG), and the
Euro Group (cf. below), enhancing their visibility. In the case of ‘Member States
with a derogation’, the new provisions (Art. 139–144 TFEU) include a precise list
59
Differentiation in the European System of Central Banks
of elements that shall not apply to this group, enumerating them more expli-
citly and in more detail than Art. 122(3) TEC of the Nice Treaty. This develop-
ment seems to point to a strengthening of treaty-based opportunity structures
for a Europe of concentric circles.
60
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
61
Differentiation in the European System of Central Banks
62
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
one vote’ is kept only until the point in Eurosystem ‘widening’, when
the Governing Council consists of more than 21 members (Art. 10(2) Protocol
No. 18 TEC), that means until the entry of Slovakia in 2009. Thereafter, only
15 voting rights are attributed to the NCB governors, who are members of the
Governing Council. The six members of the Executive Board keep one vote
each. Special rotation rules are applied to the exercise of the voting rights by
the NCB governors, who are divided into two/three groups (Art. 10 Protocol
No. 18 TEC). From more than 15 to 22 governors, they will be allocated to two
groups (ibid.). From 22 governors onwards, three groups will be established
(ibid.). These different groups are defined ‘according to a ranking of the size of
the share of their [the governors’] national central bank’s Member State in the
aggregate gross domestic product at market prices and in the total aggregated
balance sheet of the monetary financial institutions of the Member States
which have adopted the euro’ (ibid.). Acting by a two-thirds majority of all
members, the Governing Council can, however, ‘decide to postpone the start
of the rotation system until the date on which the number of governors
exceeds 18’ (ibid.). With this treaty-based pre-definition of voting rule adap-
tation, differentiation is, hence, already introduced by the treaties, pointing at
a treaty-based opportunity structure for the development of a directoire based
on economic indicators and performance.
Functional Differentiation
The functional dimension of differentiation ties in with the basic institutional
differentiation between ‘insiders’ and ‘outsiders’. Within the ESCB, ‘insiders’
take on different functions from ‘outsiders’, especially in the implementation of
ESCB decisions. As a consequence, ‘insider’ NCBs are affected differently by the
ESCB than those of ‘outsiders’ in terms of obligation to take part in supra-
national policy-making and implementation.
MONETARY POLICY-MAKING
The core function of the ESCB is European monetary policy-making. Art. 105
to 124 TEC lay down the treaty foundation of monetary policy and the role of
the ESCB in it. The core objective of the ESCB is to ‘maintain price stability’
and to ‘support the general economic policies in the Community’, while not
losing sight of its aforementioned core objective (Art. 105(1) TEC). In the light
of this priority and ‘the principle of an open market economy with free
competition, favouring an efficient allocation of resources’ (ibid.), the main
tasks of the ESCB are (1) the definition and implementation of the European
monetary policy, (2) the conduct of foreign-exchange operations, and (3) the
holding and management of the EU Member States’ official foreign reserves
63
Differentiation in the European System of Central Banks
(Art. 105(2) TEC). Within the ESCB, the ECB is the predominant institution to
safeguard this particular European monetary policy-making paradigm (Issing
2008: 85 ff.). It is exclusively and independently responsible for monetary
policy decisions (Art. 105(2) TEC; Begg 2007: 36; Issing 2008: 115 ff.) and,
hence, symbolizes ‘the institutionalization of a monetary sovereignty’ (Le
Heron 2007: 11) within EMU. The main instruments of the ECB in this context
are guidelines, recommendations, and opinions at the request of EU institu-
tions, as well as decisions and regulations on European monetary policy. The
Lisbon Treaty groups monetary policy-making for Member States whose cur-
rency is the euro under the ‘exclusive competences’ of the Union (Art. 3 TFEU)
and formally integrates the ECB into the EU’s institutional framework (Art. 13
TEU).
The ESCB’s monetary policy function exerts strong implementation pressure
on ‘insiders’, while ‘outsiders’ are affected to a lesser degree and more indirectly
(especially via markets). ESCB monetary policy decisions, taken by ‘insiders’
within the Governing Council, are directly binding for ‘insiders’ who have to
implement them on behalf of the ESCB. ‘Outsiders’ influence European mon-
etary policy-making via their integration into the General Council (Art. 45
Protocol No. 18 TEC), focusing on advisory functions, statistical data collection,
reporting activities of the ECB, etc. (Art. 47 Protocol No. 18 TEC).
FISCAL POLICY-MAKING
The ESCB is characterized and affected by the ‘asymmetry between monetary
and fiscal policy in the Euro Area . . . , with the ECB setting a predictable policy
based on price stability in the area as a whole and the member states setting
fiscal policy individually subject to the joint arrangements of the Broad Macro-
economic Guidelines and the SGP processes’ (Mayes and Virén 2007: 172).
Under the SGP (Art. 104 TEC), both ‘insiders’ and ‘outsiders’ have to keep
their national fiscal policies in line with the provisions of the pact to avoid
violations through excessive deficit spending in order to lower the costs of
supranational monetary policy-making by maintaining fiscal stability (Mayes
and Virén 2007: 160). In case of non-compliances or breaches, however, only
‘insiders’ face the risk of financial sanctions, given that special rules apply to
‘outsiders’ (Art. 122(3) TEC). Under the pact, ‘insiders’ have to prepare annual
National Stability Programs (NSPs), outlining their efforts to comply with the
pact, such as a budgetary policy that guarantees sustainability of public finances
and adheres to the treaty-based GDP threshold, policies to implement the
objectives of the NSP, and main underlying economic ideas. These NSPs form
the basis for the supranational surveillance process, for recommendations that
aim at bringing excessive deficits to an end within a given period, and for
possible sanctions in case of failure to do so.
64
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
65
Differentiation in the European System of Central Banks
BANKING SUPERVISION
The ESCB is also responsible for ‘the prudential supervision of credit institu-
tions and the stability of the financial system’ (Art. 105(5) TEC). However, this
function is assessed not to belong to the core tasks of the ESCB (Smits 1997:
319) and of central banking in general (Stadler 1996: 118). The ESCB’s and its
Banking Supervision Committee’s role within the sector is of mainly coordina-
tive and consultative character (Schüler 2003: 4). National institutions respon-
sible for banking supervision, thus, co-exist with the ESCB in this functional
sector and partake in the ECB’s Banking Supervision Committee. Based on Art.
14(4) Protocol No. 18 TEC, NCBs that were in charge of this function before
EMU continue performing it also within the ESCB. Via the ECB, the ESCB is,
moreover, integrated into international activities in the field, such as the Basel
Committee on Banking Supervision, the European Securities Committee, or
Committee of European Banking Supervisors (see Moran and Macartney’s
chapter).
From ‘a financial integration perspective, the main priority [of this area] is
to remove any supervisory obstacles to cross-border finance, notably via
enhanced supervisory cooperation and convergence’ (Papademos 2005). The
ECB advises and is consulted by the European Commission, the Council, or
institutions of EU Member States concerning the focus and ‘implementation
of Community legislation relating to the prudential supervision of credit
institutions and to the stability of the financial system’ (Art. 25(1) Protocol
No. 18 TEC). If so decided by the Council (Art. 105(6) TEC), the ECB may take
over particular tasks related to banking and financial supervision except for
insurance undertaking. So, the competences and powers of the ECB and the
ESCB depend on the Council. Thus, in this functional area, the ECB holds a
weaker position than in supranational monetary policy-making.
Within this area of functional differentiation, the institutional differenti-
ation alongside ‘insiders’ and ‘outsiders’ is relevant only insofar as the ECB’s
tasks related to banking supervision formally concentrate on credit and other
financial institutions within the Eurosystem. Yet, in practice, ‘the financial
integration process . . . has involved a substantial increase in cross-border bank-
ing’ (Papademos 2005). As a result, ‘cross-border banking broadens and deepens
banking markets, increases liquidity and risk sharing and thus strengthens the
overall resilience of the European financial system’ (ibid.). Hence, also ‘out-
siders’ are integrated into banking supervision activities of the ECB given that
economic risks are spread across the different groups of Eurosystem members.
As a result, the formal differentiation within the Eurosystem according to its
legal basis—alongside the lines of ‘insiders’ and ‘outsiders’—seems to a certain
66
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
extent to be compensated, given that not only ‘insiders’’ banking systems are
exposed to such risks due to increased cross-border activities at many levels of
the economic system.
67
Differentiation in the European System of Central Banks
No. 18 TEC), which is taken over by the ECB President or his nominee (Art. 13
(2) Protocol No. 18 TEC). Based on this competence, the ECB ‘and, subject to its
approval, the national central banks [without prejudice to Art. 111(4) TEC]
may participate in international monetary institutions’ (Art. 6, 23, and 31
Protocol No. 18 TEC). NCBs may join these efforts (Art. 23 and 31 Protocol
No. 18 TEC). In external representation, opportunity structures offered by the
treaties open a certain area of potential conflict. According to Art. 111(4) TEC,
positions ‘of the Community at international level as regards issues of particu-
lar relevance to economic and monetary union and on its representation’ are
decided upon by the ECOFIN Council by qualified majority. In the past, this
allocation of competences to different institutions in the field, that is, the
Commissioner for economic and monetary affairs, the Euro Group president,
and the ECB president, partially resulted in the EU having to orchestrate a
chorus of several voices within its external representation in financial matters
(DIE ZEIT 2007).
Changes regarding the procedure to establish and decide upon the EU’s
external representation introduced by the Lisbon Treaty (Art. 115a TFEU)
might rebalance the weight of the EU institutions in external representation
in financial matters. The new articles of the Lisbon Treaty seek to ensure a more
uniform external representation by stating that the ‘Council, on a proposal
from the Commission, may adopt appropriate measures to ensure unified
representation within the international financial institutions and conferences.
The Council shall act after consulting the European Central Bank’ (Art. 115a(2)
TFEU). In decision-taking on these issues only members whose currency is the
euro, that is, ‘insiders’ may partake in voting. So these provisions create a new
opportunity structure for further institutional differentiation within the ESCB,
favouring ‘insiders’.
More specific forms of bi-/multilateral international relations are established
through a number of regular and ad hoc high-level, ‘closed-door’ seminars,
including members of the ESCB Governing Council and their respective
national counterparts. By these means, the ESCB establishes direct contacts
between ‘insiders’, ‘outsiders’, and international financial actors. Regular
high-level seminars are held with representatives of Russia, the Barcelona
Process countries, accession countries, Latin America, and South-East Asia. Ad
hoc seminars link the ESCB with their counterparts in West Africa/South Africa
and Gulf Group countries. Moreover, contacts are established with countries of
the Middle East, neighbouring countries, emerging economies in Asia, the IMF,
G7/8, as well as G8þ (i.e. ‘Global Players’). Contacts to European non-EU
Member States, that is, Norway and Switzerland, are held via other inter-
national fora, given that they, especially Switzerland, have long before EMU
been ‘part of the club’ through their membership of the Bank for International
Settlements (BIS). Contacts with Norway, on the other hand, are said to be not
as close and less frequent.
68
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Apart from its structural differentiation into Eurosystem ‘insiders’ and ‘out-
siders’, the ESCB is characterized by two key dimensions of differentiated
integration: functional and institutional. The functional dimension comprises
different policy areas, in which the ESCB performs different functions and
holds different decision-making competences vis-à-vis other supranational
and national institutions. The ESCB holds strongest competences in supra-
national monetary policy-making. In the external representation of the Euro-
system in international organizations, the authority of the ECB to decide on the
representation of the ESCB within international cooperation (Art. 6 Protocol
No. 18 TEC) partially interferes with the external representation of the EU in
financial matters by the European Commission and the Council of the EU. Here
the Lisbon Treaty, if adopted and implemented to the letter, might lay the
ground for a more uniform representation of the EU. In payment system
oversight and banking supervision, in which the Council holds a more power-
ful position, ESCB competences strongly focus on the practical conduct of
policies as well as on the operation of policies.
The institutional dimension of differentiation seems to display a dynamic
co-existence and co-evolution of three different patterns over the first decade
of the euro: a Europe of concentric circles (‘insiders’ and ‘outsiders’), a ‘core
Europe group of the able’ (‘insiders’), and a ‘directoire of the powerful’ (‘core
insiders’).
The legal basis of the ESCB stimulated both ‘insiders’ and ‘outsiders’ to
engage in institution building and shaping. It motivated both groups to adapt
to supranational monetary policy-making and to follow the implications of the
ESCB. In consequence, a scenario of ‘outsiders’ steadily moving towards
the centre of the ESCB’s institutional architecture and towards integration
into the Eurosystem is feasible.
This chapter has provided insight into the impact of the ESCB on these two
different groups of members. With respect to the functional dimension of
differentiation, constraints derive from the ESCB’s policy-related decisions.
These constraints can be assessed to impact differently on ‘insiders’ and ‘out-
siders’. With respect to the institutional dimension of differentiation, the ESCB
showed traces of separation between ‘insiders’ and ‘outsiders’. At the same time,
the system also motivated ‘insiders’ and ‘outsiders’ to engage in the system and
its decision-making through the General Council. However, ‘insiders’ addition-
ally engaged in the Governing Council and the Executive Board in order to
shape decisions. So, in political practice as well as within the treaty-based
foundations, ‘insiders’ and ‘outsiders’ form the essential building block of the
differentiation of the ESCB’s institutional design. The differentiation amongst
ESCB members results in several concentric circles: As a consequence of
69
Differentiation in the European System of Central Banks
different speeds of rapprochement, ‘insiders’ form the ESCB ‘core Europe group
of the able’. ‘Outsiders’ are arranged around this core Europe group. The overall
result is the ESCB as a Europe of concentric circles. Within the core Europe
group of the ESCB, a ‘directoire of the powerful’ can, in analytical conceptual
terms, be assumed to form the institutional nucleus of the system.
Elements of institutional differentiation have been found within both the
treaties (‘legal architecture’) and seem to be visible also in its political reality
(‘living practice’). The treaty-based reform of voting rights and rules in the
enlarged Governing Council and a certain de facto ‘double representation’ of
some Member States (Germany, France, Italy, and Spain) in the ESCB’s govern-
ing bodies provide evidence of this process. Provisions of the Lisbon Treaty on
the Euro Group, as well as on the two groups of ‘countries whose currency is the
euro’ and those ‘with a derogation’, additionally strengthen the treaty-based
foundations of differentiation. These provisions show that the ESCB is based on
a legal foundation that provides for opportunities for the development of a
Europe of concentric circles, led by a ‘core Europe group of the able’ and guided
to a certain extent by a ‘directoire of the powerful’ (Figure 2.2).
These patterns of differentiation have, however, not induced a strong ten-
dency towards the development of one ‘Core Europe group’ or one particular
differentiation feature for the political system of the EU in general. Quite
contrary to such a ‘standard differentiation’, the number and forms of opt
outs from the overall system—that is, the variation of differentiation—have
even increased since the creation of EMU. So, the institutional architecture of
EMU has not provided for a standard differentiation design for membership
across policy areas. The opt outs from the Treaty of Prüm or the Lisbon Treaty
indicate at such variations of differentiation not directly following the EMU
model.
The most significant impact of EMU differentiation might have been more
indirect: it served as an example that, even in highly relevant policy fields,
membership did not have to imply equal rights and obligations for all EU
Member States. In this way, it might have softened concerns of the ‘community
orthodoxy’ and changed perceptions to view forms of differentiation as accept-
able solutions to enhance European integration in areas, in which not all
Member States are willing or able to follow. In the wake of the Irish referendum
on the Lisbon Treaty, a renaissance of this perception of differentiation con-
cepts as mechanisms to unfetter blockades can be observed (Dahrendorf 2008;
Habermas 2008; Hierlemann 2008: 4).
Yet, another expectation related to EMU differentiation did not materialize:
In the 1990s, some proponents of the idea of a ‘Core Europe’ (especially
Schäuble and Lamers 1994) regarded EMU not just as a mere example or role
model for differentiation. They perceived differentiation within EMU to serve
as a strategic ‘door opener’ to a more federal and integrated Europe of the
willing and able Member States. EMU members were expected to move ahead
70
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
towards closer integration also in other policy fields. They were, thus, assumed
to develop into a certain constitutional ‘avantgarde’ of European integration as
a whole. With the enlargement of EMU and in the light of the outcome of
the Dutch, French, and Irish referendums, EMU differentiation did, yet, not
provide for the basis of a more integrated group of EU members, that go ahead
also beyond monetary and economic integration.
Notes
1. The approach of the chapter is based on the research method of the Jean-Monnet Chair
for Political Science at the University of Cologne regarding the comparative analysis of
the ‘legal architecture’ (written, treaty-based provisions) and the ‘living practice’ (its
reality in practice) of and within the EU. Additionally, new institutionalism (Bulmer
1994, 1997: 4; Hall and Taylor 1996: 6; Jachtenfuchs and Kohler-Koch 2004: 101;
Knodt 2005: 18; March and Olsen 2005: 4 ff.; Peters 2000: 4 ff.; Stone Sweet and
Sandholtz 1998: 16) serves as an explanatory element for the evaluation of the impli-
cations of the ESCB for ‘insiders’ and ‘outsiders’ both within the ‘legal/formal ESCB’
(written provisions) and the ‘living ESCB’ (its reality in practice).
2. Out of the seven to nine annual meetings of the International Affairs Committee
two to three are held in EU-27 composition (i.e. one out of three meetings is held in
this extended composition). Moreover, there are regular contacts between ECB and
NCB (e.g. Bank of England) officials, partially also on a rather informal/personal level.
ERM-II links with Denmark for instance are held via the Currency Board meetings.
3. Information provided by ECB officials interviewed for this chapter.
4. Perception of ECB officials interviewed for this chapter.
71
This page intentionally left blank
3
The European Central Bank: The Bank
That Rules Europe?
David Howarth
The power of the European Central Bank (ECB) is rooted in its independence
established in the Maastricht Treaty of 1992. This power is reinforced through
the bank’s monetary policy credibility—achieved through meeting its price
stability mandate, while resisting political pressures to manipulate monetary
policy to other ends. In turn, credibility contributes to the ideational power of
the ECB, which is rooted in widespread support for price stability, one of the
core objectives of Economic and Monetary Union (EMU). The ECB’s relative
power, as one of the two leading central banks in the world, is determined by
the relative size of the Euro Area economy and the growing importance of the
euro as an international reserve currency. It is the leading face of the Euro Area
abroad and a new and important presence in several international economic
fora. The ECB is effectively the ‘captain’ of the team of Eurosystem (Euro Area)
national central banks (NCBs) as well as the wider European System of Central
Banks (ESCB)—which includes all European Union (EU) NCBs. It is responsible
for coordinating the policy making of Eurosystem NCBs in a range of areas and
NCB discussions on inflation forecasts.
However, there are clear limits to the ECB’s power. It controls neither
exchange-rate policy nor prudential supervision. Limits have been placed
upon its international role. The ECB must work with governments to build
support for low inflationary policies and maintain political support for EMU.
The ECB is one of the most consistent voices in favour of structural reform in
the European Union (EU), yet there is little the bank can do to enforce reform
in the short term. Furthermore, the ECB must share many core central banking
operations with Eurosystem national central banks (NCBs). This chapter
explores the confines of European Central Bank power.
73
The European Central Bank: The Bank That Rules Europe?
The basic power of the ECB is to define and implement the monetary policy
of the Euro Area. The ECB enjoys unrivalled goal-setting and operational
independence in the pursuit of its price stability goals, and its Governing
Council members enjoy ad personam independence. The Bank is further
sheltered from political interference by the need for the unanimous
approval of member states to change the Treaty provisions on independ-
ence. The Statute of the ECB and the ESCB (principally Article 3) sets out
the tasks of Eurosystem NCBs as ‘to define and implement the monetary
policy of the Community’; ‘to conduct foreign exchange operations’; ‘to
hold and manage the official foreign reserves of the member states’;
‘to promote the smooth operation of payment systems’; ‘and to contribute
to the smooth conduct of policies pursued by the competent authorities
relating to the prudential supervision of credit institutions and the stability
of the financial system’. The ECB can make regulations (Article 110(1) TEC),
principally with regard to the operation of the ESCB and can impose fines
or periodic penalty payments for failure to comply with obligations con-
tained in its regulations and decisions (Article 110(3) ). This competence
applies notably with regard to the reserves that credit institutions should
hold with the ECB and the prudential supervision of credit institutions—
although the Council of Ministers must first establish the broader frame-
work of rules on these matters.
The ECB’s Governing Council (comprising 6 Executive Board members and,
in 2009, 16 NCB governors) is the monetary policy committee of the Euro
Area. It formulates the monetary policy of the Eurosystem with the aim of
maintaining price stability as the Governing Council defines it, including
decisions relating to specific monetary objectives, monetary strategy, key
interest rates, and the supply of Eurosystem reserves (Article 12.1, ESCB Stat-
ute). The Governing Council adopts the internal rules of the ECB and may
decide by two-thirds of the votes cast to modify operational methods of
monetary control. It exercises advisory functions vis-à-vis other European
Union bodies. Moreover, it has the power to form opinions on its own initia-
tive on the economic policies adopted by the European Union and member
state governments on matters which fall within its jurisdiction, crucially with
regard to the pursuit of ‘stability-oriented’ economic policies.
The six-member Executive Board implements the Eurosystem’s monetary
policy—giving necessary instructions to the NCBs—in accordance with the
guidelines and decisions established by the Governing Council. It decides
upon the precise instruments to be used. It also prepares the meetings of the
Governing Council. The Executive Board may have certain additional powers
delegated to it by the Governing Council (Article 12, ESCB Statute).
74
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
75
The European Central Bank: The Bank That Rules Europe?
76
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
77
The European Central Bank: The Bank That Rules Europe?
78
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Since the Delors Committee began meeting in 1988, there has been debate about
the role to be played by the ECB in the external representation of the Euro Area in
international fora. This issue links into the broader problem of the division of
responsibilities among EU institutions over the major elements of economic
policy and the respective roles of the Council (Euro Group), the Commission,
and the ECB in external representation (Henning and Padoan 2000; McNamara
and Meunier 2002). Where the Council represents the Euro Area externally, ECB
representatives nonetheless engage in the preparation of Euro Area positions for
meetings in international fora within the EU’s Economic and Financial Com-
mittee, prior to these positions being finalized in the Euro Group.
The ECB made its initial demands for right to external representation on the
basis both of Treaty provisions that stipulate that the ‘Community’ express a
single position in external monetary policy, and of ESCB Statute provisions
(Article 6) that allow the ECB to decide how Euro Area NCBs shall be repre-
sented by the ECB and/or by Euro Area NCBs, on matters falling into its
jurisdiction (Padoa Schioppa 1999c). Thus in central banking fora, the partici-
pation of the ECB has been straightforward. For example, the ECB president
participates in the meetings of the G-10 Governors organized in the context of
the BIS and in the committees under the aegis of the governors, notably the
Basle Committee on Banking Supervision and the Committee on the Global
Finance System. Eurosystem finance ministers also have an interest in ECB
participation in intergovernmental fora. For example, the potential success of
(eventual) international exchange-rate cooperation [under the aegis of the
Group of 8 (G-8)] or concerted intervention in the currency markets relies
very much on both ex ante and ex post internal Euro Area co-ordination that
ensures that the ECB will be willing and able to implement the policy bargain.
The ECB’s status at the IMF is limited to that of observer. Its representative
attends and has the right to speak at meetings on the role of the euro in the
international monetary system, multilateral surveillance of the Euro Area and
individual countries within the zone, international capital market reports, and
world economic and market developments. The ECB has the right to send a
representative to IMF Executive Board meetings when agenda items are recog-
nized by both the ECB and the IMF to be of mutual interest for the performance
of their respective mandates. The representative can also be invited to other
Executive Board meetings, although s/he does not have the right to attend. The
official Euro Area representative on the IMF Executive Board is the Euro Group
chair. The ECB also obtained observer status in the meetings of the G-10
Ministers and Governors, which are organized in connection with the IMF
Interim Committee meetings. Although, the ECB’s role is limited compared
to that of the member state governments, its presence may help to unify
the views of the EU participants on particular matters. Moreover, the ECB’s
79
The European Central Bank: The Bank That Rules Europe?
observer status does not mean that it assumes a passive role. ECB and Euro Area
NCB representatives have taken strong, outspoken positions on major inter-
national monetary, financial and other economic issues (see Issing 1998 for one
early example).
ECB membership of the OECD, another intergovernmental institution, was
also out of the question. However, the organization deals with issues—notably
surveillance of the Euro Area—relating to the tasks assigned to the Eurosystem.
In February 1999, the OECD Secretary General confirmed that the ECB would
be allowed to participate in the work of the relevant committees and working
groups as a member of the EC delegation alongside the European Commission.
The ECB can make use of its presence in both the IMF and OECD to emphasize
the need for ongoing structural reform in the Euro Area (Stark 2008b). In the
G-8, the ECB president replaces Euro Area NCB governors during the first part
of finance minister meetings when monetary matters are discussed. In the
G-20, the ECB president attends in addition to the NCB governors from the
four member states with the largest economies.
The ECB has called for the reinforcement of the ECB’s position in these
international fora. Duisenberg (2000b) further argued for the gradual but
fundamental adaptation of the traditional institutional framework of inter-
national relations on the grounds that the existing framework—based on the
representation of national governments—‘was not tailored to the involvement
of monetary unions, nor to the advent of the Eurosystem, and more generally
the [Euro Area], as a new actor in international relations’. With regard to Euro-
system representation in international fora where both ministers and bank
governors are represented (G-8 Finance, G-20), Duisenberg focused on the
capability to speak with one voice (if and when appropriate) and a clearer Euro
Area political counterpart for the ECB. Instead of the four Euro Area member
state finance ministers (in the G-8 and G-20), he preferred a single Euro Group
representative with a higher profile. He wanted to overcome the co-ordination
problems among Eurosystem member states on external monetary policy.
Given the diverse circumstances of bilateral economic relations with third
countries, the EU finance ministers did not set arrangements for Euro Area
representation. The presence of the ECB in these bilateral discussions is now
left to the Euro Group chair. The ECB has forged and reinforced bilateral
relations with other central banks on issues of mutual concern, including
operational facilities, financial stability and the provision of technical assist-
ance. Notably, since November 1999 it has become involved in the EU
enlargement process by providing assistance to the central banks of central
and eastern European candidate countries to prepare them for participation in
the ESCB following accession and their eventual participation in the Eurosys-
tem. In addition to central banks, the ECB has developed contacts with other
relevant foreign institutions, such as banking supervisory authorities, local
banking associations, stock exchanges, and national public administrations.
80
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
The ECB’s relatively small Executive Board and its weight on the Governing
Council (6 out of 21 places, or less than third) demonstrate an important
feature of the Eurosystem. Compared to other federal banking systems, the
Eurosystem is relatively decentralized: NCBs have more sway collectively than,
say, representatives from the Federal Reserve District Banks. This reflects prac-
tical reality: the NCBs are well-established, whereas the ECB is a fledgling,
small institution. Eurosystem NCBs perform several operations vital to the
operation of the Euro Area: notably, they conduct foreign-exchange oper-
ations and ensure the smooth operation of payment systems (including TAR-
GET). The NCBs hold and manage the official foreign reserves of the member
states (of which they can provide up to 40 billion euro to the ECB) and hold
the capital of the ECB (just under 4 billion euro). However, NCBs must follow
the regulations, guidelines, and instructions of the ECB in these and several
other areas: buying and selling securities and other claims; borrowing and
lending securities; dealing in precious metals; conducting credit operations
with banks and other financial institutions based on adequate collateral; act-
ing as fiscal agents for public entities (although they may not grant them credit
facilities or buy their debt instruments directly from them). The ECB can also
engage in these activities. The precise role of the ECB in relation to the NCBs
depends on the kinds of open market operations selected (with regard to aim,
regularity and procedures). NCBs are able to perform tasks beyond those
specified in the ESCB Statute, except if the Governing Council decides that
these activities interfere with the work of the ESCB. The ECB alone attends
Euro Group meetings and Ecofin Councils. However, Eurosystem NCBs (and
ESCB NCBs) will occasionally attend informal meetings of Ecofin with varying
degrees of participation as well as meetings of the EU’s Economic and Financial
Committee when macroeconomic policy coordination issues discussed dir-
ectly impinge on them. In 2003, Euro Area NCBs lost their right to sit in
Economic and Financial Committee meetings—much to the opposition of
several NCBs, including the Bundesbank (Dyson 2008c)—which has reinforced
the importance of the ECB in European economic governance.
The degree to which the Eurosystem is centralized will develop over time.
The important role of the NCBs in ECB decision-making (in the working
groups, committees, and the Governing Council) reflects the ongoing import-
ance of the analytical—including statistical—resources available in the NCBs
and in particular the largest. The relative dependence of the ECB on the NCBs
has reduced over the past decade, nonetheless the US Federal Reserve remains
better endowed analytically than the ECB and less reliant on the state reserve
banks. The importance of the NCBs in ECB decision-making encourages a
combination of collaborative and competitive work (Goodfriend 1999;
Hochreiter 2000; Mayes 1998, 2000). In their attempt to have an impact on
81
The European Central Bank: The Bank That Rules Europe?
Governing Council decision-making, each NCB governor will use the resour-
ces of his own NCB to provide the necessary information and strengthen his
position in the ongoing debate with other NCBs and the ECB Executive Board
on appropriate policy and the way that the Euro Area economy works. The
development of the ECB’s autonomous analytical capacity in relation to that
of the NCBs will be important in determining the level of centralization in
Eurosystem policy making. The ECB has already become the most important
centre for monetary policy research in the EU (see below) hiring some of the
best monetary economists from NCBs.
Members of the Governing Council are expected to speak with one voice on
the basis of the agreed-upon forecasts, although there is no legal requirement to
do so. Efforts have been made to ensure a tight coordination of official state-
ments on ECB monetary policy: the President is spokesperson in the official
press conference following the bi-weekly meetings, while the other members of
the Council have to explain Eurosystem policy in the member states in their
own languages. There have been a number of incidents where different NCB
governors made ambiguous remarks between Governing Council meetings
that led to false predictions of monetary policy decisions (Louis 2002). How-
ever, there has yet to be a publicly expressed substantive difference of opinion
between members of the Governing Council. Another potential source of
divergence in the public expression of policy is the separate national forecasts
published by the independent NCBs. Varying NCB forecasts could send differ-
ent signals to market operators about the development of ECB policy. However,
it is the role of ECB working groups and committees to iron out differences and
ensure coherence in all the forecasts of the Euro Area prior to their publication.
The relative importance of the NCBs in the Eurosystem also arguably reflects
the highly decentralized nature of the EU political system and the problematic
legitimacy of the EU in the eyes of many member state citizens. Arguably,
European citizens are more likely to accept ECB monetary policy if they know
that they are represented, however indirectly and unofficially, by NCB gover-
nors, and that policy is designed in the fora of working groups, committees, and
the Governing Council, where NCB experts and officials predominate. This
concern was of great relevance to discussions in the ECB in 2002–3 on Govern-
ing Council reform in the context of Euro Area enlargement (see below).
The ECB Executive Board has been very cautious in its interventions into the
operation of NCBs. One of the most controversial developments during the first
decade of EMU was the Banca d’Italia Governor Antonio Fazio’s handling of the
takeover battle for Banca Antonveneta. Despite much criticism, the ECB Execu-
tive Board initially took a ‘hands-off’ approach and warned of a dangerous
precedent for ESCB independence if the Italian government used legislation to
remove Fazio (Financial Times 16 September 2005). The ECB finally adopted a
much tougher tone in mid-December 2005, after it was made public that Fazio
had received gifts from the former head of a major Italian bank. President Trichet
82
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
warned that, in accepting gifts, the Italian governor might have breached the
ECB’s code of conduct (Financial Times 17 December 2005). However, the ECB
has no investigative powers and was unable to pursue matters further. Ultim-
ately, Fazio’s resignation saved the ECB further damage to its credibility and the
danger of public battles between Governing Council members.
Although the ECB regularly insists upon its independence and directly chal-
lenges political leaders who call this into question, it needs to maintain a
constructive dialogue with democratically elected officials. The ECB does
this in its dealings with the Euro Group of Euro Area finance ministers. The
ECB also maintains direct relations with the European Parliament (EP), not-
ably in terms of ex-post facto reporting and questioning. The EP must be
consulted on appointments to the ECB Executive Board. It receives and
debates the ECB’s annual report and requests that the president and other
Executive Board members appear before the Committee on Economic and
Monetary Affairs (TEC Article 113) (see, for example, Duisenberg 2000a).
Overall, however, the EP has little say over the ECB’s management of monetary
policy. As Dyson (2000: 69) notes, the model of ECB–EP relations is no match
for US Federal Reserve–Congress relations, where a well-staffed and financed
Congressional committee maintains constant scrutiny over the central bank.
The ECB is not responsible to the EP or other EU institutions; none have the
power to dismiss ECB Executive Board members on the grounds of unsatisfac-
tory performance in fulfilment of the Bank’s own goals (Taylor 2000).
However, there are signs that the ECB has been responsive to the concerns of
the European Parliament and that a certain form of ECB accountability has
developed (Jabko 2003; Magnette 2000). While the Treaty and the ESCB Stat-
ute establish no specific appearance requirements, the EP succeeded in obtain-
ing Duisenberg’s agreement that he would appear before the Committee on
Economic and Monetary Affairs four times a year. This accountability has been
good for the ECB’s legitimacy. The wide-ranging review of the ECB by the
Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs can ensure that the Bank’s
technical decisions are subject to scrutiny from beyond the ESCB. This review
can increase awareness and widen support for the Bank’s underlying policies
and principles. Accountability to the EP has also arguably induced improve-
ments in ECB transparency, despite the absence of formal disclosure require-
ments (Jabko 2003). For instance, (nonbinding) EP resolutions on the ECB
Annual Report have repeatedly urged the ECB to be become more transparent,
and the publication of the ECB’s macroeconomic projections appears to have
been triggered by the quarterly ‘monetary dialogue’ between the ECB and the
Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs.
83
The European Central Bank: The Bank That Rules Europe?
The ECB has actively promoted structural reforms with the aim of reducing the
public-sector debt burden, in Governing Council member speeches, press
conferences, monthly bulletins, and annual reports. It has consistently
defended the Stability and Growth Pact, criticized the suspension of the
Excessive Deficit Procedure with regard to France and Germany in 2003, and
sent strong warnings about the dangers of watering down the Pact in the
March 2005 reform (Howarth and Loedel 2004). For the ECB, the Pact is a
vital tool to entrench a stability culture in the Euro Area and to avoid conflict-
ual relations with profligate governments. The ECB’s pro-reform agenda has
been challenged by government and opposition politicians in several member
states and labour leaders.
84
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
There were concerns that, following the departure of Issing and with the
decision to divide the management of Directorate Generals economics and
research, the latter would lose influence on policy making and resources.
However, Lucas Papademos, the Executive Board member in charge of DG
research since 2006, sought to allay fears by directing it ‘to focus more on
policy-related issues’ (Financial Times 1 June 2006). With a PhD from the
Massachusetts Institute of Technology and a stint as an academic at Columbia
University, he has a strong background in academic economic research.
Internal Reform
Unlike several NCBs in the Eurosystem, which have had to undergo painful
internal cuts and significant reform, the ECB expanded its staff number every
year since its creation. It remains a comparatively small and efficient central
bank. At the end of 2007, 1,375 members of staff (full-time equivalent) were
employed on permanent or fixed term, up from 1,217 staff members at the end
of 2003. This number is dwarfed by the number employees working in the
largest Eurosystem NCBs. However, the ECB’s capacities have been increased
considerably, and in some areas (notably, research) its reputation has over-
taken that of the other Eurosystem NCBs.
Despite the ECB’s reputation for efficiency, bank management had to coun-
ter a great deal of publicly expressed discontent from ECB staff who com-
plained that it suffered from poor management, was too bureaucratic, and
failed to communicated with its employees (Financial Times 5 November
2003). In October 2003, the ECB approved internal reforms aimed at improv-
ing working conditions, communication with staff, and management train-
ing. A 2003 audit of the bank’s information technology services by McKinsey,
the consultancy group, found severe management failure in the IT depart-
ment’s project planning, causing heavy budget overruns and major delays
(ibid.). Trichet dedicated his first years as president to engineering reform
throughout the bank and, in IT, saw off strikes by staff, who were concerned
about the potential redundancies resulting from reorganization.
85
The European Central Bank: The Bank That Rules Europe?
86
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Conclusion
EMU embodies ‘the triumph of technocratic elitism over the idea of political
democracy’ (Dyson and Featherstone 1999: 801). The ECB can be said to be the
principal victor in terms of real power, determining most aspects of monetary
policy for the world’s second largest economic entity. The burgeoning research
and analytical capacity of the ECB has reinforced its power, in relation both to
European and national political officials and to the Eurosystem’s NCB. Cred-
ibility also brings power, and the ECB can be judged to have achieved a
considerable amount of credibility thanks to the consistency of its monetary
policy and its ability to adopt greater transparency in explaining this policy to
both financial markets and democratically elected officials.
The democratic legitimacy of the ECB remains contested by some politi-
cians. However, Governing Council members insist upon its legitimacy. They
argue that the ECB’s mandate was established by democratically elected gov-
ernments and is more tightly circumscribed than a dual mandate including
growth and employment alongside price stability; that public support for both
EMU and the goal of price stability remains high; and that the bank has been
accountable to democratically elected officials and the public—without com-
promising its independence—through the efforts of Executive Board members
to explain bank policies regularly to members of the European Parliament,
governments and the public in speeches, press conferences, and other public
appearances.
The title of this chapter makes direct reference to the title of a much earlier
work that focuses upon Bundesbank power (Marsh 1992). On 1 January 1999,
the ECB supplanted the Bundesbank as the leading central bank on the Euro-
pean continent. To the extent that we can claim that the ECB ‘rules’ Europe, it
does so differently from the Bundesbank in the era of the European Monetary
System. The ECB sets the interest rates for 15 member states and for states in
the Exchange-Rate Mechanism (ERM-2), as well as having a strong influence
on interest rates for those satellite economies whose currencies shadow the
euro (see the chapter by Umbach and Wessels). Yet, NCB governors participate
in the setting of these rates—which was certainly not the case prior to 1999,
when the Bundesbank was notoriously hostile to interest-rate coordination
and set rates to meet its statutory mandate of domestic price stability. Even
though the ECB’s rates might not be entirely appropriate to the economic
conditions of many individual Euro Area member states, they are not the
reflection of economic developments in a single member state. The ideational
power of the ECB is at least as great as that of the Bundesbank: the former is
the guardian of price stability in Eurosystem and one of the world’s most
visible promoters of the virtues of low inflation. The augmentation of the
ECB’s research capacity reinforces its ideational power, and it is supported
by the Eurosystem NCBs which all share the same mandate. However, the
87
The European Central Bank: The Bank That Rules Europe?
Bundesbank’s influence lay not only in its success in maintaining low inflation
but also, to a large extent, on the comparative size and strength of the German
economy. The ECB manages the monetary policy of a far larger economic
entity—clearly a source of its great clout both at home and abroad—but
the Euro Area is, in its great diversity, less economically successful than pre-
unification Germany, a fact that inevitably undermines the power of the ECB’s
anti-inflationary message.
This chapter has shown that the power of the ECB is limited in several
important respects. The resistance of member state governments limits the
ECB’s influence in European economic governance, national macroeconomic
policy, and prudential supervision. Despite the ECB’s important international
profile, EU member states are unlikely to modify its observer status in the IMF
and OECD. The resistance of Euro Area NCBs also prevents the extension
of ECB activities into several core central banking operations. International
developments—and notably the rise of China and India—will limit both the
relative economic importance of the Euro Area and, eventually, the import-
ance of the euro as an international reserve currency. Increasingly complicated
financial markets—notably the rise of derivatives and hedge funds—have
undermined the credibility of ECB monetary policy and will no doubt con-
tinue to do so.
88
Part II
Eurosystem ‘Insider’ Central Banks
This page intentionally left blank
4
National Banks of Belgium and the
Netherlands: Happy with the Euro
Ivo Maes and Amy Verdun
Financial integration and monetary union have affected the functions, struc-
tures, and powers of European central banks. The scope and content of central
bank policies have changed, as has the central focus of the policies. With the
creation of the European System of Central Banks (ESCB) and the Eurosystem,
European national central banks have become part of a collective system in
which monetary policy is set centrally by the Governing Council. The ESCB
consists of the European Central Bank and all the EU national central banks
(NCBs). The Eurosystem comprises the ECB and the NCBs of EU Member States
that have adopted the euro. Given that they are now part of a larger system that
sets monetary policy of the euro area, as such, the individual national central
banks of the Eurosystem have no sovereignty to set independent national
monetary policies as had been the case in the past.
In this chapter, the cases of the National Bank of Belgium (NBB) and De
Nederlandsche Bank (DNB) are analysed with a view to what has changed in
these central banks of medium-sized European Union member states since the
onset of Economic and Monetary Union (EMU). Both central banks played a
significant role in the creation of EMU. The National Bank of Belgium played a
pace-setting role in the EMU process, whilst De Nederlandsche Bank played the
role of gate-keeper (Maes and Verdun 2005). Since the start of EMU, how have
these roles of these two central banks changed, both within their domestic
context and within the Eurosystem? The core functions of a central bank—
monetary policy, issuing banknotes, managing the gold and foreign-exchange
Ivo Maes wrote the section on the National Bank of Belgium and Amy Verdun the one on de
Nederlandsche Bank. The authors would like to thank all those who contributed to this project,
especially Kenneth Dyson and Martin Marcussen, the participants at the Cardiff EU-Consent
workshop, 2007 UACES (Portsmouth), and British Academy/EU-Consent conference. Amy
Verdun thanks some officials and the services of De Nederlandsche Bank, especially C.C.A. van
den Berg. The usual disclaimer applies.
91
National Banks of Belgium and the Netherlands: Happy with the Euro
reserves, and organizing the flow of payments—now take place within a Euro-
pean framework, the Eurosystem, in which the National Bank of Belgium and
De Nederlandsche Bank fully participate. Besides their role in the European
context both central banks also play an important role in their countries’
domestic socio-economic affairs. In this way, they are now ‘hybrid’ institutions,
performing both European and national functions. Both the anticipation of the
creation of EMU and actual experience of EMU led to changes in the Belgian
and Dutch central banks. Increasingly, there is a growing attention towards
financial stability, in line with the globalization and growing complexity of
financial markets and institutions. The National Bank of Belgium and De
Nederlandsche Bank are evolving towards more knowledge-oriented tasks and
are putting more emphasis on cost control and modern management tech-
niques. In sum, these two central banks adjusted their objectives and organiza-
tion following the creation of EMU. More than before, they focus on policies
that support monetary and financial stability.
92
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
the second President of the European Commission), played a crucial role. Later,
Rey chaired the Monetary Policy Sub-Committee of the European Monetary
Institute (EMI), which prepared the Euro Area’s single monetary policy.
With its support of European monetary integration the National Bank of
Belgium was in line with Belgium’s traditional pro-European orientation (Maes
2002). However, there were also differences of opinion at the National Bank of
Belgium. Some took a more pragmatic view, regarding Europe as primarily a
framework for the stable exchange-rate policy, to ensure discipline in the econ-
omy. For others, who were more in favour of a federal Europe, the real goal was a
common European monetary policy, both to secure increased influence over the
monetary policy stance and as a step towards political union.
The National Bank of Belgium influenced the EMU process primarily via two
channels: the Belgian authorities and the central banks of the European Union
(Smets, Michielsen, and Maes 2003). At the Belgian level, the National Bank of
Belgium helped to formulate Belgium’s ideas and positions. Its expertise was a
particularly important asset. The National Bank of Belgium also played a role in
the world of the European central banks. This was particularly in evidence at
times when the Governor was chair of the Committee of EC Central Bank
Governors, or when representatives of the National Bank of Belgium chaired a
committee or working group (cf. supra).
From a Weak Currency to the Anchoring of the Belgian Franc to the D-Mark
For the National Bank of Belgium, the Snake and the EMS were the beacons
of monetary and foreign-exchange policy (Buyst, Maes, and Pluym 2005). It
was hoped that a European anchor would have the effect of imposing discipline
on domestic economic policy and wage-setting. At first that seemed a vain
hope.
Although the early 1970s were a boom period, the seeds of Belgium’s eco-
nomic problems were sown in this period. Not only was inflation gathering
speed, nominal wages were also clearly rising faster than prices. The budgetary
situation in Belgium was also worsening. In 1981, the public deficit totalled
more than 15 per cent of Gross Domestic Product (GDP). This led to discussions
between the National Bank of Belgium and the Finance Ministry on ways of
financing the deficit. Whilst the National Bank of Belgium was sharply critical
of fiscal policy, in practice it often consented to a monetary financing of the
deficit. Moreover, the government intervened in interest-rate policy (Buyst,
Maes, and Pluym 2005). Thus, in September 1979, the government commis-
sioner exercised his right to suspend an increase in the discount rate, intended
by the Council of Regency (the highest decision-making body, composed of the
governor, the directors, and 10 regents) of the National Bank of Belgium. One
week later, when the situation in the foreign-exchange market had not
improved, the minister consented.
93
National Banks of Belgium and the Netherlands: Happy with the Euro
94
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
During the 1990s, the independence of the National Bank of Belgium was not
only reinforced through the more ambitious exchange-rate objective. There
were also significant reforms, in line with a growing Europeanization of the
National Bank of Belgium.
Belgium was in a unique position in the EU, since the National Bank of
Belgium had the power to determine the interest rate on short-term treasury
paper, albeit after ‘consultation’ with the Finance Ministry; the responsibil-
ities of the monetary and fiscal authorities were intertwined. In January 1991,
the money market and the instruments of monetary policy underwent fun-
damental reform, thereby ending the intermingling of the National Bank of
Belgium’s responsibilities with those of the Finance Ministry. The reform
made the issue of treasury certificates the exclusive domain of the Treasury.
Auction techniques were introduced. Henceforward, the market would deter-
mine the interest rate on treasury paper. As in other EU states, the National
Bank of Belgium’s new range of monetary policy instruments was based on its
function as the bank of banks. The National Bank of Belgium influenced
market interest rates indirectly, via the volume of its lending to financial
institutions and the interest rate charged. The state’s credit line was signifi-
cantly reduced. Furthermore, the state could only take out new loans in
foreign currencies if that did not conflict with monetary and exchange-rate
policy.
During the 1990s, the statutes of the National Bank of Belgium were further
adjusted in line with the provisions of the Maastricht Treaty. The law of 22
March 1993 granted the National Bank of Belgium greater autonomy in the
conduct of monetary policy. Limits were imposed on the supervisory powers of
the Finance Minister and the government commissioner. In addition, the
National Bank of Belgium was absolutely prohibited from lending money to
the government. Pursuant to the law of 22 February 1998, the basic law of the
National Bank of Belgium was further amended, introducing the principle that
the National Bank of Belgium formed an integral part of the ESCB.
In Belgium, preparations for the introduction of the euro were made by the
‘General Commission for the euro’, which was created in order to prepare
the introduction of the euro in Belgium. It had two tasks. It had to encourage
the various sectors of the economy to prepare for the advent of the euro, and it
had to monitor the cohesion of the measures in order to prevent the adoption of
conflicting strategies. The first General Commissioner, who was at the head of
the General Commission, was National Bank of Belgium director Guy Quaden.
When he was appointed Governor in March 1999, a few weeks after the intro-
duction of the new currency, he was succeeded by National Bank of Belgium
director Jan Smets. The National Bank of Belgium also provided the secretariat for
the General Commission.
The start of stage three of EMU also brought the abolition of the Belgian–
Luxembourg monetary association. From then on, Luxembourg had its own
95
National Banks of Belgium and the Netherlands: Happy with the Euro
central bank, the Banque Centrale du Luxembourg, which plays a full part in
the Eurosystem. The Luxembourg branch of the National Bank of Belgium was
taken over by the Luxembourg central bank.
On 1 January 2002, the euro banknotes were introduced in the 12 states of
the Euro Area. It was a logistical operation without precedent in monetary and
financial history. Since the National Bank of Belgium has its own printing
works, it printed banknotes which were placed in circulation on that date. In
total 550 million notes were printed. After a brief dual circulation period, the
Belgian franc notes ceased to be legal tender on 28 February 2002.
96
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
97
National Banks of Belgium and the Netherlands: Happy with the Euro
98
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
loss of monetary policy credibility in the case of a bank failure, have lost
importance.
The start of the third stage of EMU coincided with an important renewal of
the Executive Board of the National Bank of Belgium (in March 1999). Gov-
ernor Alfons Verplaetse retired and was replaced by director Guy Quaden. In
2000, Governor Quaden launched a strategic management exercise which
was triggered by the fundamental changes brought about by the single cur-
rency, as well as the spread of new information and communication technolo-
gies and the concentration in the commercial financial sector. The exercise led
to a strengthening of the National Bank of Belgium’s research capacities and
communication capabilities, as well as cost control and modern management
techniques.
Traditionally, the National Bank of Belgium devoted much attention to
macro-economic research. As already mentioned, to participate fully in the
Eurosystem, the National Bank of Belgium strengthened its research capacities.
Moreover, as a monetary authority it plays a key role in the definition of macro-
economic policy in Belgium. Indeed, the National Bank of Belgium’s role as an
advisor on economic policy has an institutional basis. In the first instance, this
role is expressed in the Council of Regency, where the social partners are also
represented. The Council of Regency’s discussions, which are based on reports
prepared by the National Bank of Belgium, help to achieve social consensus
in Belgium. With EMU, a crucial issue for the National Bank of Belgium is
the coherence between the single monetary policy and economic policy in
Belgium.
An important result of the strategic revision was also the strengthening of the
communication capabilities of the National Bank of Belgium. In 2000, a Com-
munications Service was created, which reports directly to the Governor. It
included also the museum, which was revamped and extended.
It is also noteworthy that during the final three decades of the twentieth
century, the National Bank of Belgium was entrusted with various tasks which
cannot be classed as strictly central bank functions. Indeed, they fall outside
the domain of the ESCB. The reasons are related both to the competences of the
National Bank of Belgium and to the weaknesses of other institutions in the
Belgian state. Most of these functions concern the collection and circulation
of information. The range of functions performed by the National Bank of
Belgium is larger and more diverse than that of most other central banks in
the Eurosystem. Thus, the National Bank of Belgium is a key player in the
provision and analysis of micro-economic information. The law of 24 March
1978 gave the National Bank of Belgium the task of establishing the Central
Balance Sheet Office, whose function is to collect and publish the annual
accounts of firms. The Central Office for Credits to Enterprises, established in
1967, collects data on lending in the Belgian economy. In the 1990s, the statis-
tical functions expanded as, at the request of the legislature, the National Bank
99
National Banks of Belgium and the Netherlands: Happy with the Euro
of Belgium took over a substantial part of the activities of the National Statistical
Institute, in particular the compilation of the national accounts.
Furthermore, cost control and modern management methods became more
important. For instance, the agency network was greatly reduced. Of the 43
provincial branches, 20 were closed between 1974 and 1984. In 1999, a second
streamlining operation was launched. Since March 2005, the National Bank of
Belgium has only seven establishments outside Brussels. Also, modern manage-
ment methods were introduced, like master plans and a stronger emphasis on
skills management.
There have also been considerable changes in the workforce. The number of
employees peaked on 1 January 1987 at a nominal total of nearly 3,300 units.
After that the size of the workforce declined sharply. Yet the advent of monetary
union did not lead to a significant reduction in traditional activities, whilst new
tasks were added. Thanks to productivity increases and restructuring, the work-
force contracted. On 1 January 2008 the nominal total had fallen to around
2,250 units, a decrease of nearly one third compared to 1987. This was accom-
plished without dismissals, but recruitment became very selective. In line with
the trend towards more knowledge-based tasks, the proportion of staff in
managerial and supervisory positions rose from 11 per cent in 1970 to over 20
per cent in 2008.
De Nederlandsche Bank
De Nederlandsche Bank (DNB) has been the central bank of the Netherlands
since 1814, making it one of the older central banks in Europe. Throughout this
period its role changed from being commercially involved to serving as a public
institution, completely abandoning its commercial activities and acting instead
as lender of last resort, and dealing with its three core tasks: managing currency
circulation, formulating and implementing monetary policy, and banking
supervision (Vanthoor 2005). European integration has always been part and
parcel of the modern DNB, and when possible the DNB took action to support
the European integration objective.
100
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
101
National Banks of Belgium and the Netherlands: Happy with the Euro
Finance were concerned that, once EMU was fully operational, some states
might return to their old practices of high public borrowing and high rates of
inflation. The Dutch monetary authorities were among those most supportive
of these German concerns and thus spoke up about the concerns that the
Germans had. As was already touched upon above, the Dutch–German rela-
tionship had been carefully crafted throughout the 15 years prior to signing of
the Treaty on European Union (Szász 1988, 2001). Also, the German govern-
ment had to perform a careful balancing act between being pro-active on what
it considered important, and not seeming to be too dominant within the
broader European context. In particular, the DNB supported the Stability and
Growth Pact, which both the DNB and the Bundesbank considered to be a
crucial instrument in securing stability in EMU after the adoption of EMU
(Heipertz and Verdun 2004, 2005).
The strong record of the Dutch central bank (DNB 1997) and its close rela-
tions to the German Bundesbank and the stability culture, put the then Presi-
dent of the Dutch central bank, Willem Duisenberg, in an excellent position to
be put forward as the first President of the European Central Bank. Duisenberg
personified the new institution in more than one way (De Haas and Van
Lotringen 2003). He had been an advocate of European monetary integration
since the early days and had ample international experience. Duisenberg had
worked with the International Monetary Fund from 1965–9, and then for a year
as an advisor to the Director of DNB. Thereafter he was appointed Professor of
Macroeconomics at the University of Amsterdam. He left academia to become
the Finance Minister in the social–democratic government (1973–7). These
were turbulent years for the Netherlands. After his years in the political arena
Duisenberg spent a few years in the private sector as vice-president of the
Rabobank (a Dutch commercial bank). In 1982 he became the President of De
Nederlandsche Bank, a post he kept until he left the position to head the
European Monetary Institute in July 1997 and then the European Central
Bank from its first day in June 1998.
During his years as President of the Dutch central bank Duisenberg managed
to secure a stable exchange rate to the D-Mark and to keep inflation rates low. As
part of this strategy he closely followed German monetary policies. But, con-
trary to many other countries in the 1990s, the Dutch–German exchange rate
did not come under pressure at any time, and the Dutch–German exchange rate
stayed stable when others were stretched to a +15 per cent band in 1993. Since
the start of the idea of creating EMU, the DNB worked hard to make sure that
EMU would be based on the same firm principles the DNB had itself worked
long and hard on to achieve.
In 1991 De Nederlandsche Bank’s three main tasks were managing currency
circulation, formulating and implementing monetary policy, and banking super-
vision. As DNB looked towards a future role in the Eurosystem where monetary
policy would be set centrally, it realized that changes were needed to ensure that
102
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
it was capable of effectively supporting this ECB monetary policy and of sec-
uring the overall financial stability of the Netherlands in this new context.
In preparation for entry into stage three of EMU, the adoption of the euro,
and become integrated into the Eurosystem and the ESCB, a few changes were
made. First of all, the Dutch parliament passed a change to the Bank Act. The
Dutch central bank had effectively operated as an independent central bank,
even though, formally, the Minister of Finance had the power to instruct the
DNB (in Dutch ‘aanwijzingsrecht’). But this power had been rarely used (e.g. in
1945); indeed, according to the new Bank Act of 1948, it was to be used only in
ultimum remedium—as a last resort, which never happened after 1948 (Vanthoor
2004: 164–7, 201–11). In 1998 the Bank Act was subsequently changed so as to
remove this power to comply with the requirement of the ESCB that the
national central banks have to be completely independent.
In 2002 another important change was made. Pensions and Insurance Super-
visory Authority (Pensioen- en Verzekeringskamer ‘PVK’), which traditionally
had been a separate institution, was transferred to DNB, which had a major
impact on the institutional structure of DNB. A new Act was put in place to
replace the older one (which had been in place for 50 years). In 2004 the merger
between DNB and the Pensions and Insurance Supervisory Authority was
complete.
Other restructuring that took place in light of joining EMU included the
closing of seven branches of DNB—a decision taken in 1996 leaving only the
main office and four branches open (Apeldoorn, Eindhoven, Hoogeveen, and
Wassenaar, DNB 1999: 147). The branches had as one of their tasks to verify the
authenticity and the state of banknotes. Following a decision in 2003 to dele-
gate some of those tasks to commercial banks, DNB was witnessing a downward
trend in the number of banknotes the branches were checking—still as much as
1.8 billion notes in 2004, whereas this number was down to 1.1 million notes in
2007 (DNB 2008a: 95). Given the lower workload, three of the four branches
closed on 1 July 2007 and with Apeldoorn (the former seat of the PVK) due to
close in 2010, only the headquarters in Amsterdam will remain (DNB 2008a:
120). In the years to come the DNB will still check between 600 and 800 million
banknotes per year mainly to intercept counterfeits; the banking sector will
examine and re-circulate the rest. Even though there was a reduction in the
workload over this period regarding checking for counterfeits, DNB expects a
higher workload when second generation banknotes will be introduced. In
these early years DNB would still determine itself from which press to order
banknotes (5 euro banknotes from France: Oberthur technologies; the 20 euro
bills came from the Dutch printer Joh. Enschede, DNB 2008a: 95). DNB states in
its 2007 annual report that it is expected that banknotes will be centrally
ordered by the ECB in the years to come. Furthermore, a reorganization of the
divisions and number of staff in each division was reviewed and changes were
made to reflect the new reality of EMU.
103
National Banks of Belgium and the Netherlands: Happy with the Euro
Once a member of the Eurosystem, the Dutch central bank became embedded
into this new structure and became responsible for some tasks. An example of
this joint sharing of tasks is the management of official external reserves. In
1999 part of the reserves of national central banks was transferred to the ECB. In
that year the DNB transferred 5 per cent of gold and reserves (2 million euro).
These reserves belong to the ECB but are managed by the national central
banks, based on instructions and rules set by the ECB (DNB 2000a: 179). In
addition, the Dutch central bank still holds reserves that have remained its
property. Here too, ECB rules and regulations are in place as to how the DNB
may manage these reserves: in some cases, it needs to ask prior approval from
the ECB for certain investments (DNB 2000a: 179). Finally, there are some tasks
of the DNB that have not changed because of its becoming a member of the
Eurosystem. For instance, in banking supervision, the DNB is responsible to the
national Minister of Finance.
The Bank Act of 1998 also changed some aspects of the checks and balances.
Similar to what has been envisaged in the Treaty on European Union, the
President of De Nederlandsche Bank is responsible for presenting an annual
report, which is subsequently discussed in parliament. Furthermore, the Bank
Act envisages that either of the two chambers of parliament could request to
meet with the DNB President to be given information about DNB policies and
decisions. However, the President of DNB remains independent at all times. In
the context of monetary policy setting, the DNB President is not obliged to
inform the House of Parliament whether he voted and or how he voted in
monetary policy decisions taken in Frankfurt [see Bank Act 1998, Article 18 (2)
that stipulates that the President may be asked to provide information without,
however, compromising the confidentiality of the monetary policy decisions].
When the Bank Act was revised, it was seen as very important to recognize the
historic tradition of the DNB’s integral role in Dutch society. A Bank Council
(‘Bankraad’) continued to perform this task. The members of the Bank Council
are appointed for a period of four years and represent the composition of Dutch
society. Its function is to be a sounding board for the DNB’s Governing Board.
Another aspect of embedding the DNB in society was the regular communica-
tion between its President and the Minister of Finance. For many years the two
have had weekly luncheons in which financial and economic matters are
discussed. Article 18 of the Bank Act envisages that the Bank and the Minister
should maintain regular contact. Thus the weekly lunches were kept intact so as
to ensure this regular communication (DNB 2000a: 180).
Discussions on corporate governance in the Netherlands led to a law named
after the chairperson of the committee (Morris Tabaksblat) who oversaw the
formulation of a new law. The so-called ‘Code Tabaksblat’ (Dutch Corporate
Governance Code) consisted of 21 principles of sound corporate governance
and 113 best practices. After having been discussed by parliament it was for-
mally adopted on 9 December 2003. The code stipulates that, as of 2004, all
104
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
companies that are listed on the Dutch stock exchange have to provide details
on their corporate governance in their annual report. The Dutch central bank,
of course, formally fell outside this law as it is not a listed company. Further-
more it felt that its Bank Act of 1998 for the most part already adhered to the
principles of good governance and best practices. Nevertheless, DNB decided to
change its statutes so as to reflect the Code Tabaksblat. These changes to the
statutes included among other things that the Supervisory Board will periodic-
ally review its own performance as well as that of the Governing Board; that the
Supervisory Board will draw up a profile of its size and composition; and that
the profile of the Supervisory Board will in due course be advertised on the
website. On 13 March 2007 DNB’s statutes were adjusted to reflect the stipula-
tions of the Code Tabaksblat. The annual report of 2003 for the first time
included a chapter (albeit an extremely short—two paged—chapter) on ‘cor-
porate governance’. Every annual report since has included a substantial chap-
ter on corporate governance, reporting on best practices, cost performance,
meeting targets and objectives, etc. Many of the items reported in this ‘corpor-
ate governance’ chapter of the annual reports conform to what is often cap-
tured under the header of ‘New Public Management’ practices. To give an
example, the annual report reporting over the year 2007 indicated the cost
target for expenses on personnel as having been 167.2 million euro, whereas
the actual expenses had been 168.4 million (up from the 162.7 in 2005 and
168.0 in 2004). Elsewhere in the report DNB reported on how in its recent
assessment the 2004 merger had met the objective of enhancing efficiency by
cost saving of 25 million euro (DNB 2008a: 29). One of the objectives had been
to keep full-time equivalent (FTE) staff of the new merged DNB on or below the
level of the DNB prior to the merger, which has been achieved. Back in 2001
personnel in both organizations were 1,683 FTE in DNB and PVK 177 which
changed to DNB 1,672 and PVK 231 in 2003. By the end of 2004 after the two
institutions merged the total FTE for the new DNB was 1,774. Since that date
there has been a gradual decline in FTE: 1,685 in 2005; 1,630 in 2006; 1,566 in
2007.
In its aim to increase transparency, DNB, besides publishing an annual report,
also issues quarterly bulletins and a statistical bulletin, as well as a host of other
publications (including a laymen publication ‘DNB Magazine’). In 2000, the
use of external communications was revised to reach out more to the general
public (e.g. increased use of the website first created in 1997—completely
revamped in 2004).
105
National Banks of Belgium and the Netherlands: Happy with the Euro
policy decisions). The DNB was quick to note that, contrary to what the Dutch
media suggested, it did not completely lose or transfer sovereignty. Indeed, as
one interview partner put it: ‘Before EMU we were just following policies made
in Germany; after we joined the ESCB we once again became part of the group
of people that were setting monetary policy’ (personal interview with DNB
official, Amsterdam, August 2006). In fact, the Dutch central bank had been
successfully shadowing German monetary policies and thus, effectively, had
not used its national sovereignty to set independent monetary policies (see also
Wellink 2008). However, the DNB president Nout Wellink takes part in the
deliberations and voting of the governing council that sets monetary policy. In
this context, the President Wellink has been stressing the importance of price
stability and a stability culture in monetary and budgetary policy, very much
following in the footsteps of ECB president Duisenberg. President Wellink has
continued along the lines set out in the earlier years as to the direction of
monetary policy for the Euro Area. Of course, since entering stage three of
EMU the Dutch central bank president has one vote on the governing council,
whereas in the 1970s, 1980s, and 1990s the Dutch central bank president
mostly followed German monetary policies without having a say over it.
The Treaty on European Union stipulates that monetary policy is a common
responsibility of the European System of Central Banks. Following the prin-
ciples of the Treaty, the DNB defined its new function as support for the
monetary policy by providing background information and statistics; in other
words, an accurate assessment of market sentiments and expectations
(Vanthoor 2005: 326). National central banks carry out a number of tasks that
are not necessarily part of the EU Treaty. In some states these tasks are the
responsibility of an independent regulatory agency that may or may not be the
central bank. The Bank Act of 1998 (Articles 3 and 4) captured the tasks of DNB
as follows: define and implement monetary policy; conduct foreign-exchange
operations and manage official foreign reserves; provide for the circulation of
money (banknotes); promote the smooth operation of the payment system;
contribute to the supervision of credit institutions and the stability of the
financial system; collecting statistical data and producing statistics. Let us
bunch a few of these tasks together and discuss them in turn: (1) to ensure
financial stability; (2) banking supervision; and (3) economic advisor to the
government. Changes have occurred in each of these areas.
The EU treaty stipulates that the ESCB shall facilitate the conduct of policies
by the authorities related to the stability of the financial system. These author-
ities are still predominantly national, but the ESCB can provide information,
best practices, and networking.
The DNB has responded to the new monetary environment by focusing more
attention on this aspect of its role. For instance, it produces a biannual Over-
view of Financial Stability (OFS) in the Netherlands (see DNB 2008b). However,
many of the changes in this role relate directly to policies set out by the ECB,
106
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
whereas others are the result of developments in the financial markets. Recent
developments in the real economy suggest that there has recently been less
supervision by central banks (than before the start of EMU) because in recent
years much of the liquidity creation stays outside the control of central banks.
The system therefore is more vulnerable than before to stress. To prepare itself
for possible future shocks, the DNB and the Belgian Banking Finance and
Security Commission and the Belgian central bank signed a memorandum of
understanding in 2006 that envisages close coordination in case of a financial
crisis. Likewise in February 2007 DNB and the Dutch minister of Finance agreed
to consult one another in case of a financial crisis (DNB 2007: 121). For
example, during the 2007–8 credit crunch the DNB took rapid action. It shar-
pened its control on liquidity (DNB 2008a: 61). Even though there was no risk
of a similar development in the Netherlands (there is no sub-prime market for
mortgages, by law, mortgages may not be more than 30% of the debt of a
household, and only 1% of households have a mortgage interest rate set for
less than five years, DNB 2008a: 63), the Dutch financial sector still experienced
some of the fall out of the sub-prime crises, as some banks and investors had bad
debt.
In the Netherlands banking supervision has been the responsibility of the
central bank. The creation of the ESCB was no reason to change this role.
Although the start of EMU had virtually no impact, a number of changes to
banking supervision have been made related to EU directives (Vanthoor 2006:
340). Two directives came into force in July 2002: the Act on the Supervision of
the Credit System (which covers the issuing of electronic money since 1 July
2002); and the Money Transactions Offices Act (simultaneously repealing the
1995 Exchange Offices Act) (DNB 2003: 109). In 2002 a crucial change was
made. The Pensions and Insurance Supervisory Authority, which traditionally
had been a separate institution, was transferred to the DNB, producing a major
impact on the institutional structure of DNB. A new Act was put in place to
replace the older one (which had been in place for 50 years). The new Act
envisages that the Pensions and Insurance Supervisory Authority become part
of the DNB and the new merged organization be named DNB. The latter
supervises the entire financial sector (including pensions, insurance, collective
investment schemes, exchange offices, and the like, Vanthoor 2006: 340–1). In
2004 this merger was completed. The aim of the merger was to reinforce the
grip on financial stability, and to enhance the efficiency and effectiveness of
supervision.
Since the creation of EMU the Dutch central bank has been more actively
promoting its ability to comment on the state of the Dutch economy and on
the policies of the government. It is placing more emphasis on research (cf.
DNB 2000b: 25, 29). Also, it has been more focal on socio-economic consult-
ation committees and been more outspoken in the media. Furthermore, the
traditional weekly ‘lunches’ of the President of DNB and the Minister of Finance
107
National Banks of Belgium and the Netherlands: Happy with the Euro
have kept their important place. The President informs the Minister of Finance
about strategic direction of the ECB but they also have conversations about the
policy mix of budgetary and fiscal policies on the one hand and monetary
policy on the other. They also discuss the situation in the financial system
(including the payment system). DNB President also has a seat on advice
committees such as the Social Economic Council in which employers and
trade unions are also represented and that gives advice to the government on
socio-economic policy matters. DNB President Nout Wellink also has a seat in
the Council on Economic Issues (Raad voor Economische Aangelegenheden,
REA). Overall the role of DNB has not so much contracted but rather changed.
In 2007, the so-called ‘Holland Financial Centre’ (HFC) was created, in which
DNB actively participates (DNB 2008a: 61). HFC is an organization that seeks to
strengthen an international open financial sector in the Netherlands, whilst
maintaining international best practices and keeping costs under control (DNB
2008a: 62). The DNB also seeks to increase transparency in its operations.
Conclusion
108
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
having a voice in the voting, these two actors have, in a certain sense, gained
power.
Furthermore, the National Bank of Belgium and De Nederlandsche Bank play
an important role in their respective states’ socio-economic affairs, in line with
their expertise and their special place between the public sector and the finan-
cial world, and in providing both a national and European anchorage. So, both
central banks have become ‘hybrid’ institutions, performing both European
and national functions. Furthermore, the National Bank of Belgium and De
Nederlandsche Bank are evolving towards more knowledge-oriented tasks and
are putting more emphasis on cost control and modern management tech-
niques, a general convergence among central banks.
A noteworthy area is financial stability, where both the National Bank of
Belgium and De Nederlandsche Bank have been given more responsibilities,
something that contrasts with the evolution in certain other states like
Germany and the United Kingdom. So, regarding the responsibilities with
respect to financial stability, Belgium and the Netherlands show that there is
no convergence among the European central banks.
109
This page intentionally left blank
5
Bank of France: The Challenge
of Escaping Politicization
David Howarth
Prior to 1994, the Bank of France could be described as the quiet giant of
European central banking. Most comparative studies of central bank independ-
ence rank the pre-1994 Bank of France as one of the more dependent in its
relationship to government. While responsible for the range of operations
typical of central banks and exerting potentially considerable influence on
policy making, the Bank was very much in the policy making shadow of the
Treasury direction of the Ministry of Finance, which held ultimate control over
most aspects of monetary policy and considerable influence in prudential
supervision (Goodman 1992; Prate 1987). Establishing its subordinate position
in republican policy making, the 1936 and 1945 acts that nationalized the Bank
placed it under the ‘tutelle’ of the Prime Minister’s office. While in a weak
position in relation to the Treasury, the pre-independence Bank and its Gover-
nors firmly asserted the importance of defending the value of the national
currency during periods of strong inflationary pressure and refused to accede
to certain demands that touched upon the limited range of areas under the
Bank’s control according to legislation (see Prate 1987 for examples). The
Treasury had direct say over monetary policy and dominated credit provision
until the financial market liberalization that took place from 1985 onwards. The
end of the encadrement du credit system—by which the state directed credit
provision—and liberalization enhanced the relative power of the Bank by
increasing the importance of interest-rate policy, over which the Bank had
considerable influence by virtue of its unrivalled capacity to monitor French
money supply and inflation (Goodman 1992).
Europeanization has had a significant impact on the power of the Bank of
France since the 1970s. The operation of the Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM)
of the European Monetary System (EMS) and the strong (stable) franc policy of
the second half of the 1980s and the 1990s reinforced the importance of
111
Bank of France: The Challenge of Escaping Politicization
112
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
value of the currency (Koch 1983; Mamou 1988; Patat and Lutfalla 1986; Prate
1987; Valance 1996) and occasionally did so in very stern terms. Yet between
1944 and 1994, the Bank Governor rarely intervened publicly in economic and
monetary policy and, when he did, could be sorely rebuked and even replaced,
as in 1974 (Prate 1987: 210–11). The precise nature of government control and
the legal status of the Bank were not defined in the laws on nationalization.
Assertions of autonomy depended upon the personalities involved and the
degree to which governments diverged from the goal of monetary stability. A
January 1973 law clarified Bank powers and granted it greater scope to modify
its monetary mechanisms. The 1973 reform set out certain basic principles,
allowing the Bank’s General Council free rein in their practical application.
However, the reform did not eliminate ultimate State control over monetary
policy. Various requests from the Bank of France to gain greater autonomy were
opposed by governments and the Treasury (Prate 1987). Pre-1994 relations with
the Treasury and debates on monetary policy have been frequently described as
difficult, with the Treasury maintaining the final say and considerable influence
(Koch 1983; Mamou 1988; Prate 1987).
There was strong political opposition to independence right up to the signing
of the Maastricht Treaty in 1991. None of the political parties supported the
concept of central bank independence (Balleix-Banerjee 1999). Yet, public
opinion was generally in favour of the EMU project and the transfer of monet-
ary policy to the European level. The prioritization of European objectives
resulted in French government support for EMU and tolerance of central bank
independence. In the context of global ideological trends in favour of inde-
pendence, EMU created an historic opportunity to overcome strong domestic
political and institutional resistance. Moreover, the rapid move to independ-
ence at the start of Stage II of the EMU project (1 January 1994) was justified as
building confidence in the franc in the context of record levels of speculation,
not the desirability of independence per se.
The support threshold necessary to pass legislation on independence was
raised even further because the French Constitutional Council initially blocked
legislation in 1993 on the basis of a constitutional provision that effectively
prevented the delegation of policy-making powers to an independent body. The
support of three-fifths of the members of both chambers of parliament was also
necessary to modify the constitution to achieve independence. Moreover, two
core elements of EMU found in the Maastricht Treaty that block governments
from soliciting the central bank on monetary policy and establish price stability
as the primary objective of monetary policy were removed from the French law
on independence.1 They were successfully challenged by parliamentarians in
the Constitutional Court on the grounds that they contradicted the constitu-
tional principle that the government defines the policy of the country. None-
theless, the real effect of removing these core elements of the EMU bargain from
the French law was negligible because they applied by virtue of the provisions
113
Bank of France: The Challenge of Escaping Politicization
found in the Maastricht Treaty. In the Monetary and Financial Code, which
replaced the 1993 law at the start of 2001, the wording of the Statute of the ECB
and the ESCB was incorporated and the goal of price stability established as
primary for the Bank of France. As with the ECB, no requirement of transpar-
ency was imposed upon the Bank of France. Article 3 of the 1993 law grants the
CPM the power to determine the conditions according to which its minutes
could be made public. The non-renewable, nine-year fixed terms of the six
external CPM members and the renewable, six-year fixed terms of the Governor
and deputy governors (with an age limit of 65) provided a much stronger
guarantee of personal independence than was previously the case—when no
guaranteed fixed term was provided.2
Despite the broad support for the EMU project in the French political class and
consistent public support for EMU, leading French government and opposition
politicians have refused to desist from politicizing monetary policy. From early
1994, Government politicians have repeatedly ‘scapegoated’ the Bank of France
and then the ECB for French economic difficulties—worsened by high interest
rates and then a strong euro. A surprising number of both government and
opposition politicians have been persistent in their challenge to ECB goals and
independence, particularly during electoral periods. Several recent examples
can be provided. As Finance Minister, Sarkozy, called for the ECB to adopt a
Federal Reserve–style target that includes economic growth (Financial Times, 11
June 2004), comments that he repeated as presidential candidate3 and then
President. Proposal 89 of Ségolène Royal’s 2007 Socialist Party presidential
electoral programme called for the inclusion of an employment creation ob-
jective in the ECB’s statute.4 In December 2006, when criticizing the ECB’s
decision to raise its interest rate, Royal insisted that the Bank be ‘submitted to
political decisions’ because it is not its job ‘to order [commander] the future of
our economies’.5
114
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
115
116
Table 5.1. Appointments to the Bank of France’s Conseil de la politique monétaire (1994–2007) and Comité Monétaire (2007–present)
*
This is an approximate, unscientific, figure based on a consideration of the members’ professional careers.
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
The Bank as the Public Defender of Sound Money’ and Structural Reform
Prior to independence, Bank of France governors were known for their criticism
of government policy, especially during the Fourth Republic. However, most
refrained from commenting publicly on government policy-making. Following
independence, the Bank had to accommodate itself to a more active and public
role in promoting a ‘stability culture’ in France which is one of the clearest
expressions of increased bank power since 1994. Governor Trichet made several
117
Bank of France: The Challenge of Escaping Politicization
118
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
The Bank of France holds all the responsibilities typical of national central
banks in addition to several less typical or atypical roles. Since 1999, the Bank
ensures the smooth operation of the payments system and the security of
financial transactions; monitors the security of the banking system and the
stability of the financial markets; conducts bank inspections; runs the commit-
tee responsible for granting licenses to new credit institutions and allowing
bank mergers; contributes to the drafting of regulations on credit institutions;
collects and analyses French monetary, financial, and economic data, including
balance of payments data; produces three annual growth and inflation fore-
casts; manages French exchange reserves, including gold; and provides banking
services to individual clients. Independence and EMU have had only marginal
impact on these core responsibilities of the Bank. The services of the Bank—
notably the Macroeconomic Studies directorate—provide the Governor with
quality expert advice on the state of the national and international economy
and price developments. Since 1999, they do so to enable him to make compe-
tent recommendations on Euro Area monetary policy. The Bank also has a
range of atypical roles, two of which it has developed or been assigned since
1999. It provides—uniquely in the Eurosystem—a port of entry to non-EU
banks that want to set up euro-accounts; and it provides advice on personal
debt management.
Prudential Supervision
The Bank of France has long been the centre of intelligence in the French state
on the national banking sector and the financial markets. Prior to 1994, the
Treasury’s control over prudential supervision—via the Banking Commission
chaired by the Governor of the Bank of France but under the ‘tutelle’ or control
of the Treasury—rested on expertise within the Bank. The latter provided most
of the salaried staff to the Banking Commission on temporary secondment
(approximately 400 officials at any time) and most of the detailed information
about the banking sector by carrying out operational supervision. In 1994, the
autonomy of the Banking Commission from the government was established
in law, while the Treasury’s influence was retained through a single vote on the
Banking Commission’s governing board of seven members (five of which are
nominated by the Minister of Finance). In terms of the day-to-day operation of
banking supervision, little changed because of Bank of France independence.
However, the elimination of the Treasury’s ‘tutelle’ ensured the reinforcement of
the Governor’s leadership position as Commission president with a deciding vote.
This leadership role has been seen in dealing with major problems in the
French banking sector, as in the difficulties at Société Général of unprecedented
losses caused by a single trader. In January 2008, the head of the bank, Daniel
119
Bank of France: The Challenge of Escaping Politicization
Bouton, met with Christian Noyer who, in effect, chaired a secret crisis com-
mittee that also included the head of the Financial Market Authority (Gérard
Rameix) to decide how to deal with the massive fraud in the bank and when to
make the information public. For a period of five days (19–23 January), in his
capacity as President of the Banking Commission and Governor, Noyer dis-
cussed the difficulties with Bouton and Rameix without informing the govern-
ment (let alone other members of the Banking Commission). Despite the Bank’s
long-standing role in prudential supervision, prior to independence the Governor
never played such a central role in the management of a major banking crisis.
Some (Cour des Comptes 1996) see the continued influence of the Ministry of
Finance, via the selection of five Banking Commission board members and the
voting position of the Treasury representative, as unacceptable. Other observers
would prefer the elimination of the Commission altogether and the transfer of
prudential supervision (indeed, all responsibility for monitoring the financial
markets) to the central bank, as in the Netherlands and Belgium. France is one
of the few countries in the world with shared control over prudential supervi-
sion that involves several public bodies, including the Ministry of Finance. The
French Court of Auditors (Cour des Comptes) (1996 and 2005) and the National
Assembly’s and Senate’s Finance Committees (Auberger 1996) have called for
the full transfer of prudential supervision to the Bank of France as one possible
preferred option.
However, transfer to the Bank of France is not the only recommended option.
Both the Cour des Comptes (1996) and the National Assembly’s Finance Com-
mittee (Auberger 1996; Le Monde, 29 June 1996) called for increased autonomy
and capacity for the Banking Commission: the removal of the Treasury repre-
sentative; the diversification of the recruitment of the Commission’s staff (thus
decreasing the reliance on the Bank of France); the increased representation in
the Commission’s decision-making body of members with direct experience in
the banking or business sectors (since 1993, only two of the seven members of
the Commission necessarily have expertise in the banking and financial sector);
the reinforcement of the collegial body in relation to the Commission’s Secre-
tariat (dominated by the Bank of France officials) so that the collegial body can
gain greater direct control over the process of banking supervision; and the
assignment of legal personality to the Commission so that it can pursue bank-
ing supervision cases in the courts if necessary.
Thus, the future reform of prudential supervision in France will not neces-
sarily result in a reinforced role for the Bank. An option closer to the British
and German models of an autonomous agency might be preferred. Nonethe-
less, the National Assembly’s Finance Committee (1996) also accepted the
logic of maintaining a strong link between the central bank and the Banking
Commission: ‘The role of the Bank in adjusting the liquidity of the entire
banking system imposes on the Bank a surveillance role of the liquidity of
financial institutions. There is thus a certain logic in assigning Bank of France
120
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Other Roles
Since 1984, the Bank of France Governor has held the presidency of the CECEI
(Comité des établissements de crédit et des entreprises d’investissement), the body in
charge of granting individual licenses and authorizations to credit institutions
and investment firms and responsible for approving banking mergers, and 1 of
12 votes on the Committee (another is held by the Treasury Director). Since the
CECEI’s creation in 1984, the Bank has been one of its principal sources of
information and advice, in addition to the Financial Markets Authority (Autorité
des Marchés Financiers), the French stock market regulator. Moreover, since 1984
the Bank has been in charge of the CECEI’s Secretariat. As such it prepares the
examination of applications submitted to the Committee. Independence has
not had any significant impact on the role of the Bank in this body.
Since 1994, the Bank has also had full responsibility over surveillance of the
security of the payment systems, a responsibility possessed prior to 1994 under
the ‘tutelle’ of the Minister of Finance. From 2001, the Governor gained control
over the presidency of the newly established Observatoire des cartes de paiement.
The Bank’s legitimacy in these areas—banking supervision, financial sector
supervision, payments systems, and credit cards—rests upon its unrivalled
monetary, financial and economic data, and well-established capacity for an-
alysis. It also exercises a range of functions that in other EU member states are
either conducted by the state or left to the private sector. The Bank manages the
circulation of fiduciary money, provides a service to analyse local economic
development, and is engaged in personal debt management for individuals
faced with excessive debt. This unwanted responsibility for personal debt man-
agement—‘surendettement’—was imposed on the Bank in 2006 by the govern-
ment, which pays the bank for the service. Personal debt management became
the central role of 1,300 bank staff members—approximately 10 per cent of the
total—and several of the regional branches that were not closed in the ‘down-
sizing’ from 2003 to 2006, which also explains why staff and branch cuts during
121
Bank of France: The Challenge of Escaping Politicization
this period were not as large as initially intended. This new social role consists
of helping those who are refused bank accounts/credit to sort out their financial
affairs. The relatively large number of responsibilities assigned to the Bank of
France—and ‘surendettement’ in particular—has attracted criticism from the
Cour des Comptes (2005) which has called for the Bank to be allowed to concen-
trate on its core tasks.
Prior to 2004, the Bank was not a model of cost-effective public-sector manage-
ment, which weakened the strength of its calls for structural reform and public-
sector staff cuts. The Bank has long suffered from a problem of over-employment
and very generous social provisions for its staff including a special pension
regime. Prior to independence, the Bank engaged in hesitant cuts, watered
down in the face of determined union action and the opposition of local
politicians, who baulked at staff cuts in regional branches or their closure. Bitter
and lengthy strikes were sparked by reform attempts in 1974 and again in 1987,
which led to the resignation of one of the deputy governors. The weakness of
New Public Management ideas in the French administration also helps to ex-
plain the failure to adopt efficiency enhancing reforms—such as the outsourcing
of certain technical functions as in Sweden—which could have also achieved
staff cuts. In 2003, the total staff (included seconded staff) reached 15,755.
Independence and the transfer of monetary policy in 1999 exposed Bank inef-
ficiency to greater public and government criticism. This criticism intensified
when, in 2002 and 2003, the Bank ran deficits. In February 2003, a Bank of
France report called for the closure of three-quarters of its regional branches (166
out of 211), over a period of three years, with 3,200 job cuts (out of 9,000 in the
branches), amounting to nearly one-third of the Bank’s annual budget. A second
report called for the elimination of services for individual clients.
Cuts have been significant but were less ambitious than those initially called
for by the Bank’s own management and other government sources: from 2003 to
end-2006, 2,200 jobs were cut leaving 13,500 staff and 120 branches were closed
(less than the three-quarters called for) leaving 91 branches. The dilution of cuts
allowed the Bank to avert major strikes. Firings were avoided with early retire-
ment packages, which transferred costs onto pension provision. However, the
Bank achieved an operational profit in 2006 for the first time in many years.
Sixteen of the remaining 91 branches were transformed into ‘local economic
observatories’, debt management centres, or money sorting centres. In Decem-
ber 2005, after 18 months of difficult negotiations, the Bank achieved a major
reform to its special pension plan. Further cuts are likely. In its 2005 report, the
Cour des Comptes recommends the closure of additional branches and insists that
the Bank remains over-staffed and suffers from a particularly high unit labour
122
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
The Bank of France has long possessed a strong capacity for data collection and
analysis, which Bank officials argue is unrivalled by other Eurosystem central
banks. Through its regional offices, the Bank collects detailed monetary,
financial, and economic data and information on French companies that is
123
Bank of France: The Challenge of Escaping Politicization
124
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Bank’s activities. With more open recruitment and career progression proced-
ures in place, this situation may change with time. There have been no powerful
directors of research, who might have been able to attract increased resources.
Moreover, the governors, drawn from the Ministry of Finance, possess little
academic training and thus limited appreciation of the importance of academic
economic research. Governor Noyer, with his experience of top-quality research
at the ECB, might be different in this regard, but his appointment did not result
in any significant increase in research capacity at the Bank. The small number of
Bank staff members with PhDs is in marked contrast to the central banks in
many other countries. Several Bank officials also commented on the historic
weakness of economic research in France—and notably the weakness of market-
oriented research—and the tendency for some of the country’s best academic
economists to seek training and employment in the United States.
Those working in the Research Directorate of the Bank claim (interviews 28,
30, 31 January 2008) that, following independence, the Bank directors recog-
nized that the lack of research output damaged the credibility of the Bank as an
independent policy making authority and its influence within the Eurosystem.
They deliberately set about to increase the output of research publications that
could be accessed outside the Bank. However, the officials interviewed also
note that the desire to gain a reputation for the production of academically
excellent research has not been supported by a willingness to provide increased
financial resources. The financial difficulties of the early 2000s and the power
of trade unions that have made the reallocation of resources from the branches
to the centre difficult provide additional explanations for this failure. The more
academically oriented output of the Bank is limited; the number of peer-
reviewed academic journal articles published by Bank staff remains very low
in comparison to central banks in the other large EU member states. The
reputation of the Bank’s research in international banking and academic circles
is very weak. It has few research staff: in 2008 only approximately 17 full-time
researchers work in the Bank’s Research Directorate and publish work in aca-
demic journals. The Bank organizes relatively few conferences, although the
number has increased since 2000 and four were held in 2007 and 12 in 2008. It
is not yet seen as an important centre of debate, discussion on macroeconom-
ics and monetary economics. There is some concern for this weakness in
French political circles. A French Senate report (May 2001) criticized the con-
tribution of the Bank to economic research.
The Bank has undertaken a partial response with a small increase in the
number of research staff, although repeated requests from the head of the
Research Directorate for more researchers have been rebuffed. Increased efforts
have been made to develop links with academic institutions notably through
the co-hosting and co-funding of conferences. In early 2008 the Bank was in the
process of finalizing a link with an internationally renowned research centre on
firms at the University of Toulouse, through which the Bank will finance and be
125
Bank of France: The Challenge of Escaping Politicization
126
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
127
Bank of France: The Challenge of Escaping Politicization
both Treasury control and Bundesbank diktat. France has lost monetary auton-
omy but the Bank of France has gained an important autonomous voice in
setting Eurosystem monetary policy.
Independence transformed the Bank of France into an autonomous public
actor able to express views on—and often indirect criticism of—government
policy. The Bank has made some—albeit limited—effort to increase its publi-
cation output. The Bank’s publication of its own growth forecasts—undertaken
by few EU NCBs—can be seen as an expression of its independence. Yet the
Bank’s public role has been limited since 1999, which is surprising given its
independence, the diversity of its roles, and its relative size—it employs more
people than any other EU NCB. All officials interviewed at the Bank agree that
the independent Bank of France, as a non-majoritarian institution, should be
cautious in its public role and in its dealings with government and, while
recommending reform, should refrain from direct criticism of government
policy. Since 1999, Europeanization has allowed the Bank to side-step much
of the persistent politicization of monetary policy and central banking in
French politics: French politicians direct most of their antagonism at the
ECB. However, French governments have continued to express frustration
with activities of the Bank of France when they contradict government prefer-
ences—as with the handling of the difficulties at the Société Générale. Based on
its 1996 and 1998 opinion polls, the Bank appears to have achieved a measure
of public support for its operations, at least in monetary policy. However, these
polls are now dated, and the Bank has not revealed if it has undertaken more
recent soundings of public opinion on its operations since the transfer of
monetary policy in 1999.
There has been a limited degree of convergence with the operations found
in other Eurosystem central banks. With independence and the loss of mon-
etary policy making powers, the Bank of France has faced intensified pressure
to downsize and staff cuts have been significant. However, typical of French
public administration, the Bank of France has long suffered from overstaffing,
inefficiencies, and failed reform efforts due to a strong trade union presence.
When staff cuts came they were diluted and far less severe than those faced by
the Bundesbank. The Bank maintains the largest staff of the EU central banks
and the greatest diversity of roles. The Bank’s currently (to 2009) stable
financial situation enables it to resist pressure from the government and the
Cour des Comptes to downsize further in the near future, unless the Bank
manages to shed unwanted tasks, notably ‘surendettement’. On the core oper-
ations of the Bank, Europeanization has had a limited effect of convergence.
Unlike the Banca d’Italia which has shed its atypical roles, the Bank of France
continues to perform a range of functions not held by most other EU central
banks and has gained some responsibilities since 1994—for example on ‘sur-
endettement’. There is some pressure from elements within the French admin-
istration to reform banking supervision to move to either an autonomous
128
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
regulatory body as in the UK and more recently Germany or the full transfer of
supervisory powers to the central bank as in Dutch/Belgian model. However, the
sui generis French system of banking supervision is likely to persist for some time
given that it has already survived over a decade and a half of high-profile bank
failures and the Treasury is reluctant to surrender its role. The failure of the Bank
of France to reinforce its research capacity is particularly surprising given the
relevance of research to national central bank influence in the Eurosystem. Some
Bank of France officials suggest (interviews 28 January 2008; 30 January 2008)
that the impressive data collection and analysis and the relative importance of
the French economy in the Euro Area ensures the Bank sufficient influence.
Notes
1. Law no. 93-980, 4 August 1993. LOI no. 93-980 du 4 août 1993 relative au statut de la
Banque de France et à l’activité et au contrôle des établissements de crédit.
2. Prior to independence, Governors had no guarantee of longevity and no fixed mandate
of sufficient length to protect their independence. Nonetheless, Bank Governors gen-
erally occupied their post for long periods: seven years for Jacques de Larosiere (1987–
93) and six years for Renaud de la Genière (1978–84). Even so, politics intervened
regularly. The Socialists removed De la Genière, and Olivier Wormser had only a short
mandate.
3. ‘Sarkozy wants ‘‘protective EU’’ to offset globalisation’, Euroactiv.com, Friday, 23 February
2007, updated Wednesday 28 February 2007, http://www.euractiv.com/en/elections/
sarkozy-wants-protective-eu-offset-globalisation/article-161948, accessed on 10 March
2007.
4. The Socialist candidate appears not to have noticed that the ECB already has this as a
secondary goal.
5. The precise wording that the Socialist 2007 presidential candidate used was ‘soumise à
des décisions politiques’ (Le Monde, 22 December 2006).
6. Bank officials interviewed and journalists have put this down to Noyer’s personality,
described as lacking the charisma of Trichet, timid, secretive, and averse to risk (Le
Monde, 23 October 2003). Difficult internal reform at the Bank—of which Noyer had to
take charge immediately following his appointment—might have encouraged him to
engage in a less public role. Indeed, Trichet, as ECB president, has been more actively
engaged in French public debate, appearing several times on high-profile French
television and radio talk shows to deflect blame for French economic difficulties
from the ECB’s monetary policies and the strong euro and to call for further domestic
structural reform.
7. In a rare exception to this absence from the media, the four external members of the
Monetary Committee published a short newspaper article (written collectively) on
possibilities open to France and the Bank of France to respond at the national level
to the financial crisis (‘Solutions à la crise: commençons en France’, Le Monde, 21
March 2008). One looks in vain for biographical information on the Bank of France’s
website for information about these four officials which suggests their negligible role.
129
This page intentionally left blank
6
German Bundesbank: Europeanization
and the Paradoxes of Power
Kenneth Dyson
131
German Bundesbank: Europeanization and the Paradoxes of Power
Eurosystem and ceding its core responsibility for monetary policy making to
the ECB, the Bundesbank faced difficulties in claiming to be primus inter pares
amongst NCBs, let alone ‘the bank that rules Europe’ (Marsh 1992). Its presi-
dent has only one voice and vote amongst 21 in the Governing Council of the
ECB, and its core role in the Eurosystem was defined as ‘partnership’ (Deutsche
Bundesbank 2004).
The Bundesbank’s claim to a Vorreiterrolle in the Eurosystem had to rest on
more than just its unique role in the history of European monetary unifica-
tion, the relative size of the German economy (accounting for over 40% of the
total euro cash in circulation), its weight as the biggest subscriber to the capital
of the ECB, and its past superior experience and reputation in managing
stability-oriented monetary policies and securing a ‘stability culture’. More
challengingly, to be a convincing model, the Bundesbank had to invest and
renew its remaining functions with high-quality research in order to establish
a reputation for top-quality expertise in the new competition of ideas within
the Eurosystem (Remsperger 2002, 2004; Weber 2006a). It focused on refine-
ments to the ECB monetary policy strategy (notably its ‘monetary’ pillar,
which had been relegated to second pillar status in 2003) and to analysis of
risks in financial stability. In addition, the Bundesbank concentrated on
excelling in the more ‘nuts-and-bolt’ areas of modernizing cash management,
developing and managing platforms for new pan-European payment and
settlement systems (TARGET2 in particular), and banking supervision (notably
in negotiating and applying Basle II). This challenge derived not just from a
more competitive environment of policy ideas but also from the past reliance
of the Bundesbank on its monetary policy performance rather than the quality
of its analytical economic modelling, compared for instance to the Banca
d’Italia. Its traditional advocacy of a principles-based approach exposed it
to critiques of a lack of analytical capacity. In this respect, Axel Weber’s
appointment as president was important.
The Bundesbank could draw on its strengths in representation of Germany’s
economic and financial size and its sense of a special vocation to safeguard the
Bundesbank legacy of stability to the Euro Area and to promote a long-term
culture in financial markets. However, in its new core functional areas, and
constraining its development of quality research, it could lay claim to neither
the glamour and the gravitational attraction nor the autonomy of action that it
had earlier enjoyed in its monetary policy-making function. It faced a new
difficult challenge of credibility building across a range of functions to which it
had earlier accorded a relatively low strategic profile. In meeting this challenge
the Bundesbank’s room for manoeuvre was tightly constrained by a more assert-
ive Federal Finance Ministry and by an ambitious ECB Executive Board. Its flank
was exposed to German political claims, especially from Social Democratic
Federal Finance Ministers, that central bank independence was a less relevant
principle outside monetary policy making, for instance, in banking supervision.
132
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
This radical change to its functions, and to the structure of opportunities and
constraints within which it operated, exposed the Bundesbank to new, continu-
ing public questioning and need to justify its existence. Along with internal
reforms and downsizing (between 1991 and 2007 from 16,500 to 11,160 staff
and from 202 to 47 branches), it produced profound, disquieting effects on
institutional self-confidence and morale and heightened internal conflicts. The
Bundesbank experienced a period of defensiveness, introversion, and identity
crisis that further threatened its capacity to rebuild credibility and to project a
strong shaping presence in the Eurosystem. The ECB could offer higher salaries
and more challenging posts to attract the young stars of central banking, on the
Bundesbank’s doorstep in Frankfurt; whilst the Bundesbank had to make big
staffing cuts and in 2006 lost the inducement of special salary bonuses.
The Bundesbank’s problems came to a head under the presidency of Ernst
Welteke (1999–2004) when internal dissensions over structural reform, and
also over use of its gold reserves, along with setbacks to its ambitions to
develop its role in banking supervision and financial stability, distracted and
weakened the institution within the Eurosystem. The resignation of Welteke
proved a cathartic experience, after which Axel Weber sought to develop a
sharper profile by consolidating the bank around himself in a more centraliz-
ing style than ever before and by pursuing a new image of the central bank as a
leader in public-sector modernization. However, the age of powerful Bundes-
bank presidents like Otmar Emminger (1977–80) and Hans Tietmeyer (1993–8)
was ended. Centralizing Bundesbank internal reforms to support the new
personal responsibility of the president in ECB monetary policy and to exped-
ite internal managerial reforms failed to halt the decline in Bundesbank profile
or to restore team spirit.
The Bundesbank’s central problem in redefining a new identity was how to
adjust to a major reconfiguration of its power relationships at international, EU,
and domestic levels. EMU was just a part of this reconfiguration but one that
accelerated adjustment pressures. The following five developments coincided:
. A marked increase in the rate of innovation, in complexity and in opacity
in global financial markets. Market developments included the growth in
derivative contracts and options, the use of new investment vehicles by
banks to offload risk finance, and the emergence of hedge funds and private
equity companies as major non-bank players in creating liquidity. These
developments confronted the Bundesbank with mounting pressures to be
less cautious in its attitudes to financial market liberalization, with new
challenges in controlling money supply growth and in monetary analysis,
and with new systemic risks to financial stability. This context made the
Bundesbank keen to protect the traditional German three-pillar financial
system of commercial, cooperative, and public savings banks. It sought to
frame financial market liberalization as promoting consolidation within
133
German Bundesbank: Europeanization and the Paradoxes of Power
each pillar (welcoming the Commerzbank take over of the Dresdner Bank
and Deutsche bank of the Postbank); whilst ensuring that retention of the
‘narrow’ bank concept in the latter two pillars would help retain a strong
element of long-term culture in German financial markets that would
support a high savings rate.
. The impact of IT and new public management ideas on the provision of
central banking services, notably in on-line banking, electronic payment
systems, and internal performance-related practices. The Bundesbank was
forced to reconsider its essential core functions, which functions could be
in whole or part outsourced to the private sector, notably in cash man-
agement, and above all staff cuts and less hierarchical working.
. The loss of its role as the ‘bank that rules Europe’ in monetary policy
making (Marsh 1992) to the ECB and the ECB directorate’s ambition to
centralize functions like banking supervision and payment systems. The
Bundesbank had to review its central functions once deprived of the
central operational rationale for its intellectual leadership role in Euro-
pean central banking.
. The loss of its international profile in G7, the IMF, and the BIS. The
Bundesbank had to strengthen its international bargaining power by
working harder to secure EU-wide coordination, for instance, over IMF
reform or over Basle negotiations on reform of banking supervision. Its
intra-European networking skills and coalition building assumed an even
greater importance.
. The release of the German federal government—and the Federal Finance
Ministry in particular—from the policy constraint of a strategy of needing
to ‘bind in’ the Bundesbank to its European economic and financial policies,
once EMU was achieved. Especially on the political Left, which came to
power in 1998, German politicians who had resented Bundesbank domestic
power were ready to exploit its loss of domestic political leverage. With the
first centre–Left federal coalition government in post-war history, the Bun-
desbank faced new ideological challenge. In 1998–9 the Bundesbank
was confronted with the combative Social Democratic (SPD) party chair
Oskar Lafontaine as new Federal Finance Minister and as advocate of neo-
Keynesian ideas. Although more supportive, Hans Eichel (1999–2005) and
Peer Steinbrück (2005–) placed the Bundesbank under new political pressure
with reform of the Stability and Growth Pact, reforms of domestic banking
supervision, pressures for gold sales in 2002–3, and even cuts and removal of
special salary bonuses. From 1998 the Bundesbank faced the combination of
varyingly suspicious SPD finance ministers with the challenges listed above.
In terms of visible power relationships the winners were global financial
players, the ECB, and the German Finance Ministry. To add to its domestic
134
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
EMU had paradoxical effects on Bundesbank power. On the one hand, EMU
collectively empowered central bankers at the EU level to safeguard economic
stability on the basis of an Ordo-liberal paradigm of stability-oriented policies
inspired by the Bundesbank (and of an institutional design close to that of its
more decentralized predecessor, the Bank deutscher Länder, 1948–57). In con-
sequence, the post-euro Bundesbank stressed a fundamental continuity in its
special role as the ‘guardian’ or ‘night watchman’ of stability: its Wächterrolle in
the Eurosystem. Central to all its activities remained the mission of ‘construct-
ing stability’, both in Germany and in the Eurosystem. This mission led it to act
as an advance protagonist of the ECB in asserting the institutional and policy
attributes of stability against threats: whether from opponents of a predomin-
ant role for monetary analysis and money supply growth in ECB monetary
policy; from proposals to exclude or marginalize NCBs in banking supervision
and financial stability functions; from attacks on ECB independence in succes-
sive Treaty and institutional reform proposals; or in principled resistance to
reform of the Stability and Growth Pact (Deutsche Bundesbank 2005a, c). In so
doing, it often took up tougher positions than ECB directors. Over the period
1999–2006, Jürgen Stark, its vice-president (earlier chief German negotiator of
the Pact and later ECB Chief Economist), encapsulated this role. His departure,
like that of Edgar Meister in banking supervision, ended the continuity of
personnel at the executive board level with the Tietmeyer Bundesbank.
On the other hand, EMU disempowered the Bundesbank at domestic, EU,
and international levels. The effects were most striking in relations with the
Federal Finance Ministry (especially over banking supervision reforms in 2002
and 2007 and over reducing salary bonuses in 2006); with certain Land
governments over the nomination of executive board members (notably in
2006–7 when the Bundesbank had to accept a board member it had opposed);
and with the ECB and some other national central banks in the Eurosystem
(in the competition for policy ideas). Compared to the US Federal Reserve, the
135
German Bundesbank: Europeanization and the Paradoxes of Power
ECB, and the Bank of England, the Bundesbank lost ground in the IMF and G7
(over financial stability issues) and looked increasingly to achieving common
positions in the Euro Group and ECOFIN. Unlike in constructing EMU, the
Bundesbank was cast into the position of defending the European monetary
constitution, the ‘monetary’ pillar of the ECB’s monetary policy strategy,
central banks’ role in banking supervision and financial stability, and even
retention of extra pay allowances for its staff.
The history of the Bundesbank and the euro reflects the paradox between
two types of power: power as the capacity to act in the service of its functions
and power as dominance of one actor over others. Paradoxically, in diminish-
ing its power over other central banks, the Bundesbank collectively empow-
ered EU central banks to more effectively promote economic stability within
the EU. EMU is the story of the Bundesbank’s institutional self-abnegation of
power ‘over’ others for the superior aim of enhanced collective central banking
power ‘to’ deliver a socially valued outcome—economic stability in Europe (on
these two forms of power, see Morriss 2006). The legacy of its shaping power
over the institutional design of the Eurosystem left intact (even if recurrently
challenged) the Bundesbank’s power in two of three dimensions—the power
to frame how other actors defined their interests in EMU and the power of
agenda setting (and keeping issues off the agenda). At the same time the Euro
Area reduced the visible face of Bundesbank power in being directly able to
change what others did (on the distinction between these three dimensions of
power, see Lukes 2005). This self-abnegation testifies to a long-term European-
ization process in the Bundesbank, in which accommodation trumped inertia
and resistance to the implications of European market and political integra-
tion for monetary policy.
This process of Europeanization and the outcome of accommodation testi-
fied to a distinctive conjunction of factors at work both in EMU and in
Germany. The Bundesbank was embedded in a broad domestic political con-
sensus about the primacy of European unification in German long-term
national interests and about the vital role of monetary union in that process.
Debate focused on timing and conditions, not on principle. The Bundesbank
was from 1958 onwards a pivotal player in EU central banking, its positions
refined and propagated by Emminger. EU central bankers had in turn low
collective action problems as a result of both the emerging high professional
consensus in monetary economics about price stability by the 1980s, conse-
quent on the collective experience of the Great Inflation of the 1960s and
1970s, and the habits and practices of intensive cooperation in various EU and
international fora. Accordingly, EU central bankers readily achieved solidarity
around the Bundesbank’s detailed prescriptions for European monetary and
currency union, presented to and incorporated in the report of the Delors
Committee (Dyson and Featherstone 1999). These low collective action costs
in EU central banking combined with determined, resolute, and consistent
136
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
political leadership, not least by the German Federal Chancellor and his astute
political skills in ‘binding in’ the Bundesbank, to facilitate EMU (Dyson 1998).
Both the process and the outcome of EMU illustrated that the power
that mattered to the Bundesbank was the professional capacity to shape out-
comes—a socially beneficial form of power—rather than the more instrumen-
tal power of the Bundesbank over others in gaining their compliance. The
Bundesbank focused on whether the Treaty and institutional conditions were
right to safeguard the collective professional capacity to deliver price stability.
With respect to power relationships, it was concerned to retain influence
within the Eurosystem and thereby ensure the Eurosystem’s ability to shape
the long-term expectations and behaviour of market players, price and wage
setters, and governments. The new asymmetrical power of the ECB within
European economic governance [what Dyson (2000) calls the ‘ECB-centric’
Euro Area] compensated in part for the diminished asymmetrical power of the
Bundesbank in German economic governance. After 1998–9, on issues like
Treaty revision, the application and reform of the Stability and Growth Pact
and exchange-rate coordination, the post-euro Bundesbank assigned a special
role to itself in speaking out loudly and clearly against any attempts to weaken
the collective capacity to deliver price stability. Through Stark, in particular,
it specialized in ‘voice’ on behalf of the policy paradigm that it had collectiv-
ized, notably against recurring French suggestions for European ‘economic
government’ (Hirschman 1970).
The Bundesbank is like whipped cream—the more one stirs it, the firmer
it gets.
Wim Duisenberg
137
German Bundesbank: Europeanization and the Paradoxes of Power
138
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
The enduring loyalty of the Bundesbank to the EMU process, despite these
periodic crises, reflected in part acceptance of the primacy of EMU as a political
project, in part a shared mind-set that favoured European economic and
political unification, and in part its influence in the process and over the
content of EMU during all these crises (except German unification).
139
German Bundesbank: Europeanization and the Paradoxes of Power
What factors formed the pre-euro Bundesbank’s character? First and fore-
most, the Bundesbank prided itself on being the most independent of EU
central banks (Loedel 1999b). This pride had its origins in a distinctive German
Ordo-liberalism that favoured a principles-based approach to monetary policy,
reliance on monetary rules, scepticism about formal analytical economic
modelling, and central bank independence to deliver a long-term predictable
framework of price stability free from short-term political pressures (Nicholls
1994; Weber 2006b). The historical roots lay in the nightmare memories of
hyper-inflation and its corrosive political and economic effects. The earlier,
more decentralized Bank deutscher Länder scored two notable victories over
Chancellor Konrad Adenauer: when he tried to stop an interest-rate increase:
in 1950 during the Korean War crisis; and, most famously, in May 1955 when
in his Guerzenich speech Adenauer decried its damage to ‘the small fry’. In
July 1956 the cabinet rejected Adenauer’s proposal to move the planned
Bundesbank from Frankfurt to Cologne, close to the political capital Bonn.
These practical and symbolic political victories for Wilhelm Vocke, president
of the Bank deutscher Länder, and Ludwig Erhard, Federal Economics Minister,
were the context for securing its independence in ‘safeguarding the currency’
in the Bundesbank Act of 1957 (Deutsche Bundesbank 1999; De Haan 2000).
Later Chancellors avoided repetition of Guerzenich.
Bundesbank pride was reinforced by the relative success of Germany in
avoiding the worse effects of the Great Inflation of the 1970s and in being a
pacesetter in devising a monetary rule in 1975 as a domestic discipline once
the Bretton Woods system had collapsed (Emminger 1986). In the 1980s the
Bundesbank’s reputation was further reinforced by mainstream American aca-
demic research in monetary economics that established a relationship be-
tween central bank independence and price stability and sustained growth
without boom and bust. The principle of central bank independence remained
the bedrock of its negotiating strategy on EMU and of its post-euro role in
consolidating stability.
In the context of an Ordo-liberal orthodoxy that rejected or at least substan-
tially qualified Keynesian demand management, monetary policy possessed
an enduring primacy in both macro-economic policy and in the activities of
the Bundesbank not seen in any other EU state or central bank (Dyson 1999).
The importance of its monetary policy role grew with the Bundesbank’s pace-
setting role in the ERM, based on the ‘anchor’ role of the D-Mark, along with
its long domestic record of independence. The monetary policy capacity of
other EU central banks remained undeveloped because they either lacked this
independence in setting interest rates (like the Bank of England) and/or were
constrained in monetary policy autonomy by ERM membership, becoming
monetary policy ‘takers’. This ‘benchmarking’ role in European monetary
policy meant that the Bundesbank director responsible for economic policy
enjoyed an unusually powerful internal position, with a large prestigious
140
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
141
German Bundesbank: Europeanization and the Paradoxes of Power
142
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
143
German Bundesbank: Europeanization and the Paradoxes of Power
144
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
145
German Bundesbank: Europeanization and the Paradoxes of Power
146
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
147
German Bundesbank: Europeanization and the Paradoxes of Power
148
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
149
German Bundesbank: Europeanization and the Paradoxes of Power
executive board of the Bundesbank was to be slightly larger (eight rather than
six) and to be nominated half by the federal government and half by the
Bundesrat. This return to a plurality of nominating bodies represented a
concession to the Länder and was justified as better securing the Bundesbank’s
independence.
Once the single-tier executive board was in place in 2002, internal restructur-
ing around a few dedicated service centres and staff reductions gathered pace.
They were reinforced in Weber’s ‘Strategy 2012’, which planned 9,000 staff in
2012: down 40 per cent from 15,600 in 2001 and from 18,000 in 1992, and
double the average for the Eurosystem national central banks. Weber also sup-
ported the proposal in 2006 to reduce the executive board to six, with federal
government and Bundesrat still nominating half each (and the CDU/CSU insist-
ing on the states having the right of proposal for vice-president). These changes
fitted his model of a lean, efficient Bundesbank and his strategic view that its
tough calls for domestic structural reforms to labour, product, and service mar-
kets lacked credibility if it showed lack of will and capacity to reform itself. The
Bundesbank had to be a model of structural reform in the public sector.
Banking supervision remained a continuing source of tensions with the fed-
eral government. The Bundesbank sought to raise its profile both in Basle II and
in the ECB-based Banking Supervision Committee. It actively engaged in the
Basle II negotiations on behalf of the distinctive German interests in protecting
the credit position of small and medium-sized firms. It also sought to innovate in
regulation of liquidity requirements of banks in the context of the new capital
standard. In developing a ‘principles-oriented’ approach, the Bundesbank gave
banks the choice between adopting a standard formula and using their own
internally developed liquidity risk measurement and management methods
(according to certain requirements). The Bundesbank presented this twin-track
approach as a model for EU-wide harmonization of banking supervision.
A further setback for the Bundesbank was the failure of its proposals, backed
by other NCBs, to strengthen the role of the BSC in promoting banking
supervisory convergence and cooperation within the ESCB as well as in stabil-
ity analyses of the European banking systems. Meister, the Bundesbank dir-
ector responsible for financial stability and its first chair, identified the BSC as a
potential platform for the Bundesbank to raise its profile in EU-wide banking
supervision. However, no sooner was BaFin agreed than Eichel, in a joint
proposal with Gordon Brown, proposed a comprehensive reform of European
financial supervision in April 2002. ECOFIN decided to extend the committee
structure established already for securities supervision to banking. The CEBS
began work in 2004 to advise the European Commission on preparation of
banking directives, to ensure their consistent application, and, increasingly, to
encourage convergence in supervisory rules and practices. It fell outside the
umbrella of the ESCB, which focused on macro-prudential issues, and symbol-
ically was located in London, not Frankfurt. The Bundesbank unsuccessfully
150
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
opposed this reform as too insensitive to the national, regional, and local
distinctiveness of banking structures. Once again the Bundesbank found itself
on the defensive against Federal Finance Ministry proposals.
The Bundesbank had been inhibited by its strategic commitment to retain
banking supervision as a national responsibility and prevent its centralization
in the ECB, which was sought by members of the ECB Executive Board, includ-
ing its president. The rationale for this insistence on the principle of subsidiar-
ity was the sheer complexity of different banking structures in Europe, their
particular heterogeneity in Germany, and hence the need for locally based
expertise. The Bundesbank also doubted that EU states were prepared to cede
political authority to the ESCB to deal with financial system issues. At the same
time it feared that ECOFIN might seek to establish a pan-European FSA at
collective cost to the central banks, ECB, and NCBs. The CEBS was not the
worst-case scenario. The Bundesbank not only failed to prevent a sharing of
powers with BaFin in CEBS but also failed to prevent CEBS’s location in London.
The Bundesbank held up the centralization of banking supervision in the
Dutch central bank as the preferred model and rejected the British FSA model
as undermining the capacity of the central bank to safeguard financial stability
through the early warnings provided by a detailed operational knowledge of
the banking system. Although it tried to make the German ‘dual’ system work,
it argued that it was too complex and involved an unclear division of respon-
sibilities and lack of transparency in the process. The Bundesbank argued that
BaFin officials tended to duplicate its work and were too removed from the
details, whilst tacitly supporting claims by many banks that BaFin lacked
the subject-matter competence of Bundesbank officials (a situation that
reflected the centralized operation of BaFin and the regional operation of
the Bundesbank).
In the coalition agreement of 2005 the Grand Coalition committed to a
further reform of banking supervision. The Bundesbank argued for a reform to
differentiate more clearly its role from BaFin and to avoid its officials being
drawn into the BaFin orbit. For this reason it rejected the proposal that the
Bundesbank be given a seat in the management board of the reconstituted
BaFin and sought more responsibility in banking supervision.
The Federal Finance Ministry reform proposals in 2007 occasioned major
alarm. They prioritized the removal of the supervision of investment funds
(many linked to banks) from the Bundesbank to BaFin on the ground that they
should not be classified as ‘credit institutes’. This reform, which aimed to
eliminate dual supervision, reduced the scope of the Bundesbank’s involve-
ment. In a critical opinion the ECB argued that the reform undermined the
Bundesbank’s capacity to safeguard financial stability within the Eurosystem.
More seriously, the Finance Ministry wanted to strengthen its own role by
bringing BaFin closer within its own orbit and subjecting both BaFin and the
Bundesbank to its own supervisory authority. The Bundesbank argued that
151
German Bundesbank: Europeanization and the Paradoxes of Power
152
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
The new sense of urgency that was imparted by the crisis of 2004 proved
useful to Weber. More fundamentally, however, the nature of the strategic
consolidation reflected the Bundesbank’s weakened position in domestic
semi-sovereignty games and its emerging recognition that the primary stra-
tegic requirement to overcome this handicap was to strengthen its position
in Eurosystem ‘semi-sovereignty games’. It had to re-earn credibility and
reputation in this new professional context.
The pre-euro Bundesbank’s domestic power and professional identity was
bound up with its leadership of European monetary policy. The post-euro
Bundesbank’s domestic power and professional identity was dependent on
its perceived competence in the Eurosystem as a key source of innovative
ideas and best practices across its range of functions: banking supervision,
payment and settlement systems, cash management, and—crucially—ECB
monetary policy strategy. In ensuring a clear Bundesbank imprint on the
ECB it had advantages other than just an original Bundesbank-shaped design:
physical proximity to the ECB; the number of former Bundesbank officials
working for the ECB (82 were seconded at senior levels in 2007); and the
presence of former Bundesbank directors as successive ECB chief economists
(Issing and Stark).
The decentralized structure of the Eurosystem offered an incentive to excel in
the competition of ideas. Inspired by New Public Management ideas, internal
Bundesbank reforms highlighted strengthening its five roles in applied
economic research; in quality of its financial stability analysis and promoting
the values of a long-term culture in German financial markets; in developing
stress indicators for systemically important banks; in leading operationally
and strategically on European cashless payment systems (TARGET2 and
TARGET2S); and in pioneering in efficient cash management (through the
cash electronic data interchange procedure and multi-denomination banknote
processing). The strategic cycle from 2008 to 2012 focused on ‘raising the
Bundesbank’s profile’ in these ‘core business areas’.
Already, under Welteke in 2000, the Bundesbank set up its Economic
Research Centre, along with a scientific advisory council, as the new focus
for its research activities. This Centre managed the macro-economic structure
model, forged links with applied academic research in universities and outside
research institutes on monetary policy and increasingly financial stability
issues, and sought to raise the Bundesbank’s profile in ESCB policy issues,
especially monetary analysis, the dynamics of wage setting, and analysis of
household financial situations. Weber (2006) highlighted two papers: on the
continuing value of monetary indicators in predicting Euro Area inflation
(Hoffmann 2006); and on improving the quality of monetary indicators
(Greiber and Lemke 2005). The Bundesbank focused on strengthening its
profile in the ECB Governing Council by arming Weber not just to defend
the ‘monetary’ pillar against sceptics but also in refining the contents of this
153
German Bundesbank: Europeanization and the Paradoxes of Power
154
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Voting Rules, Treaty Change, and Stability and Growth Pact Reform
The triple processes of Euro Area enlargement, of drafting the Constitutional/
later Reform Treaty, and of Stability and Growth Pact reform created strong
incentives for Bundesbank engagement in safeguarding European stability
culture. In the case of the two latter, the Bundesbank’s principled opposition
opened up tensions with some members of the ECB executive board. Common
to its positions was the stress on retaining the ‘monetary constitution’ of
Maastricht. Retaining the Stability and Growth Pact mattered not just as a
discipline on other EU governments but also as an external means of compen-
sating for the loss of the Bundesbank’s domestic capacity to discipline the
German federal government for lax fiscal behaviour through monetary policy.
EU enlargement was linked to evidence that the Bundesbank model
remained an important influence on the establishment and reform of national
central banks in east central Europe, like the Czech Republic and Poland
(Rentzow 2002). The Bundesbank was also a major source of technical advice
and training to accession state central banks on such matters as payment
systems, banking supervision, and financial market stability. This role was
formalized in its restructured Centre for Technical Central Bank Cooperation
(Deutsche Bundesbank 2005d). However, enlargement was also a source
155
German Bundesbank: Europeanization and the Paradoxes of Power
156
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
In contrast to the original draft, the final document signed in October 2004 lay
down not only ‘balanced growth’ but also ‘price stability’ as EU objectives. The
Bundesbank was notably active on this issue.
German breaches of the Stability and Growth Pact from 2001, the crisis of
November 2003 over the German federal government’s mobilization of sup-
port in ECOFIN to avert the next stage in the excessive deficit procedure, and
subsequent discussion about reform of the Pact highlighted the diminished
power of the Bundesbank. It illustrated a more assertive Federal Finance
Ministry, no longer needing to ‘bind in’ the Bundesbank to its positions. Led
by Stark, who had been chief negotiator of the original Pact with Tietmeyer,
the Bundesbank adopted a position of fundamental opposition to reform
(Schäfer and Hagelueken 2005). It identified the problem as a failure to apply
its provisions. The Schröder government sought flexibility in both its terms
and its application so that the Pact would function not just to flank the ECB
monetary policy but also to give governments greater scope for using public
spending and tax policies to facilitate painful domestic structural
reforms. Unlike the Federal Finance Ministry, the Bundesbank was very dissat-
isfied with the final outcome in the 2005 reform (Bundesministerium der
Finanzen 2005; cf. Deutsche Bundesbank 2005c).
Conclusion
157
German Bundesbank: Europeanization and the Paradoxes of Power
158
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
159
This page intentionally left blank
7
Bank of Greece: Latecomer,
Uphill Adjustment
George Pagoulatos1
Why should the Bank of Greece warrant particular attention? In the early 1990s,
Greece posted the worst record among all EU member states in terms of deficits
and inflation. The story of Greece’s EMU accession is the uphill adjustment
course of the most laggard of EU-15 economies, steered successfully by the
country’s central bank, the Bank of Greece. Thus, Greece was a latecomer in
the Euro Area. It was the only state that wanted but could not enter in 1999 and
remained in the antechamber for two more years before finally managing to
accede alone in 2001, into stage three of EMU. This late accession was not a
function of weak will but of acutely problematic initial macroeconomic condi-
tions, testifying to the intensity of the adjustment enterprise and the scale of the
final achievement. The Bank of Greece steered this arduous monetary adjust-
ment course, led by Governor Lucas Papademos, who subsequently became
vice-president of the European Central Bank. The wide initial gap between
capabilities and expectations, and the central bank’s leading role in bridging
the gap, makes Greece a particularly revealing case study. The Bank of Greece
offers a hard case of successful application of the orthodox EMU adjustment
strategy, led by a rigorous and consistent disinflationary monetary policy.
The Bank of Greece (BoG) historically underwent three main evolutionary
stages, following closely the European trend. Initially, a strong central bank
was founded in 1928, in order to establish the monetary guarantees that would
safeguard the interests of international creditors. The BoG was one of the
central banks established by the League of Nations Financial Committee,
endowed with the exclusive right to issue currency, a strong orthodox mon-
etary and exchange-rate policy orientation, and important statutory guaran-
tees of legal independence (Mazower 1991: 103 ff.; Pepelasis-Minoglou 1998).2
Subsequently, in the early post-war period, the Bank was subjected to extensive
161
Bank of Greece: Latecomer, Uphill Adjustment
By the time of initiation of EMU and the Maastricht Treaty of 1993, the long-
standing and structural features of Greece’s political economy corresponded to
what has been broadly, albeit impressionistically, identified as a Southern Euro-
pean model. Several—though certainly not all—of the main patterns of the
Greek system may be generalizable across Southern Europe: a post-war tradition
of far-reaching financial intervention, with a traditionally credit-based, under-
developed financial system (Zysman 1983), weak, mostly state-controlled and
162
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
163
Bank of Greece: Latecomer, Uphill Adjustment
40
38
Elections 1981
36
34
32
30
28 Elections 1985
26
24 Elections 1989
22 Elections 1977
20
18 Elections 1990
16 Elections 1993
14
12
10
8 Elections 1996
6
4
2
0
1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 1999
Figure 7.1. The Greek electoral cycle: fiscal and monetary expansion, 1975–99
Sources: Pagoulatos (2003a); Ministry of National Economy (1998, 2001); Bank of Greece (1993–
2001).
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000
−5
−10
−15
−20
Inflation (CPI) Nominal saving deposit interest rate
Short-term bank lending interest rate Short-term bank-lending deposit
Real lending interest rate rate spread
Figure 7.2. Greek inflation, interest rates, and short-term bank-lending deposit rate
spread, 1950–2000
Sources: Pagoulatos (2003a); Bank of Greece (1992, 2000); Ministry of National Economy (2001).
164
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
165
Bank of Greece: Latecomer, Uphill Adjustment
precondition for the successful exercise of monetary policy. It derives from the
orthodox literature that governments may well have a positive interest in
allowing their central bank a significant degree of autonomy, institutional
independence being considered a factor enhancing central bank credibility
and effectiveness in combating inflation (Cukierman 1992; Giavazzi and
Pagano 1988; Gilardi 2002). This is even more the case with governments
plagued by inadequate resources, poor policy effectiveness, and questionable
credibility. Of particular concern to state actors is the issue of creditworthiness:
harsh market penalties (in the form of higher premiums) await borrower
governments lax in combating inflation. For these reasons, the dominant
orthodoxy held, it is desirable for democratic governments to have one macro-
economic policy instrument which can respond exclusively to the technical
requirements of the economy, and to achieve that it is in their interest to
extend a significant degree of central bank autonomy (Woolley 1985: 334).
By the early 1990s prolonged macroeconomic instability was turning into
serious political liability. The socio-economic demand for currency stability in
the face of persisting high inflation ended up empowering the central bank,
leading government to entrust it with more decisive control over monetary
instruments in pursuit of disinflation. Thus, domestic economic policy failure,
rooted in enduring patterns and structural factors, created favourable condi-
tions for a bolder, active BoG involvement in the EMU adjustment process.
The growing distance between the emboldening pace of European economic
integration and Greece’s lagging policy performance in meeting its challenges
during the 1980s and early 1990s generated a vacuum of economic policy
leadership. Bolstered by the rapidly rising importance of central banking
after Maastricht, and the favourable economic, politico-institutional, and
ideational conditions in the EU, the Bank of Greece rushed to fill the void.
166
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
167
Bank of Greece: Latecomer, Uphill Adjustment
18
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
−2 1980 1990 2000
−4
−6
Greece EU average
Figure 7.3. Real short-term interest rates: Greece and EU, 1980–2000
Sources: Pagoulatos (2003a); IMF (2000); Ministry of National Economy (1998, 2001).
168
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
169
Bank of Greece: Latecomer, Uphill Adjustment
170
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
171
Bank of Greece: Latecomer, Uphill Adjustment
The Monetary Policy Shift and the Political Ascendance of the BoG
Over the 1990s, financial liberalization and monetary adjustment led to
macroeconomic convergence in three closely related ways. First, as men-
tioned, financial liberalization was the sine qua non precondition for allowing
monetary policy to become assertive and carry the brunt of stabilization.
Liberalization allowed the introduction of new instruments of monetary man-
agement. It enabled the BoG to rely flexibly on open market operations,
seeking to influence short-term interest rates in the interbank market as its
main intermediate goal. Second, financial liberalization generated flexible
conduits of intermediation: mostly short-term government securities markets
and the associated distribution channels such as mutual funds. After the
172
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
government had shifted away from deficit monetization, they allowed for
public deficits to be absorbed by private investors. Third, the greater role of
private investors in public deficit financing subjected government to stricter
discipline in its monetary and fiscal policies (OECD 1995: 58–60).
In its annual reports of the early 1990s, the BoG mentioned the balance of
payments, GDP growth, and banking liberalization as additional secondary
objectives to the reduction of inflation. Following other central banks, however,
it was already succumbing to the appeal of monetary targeting. After capital
movements were fully liberalized in 1994, the BoG adopted an exchange-rate
intermediate target (publicly announced on an annual basis), alongside its
monetary target. Progressively the monetary target was de-emphasized, and
the BoG after 1997–8 endorsed a version of inflation targeting, setting the
ultimate inflation objective for two years ahead (Bank of Greece, various years;
Voridis, Angelopoulou, and Skotida 2003).
Until 1994, the BoG was clearly not independent (Pagoulatos 2003a).4 After
1994, when the Maastricht-imposed abolition of the monetary financing of
government deficits entered into force, the BoG satisfied all the formal criteria
of economic independence. Finally, in the context of full statutory harmon-
ization with the Eurosystem, law 2548 of December 1997 (‘Provisions relating
to the Bank of Greece’) granted the BoG complete institutional independence
and stipulated that ‘the primary objective of the Bank of Greece shall be to
ensure price stability. Without prejudice to this primary objective, the Bank
shall support the general economic policy of the government.’ The law estab-
lished BoG independence from any government instructions or advice, exclu-
sive authority in the exercise of monetary policy, a six-year renewable term for
the governor and deputy governors, and a Monetary Policy Council (compris-
ing the governor, the two deputy governors, and three additional members).
The Monetary Policy Council, which began to operate in 1998, was assigned
responsibility for decisions pertaining to monetary policy definition and
implementation and to the conduct of exchange-rate policy, the operation
of payment systems, and the issue of banknotes.
The primacy of the euro accession objective, in an adverse environment of
large deficits and a tradition of lax monetary and fiscal policies, endowed the
central bank with extraordinary political authority. The BoG has been widely
credited for Greece’s accession to the Euro Area. Crucial after 1994 was the
presence at the helm of Professor Lucas Papademos, a widely respected mon-
etary economist and pragmatic proponent of the orthodox mix of drastic
disinflation and fiscal overhaul, combined with growth-enhancing structural
liberalization.
Thus the cross-party political adoption of euro entry as a ‘national object-
ive’, combined with the acute macroeconomic conditions, led to a momen-
tous increase of central bank power. In sum, the gains of central bank
authority in the domestic socio-political system were a combined result of its
173
Bank of Greece: Latecomer, Uphill Adjustment
endowment with formal institutional independence after 1994 and the suc-
cessful implementation of the Euro Area accession mission.
174
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Equity capitalization in Greece rose from 2 per cent of GDP in 1985 to 15 per
cent in 1994 up to 169 per cent in 1999, then receding to 98 per cent in 2000
following the decline of stock prices (Capital Market Committee 2001: 40). As
in continental Europe, financial liberalization in Greece has notably increased
the role of the capital market but has not as yet reversed the financial system’s
bank-based character. Liberalized banking competition is thus the main after-
math of financial deregulation, involving important efficiency as well as sys-
temic safety implications. These shape the novel environment in which the
BoG’s supervisory responsibility is exercised. Liberalization increased bank
competition in interest rates, though with a significant time lag. Falling lend-
ing rates and more aggressive banking competition animated demand for
credit, which had been suppressed by the high interest rates over much of
the 1990s. Consumer credit grew at an average annual rate of about 40 per cent
over the period 1994–2000, but the ratio of consumer credit to GDP in 2000
was only 4.5 per cent in Greece compared to 10 per cent in the Euro Area
members. Similarly, the corresponding ratio for mortgage lending in 2000
stood at about 8 per cent compared to the EU average of 40 per cent. By
2006 the figures were converging to Euro Area standards.
On the assets side, banks developed trading activities and securitization
operations (including fees opportunities for advising and underwriting),
while the fall of traditional deposits from the 2000s was countered by the
rise of money market mutual funds and other liabilities (Belaisch et al. 2001).
Income from the management of investment and pension funds controlled by
the larger banking groups has been assuming important proportions in Greece
and throughout the Euro Area. In 2000, the majority of mutual funds operat-
ing in the Greek market were banking group subsidiaries. Moreover, the copi-
ous windfall income achieved from securities trading, especially during the
Greek stock market boom of 1998–9, allowed banks previously burdened with
bad debts to clean up their portfolios and list very high profits.
175
Bank of Greece: Latecomer, Uphill Adjustment
176
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
177
178 Shareholders’ General Meeting
Governor: N. Garganas
Deputy Governor: P. Thomopoulos Banking and Credit
N. Paleokrassas Committee
Government Financial
Payment Systems Information Systems
Operations and Accounts Cash Department
Department Department
Department (9 Sections)
(3 Sections) (13 Sections)
(10 Sections)
Economic Research
Statistics Department Internal Audit Department Printing Works Department
Department
(11 Sections) (3 Sections) (7 Sections)
(15 Sections)
Technical Services
Legal Department Internal Relations Division Accounts Department
Department
(4 Sections) (2 Sections) (5 Sections)
(6 Sections)
The turn of the century finds the BoG part of a different balance between state
and financial system, in a novel political economy. The banking system is no
longer government-controlled and forced to subsidize developmental or redis-
tributive priorities, but free to operate along profit-maximizing lines. The
central bank is vested with full political independence, is institutionally pro-
hibited from participating in the primary market for public debt, and is offi-
cially endowed (as part of the Eurosystem) with a statutory commitment to
price stability. The government has no channel of access to preferential credit
by taxing the banking system, but is forced to finance its deficit by resorting
to the internationalized money markets. On the ascending side in terms of
importance and bargaining power are financial markets, banks, financial
investors, institutional stockholders, and bondholders. Disinflation becomes
a principal normative determinant, given that both government and the
private-enterprise sector as deficit units rely exclusively on liberalized financial
markets able to demand constantly higher returns, and given the supreme
bargaining power of the (typically inflation-averse) creditors within the
system.
Since the second half of the 1980s and especially over the 1990s, the BoG
steered the structural transformation of the Greek financial system and the
momentous change of monetary policy that landed an erstwhile problematic
economy at the monetary core of the EU. The prize of the BoG’s leading role in
the economy’s nominal adjustment process was its own institutional inde-
pendence, if only short-lived, as its ‘sovereign’ policymaking authority was
surrendered to the Euro Area. The BoG was transformed to national-level
executive branch of an independent European supranational institution. For
an economy with a long track record of monetary instability, such surrender of
monetary independence meant that much more was to be gained than lost.
However, significant structural, organizational, and functional transform-
ations of the BoG have been associated with this development.
The BoG continues to operate as a custodian of the national economy,
authoritative source of independent technocratic assessment of economic
conditions, and par excellence ‘objective’ economic advisor to the government.
In the initial climate of euphoria that followed successful accession to the Euro
Area, the BoG enjoyed public visibility, cross-party respectability, and consid-
erable popularity. The latter was soon to recede as life under the euro gave rise
to a new generation of problems. Its institutional role as part of the Eurosystem
179
Bank of Greece: Latecomer, Uphill Adjustment
renders the BoG a representative of the orthodox central banking doctrine that
(given the commitment of ECB monetary policy to price stability and of
national fiscal policy to flanking budgetary discipline and fiscal sustainability)
economic growth can only result from structural reforms, that is, most prom-
inently market liberalization, labour-market flexibility, and far-reaching pen-
sion reform. The BoG has been the most persistent advocate of wage
moderation and structural reforms in these politically controversial policy
areas, consequently becoming the target of widespread political attacks, to
an extent unseen in the past. Susceptibility to such political hostility is further
aggravated by the central bank being perceived as a banking system ally and
apologist of its galloping profitability. Being the flipside of the rapidly increas-
ing indebtedness of Greek households, bank profits and what is perceived as
the BoG’s ‘neo-liberal agenda’ are becoming a focal point of political oppos-
ition from the Left and the populist Right.
We are thus faced with what we might call ‘a paradox of central bank
depoliticization’. Before acquiring independence the central bank was subject
to the government’s politicized macroeconomic governance. While being
used as an instrument in the service of the government’s objectives, the central
bank was nonetheless rarely accused of pursuing a politico-ideological agenda,
not least because the government absorbed the political heat of such oppos-
ition. As an independent institution, however, and especially as executive arm
of the ECB, the national central bank becomes the domestic focal point of
opposition against what a significant part of the political spectrum regards as
‘monetarist’ and ‘neo-liberal’ economic policy. In other words, the national
central bank’s depoliticization, by way of independence from national gov-
ernmental political objectives, has subjected it to far greater political contro-
versy than it had ever elicited during its long period of supposed
‘politicization’. The answer to this apparent paradox is, of course, that, for all
its technocratic robustness, central banking orthodoxy is not distributionally
neutral: it affects socio-economic interests in different ways, it involves gains
and losses.
Notes
1. The chapter has benefited from the research assistance of Christos Triantopoulos.
2. The 1928 Charter provided for a five-year term of BoG governors and for an inde-
pendent arbitration commission to resolve disputes in case of disagreement between
BoG and government, and seriously restricted the BoG’s direct or indirect financing of
government or public enterprises.
3. The book of Halikias (1978) (BoG governor for 1984–92) is representative of the
monetarist-leaning central bank orthodoxy.
4. Until 1994 the BoG satisfied only 3 of the 10 generally accepted formal criteria of
political independence. Among the formal criteria of economic independence, until
180
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
end 1993 only the discount rate criterion was satisfied (but then, the discount rate
was of minimal importance anyway in a regime of administered interest rates). In
terms of formal political independence, Grilli, Masciandaro, and Tabellini (1991)
ranked the BoG over the central banks of Britain, Portugal, Japan, Belgium, and
New Zealand and at the same level as those of France and Spain. However, in overall
pre-1994 formal independence, the BoG was outranked by all, except Portugal and
New Zealand.
5. Economic Bulletin (since 1992), Monthly Statistical Bulletin (since 1999), Monthly
Statistical Bulletin of Economic Conjuncture (since 1997), and Monthly Bulletin of
Regional Economic Conjuncture Macedonia-Thrace (since 1999).
181
This page intentionally left blank
8
The Banca d’Italia: Between
Europeanization and Globalization
Lucia Quaglia
The Banca d’Italia is one of the largest central banks in the European Union
(EU). It is a relatively powerful player in the Eurosystem, which it joined when
the third stage of Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) began in 1999. In an
interview released in the run up to the third stage, its Governor, Antonio Fazio,
expressed his concerns about Italy’s membership of the single currency, argu-
ing that it would be a ‘purgatory’ (Financial Times, 10 November 1998).
This chapter addresses the question of what have been the main changes
experienced by the Banca d’Italia as a result of Europeanization and globaliza-
tion over the last 20 years, but with the focus on the most recent period, from its
entry into the Euro Area. To what extent has the Italian central bank been able to
resist or mediate external pressure for change, namely, Europeanization and
globalization, and how has it adapted to them? Has this led to convergence of
institutional structures, policy templates, and roles performed by the Banca
d’Italia? How has its power in national, EU, and international monetary and
financial matters changed after the establishment of European monetary union?
The chapter is organized according to a temporal sequence, taking a dia-
chronic perspective in order to explain continuity and change over time. As
Europeanization is a long-term incremental process, its direct and indirect
effects should be traced and assessed over time. The chapter first examines
the independence, internal governance, legitimacy, policies, and atypical roles
performed by the Banca d’Italia prior to the establishment of European mon-
etary union. The second part examines these issues with reference to the
period after the creation of monetary union. These sections, which help to
trace institutional and policy convergence over time, also discuss the institu-
tional context and power relations in which the central bank is embedded.
Finally, the chapter explores the role of the Banca d’Italia in the Eurosystem,
including the interactions with the European Central Bank (ECB), and its
183
The Banca d’Italia: Between Europeanization and Globalization
The Banca d’Italia has often been described as the least independent among
the group of independent central banks or, to put it another way, as the more
independent within the category of the dependent central banks (Financial
Times, 22 November 1989). Indeed, until the changes introduced in the early
1990s in preparation for monetary union and discussed in the following
section, in economists’ rankings the Banca d’Italia used to be awarded fairly
high scores as far as political independence (especially, personnel independence)
was concerned, but scored rather low on economic independence (Alesina and
Summers 1993; Cukierman 1992; Grilli, Masciandaro, and Tabellini 1991).
The Bank’s personnel independence was safeguarded by the legal provisions
and established practices for the appointment of the Executive Board (Diret-
torio), the length of its members’ tenure in office, and difficulties of dismissal,
as well as by the distribution of power within the Bank. The procedures for the
appointment process and the practices that developed over time, as well as the
position of the Governor, as discussed below, very much limited the power of
the political authorities in selecting the top management of the Bank,
strengthening its independence.
184
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Before the 2005 reform, legislation limited the direct influence of the polit-
ical authorities in the appointment process of the Governor and the other
members of the Executive Board. The Executive Board consists of the Gov-
ernor, the Director-General, and three Deputy Directors-General. In 2006 the
number of deputy directors-general was raised from two to three, so as to have
an odd number of members. Prior to 2005, the nomination of all four members
of the Executive Board, including the Governor, was proposed by the Board of
Directors (Consiglio Superiore). It had to be approved by a decree of the presi-
dent of the Republic, acting on the proposal of the prime minister together
with the Treasury minister, after discussion in the Council of Ministers. Fur-
thermore, the practice of internal appointments to senior and top positions in
the Bank generally prevailed. Hence the Governor was generally chosen from
among deputy governors, and deputy governors were normally chosen from
among senior officials at the Bank.
Moreover, before 2005, all four members of the Executive Board were
appointed sine die, that is, their mandate was open-ended and there was no
age limit. In practice, since the Second World War the longest period for
governors to have remained in office was for a decade or more, like other
members of the Executive Board. The same body that proposed the appoint-
ment of the members of the Executive Board, the Board of Directors, could
repeal their appointment through a joint decision-making procedure, involv-
ing the government and the President of the Republic (Finocchiaro and Con-
tessa 2002). However, the members of the Board of Directors are elected by the
holders of the Bank’s capital quotas by a secret vote in a process apparently
immune from interference from the government of the day, generally follo-
wing the proposals put forward by the Bank itself (interviews, Rome, March
2002).
The appointment of the members of the Executive Board for life, together
with the distribution of power within the Bank, as determined by its govern-
ance structure, contributed to make the Governor a powerful figure. Until
2005, the Banca d’Italia was one of the most centralized and hierarchical
central banks in Europe. The distribution of power within the Bank was very
much skewed in favour of the Governor. He had wide powers and discretion, in
that all responsibilities in monetary, exchange-rate, and supervisory policies
were concentrated in his hands.
In contrast to this relatively high personnel independence, the economic
independence (in economists’ studies also referred to as ‘instrument’ inde-
pendence, see Cukierman 1992; Grilli, Masciandaro, and Tabellini 1991) of
the Bank was low and was completed only in 1993, when the overdraft
account of the Treasury at the central bank was closed down, in order to
prepare for the final stage of monetary union. Nonetheless, the financial and
organizational independence in terms of economic resources available to the
central bank was and is remarkable. For example, Bank officials are among the
185
The Banca d’Italia: Between Europeanization and Globalization
best-paid civil servants in Italy, and the Governor is one of the best-paid
governors in the world. This is important because it has allowed the central
bank to attract and retain high calibre, well-trained officials, who, in turn,
have provided the Bank with advanced economic knowledge. In the macro-
economic field, this is a clear instance of ‘when knowledge is power’ (Haas
1990).
The other side of central bank independence and power is its accountability
and legitimacy. Until the 2000s, the legitimacy of the Banca d’Italia had hardly
ever been questioned in Italy, for a variety of reasons. Before the statutory
changes introduced in order to comply with the Maastricht Treaty in the early
1990s, the Banca d’Italia was not legally independent of the government.
Hence the issue of accountability was not very significant. Moreover, the
Banca d’Italia could rely on widespread domestic public acceptance of its
activities and the policies that it delivered. Public opinion surveys reveal that
the Banca d’Italia was the most trusted institution in Italy. Indeed, the intan-
gible assets of the Bank, such as expertise in monetary and financial matters
and a distinctive operational culture, were important in fostering public sup-
port, as were some of the atypical roles performed by the central bank over
time, as elaborated below.
Let us now look briefly at the power of the Banca d’Italia in the main policies
in which it was involved before the establishment of the Eurosystem: monet-
ary policy, exchange-rate policy, and financial stability.
Monetary Policy
Before the changes implemented in the early 1990s in preparation for monet-
ary union, power in the conduct of monetary policy in Italy was formally
shared between the Treasury and the central bank. It should be noted that,
before the amendments introduced in order to comply with the Maastricht
Treaty, the Italian central bank was not assigned the statutory objective of
maintaining price stability. On the one hand, in practice, the Bank had a
preponderant power in the conduct of monetary policy, because it had the
technical expertise, macroeconomic credibility, and knowledge of the market
that until the early 1990s the Treasury (or any other governmental body)
lacked (Quaglia 2005a). On the other hand, the Bank’s power in monetary
policy was de facto limited by the conduct of fiscal policy, which, unlike
monetary policy, was in the hands of the political authorities, negatively
affecting the economic independence of the Bank.
Together with the institutional arrangements for central bank independ-
ence, monetary policy is the domain in which the impact of economic ideas,
in the form of ‘policy paradigms’ (cf. Hall 1993) has been greatest in promoting
convergence in Europe and worldwide (Dyson 1994; Marcussen 2000; McNa-
mara 1998). In the 1980s, the monetary policy paradigm at the Bank changed
186
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Exchange-Rate Policy
Italy joined the technical part of the EMS, the Exchange-Rate Mechanism
(ERM), in 1979. Afterwards, exchange-rate policy became a key component
of the monetary policy strategy followed by the Banca d’Italia, whereby the
quantity of money (M2) was the intermediate target and the exchange rate was
a ‘quasi final objective’ (Sarcinelli 1995). Hence, the ERM was used by the
Italian central bank as a mechanism to foster macroeconomic convergence,
first and foremost convergence of monetary policy and inflation performance
(Ciampi 1990). Exchange-rate policy was crucial in this strategy, deploying
‘Europe’ (to be precise ERM membership) as an external constraint, which
augmented the decision-making power of the Bank domestically, shielding
the conduct of monetary policy from political interference.
Before European monetary union, decision-making power in exchange-rate
policy was shared between the Banca d’Italia and the Treasury. The Bank was
responsible for the day-to-day management of the exchange rate, while the
government decided on the exchange-rate regime, and the Treasury, together
with the Bank, was involved in parity realignment in the ERM. De facto, the
domestic power of the Bank in exchange-rate policy went well beyond what
was prescribed by legal provisions, for the same reasons as in monetary policy:
advanced macroeconomic knowledge, market expertise, and limited Treas-
ury’s technical capabilities.
However, the external power of the Bank in exchange-rate policy was cur-
tailed by the dominant role of the Bundesbank, which was the ‘leader’ of the
ERM (on the functioning of the ERM, see Giavazzi and Giovannini 1989;
Giavazzi, Micossi, and Miller 1988). In other words, the other central banks
in the system had largely to adapt to the Bundesbank’s monetary policy, which
indirectly influenced the conduct of the monetary and exchange-rate policies
in other European states.
Participation in the EMS, which was an exchange-rate regime based on an
adjustable peg, produced a major shift in Italian exchange-rate policy and
monetary strategy. In short, Europeanization effects were at work well before
the establishment of monetary union. From the first half of the 1980s onwards
realignments of the lira never fully compensated for the inflation differentials
187
The Banca d’Italia: Between Europeanization and Globalization
between Italy and the low-inflation states within the ERM (Ciampi 1990).
Furthermore, from 1987 to 1992, no realignments took place, leading to an
appreciation of the lira in real terms (Gaiotti and Rossi 2003,). It was the so-
called ‘strong’ exchange-rate policy (or ‘hard currency’ option) coupled to a
relatively tight monetary policy.
The withdrawal of the lira from the ERM in September 1992 reversed the
exchange-rate policy followed by the Italian authorities during the 1980s. The
subsequent floating lira became an important element of the Italian strategy,
fostering an export-led boom, which in turn sustained Italian economic
growth in a phase of fiscal retrenchment and slow growth in the EU. The lira
re-entered the ERM in November 1996, which was essential to fulfil the nom-
inal convergence criteria in order to join monetary union in the first wave in
January 1999.
Those critical of Euro Area membership argue that the loss of competitive-
ness that affected Italian goods and services and the deficit in the balance of
payments since the late 1990s suggest that, as far as variables in the real
economy are concerned, Italy was not ready for European monetary union.
Not enough ‘real’ convergence had taken place in preparation for the final
stage of EMU. Governor Antonio Fazio and some of his close advisers were
leading proponents of this ‘Eurosceptic’ interpretation of Italy’s membership
in European monetary union (Quaglia 2004). In an interview released shortly
before the beginning of the final stage Fazio argued that Italy was not ready for
European monetary union because in particular structural reforms had not
been carried out (Financial Times, 10 November 1998). A senior official at the
Bank interviewed in 2001 likened Italy’s performance in the Euro Area to a
medium-weight boxer fighting a match against a heavy-weight opponent
without proper training (interview, Rome, June 2001).
Financial Stability
The Banca d’Italia is responsible for the systemic stability of the financial
sector, including all financial intermediaries; the prudential supervision of
banks and securities market intermediaries; the oversight of relevant markets
for monetary policy; and the oversight of the payments system. Financial
supervisory tasks have not substantially changed with European monetary
union. The main change took place in 2005, as discussed below, in that until
that date the Bank had been responsible for safeguarding competition in the
banking sector. Overall, as compared to other European central banks prior to
monetary union, the Banca d’Italia had extensive and largely discretionary
power concerning banking policy and prudential supervision. Indeed, it was
the only central bank in Europe in charge of competition policy in the banking
sector. This almost unchecked power became evident in 2005, as elaborated
below.
188
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Other Roles
Besides the three core central banking policies (monetary policy, exchange-
rate policy, and financial stability and supervision), the Banca d’Italia has
performed a variety of services for the government. However, they have been
reduced over time, as a certain degree of convergence of the ‘other functions’
performed by central banks has taken place in the Eurosystem. The Bank used
to act as banker to the government, a function that came to an end in 1993 and
was ruled out by the EMU provisions in the Maastricht Treaty. Nowadays the
government has a non-interest–bearing deposit at the Bank, and the overdraft
facility has been closed. The Bank used to manage the public debt, in conjunc-
tion with the Treasury, but in the 1990s this task became the competence of
the Treasury alone. The Bank manages the payments system, a task that is
shared with other central banks in the Eurosystem (see below). All banks based
in Italy are obliged to keep a non-interest–bearing deposit at the Bank, which
acts as lender of last resort. In addition, the Banca d’Italia has often acted as an
adviser to the government on a variety of matters.
Over time the Banca d’Italia has performed other functions that can be regarded
as ‘country-specific’, that is to say, result from the configuration of the Italian
socio-economic and political system. It was a ‘strong’ central bank in a ‘weak’
state (cf. the Banque de France). This meant that the Banca d’Italia acted outside
the traditional boundaries of a central bank, performing certain functions that
should arguably have been carried out by other parts of the Italian state apparatus
or civil society. This situation strengthened the power of the central bank, but also
made its functions more complex. Once in European monetary union some
of these functions came to an end, so that the Italian central bank has converged
towards practices of other central banks. At the same time, as we see below,
some new self-assigned roles have been taken on board by the central bank.
189
The Banca d’Italia: Between Europeanization and Globalization
Until the early 1990s, the Banca d’Italia had a near monopoly of expertise in
Italy, a trend that continued in the 2000s, even though the Treasury augmen-
ted its technical capabilities from the 1990s onwards. The Bank has been at
the forefront of the development of Italy’s ‘economic culture’. Its Research
Department has been the research centre par excellence in the economic field in
Italy. The Bank has awarded scholarships for post-graduate education abroad.
Many of these award holders later joined the Bank. The cutting-edge economic
expertise enjoyed and deliberately developed by the Banca d’Italia was a clear
case of ‘when knowledge is power’ (Haas 1990) for several reasons. First, at the
domestic level, the wider implications of certain ‘technical’ decisions taken by
the central bank were not always understood, a priori, by the government and
the political class, which did not have direct access to technical knowledge
(Quaglia 2005b). Second, the Italian central bank’s strategy to strengthen its
informal power in international and EU policy fora was to deploy the ‘force of
argument’ (or of ‘numbers’) as a way to tip the balance in the policy discus-
sions in certain directions and to persuade other macroeconomic authorities.
As argued below, the quality of economic knowledge and the calibre of experts
to which central banks have access has become an important source of infor-
mal power in the Eurosystem.
The Banca d’Italia has also been a breeding ground for talented civil servants
and the financial elite. It has ‘exported’ credibility, expertise, and personnel for
the conduct of Italian economic policy to other parts of the Italian state
apparatus, the private sector, and international organizations. Interestingly,
the Bank has been the ‘exporting’ institution, whereas central banks in other
countries more usually ‘import’ senior officials from outside (cf. the Bundes-
bank and the Banque de France). This was also an indicator of the power
(power of appointment, technocratic power) enjoyed by the Bank.
The Banca d’Italia has represented a ‘credible interface’ for Italy with the
outside world—the ‘power of credibility’. Since the post-war period it has
interacted with foreign institutions (i.e. other monetary authorities and inter-
national organizations) and, more generally, has kept contacts with the out-
side world. After the upgrading of technical capabilities and human resources
at the Ministry of the Treasury, which led to the ‘empowerment’ of the Treas-
ury (later reformed into the Ministry for the Economy), the function of exter-
nal economic representation and credible interface between the domestic
arena and the international environment has largely been taken over by this
Ministry.
190
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
191
The Banca d’Italia: Between Europeanization and Globalization
192
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
and foremost the Governor, who had the ultimate decision-making power at
the Bank.
As a result of the changes introduced in 2005 in order to step up the
transparency and accountability of the central bank, written justifications
for decisions taken, especially in the supervisory field, have to be provided
by the Bank, and the minutes of the meetings of the Executive Board have to
be kept. The report on supervisory activities is due twice a year, not once a year.
Since 1999, the monetary policy in the Euro Area is conducted by the ECB
and the Eurosystem, which very much adopted a German model for the
conduct of monetary policy and central bank independence (Dyson 2000).
The Banca d’Italia participates in policy formulation and implementation as a
member of the Eurosystem. Similarly, exchange-rate policy is conducted at the
Euro Area level. For these two policies convergence has been complete. On the
one hand, the Banca d’Italia has lost the power to conduct these policies at
the national level. On the other hand, this power is now shared with the ECB
and other participating central banks at the Euro Area level.
In contrast, financial stability and financial supervision remain largely
national competence, even though the mechanisms for institutional cooper-
ation in the EU and the Euro Area have been stepped up. Unlike in monetary
policy and exchange-rate policy, ‘positive integration’—characterized by spe-
cific EU models or provisions to be adopted by the member states—has been
minimal in the EU as far as financial supervision is concerned. Even within the
Eurosystem, different institutional frameworks and policy paradigms persist.
This is not only because financial systems vary remarkably across Europe, but
also because, unlike the stability-oriented paradigm in monetary policy, based
on central bank independence, there is not a benchmark institutional model
or widely accepted technical framework in financial supervision (Busch 2004).
It should also be noted that the Banca d’Italia during the Fazio governorship
opposed any expansion of the ECB’s competence in the supervisory field (Sole
24 Ore, 16 February 2002), and by closing ranks with some other national
central banks, it was successful in doing so.
At least until the 2000s, the Banca d’Italia had traditionally been regarded as
an effective supervisor, which also made the Bank intellectually powerful in
European and international supervisory networks and fora. Except for the
bankruptcy of Banco Ambrosiano in 1981, there were no major financial
scandals in Italy in the 1980s and 1990s. Hence Italian policymakers had no
need to consider alternative supervisory models. However, the early 2000s
proved to be a more turbulent period, with the insolvency of the Argentinean
bonds, the financial collapse of Cirio in 2002, and Parmalat’s insolvency in
2003. Although these episodes could hardly be attributed to systematic super-
visory failures, they triggered a heated debate about the configuration and
allocation of supervisory responsibilities in Italy and weakened public confi-
dence in the existing supervisory framework.
193
The Banca d’Italia: Between Europeanization and Globalization
194
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
had lost some core functions and partly because foreign banks, largely as a
consequence of EMU and more generally financial globalization, tried to
penetrate the Italian market in the 2000s. The Banca d’Italia reacted by endea-
vouring to protect the italianita’ delle banche (basically, Italian ownership of
the banks operating in Italy). As part of the Bank’s ‘grand design’ for reshaping
the banking system in Italy, Governor Fazio consistently opposed foreign
shareholdings and never authorized a foreign takeover, in an attempt to
prevent, or at least to slow down, foreign penetration of the Italian market
(Financial Times, 11 February 2005; 17 February 2005; 31 March 2005). The
Bank’s official explanation was that this strategy was designed to give the
domestic banking system time to adjust and to become competitive inter-
nationally. Critics (e.g. the Financial Times was particularly vocal on this)
argue that it was economic protectionism, coupled with dirigiste attitudes.
Mario Draghi, former vice-president and managing director of Goldman
Sachs (an international investment bank), based in London, and former
Director General of the Italian Treasury in the 1990s, took over from Governor
Fazio in 2006. From the outset, Draghi gave clear signals of change, albeit
emphasizing the continuity of the prestigious tradition of the Bank of Italy.
Following the new rules agreed in 2005, three new members of the Executive
Board were appointed: they all had considerable international experience and
were either internal to the Bank, or had spent a considerable part of their career
there. Besides changes at the level of the senior management, the approach
adopted by the new governor and the Executive Board can be summarized as
more openness, accountability, and efficiency. The priority was to regain
‘credibility’.
The first objective was to open up and modernize the Italian financial sector,
in marked contrast to the approach taken by Fazio. Draghi was keen to
encourage mergers in the banking sector, making clear that, if banks’ execu-
tives failed to take the initiative, he would not oppose foreign takeovers. The
second objective was to rationalize the Bank’s structure and its resources by
initiating the process of closing down the existing delegations in EU capitals,
but strengthening the Bank’s delegations in the United States and Japan.
Third, Draghi expressed positive attitudes to membership of the Eurosystem,
seeking to specialize the Bank of Italy on specific activities. Finally, in the new
management style, there has also been deliberate emphasis on accountability
and transparency. For example, given the fact that Draghi was a former execu-
tive at Goldman Sachs, when taking office he announced that he would
abstain from any decisions involving his former employer for one year.
Despite the appointment of Draghi in 2005 and the changes that have
gradually taken place since then, unlike the Swedish central bank (see Marcus-
sen, this volume), the Banca d’Italia, like the Banque de France (see Howarth,
this volume) has not embraced a new public management approach, which
emphasizes performance indicators, monitoring, outsourcing, and so on. It
195
The Banca d’Italia: Between Europeanization and Globalization
The Banca d’Italia is the third largest central bank in the Eurosystem and has
been eager to remain an influential actor there. Among the national central
bank governors, Fazio was one of the most determined to safeguard the com-
petences of national central banks within the Eurosystem—or, to put it
another way, to limit the competences and power of the ECB and its Executive
Board in Frankfurt.
The contributions of the Banca d’Italia to the design and setting up of the
ESCB, Eurosystem, and ECB are not comparable to those of the Bundesbank,
which largely provided the institutional and policy templates for the ECB
(Dyson 2000). However, three types of inputs can be identified. First, the
Banca d’Italia seconded a considerable number of officials to the ECB head-
quarters in Frankfurt when the ECB was established. This was important in the
early years of the ECB, when it was in the process of hiring its own staff. Some
of the Italian officials seconded to Frankfurt subsequently returned to the
Banca d’Italia, and the ECB has established procedures to hire its own staff,
also at senior level, even though the number of senior officials initially
employed by national central banks remains high.
Second, the Banca d’Italia played an important role in the establishment of
the Trans-European Automated Real-time Gross Settlement Express Transfer
System, or TARGET, which was completed in 1999. TARGET was created by
interconnecting 12 national euro real-time gross settlement systems and the
ECB payment mechanism and is used for the settlement of central bank
operations, large-value euro interbank transfers, and other euro payments in
real time. In October 2002, the Governing Council of the ECB decided to
establish TARGET 2 in preparation for the enlargement of the Eurosystem,
based on a single shared platform for the central banks that decided to join it
and were willing to give up their own national real-time gross settlements
platform. The central banks of Italy, France, and Germany, building on their
expertise in payment systems, offered to provide the technical platform in
2002, and the ECB Council accepted in 2004. TARGET 2 is operational and the
Banca d’Italia is also involved in the setting up of TARGET 2 Securities, a
system for the clearing and settlement of securities in the Euro Area.
196
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
197
The Banca d’Italia: Between Europeanization and Globalization
power, which rests with the national central banks and the national supervis-
ory authorities sitting on the BCBS. This status quo might, however, change if
the composition of the BCBS is amended or if the ECB is given new compe-
tences in the supervisory field.
In the negotiations of both the Basel I and the Basel II Accords, the Banca
d’Italia endeavoured to make sure that issues that were important for the
competitiveness of the Italian banking system were taken into account. On
certain issues, the Banca d’Italia forged an effective alliance with the Bundes-
bank, given their similarity of interests (interviews, Rome, July 2006; Frank-
furt, January 2006), such as preventing negative effects of the Basel II
agreement on small and medium-sized enterprises (Wood 2005), which are
widespread in both Italy and Germany. During the negotiations, German and
Italian policymakers co-operated on this matter—for example, by conducting
joint studies—and achieved positive results, with the final draft of Basel II
regarded as providing favourable treatment for small and medium-sized en-
terprises. Another important goal of the Italian, British, and German author-
ities was to make the new accord less pro-cyclical, in which they were
successful, as becomes obvious when the first draft of the accord is compared
with the draft eventually agreed in 2004.
This chapter examined the evolution of the Banca d’Italia between European-
ization and globalization. These two processes promoted institutional and
policy convergence, and redefined the power of the Italian central bank,
domestically, internationally, and in the EU. The chapter argued that conver-
gence of institutional and policy templates has mainly been imposed by
external factors, such as European monetary union and Eurosystem member-
ship, EU legislation, other (non-legally binding) international agreements,
pressure exerted by the financial markets, and international circulation of
ideas in the form of policy paradigms.
Some of these factors were at work well before the establishment of Euro-
pean monetary union, reminding us that Europeanization and globalization
are long-term phenomena and can be better understood by taking a dia-
chronic perspective. These external factors triggered changes that affected
both the institutional framework of central banking in Italy and the main
policies conducted by the central bank, though to a different extent. Some
policies, first and foremost monetary and exchange-rate policies, have con-
verged completely in the Euro Area, whereas others, above all financial super-
vision, have not converged significantly, and divergence persisted across the
EU/Euro Area. Overall, the atypical roles performed by the Banca d’Italia
converged, leading, not without some hitches, to a ‘normalization’ of central
198
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Acknowledgements
I wish to thank the editors, Charles Goodhart, John Woolley, and the participants in the
workshops in Cardiff and at the British Academy for their comments on an early draft of
this chapter.
199
This page intentionally left blank
Part III
‘Temporary’ Outsiders: Pace Setters
and Laggards
This page intentionally left blank
9
Estonia, Hungary, and Slovenia:
Banking on Identity
Béla Greskovits
203
Estonia, Hungary, and Slovenia: Banking on Identity
204
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
205
Estonia, Hungary, and Slovenia: Banking on Identity
moments, such as the stabilization package of 1995, that Hungarian fiscal and
monetary policies could be coordinated.
As to central bankers’ interaction with social partners, business associations,
and trade unions, varieties of capitalism scholars identified patterned variation
within the club of OECD economies. They argue that ‘the effects of monetary
policies cannot be understood without paying attention to the conditioning
influences of wage bargaining structures and processes’ (Iversen and Pontusson
2000: 12). If wage bargaining is centralized and coordinated, social partners
concerned about the economy-wide levels of inflation and unemployment are
likelier to respond to central bank signals with wage restraint. Such response
pre-empts the need for overly restrictive monetary policies. In turn, highly
decentralized, fragmented industrial relations regimes make such accommoda-
tion unlikely (Franzese and Hall 2000: 178–9). Adapted to east central European
cases, the varieties of capitalism approach help to identify important differ-
ences. Central bank policies in Slovenia, just like in many West European states,
have been backed by centralized and coordinated neocorporatist institutions of
social partnership. In contrast, central banks in Estonia and Hungary (and all
other east central European states) have operated against the background of
highly fragmented, decentralized industrial relations regimes, and monetary
policy has remained exogenous to atomized wage bargaining. Generally, the
interplay between central banks and the regimes of industrial relations has
developed in rather ‘un-European’ directions in the region (Table 9.2).
Both the Bank of Estonia and the National Bank of Hungary interact with
commercial banking sectors, which, to much larger extent than Slovene banks,
have undergone almost complete privatization to transnational investors.
Again, the almost complete transnationalization of commercial banking ex-
hibits striking divergence from what Europeanization of this sector would mean.
206
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Table 9.2. Employer organization, union density, and pattern of wage bargaining
in Estonia, Hungary, and Slovenia, 2002–3
Source: Visser (2005). Index of centralization: maximum 0.71 (Austria), minimum 0.13 (U.K.). Index of
coordination: maximum 0.64 (Finland), minimum 0.11 (Lithuania).
Foreign dominance in the banking sector of most EU old member states has
been the exception rather than the rule. It is only in Luxembourg and Greece
where foreign banks’ power compares with the situation in east central Europe
(Claessens, Demirgüc-Kunt, and Huizinga 1998; Table 9.3).
However, the un-European ownership pattern proved helpful in the course of
‘extreme ‘‘top-down’’ Europeanization that has required a rapid alignment of
financial sector regulation with EU regulations as part of the accession process’
(Mohácsi Nagy 2006: 259). Foreign banks have deepened domestic financial
markets and rapidly ‘imported’ high standards of management and governance
in Estonia and Hungary, while the coordination of Slovene banking sector has
remained somewhat rudimentary and less transparent. At the same time, in the
former two countries foreign subsidiaries’ ability to borrow from their parent
institutions has impaired the effectivity of changing reserve requirements as a
monetary policy instrument.
Estonia
Number of foreign banks in total (%) 43 57 86
Foreign bank assets in total (%) 35 98 99
Slovenia
Number of foreign banks in total (%) 12 21 40
Foreign bank assets in total (%) n.a. 15 30
Hungary
Number of foreign banks in total (%) 61 76 70
Foreign bank assets in total (%) 61 67 83
EU-15 average
Number of foreign banks in total (%) 30 n.a. n.a.
Foreign bank assets in total (%) 20 n.a. n.a.
207
Estonia, Hungary, and Slovenia: Banking on Identity
208
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
209
Estonia, Hungary, and Slovenia: Banking on Identity
The majority of east central European countries had to build new nation states.
All of them faced recession, inflation, and chaos, and wanted to ‘return to
Europe’. This section traces their initial decisions empowering or limiting the
power of central bankers to past legacies and their perception as either assets or
threats from the viewpoints of national independence, economic success, and
the perspective of Europeanization.
Estonia
Since inherited institutions and skills of monetary coordination were absent in
Estonia, central bankers’ power could not originate from public trust in their
professional competence. Given that the rapid shift to a national currency with
fixed exchange rate and a currency board mechanism, backed by a constitu-
tionally enshrined balanced budget provision, led to massive social dislocation,
the sources of political support for such radical measures are far from trivial.
Their support could not purely stem from international backing, as crucial
decisions had been taken in 1992 before massive external pressure or assistance
could materialize. Indeed, former Estonian prime minister Mart Laar (2002:
114) recalled that ‘[i]n the Spring of 1992 the International Monetary Fund
(IMF) initially urged Estonia to postpone monetary reform until its technical
capabilities were more advanced.’ The engagement of émigrée policy advisors is
noted in the literature. However, the fact that Estonia’s exclusive monetary
reform committee included Jeffrey Sachs’s doctoral student Ardo Hansson
(hardly a senior representative of global academic or financial circles at the
time,) seems less a proof of powerful external influences than of a pre-existing
domestic consensus favouring radical solutions.
Since the technicalities and risks of monetary policy had been hardly intelli-
gible for politicians, let alone ordinary citizens, the origins of such consensus
are puzzling. ‘The fact that politicians that outwardly supported the currency
210
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
board were at the same time sure that after monetary reform the central bank
would continue to deliver ‘‘cheap credits’’ to inefficient factories and collective
farms indicates that many politicians probably never understood exactly what
they supported’ (Laar 2002: 121–2). How then could a socially particularly
costly variant of a ‘stability culture’ (Dyson 2002a) sink roots in Baltic soil?
The answer points to its close fit with ‘sentiments of wider resonance’,
especially the ‘collective commitment to nationhood . . . and independence’ (Landes
1991: 49, emphasis added).
According to Anderson (1991: 7, emphasis added), ‘regardless of the actual
inequality and exploitation that may prevail in each, the nation is always conceived
as a deep horizontal comradeship’. Regained freedom to ‘imagine’ and craft a
national community has enjoyed immense popularity in the Baltics over the
whole period of transformation (Lagerspetz and Vogt 2004). Stability culture
and trust in its guardians, the currency board, a balanced budget, and central
bankers, could become a cornerstone of national identity, especially as meas-
ures to foster national independence and transformation have been introduced
as part and parcel of the same policy package.
The link among identity politics, the monetary regime, and tolerance for
social hardship has been reinforced by the issue of a new currency, a core
means and symbol of sovereign statehood (Laar 2002: 125). The enthusiasm
with which the stable kroon was received elevated the symbolic status of the
monetary authority, and enhanced the popularity of central bankers as nation
builders. Institutional insulation of monetary policy resonated well with the
public sentiment that the cause of national independence ought to be removed
from the everyday struggles of democratic politics. It was on these grounds that
the Bank of Estonia governor in 1991–5, Siim Kallas, could build political
capital around his role as ‘father of the national currency’. Still in office, in
1994 he founded the Reform Party that came in second in the 1995 parliamen-
tary elections and remained politically influential afterwards (Smith 2002).
Kallas became minister of finance (1999–2002), prime minister (2002–3), and
Estonia’s EU Commissioner (2004).
‘De-politicization’ of monetary coordination has not been buttressed by
democratic means alone. In the early 1990s Estonia introduced restrictive
citizenship laws that deprived many ethnic Russian ‘losers of the transform-
ation’ of the right to oppose radical transformation by democratic vote
(Smith 2002). These measures muffled conflicts and relieved central banks
and other sites of public policy from losers’ pressures.
Identity politics cemented the hegemony of stability-oriented institutions in
yet other ways. Estonian policy makers refused to help troubled industrial firms
and banks by subsidies and grace periods for restructuring bad debts (Table 9.1).
Lack of protectionism, however, could be more easily justified on grounds of
perceived vulnerability of the national economy to post-colonial influences. In
Laar’s words, after 1940 a ‘large Soviet military garrison and the continued
211
Estonia, Hungary, and Slovenia: Banking on Identity
influx of Russian speaking colonists who acted like a ‘‘civilian garrison’’ re-
placed the lost population. In order to effect colonialization, rapid industrial-
ization was launched by Moscow’ (Laar 2002: 37). By implication, after
independence, since most managers and workers were ethnic Russians, radical
de-industrialization could be perceived as a means of de-colonialization. The
imminent atrophy of business and labour organizations has not been viewed
as too painful a loss, even if it led to highly fragmented industrial relations that
impaired the prospects for socially embedded coordination, and reinforced
exogenous monetary policy as the ‘only game in town’.
Furthermore, faced with the banking crises of the early 1990s and the tasks of
bank privatization, the Bank of Estonia acted as a substitute police force.
The government soon found out that it was not possible to compete against the influx of
Russian organized crime into Estonia with a police force which was still in the process of
being built up. And so the government had no alternative other than to try to weaken
organized crime by introducing a series of economic measures designed to cut its sources
of income and prevent its entry into the banking sector.
(Laar 2002: 191–3)
In consequence, the Bank of Estonia urged the demise and bankruptcy of banks
with suspicious portfolios by the abrupt withdrawal of public assets and setting
strict prudency standards. It also encouraged acquisitions by Western banks,
which rapidly emerged as ‘absolute market leaders’ (ibid.).
Slovenia
Since Slovenia faced a triple transformation to nation state, democracy, and
capitalism (Offe 1991), some factors that empowered Estonian central bankers
have been at work in Slovenia too. The new currency fostered identity through
its national imagery, replaced the cacophony of a multiple-currency regime
with ‘unity in ‘‘economic language’’ ’, and consolidated the ‘trustworthiness
of the institution that issued it or guaranteed its value’ (Helleiner 2003: 101,
112–13). However, the Bank of Slovenia has never acquired the unchallenged
hegemony of its counterpart in Estonia.
Unlike policy makers in Estonia, Slovene monetary strategists opted for a
separation between policies to achieve independence and to foster transform-
ation. ‘In the belief that the new country could start as a genuine market
economy’ banks and industrial firms were granted grace periods, subsidies,
and loans to adjust and restructure (ibid.). Over the 1990s, administrative
barriers hindered foreign takeover, especially in the banking sector. Consistent
with the above, macroeconomic independence had been sought by a ‘prag-
matic economic policy and a floating exchange rate system for the new cur-
rency . . . It was hoped that such a policy would result in smaller output losses
and lower unemployment by allowing some inflation’ (Mencinger 2004: 78).
212
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
This approach continued in the face of external advice. Although the same team
of foreign advisors, led by Sachs, proposed similar remedies to the economy’s
woes in Slovenia as in Estonia, namely, fixed exchange rates, radical stabiliza-
tion, liberalization, and privatization, their suggestions were ‘stubbornly
rejected’ in Slovenia (Mencinger 2004: 76).
Due to gradualism in commercial bank transnationalization, reserve require-
ments remained effective tools at the Bank of Slovenia’s disposal until (and
even beyond) the early 2000s when recurrent EU pressures ultimately forced
Slovenia to grant private and foreign capital freer access to its banks (Lindstrom
and Piroska 2007: table 1.3). Ironically, then, resistance to some of the top–
down pressures of accession Europeanization in the banking sector helped the
Bank of Slovenia to succeed in the main task of membership Europeanization:
full compliance with the Maastricht convergence criteria.
To a large extent, the divergence of Estonian and Slovene paths can be traced
to differences in legacies and their perceptions. First, in contrast to Estonia,
Slovenia did not have to build institutions of macroeconomic coordination
from scratch. Second, Slovene gradualists generally ‘considered the legacy of
the past an exploitable advantage’ (Mencinger 2004: 76). Domestic policy
makers’ credibility was enhanced by their competence acquired in the last
decades of Yugoslav communism when ‘many economists studied abroad,
acquiring a solid understanding of Western economics, and were therefore
not easily awed by foreign advisers’ (ibid.)
An important Yugoslav legacy was the long experience with workers’ self-
management that added a level of participatory decision making unknown in
other east central European states. Independent Slovenia embraced this legacy
and developed it into a system of negotiated industrial relations. Especially after
the initial recession removed from power the Right-wing coalition that won the
first parliamentary elections, ‘political exchange between centre-Left govern-
ments and organized economic interests became a permanent feature and the
key mode of interest concertation, giving social legitimacy to market reforms’
(Stanojevic 2003: 290). Centralized institutions of industrial relations strength-
ened cooperative social partners and mitigated the costs, and facilitated the
political acceptance, of stability-oriented monetary policies. In essence, encom-
passing social partnership has become the expression of a Europeanized and
inclusive variant of nationalism that did not perceive Slovenia as permanently
threatened by enemies from within and without.
For all these reasons, central bank independence and power emerged in the
context of a power-sharing arrangement with other important economic interests
and institutions. Above all, Slovene central bankers’ power originated from
their negotiated relationship with social partners. On the one hand, central
bank independence has become part and parcel of an inclusive and balanced
national agenda that successfully resisted external pressures for radicalism. On
the other hand, as Slovene nationalism unambiguously favoured a ‘return to
213
Estonia, Hungary, and Slovenia: Banking on Identity
Hungary
The Hungarian route to central bank independence is distinguished from the
Estonian path by its gradualism, and from the gradualist Slovene path by fierce
partisan struggles around central bank independence. Since the Hungarian
nation state and national currency survived communism, central bankers
could not pose in the role of nation builders. Nor could they gain power as
the monetary guardians of encompassing social partnership, as Hungary lacked
such institution. Essentially, Hungarian central bankers’ power depended on
partisan struggles mitigated by top–down pressures for Europeanization.
Similarly to Slovenia, Hungary inherited foundations of macroeconomic
coordination. Importantly, a two-tier system that separated the central bank
from commercial banks had been put in place as early as the second half of the
1980s. Indeed, from the early 1980s, market-oriented economic reforms and
the management of accumulated huge foreign debt had facilitated the integra-
tion of Hungarian financial technocracy into international networks. Fellow-
ships, conferences, debt negotiations, lobbying for new external resources,
education, and training grants were as important in fostering such linkages as
Hungary’s early IMF and World Bank membership. New skills were developed
during this integration process, such as familiarity with the logic of stabilization
programmes, statistical and analytical capacities, and negotiating with foreign
creditors and investors, skills that were even more badly needed after 1989.
One consequence was that Hungary’s shift to the monetary coordination of a
market economy could be relatively organic, gradualist, and ‘home-grown’,
similar to that of Slovenia. While the role of foreign assistance was more
accentuated before than after the collapse of communism, the task of main-
taining international creditworthiness has remained an important driving force
of the National Bank of Hungary’s Europeanization. Given the imperative of
foreign debt management, the reluctance with which central bank independ-
ence was adopted seems surprising.
The apparently weak support for a stability culture can be traced to the
fact that Hungarian elites and publics have not perceived the overarching
social purpose of transformation in terms of national identity or social
partnership. For historical reasons, the popular legitimating principle of
Hungarian capitalist democracy has been public social provision that typically
contradicted macroeconomic stability (Bohle and Greskovits 2007; Kornai
1996). As in the other two cases, initial choices take us far in understanding
the difference.
Hungarian reformers were well aware of the social hardship coming with
economic collapse and market reforms, but could not fall back upon identity
214
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
215
Estonia, Hungary, and Slovenia: Banking on Identity
How have the increasing pressures for sustainable compliance with the Maas-
tricht convergence criteria affected the fortunes of central banking around, and
especially after, EU accession? This section argues that central banks’ origins in
terms of power and the institutional features adopted in the course of preparing
for EU accession have had an impact on the dynamics of Europeanization after
membership.
In the early 2000s, all three central banks optimistically prepared for joining
ERM II in 2004 and changeover to the euro in 2007. However, only Slovenia
could introduce the euro as planned. The Bank of Slovenia mastered this task by
utilizing the same neocorporatist institutions that had shaped and helped its
Europeanization during the accession period. Uniquely in the region, in April
2003 Slovene social partners signed an encompassing pact on future wages and
216
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
217
Estonia, Hungary, and Slovenia: Banking on Identity
218
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Table 9.5. Hopes and fears about the euro in Estonia, Hungary, and Slovenia (% of answers)
Sources: Introduction of the Euro in the New Member States. Flash Eurobarometer November 2006, 2007. The
Gallup Organization—European Commission. Country Scorecards.
fears about the euro mainly in terms of identity. In concrete terms, more than
half of Estonians are concerned about loss of national identity (and a third
about loss of control over economic policy) associated with the changeover to
euro. Only a minority of Estonians expects to feel more European after the
adoption of Europe’s single currency. In the light of recent incapacity to sustain
macroeconomic stability, the fact that Estonians trust their central bank signifi-
cantly more than EU institutions as a source of reliable information on the euro
is no less ironic than Hungarians’ trust in EMU as an engine of fast growth and
employment. Nonetheless, such puzzles of trust and mistrust seem to support
those who believe in the power of ideas and even of misperceptions.
For the above reasons, the EMU project appears to be less compatible with
national agendas than central bank independence had been, and this conflict
impairs its public acceptance and political support. Bearing this in mind, it is less
than surprising that the euro has lost popularity all over the region. In Septem-
ber 2007 only less than half of Hungarians and hardly a third of Estonians were
happy with the prospect of having euro as their official currency (Table 9.5).
Indeed, in 2008 inflation accelerated and social protest intensified even in
Slovenia. A general strike in March 2008 signalled a possible end to wage
moderation and the strength of demands for convergence in real wages.
Conclusions
What do these cases reveal about central bank convergence, power, and Euro-
peanization? They show that the convergence of postcommunist central banks
219
Estonia, Hungary, and Slovenia: Banking on Identity
on the norms and standards of central bank independence paralleled and inter-
acted with processes of divergence. Varied configurations of central bank respon-
sibilities and policy instruments have emerged, along with distinctive patterns
of dominance, involving collaboration or rivalry with fiscal authorities, indus-
trial relations regimes, commercial banks, and political parties.
It follows that, although independence became a common key aspect of
central bankers’ identity and institutional power, their profile also responded
to particular political opportunity structures, placing them in the varied roles of
nation builders, social partners, and partisan agents. Accordingly, central bank
power has been as much shaped by perceived national vulnerability and
other sentiments of wider resonance, such as trust in social partnership or
demands for social welfare, as by their demonstrated technocratic competence
and international connectedness.
The chapter offers some lessons for students of Europeanization. One finding is
about its dynamics over time. Central banks’ origins of power and institutional
features adopted in the course of Europeanization before EU accession have had an
impact on the dynamics of Europeanization afterwards. In the case of Slovenia, the
former process reinforced the latter. Institutionalization of social partnership
during the transition period helped the Slovene central bank to complete Euro-
peanization by rapid euro entry. In the Estonian case, the opposite influence is
evident. Success in nation building and Europeanization leading to accession
empowered the central bank as Estonia’s most reputed economic institution.
However, public trust backfired after EU accession, since the central bank delayed
necessary institutional adjustment, even if on the route to euro entry the currency
board appears to be dysfunctional as the guardian of stability.
Finally, the chapter’s findings confirm earlier research on the interplay of
Europeanization processes across varied policy issue areas (Bohle and Greskovits
2006). Europeanization of economic policies is not a ‘seamless web’. Rather,
advance in one issue area might undermine or delay advance in another, and
thus simultaneous compliance ‘with everything’ might prove to be either
impossible or undesirable.
220
10
Czech Republic and Poland: The Limits
of Europeanization
Rachel Epstein and Juliet Johnson
221
Czech Republic and Poland: The Limits of Europeanization
222
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
223
Czech Republic and Poland: The Limits of Europeanization
By the time the Berlin Wall fell in 1989, a hard-won consensus had devel-
oped among international financial institutions, governments, and central
banks in the advanced industrial democracies on the importance of central
bank independence and price stability. As a result, during the early years of
transition, international institutions presented a unified policy front to post-
communist governments. A wide range of external actors such as the IMF,
the World Bank, USAID, the Bank for International Settlements (BIS), and
central banks such as the Bundesbank and the Bank of England came to-
gether to encourage post-communist states to create independent central
banks. They not only promulgated the twin mantras of central bank inde-
pendence and price stability, but also provided the technical assistance and
training necessary to put these ideals into practice. This assistance included
everything from IMF missions and resident experts to sophisticated training
programmes designed for post-communist central bankers. For example,
approximately 4,500 central bankers from the 10 post-communist states
that would later join the EU took part in training courses at the Bank of
England’s Centre for Central Banking Studies (CCBS), the Joint Vienna Insti-
tute (JVI), and the IMF Institute between 1991 and 2000 (Figure 10.1). The
Polish and Czech central banks were among the leading recipients of this
training. By the end of 1993, over 300 of their central bankers had already
taken a CCBS, JVI, or IMF course.
The EU itself did not become significantly involved with central bank
transformation until later, when EU enlargement came onto the agenda
and the European Central Bank (ECB) began operations. The ECB then
worked to harmonize the relevant accession-state legislation with the EU
acquis communautaire (which requires a high level of central bank independ-
ence), to improve central bank operations, to upgrade payment and settle-
ment systems to EU standards, and to ensure consistency of statistics and
IT infrastructure and applications with current EU members. EU accession
conditionality reinforced domestic commitment to these efforts, but the
possibility of future EU membership did not represent the initial or primary
impetus for change. The transformation of post-communist central banks
into independent guardians of price stability thus represented not so much
Europeanization as internationalization, with central banks adapting to
an established international model. As we discuss below, in Poland and
the Czech Republic the concerted, credible efforts of international institu-
tions to promote central bank independence practically guaranteed success
in the face of domestic uncertainty over appropriate post-1989 policy
choices.
224
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
800
700
600
Number of participants
500
400
300
200
100
ia
lic
a
a
ia
ia
lic
ia
ry
nd
ni
ni
en
ar
tv
an
ub
ub
ga
to
ua
la
La
lg
ov
om
ep
ep
un
Es
Po
th
Bu
Sl
R
R
Li
ak
ch
ov
ze
Sl
C
Figure 10.1. Central bank participants in CCBS, JVI, and IMF institute courses, 1991–
2000
Source: Data provided to the authors by the CCBS, JVI, and IMF.
Poland
By the close of 1997, the National Bank of Poland (NBP) was among the most
independent central banks in the world (Cukierman, Miller, and Neyapti
2002). Two sets of legislation, in 1990 and 1997, as well as the adoption of a
new constitution in 1997 that supported central bank independence and price
stability resulted from domestic political conflicts in which Polish supporters
of central bank independence prevailed. The internationalization of Polish
monetary and bank regulatory policy was in turn linked to international
institutions’ consistent involvement in Polish economic reform. Indeed, a
transnational coalition overpowered a serious challenge to central bank inde-
pendence in the mid-1990s, which led to further institutionalization of inter-
national norms towards the end of the decade.
Polish actor uncertainty was strongest in the first four years of the transition
when post-communist states experimented with approaches to macroeco-
nomic stabilization and the introduction of markets. There is evidence of
Polish uncertainty regarding how to structure the central bank and of the
225
Czech Republic and Poland: The Limits of Europeanization
226
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
responsibilities were ‘not confined to those of God and History’ but were also
to ‘society and the national economy’, he took aim at what he called ‘exces-
sively restrictive monetary policy’.3 He also lamented the fact that power
within the NBP was, in his view, dangerously centralized with respect to
monetary policy and bank regulation. Finally, Kołodko complained that the
Ministry was never consulted on major central bank policy shifts (interview
with Kołodko). As a potential remedy to these perceived problems, the SLD–
PSL coalition tabled legislation to increase political control over the central
bank (particularly through appointments), remove its regulatory authority,
and loosen limits on central bank lending to the government.4
The government’s legislation drew an immediate and negative reaction
among Poland’s external advisors. At this point international actors had no
more central bank independence-related conditionality agreements pending,
while EU membership was not explicitly tied to the nuances of central bank
governance at that time. Lacking any ‘hard’ tools of enforcement, IMF, World
Bank, and USAID representatives turned first to their Polish allies, including
those who had been heavily influenced by international financial institutions’
training. A transnational coalition comprising international financial institu-
tions’ officials, Gronkiewicz-Waltz, Śleszyñska-Charewicz, and politicians
from the Freedom Union party (chaired by Leszek Balcerowicz) worked to-
gether to perfect arguments in defence of central bank independence to pre-
sent to the public and the Sejm. In addition, the international financial
institutions contributed to alternative legislation to insure that legal changes
would reflect international trends towards greater central bank independence.
The Freedom Union ultimately put forward that legislation. Finally, in public
settings, the international financial institutions and the EU lobbied heavily
against the SLD–PSL legislation, which undermined its legitimacy in Poland.
After more than a year of political conflict, the Freedom Union’s central
bank independence-preserving legislation prevailed, while the SLD–PSL pro-
posals were ‘quietly shelved’.5 This was a surprising outcome, not least because
the SLD–PSL coalition had an overwhelming majority in the Sejm. But it is
explicable because of the overwhelming rejection of the SLD–PSL legislation
by the international financial institutions and the EU. Given their unified pro-
central bank independence position and the increasing consistency in West-
ern practice, Poland’s external advisors had enormous credibility. Although
Poland’s EU membership or access to financial assistance was not at stake, the
potential reputational costs of violating international norms were sufficiently
threatening to cause Poland’s communist successors to relent. In 1997, the
Sejm approved a new constitution in which central bank independence was
further institutionalized, including clarifying the president’s role in selecting
the NBP chair and banning government borrowing from the central bank.6
Thus central bank independence was institutionally stronger in the wake of
the conflict (Cukierman, Miller, and Neyapti 2002: 242).
227
Czech Republic and Poland: The Limits of Europeanization
Czech Republic
As in Poland, Czech policy makers turned to international models and assist-
ance to transform their central banking institutions. The November 1989
Velvet Revolution initiated a sharp break with the previous regime, bringing
to power individuals with a strong commitment to political democracy and
economic liberalization. Like the NBP, the Czech National Bank (CNB) quickly
became one of the world’s most independent central banks (Neyapti 2001).
The CNB took advantage of foreign expertise and encouragement to transform
itself into a formidable, capable institution. As a result, again like the NBP, the
CNB later defeated a serious challenge to its independence. By the time the
Czech Republic entered the EU, the CNB had already become a respected
member of the international central banking community.
The transition empowered a small circle of neo-liberal Czech economists
such as Václav Klaus, then a leading figure in the Civic Forum, and Josef
Tošovský, named governor of the Czechoslovak State Bank (CSSB) in January
1990. These individuals had internalized the international central banking
consensus through their studies and experiences abroad in the 1980s, and
looked to international institutions to legitimize and assist efforts to transform
the CSSB along these lines. Beyond this small circle, however, few domestic
actors held strong opinions about central bank independence, and its ramifi-
cations were not widely understood. Therefore, its international legitimacy
and clear break from the communist past made implementing the initial
changes relatively uncontroversial.
An interim central banking law came into force on 1 January 1990, but did
not include central bank independence. Uncertain policy makers quickly
brought international expertise to bear upon the process of revision. The
IMF and the World Bank advised the government on drafting a new Law on
the CSSB during 1990–1, one modelled heavily on the Bundesbank. This law,
which passed nearly unanimously on 20 December 1991, and took effect on 1
February 1992, established central bank independence and made currency
stability the CNB’s primary aim (Mataj and Vojtı́šek 1992). As a leading
Czech economist noted, ‘passage of the Act in this form confirms how rapidly
a political consensus has been achieved regarding the positive significance of
central bank independence on currency stability in this country’ (Pospı́šil
1996). After the Velvet Divorce separating the Czech and Slovak Republics,
the new Czech constitution and Act on the CNB (both of which came into
force on 1 January 1993) further institutionalized the CNB’s economic role and
independence, and transferred the rights and duties of the CSSB to the CNB.7
The CNB also kept most high-level personnel from the CSSB, making the
transition from CSSB to CNB nearly seamless in the Czech Republic.
The CSSB under Tošovský’s leadership also took advantage of international
technical assistance and training. As Vladimir Valach, CSSB first deputy
228
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
chairman, observed, ‘On 1st January 1990, development became much faster.
The whole top management of the new federal Central Bank changed. . . . I got
the chance to be at the centre of an unrepeatable process of bank reform, of the
ferment of seeking new routes, approaches and mechanisms’ (Valach 2004).
The CSSB sought these new approaches in the West. One Czech central banker
stated strongly that ‘We didn’t hesitate. We knew we had to join the West. . . .
In the CNB, these changes are Tošovský’s work. He constituted the bank as a
typical Western European bank. He took the structure, methods, and technical
ways of the West and put them in the CNB’ (personal interview, 2000). With a
lack of experience and training, the central bankers relied heavily on the
assistance efforts of international institutions and central banks (Czech
National Bank 2003; Tůma 2004). By the mid-1990s, the CNB had firmly
adopted the norms and practices of the international central banking commu-
nity. As in Poland, the CNB’s international support would prove vital in defend-
ing central bank independence against a domestic political attack.
The CNB’s formerly secure status became politicized after an exchange-rate
crisis in May 1997 forced the CNB to abandon its exchange-rate peg and signifi-
cantly raise interest rates. The ensuing economic turmoil contributed to the
resignation of Prime Minister Václav Klaus (by then head of the Civic Democratic
Party, ODS) and his temporary replacement by CNB governor Tošovský in Decem-
ber 1997. Tošovský led a caretaker government until Miloš Zeman’s newly elected
Social-Democratic (CSSD) minority government took power in July 1998. Cir-
cumstances surrounding the 1997 events turned both Klaus and Zeman against
the CNB. Klaus blamed the CNB’s tight monetary policy for the 1997 crisis and his
own political troubles, while Zeman blamed the same restrictive CNB policies for
the Czech Republic’s slow post-crisis recovery (Bönker 2006; Klaus 2000).
Ironically, Zeman and Klaus used the need to harmonize the Act on the CNB
with the EU acquis in 2000 to rein in the independence of the central bank. In
preparing the Act’s amendment, Klaus’s ODS introduced new limitations on
the CNB, including a requirement to set the inflation target in consultation
with the government, to get parliamentary approval of the CNB budget, and to
get governmental approval of the president’s choice for the CNB governor and
board. Zeman’s government accepted Klaus’s proposals in June 2000. The IMF,
ECB, and European Commission all spoke out against the draft amendment, as
did the CNB and President Václav Havel. Nevertheless, the CSSD and ODS-
dominated parliament not only passed the amendment, but overrode Havel’s
veto. The revised Act on the CNB took effect in January 2001. It briefly seemed
as if central bank independence had suffered a devastating blow in the Czech
Republic.
The influence of international institutions ultimately foiled Klaus and
Zeman’s efforts, however, as the CNB’s protected constitutional status and
EU accession pressures undid the amendment’s damage to central bank inde-
pendence. The first strand unravelled as Zeman unwittingly pushed his luck
229
Czech Republic and Poland: The Limits of Europeanization
with the CNB. In November 2000, Tošovský resigned from the CNB to head the
Financial Stability Institute at the Bank for International Settlements, and
President Havel appointed Zdenek Tůma as his replacement. The Zeman
government appealed the appointment to the Constitutional Court, arguing
that the appointment should have required governmental approval. In re-
sponse, the Constitutional Court not only rejected the government’s petition,
but declared that the portion of the amendment on appointments violated the
CNB’s independence and was thus unconstitutional. The 1993 Constitution’s
protections for central bank independence, inspired by international experi-
ence and advice, had successfully shielded the CNB from this challenge seven
years later. Then, under pressure from the EU—which argued that the other
ODS-sponsored parts of the 2000 amendment contradicted the acquis—a new
amendment fully restoring the CNB’s previous status came into effect in May
2002. In the end, the Act on the CNB protected the CNB’s independence,
changed its primary objective to price stability, and prohibited it from provid-
ing short-term credit to the government. As a result, like in Poland, Czech
central bank independence emerged from this challenge strengthened both in
law and in practice.
230
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
investors pushed the east central European states to develop euro entry strat-
egies, with firm time commitments, even before these states had become EU
members (Bönker 2006). On the other hand, the ECB strongly discouraged the
new member states from pursuing rapid euro entry. ECB president Jean-Claude
Trichet even argued, somewhat pedantically, that east central European states
were akin to young but underdeveloped athletes seeking to join a ‘champion
league’ before they were fit.8 Given existing troubles in the Euro Area, and the
increased risks of financial instability that expansion would present, the ECB
was wary of bringing in new members who may not be completely prepared.
Western central bankers and economists have sent similarly mixed messages.
Some advocated rapid adoption or even unilateral euroization (Breuss, Fink,
and Haiss 2004; Buiter 2004; Eichengreen 2003; Schoors 2002), while others
urged great caution and lengthy postponements (Begg 2006; Dumke and
Sherman 2000; Égert, Gruber, and Reininger 2003; Krenzler and Senior Nello
1999). On institutionalizing central bank independence, there were never
such disagreements among external advisors to east central Europe.
International actors faced perhaps the greatest credibility challenge regard-
ing the mandated process of euro adoption: fulfilling the Maastricht conver-
gence criteria. Although EU accession states committed to joining the Euro
Area at some future date, there is no fixed timetable or deadline for doing so.
The European Commission and the ECB insisted that the east central European
new member states meet the Maastricht criteria to the letter before Euro Area
accession. However, other external actors widely criticized the criteria as being
too restrictive, especially the requirement that the fast-growing prospective
Euro Area members both maintain very low inflation rates and remain in the
ERM II pegged exchange-rate regime for at least two years. The ECB has
explained this requirement as the best method available for ascertaining the
appropriate convergence rate between national currencies and the euro to
prevent destabilization upon entry to the euro zone or after. But despite this
rationale, an IMF report otherwise praising the ECB argued that ‘the Maastricht
criteria—specifically the inflation criterion together with the exchange rate
stability criterion—could be overly binding for the CECs’ (Schadler et al. 2005).
Moreover, unlike with central bank independence, in the case of euro entry
the central bank internationalization and Europeanization processes conflict.
Best practice in international central banking calls for inflation-targeting
monetary policy regimes. Both Poland and the Czech Republic became infla-
tion targeters in 1998, well before their 2004 EU entry. Indeed, the ECB itself is
an informal inflation targeter. Entering ERM II would force east central Euro-
pean central bankers to revert to a less flexible peg.
In short, international institutions have little credibility with Polish and
Czech policy makers on the euro entry issue because of their inconsistent
advice and actions regarding the desirability, timing, and mechanisms of
adoption. This lack of credibility left the door open for domestic debates
231
Czech Republic and Poland: The Limits of Europeanization
about the euro in Poland and the Czech Republic, battles which confident east
central European policy makers, central bankers, academics, and populaces
were by that time relatively well-equipped to wage.
Poland
Whereas international institutions exercised substantial authority over central
bank structures and the terms of debate concerning central bank independ-
ence and price stability from 1989 until 1997, external actors, and particularly
the EU and ECB, largely failed to facilitate Poland’s rapid convergence with
Euro Area membership criteria. Although monetary indicators have been
moving in the right direction, fiscal measures have not. Because of the absence
of domestic actor uncertainty and lack of euro credibility by the late 1990s and
early 2000s, the contours of conflict on this issue evolved, not between polit-
ical parties, but instead between the central bank and politicians—from across
the political spectrum. Central bank–government conflict has essentially
resulted in a stalemate with no immediate prospects for euro entry. This
development occurred because Poland’s central bankers, who generally favour
euro entry, are no longer empowered by international institutions’ credibility,
changing the domestic balance of power. In the battle with successive govern-
ments, central bankers have become relatively weaker on the question of
European monetary integration.
Since 1997 when the NBP’s independence was strengthened, the central
bank has been in a strong position to pursue EMU convergence on the mon-
etary side, even as it has had virtually no power to persuade politicians to meet
the fiscal requirements. NBP governors Gronkiewicz-Waltz until 2000 and
Leszek Balcerowicz (2000–7) have been inflation hawks (along with their
Monetary Policy Councils, a result of the 1997 legislation). Between 1997
and 2004, the central bank at times used restrictive monetary policy to try to
negotiate out of successive Polish governments commitments to fiscal austerity
(Zubek 2006). One such episode became so heated that the centre–left SLD–
UP–PSL governing coalition threatened in 2001 and 2002 to limit the bank’s
independence, a proposal that ultimately went nowhere (Epstein 2002).
Motivated in large measure by the perceived benefits of macroeconomic
stability and the structural reforms that EMU convergence would require,
the Polish central bank has been a strong supporter of early euro entry. Indeed
in 2002, Balcerowicz had plans for Poland to join ERM II by 2004 in hopes of
adopting the euro by 2007. That timetable, as well as subsequent central bank
aspirations, fell by the wayside.
While the central bank has been eager, politicians have been unwilling to
undertake the structural reforms that would cut annual government outlays,
even though the 1997 constitution limits government debt to the 60 per cent of
GDP prescribed by the Maastricht convergence criteria. For Poland, the state’s
232
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
233
Czech Republic and Poland: The Limits of Europeanization
Czech Republic
The Czech experience with the euro shares much in common with that of
Poland. International actors lacked credibility on this issue in the Czech
Republic, and so could do little to effectively support the Czech National
Bank in its push for early euro entry. As in Poland, the CNB retained its
reputation as an inflation hawk, but Czech politicians could not maintain
conservative fiscal policies. The CNB also faced an additional obstacle in the
person of Vaclav Klaus, a long-time Euro-sceptic and CNB foe, who used his
influence to undermine the CNB’s early euro entry efforts. As a result, not only
did the CNB lose a key battle over early euro entry in 2004–5, but the CNB itself
became divided over how quickly to introduce the euro.
The independent CNB under both Tošovský and Tůma avidly pursued mon-
etary convergence with Europe. Since moving to its inflation targeting regime
in 1998, it has kept a tight hold on monetary policy, to the chagrin of many
Czech politicians, academics, and businesspeople. Geršl (2006) found in a
survey of articles in the leading Czech financial newspaper from 1997 to
2005 that every government comment expressing dissatisfaction with the
CNB signalled the CNB to ease monetary policy. The signals from other
interest groups did the same: the financial sector (70%), employers (100%),
unions (100%), and ‘others’ (96.5%). The CNB resisted this pressure, and by
2002 Czech inflation met the Maastricht convergence target.
In contrast, the Czech Republic began running significant fiscal deficits after
the 1997 crisis, reaching a high of 11.3 per cent in 2003—the largest deficit
among the prospective EU new member states. The CNB felt powerless to
restrain politicians on its own, so it promoted early euro entry to impose fiscal
discipline on the government (Johnson 2006). However, the CNB found itself
in a relatively weak position to fight for the euro, because of both the lack of
outside support from the ECB and its own sharp criticism of the Maastricht
criteria, especially ERM II.11 In short, the CNB berated the government for not
meeting one set of the Maastricht convergence criteria, while itself challen-
ging the legitimacy of another. This position did not raise the credibility of
either the CNB or the euro entry process.
Without useful levers of international influence, the CNB faced difficulty in
rallying domestic support for its euro entry campaign from either of the largest
Czech political parties. The leftist CSSD generally approved of Europe but
preferred higher social spending than meeting the Maastricht fiscal criteria
would allow. On the other hand, while Klaus’s centre–right ODS party sup-
ported fiscal rectitude, it also had a deep Euro-sceptic streak. Klaus in particular
often berated European ‘socialism’ and questioned the efficacy and desirability
of the Euro Area. To make matters worse for the CNB, Klaus succeeded Vaclav
Havel as Czech president in February 2003, ironically giving him the sole
appointment power over the CNB governor and board members that he had
234
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
fought to take away from the presidency just a few years earlier. Finally, the
divided electorate repeatedly forced Czech parliamentarians to form tenuous
governing coalitions or to rule as minority governments, with little mandate
for or ability to implement fundamental policy reforms. As a result, the
appropriate timing of euro entry became an issue of heated political debate,
with conflict coming to a head over the Czech euro entry strategy.
In its draft strategy of December 2002, the CNB ambitiously suggested 2007
as the Czech Republic’s target entry date.12 Although new CSSD Prime Minis-
ter Vladimı́r Špidla was willing to use the Maastricht criteria as an excuse for
stepping up fiscal reforms, many in his own party failed to support him. The
government also feared making a euro entry strategy public until after the June
2003 Czech EU referendum, given the relatively Euro-sceptic Czech public
(Bönker 2006). As a result, months of discussion followed, during which the
CNB criticized the Špidla government for badly missing its fiscal deficit targets
and not taking the Maastricht criteria seriously. President Klaus hit back by
criticizing the CNB’s inflation targeting as ‘fiction’ and stating that it would be
‘unwise’ to adopt the euro.13
In September 2003, the CNB and the government finally agreed on a revised
strategy, one which represented a significant compromise for the CNB.14 It
stated that joining the Euro Area in 2007 would not be possible because ‘the
current outlook . . . does not indicate that the public budget deficit criterion
will be fulfilled by [June 2006]’, and it revised the expected entry date to 2009–10
at the earliest. Even this agreement proved unsustainable, however, and tensions
grew as the government continued to spend in excess of the promised targets.
Persistent high deficits exacerbated by another spate of pre-election spending in
mid-2006 finally forced a complete revision of the strategy in August 2007.
Despite the protests of CNB governor Tůma and Finance Minister Miroslav
Kalousek, the revised strategy did not set a new target date for euro entry. ODS
Prime Minister Miroslav Topolanek said that he refused to set a date because
his tenuous government –with 100 ODS deputies plus their smaller coalition
partners facing off against 100 CSSD opposition deputies—could not ensure
long-term compliance with its plans for fiscal reform.15
Not only did the CNB lose the political battle over early euro entry, but its
pro-euro stance has been undermined from within. When the terms of three
CNB board members expired in February 2005, President Klaus replaced them
with close allies and fellow Euro-sceptics. Klaus did so again in November
2006, when he replaced two more outgoing board members with like-minded
economists. Afterwards, only Governor Tůma and Vice-Governor Niedemeyer
remained from the seven-member board that had approved the CNB’s initial
ambitious euro strategy in 2002. Once on the board, the Klaus appointees
publicly spoke with great wariness about the euro. For example, Mojmir
Hampl urged caution and argued that successful euro entry did not represent
a meaningful measure of a country’s economic health.16 Faced with challenges
235
Czech Republic and Poland: The Limits of Europeanization
from without and within, Tůma simply stated that the timing of Czech Euro-
Area entry is now ‘a political decision’.17
The Czech and Polish central banks have, in a surprisingly short period of
time, converged with European central banks in terms of internationally
accepted norms and practices. Both eagerly defend central bank independence
and their inflation-targeting regimes. Both have developed sophisticated eco-
nomic modelling and research capabilities. Both have ensured that their
states’ central banking legislation, payment systems, statistical departments,
and so forth substantially comply with international best practice and
EU/ESCB requirements. The international consensus on the value of these
developments and international assistance to achieve them made it possible
to transform these central banks. Importantly, this transformation took place
primarily immediately after the transition when domestic actor uncertainty
was at its height.
In addition, because central bank independence was firmly institutionalized
in this early era, and reinforced by international practice and pressures, it
became difficult for domestic political leaders to overturn it later. The com-
bination of the institutionalization of central bank independence, the devel-
opment of extensive economic expertise within the central banks, and the
active support of an influential transnational community of central bankers
sharing the same beliefs and responsibilities, have dramatically increased the
domestic power of east central European central banks. In a short period of
time, they moved from simple communist-era accounting bureaucracies to
prestigious and influential domestic economic policy makers.
But ironically, internationalization also gave east central European central
bankers the tools with which to challenge certain aspects of Europeanization.
Polish and Czech central bankers critique European practices with great
authority. They are not willing to accept ECB arguments in favour of the
inflation criterion or ERM II membership at face value, and they forcefully
upbraid the EU for not enforcing the fiscal rules of the Stability and Growth
Pact. Moreover, they are wary of giving up their flexible inflation-targeting
regimes without the promise of rapid euro entry in return. In short, they
behave just as national central bankers in Western Europe or in North America
would. In this sense, the NBP and CNB have experienced significant conver-
gence with Europe.
Yet, although Czech and Polish central banks have gained enormous stature
at the international level, their power has not increased commensurately at
either the European or domestic levels. The east central European central
bankers have been unable to alter the terms of debate on euro entry and will
236
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
clearly remain (and be treated as) junior partners at the ECB and in the ESCB.
As a result, Czech and Polish central bankers have defended early euro entry,
but without international support and, increasingly, without as much enthu-
siasm. Although the CNB and NBP promote the positive aspects of euro entry
in order to press fiscal restraint on their governments, the central bankers
themselves appreciate very well the arguments both for and against entering
the euro in the near term. They resent the ECB and EU for their inflexibility
and inconsistency on the Maastricht convergence criteria, and have become
more reluctant to spend their limited political capital on shooting at a moving
goalpost.
This situation in turn ultimately threatens the power of European central
banking. The EU and ECB are divided between the ‘in’ Euro-Area states and the
‘out’ states. For European central bankers to speak with a common and power-
ful voice in the face of increasing challenges to central bank authority from
politicians and markets, and for east central European central banks to retain
their hard-won domestic influence and credibility, the EU cannot afford to
long exclude the largest of its new member states from the ‘euro club’.
Notes
1. For further elaboration on these variables across a range of issues, see Epstein (2008).
2. The UK and Denmark have legal ‘opt-outs’ negotiated into the Maastricht Treaty.
Sweden is under obligation to join, and plans to hold a referendum on the issue in
2012.
3. G. Kołodko, ‘Central Bank Responsibilities: Not Only to God and History’, Polish
News Bulletin, 6 September 1994. Also see ‘Between Inflation and Recession: A
Dispute over Interest Rates’, Polish Press Agency, 30 September 1994.
4. See the ‘Central Bank Facing Changes’, Polish News Bulletin, 20 September 1995; and
K. Kowalczyk, ‘The NBP’s Fortress’, Polish News Bulletin, 5 October 1995.
5. K. Bobinski, ‘Survey—Poland: The Central Bank’, Financial Times, 26 March 1997: 4.
6. See the Constitution of the Republic of Poland, Article 227 and Article 220–2.
7. 1993 Constitution of the Czech Republic, Chapter 6, Article 68.
8. J.-C. Trichet, ‘Looking at EU and Euro Area Enlargement from a Central Banker’s
Angle: The Views of the ECB’, speech at the Diplomatic Institute, Sofia, 27 February
2006.
9. This data come from Economist Intelligence Unit: Poland, 10 July 2007.
10. ‘NBP Head Skrzypek Expects Euro Adoption Not Before 2012, Wants Fast ERM II
Path’, Poland Today, 25 September 2007.
11. See Z. Tuma, ‘Europe’s Club of Nations Needs a Rule Change’, Financial Times,
4 January 2007.
12. Czech National Bank, ‘The Czech Republic and the Euro—Draft Accession Strategy’,
23 December 2002, www.cnb.cz.
237
Czech Republic and Poland: The Limits of Europeanization
13. ‘Klaus Says Deflation in Czech Rep Not Good, Blames CNB’, CTK Business News,
22 April 2003.
14. The Czech Government and the Czech National Bank, ‘The Czech Republic’s Euro-
area Accession Strategy’, September 2003, www.cnb.cz.
15. ‘Czech Euro Strategy Says Public Finances Still Hamper Adoption’, CTK Business
News, 27 August 2007.
16. ‘Czech Central Banker Urges Patience in Shift to Euro Zone’, Dow Jones International
News, 19 October 2007.
17. ‘Czech Central Banker: Euro-Zone Entry Is Political Decision-Report’, Dow Jones
International News, 5 November 2007.
238
Part IV
‘Semi-Permanent’ Outsiders
This page intentionally left blank
11
Bank of England: Learning
to Live with the Euro
Charles Goodhart1
1997 was a climacteric year for the Bank of England, and for political
developments in the UK. In early May, the Labour Party won a resounding
General Election victory. Thirteen years of Conservative government came to a
crashing end, marked in the years since 1992 by internal infighting between
euro-sceptics and euro-philes.
Within a week the incoming Chancellor of the Exchequer, Gordon Brown,
had awarded the Bank of England operational independence,2 and within
two weeks had stripped it of its role in both banking supervision and debt
management.3
Prior to the departure of the UK from the Exchange Rate Mechanism in
September 1992, the Bank had been one of the more subservient central banks,
in the sense that the key (interest rate) decisions for determining macro-monet-
ary policy were taken by the Chancellor, often after consultation with the Prime
Minister. The Bank could, and did, advise on these, in private and behind the
scenes, and was often influential; but the politicians and, especially, the Treasury
kept pressure on the Bank not to reveal publicly when the Bank’s advice differed
from the action taken. The Bank was discouraged from publishing its own
forecast, (for fear of commentators focussing on discrepancies between the two,
Bank and HMT, forecasts), and its Quarterly Bulletin Assessments were submitted
to, read, and sometimes censored by HMT.
In the 1980s and 1990s, the Bank had three core purposes (CP). As articulated in
the Annual Report of 1997, they were the following:
1. Maintaining the integrity and value of the currency. Above all, this
involves securing price stability as a precondition for achieving the wider
241
Bank of England: Learning to Live with the Euro
economic goals of sustainable growth and employment. The Bank does this
by influencing decisions on interest rates, on the basis of economic and
financial analysis of development both at home and abroad; by participating
in international discussions to promote the health of the world economy;
by implementing agreed policy through its market operations and its deal-
ings with the financial system; and by maintaining confidence in the
note issue.
2. Maintaining the stability of the financial system, both domestic and
international. The Bank seeks to achieve this through supervising individual
institutions and markets; through monitoring the links between financial mar-
kets; through analysing the health of the domestic and international economy;
through co-operation with other financial supervisors, both nationally and
internationally; and through promoting sound and efficient payment and
settlement arrangements. In exceptional circumstances, the Bank may also
provide or organise last resort financial support where this is needed to avoid
systemic damage.
3. Seeking to ensure the effectiveness of the UK’s financial services. The
UK needs a financial system that offers opportunities for firms of all sizes to
have access to capital on terms that give adequate protection to investors, and
which enhances the international competitive position of the City of London
and other UK financial centres. The Bank aims to achieve these goals through its
expertise in the market place; by acting as a catalyst to collective action where
market forces alone are deficient; by supporting the development of a financial
infrastructure that furthers these goals; by advising HM Government; and by
encouraging British interests through its contacts with financial authorities
overseas.
So long as the Bank remained subservient, its ability to influence, and its
contribution to, CP1 (i.e. to maintain price stability) remained limited. Not
surprisingly therefore, it invested more of its energies into CP2 (maintaining
financial stability), and CP3 (enhancing the efficiency and role of the UK’s
financial system in general, and of the City of London in particular). With the
abolition of exchange control, the ending of the building societies’ cartel, and of
restrictive practices in the London Stock Exchange (Big Bang) the 1980s was the
heyday of CP3. The government was strongly supportive, but the Bank played a
major effective role (David Walker being one of the key protagonists in the
Bank). During the 1970s and 1980s, banking supervision (CP2) became the
fastest growing part of the Bank, though a series of crises—fringe bank crisis,
1973–4; Johnson-Matthey Bank failure, 1984; Barings, 1995; and BCCI, 1991—
seriously tarnished its reputation in the eyes of many external commentators.
After the UK had been forced out of the ERM, the then Chancellor, Norman
Lamont, adopted the strategy of inflation targetry in October 1992. This new
242
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
strategy was announced and implemented with remarkable speed after the ERM
exit. But, after the relative failures of the government’s earlier monetary target-
ing strategy (the Medium-Term Financial Strategy, MTFS, 1979–85) and of its
external peg strategy (1988–92), the government itself had little credibility left.
As an expert, non-political institution the Bank did have credibility. So Lamont
turned to the Bank to provide independent support, by now requiring it to
publish its Inflation Report (without any prior censorship). A few years later,
Ken Clarke as Chancellor reinforced this by having the Governor’s advice
published verbatim in the ‘Ken and Eddie show’ (Eddie George being the then
Governor). All this is detailed at much greater length in Goodhart (2008).
But these changes to the role and status of the Bank were comparatively
small, in contrast to the devolution of operational independence to the Mon-
etary Policy Committee of the Bank of England in May 1997. Suddenly this
elevated the role of CP1, and the decision on interest rates, to primacy in the
Bank. Meanwhile, the removal of banking supervision to the Financial Services
Authority simultaneously led to a downgrading in the importance of CP2.4
At a stroke, the role of the Bank had been shifted from one in which they
were akin to central banks on the Continent (such as the Banca d’Italia and
Banco de España), with little role in macro-monetary policy because of the
ERM, but a large role in banking supervision, to bring it to a position like the
Bundesbank, with monetary policy autonomy and a much lower profile on
financial stability issues.
Amongst continental central banks the Bundesbank was the ‘big loser’ in the
shift to the European System of Central Banks (ESCB). But, if the Bundesbank
had opposed the creation of the ESCB, it is doubtful whether the German
people, or their legislature (Bundesrat and Bundestag), would have approved
it. Largely in order to gain the (reluctant) assent of the Bundesbank to the
launch of the ESCB (and the euro), the Bundesbank was, in effect, enabled
to shape the ESCB and ECB in its own image (or so it is widely believed in the
UK). This involved features such as almost total independence from govern-
ment, (indeed much more so than the Bundesbank had), considerable goal
independence to decide its own definition of price stability, a prominent ‘mon-
etary’ pillar, and a collegiate, consensual approach to decision-making.
All this was quite at odds with the British approach, which followed on
from the initial New Zealand model in many respects. This latter model allowed
the Bank of England operational independence, but no goal independence,
emphasizing the focus on an inflation target, set by the Chancellor. Decision-
making was to be individualistic, and, so the British contend, much more
transparent than that of the Governing Council of the European Central
Bank. These differences of viewpoint are highlighted in the entertaining
papers by Buiter (1999) and Issing (1999). The then Chancellor, Gordon
Brown, is believed to be (justly) proud of the constitutional structure that he
243
Bank of England: Learning to Live with the Euro
set out for the Bank and for the conduct of monetary policy, as codified by the
Bank of England Act 1998. He, and many others in the UK, believes this struc-
ture to be superior to the German model adopted for the ECB. That may be one
of the reasons for Brown’s supposed coolness towards joining the Euro Area.
Be that as it may, by his regime change in May 1997 Brown revised the role of
the Bank from one in which its position and status would not be greatly altered
by entry into the Euro Area to one in which it too would be a ‘big loser’.
Everyone knew this, at least at the back of their minds. Nevertheless the Bank
prided itself, and rightly so, on the professionalism, expertise, and independ-
ence of its staff. Whatever the implications for the Bank itself, the case—the
benefits and disadvantages—of UK entry into the euro were carefully and fairly
laid out by its economic research staff, notably its Chief Economists, John
Flemming followed by Mervyn King. I was not myself working in the Bank in
those years, but my (reasonably well-informed) understanding was that there
was much the same balance of euro-philes and euro-sceptics in the Bank, both
after 1997 as well as before, as in the intelligentsia as a whole.
There were two major reasons why the Bank would have found it extremely
difficult to have expressed an overt view/position on the merits of euro entry,
prior to the government itself coming to a decision on the economic merits of
the case. First, it was a major, strategic political decision. As public-sector
officials, the Bank had to be prepared wholeheartedly to implement whatever
people and government decided to do. Taking a clear, overt position could leave
the Bank in a very exposed position if the decision went the other way. Second,
there was an obvious potential conflict of interest, especially after May 1997.
The Bank’s own role would now have been dramatically affected by entry.
Under these circumstances any public position-taking, especially if advocating
staying outside, could have been attacked as self-seeking.5
So, from a fairly early stage, certainly by 1997, the Bank’s strategy was
decided. The Bank would not give any view on the overall question, whether
or not UK entry into the Euro Area would be desirable. Thus, in his speech to the
British/Swiss Chamber of Commerce on 12 September 2000, the Governor
Eddie George said the following:
But let me make clear, from the outset, that monetary union is fundamentally a political
rather than an economic issue. It necessarily involves the deliberate pooling of national
sovereignty over important aspects of public policy, in the interest not just of collective
economic advantage, but of a perceived wider political harmony within Europe.
As a central banker, I have nothing to say about the politics of monetary union—that’s for
elected politicians and clearly political opinion is divided—not just in the UK—about how
far and certainly how fast to go in the sensitive matter of pooling national sovereignty.
But monetary union is also an economic issue and that is my concern.6
He went on to outline the economic pros and cons,7 but neither he, nor any of
the other spokespersons for the Bank in these years, like Howard Davies and
244
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
245
Bank of England: Learning to Live with the Euro
whether the views of the Bank (and Treasury) were tilted against euro entry
by that experience. In my view both suppositions were mostly, perhaps
entirely, mistaken. Bank (and Treasury) officials were good enough economists
to know that a single currency is a much more robust regime than a pegged
exchange rate. The former cannot be subject to speculative attack. Once
adopted, it can only break apart, if some internal segment makes a (political)
decision to do so.
The problem with a single currency is, instead, that it may condemn some
parts of the zone to long-lasting inflationary, or deflationary, pressures in the
face of asymmetric shocks. That is why issues of whether the UK economy had
converged to its Continental neighbours, and of the flexibility of adjustment
mechanisms, figured so large in the commentaries and discussions, both in the
Bank and in the Treasury.
Through all this, the Bank’s strategic position remained constant; that the
issue of entry was primarily a political matter, on which it would be inappropri-
ate for the Bank to comment. There were, of course, economic advantages
and disadvantages. The Bank would enumerate and report these, but would
246
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
consciously abstain from reaching any conclusion about the overall balance of
pros and cons. In this respect, the Bank’s position was, rather nicely, the mirror-
image reverse of that taken up by the government, and in particular by the
Chancellor. For the Labour government, the political and constitutional issues
pointed, fairly clearly, to a case for UK entry into the Euro Area. Instead, the issue
for them was primarily economic.
The Government’s conclusions, as the Chancellor of the Exchequer set them out in his
statement to Parliament on 27 October, began by addressing three issues of principle. It
concluded first that, in principle, a successful single currency within a single European
market would be of benefit to Europe and to Britain. Second, to share a common
monetary policy with other Member States represents a major pooling of economic
sovereignty; but, while this constitutional issue is a factor in the decision, it is not in
the Government’s judgment an overriding one. Rather it signifies that in order for EMU
to be right for Britain the economic benefit should be clear and unambiguous. If, in the
end, a single currency is successful, and the economic case is clear and unambiguous,
then the Government believes Britain should be part of it. There is a third issue of
principle, namely popular consent, which the Government has reiterated will be tested
through a referendum.
The UK Treasury has published its assessment of five economic tests that define whether a
clear and unambiguous case can be made for the UK to join EMU. These are: whether
there can be sustainable convergence between Britain and the economies of a single
currency; whether there is sufficient flexibility to cope with economic change; the effect
on investment; the impact on the UK’s financial services industry; and whether it is good
for employment.
Applying these five economic tests leads the Government to the following clear conclu-
sions. British membership of a single currency in 1999 could not meet the tests, so that
joining at the start of EMU is not in the country’s economic interests. The Government
will therefore be notifying our European partners, in accordance with the Maastricht
Treaty, that we will not seek membership of the single currency on 1 January 1999. The
Chancellor emphasised that there is no need—legally, formally or politically—to re-
nounce our option to join for the period between 1 January 1999 and the end of the
current Parliament; nor would it be sensible to do so. But he concluded that, barring some
fundamental and unforeseen change in economic circumstances, making a decision
during this Parliament to join is not realistic. It is therefore sensible for business and the
country to plan on the basis that, in this Parliament, the Government does not propose to
enter a single currency.
247
Bank of England: Learning to Live with the Euro
The basic economic rationale for not joining the euro, as set out then in 1997,
was that sustainable and durable convergence with the rest of the prospective
Euro Area had not yet been achieved. In particular, short-term interest rates on
the Continent were around 3–4 per cent, compared with over 7 per cent in
Britain. HMT’s accompanying paper, setting out the five tests that Britain would
have to pass before joining the Euro Area, noted that Britain had more non-EU
trade, more home loans at variable interest rates than its partners, and that it
was the only oil exporter in the EC. Those factors made it hard for the UK’s
economic cycle to match those on the Continent, and for its interest rates to be
the same. Moreover, sterling had appreciated strongly at this time, and was
expected by many to fall back shortly, so there was a disinclination to lock in a
high real exchange rate. So, there was quite general approbation of the decision
to defer the decision, though The Economist (1 November: 31) grumbled that
not enough was being done to promote convergence. Nevertheless, many euro-
philes were encouraged by the generally pro-European tone of the 27 October
statement, while the euro-sceptics were cheered by the actual decision to stay
out, if only for the time being.
Anyhow, these same five economic tests gained a totemic importance for the
Chancellor, and, without his imprimatur, it was generally accepted that the
promised referendum on entry would have no chance of success. His October
statement ruled out British entry for the life of that Parliament, but no longer.
So when Labour was re-elected in 2001, shortly thereafter a major exercise for
the Treasury became to subject these same five tests to much more detailed
248
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
scrutiny. This was a major analytical study, in which a large number of outside
academic economists (including me) participated. Note, however, that the Bank
did not participate in this exercise,8 and was neither used, nor sought to be
involved, as an official adviser.
At the same time as the ‘five test’ exercise was being conducted, preparations
had to be run in tandem to consider the practical implications, if the decision
went in favour of UK entry. Having been marginally involved myself in the
former exercise as an outsider, my own impression was that the write-up of
those tests which might not prove favourable was left very much in an ‘either/
or’, ‘on the other hand/on the other’, mode until the last moment. Officials did
not know, nor could they presume to guess, the outcome in advance. So,
practical preparations for possible entry continued to be made until June 2003.
249
Bank of England: Learning to Live with the Euro
proposed, established, and chaired, and which represented all the City’s main
constituencies. CEG met regularly between 1999 and 2005, and still meets
once a year (to discuss developments in the Euro Area, such as infrastructure
projects, rather than euro preparations). As a result of cooperation with the City
through CEG, the Bank was able to publish a change-over plan in sterling
wholesale markets in Practical Issues, and keep it up-to-date on the Bank
website. This is discussed in much more detail in the next section. The Bank
also contributed to the UK National Changeover Plan and the regular reports
to Parliament coordinated by HMT.9
The conclusion of the five test study—UK Membership of the Single Currency:
An Assessment of the Five Economic Tests, June 2003—effectively repeated the
negative conclusion about sustainable convergence (and flexibility) that
had been made in October 1997. Thus the concluding, and crucial, paragraph
6.6, p. 228, reads as follows:
Overall the Treasury assessment is that since 1997 the UK has made real progress towards
meeting the five economic tests. But, on balance, though the potential benefits of in-
creased investment, trade, a boost to financial services, growth and jobs are clear, we
cannot at this point in time conclude that there is sustainable and durable convergence or
sufficient flexibility to cope with any potential difficulties within the euro area. So, despite
the risks and costs from delaying the benefits of joining, a clear and unambiguous case for
UK membership of EMU has not at the present time been made and a decision to join now
would not be in the national economic interest.
In the immediately following years the Euro Area grew more slowly than the
UK. Also, London reinforced its position as the leading capital market centre for
the Euro Area, despite being an ‘out’. Moreover, the sterling exchange rate
against the euro became rather stable (till 2007–8), even while the paths of
interest rates in London and Frankfurt continued to diverge. For all these, and
other, reasons advocacy in the UK for entry into the Euro Area waned, indeed
largely disappeared. The lobby group in favour of entry, Britain in Europe,
wound itself up.
Through all this discussion, the Bank had consciously kept to the side lines
on the wider issue of whether the UK should enter, or not. There was, however,
a more operational, educational, and technical field, related to the establish-
ment of the Euro Area into which the Bank flung itself with enthusiasm and
conviction.
London is the largest international financial centre in the world; New York and
Tokyo are perhaps bigger overall, but the predominant part of their business is
250
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
domestic, rather than international. London had become, by the 1990s, the site
of much of the financial intermediation involving its European partners. So,
whether in, or out, of the euro, much of the business undertaken in legacy
currencies in London would have to switch onto a euro basis when the Euro
Area commenced on 1 January 1999.
That this change-over to the euro would be important for the City, and
essential to get right, was not fully recognized by commercial institutions in
the early years. As early as 1995 from senior conversations across the City,
Bank officials all too frequently heard that, even if the euro started, about
which there was considerable scepticism in the City, the UK would not be a
member ‘and so we don’t need to do anything’. The Bank, notably the Gov-
ernor Eddie George, and John Townend, George’s Alternate at the European
Monetary Institute, were convinced that this view was wrong. The Alternate’s
Committee was charged with responsibility for all the technical preparations
for the euro. Because of this work which was just beginning, Townend was well
placed to understand precisely how the euro was going to be introduced, both
at the retail and at wholesale levels, as decisions were taken—strictly by the
EMI Council but the Alternate’s Committee was very influential. So George
asked Townend to write a paper for circulation to senior executives across
the City, to explain why practical preparations in the London wholesale
markets were as critical as on the Continent, whether or not the UK was to
become an initial member of the euro. Hence the first Practical Issues was
published in May 1996. It was only a dozen pages long but went to 200 or so
senior people across the City and was influential in helping to serve as a wake-
up call. From that point on, the euro responsibility came gradually to domin-
ate Townend’s Bank role.
As another indication of the delayed recognition in the City, and the appre-
ciation of the euro’s importance in the Bank, Howard Davies, then Deputy
Governor, stated in his speech to the Futures and Options Association Inter-
national Derivatives Week Conference on 4 June 1997, that
The assessment was that relatively few market participants in London had made serious
preparations for EMU, and seemed unsure of how to proceed. Only 6 per cent of brokers
and own account traders had made contingency plans for the introduction of EMU. But
this survey was undertaken in April of last year, and I am confident that the responses
would be different today.
Certainly a lot of work has been done in the London market, co-ordinated and steered by a
team in the Bank, to ensure that London is as well prepared as other European centres for
EMU. And our assessment now, which I believe is shared by the EMI and the Commission,
is that London is as well prepared as most if not all European centres.
I can assure you that the Bank of England itself will be ready for EMU on 1 January 1999,
whether or not the UK is a member. We will be able to offer euro accounts and euro
settlement facilities. We have taken the lead in work on market conventions across
251
Bank of England: Learning to Live with the Euro
Europe. EMU is likely to bring harmonisation of conventions such as day count and
frequency of coupon payments among Europe’s bond markets, and the London market is
ready to do that.
Prior to 27 October 1997, when the decision to enter the Euro Area was deferred
into the next Parliament, the Bank had to work under the assumption that
entry was a real possibility, despite the agreement by both main political parties
to submit any proposal to join to a referendum, and the continuing apparent
majorities in the opinion polls against joining. Opinions can change. A note
outlining the main features of the Bank’s work, pre-October 1997, is contained
in the Bank’s Annual Report and Accounts for 1996.10
The 27 October statement did not, in the event, slow down work on prep-
aration for the euro, especially in wholesale markets in London. In any case,
there remained a need to prepare in advance, should Britain eventually decide
to join. ‘Prepare and decide’ was the then common watchword.
Thus John Townend in his Bank of Wales lecture, 29 October 1997, on ‘The
U. K. and the Euro’, stated that
The other condition for London to thrive as a financial centre after EMU begins is that it
must be well prepared for the introduction of the euro. The Bank of England is playing a
substantive role in the preparations in two complementary ways. First, through our
participation in the work of the EMI, we aim to make sure that the design of EMU is
capable of being delivered in a technical sense. I referred to this earlier.
Our other role is to co-ordinate the preparations for the introduction of the euro across
the financial sector, to the extent that co-ordination is required. The Bank’s role in helping
the financial community to prepare for the euro was recognised and reconfirmed by the
Chancellor this summer when he launched his complementary initiative to begin pre-
paring the business community for the euro. In addition to making our own internal
preparations at the Bank, we play a co-ordinating role in the financial community in three
main ways:
. First, our job is to ensure that the necessary infrastructure is developed in the UK to
allow anyone who wishes to do so to use the euro in wholesale payments and across
the financial markets from the first day of EMU.
. Second, we aim to promote discussion between the EMI, national central banks and
market participants across Europe about practical issues on which the market is
seeking a degree of co-ordination.
. And, third, we provide information: for example, through our quarterly series of
editions on Practical Issues Arising from the Introduction of the Euro, which is
distributed to around 32,000 recipients across the City and beyond, including
many (I hope) to Wales and 4,000 directly abroad. And following the successful
symposium we held early this year, we are planning to hold a further symposium,
next January at the Bank, on London as the international financial centre for the
euro.11
252
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
253
Bank of England: Learning to Live with the Euro
Market Operations, he had also been the Governor’s Alternate on the EMI
Council, which means that he did the main donkeywork, together with Ste-
phen Colllins, the second Alternate. Prior to the 1998 establishment of the
ECSB, the EMI was the main centre for the technical preparations for EMU.12
The role of the Co-ordination Unit, as set out in the Annual Report of 1999,
was to be
responsible for co-ordinating the Bank’s work on Europe, which is carried out by each of
the Bank’s main operational areas. It takes a lead on the issues that affect the Bank as a
whole but which do not fall within the ambit of any of the operational areas. It is also
responsible for co-ordinating the Bank’s involvement with the European Central Bank,
other EU central banks and the EU Economic and Financial Committee. It maintains
contact with, and provides technical information to, financial institutions operating in
euro markets and with responsibility for euro infrastructure.
The Coordination Unit was a relatively small part of the Bank, involving not
much more than about 1 per cent of the total staff, and of its direct costs, see
Table 11.1 and Figure 11.1, taken, respectively, from the Bank’s Annual Reports
in 2000 and 2001.
Despite being small, the senior staff13 in the Unit were of very high quality,
including top-class officials such as Bill Allen, who became Director for Europe
after John Townend’s retirement in June 2002, Stephen Collins, Jon Carr, and
Paul Richards, a financial expert in the City who was seconded to the Bank in
February 1997 and joined full time in 2002.
In the first year of the existence of the Euro Preparation Division, 1996–7, its
main function was to prepare for possible UK entry. But after the 27 October
1997 Statement its most immediate task was primarily an educational and
co-ordinating exercise to prepare the City of London, and indeed the Bank
itself, for the change-over to the euro on 1 January 1999, though of course it
also continued preparations for euro entry until after 2003.
Business units
Monetary Analysis and Statistics 16.5 16.9 18.9
Financial Market Operations 43.6 41.3 45.7
Financial Stability 8.1 8.4 8.9
Co-ordination Unit for Europe 1.3 1.3 1.4
Centre for Central Banking 1.5 1.3 1.5
Studies
Printing Works 39.5 37.7 34.5
Registrar’s Department 4.0 3.8 3.6
114.5 110.7 114.5
254
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
2000 2001
Figure 11.1. Bank of England: numbers of staff by area, 2000 and 2001
As already noted, the City of London was the largest financial centre affected
by the change-over in wholesale financial markets from legacy currencies to the
euro at its launch at the beginning of 1999. The Bank was integrally involved in
co-ordinating the preparations in the City for the launch of the euro. Although
individual firms were responsible for their own preparations, the Bank sought to
achieve a consensus where a common approach was required, and to communi-
cate the results across the market as a whole (e.g. through the early editions of
Practical Issues Arising from the Introduction of the Euro in 1997 and 1998). The Bank
was also concerned to ensure that large firms and the financial infrastructure in
the City were prepared for the ‘conversion weekend’ at the beginning of 1999. In
the run-up to the conversion weekend, during the weekend itself, and in its
immediate aftermath, the Bank kept in regular contact with all the key firms in
the City to check that they were ready, and in case there were any problems. In
the event, the change-over went without any significant hitches, as the City was
well prepared. The change-over to the euro in wholesale markets was one of the
largest operations ever undertaken in the City. The Bank’s involvement was
consistent with its ‘CP3’ role at the time.
The details are set out in the early editions of Practical Issues. These were
widely used, not only in the City, but also across the Euro Area. Indeed the
circulation list of Practical Issues was literally global, issuing some 32,000 copies,
by far the largest circulation of any Bank publication. The other central banks in
Europe helped and co-operated in the publication of Practical Issues, but none of
them published anything comparable in quality or circulation. Many experts
(including European Commissioner Mario Monti) regarded Practical Issues as
equivalent to ‘the Bible’ for the wholesale euro launch in 1999, which was
remarkable given the likelihood, later confirmed, that the UK would be an ‘out’
central bank.
255
Bank of England: Learning to Live with the Euro
The Bank also monitored the retail banking change-over in the Euro Area
between 1999 and 2001 and the issue of euro notes and coin and withdrawal of
legacy national notes and coin at the beginning of 2002. This was consistent
with the UK’s policy of ‘prepare and decide’; and it was felt that there was a one-
off opportunity to learn from the experience of the Euro Area, particularly in
the large countries, before memories faded. The Bank was in a unique position
to learn these lessons because of its own responsibilities and its good relations
with the national central banks (NCBs) in the Euro Area. The details are set out
in later editions of Practical Issues (1999 to 2002), to which a number of NCBs
contributed.14 The issue in May 2002 provides a very comprehensive account of
the completion of the retail banking change-over and of the issue of euro-
currency, together with drawing some lessons for subsequent entrants, whether
the UK or not.
In this largely educational role, much of the work of the group involved the
dissemination of advice about the practical issues arising from the euro, in the
256
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
pamphlets that they published, mostly via the web on the Internet, semi-
annually. Prior to 1 January 1999, this publication was entitled Practical Issues
Arising from the Introduction of the Euro, but once the euro was introduced in
January 1999, the title had to be shortened to Practical Issues Arising from the
Euro; it was more familiarly known throughout as Practical Issues. There were
some 18 issues circulated by November 2002.
Much of the work involved was somewhat technical, concerned with
the details of the new systems and market processes involved. For markets to
work, it is, however, essential to get such details exactly right. However,
I doubt whether the readers of this book want to be taken through them in
any detail, and those that do can directly consult the Bank of England’s
website.15
For the reasons already stated, the Bank and the City of London played a key
role in the conversion of wholesale markets to the euro in January 1999. The
subsequent adoption of euro-currency, notes, and coin, in January 2002,
a technical triumph, had much less impact on the ‘out’ countries.
Once it became clear in June 2003 that the UK would remain ‘out’ for the
foreseeable future, (which in economics is a rather short horizon of about 2/3
years!), interest in the subject waned, and Practical Issues ceased. During the
257
Bank of England: Learning to Live with the Euro
years of ‘prepare and decide’ much had been done to assess the implications of
the UK’s potential entry for retail markets and the currency change-over. This
was pulled together in a stand-alone document, dated September 2005, entitled
Publications on Europe: City Guide to a UK Euro Changeover.16
The conversion weekend in January 1999 represented the high point of the
work of the Euro Co-ordination Group. Although no one knew, with any
assuredness, what the outcome of the ‘five tests’ exercise would be until the
last moment, the different and rather better trajectory of the UK economy than
of its Continental partners, the belief of the Chancellor that the institutional
structures for monetary and fiscal policies that he had created in the UK were
superior to those in the Euro Area, and the continuing (opinion poll) majority
against entry made entry increasingly unlikely. After June 2003 it rapidly dis-
appeared as a current issue. Yet, under slightly different circumstances that need
not have been so, and, should circumstances change (as they will), the issue of
UK entry might revive. Who knows? If so, the preparatory work done in the
Bank on the retail side and for the currency change-over would come in very
useful.
Whither Now?
Despite the UK being an ‘out’ country, relationships between the Bank and both
the NCBs and the ECB of the Eurosystem have remained mostly good. The Bank
still plays a (minor) role in the ESCB through its membership of the General
Council of the ESCB, though, of course, the key macro-monetary decisions are
taken by the Governing Council, from which the ‘outs’ are excluded. The
members of the Governing Council of the ECB would welcome the ‘outs’ to
join them, and hope that it will happen soon.
One must assume that it is somewhat galling for the Euro Area members to
have the main capital market of the Euro Area sited in London, in an ‘out’
country. There are, I believe, suspicions that a few of the rare areas of discord
have related to a disinclination in the Euro-Area members to give London an
easy ride. An example was the initial discussions of how the ‘out’ countries
might link into the Euro-Area TARGET payments system, though this latter is a
tortuous and technical matter with which I am not personally familiar.
With domestic price stability being the main monetary objective, both in
the Euro Area and in the UK, and with floating exchange rates, the key
requirement both for the Eurosystem and the Bank of England has been to
keep their ‘own houses in order’, and both have achieved that. Within the
wider international political scene, the ECB and its President wield even more
weight and influence than the Bundesbank and its President used to do; but,
equally, the governors of the NCBs have a diminished role. If the UK were to
join the Euro Area, the Bank would become a small fish in a much bigger pool.
258
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
259
Bank of England: Learning to Live with the Euro
to advise the Governor on conditions in the Euro Area more widely at the
monthly ECB meeting, one vote amongst many, perhaps 1 in 25. The idea
that the Bank could fashion for itself a special position in the ESCB, rather as
the Federal Reserve Bank of New York has in the Federal Reserve System is, in my
view, highly unlikely. Why should the ESCB transfer any special operational
role from Frankfurt to a ‘Johnny-come-lately’ in London; anyhow such oper-
ations now mostly get done in cyberspace.
With their macro-monetary policy roles much diminished, national central
banks within the Eurosystem and the ESCB have, naturally enough, been
hanging on, like grim death (an apposite analogy?), to such supervisory and
CP3 (financial efficiency) roles as they found themselves left with. But, as
already noted, the Bank has either been stripped of, or has abandoned, most
of these in its focus on CP1.
If the UK should join the euro, it could be argued that the optimal size of the
Bank of England would be two persons,19 the Governor and her/his secretary.
The building on Threadneedle Street could easily be put to other uses.
Notes
1. My thanks are due to Bill Allen, Jon Carr, Stephen Collins, Nigel Jenkinson, Paul
Richards, and John Townend for advice, assistance, comments, and suggestions. All
interpretations and errors, however, remain my own. I also want to thank Mrs.
Margot Hone for permission to reproduce her husband’s, Basil Hone’s, excellent
cartoons, which had previously appeared in the Bank of England’s publication,
Practical Issues, under the pseudonym, Ben Shailo. Finally, I want to thank Marina
Emond for excellent secretarial assistance.
2. From then onwards the Monetary Policy Committee of the Bank of England, chaired
by the Governor, and consisting of four other internal Bank officials and four external
members, (appointed by the Chancellor), were delegated the power to set the short-
term policy interest rate, without direction or interference from politicians. The MPC
was not, however, given goal independence. The MPC’s goal, of achieving an infla-
tion target, was set for it by the Chancellor.
3. Neither of these structural changes had any connection, as far as I am aware, with
wider European developments.
4. Indeed it remains to this day unclear exactly what is the prudential role and functions
of a central bank retaining responsibility for overall financial stability but without any
supervisory operations, though it certainly has some, notably oversight of the pay-
ments systems.
5. If the Government had decided that the economic case had been met, the Bank would
most likely have been pressed to state whether it agreed with that, or not. It is, of course,
an untestable counterfactual, but I, and most others, believe that the Bank would have
assessed the balance of economic advantage then dispassionately and analytically
without giving any weight to the implications for its own future status and position.
260
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
261
Bank of England: Learning to Live with the Euro
banks: one of these relates to the need for reserve requirements on the banking
system and another to the terms of access of non-euro area Member States to intraday
liquidity within TARGET (the proposed interlinking of Real-Time Gross Settlement
payments systems). Other topics on which national central banks have been heavily
engaged with the EMI include the drafting of the legal Regulations on the euro, the
design of the revised Exchange Rate Mechanism (membership of which will be
voluntary), the specification of euro banknotes and the specification of the statistical
requirements for EMU.’ Annual Report (1997)
13. The junior staff were no doubt top-class too, but I never got to know them.
14. Once again, I am entirely indebted to Paul Richards for the information in these last
couple of paragraphs.
15. In order to give readers a slight flavour of what went on, the Contents Pages of the
December 1998 issue provide an idea of the scope of the change-over, Annex C, and
the opening five pages of the June 1999 issue, Annex D, give a good, general account
of what occurred and the Bank’s role in it. These, again, are available from the author
on request.
16. The first three contents pages also available as Annex E, on request from the author.
17. That should not be taken to imply that I think that it has no useful role. It can try to
analyse the nature of systemic risks and threats to the overall financial system and to
promote solutions to collective action problems and other sources of market failure
that strengthen financial resilience and are justified on cost–benefit grounds. A few
examples would be analysis of networks, especially of the payments systems, of the
resilience of market and funding liquidity, and—on the risk reduction side—ap-
proaches to strengthen the wholesale payment systems and to improve the access
to funding and the use of standing facilities in stressed conditions.
18. Although less so than for several national central banks within the Euro Area, which
entered the Eurosystem with a far more bloated staff size than the Bank of England
has achieved.
19. This is, of course, hyperbole. London would become, even more than it already is, the
financial centre of the Euro Area. The Bank of England would have access to market
intelligence, e.g., about financial stability issues that the ECB should want to know.
But the Bank would need to become much smaller with a focus totally different from
its present one.
262
12
Denmark and Sweden: Networking by
Euro-Outsiders
Martin Marcussen
263
Denmark and Sweden: Networking by Euro-Outsiders
60
55 Denmark
50
45
40 Sweden
35
30
25
-2
-2
-1
-2
-2
-2
-2
-2
-2
-2
-2
-2
-2
-2
-2
-2
04
98
90
05
95
06
93
01
02
03
99
07
94
96
00
97
20
19
19
20
19
20
19
20
20
20
19
20
19
19
20
19
Figure 12.1. Public support for the euro in Sweden and Denmark
Sources: Standard EuroBarometer, EB43-EB67.
the broader public. Underneath the surface, Danish and Swedish civil servants
are negotiating their ways through and beyond the EU labyrinth, creating cross-
national networks of contacts and adapting their institutions to the reality of
European integration (Jacobsson, Lægreid, and Pedersen 2004; Lindahl and
Naurin 2005; Vifell 2006).
In line with the rest of the book, this chapter focuses exclusively on this
second and hidden face of European integration processes: the everyday life of
central bankers who continuously are forced to negotiate their ways in Euro-
pean decision-making. Central bankers in Denmark and Sweden are in a very
particular situation because their domain—monetary and financial policies—is
exempted from European integration while, at the same time, highly inter-
woven into the European macro-economic organizational field. This situation
distinguishes these two small central banks that traditionally have been deci-
sion-takers from a third euro-outsider, the Bank of England, which has a com-
pletely different historical legacy and tradition of working on the global level as
a decision-maker and with a different position in Europe interlinked with
the City of London (see Goodhart’s chapter in this volume). In this light, the
Swedish and Danish central bankers, more urgently than is the case with the
Bank of England, need to compensate for being Euro-outsiders (Marcussen
2007a). The paradox is that Danish and Swedish central bankers, despite their
Denmark
2 June 1992: Referendum about the Maastricht Treaty with 49.3 50.7 83.1 Rejected
a protocol in which the Danish government promises to
organize another referendum before adoption of the Euro
18 May 1993: Referendum about the Maastricht Treaty with 56.7 43.3 86.5 Accepted
a declaration stating that the Danish government has
obtained an opt-out from the third stage of EMU
28 September 2000: Referendum about abolishing the 46.9 53.1 87.5 Rejected
opt-out and introducing the Euro
Sweden
14 September 2003: Referendum about introducing the Euro 42 55.9 82.6 Rejected
264
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
265
Denmark and Sweden: Networking by Euro-Outsiders
necessary reforms, then the attractiveness of the Euro Area network may de-
crease (see Epstein and Johnson in this volume).
In a historical perspective, both the Danish and Swedish central banks have
been involved in formal and informal international cooperation for the pur-
pose of maintaining a stable exchange rate (Table 12.2). Over the last 150
years, stable exchange rates and participation in some kind of cooperative
framework have been the rule rather than the exception. Seen in that perspec-
tive, the current position of the Danish and Swedish central banks as euro-
outsiders is abnormal, all the more so for Sweden than for Denmark, which in
1999 chose to link its currency to the euro within the framework of the
Exchange Rate Mechanism II (ERM II).
The question about how Danish and Swedish central bankers cope with
being euro-outsiders highlights the role of organizational reform and how
they implement networking strategies to compensate for their exclusion from
the euro-club. The chapter adopts both an ‘outside-in’ perspective (on the
impact of European monetary integration on Danish and Swedish central
bank institutions) and an ‘inside-out’ perspective (on the network strategies
pursued by these two euro-outsiders in the European macro-economic organ-
izational field). The conclusion is that, on both these levels of analysis, Euro-
peanization has taken place, but that Europeanization takes different forms in
Sweden and in Denmark. Whereas the Danish central bank copes with Euro-
outsiderness by modernizing its organizational culture while essentially main-
taining its structural features intact, the Swedish central bank has been in a
constant reform process over the last 10–15 years, profoundly altering its
structures, relations, and functions in line with a global trend of public-sector
modernization. Whereas the Danish central bank is opening up and increas-
ingly engaging actively in all sorts of central bank networks in Europe and
elsewhere, it suffices for the Swedish central bank to exploit the large networks
it has built up over the last 75 years. Thus, it is hard to observe any kind of
convergence between the two banks. However, in their different ways, both
Table 12.2. The Danish and Swedish central banks in successive cooperative currency
arrangements
ERMII 01.01.1999–present
ERM 17.05.1991–19.11.1992 01.01.1979–01.01.1999
Snake Cooperation 03.1972–29.08.1977 19.02.1972–01.01.1979
Smithsonian Agreement 19.12.1971–19.03.1973 19.12.1971–19.03.1973
Bretton Woods 31.08.1951–23.08.1971 12.12.1946–23.08.1971
Interwar Gold Standard 01.04.1924–27.09.1931 01.01.1927–29.09.1931
Classical Gold Standard in the form of 27.05.1873–02.08.1914 01.01.1875–06.08.1914
a Scandinavian Currency Union
from 01.01.1877
Sources: Jonung (2000); Mikkelsen (1993); Olsen and Hoffmeyer (1968); Svendsen and Hansen (1968).
266
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
For a long period before, during, and after the Second World War, the former
Social Democratic Minister of Finance, Carl Valdemar Bramsnæs, was Danish
central bank governor (1936–49). Written correspondence, board minutes,
and personal diaries retrieved from the archives of the Danish central bank
show clearly that Denmark had no permanent and strong network of inter-
national contacts to exploit during these years. In addition, the Danish central
bank had no significant international capacity. There was not much travelling,
and the Danish central bank governor did not seem to be informed about,
interested in, or participating in international policy formulation or exchanges.
One of the few links to the outside world was to neighbouring Sweden, where
the Riksbank had become a member of the Board of Directors of the Bank
for International Settlements (BIS). Not being at ease with other foreign
languages, the link to the Riksbank and its governor, Ivar Rooth, allowed com-
munication on the basis of the mother tongue and between two relatively
similar political and administrative cultures. Thus, occasionally and almost
randomly, the Danish central bank received scattered information about cen-
tral bank business in Europe and policy issues in general. For instance, during
the Second World War, Denmark was isolated from, and mostly unaware about,
negotiations taking place in Bretton Woods. The Danish diplomat, Henrik
Kauffmann, who during the years of German occupation of Denmark walked
the corridors of Washington, did not formally represent the Danish govern-
ment and was only present during the Bretton Woods negotiations in his
personal capacity (Lidegaard 2005). In short, before the Second World War,
the Danish economic governance structures including the central bank and
the Ministry of Finance seemed to be sheltered from international develop-
ments and influence (Østergaard 1998).
During the 1950s and 1960s, Svend Nielsen (governor 1950–64) focused
his attention on the US and British central banks. The perception inside the
Danish central bank was that the locus of decision-making power was placed in
organizations such as the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and that par-
ticularly the British and American central banks constituted gateways to infor-
mation. With the establishment of the Marshall Plan and the Organization for
267
Denmark and Sweden: Networking by Euro-Outsiders
268
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
269
Denmark and Sweden: Networking by Euro-Outsiders
May 2004
Accounting Committee
Bank Note Committee
Statistics Committee
Budget Committee
IT-Committee
March 2008
External Communications Committee
International Relations Committee
Banking Supervision Committee
Human Resources Conference
Statistics Committee
Budget Committee
IT-Committee
Figure 12.2. The Danish central bank’s participation in ESCB committee work, 2004 and
2008
Source: Danmarks Nationalbank, May 2004 and March 2008.
270
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
(Table 12.6). Fixed exchange rates, low inflation, and stable budgets became the
solid pillars of Danish macro-economic policy (Marcussen 2002). In addition to
structural reforms in the labour market, a permissive consensus seemed to have
developed around traditional central bank ‘sound policy’ values. Inside the
Danish central bank, formal changes have been minimal. In 1998, a so-called
‘information office’ and a website were installed, underlining a felt need to
respond regularly and systematically to inquiries. In the following years, a
number of regular publications were streamlined, in terms of both form and
content, thereby appealing to a larger readership.
The number of employees has, overall, remained relatively constant. How-
ever, the composition of employees has changed. Slowly but steadily, an
increasing number of university-educated economists define the central
bank, replacing employees from other lower-educated branches. The bank has
quite a low turn-over rate and the average years of service seem to be very high
(13–15 years on average; 21–2 years at top level). The number of employees
with more than 25 years of service amounts to 20 per cent. A survey conducted
among the employees concluded that employment satisfaction is high. In
addition, the Danish central bank has for many years figured among the 15
most popular workplaces in Denmark for newly graduated economists (www.
universumeurope.com). From 2000, a personnel directive was adopted empha-
sizing the importance of employee satisfaction and human resource develop-
ment. Increasingly, emphasis is placed on education and skill-upgrading
of employees. Over the last decade, the budget consecrated to education and
training has increased manifold. Interestingly, the Danish central bank actively
encourages its younger economists to take a stage in one of the many inter-
national financial institutions. On average 15–20 persons are permanently on
leave from the bank, spending time in an international organization.
From 2000, like many other public organizations, the bank explicitly stated
its basic values. One central element is to safeguard traditions while attemp-
ting to engage in renewal. Another central value is to provide services to the
public. Transparency becomes central in that regard (see Jabko in this volume).
The level of transparency institutionalized in the Danish central bank does not,
however, measure up with other euro-outsiders such as the Swedish Riksbank
and the Bank of England, nor does it compare with the ECB (Figure 12.3).
The Danish governor does not have an obligation to explain his policies in
parliament, and no minutes are released from decision-making forums. Inside
the Danish central bank, this relatively low level of transparency is explained by
the fact that the Bank on a day-to-day basis is demonstrating to the world that it
is pursuing a stable currency objective within the framework of the ERM II.
Since the markets can observe directly whether the Bank is succeeding or not,
it is argued that there is not much more to tell the financial markets.
This argument stands in contrast to central banks, such as the ECB, the
Bank of England, and the Swedish Riksbank, which manage floating currencies
271
Denmark and Sweden: Networking by Euro-Outsiders
14
12
Danmarks Nationalbank
10 Sveriges Riksbank
8 Bank of England
ECB
6
4
1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005
Figure 12.3. Central bank transparency, 1998–2005
The transparency index is constituted by the following five elements: political transparency (open-
ness with regard to policy objectives), economic transparency (openness concerning information used
for monetary policy), procedural transparency (openness about the ways in which policy decisions are
being made), policy transparency (prompt disclosure and explanation of decision made), operational
transparency (openness in relation to the implementation of the policy actions). Minimum score is ‘0’,
maximum score is ‘15’.
Source: Dincer and Eichengreen (2007: 41).
272
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Table 12.3. Staff costs in the Danish and Swedish central banks
2004 (1) Annual (2) Staff costs (2)/(1) Relative Staff costs per Index of
salary in per employee price employee per PPP-corrected
industry per year level year in Dkr., staff costs
in Dkr. in Dkr. PPP corrected
higher than in manufacturing, they are among the lowest in European central
banking (Table 12.3).
Reforms or not, the Danish central bank governor has for years topped the
rankings of the most trusted and most powerful decision-makers among Dan-
ish elites (Berlingske Nyhedsmagasin, various years). The Danish central bank
governor does not have to face continuous contestation like, for instance, the
president of the ECB. He or she rarely has to stand up and defend his actions in
order to remain a recognized and legitimate public authority in the Danish
society. In contrast to Sweden, the Danish governor receives a relatively
modest salary (Table 12.4) while tending to remain much longer in office
(Table 12.5).
Table 12.4. Danish and Swedish central bank governors’ salaries, 2003 (US$)
Membership of the Board of the Bank for International Settlements adds another $90.000 to the salary.
Source: www.centralbanknews.com, 18 August 2003; annual reports.
273
Denmark and Sweden: Networking by Euro-Outsiders
For the Swedish Riksbank, the 1930s constituted a formative decade that had
lasting impact on its international strategy. In those years, political, entrepre-
neurial, and academic elites were driving forces in the construction of broad,
diversified, world-wide networks of contact. Ivar Rooth (governor 1929–48)
drove the creation and helped cultivate a large portfolio of formal and informal
contacts. At an early stage, he was the only Scandinavian central banker who
engaged himself actively in the formative period of the BIS. Rooth’s personal
archive at the Riksbank shows the ways in which he emphasized international
contacts. During his very first months as governor he travelled among the
major European capitals with a view to personally securing good relationships
with the most important players in the field. Detailed travelling notes demon-
strate how he deliberately assembled a portfolio of preferred contacts that could
be activated in the future if need be. In the following two decades, while
working hard to maintain established links, a large amount of new persons
and institutions were added to his personal network.
The direct and indirect results of this work were many. At the most basic level,
Rooth simply obtained information about opportunities and threats on the
international financial scene. During the first years, for instance, he obtained
a privileged position in observing the financial unrest emanating from the
United States; he gained inside information about the plans for the new BIS
(referred to as the ‘International Bank’ in those early days); and he even entered
an operational partnership with the Bank of England about an informal mutual
early warning system in the event of interest rate modifications. Indirectly,
Rooth inspired confidence in his partners abroad. This comes out clearly
when members of the BIS Board were to be selected from among the share-
holders of the organization. Many central bankers stood up to defend his
candidacy in the closed process. In addition, during the Second World War,
by representing neutral Sweden, Rooth was able to function as an effective and
trusted channel of communication between central bankers from Allied as well
as from aggressor countries. Over the years, the web of central bankers around
Rooth grew larger and became increasingly intimate and personal in character.
During the Second World War, he often ran a personal risk in travelling through
war-torn Europe to maintain and expand essential contacts.
Per Jacobsson, another Swedish economist, occupied for many years the
influential role of Head of the Monetary and Economics Department at the
BIS. Rooth paved the way for his international career, which started at the BIS.
Whereas Rooth was respected and liked for his integrity and social intelli-
gence, Jacobsson was highly valued for his academic skills. As the main author
of almost two decades of annual reports for the BIS, Jacobsson travelled the
world as a very knowledgeable and effective consultant (Jacobsson 1979).
Thus, he was actively involved in Jean Monnet’s modernization plan in
274
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
275
Denmark and Sweden: Networking by Euro-Outsiders
200 4
180 3.5
160
3
140
120 2.5
100 2
80 1.5
60
1
40
20 0.5
0 0
ESCB BIS Brussels Norden OECD IMF Eurostat G10 Others
# meetings 177,5 74,5 36 18 14 9 8 4 13
# meeting forums 49 31 10 17 8 5 4 2 13
Meeting intensity 3,62 2,4 3,6 1,05 1,75 1,8 2 2 1
meetings in no less than 139 forums, amounting to 354 meetings (Figure 12.4).
These data are only rough indicators of international networking for they
ignore the informal dimensions of trans-national central bank cooperation.
But it clearly underlines the fact that euro-outsiders, like Sweden, need not be
excluded from international cooperation.
Whereas the Danish central bank has not engaged in radical institutional
reforms since the Second World War, the Swedish central bank has gone
through comprehensive modernization programmes since the end of the
1980s (Table 12.6). Already in 1988, the Swedish central bank stood out as a
first mover among central banks in the world. A reform of the Riksbank act
granted the governor more legal autonomy, thereby leading a world-wide trend
of central bank reform in that direction. Having left the ERM in November
1992, the Riksbank in 1993 explicitly declared an inflation target (IT) regime.
Given that the first to declare an explicit inflation target were the Reserve Banks
of New Zealand in July 1989 and of Australia in April 1993 (see Eichbaum in this
volume), the Bank of Canada in February 1991, and the Bank of England in
October 1992 (see Goodhart in this volume) the Riksbank was again among the
first movers in what a decade later became a distinct global fashion. At about
the same time, but initially without success, initiatives were taken to grant the
Riksbank even more legal autonomy. A new central bank law was not adopted,
however, till 1998 and entered formally into force in 1999.
Also, in the area of central bank transparency the Riksbank took the lead
(Figure 12.3). Inflation reports are regularly published; press releases explain
monetary policy decisions; the minutes of the meetings of the Directorate are
276
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Table 12.6. Two worlds apart: institutional reforms in the Swedish and the Danish
central banks
Denmark
1982 The government declares its support for a fixed exchange rate regime.
A so-called ‘sound policy’/‘stability-oriented’ macro-economic policy strategy is being pursued,
implying sound money (low inflation) and sound finances (balanced budgets)
Sweden
1982 The government announces a 16 per cent devaluation within the framework of the ERM
1988 A new Riksbank Act:
The chairman of the Governing Board is no longer appointed by the government, but by the
other seven members of the Board.
The Governor’s term in office is made longer (five years) than that of the rest of the Board and the
parliament (three years, at the time).
There is no indication of the objective for monetary policy-making.
1991 The government declares that low inflation is an overriding goal for stabilization policy.
1992 November: After repeated speculative attacks against the Swedish currency the Riksbank
abandons the pegged exchange rate policy.
1993 January: The Riksbank declares an explicit inflation target.
February: A parliamentary committee presents a proposal for a new Riksbank Act, including a
price stability objective for monetary policy and increased central bank independence. The
proposal does not achieve enough political support and is not formally presented to the
parliament.
October: The first internal Inflation Report is published.
1995 January: Sweden becomes a member of the European Union.
November: The first Inflation Report signed by the Governor is published.
1997 The Riksbank starts to publish its inflation forecasts and Financial Stability Reports.
1997 A new proposal for a price stability objective and increased central bank independence is
presented, this time based on broad political consensus.
1999 An amended Riksbank Act comes into effect.
made public two weeks after the meeting; and the governor meets with the
Parliamentary Financial Committee twice a year. Interestingly, today’s central
banking in Sweden very much resembles the experience of the 1930s (Berg and
Jonung 1998). In 1931–7, Sweden declared an explicit inflation target with a
view to anchoring expectations. In addition, the Riksbank produced regular
reports spelling out the details of monetary policy, and Ivar Rooth met regularly
with the Parliamentary Banking Committee to explain and defend his decisions.
Finally, the media gave wide coverage to monetary policy-making, thereby
emphasizing yet another aspect of central bank transparency.
Today, Riksbank personnel talk about ‘a clash of reform cultures’ between the
prominent idea in Sweden that a central bank that demands reforms elsewhere
in the economy ought to be a first mover and show the way for the others and
the continental perspective, according to which central bankers are classical
institutions with long established traditions that ought to be maintained and
protected from outside involvement (though see Dyson in this volume on Axel
Weber and the Bundesbank). For this reason alone, very few Riksbank managers
feel attracted by the European way of running central banking and often indicate
that it would be easier to sell European monetary cooperation to the Swedish
277
Denmark and Sweden: Networking by Euro-Outsiders
population if the continental model would actively engage with modern man-
agement philosophies, thereby constituting a lodestar.
Within the Swedish central bank, these structural and policy reforms implied
considerable organizational and procedural changes. Over the decade from
1997 the organization and culture of the Riksbank have been completely over-
hauled. Competences were gradually transferred from the top level manage-
ment to the individual departments. The number of departments has been
reduced from 16 to 11 in 2000 and then again from 11 to 7 in 2004. The
regional offices were closed down, and a considerable number of employees
in these offices as well as in the Riksbank building have been dismissed. For
instance, in 2003 the Board of the Riksbank decided that the number of
employees (FTEs) would be reduced by 10 per cent over a three-year period
(Figure 12.5). Regular attitude surveys among bank staff have been carried out
since 1997. Not surprisingly, a recent survey concludes that the employees in
the units that have been cut down ‘tend to have more negative impressions’ of
the Riksbank and its governor (Sveriges Riksbank 2007: 52). Towards the end
of the 1990s, the Riksbank used to be one of the most attractive workplaces in
Sweden for newly graduated economists. This is no longer so. The Riksbank has
dropped out of Universum Communication’s ranking of the top-15 most popu-
lar workplaces for economists in Sweden (www.universumeurope.com).
All managers of the Swedish central bank have been going through intensive
management training with particular focus on communication and output per-
formance. The official corporate culture statement in 2002 is based on openness,
competence, cooperation, overall view (whole of government), initiative, and
800
750
700
650
600
550
500
450
400
350
1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006
Sweden 754 709 664 669 460 488 501 450 420 429 404
Denmark 593 578 589 592 586 579 566 556 552 563 559 544 536 516 515
Figure 12.5. Development in staff numbers (FTEs) of the Danish and Swedish central
banks
Source: Annual Reports from the Swedish and Danish central banks.
278
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
respect. The Executive Board adopted a so-called strategic plan in 2005, with
strategic targets emphasizing quality, efficiency, and confidence, and in 2006
this plan was turned into a ‘new vision’ for the Riksbank. By constantly compar-
ing itself to other central banks as well as other public authorities and private
corporations, and by constructing an organization prepared for change, the ‘new
vision’ is supposed to be transformed into reality. Over the years, the central bank
has, by example and choice, taken a lead in the discussion among central banks
about central bank efficiency. The point of departure is that central banks are not,
like private corporations, exposed to market competition as a result of which
other efficiency-enhancing mechanisms have to be installed. Completely in line
with values associated with the New Public Management doctrine, the recom-
mendation is to reduce the number of tasks entrusted to central bankers. These
tasks should focus on the efficiency of the payment system and maintaining price
stability, on spelling out precisely when an outcome has been achieved (by
introducing inflation targeting, for instance), and on improving the
transparency of the organization thereby allowing for internal and external
evaluations of the bank (Blix, Daltug, and Heikensten 2003). In short, the Riks-
bank seems to have closely followed mainstream advice about central bank
modernization (Marcussen 2009; Mendzela 2002, 2003, 2006).
279
Denmark and Sweden: Networking by Euro-Outsiders
Table 12.7. Danish and Swedish strategies of coping with being euro-outsiders
Sweden Denmark
contrast to the Danish central bank, it has traditionally been very well integrated
into international financial circles (Table 12.7). In short, being in the same
position as euro-outsiders does not imply convergence in the ways in which
structural reforms are undertaken and international networking is
being diversified. Formulated differently, the fact that the two banks do not take
part in substantial elements of European monetary integration does not mean
that Europeanization has not taken place. Both central banks have changed, but
in quite different ways and in conjunction with broader global reform trends.
Over a 70-year period, the Danish central bank altered its networking strategy
to a much larger extent than the Swedish Riksbank. The Riksbank seems to
have consistently followed an internationally oriented diversification strategy,
establishing strong as well as weak ties with a large number of relevant actors,
inside and outside Europe. The Danish central bank was gradually internation-
alized after the Second World War, but for many years it strategically linked
itself to what it perceived to be the most powerful actor on the scene of global
finance (first Sweden, then Britain and the United States, and finally Ger-
many). With its non-membership of the Euro Area, it opened up, and diversi-
fied its links to other actors, thereby trying to compensate for its lack of
information. In recent years, despite being a euro-outsider, the Danish central
bank also put much more emphasis on committee work in the ESCB context. In
principle, Denmark has only access to committee work in the so-called
extended composition. On occasions, however, Denmark has received specific
invitations to participate in committee work in standard composition. Clearly,
when it comes to voting in these committees, Denmark does not participate. In
addition, the analytical capacity of the Danish central bank has been boosted
by, for instance, increasing the ratio of employees with a formal education in
economics. Over recent years, more PhDs are being employed by the Danish
central bank.
Traditionally, the Riksbank has been accustomed to being present in inter-
national economic organizations. Denmark was always a decision-taker, not
Sweden. The Riksbanks has always been part of the powerful G10—a forum of
decision-makers. The only problem faced by the Danish central bank is that it is
280
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
281
Denmark and Sweden: Networking by Euro-Outsiders
trend seems to be that Euro Area exclusion at least has not hindered, maybe
even encouraged, processes of micro- as well as macro-innovation in central
banking. Thus, in both Sweden and Denmark central bank stability-oriented
values constitute the locus around which all national debates oscillate. Inde-
pendent from the choice of currency regime, in both Sweden and Denmark it is
uncontested that wage-negotiations, public spending-programmes, and private
investments should support, not threaten, the underlying stability of the econ-
omy. Low inflation, public budgets in surplus, and a sustainable balance of
payments seem to constitute deep core values among the major political parties
and other opinion makers. The euro-outsider status has not diminished this
particular stability-oriented consensus. If anything, it seems to have helped to
further consolidate a basic belief in the value of stability and the role of central
banks in fostering stability. In this context, it comes as no surprise that the
authority and legitimacy of central banks in the respective states is consi-
derable. Central banks in Denmark and Sweden are safely located in powerful
positions right at the centre of macro-economic decision-making. On this
score, the Swedish and Danish central banks seem to differ from continental
European central banks in the sense that these former maintained and even
consolidated their traditional powerful positions in national policy processes,
whereas the latter transferred much of their authority to the ECB together with
the competence of making monetary policy. Even the Danish central bank,
which in reality does not exercise any sovereignty in the area of monetary
policy-making, is perceived as a natural authority on the Danish political scene.
Both Sweden and Denmark rank high in international bench-marks
that value competitiveness, flexibility, and innovation. Their status as euro-
outsiders had as a consequence that economic stakeholders in these two small
and open countries were exposed to risk in a different way from many euro-
insiders. Indeed, euro-insider status has often functioned as a safe heaven for
large as well as small EU member-states, and as an external anchor that can
provide stability and eliminate some key risks. Whether the status as a euro-
insider also eliminates some of the incentives to undertake structural reforms is
debatable (Duval and Elmeskov 2005). It is clear, however, that the status as a
euro-outsider in no way hindered profound structural reforms to labour and
product markets and that these reforms seem to have placed these euro-out-
siders among the most innovative economies in the world. In addition, it is
clear that central banking in Sweden and Denmark has encouraged, and to
some extent created, the right conditions for structural reforms. Continuously,
central bankers have pointed to the necessity of streamlining economic insti-
tutions, have urged politicians, businesses, and trade unions to work together
on these reforms, and have provided economic analysis and data to scientific-
ally underpin economic reforms.
If this kind of continuous reform can be referred to as a form of macro-
innovation relating to the function of the overall economic system, then it
282
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
283
This page intentionally left blank
Part V
Lessons from Non-European
Central Banks
This page intentionally left blank
13
The Political Economy of Central
Banking in Australia and New Zealand
Chris Eichbaum
This chapter examines the political and economic context of central banking
in Australia and New Zealand and seeks to illuminate the causes and conse-
quences of markedly different trajectories of institutional reshaping in the two
nations. The focus is largely on institutional reshaping over the past 25 years
and on patterns of similarity and difference over that period. Both Australia and
New Zealand are classified as Westminster political systems. However, the
former has a federal constitution and a bi-cameral legislature (with the govern-
ing party only infrequently commanding a majority in both houses). The
latter is a unitary state, with a single legislature. Until the 1980s the political
economy of both states reflected what Castles (1984, 1988) termed the ‘politics
of domestic defence’, dominated by recourse to barrier protection through
tariffs and import licensing, and quasi-corporatist, centralized systems of
wage fixing (the ‘wage earners welfare state’). The ‘unmaking of the politics of
domestic defence’ served to liberate the central banks of both states as finance
markets were liberalized and currencies floated (with attendant challenges in
terms of the stability of the financial system), border protection removed, and
wage-fixing systems decentralized (largely by agreement in Australia, and by
legislative fiat in New Zealand during the early 1990s). Central banks in both
states directed policy (or have been tasked with directing policy) to the main-
tenance of price stability, and have, by evolving practice or legislative fiat,
become operationally independent. Fiscal policy has increasingly become
subject to sanction or accommodation by independent monetary policy
authorities. In short, central banks have become extremely influential policy
actors in their own right.
287
The Political Economy of Central Banking in Australasia
In 1989 the Reserve Bank of New Zealand Act gave New Zealand’s central
bank operational independence to pursue a single economic objective—achiev-
ing and maintaining price stability. The 1989 Act repealed legislation
passed in 1964 which had enjoined the Bank to direct policy to multiple
objectives—the maintenance and promotion of economic and social welfare,
and promoting the highest level production and trade and full employment.
Under the 1964 legislation the Bank was required to give effect to the monetary
policy of the government of the day; under the 1989 Act monetary policy is
directed to meeting the terms of a Policy Targets Agreement agreed between
the relevant Minister (typically the Minister of Finance) and the Bank Gov-
ernor. These terms are also incorporated into the Governor’s contract of em-
ployment. The 1989 Act vests full authority for the determination of monetary
policy in the Governor—not in the Board of the Bank or a monetary policy
committee. Under the 1964 legislation the Secretary of the New Zealand
Treasury was a member of the Board of the Bank; that is no longer the case
under the 1989 Act. The role of the Board is to monitor the Bank and the
Governor on behalf of the Minister. In the event of a vacancy in the position of
Governor the Board is tasked with recommending an appointment to the
Minister. Since 1989 a number of central banks have been granted operational
independence, but with a measure of goal dependence—typically the goal has
been that of price stability.
While, from the vantage point of both New Zealand and Australian policy-
makers it is now acceptable to posit a degree of convergence as regards the
practice of central banking, it has not always been so. Indeed, in the 1990s for
New Zealand policymakers (and for those enamoured of the New Zealand
model) it was almost de rigueur to point out the institutional inadequacies of
the Australian arrangements. And in a formal sense at least, those arrangements
(or institutional ‘pillars’) have not changed: the Reserve Bank of Australia is still
enjoined to direct policy towards multiple objectives, it still maintains a
relationship of ‘consultative independence’ with the government of the day,
the Secretary to the Treasury still has a seat as of right on the Board of the
Reserve Bank, and it is the Bank Board (which combines ‘professional’ or
full-time members with individuals drawn from a range of industry sectors)
that is formally tasked with the development of monetary policy. Policy is
informed, to a degree, by an inflation target—a target developed largely by
the Bank itself, a target of an annual rate of inflation of between 2 and 3 per
cent over the cycle. This target was imported into a statement on the conduct of
policy agreed between former RBA Governor Ian Macfarlane and Treasurer
Peter Costello shortly before Macfarlane assumed office in 1996. So far as the
formal statutory arrangements are concerned, the Australian statute remained
largely intact since the tempestuous times of 1945, as have—notwithstanding
remarkable changes in context—the formal institutional arrangements within
which policy has been determined and implemented. But while the trajectory
288
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
There are obvious limits in focusing on differences in the formal (as distinct
from conventional or behavioural) markers of central bank independence. In
the final analysis it is behaviour that counts. But one key issue raised by a focus
on the two Australasian central banks is how to account for and explain
institutional difference—why it is that certain institutions have been shaped
or reshaped in certain ways—and the logic of institutional reshaping. The
extent and specific manifestations of this difference vary over time. The pol-
itical-economy code that shapes or reshapes the institutions of central banking
is suggested by elements of the statutes governing the two Australasian
‘banks of reserve’.
While until 1989 both institutions were formally given status and function
by statutes that did not, in substantive terms, differ significantly in institutional
form, this changed with the passage of the Reserve Bank of New Zealand
Act in 1989. The differences between this Act, and the corresponding Australian
statute, the Reserve Bank Act 1959 are captured in elements of the formal
institutional arrangements which govern the development and implemen-
tation of monetary policy. The charters of the two central banks prescribe the
objective(s) to which policy shall be directed and the governance and
accountability arrangements in pursuit of the objective(s), and, at the level
of policy goals, defines the relationship between the bank and the government
of the day.
289
The Political Economy of Central Banking in Australasia
The functions of the RBA are detailed in section 10 of the Reserve Bank Act,
the wording of which clearly indicates the status of the Board of the Bank in
terms of its statutory authority in both policymaking and governance:
(1) Subject to this Part, the Board has power to determine the policy of the
Bank in relation to any matter and to take such action as is necessary to
ensure that effect is given by the Bank to the policy so determined.
(2) It is the duty of the Board, within the limits of its powers, to ensure that
the monetary and banking policy of the Bank is directed to the greatest
advantage of the people of Australia and that the powers of the Bank
under this Act, the Banking Act 1959 and the regulations under that Act
are exercised in such a manner as, in the opinion of the Board, will best
contribute to:
(a) the stability of the currency of Australia;
(b) the maintenance of full employment in Australia; and
(c) the economic prosperity and welfare of the people of Australia.
(Section 10, Reserve Bank Act 1959)
By contrast, the charter prescribed in the Reserve Bank of New Zealand Act
1989 directs the Bank to a single economic objective:
The primary function of the Bank is to formulate and implement monetary policy
directed to the economic objective of achieving and maintaining stability in the general
level of prices. (Section 8, Reserve Bank of New Zealand Act 1989)1
The Australian statute provides that the Board of the Bank has the power to
determine the policy of the Bank. It is sufficient to note at this point that it is
the Board, and not the Governor alone, in which the power of policymaking
resides, and that, typically, in making appointment to the Reserve Bank Board
successive Australian governments have sought to bring a range of interests to
the task of policymaking, including, at various times and in varying combin-
ations, manufacturing, rural, mining, and employee interests, and academic
economists.
In contrast, the New Zealand policymaking arrangements are premised on a
set of contractual arrangements between the government of the day, through
the Minister of Finance or Treasurer, and the Governor of the Bank, and subject
to the Bank’s primary objective. While the primary objective of monetary
policy is prescribed in the statute, the specific target to which monetary policy
is directed is codified in a policy targets agreement between the Minister and the
Governor. The Governor is tasked with ensuring, ‘that the actions of the Bank
in implementing monetary policy are consistent with the policy targets fixed
under section 9 of [the] Act’ (Section 11, Reserve Bank of New Zealand Act
1989). The Governor is appointed by the Minister on the recommendation of
the Bank’s Board of Directors, (Section 40, Reserve Bank of New Zealand Act
1989), and is duty bound, ‘to ensure that the Bank carries out the functions
290
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
imposed on it by [the] Act’ (Section 41, Reserve Bank of New Zealand Act 1989).
While the Bank has a Board of Directors, the role of the Board is largely directed
to ensuring that the Governor of the Bank fulfils the terms of the contracted
Policy Targets Agreement.
The statute prescribes the grounds on which a Governor may be removed
from office, either on the initiative of the Minister or on the recommendation
of the Board, grounds which include a failure to achieve contracted policy
targets, and actions inconsistent with the Bank’s primary function (Sections
49 and 53, Reserve Bank of New Zealand Act 1989).
The accountability requirements for both central banks are detailed in stat-
ute, and, in the case of the RBA evolved in ways consistent with the statute, and
have in recent years been codified in an agreement between the Governor and
the Treasurer. Both Banks publish reports or statements on the conduct of
monetary policy, and both appear before committees of the respective parlia-
ments. And both statutes specify the rights of bank and government in policy
determination and in the event of the government of the day requiring the
bank to significantly modify the course of a preferred policy path.
In the case of the New Zealand statute the Reserve Bank Governor and the
government of the day codify agreed policy targets in a Policy Targets Agreement
(which must be consistent with the Bank’s principal target). However,
the government possesses a residual power to direct the Bank to formulate and
implement policy for any economic objective, other than the economic
objective specified in section 8 of the Act (the principal, objective), for a period
(Section 12, Reserve Bank of New Zealand Act 1989). This provision has, to date,
not been activated by any government.2 In the New Zealand context,
however, the possibility of the government seeking recourse to this facility was
raised by the Minister of Finance in 2007. The Australian statute also provides for
an override or disputes procedure. Section 11 of the Reserve Bank Act requires
the Board of the Bank to inform the government of Bank policy from time to
time, and prescribes a process to be followed in the event of a difference of
opinion between the Government and the Bank Board. This process allows the
government of the day, through the Treasurer, to determine the policy to be
adopted by the Bank, but requires that the Parliament (and through the Parlia-
ment, the public at large) be provided with all relevant information relating to
the difference of opinion and the rationale for any government override.
Both central banks have responsibility for financial system stability, and
increasingly are cooperating on a trans-Tasman basis on issues of prudential
regulation and financial stability (the more so given the recent period of inter-
national financial instability). The RBNZ is tasked in statute with using its
powers to promote the soundness and efficiency of the financial system, and
to avoid the significant damage to the financial system that could be caused
by the failure of a registered bank. The approach taken by the bank involves
three pillars—self-regulation, market discipline, and regulatory and supervisory
291
The Political Economy of Central Banking in Australasia
292
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
With its focus on price stability, and the formal context for relations between
bank and government influenced by agency theory, the Reserve Bank of New
Zealand Act 1989 is very much a reflection of the intellectual climate of the
times. But as we have already noted, Australian central banking continues to
operate according to an institutional scheme reflecting the third stage in the
development of central banking. In some respects the current statutory arrange-
ments—and the Bank’s dualist charter and the structure of its board are most
often cited here—evoke aspects of an earlier Keynesian settlement. Equally,
however, those arrangements are quite consistent with what Blinder (1998)
characterized as ‘modern central banking’.
The somewhat ‘dated’ Australian arrangements could perhaps be excused if
they simply reflected an institutional ‘overhang’ from an earlier time, and if
central bank policy and practice (as articulated by Australia’s central bankers)
was not couched in terms of the formal statutory arrangements. However,
successive governors of the Bank appeared to be quite comfortable operating
with a charter that directs the Bank to multiple objectives, and defended the
Bank’s governance arrangements against the accusation that they compromise
the independence of the institution.4 The chapter considers below the extent to
which antipodean central banking might be exhibiting the characteristics of a
fifth age of central banking.
In order to fully illuminate and account for the patterns of similarity and
difference between central banks and central banking in Australia and New
Zealand—and to complement the standard historical taxonomy of ages
of central banking—two particular drivers need to be factored into the discus-
sion. They are institutional credibility and institutional legitimacy. The argu-
ment (which is more fully developed in Eichbaum 1999) is that a stable
institutional settlement (in essence, a political settlement) requires high en-
dowments of both credibility and legitimacy. Institutional (and policy) cred-
ibility is required to counter the problem of dynamic inconsistency (Kydland
and Prescott 1977). Politically porous institutional arrangements, it is argued,
lack credibility. Opportunistic and discretionary monetary policymaking, con-
ducted with a short-term bias, will cause price setters to factor a risk premium
into forward contracts. Institutional legitimacy has two dimensions. The
central bank and the conduct of monetary policy more generally will be per-
ceived as legitimate where monetary policy balances the need for stable prices
with the needs of non-financial actors with real economy interests (addressing
both stabilization and growth imperatives); and, second, to the extent that they
satisfy tests of democratic governance and accountability (mitigating the per-
ception or actuality of a democratic deficit). Conceived in this way, the ‘equi-
librium’ condition for a stable institutional settlement is one in which
endowments of both credibility and legitimacy are optimized.
The Reserve Bank of New Zealand Act 1989 represented a regime shift of
paradigmatic proportions. But it was a shift that was, at its core, designed to
293
The Political Economy of Central Banking in Australasia
address a significant credibility deficit. The RBNZ, which had de facto since late
1984 enjoyed the kind of ‘independence’ codified in the 1989 Act, was a
significant actor in its own institutional reshaping. It drove the process of policy
formation, and, significantly, mobilized sufficient support within the govern-
ment to ensure that its own preferences as regards the detail of institutional
form prevailed over those advocated by the New Zealand Treasury.
The fact that an incumbent government might wish to limit its own capacity
for discretionary policymaking is, given the behavioural assumptions that
inform the rational choice case for central bank independence, conceptually
somewhat problematic. Some accounts (e.g. Goodman 1992) seek to remedy
this by postulating that an incumbent government will act where it faces the
prospect of imminent defeat and wishes to limit the capacity for discretionary
action on the part of its successor. There is much in the New Zealand case to
support this line of argument. By 1988–9 the fourth Labour Government was
facing the probability of defeat in the 1990 election, and the public justification
for the Act, captured in the political discourse of the time, was one predicated
on the policy failings of earlier governments and the prospect for those
failings informing the conduct of policy under future governments. Faced
with the opportunity to codify its de facto independence in a more durable
form, the government created the conditions for a significant reconfiguration
of the domestic political economy, and for a more independent political role for
the central bank. In so doing, it nurtured a critical mass of support for the kinds
of legislative changes that it initiated in 1988.
Moreover, by zero-basing the process of institutional design, the architects of
the Act—within the government and within the Bank—were able to draw on
the prevailing institutional prescription, one that privileged operationally in-
dependent central banks, tasked exclusively with the achievement and main-
tenance of price stability. For the architects the principal objective was the
restoration of credibility to the conduct of monetary policy. There was not
total disregard of institutional legitimacy. Those most closely involved in the
design of the Act were concerned to arrive at an institutional settlement that
respected the rights of the legislature in a Westminster-style democracy. But, to
the extent that legitimacy was a consideration, it was captured and disposed of
in the contractual nature of the accountability regime, and not viewed as a
consideration in designing either objectives or wider governance arrangements.
The fact that the government retained the right in statute to provide the
governor with policy targets, and, in limited circumstances, to override the
principal objective, was viewed as sufficient.
The dominant economic interests demanded credibility in the conduct and
substance of policy, and the Bank, concerned to administer a further circuit
breaker to inflationary expectations, was also driven by this imperative. In the
context of an environment in which the institutions of the New Zealand state
were being progressively reshaped according to the tenets of agency theory,
294
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
the vehicle of a contract between the government, as principal, and the central
bank governor, as agent, was readily at hand. The de facto changes in the post-
1984 period shifted the Bank’s position, and the subsequent codification of
these changes in the 1989 Act was informed by the quest for credibility. The
Bank’s stock of credibility had appreciated.
If the New Zealand changes represented a paradigm shift, institutional
reshaping in Australia has been of a more incremental kind, based on the
legislative changes of the early post-War period. Whereas New Zealand entered
the 1980s with institutional arrangements carrying a significant credibility
deficit, the institution of Australian central banking had been subject to a
searching evaluation through the 1981 Campbell Committee Inquiry into
the financial system. Its report recommended the liberalization of the finance
sector (and presaged the floating of the Australian dollar), and, with reference to
the RBA, endorsed the institutional status quo (Bell 2006: 21–5). However, the
1980s, and the early 1990s in particular, were to see a political contest over the
Australian central bank predicated on the allegation of an acute credibility
deficit as the basis for radical institutional change—along the lines of the New
Zealand model. The case for reform rested on the low score of the RBA on the
standard formal indices of central bank independence. The intellectual climate
of the times (no better demonstrated than in the ‘New Zealand model’) privil-
eged an institutional model in which central banks focused exclusively on price
stability, and in which operational independence from government—and
indeed the implementation of monetary policy clearly at variance with the
political interests of incumbent governments—was held to be virtuous. In a
climate in which the quest for low inflation was the only game in town, a
central bank tasked to deliver multiple objectives ‘invited’ a credibility deficit.
The RBA was governed by a Board, in which membership of financial actors was
specifically precluded (and which included a ‘representative of the Treasury’),
and was enjoined to develop and implement policy in consultation with the
government. This credibility deficit was pronounced amongst those actors who
held the assumption of a direct correspondence between statute and behaviour
(which standard textbook accounts implied).
The perception that the Australian institutional arrangements were politic-
ally porous was further encouraged by the imprudent remarks of politicians,
who claimed to be able to influence the conduct of monetary policy. These
politicians were, in the words of the Reserve Bank Governor of the time,
‘chastised’ for these observations, and may well have regretted them. However,
while within the domestic environment financial actors may have been
inclined to dismiss such observations as evidence of political hubris, in overseas
markets such comments merely served to reinforce the appearance of a
systemic weakness in institutional design. There was little, if any, evidence
of direct political involvement in the conduct of monetary policy decision-
making; if anything, the evidence was that ‘political considerations’ influenced
295
The Political Economy of Central Banking in Australasia
the Board of the Bank to time policy changes specifically to avoid the appear-
ance of political influence. However, the prevailing view—particularly in off-
shore markets—was one of a politically porous set of institutional arrange-
ments, and of an increasingly acute credibility deficit.
Two competing political prescriptions were on offer in Australia in the early
1990s. One prescription sought to replicate the New Zealand model; the other,
to effect an increase in institutional and policy credibility without any conse-
quential diminution in the legitimacy of the institution (and without the
requirement to revisit the statutory framework). The second prevailed. Having
moved to a position where both endowments of legitimacy and credibility have
been optimized, the reshaping of the Australian central bank resulted in a
position of relative equilibrium, reflected in a bi-partisan policy settlement.
Two aspects of the on-going institutional reshaping of Australia’s central
banking arrangements have been particularly significant. The first was the
development by Bank and government of an inflation target: of an annual
rate of inflation of between and 2 and 3 per cent over the course of the business
cycle. The development of an inflation target was seen as mitigating the dele-
terious consequences of the credibility deficit, while at the same time being
consistent with the maintenance of the dualist approach suggested by the
Reserve Bank charter. The second was the agreed statement on the conduct of
monetary policy embodied in an exchange of letters between the Bank Gov-
ernor and the Treasurer in August 1996, subsequently reaffirmed in July 2003
and September 2006.
The agreed statement was reviewed following the change of government in
Australia in November 2007. One of the first items of business for the incoming
government was to recommit to an agreed Statement on the Conduct of
Monetary Policy. On 6 December 2007, the new Prime Minister Rudd and
Treasurer Swan released a revised Statement, outlining the ‘mutual understand-
ing on the conduct of monetary policy between the new Government, repre-
sented by the Treasurer, and the Governor as Chairman of the RBA Board’. The
Statement contains a number of new elements. The positions of Governor and
Deputy Governor of the Bank are to be raised to the same level of statutory
independence as the Commissioner of Taxation and the Australian Statistician.
This means that appointments will be made by the government, but that any
termination will require parliamentary approval (now a higher threshold than
applies in the New Zealand legislation, where the formal power to terminate
the Governor’s employment—albeit subject to a number of tests—resides with
the government). In respect of future Board appointments, the Secretary to the
Treasury, and the Governor of the Reserve Bank will maintain a register of
‘eminent candidates’ from which the Treasurer will make appointments to
the Board. These developments were heralded as bringing in a ‘new era of
independence for the RBA’. The Prime Minister and the Treasurer viewed the
revised Statement on the Conduct of Monetary Policy as ‘an important step
296
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
While the overall scheme of the Reserve Bank Act remains, in terms of the
sentiment (certainly politically, and possibly within the Bank) that is expressed
in the Policy Targets Agreement, there is a tacit acceptance of the need for a
measure of policy dualism and—notwithstanding statutory references to
economic policy objectives in isolation—of the interdependence of economic
and social policy.
297
The Political Economy of Central Banking in Australasia
The New Zealand arrangements have also been the subject of a technical
review, conducted in 2000 by Professor Lars Svensson. On balance the Svensson
report was supportive of the monetary policy regime and the Bank’s conduct of
monetary policy.5 Svensson (2001) did, however, recommend a number of
changes, including to the inflation target and to the Bank’s governance arrange-
ments. They included that
. The Bank’s inflation target be restated as a point target of 1.5 per cent
. A formal monetary policy committee, comprising the Governor and four
other Reserve Bank staff, be formed (with the change to be made at the
beginning of the next term of the Governor)
. Changes to the accountability arrangements and Bank governance, specif-
ically that the Board of the Bank consist only of non-executive directors,
with the Chair of the Board selected by these non-executive directors
(under the 1989 Act the Governor and Deputy Governors were members
of the Board and the Governor the Chair of the Board)6
Svensson’s recommendations regarding changes to accountability arrange-
ments and specifically to the composition of the Board of the Bank were largely
accepted. However, the government chose not to act on his recommendation to
establish a monetary policy committee or to amend the Policy Targets Agree-
ment to provide for an explicit mid-range point target.
While the New Zealand arrangements are unlikely to be revisited in the short
term, recent developments suggest that there is every prospect of a further
refining of those arrangements. Both Australian and New Zealand central
banks, in common with those in a number of other jurisdictions, have been
faced with the challenge of asset-price (house price in particular) inflation (Bell
2006: 181–97 on the Australian case). New Zealand policymakers have, since
late 2005, been exploring whether supplementary policy instruments might be
deployed to complement monetary policy in the task of managing inflation
pressures (RBNZ/The Treasury 2006). And in both jurisdictions there are clearly
on-going challenges associated with the alignment of monetary and fiscal
policy.7
For over two decades the RBA has intervened, as appropriate and necessary, in
the foreign-exchange markets. The policy rationale for recourse to foreign-
exchange intervention dates from the Campbell Committee inquiry into the
financial system, which indicated that, in the absence of a clean float, some
intervention may be required from time to time. On 11 June 2007 the RBNZ
confirmed that, for the first time, it had intervened in the foreign-exchange
market.
In July 2007, with the US/NZ dollar cross rate reaching ‘exceptional’ levels,
the level of political discomfort with the conduct of monetary policy surfaced
again. The Leader of one of the parties supporting the coalition government
298
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
In a speech in August 2007 Finance Minister Cullen signalled his concern with
aspects of New Zealand’s monetary policy framework, noting that
The accepted consensus has been that our monetary policy framework doesn’t have an
impact on long run growth. In other words, monetary policy helps keep the economy
stable by moderating economic cycles, without impacting on the sustainable rate of
growth of the economy.
My overriding concern is that this view no longer holds. . . .
So I think we need to look seriously at the monetary policy framework and whether it can
be made more effective at curing the inflation disease without killing the patient in the
process. (Cullen 2007)
299
The Political Economy of Central Banking in Australasia
difference. The differences, such as they are, are more marked in the formal or
statutory realm and much less so in the actual conduct of monetary policy and
in relationships between central banks and governments. Australia still ‘of-
fends’ against an earlier orthodoxy by retaining a statute that codifies policy
dualism, by a mode of policymaking by a mixed board of professionals and
‘lay’ representatives, and by continuing to have the Secretary of the Treasury
on that Board. The defining features of New Zealand’s formal arrangements
have already been well rehearsed. They are a single focus on price stability,
policymaking vested in the Governor and in a contractual relationship be-
tween Governor and government that provides operational autonomy for the
former on the basis of goal dependence stipulated by the latter, and a Board
that is tasked principally with oversight of the performance of Governor—as
agent—on behalf of the Minister—as political principal. Both formal regimes
provide for a policy override, but—to date at least—there has been no recourse
to this facility.
Looking closer at the second tier of the formal arrangements—the exchange
of letters in the Australian case, and the Policy Targets Agreement in New
Zealand—one detects a high degree of similarity. Australia’s exchange of letters
in 1996 incorporated an inflation target, developed by the Bank itself as a
means of providing a more explicit (and credible) anchor for monetary policy.
This target remained unchanged for 11 years. It is a soft-edged and medium-
term target that enjoins the Bank, and the government, to direct policy to the
objective of keeping underlying inflation between 2 and 3 per cent, on average,
over the cycle. It bears a striking similarity to the target first incorporated into
the New Zealand Policy Targets Agreement in September 2002, some 8 years
after the Macfarlane/Costello exchange of letters, and 13 years after the passage
of the Reserve Bank of New Zealand Act 1989. The 2002 PTA is, as we noted,
significant also because it locates monetary policy within a wider set of policy
objectives. Although perhaps not policy dualism in the same way that it is
expressed in the charter of the RBA, it is as close as one might come to an
explicit commitment to policy dualism without revisiting the overall scheme
of the Act.
Both Banks produce regular reports on monetary policy: Monetary Policy
Statements in the case of the RBNZ, and Statements on Monetary Policy released
four times a year by the RBA. Both Banks appear regularly before committees of
their respective national legislatures: the RBNZ before the Finance and Expen-
diture Committee of the New Zealand Parliament, and the RBA before the House
of Representatives Standing Committee on Economics, Finance and Public
Administration.
While the election of a centre-right government in 2008 has seen a slight
shift away from the policy dualism that formerly linked economic and social
policy, there is still less distance now between the approaches of New Zealand
and Australia approaches.
300
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Central banking is, in substance and in form, a particular and different variant of
democratic decision-making (see Marcussen in this volume). In the case of both
the antipodean central banks there has been a progressive move towards depol-
iticization. Indeed the quest for institutional and policy credibility is in large
part about inoculating central banks and the conduct of monetary policy from
the democratic distemper that is evidenced in short-term and electorally oppor-
tunistic decision-making. It is not, however, clear that the Australasian central
banks have embraced, or been embraced by the imperatives of apoliticization
(Marcussen, this volume). Policymaking within the RBA is characterized by a
Board bringing both ‘expert’ and ‘lay’ perspectives to the process. It is clearly
decision-making by committee, but is hardly a new trend (and, as we noted,
offends against the orthodox prescription by providing representation for the
Treasury on the Bank Board). New Zealand in fact moved from decision-making
by committee to one-person decision-making by the Governor alone in 1989.
While this could be seen as at variance with the putative ‘fifth age’ of central
banking, the change reflected the tenets of agency theory and the hard-edged
contractualism of the New Zealand variant of the New Public Management
(Boston et al. 1996). It was also consistent with the orthodox institutional
prescription (Rogoff 1985).
Both central banks embraced the need for a much greater measure of
transparency in the conduct of monetary policy, and a recent decision by
the Board of the RBA will now see minutes of Board meetings released. The
RBNZ publishes three-year forward projections of monetary conditions, but
this is not a practice favoured by the RBA. Accountability arrangements for
both Banks include regular briefings to, and questioning by, committees of
their respective parliaments. Both central banks have adopted inflation tar-
geting of the flexible kind. New Zealand arrived relatively recently, and
through an iterative process of the review and renegotiation of Policy Target
Agreements, at a target almost identical to that developed by the RBA in the
early 1990s. As one of the architects of the Australian inflation target argued,
this target, along with the other pillars of the Australian settlement, has been
less an aspect of science, and more a feature of the ‘art of monetary policy’
(Fraser 1994).
301
The Political Economy of Central Banking in Australasia
What then of the scope, content, processes, and outcomes associated with
central bank reforms in New Zealand and Australia and the lessons that might
be taken from the experience of the antipodean central banks? Clearly con-
text—and, more to the point, differences in constitutional, political, and
economic contexts between Australasian and European central banks—is
vitally important. The two Australasian central banks are national institutions,
notwithstanding the interdependencies associated with the international
qualities of financial markets and, increasingly the governance of those mar-
kets. The ECB is, in charter and function, a supranational institution and one
that operates under a very different governance structure. However, ideas
travel, and benchmarking and policy transfer are integral to central banking,
whether in Europe or in Australasia. Unsurprisingly therefore, the Australasian
experience speaks to the challenges of European central banking.
The first, somewhat self-evident point to note is that central banks are
creatures of politics: if only because, whatever their quasi-constitutional status
in the administrative topography, they are established, tasked, and held
accountable by way of statutes (or treaties).
The second is that endowments of credibility are clearly important in enab-
ling central banks to achieve and maintain price stability. However, though
necessary, credibility may be by no means sufficient as a basis for establishing
an enduring institutional settlement. Institutional arrangements and the con-
duct of policy also needs to meet the test of legitimacy. This test is in part about
the specific nature of inflation targets and the conduct of monetary policy, and
in particular about ensuring that price stability does not come at the cost of
undue variability in output. It is, in other words, about being conscious of trade-
offs. In this sense, one can argue that monetary policy will meet the tests of
credibility and legitimacy if the cure ensures the continuing rude good health of
the patient. But legitimacy is also about other aspects of the institutional mix,
including the governance arrangements for central banks and the wider context
within which central banks, governments, economic actors, and civil society
more generally engage.
In part the legitimacy issues relate to the formal tasking or charters of central
banks, The primary objective of the European Central Bank is to maintain
price stability, operationalized as inflation rates of ‘below but close to 2
percent’ over the medium term. But the ECB charter also directs the Bank,
‘without prejudice to the objective of price stability’ to, ‘support the general
economic policies in the Community with a view to contributing to the
achievement of the objectives of the Community’, and these include a high
level of employment and sustainable and non-inflationary growth.
So what is the nature of the ECB’s charter or mandate—a sole focus on price
stability or a measure of policy dualism? Responding to a question at the ECB’s
monthly press conference in February 2008, its president Jean-Claude Trichet
reflected on the uncertainties facing central bankers (including financial
302
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
market turbulence and wage pressures) and remarked that, in the face of such
uncertainty,
[W]hat is certain is that we have an anchor. We have only one needle in our compass, as I
have always said, which is that we have to deliver price stability in the medium term.
(Trichet 2008, emphasis added)8
Problems of accountability could only arise if the ECB—having only one instrument at its
disposal—had the mandate to pursue several objectives. Then, it would have to explain
potential conflicts between the objectives, and, if necessary, to justify its own prioritisa-
tion of objectives in a democratic manner.
The experience of the Australian and New Zealand central banks suggests that
the imperatives of legitimacy cannot simply be satisfied by procedural or
accountability mechanisms that address the kinds of potential democratic
deficits attendant upon central bank independence. Legitimacy is as much
about what central banks do as how they do it.
303
The Political Economy of Central Banking in Australasia
Notes
304
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
305
This page intentionally left blank
14
The US Federal Reserve and the Politics
of Monetary and Financial Regulatory
Policies
John T. Woolley1
307
The US Federal Reserve and the Politics of Monetary Policy
emerged for the Fed, arising directly from the failure of financial markets and
regulators to identify and contain financial risks. The Fed, together with the US
Treasury and other agencies, responded aggressively and creatively to those
events, fundamentally, perhaps temporarily, reshaping the US financial indus-
try. Deep criticism seemed certain to yield major reforms of financial regula-
tion. It seems unlikely that these reforms will call into question the Fed’s
fundamental autonomy and authority, but the circumstances pose political
risks for the Fed unlike any since the 1970s.
The chapter focuses on influences on the central bank that have figured
prominently in scholarly writing: the structure of political institutions and the
place of the central bank among these institutions; the varying distribution of
interests and preferences across these institutions; the development of policy ideas
about the conduct of monetary policy; and the changing problems arising from
the developing economic system. Because these influences often interact, they
are to some degree interwoven in the analysis.
The central argument is that, in terms of the usual indicators of central bank
independence, very little has changed about the Fed. In terms of pressure from
other institutions and interests, the Fed’s environment became more benign.
The preferences that were arrayed within and outside the Fed in the 1980s
created space in which the Fed was able to establish not just its own credible
commitment to low inflation but also the political sustainability of this com-
mitment. With respect to issues of disclosure and transparency, the Fed has
been remarkably sensitive to its environment. The linked notions of transpar-
ency and inflation targeting have been welcomed at the Fed, but not officially
embraced precisely because of the legal environment that commits the Fed to
consider both output growth and inflation. The consolidation of European
monetary union and rise of the ECB have clearly affected the Fed, but in
relatively modest ways. By the end of 2007, however, the Fed was shocked by
unanticipated financial crisis.
The dominant policy problem for central banks during this period was how to
manage inflation—the risks of financial collapse seemed remote. In a useful and
comprehensive essay, Blinder (2004) wrote that worldwide in the past 20 years
there have been three developments in central bank behaviour so important as
to justify calling them ‘revolutionary’: (1) increasing policy transparency; (2)
increasing reliance on collective rather than individual decision-making; and
(3) increasing reliance on financial market indicators to guide policy. Blinder’s
second point does not, of course, apply to the Fed, where collective decision-
making has long been the rule. In other essays, Goodfriend (2003, 2005) argued
that the most important developments in US monetary policy were in the realm
of policy-makers’ understanding of the constraints imposed by the working of
the economy. The basic lesson of the early 1980s was that, in an economy of
agents with forward-looking price expectations, the only stable inflation
rate was a low rate, and that could only be achieved as a result of a credible
308
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
309
The US Federal Reserve and the Politics of Monetary Policy
0.08
0.06
0.04
Growth rate
0.02
−0.02
−0.04
2/1/1961
2/1/1965
2/1/1969
2/1/1973
2/1/1977
2/1/1981
2/1/1985
2/1/1989
2/1/1993
2/1/1997
2/1/2001
2/1/2005
2/1/2009
Date
Figure 14.1. US real GDP growth over quater year prior, 1964–2007
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.
16
14
12
10
Inflation
8 US Headline CPI
US Core
Euroland HICP
6
0
Jan-61 Jan-65 Jan-69 Jan-73 Jan-77 Jan-81 Jan-85 Jan-89 Jan-93 Jan-97 Jan-01 Jan-05 Jan-09
Date
310
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
12
10
8
Rate
0
Jan-61 Jan-65 Jan-69 Jan-73 Jan-77 Jan-81 Jan-85 Jan-89 Jan-93 Jan-97 Jan-01 Jan-05 Jan-09
Date
25.00
20.00
15.00
Federal funds rate
10.00
Real FFR
Nominal FFR
5.00
0.00
−5.00
−10.00
Jan-61
Jan-65
Jan-69
Jan-73
Jan-77
Jan-81
Jan-85
Jan-89
Jan-93
Jan-97
Jan-01
Jan-05
Jan-09
Date
Figure 14.4. Nominal and real rederal funds rate January 1964–February 2008
Sources: Nominal Rates: US Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Real Rates: Nominal rate
minus the contemporaneous CPI, calculated by author.
311
The US Federal Reserve and the Politics of Monetary Policy
Real GDP growth rate 0.024 0.023 0.024 0.013 0.000 0.010
Headline inflation (CPI) 6.130 3.450 3.120 1.130 3.010 2.320
Unemployment 6.030 1.890 5.840 1.070 0.190 0.820
Nominal federal funds rate 7.640 3.710 5.670 2.350 1.970 1.360
Data Sources: GDP, US Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis; CPI and Unemployment, US.
Bureau of Labor, Department of Labor Statistics; Federal funds rate, US Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.
Federal Funds Rate. The Federal funds rate, or overnight interbank rate, has
been the main monetary policy instrument in the United States. Figure 14.4
plots the monthly average nominal and real Federal funds rate (FFR) from 1964
to 2008. In general, the nominal rate has been more volatile than the real rate.
Following a very volatile period in real and nominal rates in the period 1974–
82, the FFR has become more stable. Since 1983, the real FFR has usually been
between 2 and 5 per cent. However, the real FFR rate was negative, a very
stimulative policy stance, in 1992–3 and again in 2003–4 (contrast especially
the period from 1974 to 1980).
Altogether, these data show an economy that seemed to be functioning
exceptionally well on the aggregate. Missing from these pictures, and from
monetary policy discussions, was a sense that the financial economy was
moving toward a period of crisis.
The Fed has three main components: the Board of Governors, the District
Banks, and the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC). Collectively, the
System’s legal authority stems from the Federal Reserve Act.3 In 1978 the Act
was amended in two critical ways. First, it required semi-annual Congressional
testimony on the conduct of monetary policy, later regarded as a core element
in Fed transparency. Second, it codified explicitly the Fed’s obligation to pursue
the goals of long-run growth and price stability.4 This two-goal legislative
mandate has been one important factor in the Fed’s reluctance to embrace
explicit inflation targeting, and is an important source of many contrasts
between the Fed and the ECB.
Uniting all the components of the Fed is a large and exceptionally talented
staff including scores of PhD economists. The intellectual power of the staff
means that the Fed is at the forefront worldwide of discussion and analysis in
relevant epistemic communities. However, interestingly, the Fed has frequently
312
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
not been among the world’s leading central banks when it comes to institu-
tional innovation and policy leadership. The Fed has resisted almost every
panacea or fad that has swept markets or academia, including Keynesianism,
monetarism, commodity price targeting, the separation of monetary policy
from financial institutions regulation, and inflation targeting. This resistance
reflects an institutional culture of reluctance to interfere with markets and an
inbred scepticism toward fads. It also reflects important preferences in the Fed’s
political environment, especially Congressional insistence on balancing the
pursuit of growth and the fight against inflation.
The Board of Governors is a seven-member board, also called the Federal
Reserve Board (FRB), located in Washington D.C. The members are appointed
to 14-year terms (or portions of unexpired terms) by the US President, with the
consent of the Senate. The Chair is appointed by the President, with the
consent of the Senate, from among the members of the Board, to serve a four-
year renewable term.5 The Board is responsible for setting reserve requirements
for member banks. It also sets the discount rate, that is, the rate at which the Fed
lends directly to eligible financial institutions. The discount rate is changed
upon the request of the Boards of Directors of Federal Reserve district banks.
Policy innovations adopted in December 2007 to address the financial crisis (see
more below) had the interesting characteristic of clearly placing the initiative
for new policy directions in the FRB, not the FOMC.
The FRB also sets and implements regulation of a variety of financial institu-
tions under authority granted by law. While demanding and time-consuming,
Board members have considered these tasks to be far less engaging than mon-
etary policy (cf. Meyer 2004: xvi). Regulations are referred to alphabetically—
Regulation A through Regulation GG. Regulation A, for example, deals with
borrowing at the discount window (i.e. ‘extending credit to depository institu-
tions and others’).6 Regulation C governs Home Mortgage Disclosure for some
lenders. Regulation K covers the operation of foreign banks in the United States.
The Board’s economic staff provide highly influential technical assistance to
the Board and the Federal Open Market Committee. They prepare the crucially
important monetary policy forecast. The Board’s three main economic research
divisions have some 450 staff, of whom about half are PhD economists.7 Fed
staff report to the chair (Meyer 2004: 26–7). By far the heaviest weight of staff
resources resides with the Board rather than the district banks.
The 12 Federal Reserve District Banks are headed by Presidents, appointed by
local boards of directors subject to approval by the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System. Five of the 12 Presidents participate each year as voting
members of the FOMC. Among them is always the president of the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York, who by convention is also always selected as Vice-
Chairman of the FOMC. Voting seats rotate among the other Presidents, but
all of them attend FOMC meetings and participate fully in deliberations. In
some circumstances, not involving formal votes on policy, but in questions of
313
The US Federal Reserve and the Politics of Monetary Policy
procedure and public openness, the views of all Presidents are considered in
seeking a consensus. The opportunity to participate in monetary policy delib-
erations is a major motivation for becoming a district bank president.
While initially the district banks were dominant in the Fed, by 1935 a series of
reforms had shifted authority to the FRB. Over time, the district banks have
come to be engaged primarily in commercial bank supervision and in the
provision of financial infrastructure services—especially cheque clearing and
currency distribution. In the total 2007 budget of the Fed, the district banks
accounted for about 90 per cent of total expenditures. Of the total district bank
budget expenditures, only about 12 per cent is classified as being involved in
‘monetary and economic policy’ (BGFRS 2007b: tables 1.2; E.3). Of the 19,828
employees at district banks in 2006, only 928 (or 5 per cent) were involved in
monetary and economic policy. However, the district bank economic staff
provide an alternative view of the economy to that taken by the Board staff,
and this diversity of views is generally agreed to be a source of institutional
strength. Historically, some of the district banks have been particularly hospit-
able to insurgent groups of economists, such as the monetarists. White’s (2005)
estimates suggest that about 270 economists are employed by the district banks.
A disproportionate share is located at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York,
with some 15–20 at each of the other banks (Goodfriend 2000: 14). Over 70 per
cent of the articles on monetary policy published by US-based economists in
US-edited journals appear in Fed-published journals or are co-authored by Fed
economists (White 2005).
The district banks have no budgetary autonomy vis-à-vis the FRB. However,
fee-based services delivered by the district banks generate revenues for the banks
as a group that offset nearly half their budget expenditures. The balance of System
revenues is generated from earnings on the assets that are held in the Open
Market portfolio. These earnings far exceed the total expenses of the Federal
Reserve System, and the balance is returned to the US Treasury. This financial
autonomy is one key element in making the Fed independent of Congress.
The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) is the locus of decision-making in
open market policy—setting the level of the Federal funds rate and, increas-
ingly, interpreting that action for the benefit of outside observers. The FOMC
meets regularly—now eight times per year—in Washington D.C. in the offices
of the FRB. While there are only 12 voting members, there are many others in
attendance, including non-voting Presidents, Board staff, and district bank
staff. By convention, the Chair of the FRB is selected to be Chair of the FOMC.
All observers concur that the Fed Chair is far and away the most influential
member, as he controls the agenda and the staff (Woolley 1984). Her or his
personal style looms large for most participants. Alan Greenspan, for example,
was famous for opening the policy discussions in the FOMC by offering his
analysis and stating a policy preference. On occasion, Greenspan would use that
opportunity to explicitly ask for Committee support for his preferred policy.
314
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Greenspan routinely led a lengthy discussion of monetary policy issues with the
Board on Mondays prior to FOMC meetings. Meyer (2004: 51) suggests this
contributed to the near absence of FOMC dissents by Board governors.
315
The US Federal Reserve and the Politics of Monetary Policy
By the end of August 2007, however, the existence of a widespread crisis was
clear, and Bernanke’s tone became more cautious. He essentially said that
‘nobody saw it coming’.
316
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Although this episode appears to have been triggered largely by heightened concerns
about subprime mortgages, global financial losses have far exceeded even the most
pessimistic projections of credit losses on those loans. . . . [T]he difficulty of evaluating
the risks of structured products that can be opaque or have complex payoffs has become
more evident. (Bernanke 2007c)
Beginning in August 2007, the Fed adopted a sequence of novel and aggressive
intervention strategies intended to address the collapse of markets for certain
kinds of financial instruments.15 When the crisis intensified in September
2008, these novel strategies were expanded further. The Fed’s new measures
had been studied years earlier by the staff as hypothetical responses to two
potential threats: deflation and resulting zero nominal interest rates, or the
sharp reduction in outstanding government debt possible with sustained
budget surpluses.16 These new strategies radically changed the Fed’s balance
sheet, which more than doubled in size and profoundly increased in risk.17
The Fed began in August 2007 by liberalizing the terms of access to the
discount window. In December, the Fed defined new intervention ‘facilities’
that presented a way to address liquidity problems without generally lowering
interest rates. The Term Auction Facility18 (TAF, launched in December 2007)
provided funds through the discount window; the Term Securities Lending
Facility (TSLF, created in March 2008) lends treasury securities to primary
dealers19 in exchange for less liquid securities at rates determined through
auctions. The Primary Dealer Credit Facility (PDCF, created in March 2008)
lends through the discount window to Primary Dealers. At the same time, the
Fed announced an aggressive programme of ‘repurchase agreements’ through
the open market desk.20
By October 2008, near-collapse in credit markets brought another round
of innovations. Some actions, by the Fed alone, were authorized under the
‘unusual and exigent circumstances’ clause of Federal Reserve Act Section 13(3)
which had never been invoked.21 These included the Asset Backed Commercial
Paper Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility (AMLF, September 2008),
Commercial Paper Funding Facility (CPFF, October 2008), and the Money Mar-
ket Investor Funding Facility (MMIFF, October 2008). The Fed began purchasing
obligations of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. The remaining investment banks,
Goldman Sachs and Morgan Stanley, were declared to be ‘bank holding com-
panies’, bringing them under the direct regulatory supervision of the Fed. The
Fed began paying interest on required reserves for the first time.
317
The US Federal Reserve and the Politics of Monetary Policy
Perhaps most stunning, the Fed and Treasury cooperated in promoting what
was widely called ‘the bailout bill’ to create a $700 billion fund to be used to buy
government equity positions in financial institutions (and indeed, any firm).22
This abrupt reversal of prior free-market rhetoric seemed to have the perverse
effect of telling investors that conditions were far worse than they had previ-
ously thought. Stock markets swooned worldwide and US consumer confidence
hit a record low. Credit markets did show signs of recovery, as spreads between
government and interbank borrowing rates began to narrow.
At the technical level, the Fed’s new strategies were similar to intervention
techniques widely used in Europe. Through loans, swaps, and outright pur-
chases, these programmes replaced billions of dollars of illiquid financial assets
with high-quality treasury securities, all in an effort to keep financial markets
functioning.23
Repeatedly during the crisis, actions were undertaken in close coordination
with the G-10 central banks. On numerous occasions central banks simultan-
eously undertook parallel interventions to address liquidity issues.24 Extraor-
dinary swap lines were created with the ECB, BOE, and SNB; and later expanded
and extended.25 There were additional coordinated interventions conducted by
G-10 central banks.26
Critics were justified in calling the undertaking a bailout of financial markets,
but it was incorrect to suggest there were no costs for the financial institutions and
thus that moral hazard was unquestionably being encouraged.27 Politically, how-
ever, the perception was widespread in the United States that the central bank was
bailing out Wall Street, while ordinary citizens were losing their homes. The future
strengthening of financial regulation in the United States looks quite certain.
Transparency
318
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
319
The US Federal Reserve and the Politics of Monetary Policy
Two factors shape the Fed’s relationships with other political institutions and
with the media. First, when conservative (i.e. Republican) politicians control
any one of the House, Senate or Presidency, they are in a position to veto any
legislative initiatives hostile to the Fed (Krehbiel 1998; Morris 2000). Second,
when the economy is doing well, the Fed’s political environment has been
benign, no matter what the distribution of partisan preferences.
Since the Carter administration (1977–80), Democrats have had unified con-
trol of Congress and the Presidency for only two years, 1993–4. That is, Repub-
licans controlled at least one veto point at all other times. Although the Reagan
Presidency (1981–8) saw ample tension between the administration and the
Fed (Greider 1987; Woodward 2001), the relatively supportive political context
provided the political cover that the Fed needed in order to establish the notion
that a credible low-inflation policy could yield acceptable rates of employment
and economic growth.
Congress
One relevant indicator of Congressional interest is the proportion of all hear-
ings in both House and Senate dealing with monetary policy, inflation, prices,
interest rates, and price controls.32 Consistent with the notion that a good
320
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
The Administration
Classic studies of the politics of macroeconomic policy in the United States
have been based around two assumptions. First, Presidents dominate macro-
economic policy. Second, Democrats seek to reduce unemployment, while
Republicans try to reduce inflation (Bartels and Brady 2003; Hibbs 1977).
There are many accounts from studies of US monetary policy of Presidents
and their advisors trying to influence monetary policy, usually in an expan-
sionary direction, and commonly as a presidential election approaches
(Woodward 2001).
The FOMC transcripts show that the Administration and fiscal policy get
regular attention from the FOMC, more so than Congress, with more frequent,
321
The US Federal Reserve and the Politics of Monetary Policy
sharper upswings (Woolley 2007). This record belies any notion that the Fed’s
inflation responsibilities, independence, and power enable it to be indifferent
to fiscal policy. Increases in FOMC attention to the Administration are linked to
major new budget and taxing initiatives generated from the White House. For
example, in 2001, FOMC members devoted a lot of time to discussing Bush
administration fiscal policy and its likely effects on the economy.
The Media
Increased media attention to policy problems and institutions often presages
policy innovation (Baumgartner and Jones 1993). The pattern of attention to
the Fed and monetary policy by major US newspapers since 1978 has essentially
followed the path of inflation—trending steadily downward. A combined count
of articles reporting on monetary policy by three leading newspapers, Wall
Street Journal, Washington Post, and New York Times, from 1977 to 2006 reveals
a steady decline during the period (Woolley 2007). From a journalistic perspec-
tive, monetary policy became less interesting and less newsworthy.
In summary, in recent years the political environment of the Federal Reserve
has been very benign. It is a near-certainty that this flows from macroeconomic
performance that has been good and steady. With the financial crisis and
economic slowdown of early 2008, joined with the context of a Presidential
election year, Congressional and media attention has increased dramatically as
one would expect.
The heart of discourse inside the FOMC has to do with the conduct of monetary
policy in response to inflation and economic output. This is where the policy
action really is, and it is where we would expect to see considerable change during
this period, given accounts by informed ‘insider’ observers like Blinder and Good-
friend. The results from the FOMC transcripts confirm that important changes
occurred. Over time, there was less focus on the details of the implementation of
policy—interest rates, money supply targeting, etc.—and more on understanding
and steering the primary targets—inflation and growth of output.
322
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
0.120 16
14
0.100
Reference lines/Total lines
12
0.080
Inflation rate
10
Infl References
0.060 8 Recent Core CPI
10 per. Mov. Avg. (Infl References)
6
0.040
4
0.020
2
0.000 0
17/1/1978
17/1/1980
17/1/1982
17/1/1984
17/1/1986
17/1/1988
17/1/1990
17/1/1992
17/1/1994
17/1/1996
17/1/1998
17/1/2000
Date
declined and stabilized, the proportion of meeting time devoted to inflation has
at least doubled (see Figure 14.5). In the initial period from mid-1978 through
mid-1983, attention to inflation declined roughly as the observed core rate of
inflation declined. However, the increasing core rate from 1984 to 1990, while
modest by standards of prior history, was accompanied by large increases in
FOMC concern. In this period, the FOMC was determined to demonstrate the
credibility of its own commitment to stable, low inflation. From then on, the
Fed’s rhetorical responses to inflation became, by historical standards, hyper-
sensitive. This may be expected in an institution intent on building a credible
commitment to maintaining low rates of inflation.
As early as 1978, the FOMC discussed a proposal from district bank presidents to
set long-term targets for the monetary aggregates as a way of trying to influence
long-run expectations about inflation, especially on the part of people engaged in
contract negotiations throughout the economy (FOMCT, 18 April 1978). Objec-
tions were based on the fear that their instruments were insufficient to assure that
they could hit the target—and the result for Fed credibility would be worse.
Nearly a decade later, another district bank president argued explicitly for
inflation targets (FOMCT, 15 December 1986). He argued that, given the prob-
lems with relying on the monetary aggregates as guides to policy, announcing
long-run targets for inflation would be an effective way of communicating more
clearly with the public. However, despite some expressions of interest, the topic
was dropped with little extended discussion.
323
The US Federal Reserve and the Politics of Monetary Policy
A few members continued to raise the issue from time to time. Partly in
response, in February 1995, at a time when related legislation had been
introduced in Congress, Chairman Greenspan organized an FOMC discussion
on the topic, with ‘pro’ and ‘con’ statements from members in order to be able
to define a Fed position on anticipated Congressional legislation on inflation
targets. The debate in the FOMC was framed as one between considering a
single goal as opposed to multiple goals. Again, the argument was made that
setting such a target would not be credible and, thus, would undermine Fed
reputation. Doubts were expressed that the Bundesbank had, in practice, either a
single overarching price stability objective or that its alleged credibility actually
bought it much of a reduced cost of fighting inflation. Greenspan concluded
the discussion by observing:
We now understand why this Committee has had difficulty confronting this issue. It is
because we are as split down the middle as we could possibly get. . . . My own impression
is that even if we now locked into law a fixed inflation rate—say, 2 per cent or 1 per cent—
and the Congress voted for it with a large majority, in the first recession everyone would
be arguing to go in a different direction. . . . You may recall that a couple of years ago, we
all basically said we were going to have to move early on the up side or we would not
achieve anything resembling price stability. Now, I submit to you that is exactly what we
did. . . . But that objective is not being implemented in a straight line because we have
recognized, and I think correctly, that the Congress would not give us a mandate to do
that. . . . We [sh]ould always be moving in the direction of price stability, recognizing that
we would not do so in a straight line because I do not think we have the philosophical,
cultural, or political support in this society for that. (FOMCT, 1 February 1995: 58)
The committee returned to the issue again in late 1999 and in 2000. In June 2000,
Greenspan again ended the discussion by arguing that the claims for the benefits
of inflation targeting were empirically dubious and the practice politically risky.
‘It is too soon’, he stated, ‘to make a judgment as to whether official inflation
targeting actually works’ (FOMCT, 27 June 2000: 84). Moreover, Greenspan
observed that attempting to get agreement within the FOMC to pursue a specific
price level, without regard to the cost of getting there, would be too divisive.
With the appointment of Ben Bernanke as Chair in February 2006, the Fed,
for the first time, was headed by someone whose reputation was almost exclu-
sively as an academic.35 All Fed Chairs starting with William McChesney
Martin (1951–70; Burns 1970–8; Miller 1978–9; Volcker 1979–87; Greenspan
1987–2006) had been distinguished by their pragmatic, eclectic approach to the
conduct of policy. They emphatically were not partisans for any panaceas
popular in academia. Bernanke, by contrast, was known as an advocate of
inflation targeting long before entering public life (e.g. Bernanke and Mishkin
1997). In September 2006, Bernanke was joined on the Board by Frederic
Mishkin, a long-time academic collaborator and inflation targeting advocate.36
It seems likely that there was an understanding involved in Bush’s appoint-
ing in quick succession long-time Fed staff ‘baron’ and Greenspan advisor
324
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Donald Kohn as Fed Vice-Chair in May 2006, followed a few weeks later by the
appointment of Mishkin as governor.37 Kohn was known to financial markets
and was understood to be a critic of inflation targeting. In May 2006, Bernanke
appointed Kohn to head a committee to study how the Fed communicates with
financial markets. Its work eventually generated a consensus in favour of
announcing longer-term forecasts, similar to practice at the ECB and the Bank
of England.38
325
The US Federal Reserve and the Politics of Monetary Policy
0.080
0.070
References/ Total lines
0.060
0.020
0.010
0.000
17/1/1978
17/1/1979
17/1/1980
17/1/1981
17/1/1982
17/1/1983
17/1/1984
17/1/1985
17/1/1986
17/1/1987
17/1/1988
17/1/1989
17/1/1990
17/1/1991
17/1/1992
17/1/1993
17/1/1994
17/1/1995
17/1/1996
17/1/1997
17/1/1998
17/1/1999
17/1/2000
17/1/2001
Date
emerging Europe, both in the details of specific comments and in the broad
trends in discourse in the FOMC.
The FOMC received staff briefings from time to time that mentioned the
Maastricht process and progress toward European monetary union, but Maas-
tricht was hardly a big issue in its discussions. The first references one can
find from FOMC members (as opposed to staff) reveal a plainly sceptical tone—
dubious about the politics of monetary union; dubious about the political will
required to meet the criteria specified for monetary union; and uncertain about
where the project was really going. In 1994 members discussed the implications of
the creation of the European Monetary Institute for the Bank for International
Settlements. Would the BIS ‘be effectively neutered’?39 Would the problem of
meeting the Maastricht convergence criteria provoke an economic slowdown in
Europe?40 In 1995, the FOMC heard that moves toward European monetary union
were a source of uncertainty, and would lead to increased market volatility.41
In 1996, the FOMC was briefed that France and Germany will likely lead ‘a
small band’ into full economic and monetary union.42 Again in 1996, doubts
were expressed that the future ECB and the euro could match the standard of
value achieved by the D-Mark. Therefore there was a need for the FOMC to
think clearly about ‘what kinds of arrangements we will want to have with that
central bank.’43 Also in 1996, participants asked whether the French were
fiddling the Maastricht criteria and whether this will get the blessing of the
European Commission.44
Doubts begin to recede in 1997, when the FOMC was advised that European
monetary union was likely to begin on schedule with 11 participants, but
326
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
the fiscal criteria in the Maastricht Treaty would be ‘missed or fudged’ by most.45
In mid-1998, they were told ‘jitters’ about the introduction of the euro were ‘out
of the way’, and there was a risk that the US dollar would decline against
European currencies.46 In September 1998, the FOMC was briefed on technical
issues concerning the exchange of D-Mark-denominated assets for euro-denom-
inated assets. In December 1998, it was noted that the Fed and the ECB are likely
to maintain official interest rates for the early months of 1999, which should
provide ‘a very good background for a successful introduction of the euro’.47 It
was noted in February 1999: ‘The weekend conversion to the euro went quite
smoothly. . . . ’48 In August 1999, the FOMC were reminded, unfavourably, of the
strong market response to statements made by ECB president Duisenberg.49
The discussions inside the FOMC about Europe, as revealed by systematic
keyword searches, have two important characteristics: First, in the period 1978–
82, over half the references to institutions or actions located in the European
continent (including the UK) referred to a specific country, central bank, or
currency. As is illustrated in Figure 14.7, from August 1998 forward, in a striking
change, 80 per cent of those references were exclusively to ‘European’ institu-
tions.50 Europe became a reality for the FOMC.
Second, the frequency of FOMC references to institutions or events located in
the European continent increased continuously from 1992 to the end of 2001.
In short, not only did FOMC participants substitute ‘euro-talk’ for discussions
1.0
0.9
Proportion of ‘Euro’ References
0.8
0.7
0.6
Series1
0.5
10 per. Mov.
Avg. (Series1)
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
17/1/1978
17/1/1979
17/1/1980
17/1/1981
17/1/1982
17/1/1983
17/1/1984
17/1/1985
17/1/1986
17/1/1987
17/1/1988
17/1/1989
17/1/1990
17/1/1991
17/1/1992
17/1/1993
17/1/1994
17/1/1995
17/1/1996
17/1/1997
17/1/1998
17/1/1999
17/1/2000
17/1/2001
Date
Figure 14.7. ‘Euro’ references (EMS, EMU, ECB, Euro) as share of FOMC references to
European countries and institutions (e.g. Bundersbank, Bank of France, Germany,
France)
Source: Author’s calculations, see Woolley (2007).
327
The US Federal Reserve and the Politics of Monetary Policy
0.003
0.025
References/Total lines
0.002
all europe
0.015
10 per. Mov.
Avg. (all
0.001 europe)
0.005
0
17/1/1978
17/1/1979
17/1/1980
17/1/1981
17/1/1982
17/1/1983
17/1/1984
17/1/1985
17/1/1986
17/1/1987
17/1/1988
17/1/1989
17/1/1990
17/1/1991
17/1/1992
17/1/1993
17/1/1994
17/1/1995
17/1/1996
17/1/1997
17/1/1998
17/1/1999
17/1/2000
17/1/2001
Date
Figure 14.8. All references to european currencies, central banks, or countries, FOMC
meetings 1978–2001
Source: Author’s calculations, see Woolley (2007).
Conclusions
US economic performance in the period from 1979 to 2007 was quite good—
economic growth remained strong and was less volatile; inflation dropped and
became more steady; unemployment fell and also became more steady. In part,
the ‘good news’ for policy-makers reflected little more than good luck. In part, it
reflected conscious choices and adjustments that policy-makers made. Both the
luck and the choices were conditioned by political alignments that facilitated
good (or poor) choices. Mainstream analysts, however, failed to anticipate the
growing risks that convulsed the economy in 2008.
The Fed’s control over the key monetary policy instrument, the Federal funds
rate, was never seriously criticized, much less contested. In short, the Fed’s
power over its monetary policy instruments has hardly been greater. While
economic performance, as measured by outcomes, was quite good, a close
observer will see that the Fed has been surprised repeatedly by developments
in capital markets and foreign-exchange markets. Despite a determination to be
ahead of the game in fighting inflation, policy-makers have nonetheless been
reactive, and that is certainly true with respect to their Congressional audience.
328
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
There were dramatic changes in the way policy was discussed and conceptu-
alized inside the FOMC. Monetarism and monetary targeting bloomed and
faded. Discussion of indicators of real output increased dramatically. Attention
to inflation soared, despite objective evidence that inflation was well under
control. Europe became a reality for the FOMC and of increasing importance.
While Europeanization mattered at the Fed, the Fed did not look to Europe or
the ECB for inspiration or guidance at a technical level. Nonetheless, many
within the Fed have followed with great interest the ECB’s engagement with
inflation targeting and the different approaches to transparency at the ECB,
Bank of England, and elsewhere. These projects are viewed with great sympathy
at the Fed, but, as reflected by the statement of Alan Greenspan quoted above,
the Fed has been sceptical about inflation targeting on empirical grounds and
cautious given the US legal context. The clear misgivings about US policy from
the European side have had to do with the fear that the Fed is mistakenly
unleashing a round of inflation.
The crisis of 2007–8 showed that the world’s leading central banks shared
quite similar understandings of their context, and similar optimism about the
pricing of risk in financial markets. Central banks responded in coordination
using very similar techniques. It is hard to imagine more compelling evidence
of ‘convergence’ than what is offered in these events. This convergence is
driven by the profound globalization of finance, which spread primarily US-
originated securitized mortgages to financial institutions worldwide. The Fed is
at the heart of this process, but it is not clear as of today, that the Fed weighs
very heavily the impacts its policies create outside the United States.
The crisis also illustrated clearly that Fed’s unilateral power of action in
cleaning up after financial crises is not in question—although in sorting
through the wreckage after the still-unfolding crisis is over, conditions may
change. The challenge for coming years will be for private markets, central
banks, and financial regulators across the world to devise means to expose
and control financial risks. The magnitude of the crisis, despite the Fed’s rescue
efforts, assures that the United States will see a searching examination of
financial regulation.
Notes
1. I appreciate the helpful comments on previous drafts from the editors, Michael Moran,
Randall Henning, Benjamin Cohen, and Robert Franzese. The work benefited from the
research assistance of Andrea Haupt and David Weaver.
2. In recent years the Federal Reserve has regarded the deflator of Personal Consumption
Expenditures (PCE) as a more accurate measure of inflation. The CPI and PCE are
highly correlated.
3. US Code Title 12, Chapter 3.
329
The US Federal Reserve and the Politics of Monetary Policy
4. The Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978, also known as the Hum-
phrey Hawkins Act, revised the Employment Act of 1946. The 1946 Act had stated
that the government’s goals, and only by implication the Fed’s, were ‘to promote
maximum employment, production and purchasing power’.
5. For many years, the term of the chairman happened to be renewable during a
presidential election year. However, starting with Bernanke, the terms are aligned to
the middle of the Presidential term.
6. The regulations are codified in the Code of Federal Regulations (CFR) title 12, Banks and
Banking and include parts 201 through 233. The CFR is officially updated yearly, and
is now available online: http://www.access.gpo.gov/nara/cfr/cfr-table-search.html#
page1.
7. Division of Research and Statistics, the Division of Monetary Affairs, and the Division
of International Finance. Other divisions also employ PhD economists. http://www.
federalreserve.gov/research/default.htm.
8. In October 2008, Greenspan admitted in Congressional testimony that he had mis-
takenly presumed that the self-interest of banks and other financial institutions
would be sufficient to protect shareholders. See Kara Scannell and Sudeep Reddy,
‘Greenspan Admits Errors to Hostile House Panel’, Wall Street Journal, 24 October
2008. [http://online.wsj.com/article/SB122476545437862295.html.]
9. The FFIEC, created in 1978 by the Financial Institutions Regulatory and Interest Rate
Control Act, is intended to create common standards for financial institutions exam-
inations among the Federal Reserve System, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corpor-
ation, the National Credit Union Administration, the Office of the Comptroller of the
Currency, and the Office of Thrift Supervision.
10. Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corpor-
ation, and the Office of Thrift Supervision.
11. The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (previously the Standing Commit-
tee on Banking Regulation and Supervisory Practices) was launched in 1975 by
G-10 central banks at the Bank for International Settlements (BIS) in Basel. Now,
the Committee includes representatives from Belgium, Canada, France, Germany,
Italy, Japan, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, the
United Kingdom, and the United States. Countries are represented by their
central bank and/or also by other authorit(ies) with formal responsibility for
the prudential supervision of banking. The United States and UK have been
driving forces in the Basel process (Calomiris and Litan 2000); http://www.bis.
org/bcbs/index.htm.
12. Freddie Mac: Created in 1970 as Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation; Fannie
Mae: Created in 1938 as Federal National Mortgage Association; 1989 legislation
severed Fannie Mae’s supervision by the Federal Home Loan Bank Board.
13. ‘Subprime’ is not precisely defined. Generally, subprime mortgages have adjustable
rates following a fixed low rate for the first two years. The adjustable period is typically
28 years—the so-called 2/28 mortgage. The down payment may be zero. Borrower
income may not be documented fully or at all. By contrast ‘prime’ mortgages involve
a substantial down payment of 10 to 20 per cent of the home price, no low introduc-
tory rate, and careful documentation of borrower income.
330
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
331
The US Federal Reserve and the Politics of Monetary Policy
27. From their peak values in 2007, NYSE financial stocks had fallen some 45% by
November 2008. Lehman Brothers stock went from $65 þ to $0 in seven months.
Bear-Stearns stockholders lost something like 90% of the value of their investments in
a matter of days. Banks took losses estimated at over $200 billion (Bloomberg 29
March 2008). Collateral for loans and advances through the Fed’s discount window
for non-government securities without current market prices have been valued at 70
to 85 of par, which is a substantial allowance for risk by the Fed. See http://www.
frbdiscountwindow.org/discountmargins.cfm?hdrID¼21&dtlID¼83.
28. Especially the rulings in Merrill v. FOMC 585 F 2d 778 (1977) The ‘domestic policy
directive’, the instructions to the Open Market Desk were distinguished from the
transcripts and accorded greater confidentiality by the Supreme Court. FOMC v.
Merrill 443 US 340. Department of Justice statement may be found here: http://
www.usdoj.gov/oip/foia_updates/Vol_XV_2/page3.htm.
29. The 1994 move to a tighter policy stance came after a long period of stable policy and
was the first tightening action in nearly five years.
30. Greenspan, FOMCT, 31 January 1995, p. 21: ‘It is my impression that House Banking
Committee Chairman Leach has been holding off on any legislative initiatives in this
area on the grounds that we are going to do it ourselves . . . if we don’t set our own
policy, there will be real interest in that committee in trying to do something.’
31. We might not expect to find policy-makers in truly independent institutions regularly
pondering their independent status. In 1981, arguing for immediate public release of
the policy directive, Governor Henry Wallich suggested that his colleagues should
‘look at what other central banks do’. The Bundesbank, he observed, calls a press
conference every time they take action and explain what they are doing. ‘How could
that be?’ responded another Governor. Wallich answered, ‘Well, I guess they are an
independent central bank’ FOMCT, 2 February 1981.
32. These data are at: http://www.policyagendas.org/datatools/toolbox/analysis.asp.
33. Mack’s legislation was known as the ‘Economic Growth and Price Stability Act’. In
104 it was S1266/HR2445; in 105 it was S611/HR 1396; in 106 it was S1492.
34. This testimony is archived on the FRB website.
35. Bernanke joined the Board as a Governor in 2002, then resigned in 2005 to become
Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisors. Arthur Burns had much more public
involvement.
36. Mishkin was research director at the Federal Reserve Bank NY from 1994 to 1997.
37. Mishkin and Kohn were both under consideration as possible appointees as Vice-
Chairman (Ip 2006).
38. Bernanke’s appointment followed a precedent of assigning similar tasks to the FRB
Vice-Chairmen including Roger Ferguson, Alan Blinder, and David Mullins.
39. Greenspan, FOMCT, 20 July 1994 conference call.
40. Governor Lindsey, FOMCT, 6 July 1995.
41. Staff advisor Truman, 26 September 1995.
42. Staff advisor Truman, 21 May 1996.
43. President Jordan, 2 July 1996.
44. Colloquy between Governor Lindsey and Staff advisors Truman and Fisher, 24 Sep-
tember 1996. Truman opined, ‘The question, Governor Lindsey, is whether we
are talking about high politics or grass root politics and that is another source of
332
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
uncertainty. The high politics may bring it about. The question is whether the grass
root politics will follow the high politics.’
45. Staff advisor Truman, 2 July 1997.
46. Staff advisor Hooper, 30 June 1998.
47. FOMC Vice-Chair McDonough, 22 December 1998.
48. Staff advisor Fisher, 2 February 1999.
49. Staff advisor Fisher.
50. That is, EMU, EMS, ECB, or any word or phrase with ‘euro’ in it.
333
This page intentionally left blank
Part VI
Convergence and Divergence
This page intentionally left blank
15
Financial Supervision:
Internationalization,
Europeanization, and Power
Michael Moran and Huw Macartney
We are grateful for many helpful comments offered in the British Academy Workshop of
November 2007, at which drafts of chapters were presented; to the editors for their acute
comments, and their patience; and above all to Lucia Quaglia for numerous perceptive com-
ments and characteristically generous sharing of information.
337
Financial Supervision
These last remarks provide the shape of what follows, for they allow us to
make a distinction between three different faces of change that deeply affect
supervisory worlds: the structural, the institutional, and the epistemic. The
structural face of convergence/divergence refers to changes in the scale, organ-
ization, and trading patterns of financial markets and in the key actors in those
markets. The extent to which, for instance, convergence is, or is not, taking
place through the cross-national integration of markets is obviously a crucial
underlying force—though not necessarily a determining force—in the extent
to which regulatory and supervisory institutions are being reshaped. The insti-
tutional face of convergence/divergence refers to the extent to which institu-
tions responsible for regulation and supervision are coming to resemble each
other in their structures and responsibilities and, at the most developed, the
extent to which European Union–level institutions are appearing. Finally, the
epistemic face refers to the extent to which the creation of an epistemic com-
munity of banking regulators has been hastened in the age of the euro; the
extent to which, if it has been hastened, that process can be traced to the
experience of European monetary integration; and the extent to which an
epistemic community characterizes the borders of either the EU as a whole or
the Euro Area?
These distinctions are important for one obvious analytic reason: that we
should not expect the three faces of convergence/divergence to change in unison,
or even to vary in the same direction. But they are also important for substantive
(historical) reasons. Structural convergence, and the supervisory issues that it
raises, is hardly the creation of the age of the Euro Area. Likewise, the organization
of supervision neither dates from the establishment of the Euro Area, nor is it
confined to the Euro Area or the EU. On the contrary, for a long time the key arena
of supervision has lain, and continues to lie, in the Basel Committee on Banking
Supervision of the Bank for International Settlements. That is a natural and
unavoidable outcome of structural convergence in global banking markets
(Basel Committee on Banking Supervision 2003, 2007). Perhaps most important
of all, the epistemic community of central bank regulators and supervisors has a
long history—and, as Marcussen’s work (2007b, and in this volume) shows, may
indeed be subject to a process of convergence that is more or less independent of
anything that is happening either in the EU or in the Euro Area.
Of these three faces of convergence/divergence, the epistemic face is the most
important, for it affects the exercise of ‘soft’ power (Nye 2004). Power in cross-
national banking supervision is ‘soft’ because governance operates via dispersed
networks, not hierarchically authoritative institutions; because compliance is
the product of negotiation; and because the ‘soft technology’ of bank regula-
tion depends on the development of shared understandings about the pur-
poses, the techniques, and the substantive rules of banking supervision. All
these reasons help explain why it makes sense to speak of an epistemic com-
munity in cross-national banking supervision and regulation.
338
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
339
Financial Supervision
The ECSB shall contribute to the smooth conduct of policies pursued by the competent
authorities relating to the prudential supervision of credit institutions and the stability of
the financial system.
But Article 105:6 sets boundaries to the exercise of any powers by the ECSB that
might intrude into the competence of national supervisory authorities:
The Council may, acting unanimously on a proposal from the Commission and after
consulting the ECB and after receiving the assent of the European Parliament, confer
upon the ECB specific tasks concerning policies relating to the prudential supervision of
credit institutions and other financial institutions with the exception of insurance under-
takings.
In Dermine’s (2006: 61) words again ‘The Treaty is explicit on the principle of
decentralization and allocation of regulatory powers and supervisory powers to
national central banks. It is only in very special circumstances, and with unan-
imity in the European Council, that the ECB will be allowed to regulate or
supervise financial institutions.’
This formal picture of decentralization needs to be qualified in three ways.
First, the pattern of financial supervision at national level is a complex patch-
work, often plagued by coordination problems—evident in the crisis of 2007,
examined below. It is a curious mix of different historical institutional legacies
(central bankers); of different private and public partnerships (depositor protec-
tion schemes); and the diffusion of independent regulatory agencies, such as the
UK Financial Services Authority (FSA), dating from 1997, and the German
Bundesanstalt für Finanzdienstleistungsaufsicht (BaFin), dating from 2002 (for
overview, Kahn and Santos 2004). What is more, the patchwork is becoming
more complex with the accession of new EU member states carrying a wide
range of institutional histories and supervisory traditions (Johnson 2006;
340
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
341
Financial Supervision
groups. Out of approximately 8700 licensed banks in the EU, 46 large banking groups
with cross-border activities (both wholesale and retail) have emerged. They represent 58
per cent of total EU banking assets and more than one quarter of their assets (over 14
per cent of total) are in other Member States. 21 of these groups have significant
operations outside their home country. . . . In the Member States which acceded in
2004, on average 70 per cent of banking assets are foreign-owned and the market
share of foreign banks often exceeds 50 per cent.
(Economic and Financial Committee 2007b: para. 22)
342
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
343
Financial Supervision
tacit knowledge of those with business experience to the rise of those who
claim a professionalized, systematic knowledge of bank regulation. The most
developed version is the emergence of the profession of bank regulator,
either in specialized divisions within central banks or in ‘non-majoritarian’
regulatory organizations like the United Kingdom FSA. Whilst there exists no
single policy paradigm, there is a high degree of homogeneity within the
‘community’ of banking regulators. It is composed predominantly of trained
research economists and specialists with PhDs in financial economics. For
example, the Committee of European Banking Supervisors (CEBS) comprises
46 active members from respective national regulatory agencies. Of this num-
ber, three are professors at the universities of Amsterdam, Portugal, and
Vienna (Arnold Schilder, Pedro Duarte Neves, and Andreas Ittner), whilst
a further three are university lecturers (Rumen Simeonov, Jukka Vesala, and
Mihaly Erdos). At least eight of the members hold PhDs, whilst a further three
have postgraduate qualifications in economics. Of the remaining mem-
bers, the majority are trained research economists. This is clearly a ‘scientific’
community.
Second, the creation of the ECB has itself been a major contribution to this
epistemic convergence, for it functions as a highly technocratic institution: a
big employer of the professionally qualified; a big supplier of standardized data
conforming to agreed technical forms; and a major disseminator—through its
working paper publications, its monthly review, and its twice-yearly Financial
Stability Review—of bodies of data. Just how far the discussion of regulatory
issues is now encapsulated in a highly technical language that the profes-
sionals use to communicate is illustrated by a passage in the June 2007 issue
of the ECB Financial Stability Review. A boxed study offers an elaborately
modelled account of banking and insurance risks, which covers three pages.
It introduces the features in the following way:
From a financial stability perspective, it is useful to decompose the risks faced by the
financial sector into systematic, sector-specific and idiosyncratic components. The aim
of this Box is to apply a latent factor model framework to achieve such a decompos-
ition for both the banking and insurance sectors. Principal component analysis is a
dimension reduction technique that makes it possible to approximate large multivar-
iate datasets with a limited number of factors which account for the largest share of the
changes in the original data. The variance of the data can be explained by a model of
unobserved factors that are common to all or most of the variables, and an idiosyn-
cratic component which corresponds to variable-specific factors. In this way, each
variable can be represented as a linear combination of common factors plus idiosyn-
cratic ones. (ECB 2007: 115)
This scientific turn is not confined to the ECB. In states within the Euro Area
the very creation of the ECB has led to significant changes in goal definition
for those domestic institutions that carried out the central banking functions
now performed at supranational level. The consequence has been a major
344
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Increasingly, standards and best practices are set and defined at global level, for example
on accounting, auditing and banking capital requirements. Considering the size of the EU
market, and Europe’s experience in pragmatically uniting the legitimate call for harmon-
ised rules and the diverging needs of different markets/cultures/players, the EU must have
a leading role in standard setting at global level.
(Commission of the European Communities 2005: 15)
345
Financial Supervision
346
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
The character of the crisis has been concisely summarized by the Vice-Presi-
dent of the ECB as follows:
Banking crises usually spring from wider problems in the macro-economy, and
this crisis fits that pattern. Its origins lie in the financial history of the United
States in the new millennium: an age of cheap money, intense competition
between financial institutions, and a continuing history of financial innov-
ation; in other words, an extension of the now quite familiar history of the
financial services revolution. That competition opened up new markets, in
particular the notorious market in ‘sub-prime’ mortgage-backed loans, when
poor credit risks were encouraged to take out property-backed mortgages—
often on the basis of fraudulent declarations of ability to repay loans. The
extent of bad debt problems in that market became clear in spring 2007. The
mechanism by which these problems were more widely, indeed internation-
ally, transmitted shows one aspect of convergence that we identified earlier:
structural convergence. The growth of internationally integrated markets in
securitized debt led to the packaging of these sub-prime loans at attractive
rates. It was the packaging, and therefore the aggregation of these dubious
loans into securitized bundles, that left many financial institutions with com-
mercial paper that was of dubious worth—or in some cases actually worthless.
That in turn led to a climate revealed in any anatomy of financial crises: a crisis
of trust between actors in markets, an unwillingness to do business in this
atmosphere, and a consequential inability of some institutions to finance
their loan books. As always in financial crises, there were two elements which
interacted in complex ways: a ‘real’ crisis as some institutions discovered
that large parts of their loan book were worthless, or of considerably less
worth than imagined, since the value of the paper which had been securitized
had been greatly overvalued; and a crisis of trust encompassing a much wider
range of institutions as, in conditions of non-transparency, institutions
347
Financial Supervision
declined to deal with, especially to loan to, each other, in the absence of good
information about the scale of systemic problems.
The mechanism by which this was transmitted to Europe was the global
organization of this market in securitized paper. August saw bailouts for two
German banks, arranged in an ad hoc fashion by the Bundesbank, and disclos-
ure of serious losses at a range of other institutions in France and the Nether-
lands. In the same month the ECB, in its role as system manager, made the
largest injection of funds into the market since the ‘9/11’ crisis of 2001. In
September the crisis prompted the first public bank run in the United Kingdom
since the nineteenth century when customers queued outside the branches of
Northern Rock, a former building society converted into a bank with a large
mortgage property-backed loan book financed by borrowing on the inter-bank
market. The crisis of 9 August caused a sharp change in behaviour in the inter-
bank loan market; Northern Rock found it increasingly difficult to fund its
borrowing, and was obliged to reveal that it had turned to the Bank of England
for assistance. This announcement prompted a collapse of confidence in the
bank on the part of large numbers of individual investors, who queued to
withdraw their money. Repeated assurances from the elite of the domestic
regulatory community (the governor of the Bank of England, the Chancellor
of the Exchequer, and the head of the Financial Services Authority) failed to
convince depositors. Only the announcement on day five of the crisis that the
Exchequer—that is, the full resources of the state—stood behind Northern
Rock, and would guarantee all £28 billion of its deposits and, by implication,
the deposits of all other banks in the UK, saw an end to the public panic, though
not to Northern Rock’s problems, as a further loosening of the terms of
assistance in October showed (Bowers and Inman 2007). The exact connection
between the contagion of panic and real problems with the worth of Northern
Rock’s loan book has still to be established at the time of writing.
The crisis shows that structural convergence is now particularly important,
though it is not clear that we can identify an independent Euro Area effect.
The signs of this convergence are plain both in the development of integrated
markets dealing in the tainted paper, and in the rapid spread of the contagion of
panic across markets in different national jurisdictions.
In contrast, the crisis shows the persistence of institutional divergence. This
was naturally the case in the instance of the UK, which has remained outside
the Euro Area, and where the management of the crisis was largely determined
by domestic political pressures. In the case of the Euro Area, the diversity of
institutional responses is also striking. The epicentre of the crisis, the two
German banks that went under, was largely managed domestically, by ad hoc
coalitions organized principally by the Bundesbank.
The organization of the British crisis is particularly striking, for here we are
talking about the dominant banking centre in the EU. As we have noted, the
UK was not the only national system to experience crisis, but what makes the
348
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
case special are two considerations: the UK—or rather the City of London—is
the linchpin of the European banking system; and the crisis of Northern Rock
was peculiar in its public character, its scale, and its prolonged form. It
involved a complex system of bureaucratic politics between four institutional
actors: the Bank of England, as central bank responsible for the orderly con-
duct of the markets; the Financial Services Authority, the responsible regula-
tory body; the Treasury, which in the end was the only effective ultimate
guarantor because the resources of the state stood behind it; and other key
actors in the core executive, notably the Prime Minister, anxious that the crisis
not fatally damage public confidence in the capacity of the Labour Party to
manage financial markets. In part this bureaucratic politics involved the
familiar search for some means of effective coordination under the pressure of
a crisis which demanded rapid response, and the equally familiar ‘blame game’
which is played in all regulatory disasters.
But above all what is striking about the UK crisis is the way its attempted
resolution was prescribed by the high politics of the core executive. The
Treasury’s guarantee to cover all the deposits was prompted by the fear that
otherwise New Labour would experience its own ‘Black Wednesday’, the cur-
rency crisis that destroyed public confidence in the financial capacity of the
Conservative Party for more than a decade. What is more, the institutional and
epistemic faces of the UK system after the crisis were largely conditioned by
the domestic UK context. The intellectual content of the debate about the
regulation of systemic stability has been dominated by the interests of small
and medium-sized depositors: in the crisis-driven guarantee by the Chancel-
lor, as he desperately sought to avoid meltdown at the height of Northern Rock
panic, that all deposits would be safeguarded by the state; in the subsequent
ad hoc extension of the generosity of the deposit protection scheme; and in the
announcement that this is indeed only ad hoc, contingent on a review of the
scale of the whole scheme. The Chancellor has now foreshadowed the legisla-
tion that will be introduced to reform the system in the spring of 2008. It is still
not clear who the big winner will be. The Chancellor’s initial thoughts advan-
taged the Financial Services Authority, which would be given more statutory
control over the banking system (Parker and Strauss 2008). But the most recent
intervention in the debate about blame—the report of the House of Commons
Treasury Select Committee on the affair—is scathing in its judgement of FSA
regulatory incompetence (Treasury Committee 2008).
This interpretation is confirmed by the tentative scheme announced in
January 2008 to rescue Northern Rock through a convoluted public–private
partnership—a package designed to avoid tainting the Labour government
with the stain of nationalization of a major financial institution. Likewise the
institutional face of the crisis has been dominated by the ‘blame game’: the
attempt to blame the present administration for the allegedly uncoordinated
character of the present system; the attempt to avert blame, notably by the key
349
Financial Supervision
actor in the core executive, the Prime Minister, who is the official author of that
system; and the attempt by the different institutional actors (the central bank,
the Financial Services Authority, the Treasury) to shift blame between each other.
If structural convergence, and institutional divergence, was the mark of the
crisis, the epistemic face of the crisis is remarkable for its lack of change. Crises
in any regulatory system are important because they typically force actors to
think in entirely new ways, not just about the management of the particular
crisis, but about the management of the whole system. There is very little
evidence of this here. The ‘don’t panic’ response of the ECB president, Jean-
Claude Trichet, in mid-August 2007—‘I call on all parties concerned to continue
to keep their composure’—catches this resistance to anything epistemically
radical. Likewise the response of European Commissioner Charles McCreevy
after the mid-September meeting held when the Northern Rock crisis was still at
its most intense: ‘We are making progress, but I would not want to put it any
stronger than that. . . . We are moving to the next stage. You can only move as
fast as you are allowed’ (Barber 2007). It is true that as the systemic crisis
intensified in the spring of 2008 central banks were propelled to a more activist
stance in trying to stabilize the system; but this activism was belated, ad hoc
and uncoordinated.
Why is a system which is experiencing significant structural convergence,
and which in the crisis of 2007 suffered so dramatically the consequences of
that structural convergence, showing such an inability to converge institution-
ally and epistemically? The modern age of banking instability began in the early
1970s, and what has been most marked is precisely the capacity of policy actors
to learn from the successive crises—to remake institutions radically, and to
refashion their epistemic worlds. Why is the Eurosystem finding this so diffi-
cult?
Three possibilities suggest themselves. The first may be expressed in the
question: crisis, what crisis? The little local difficulties of summer and autumn
2007 were, after all, managed Trichet-fashion—by a little flexibility. It is, how-
ever, hard to maintain this equable response in the face of problems that
continue to unfold, the collapse of banks, and the first public run on a bank
in the EU’s leading banking member for over a century. A second possibility in
effect derives from neo-institutional theory: that the EU’s institutions are so
laden with veto points that, in McCreevy’s words, ‘you can only move as fast as
you are allowed’. But this is hard to reconcile with the evidence presented
earlier of the dense organized epistemic community, itself linked to wider
global communities of banking regulators, used to confronting problems of
regulation in a well-developed technical language. The ‘scientization’ of cen-
tral banking identified by Marcussen (this volume) has provided regulators
with a set of well-developed intellectual tools. A third possibility is that,
writing still as the crisis unfolds, we are too early to pick up the transform-
ations that may be taking place. It is, indeed, a feature of the transforming
350
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
power of crisis that even participants may not be aware just how much they are
changing under the pressure of critical events. And, as we have noted, the crisis
has already forced a growth in central bank activism in crisis management.
351
Financial Supervision
352
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
353
This page intentionally left blank
16
Monetary Policy Strategies
Iain Begg1
355
Monetary Policy Strategies
whether central bankers have focused too much on price stability, to the
neglect of the underlying stability of the financial system.
The chapter sets out what appear to be the main features of the state-of-the
art, delves into why they have arisen, and explores emerging directions
for monetary policy and unresolved debates. It shows that today’s strategies
reflect evolving ideas about what monetary policy can, cannot, and should do,
and that in the EU, at least, there has been an intriguing iteration between
institutional and constitutional changes and the development of strategies.
There may not be a single model of best practice, but it is clear that there are
systematic preferences.
Monetary policy has evolved considerably over the last quarter of a century. In
many parts of the world it has become the primary instrument of macroeco-
nomic policy, with fiscal policy relegated to a supporting role. Price stability
has been elevated to be the principal policy objective, while granting of
independence from political control and various other institutional changes
in central banking, such as resort to monetary policy committees (MPC)
and new approaches to transparency, have come to characterize the broad
approaches deployed (Blinder 2004; Blinder and Wyplosz 2004; Mishkin
2007a; Siklos 2002). In this process, power has shifted from politicians to
central bankers and an intriguing element has been that this transfer has
happened with only limited public debate and, despite occasional rumblings,
has not elicited much opposition.
New ideas about the purpose and scope of monetary policy have been highly
influential, leading in some cases to significant legal and institutional trans-
formations, such as those that altered the role of the Bank of England during
the 1990s (see Goodhart’s chapter in this volume). In others (notably the US
Fed), the effects of new ideas have been more subtle, with substantial changes
of style or emphasis which draw on new thinking about how to conduct
monetary policy, even though the institutional framework has been stable
(see Woolley, this volume). Amidst these changes, it is evident that the manner
in which the European Central Bank (ECB) has been constructed partly reflects
the Bundesbank tradition, but is partly also attributable to the evolving norms
and practices of the central banking community of the advanced nations
(see, also, Howarth’s chapter in this volume).
Bernanke (2004b) suggests that two over-arching frameworks for monetary
policy can be distinguished. Although he draws parallels with the distinction
between ‘instrument rules’ and ‘targeting rules’ common in much of the
literature, he contends that these labels are somewhat misleading and opts
instead for the terms simple feedback policies and forecast-based policies as more
356
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
357
Monetary Policy Strategies
reasons is one of the most tricky because of the uncertainty about how the
economy will evolve (see, also, Tucker 2006). While some trends lend them-
selves relatively straightforwardly to prediction, certain structural changes are,
by their nature, much harder to factor into decision-making or to identify as
they happen. In the UK, for example, the wave of immigration following the
2004 enlargement of the EU was bound to have effects on labour market
pressures, but these could not be fully predicted. Breakthroughs that result in
new sources of supply or new ways of producing may result in step-changes,
and it is too easily forgotten that economics is a behavioural rather than a hard
science: consumption or savings patterns will not always respond identically
to particular signals. Bernanke cites the productivity surge in the late 1990s as
such a change.
358
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Over the last 20 years, dissatisfaction with monetary targeting caused by the
lack of stability of the relationship between monetary growth and prices
(Mishkin 2007a) has been superseded by forms of inflation targeting as the
preferred approach. In essence, inflation targeting shifts the focus from the
intermediate target of monetary growth to the outcome variable—price stabil-
ity. Its emergence as a nominal anchor for policy reflects the conjunction of
new thinking about how to deal with the time inconsistency problem2 and to
manage expectations better. Mishkin (2007a) makes the point that central
bankers can, in practice, cope straightforwardly with time inconsistency prob-
lems by refusing to let the short-term dominate, but if politicians—who typic-
ally have shorter time horizons—are able to instruct the central bank, time
inconsistency will remain. This is one of the reasons why independence of
central banks has become part of the contemporary monetary policy package.
359
Monetary Policy Strategies
. An explicit numerical target for inflation, coupled with the aim of avoid-
ing volatility in either inflation or output. He observes that many central
banks acknowledge that they implement what he calls ‘flexible’ inflation
targeting—that is paying attention to stabilization of the real economy—
but suggests that the aims for the real economy and information about
trade-offs and weightings given to different objectives are neither explicit
nor consistent.
. Targeting forecasts of inflation rather than the inflation rate itself.
However, he is critical of monetary authorities that do not build-in to
360
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
their forecasts changes in the instrument rate itself, noting that for
private sector agents what shapes their behaviour is expectations of
future rate movements. Indeed, the information conveyed by the current
policy rate is only useful to the extent that it conveys information about
future rate developments.
. A high degree of transparency that simultaneously enhances central
bank accountability and contributes to the effective implementation of
policy. Svensson maintains that if inflation forecasts or output forecasts
do not include the projected effects of policy rate changes that would be
consistent with the optimal instrument rate path, they risk misleading
private agents. He therefore argues for publication of the optimal projec-
tion, including information on the optimal policy rate path.
According to Rose (2007), what is striking about inflation targeting regimes is
that they are the reverse of all three main elements of Bretton Woods: capital
movements are free, exchange rates are free to float, and it is the price level
which is targeted. He also notes that countries have not adopted inflation
targeting because of adherence to a rule-based international system, but have
taken this direction independently, resulting in a system that has grown
in what he describes as a ‘Darwinian’ way. Consequently, Rose (2007: 671)
comments, ‘the key players are central banks; these are now more independ-
ent, accountable and transparent than under Bretton Woods’. He notes,
further, that where Bretton Woods was increasingly criticized by prominent
academic economist, inflation targeting seems to find favour.
Best Practice?
There are, not surprisingly, differing views on the best approach to monetary
policy. Svensson (2006: 2) makes the simple point that
the implementation of best-practice monetary policy takes into account that monetary
policy is actually the management of private-sector expectations . . . [and that] . . . what
matters for private-sector decisions are the private sector’s expectations about future
interest rates. Therefore, the implementation of best-practice monetary policy consists
of announcing and motivating the bank’s forecasts of inflation, the output gap, and,
importantly, the instrument rate. This is the most effective way of managing private-
sector expectations.
Svensson consequently argues that the central bank should have its own view
of the optimal interest rate path, based on its analysis of economic develop-
ments. Whether or how much to divulge about the trend is a matter of
judgement. Indeed, judgement is widely regarded as the key component of
monetary policy strategy—after all why would we need central bankers if the
models they use were sufficient for the right decisions to be made?
361
Monetary Policy Strategies
362
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Institutional Structures
Different facets of the institutional structure within which central banks operate
can affect the approach to monetary policy. They include whether or not the
government retains powers to set operational targets, the power over appoint-
ments, including whether central bank board members can be fired, and the
arrangements for holding the central bank to account. At an operational level,
the composition of the monetary policy committee that makes policy decisions
and the manner in which it functions varies among leading central banks.
All these factors, and more, can have some impact on monetary policy
strategy. The Bank of England, for example, has an MPC with nine members,
five of whom are internal and four external. While Eddie George was Gov-
ernor, he always voted last on interest rate decisions, and always sided with the
majority (and hence, on close decisions, acted as the swing voter). His succes-
sor has sided a couple of times with the minority, a tactic than can itself be a
signal about future intentions if markets assign greater weight to the Gover-
nor’s view. Alan Greenspan, by contrast, signalled his view in advance, argu-
ably defying the rest of the open-market committee to contradict him. The
Governor of the Reserve Bank of New Zealand is the sole decision-maker, but is
advised by a committee, with the result that the decisions are, in fact, more
collegial than the formal arrangements imply, according to Svensson4 (2007).
363
Monetary Policy Strategies
do have strategic ramifications, a good illustration being the form that the
inflation target takes. In some cases, the objective is set in terms of a range,
which can give the central bank some leeway, though at the expense of
increasing uncertainty. Others specify a point target, making it more evident
to private agents when conditions presage a change of interest rates, thereby
enhancing predictability. Some, such as the Fed (not an inflation targeter), do
not disclose a value for inflation, leaving it to be inferred by market actors.
Two central banks that employ very similar approaches are the Swedish
Riksbank and the Bank of England. Both have symmetrical inflation targets
with a 1 percentage point tolerance band. The Riksbank’s framework also
provides for inflation being returned to the target rate within two years of
any deviation from it. Yet, it does allow for the possibility that where a
deviation from target is larger, it may make sense to allow a longer period. So
far, this prospect has been only theoretical. The Riksbank makes clear that,
although it has an explicit target for CPI inflation, it recognizes that there are
other relevant definitions of inflation. It therefore monitors a second con-
sumer price index (UND1X) which strips out from the CPI the effects of
indirect taxes, subsidies, and mortgage payments, and states that it pays
attention to asset price inflation. However, the Riksbank also states that it
distinguishes between inflation measures that bear on the inflation forecast
and the targeted variable itself. Thus it may comment on trends in other series,
but does so as part of its decision on how to meet the CPI target.
The empirical evidence is also revealing in other respects. On the surface, the
ECB should not adopt a Taylor rule, since it has hierarchical objectives in which
price stability has pride of place. Yet, among others, Surico (2003) suggests that
it has come very close to following such a rule, erring if anything on being soft
on the inflation component of the rule. Similarly, Hayo and Hofmann (2006)
suggest that the ECB has given much more weight to the output gap than the
Bundesbank ever did. The fact that central banks have only imperfect
knowledge is, however, highlighted by Issing (2005b) who observes that not
being sure about the true output-level gap or the likely impact of major
institutional developments creates uncertainty and calls for the exercise of
judgement. This renders difficult the use of simple rules—such as the Taylor
rule—that assume the output gap can be monitored straightforwardly.
364
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
365
Monetary Policy Strategies
The ECB’s definition of price stability as a reference value of 2 per cent for
HICP inflation for the euro area as a whole is consistent with the practice of the
member central banks in the years leading up to the start of the single cur-
rency, and it has made clear that the target range is above 0 per cent inflation,
then (after an evaluation of its strategy in 2003) further clarified the aim as
being close to 2 per cent. Strictly, though, the ECB does not have an inflation
target and the ECB approach explicitly acknowledges that price stability is a
medium-term goal, thereby allowing for some short-term deviation from the
reference value. Some critics have argued that the ECB reference value is too
restrictive (see, for example, Svensson 2002) and that it would be better if the
ECB adopted a more symmetrical target, as in Sweden or the UK.
The ECB’s two-pillar strategy (Issing et al. 2001) gave considerable notional
weight to the growth of the monetary stock, with a reference value of 4.5 per
cent for annual monetary growth (M3) ostensibly setting a rule for interven-
tion. The ECB’s strategy, described as hybrid by Bordes and Clerc (2006), is
more difficult to explain than pure inflation targeting or monetary growth
targeting. Issing (2006: 6) defends the approach in the following terms: ‘the
two pillars serve the purpose of organising the incoming data in a structured
way basically under the aspect of the relevant time horizon. The cross-
checking is a means of reconciling the shorter-term analysis with the longer-
term perspective leading to a consistent, ‘‘unified’’ overall assessment’.
Even a cursory look at the data suggests that the monetary pillar reference
value is a rule honoured above all in the breach. However, as explained in
Fischer et al. (2006), the Quarterly Monetary Assessment (QMA) undertaken
by the ECB staff, but not made public, is more comprehensive than just looking
at the monetary aggregate, since its purpose is to understand how monetary
conditions bear on price stability. They conclude that the use of the monetary
pillar has allowed more rounded analysis—sometimes referred to as a cross-
check—of inflation dynamics than reliance solely on the economic analysis
pillar and, thus, made for better decisions. Yet, their evidence also suggests that,
although both pillar have tended to point in the same direction most of the
time, the economic pillar has been the more influential overall in interest rate
decisions when, in their words, the monetary pillar gives a blurred signal.
The ECB approach prompts the broader question of whether money matters
in monetary policy-making. In 2003, the ECB appeared to diminish the role of
the monetary pillar, re-branding it as ‘monetary analysis’ and reversing the
order of the two pillars. For the ECB, the monetary pillar provides a cross-
check on price movements in the longer-run, whereas the economic analysis
is considered to be more revealing about the short-run. In fact, most central
banks take some account of monetary growth according to the OECD (2007:
annex to chapter 2, paragraph 2) which comments that ‘only the US Fed does
not put any noticeable weight on money supply’. However, the degree to
which other central banks take account of money is limited (Woodford 2007).
366
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
By contrast, critics of the ECB suggest that it places too much weight on
monetary aggregates, but the issue is not easy to verify because the ECB has
never signalled an explicit weight and, in all probability, would expect to vary
the weight over time in any case.
Thus, one dimension that distinguishes different strategies is the precise
manner in which money is taken into account. The euro area is adjudged to
have a relatively stable demand for money, which means that it is a relatively
more reliable indicator for policy purposes. The euro area (according to the
OECD 2007) has also had less financial innovation than other currency areas
so that there is less distortion of the relationship between money supply and
inflation, although the OECD reports that the stability of the relationship may
be diminishing, as shown by a less stable velocity of circulation. The housing
market is considered to be a particularly important factor and the OECD cites
evidence that most of the overshoot of M1 in the euro area is attributable to
mortgage lending.
Consensus or Debate
One of the more striking inferences to draw from a review of monetary policy
strategies is how little room there appears to be for debate about the social
welfare aims central banks, with all their power, are trying to achieve, and this
lack of debate pervades approaches to monetary policy. It would scarcely be an
exaggeration to say that most of the discourse is around how to conduct
policy, not why or for whom it is being conducted. Buiter (2006) argues that
to target inflation, even in the flexible inflation targeting manner, is a policy
approach bereft of any microeconomic foundations about what improves
welfare and, with customary robustness, he casts doubt on the consensus
that says inflation targeting and independent central banks are optimal. Simi-
larly, Bean (2007) points to the problem within flexible inflation targeting that
the choice of what weight to give to a real economy variable is ultimately
a normative one, and he notes that some micro-foundations of the approach
ignore legitimate distributive issues of an uneven incidence of unemploy-
ment. The fallout from the 2007–8 credit market turmoil is likely to be another
source of disquiet.
A pointed question posed by Buiter (2006: 24) is whether the strength of the
independence granted to some central banks is such that they are devoid of
incentives. As he puts it:
while many central bankers may be motivated in their approach to the job by a sense of
public service, by duty and by unflinching commitment to the central bank’s mandate,
one would like to see these higher motives reinforced by such primitive but frequently
more reliable motives as the desire for power, prestige, wealth, comfort and leisure. This
problem is especially acute when the monetary policy decision is a group decision; it gets
more severe the larger the monetary policy making committee.
367
Monetary Policy Strategies
For Buiter the problem cannot readily be solved because independence and
accountability are, in many ways, incompatible. However, he argues forcefully
for limiting the tasks assigned to the central bank to monetary policy, exclud-
ing tasks such as supervision of financial intermediaries and control of pay-
ments systems, and he also advises central bankers to avoid commenting on
fiscal or structural policies that are not part of their direct remit.
368
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Validation by Performance?
Monetary policy strategies seem to attract only limited debate outside special-
ist circles, and even then the differences of opinion are typically more
about the timing of decisions or the quality of analysis than the underlying
strategies. It may therefore be reasonable for a performance yardstick to be
used to assess them, rather than more politicized judgements. Indeed, it is in
some ways a surprise that inflation targeting has not been more problematic,
given the expectation that while it offered a compelling solution for achieving
price stability, it was likely to be at the expense of greater output volatility. In
fact, most inflation targeters can take comfort from the out-turns. Bean (2007:
15), commenting on the period since the UK adopted inflation targeting
(becoming known as the ‘Great Stability’), observes that ‘the really remarkable
thing is how stable output growth has been’ [emphasis in original]. He accepts
that an absence of shocks and other structural factors that can be characterized
as ‘good luck’ have played a part, but having reviewed a variety of such
other explanations, implicitly favours the view that good policy has played a
considerable part.
This would come as no surprise to Mishkin (2007a) who notes that while
inflation targeting pushes central banks to avoid a focus on short-term real
economy variables, thereby dealing with time inconsistency, it is not incom-
patible with output stabilization over the longer term. He notes, too, that
countries that have adopted full inflation targeting monetary policy strategies
have fared well economically, with no apparent cost in terms of output vola-
tility. However, Mishkin qualifies his praise by noting that prominent coun-
tries that have not adopted inflation targeting have also performed well,
notably the United States,6 and he offers the explanation that these countries
have been able to find alternative strong nominal anchors. Nevertheless, the
369
Monetary Policy Strategies
emerging evidence that Mishkin reviews suggests that inflation targeting may
be better at curbing expectations of inflation and at diminishing inflation
persistence.
In a careful analysis, Rose (2007) finds that despite a floating exchange rate
being a feature of inflation targeting regimes, exchange rate volatility is mar-
ginally lower, on average, than for other monetary regimes. This is not as
paradoxical as it seems in that the inflation targets are typically very similar
(2% CPI, for example, is typical). Rose (2007) also finds that inflation targeting
countries do not seem to be at risk from capital ‘stops’ which arise when short-
term capital flows suddenly desert a country, even though inflation targeting
implies no controls on capital. The obvious explanation is that capital is
attracted to the stability that the monetary regime provides.
There has been some criticism, especially since the launch of the euro, that
price increases have been higher (or perceived to be so) than revealed by the
core inflation index used by the ECB (and the Bank of England). Yet in this
regard, it is important to recognize that highly visible price increases (the
baguette or the café au lait) are offset by falls in the prices of less frequently
purchased items; in other words, the move to the euro has resulted in some
relative price adjustments. While it is probably true that some sellers exploited
the opportunity of the conversion to the euro, it is important to recognize that
the transition is a one-off change.
Concluding Remarks
370
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
inflation targeters. Dissent from this consensus is rare. Willem Buiter (2006:
39) is a prominent exception, arguing that
flexible inflation targeting . . . is incompatible with the mandate of every central bank
that has price stability as its primary objective. It risks imparting an upward bias to
inflation. It sets monetary policy design and implementation back to before 1989—the
year New Zealand first adopted inflation targeting. The solution is to drop flexible
inflation targeting and replace is with lexicographic or hierarchical inflation targeting.
By this, Buiter means giving price stability pride of place and, by implication,
playing down the weights given to stabilization of the real economy so long as
price stability has not been assured.
However, it deserves to be stressed that central banking is about more than
price stability and, as regards financial stability, recent events have exposed
greater divergences (and, arguably, failures) in approach. It may be, therefore,
that the pursuit of price stability has over-shadowed other dimensions of
stability, notably financial stability, though as Pisani-Ferry et al. (2008) point
out the resilience to shocks of the macroeconomic system as a whole is another
vital facet of stability. Here, European countries may have more in common
with each other than with other parts of the world, especially in the relation-
ship between fiscal policy and monetary policy, though with continuing
ambivalence about how structural policies enter the equation.
It can be argued, further, that today’s consensus on monetary policy strategy
reflects the rather benign conditions that have prevailed in recent years. In-
creased global competition has held down consumer prices and although there
have been periodic swings in oil prices, they have, on the whole, not led to
attempts by wage negotiators to push up nominal wage rates in a compensating
manner, as occurred in the 1970s and 1980s. Immigration to OECD countries
with relatively tight labour markets has probably also played a part, while persist-
ent unemployment in others has meant that labour markets have had some slack.
Nevertheless, there are several areas where reform or refinement of monetary
policy strategies can be contemplated. Some are largely technocratic issues,
such as the degree to which the central bank should seek to present an interest
rate path in both its forecasts and its pronouncements. In 2005, for example,
the Riksbank shifted its forecasting strategy to factor-in changes in interest
rates anticipated by the markets, rather than forecasting on the assumption
of an unchanged repo rate and has since (2007) further refined its approach,
whereas the Bank of England appears to be more hesitant. Other disputed areas
are more political, for example Mishkin (2007a) argues that there four aspects
of monetary policy strategy on which there is debate about the way forward:
. What definition of an inflation target to favour given the distinction
between the price level and the current inflation rate.
. The optimal degree of transparency. At issue here is whether more is
always better, or whether there should be limits to transparency, either
371
Monetary Policy Strategies
to avoid confusing the public or because central bank mystique can still
be a valuable attribute (Geraats 2007).
. How to deal with asset price movement and whether asset prices should
be explicitly targeted, irrespective of any pass through into inflation, or
simply monitored as a potential influence on prices.
. Whether the exchange rate should be treated as a separate aim of policy,
an issue that manifestly came to the fore in the 2007 French election.
Notes
1. The research on which this chapter draws is part of the Integrated Project ‘New Modes
of Governance’ (www.eu-newgov.org), financially supported by the European Union
under the 6th Framework programme (Contract No. CIT1-CT-2004-506392). I am
grateful to Charles Goodhart and the editors of this volume for helpful comments on
a previous draft.
2. The notion that the monetary authority may be tempted to court popularity by
opting for looser monetary policy in the short-term, despite being aware of the
adverse longer-term consequences of igniting inflation.
3. Nevertheless, Pisani-Ferry et al. (2008) argue that it would benefit from fully adopting
an inflation targeting approach.
4. Who, it should be noted, has advised the Reserve Bank that it should have a broader
decision-making committee.
5. In fact the statutory instruction to the Fed identifies moderate long-term interest
rates as a further objective, along with a general duty to promote financial stability
and a sound banking system.
6. More controversially, he also cites Germany, a country which has undoubtedly
achieved enduring price stability, but given the record of that country’s real economy
since the early 1990s, the verdict on other aspects of economic performance may be
less flattering.
372
17
Scientization of Central Banking:
The Politics of A-Politicization
Martin Marcussen
Central banks across the world are embedded in a variety of national contexts
and histories. They are exposed to a multitude of challenges that require
learning and adaptation in very specific situations. Globalization, regional
integration processes, financial crises, wars, and terrorist attacks impact differ-
ently on central banks. In most cases, the central banks feel that flexibility and
change are imperative because of these challenges. Seen in that light, we
would not expect central banks across the globe to display isomorphic char-
acteristics. Although central bankers model each other’s practices, structures,
and ideologies, they do not copy these features one-to-one. Instead, they
translate and convert institutional fashions from other contexts into a format
that resonates with the existing domestic structures, relations, and ideas.
Emulation does not necessarily imply institutional convergence. Indeed, in
preparation for major institutional reform, a comparative study commissioned
by the Reserve Bank of New Zealand concluded that in the 1980s ‘there was
little commonality among central banks in their precise functions, objectives,
or even the question of who should set the objectives. The evidence was that
few central banks at the time had well-defined, stable, objective functions’
(Singleton et al. 2006: 140). Central bankers are therefore commonly regarded
as an ‘oddly assorted bunch’. Many national idiosyncrasies persist that may no
longer have a place, though ‘ . . . these may have deeper roots than many
people assume’ (Deane and Pringle 1994: 338).
Despite the danger of oversimplification, the chapter neglects many of
the differences that exist between central banks. It adopts a meso-historical
perspective on central banks and central banking in order to identify the
conjunctures through which central banking has developed over the last
couple of centuries. In short, at this level of abstraction, the chapter considers
central banking and central banks to be distinct analytical categories, thereby
373
Scientization of Central Banking: The Politics of A-Politicization
374
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
and a stable exchange rate. Finally, in the fourth stage, central banks were
granted formal autonomy to pursue a single objective, most typically price
stability (see Begg in this volume). They maintained their currency function
and responsibility for the overall stability of the financial system (although
their supervisory functions vary from country to country).
The shift from the first to the second stage can be explained by the gradual
development of private banking and the consequent risk of bank failure. The
government’s bank simply had to take on additional functions to assist
in situations of financial default, sometimes as lender of last resort (see
Moran and Macartney in this volume). The shifts from the second to the
third stage and from the third to the fourth stage can be accounted for by
successive crises in the form of the inter-war economic depression, the two
world wars, and the great inflation of the 1970s. With that background in
mind, this chapter asks the question whether globalization implies that yet
another stage in the development of worldwide central banking is taking
shape. In other words, is there indicative evidence to support a plausible
claim that central banking is moving into a fifth age (Table 17.1)?
The question is whether key trends are so significant and general in scope
that they contribute to laying the foundations for a new stage in the develop-
ment of central banking. Attention will be directed towards a major trend,
scientization, and the way in which scientization is being bolstered by hori-
zontal bureaucratic extension, collective decision making, external commu-
nication, and outcome management.
Scientization
While the 1990s were characterized by a worldwide surge in organizational
reform enhancing the instrument autonomy of central banks, that is, freedom
from being supervised by political authorities in the process of implementing
monetary and financial policies, the 2000s appear to be characterized by
scientization. In the previous decade, monetary and, to the extent that bank-
ing supervision was in the hands of central bankers, financial policy making
were depoliticized. These two policy areas were shielded from what were seen
to be short-term political considerations. The arena for ideological debate and
political deliberation shifted away from the world of central banking towards
other areas of political life. Central banking was institutionally and legally
exempted from ordinary democratic decision making.
In the 2000s, however, central banking is becoming increasingly apoliti-
cized. Max Weber referred to this process as ‘rationalization’: ‘the process by
which explicit, abstract, intellectually, calculable rules and procedures are
increasingly substituted for sentiments, tradition, and rules of thumb’
(Wrong 1970: 26). When ideology is being displaced by science, central
bankers gain legitimacy and authority by basing their views on, and applying,
375
376
First age 1600s–1800s Second age 1873–1914 Third age 1930s–1970s Fourth age 1980s–1990s Fifth age? 2000s
Regime Mercantilism/colbertist Gold standard/Laissez faire Bretton Woods/Keynesian Washington consensus/ Post-Washington
Nationalism internationalism nationalism Monetarist consensus/
internationalism transnationalism
Arena shifting Few state-owned central De facto autonomous Integrated central banking Formally autonomous Scientization
banks central banking central banking
Bureaucratic scope Small—disparate Establishment of basic Building up Building down Building out (alliances)
structures
Decision making Subdued the will of the Discretionary Public service machine Let managers manage. Committees and outcome
principal bureaucracy. Process Business and output management
administration management
Communication Non-existent Non-existent Legalistic—formalistic Techno-speak Transparency
Targets Servicing the state and its Currency stability Multiple goals—internal Monetary targeting Inflation targeting
war-economy and external
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
the language of science. Human affairs are being reduced to ‘calculable, cold,
hard, ‘‘matter-of-factness’’ ’ lying outside—indeed transcending—the sphere
of political action (Gregory 2007). Scientization implies that power is being
concentrated in the hands of those who master the discourse of science,
scientific ‘techno-speak’. Central banking is becoming a matter for intellec-
tuals, thus implying that it is an elite phenomenon with which elected poli-
ticians would not even consider dealing (Woods 2002: 25–45, 34–7). It is being
dehumanized, eliminating personal ideological and emotional features that
escape calculation. In line with Weber’s portrayal of the ideal typical civil
servant, central bankers are being presented, and sometimes present them-
selves, as passionless machines and specialists without spirit (Marcussen
2006a).
Scientization, which apoliticizes the art of central banking, is fundamentally
different from autonomization, which depoliticizes central banking. Autono-
mous central banking does not imply that media and politicians and other
opinion makers do not care about or pay attention to the métier of central
bankers; scientization does. Autonomous central banking does not imply that
central bankers are automatically considered to be right when they make
decisions; scientization does. And autonomization does not imply that central
bankers are being uncritically listened to as the Delphi oracle, even when
speaking out on matters that lie far beyond the narrow field of monetary and
financial policy; scientization does. For instance, Alan Greenspan’s inclination
to speak out on issues that are formally beyond the authority of the Federal
Reserve was legendary, and he possibly inspired central bankers elsewhere to
do the same (Meyer 2004: 215).
The claim is not that central banking is ‘scientistic’. Genuine science is
open-ended, keeping alive a continuing conversation between theory and
practice, not attempting to close debates and not presenting general, everlast-
ing truths about human affairs. Central banking, on the other hand, appears to
be ‘scientific’, representing a closed scientism which is ‘self-confirming, essen-
tially an ideology or dogma presented in the guise of science’ (Gregory 2007).
Importantly, the argument here is not that scientization and the ways in which
it unfolds are universal phenomena. The meso-perspective adopted in this
chapter is more interested in attempting to identify trends that, at some
point in the future, may end up being more general phenomena in the
world of central banking.
The American Federal Reserve Banks account for more than half of all
published central bank research output (St-Amant et al. 2005: v), but the
European Central Bank (ECB) also qualifies as a research powerhouse. In
terms of full-time researchers, for instance, the ECB has a larger research
directorate than the Department of Economics at the London School of Eco-
nomics and Political Science (Marcussen 2006a: 93). Over its 10 years of
existence, however, it has yet to achieve the level of authority enjoyed by
377
Scientization of Central Banking: The Politics of A-Politicization
the Bundesbank, the bank on which it was modelled (Jabko 2003). Since the
ECB can still not speak without any visible opposition, the rationalization of
the bank remains incomplete.
Scientization expresses itself in relation to many dimensions of central
banking. Central bankers start to make epistemic alliances with other mem-
bers of the scientific community (‘building out’); coincidence, prejudices, and
discretion are being filtered out of decision making in an ‘instrument rational’
manner (collective decision making); procedures are being instituted to min-
imize haphazard and random reactions to central bank decision making,
so-called ‘irrational exuberance’ (transparency and communication); and
measurable performance is based on few and exact standards (inflation target-
ing). In the following, these components of scientization will be discussed
individually.
Building Out
The first central banks were established more than three hundred years ago,
but the real upsurge in central bank institutions proper took place in the inter-
war years. Since then, the world has witnessed a steady increase in the number
of central bank institutions. Indeed, ‘[if] the fundamental, evolutionary criter-
ion of success is that an organization should reproduce and multiply over the
world, and successfully mutate to meet the emerging challenges of time, then
central banks have been conspicuously successful’ (Goodhart, Capie, and
Schnadt 1994: 91). Today, almost all sovereign states have established a central
bank. It has become a sign of statehood on the same level as a national
anthem, flag, and army (ibid. 26).
With the politicization of central banking in the immediate post–Second
World War period, most central banks were charged with additional functions
and grew considerably in size. Together with the rest of the national public
administration, the number of personnel, departments, sections, and admin-
istrative levels continued to grow. Central banks developed their administra-
tive structure. Integrated central banking could be characterized as a
paternalistic, formalistic, and hierarchical machine bureaucracy in which
employees held steady career prospects and where form and process mattered
more than substance.
The global wave of New Public Management changed all that. Central
bank organizations everywhere underwent considerable trimming—‘building
down’ (Morgan Stanley 2004: xi). To reduce the number of employees became
an objective in itself and a single measure of success of central bank reform.
Modernization became synonymous with downsizing. The administrative and
management culture also shifted. Whereas central banks were regarded as
distinct bodies of public administration in the immediate post–Second
World War period, during the 1980s and 1990s they came to be considered
378
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
379
Scientization of Central Banking: The Politics of A-Politicization
380
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
381
Scientization of Central Banking: The Politics of A-Politicization
decisions. The clearer the central bank is about what it is doing and why, the
easier it becomes for the financial markets to form an opinion of how the
short term develops. If the financial markets are clear about the short term,
then, it is argued, the central bank can more easily achieve its objective in the
medium to long term.
Central banks with a long history of policy effectiveness and credibility do
not necessarily need to talk as much as central banks with a low level of
perceived credibility. That is ‘why ‘‘nouveau riche’’ institutions with poor
credibility ‘‘talk,’’ and why institutions that have a great ‘‘wealth’’ of credibil-
ity can afford to whisper’ (Eijffinger et al. 2000: 119). This may explain why a
hitherto unheard of degree of transparency has been adopted in Norway. The
Norwegian Governor, Svein Gjedrem, decided that his quarterly inflation
reports ought to contain projections of interest-rate levels three years into
the future (Financial Times, 26 May 2006). Other central banks plan to follow
the trend in the name of transparency, but critics argue ‘that there is no point
in announcing intentions for the future if that future is clouded in mystery’
(Grauwe 2006).
Increased and improved communication with the external world is closely
connected to the habit of making decisions collectively rather than on an
individual basis. Committee decision making simply helps open the doors to
the inner circles for professional central bank watchers in the financial media,
stock exchanges, and private banks. Transparency is also closely connected to
the next global trend in central banking: inflation targeting. Former Swedish
central bank governor Lars Heikensten (2005: 6) argued that inflation target-
ing is now being conducted ‘almost by necessity with a high degree of open-
ness and clarity’.
Inflation Targeting
Inflation targeting—the notion that the bank, typically together with the
national treasury, determines an acceptable range within which price inflation
is allowed to settle—is now recognized as a worldwide central banking trend
(Mahadeva and Sterne 2000). During the Classical Gold Standard, central
bankers were most interested in external stability in the value of the currency.
By contrast, central bankers in the post–Second World War period were asked
to pursue several objectives simultaneously, such as growth, employment, and
financial as well as price stability. During the late 1970s and the 1980s, many
central banks started establishing monetary targets, which is an arrangement
under which the central bank aims for a certain money supply growth rate (see
Begg in this volume). In the United States, the idea of monetary targets entered
political discourse in 1974, but it took until 1979 before Fed Chairman Paul
Volcker implemented it. It lasted only a couple of years as a watered-down kind
of ‘pragmatic monetarism’ (Kettl 1986: 144, 173). In practice, monetary policy
382
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
383
Scientization of Central Banking: The Politics of A-Politicization
Governance Transnationalization
Governance Communities ! Knowledge Communities
Political Governance ! Knowledge Governance
Knowledge Production
Scientific Pluralism ! Scientific Overlay
Civil Servant—Politician Relationship
Depoliticization ! Apoliticization
External Accountability ! Internal Accountability
384
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
385
Scientization of Central Banking: The Politics of A-Politicization
normative governance; knowledge and data, that is, cognitive governance; as well
as meaning, common histories, myths about the past, and visions about the
future, that is, imaginary governance (Marcussen 2006b). It is therefore possible
that a movement from political governance to knowledge governance is taking place
as a result of scientization. Political governance can, for the sake of argument,
be simplistically defined as using regulation to solve a concrete societal prob-
lem (Chandler 1958: 260). The practical aspects of problem solving—‘the art of
central banking’—rather than theorizing for the sake of theory—‘the science
of central banking’—have traditionally been central to the business of central
banking. Theoreticians have not been held in high esteem in central bank
circles, and it has been argued that the art of central banking is driven by
intuition and life experience. John Maynard Keynes, for instance, was viewed
among central bankers as a distant theoretician, and Strong and Montagu
Norman feared that people like him would overshadow the ‘practical bankers’
(Jacobsson 1979: 45). However, this may cease to be the case. In contrast to
political governance, knowledge governance can be defined as the production
and dissemination of norms, knowledge, and identity. Central to knowledge
governance is the idea that knowledge production is an objective in itself, that
is, more knowledge is better than less knowledge.
Related to the development of knowledge governance is the question of what
knowledge is and which aspects of knowledge ought to be expanded through
intensified and systematic research. It is possible that scientization within
central banking implies a movement from scientific pluralism to a strategic overlay
of particular research disciplines and approaches. Since many central banks provide
for their own income and to a large degree have a free hand when spending that
money, and as central bankers tend to spend considerable amounts of money
on a few areas of research activity, one would expect to see a more noticeable
expansion of research activity in some areas of research than others. Through
the massive injection of central bank money into research activities in delim-
ited fields of research, many more actors will suddenly become players in the
field of generating knowledge within a particular subset of macro-economic
research. This is already a noticeable phenomenon in the North American
scientific community. Here, central bank research appears to ‘crowd-out’
research on alternative monetary regimes (White 2005: 326). In other words,
the scientization of central banking may cause a bias in research focus, since
very few other sources of research funding, private or public, will be able to
match the cash flow emanating from central bank circles. It is difficult to
predict whether this potential research bias will have enduring consequences
for the development of the economic sciences in particular and the social
sciences in general. However, it is to be expected that the scientific disciplines
of most relevance to central bankers will tend to play a dominant role in the
overall field of macro-economic research (Apel et al. 2008). In consequence, the
central banks have a sort of oligopoly on monetary opinion (White 2005: 327).
386
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
By the same token, just as specific scientific disciplines can become over-
emphasized by an extraordinary injection of funding, so also can specific
scientific approaches. The new impetus to macro-economic research may
have an impact on the scientific discourse in general and, consequently, also
on which approaches are considered to be marginal or peripheral and which
are considered to be central or important. Indeed, it has been documented that
central banks tend to subsidize research that takes the institutional status quo
for granted (White 2005: 344). Since the new actors in the knowledge game are
relatively well financed, and since it may reasonably be expected that they will
have quite a narrow agenda, central bankers may be able to discipline the kind
of discussions held in certain domains of economic research. Within the field
of research on monetary policy, some voices in the ongoing academic debate
may be strengthened, while others become weaker. If central banking ideas
about obtaining stability via sound money, finances, and institutions have
achieved the status of hegemony, this status can be expected to be further
consolidated by additional funding in its favour.
Within central bank circles, this power to actually influence the entire
research climate and the conditions of research is fully recognized and even
valued. A Swedish central bank governor held that ‘[s]everal of my academic
contacts have stressed how valuable the contact with the central bank world is
for their research’ (Heikensten 2005). For instance, the most recent evaluation
report written by ECB researchers argued that the benefits to be attained by a
central bank from engaging actively in academic research include the fact that
the central bank ‘can stimulate and encourage external research on issues of
interest to the central bank through publications, conferences, and consulting
relationships’ (Goodfriend, König, and Repullo 2004: 5). The ‘research power-
house’, the ECB itself, has ostensibly grasped the overall idea behind the
concept of research management, since it ‘uses its research capacity to encour-
age, coordinate, and lead research efforts of the national central banks of the
Eurosystem’ (ibid. 22). And this is apparently not in vain. The evaluation
concludes that ‘[g]iven its place at the centre of a continental system of central
banks, it is not surprising that the ECB has already had a major effect on
academic discourse throughout Europe’ (ibid. 24).
The scientization of central banking may also have an impact on the power
relationship between civil servants and politicians, typically in favour of the
unelected civil servant, that is, the central banker. As mentioned, one result of
scientization may be a movement from depolitization to apolitization of the civil
servant–politician relationship. First, scientization consolidates the autonomous
status of civil servants by objectifying monetary policy making. It becomes
‘unthinkable’ to start a political argument with a civil servant who possesses
recognized scientific authority. Rather, to boost their own credibility, politi-
cians might instead tend to socialize with and even publicly flatter the civil
servant in question (Marcussen 2006a). The subtle longstanding relationship
387
Scientization of Central Banking: The Politics of A-Politicization
between the Governor of the US Federal Reserve and the American Congress
can serve as an illustrative, albeit not necessarily entirely representative,
example. Twice a year, in February and July, the Fed’s Federal Open Market
Committee reports to Congress on the conduct of economic and monetary
policies—the so-called Monetary Policy Reports (see Woolley in this volume).
The release of the report is followed up by the Fed Chairman testifying in
Congress before the Banking Committees of both the Senate and the House. As
an example, a transcript of the so-called Humphrey-Hawkins hearings in the
Senate’s Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs Committee reads as follows:
I have had the privilege over an extended period of time as a Member, as Chairman, as
Ranking Member, to work with Alan Greenspan in his capacity as Chairman of the Board
of Governors, and it is something that I will always be proud of. I will always be proud to
be able to say that I worked with the greatest central banker of the era. . . . I think one of
the great services you provided to this country has been the wisdom of your views and
the credibility that they contain when you have been willing to speak out. . . . In
reviewing the great bankers in world history, I think Alan Greenspan qualifies as the
greatest central banker in the history of the world. (Senator Phil GRAMM, Republican
from Texas, banking.senate.gov/_files/107835.pdf, pp. 1–2)
As always, I welcome [Alan Greenspan] and thank him for the service he gives our
Nation. (Senator Jon S. CORZINE, Democrat from New Jersey, banking.senate.gov/_files/
107835.pdf, p. 5)
Second, scientization may imply that civil servants with recognized scientific
authority are encouraged to engage in policy issues and domains that are not
part of their primary area of responsibility. The functions and responsibilities of
the civil servant grow exponentially with the degree of scientization. This may
take two forms. One is the case where the central banker takes the initiative to
engage in questions related to education policy, public administrative reform,
and even cultural matters. Thus, researchers employed in the ECB do not hesi-
tate to express criticism of the efficiency of the public sector in various European
countries (e.g. Afonso et al. 2003). In an American context, Chairman Green-
span earned a notorious reputation for speaking out on issues lying far beyond
the authority of the Federal Reserve, including politically contentious issues.
Another form is the case where politicians and media alike consult central
bankers on their own about questions that are only marginally related to central
banking. This may take place in various hearings or in other public spheres.
Third, scientization has an impact on the mode and type of communication
taking place in the political sphere. Apolitization through scientization means
that the entire language of the field is changing. In contrast to political and
administrative statements, a major characteristic of scientific statements ‘is
that they are privileged in the sense that, if derived in accordance with scien-
tific procedures, they are considered to give greater assurance of truth. It is
more useful if conclusions on, say, what works and what does not work in
388
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
389
Scientization of Central Banking: The Politics of A-Politicization
390
18
Transparency and Accountability
Nicolas Jabko
391
Transparency and Accountability
At the most commonsense level, a central bank that lives up to the norm of
transparency is one that makes its decisions in the public eye and renounces
the ‘mystique’ of secrecy. This is the case if central bankers communicate
abundant and timely information about their decisions and about the process
that leads them to make these decisions. A commonsense definition of
accountability is arguably somewhat more demanding. A central bank can
be called accountable if it can be held to account for its decisions—both in
the sense of explaining its decisions and in the sense of taking responsibility
for its decisions. This, in turn, requires a constituency or even perhaps a
political body to which the central bank must be brought to account.
Although these two basic definitions are widely open to discussion, a variety
of techniques that purport to enhance central bank transparency and account-
ability have spread across the world since the 1980s. The most commonly cited
transparency enhancements are the dissemination of inputs to the monetary
policy process (including inflation and other economic forecasts and models
that central bankers use as information for making policy); the publication of
data about the process and output of monetary policy (minutes of monetary
policy meetings, voting records, press conferences, and other central bank
statements about policy trends). The most commonly cited accountability
enhancements—in addition to the above—are the holding of regular parlia-
mentary hearings of central bankers, the holding of increasingly open
appointment (or re-appointment) procedures for central bankers, and more
generally the existence of a regular debate and interaction between central
bankers and various outside constituencies.
The value that is generally ascribed to transparency and accountability in
central banking rests on two conventional rationales—one economic and one
political. The economic rationale puts great emphasis on the need for trans-
parency in order to achieve economic policy goals. According to this reason-
ing, both real changes in the economy and the evolution of economists’
thinking call for enhanced central bank transparency.1 As financial markets
became more global and instantaneously responsive, monetary policy has
become the central avenue not only for ensuring price stability, but also for
macroeconomic demand management. Interest rates are now the main instru-
ment for economic stabilization. In this new context, the expectations of
market actors and the credibility of monetary policy become increasingly
important. Central bankers need the cooperation of market actors in order to
set medium- and long-term interest rates. This in turn would explain the new
emphasis on transparency and the increasing importance of ‘how central
bankers talk’ (Blinder et al. 2002). Transparency is part and parcel of the public
relations strategies that central bankers develop in order to communicate their
intentions to market actors.
392
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
The political rationale for the new consensus seems to stem from the global
trend of increasingly independent central banks.2 Accountability, in particu-
lar, is a normative requirement in a democratic context. As one central banker
put it, ‘independence and accountability are two sides of the same coin’ (Issing
1999: 505)—or, this is the way things should be from a normative democratic
perspective. The delegation of important policymaking powers to unelected
central bankers raises serious concerns about the compatibility between cen-
tral bank independence and democratic ideals. Some scholars have echoed
these concerns and have questioned whether independent central bankers can
truly be held accountable for their decisions [Berman and McNamara 1999;
Cerny 1999; Pauly 1997; for a rather harsh view from a (British) central bank
insider, see Buiter 1999]. The resonance of such arguments in a democratic
context helps explain, in turn, the insistence of politicians on the norm of
accountability and the willingness of central bankers and financial officials to
adopt it—at least in rhetoric.
Does this conjunction of powerful economic and political rationales mean
that there is now a strong consensus on the need for transparency and
accountability in modern central banking? The problem with this view is
that there are good political reasons to question the strength of the consensus.
393
Transparency and Accountability
394
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
entrenched, the better central bankers will be able to resist forms of transpar-
ency and accountability that might encroach on their independence.
A second factor in explaining variation in transparency and accountability
practices is the power of the legislature to oversee the central bank. Interest-
ingly, the principle of legislative oversight is no longer really contested any-
where. Even when central bankers are independent from the executive branch
of government, it is now generally accepted practice that they must publicly
report on what they do to the legislative branch. But there remains consider-
able variation in oversight power. The US Congress’s claim to oversee the Fed is
virtually uncontested due to its power and prestige within the American
system of government. As for the European Parliament, it started from a
particularly weak position within the EU and had to work hard to assert a
relatively modest claim to oversee the ECB.
The third factor that fosters variation is the capacity of the executive branch
to assert policy leadership in relation to the central bank. Monetary policy
operates in a broader context of economic policies that remain, for the most
part, executive prerogatives. In the United States, the executive claim to eco-
nomic policy leadership stems from the President’s democratic mandate to
implement the policies for which he has been elected, notwithstanding the
important powers of the US Congress in fiscal matters. Executive power at the
EU level is neither unified, nor a straightforward expression of democratic will.
The Euro Group—which brings together the finance ministers of the countries
that have adopted the euro—would be the most likely candidate for policy
leadership on fiscal matters. Yet, it is far from a cohesive body of government
and is therefore largely unable, at this point, to exert genuine policy leadership.
Although each of the above three factors provides only a partial picture of
the institutional context within which the central bank operates, they interact
to produce rather different equilibrium points for transparency and account-
ability practices in the United States and in the EU. The nature of central bank
transparency and accountability practices ultimately depends less on the pres-
ence or absence of specific transparency and accountability provisions than on
local institutional dynamics.
395
Transparency and Accountability
in Congress. But there were many other changes as well: the publication of
forecasts starting in 1979; the introduction of the Beige Book about regional
economic conditions in 1983; the publication of minutes of Federal Open
Market Committee (FOMC) meetings after 1994; and, most recently, Ben
Bernanke’s pledge to publish ‘enhanced projections’ by FOMC members
about key economic aggregates (Bernanke 2007d). At the same time, the
United States is relatively late in adopting certain measures that have become
accepted practice in many other states and that can be described as transpar-
ency-enhancing, like inflation targeting. The question is what factors pro-
voked these various moves and what is pushing the United States to adopt
its own, relatively singular version of transparency and accountability. When
we examine this question, the evolving political environment of the Fed
looms large in comparison to strictly economic or democratic concerns.
The Fed’s Rise to Prominence and the Mounting Pressures for Transparency
and Accountability
The 1970s were years of turmoil for the Federal Reserve as well as for successive
administrations. As the US economy ran into double-digit inflation figures,
politicians in Congress increasingly questioned the executive branch’s eco-
nomic policies, including the Fed’s. Of course, the Federal Reserve exists by
virtue of an act of Congress, the Federal Reserve Act of 1913. As former Fed
chairman Paul Volcker famously put it, ‘Congress has made us, Congress can
unmake us.’ The Senate also has the power to confirm or invalidate the
president’s appointments of the Fed’s governors and chair. Yet, during the
first few decades of the Fed’s history, Congress deferred to the administration
in matters of economic policies and the Fed had trouble asserting its inde-
pendence.7 Until the 1970s the Fed’s accountability was mostly vis-à-vis the
administration and the Department of Treasury—and thus outside the reach of
Congress.
In fact, the first steps toward the present framework of Fed’s transparency
and accountability stemmed from Congressional efforts to clip the wings of
the executive in matters of monetary policy. After a long period of ‘imperial’
presidency, the 1970s saw a reassertion of Congressional oversight over the
Federal Reserve as well as other executive agencies. Only in the mid-1970s did
Congress start a practice of regular hearings of Federal Reserve Board officials,
in addition to the normal appointment hearings at the Senate. The Federal
Reserve Reform Act (1977) and the Full Employment and Balanced Growth
(Humphrey-Hawkins) Act (1978) reasserted Congress’s oversight role and
redefined the Fed’s mandate. Inflation projections, for example, stemmed
from the Fed’s obligation to publish its ‘prospects for the future’. Court cases
also played a role in prompting the Fed to become more open, especially the
Merrill versus Federal Open Market Committee ruling by the US Supreme Court
396
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
397
Transparency and Accountability
Greenspan was able to develop a good working relationship with Clinton and
his long-time Treasury Secretary Robert Rubin. Clinton chose to reappoint
Greenspan—and he would presumably have acted differently if Greenspan
had not been a good ‘team player’ (Woodward 1997: 159–60). The adminis-
tration’s claim to policy leadership was reasserted with a vengeance by the
post–2000 Bush administration, when Greenspan endorsed the president’s tax
cuts despite mounting fiscal deficits.
Once again, therefore, the key factor that pushed the Fed to change its
approach to transparency and accountability was really the renewed pressure
coming from a powerful Congress—a structural characteristic of the US polit-
ical system. In the early 1990s, Congress was demanding more transparency
and accountability as a prerequisite to approval of the administration’s fund-
ing of international organizations. In that context, the Fed and some other
federal agencies fell under the same Congressional axe. The single most
important consequence was the 1994 decision to publish minutes of the
FOMC meetings. The consequences of this decision are actually ambiguous.
According to Meade and Stasavage (2008), it may have rigidified the style of
FOMC debates, as participants apparently began to voice their opinions less
freely. Critics would add that the publication of minutes is a rather limited form
of accountability, especially since the minutes are edited and were revealed
only many weeks after the decision. (The delay was shortened to three weeks in
2005.) All this may be true, but it was nonetheless a departure from existing
practice.
Increasingly, and perhaps surprisingly, voices from within the Federal Reserve
System were heard supporting the push for greater transparency and account-
ability. The central bankers were above all concerned not so much about their
own accountability, but about the benefits of explaining monetary policy
decisions to the markets.9 But they also knew there was an outside demand for
more transparency and accountability. Most vocal among them in the 1990s
was vice-chair Alan Blinder, a Clinton appointee to the Federal Reserve Board.10
Blinder’s reasoning was political as well as economic, since he believed that both
the Fed’s democratic credentials and its credibility would be best served by
enhanced transparency and accountability. Originally a product of distinctively
American political pressure coming from the US Congress, the Fed’s conversion
to transparency and accountability was now complete—or was it?
The Debate Over Inflation Targeting and the Problem of the Dual Mandate
Let us examine the substance of the Fed’s transparency and accountability.
One glaring aspect that seems to be missing in the case of the US Federal
Reserve is a clear policy target. There is an interesting political story behind
this absence—one that highlights potential contradictions in the new ethos of
transparency and accountability. And the resistance to this particular step
398
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
once again comes from the particular political environment in which the Fed
finds itself, namely, as an independent central bank subject to strict legislative
oversight from the US Congress.
The first episode of this story about inflation targeting started as a technical
debate in central banking and economist circles. After the heyday of monet-
arism in the early 1980s, central bankers were looking for a policy target that
would be both an appropriate intermediate goal for monetary policy and a way
to anchor market expectations. Inflation targeting emerged as a potential
solution to this problem in New Zealand and Europe. The Bank of New Zealand
pioneered the use of numerical inflation targets for monetary policy in the late
1980s. The Maastricht Treaty’s definition of price stability as the ‘primary’ goal
of monetary policy in 1992 was a step in the same direction. One of the
benefits of this approach was to enhance the transparency of the decision-
making process. If there were a clear target that everybody could see, central
bank transparency and accountability would be presumably enhanced.
Yet in the United States these international developments toward greater
transparency were controversial because of the so-called ‘dual mandate’ of the
Fed since the 1978 Humphrey-Hawkins Act. The Fed’s task is not only to fight
inflation but also to pursue ‘full employment and balanced growth’ at the same
time. On the one hand, the Fed’s defence of its growth-enhancement mandate
is often largely a matter of rhetoric. There were times when the Fed acted as a
very hawkish inflation fighter—especially under Paul Volcker in the 1980s. The
Fed could argue that it was impossible to make progress on all fronts at the same
time, and thus arguably obfuscate its mandate (e.g. Wyplosz 2001: 5). On
the other hand, the dual mandate also means that the governors are legally
bound to worry about growth as much as about inflation. In the Fed’s recent
history, ‘doves’ who argued that growth should not be sacrificed to the fight
against inflation have been able to invoke the dual mandate in support of the
argument.11 From this perspective, the dual mandate may be argued to ensure
that central bankers are held accountable for the goals set for them by Congress.
The US debate on inflation targeting quickly became partisan. On the
Republican side of the aisle, Congressmen Coney Mack and Jim Saxton argued
that the Fed should have a single hierarchical mandate of price stability,
meaning zero inflation. They favoured not only inflation targeting but a
change in the mandate of the Fed. Others, especially among Democrats,
argued that the mandate should not be changed and the Fed should stay
away from inflation targeting. They feared that an inflation target would assign
more weight to the price stability mandate of the Fed and would authorize the
Fed to disregard its employment mandate. After some hesitations, Greenspan
sided with the second camp in the name of flexibility, and the Mack-Saxton
proposal went nowhere in the 1990s.
The next episode of this inflation-targeting saga started when Ben Bernanke
was appointed chair of the Fed in 2006 and is still being played out. Bernanke
399
Transparency and Accountability
400
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
401
Transparency and Accountability
2000, the ECB acknowledged that the European Parliament is the only body
‘directly elected by the European citizens and, consequently, plays a crucial
role—the ECB must be accountable to the Parliament for the conduct of
monetary policy. ( . . . .) In this sense, the relations between the ECB and the
European Parliament must be considered as more than a simple statutory
requirement’ (European Central Bank 2000: 54). Early on, therefore, the ECB
started a practice of sending Executive Board members to explain monetary
policy before the European Parliament (see Jabko 2003).
The sheer force of democratic ideals is insufficient, however, to explain the
growing importance of transparency and accountability in the official rhetoric
of both the Parliament and the ECB. Since the Maastricht Treaty did not
explicitly provide for it, an accountability relationship developed progres-
sively as a practical result of interactions between key actors. By the ECB’s
own admission, the hearings ‘contribute to safeguard the independent status
of the ECB. Consequently, it is certainly in the ECB’s enlightened interest to
carry on with such relations’ (European Central Bank 2000: 54). Thus, the
evolution of the ECB’s official position is, for the most part, the result of a
calculation. The expected gains in terms of consolidated independence are
perceived as far higher than the expected costs of acknowledging the European
Parliament’s role as a privileged interlocutor.
In the absence of strong parliamentary powers at the EU level, the ‘dialogue’
is in fact not very constraining. A new routine of quarterly hearings of the
president of the ECB before the European Parliament’s Economic and Monet-
ary Affairs Committee has been established. The main actors looked at foreign
models as sources of ideas, especially the US model. Yet despite the recurrent
reference to the Fed’s accountability to the US Congress, the staging of ECB
hearings is revealingly different from the hearings of the chair of the US
Federal Reserve by Congressional committees. Whereas the chair of the Fed-
eral Reserve stands in the witness box and must answer questions asked by a
small number of Congressmen who sit above him like judges, the president of
the ECB addresses a floor of European Parliament members from a platform
where he is seated next to the chair of the Economic and Monetary Affairs
Committee. Moreover, the ECB president’s hearings only last two hours, and
members of Parliament are only allowed to ask the President two questions,
which he can therefore dodge quite easily. Here again, the difference with the
US situation is striking, since the chair of the Federal Reserve is subjected to a
barrage of questions from Congressmen.
In sum, the ECB and the European Parliament came to an agreement on the
rules of the accountability game because both bodies had a clear interest in
playing that game. Accountability became a terrain of political contest
between two bodies that defended what they had identified as their primary
interests. The ECB wanted more democratic legitimacy, which it could acquire
through good relations with the European Parliament. Conversely, the European
402
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
Parliament desired a greater say on the conduct of economic policy within the
EU, which it could gain from its relations with the ECB. Thus, in many
respects, the ‘dialogue’ between central bankers and members of the European
Parliament developed into a form of exchange.
The real question is whether the game of central bank accountability
between the ECB and the European Parliament really serves democracy, or
merely the interests of the various actors who play that game. It is important to
realize that both hypotheses could well be valid at the same time. The evolving
debate on central bank accountability represents an interesting attempt to
‘muddle through’ a new democratic practice, yet it is also, and perhaps inevi-
tably, a power play between the main actors—just as in the United States. Despite
the continuous upgrade of its powers since the 1980s, the European Parliament
does not in any sense match the power and prestige of the US Congress. The
European Parliament gained its oversight role over the ECB only by courtesy of
the member states, and, furthermore, this oversight is limited to mere ‘reporting
requirements’. This affects the Parliament’s power to hold the ECB accountable.
The practice of parliamentary hearings has different parameters and results,
despite the superficial similarity between the EU and the United States.
Just as important, there is almost no form of accountability to the executive in
Europe—largely because there is no unified executive able to claim policy
leadership. Thus far, the Euro Group—that is, the caucus of Euro Area finance
ministers within the EU Council—has not asserted very strongly its preferences
vis-à-vis the ECB. This is due to the difficulties of coordinating member govern-
ments’ economic policies, as well as to the extent of ECB independence in the
Treaty. Only with the nomination of Jean-Claude Juncker as the chair of the
Euro Group did this situation begin to change. But the chair has no hierarchical
powers over his colleagues, so his room for manoeuvre is limited. By contrast,
member states are still vested with so much power and legitimacy that central
bankers are very cautious when it comes to accountability toward the member
governments. This also explains the relative opaqueness of the ECB when it
comes to minutes and voting patterns. In the absence of a truly unified EU-level
economic stance, the governors of national central banks refuse to be exposed
to the heat of national debates on their positions within the Governing Council.
403
Transparency and Accountability
Federal Reserve. Those who hold this view favour the ECB’s mandate from
a transparency and accountability perspective, which has the advantage of
being clearly hierarchical. From this perspective, the mandate is transparent,
and the ECB is ‘accountable for the fulfillment of its mandate’ (Issing 1999).
On the other hand, it is also possible, and indeed more conventional, to
argue in favour of more open-ended goals for policymakers as a way to reinforce
their accountability. In political theory, the standard conception of account-
ability assumes that there is room left for policymakers to exercise discretion,
and that the evaluation of policies takes place ex post. The existence of mean-
ingful accountability is then opposed to the definition of a strict mandate
(Pitkin 1967). In this conception, therefore, too much transparency can actu-
ally come at the cost of accountability.
Second, the self-definition of their role by central bankers is different in the
ECB and in the United States. While the Fed is an independent central bank, it
has had to live with a particularly broad mandate that includes growth and
employment as well as low inflation. In the Euro Area, the situation is very
different because the ECB’s mandate is narrower—with price stability defined
as a ‘primary objective’. But arguably even more important is the fact that
Eurosystem central bankers have come to see a narrow technical definition of
their task as a guarantee of their hard-won independence. Unlike their Ameri-
can counterparts, they are in an EU sphere where nobody has sufficient
legitimacy to make clear—let alone partisan—policy choices. The conse-
quence is that central bankers attempt to escape political debate and to deny
the existence of difficult trade-offs altogether.
Does an inflation rate ‘below 2 per cent’, namely, the ECB’s unilaterally
chosen ‘reference value’, strictly correspond to the Treaty’s objective of ‘price
stability’? This is debatable—to say the least. In 2003, the ECB chose to specify
its objective and announced a target of ‘below but close to 2 per cent’. The first
remarkable fact is that, unlike the US situation (or the Japanese situation),
there was no unified political body able to really discuss—let alone to dis-
agree—with the ECB on this matter. Despite a formal recognition of the Euro
Group and the introduction of a stable chairmanship during the EU Constitu-
tional Convention of 2002–3, the forums toward which the ECB is supposed to
be transparent and accountable remain ill designed. If this situation ever
changes, it will not be simply because of a universal realization that change
is desirable from the viewpoint of transparency and accountability—some
very serious political obstacles stand in the way.
In addition, it is possible to question, from a substantive perspective, the
ECB’s adherence to a rather rigid conception of central bank independence
and its refusal to engage in a debate about its policy target. While understand-
able in its own terms, given the ECB’s political environment, the absence of
substantive debate is not necessarily the way of ensuring satisfactory standards
of transparency and accountability.12 After all, the fact that price stability and
404
Central Banks in the Age of the Euro
central bank independence are given such high priority in the Maastricht
Treaty must itself be understood as the output of a political process, not simply
as a legal translation of economic rationality. In the French referendum of May
2005 on the EU Constitutional Treaty, one of the recurrent arguments of
opponents was the ‘democratic deficit’ of the EU and specifically the ‘lack of
accountability’ of the ECB. But then, again, there is a gap between a diagnosis
of the situation and a political cure.
Concluding Remarks
405
Transparency and Accountability
much less seamless than they appear at first sight. As long as there is room for
incoherence within and deviation from the consensual norms, the façade can
nonetheless cover the reality without generating too much cognitive disson-
ance. Only when we stop believing in the reality of the façade will we need to
move to another (consensus) view.
Notes
1. The importance of monetary policy credibility is one way to address the time
consistency problem pointed out by Kydland and Prescott (1977). On the import-
ance of transparency to help central banks achieve their policy objectives and
buttress their credibility, see Geraats (2002), Stasavage (2003).
2. McNamara (2002) lists 38 countries that have made their central banks independent
in the course of the 1990s. Pollilo and Guillen (2005) calculate that more than 80
countries have adopted legal provisions that increase the independence of their
central banks; Marcussen (2005) finds roughly similar numbers.
3. Political theorists have typically conceptualized accountability in the context of
electoral representation and often concluded that it was difficult to achieve in
practice. The addition of power delegation from elected officials to independent
central bankers arguably makes accountability even harder to operationalize. See
Pitkin (1967), Mansbridge (2003).
4. See for example the heated Buiter–Issing and Elgie–De Haan–Amtbrink debates on
the issue of whether or not central banks in Europe had become more accountable in
the 1990s: (Buiter 1999; De Haan and Amtenbrink 2000; De Haan and Eijffinger
2000; Elgie 1998, 2001; Issing 1999).
5. These factors can thus be called institutions in an anthropological sense, like
‘planets fixed in the sky’ (Douglas 1986: 46–7).
6. This change contrasts with Woolley’s (1984: 26) earlier assessment that monetary
policy was ‘made in great secrecy’.
7. For a narration of William Cheshire Martin’s role in securing the Fed’s independence
not from but ‘within the government’, see Bremner (2005).
8. Labor Secretary Robert Reich (1997) was one of the most outspoken critics of Green-
span’s influence on the administration’s policies.
9. According to Woodward (1997: 114, 226–7), Greenspan favoured transparency also
because he thought it magnified his own power. For an early expression of this
concern for the benefits of transparency, see Goodfriend (1986).
10. Blinder (2004: 5–33) offers his own account of his advocacy of transparency within
the Board of Governors.
11. Meyer (2004) cites a 1996 meeting at which Janet Yellen, a member of the FOMC,
boldly challenged Alan Greenspan on this issue.
12. See Stasavage (2003) for an argument that reconciles monetary policy credibility
with a degree of democratic accountability, but on the condition that central bank
independence ceases to be an absolute principle.
406
References
Adolph, C. (2003). ‘Paper Autonomy, Private Ambition: Theory and Evidence Linking
Central Bankers’ Careers and Economic Performance’. Paper presented at the annual
meeting of the American Political Science Association, Philadelphia, 28–31 August.
—— (2005). ‘Three Simple Tests of Career Influences on Monetary Policy’. Paper pre-
sented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washing-
ton, DC, 1–3 September.
Aeschimann, E. and Riché, P. (1996). La guerre de sept ans: histoire secrète du franc fort, 1989–
1996. Paris: Calmann-Lévy.
Afonso, A., Schuknecht, L., and Tanzi, V. (2003). ‘Public Sector Efficiency: An Inter-
national Comparison’, ECB Working Paper, no. 242, July.
Ahearne, A., Gagnon, J., Haltmaier, J., and Camin, S. with Erceg, C., Faust, J., Guerreri,
L., Hemphill, C., Kole, L., Roush, J., Rogers, J., Sheets, N., and Wright, J. (2002). ‘Pre-
venting Deflation: Lessons from Japan’s Experience in the 1990s’. International Finance
Discussion Papers #729, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Alesina, A. and Summers, L. (1993). ‘Central Bank Independence and Macroeconomic
Performances’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 25, 2: 151–63.
Anderson, B. (1991). Imagined Communities. Reflections on the Origins and Spread of Nation-
alism. London and New York: Verso.
Andrews, D. M. (2003). ‘The Committee of Central Bank Governors as a Source of Rules’,
Journal of European Public Policy, 10, 6: 956–73.
Apel, E. (2003). Central Banking Systems Compared: The ECB, The Pre-Euro Bundesbank and
the Federal Reserve System. London: Routledge.
Apel, M., Heikensten, L., and Jansson, P. (2008). ‘Monetary Policy and Academics: A Study
of Swedish Inflation Targeting’, in A. B. Shani, S. A. Mohrman, W. A. Pasmore, B. Stymne,
and N. B. Adler (eds.), Handbook of Collaborative Management Research. London: Sage
Publishers, 375–402.
Armstrong, J. (1973). The European Administrative Elite. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univer-
sity Press.
Auberger, P. (1996). Rapport d’information de l’Assemblée Nationale, no. 2940.
Baldwin, R., Berglof, E. Giavazzi, F., and Widgren, M. (2001). ‘Preparing the ECB for
Enlargement’ Centre for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper, no. 6.
Balleix-Banerjee, C. (1999). La France et la Banque Centrale Européenne. Paris: PUF.
Bank Act (1998). ‘Wet van 26 maart 1998, houdende nieuwe bepalingen inzake De
Nederlandsche Bank NV in verband met het Verdrag tot oprichting van de Europese
Gemeenschap’, Staatsblad 2004, 556 (version as of 30 October 2004).
Bank for International Settlements (2008). Global Monetary and Financial Disorder, www.
bis.org/events/conf080626
Bank of England (1996–2001). Annual Report. London: Bank of England.
—— (1999–2002). Practical Issues Arising from the Euro. London: Bank of England.
407
References
Bank of England (1996–1998). Practical Issues Arising from the Introduction of the Euro.
London: Bank of England.
—— (2005). Publications on Europe: City Guide to a UK Euro Changeover. September, www.
bankofengland.co.uk/publications/other/europe/cityguide/index.htm
Bank of Greece (various). Report of the Governor for the Year. Athens: Bank of Greece.
Barber, T. (2007). ‘EU Adopts Flexible Stance on Bank Crises’. Financial Times, 16
September.
Bartels, L. and Brady, H. (2003). ‘Economic Behavior in Political Context’, American
Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 93 (May): 156–61.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2003). High-level Principles for the Cross-branch
Implementation of the New Accord. Basel: Bank for International Settlements.
—— (2007). Principles for Home-Host Supervisory, Cooperation and Allocation Mechanisms in
the Context of Advanced Measurement Approaches (AMA). Basel: Bank for International
Settlements.
Baumgartner, F. and Jones, B. (1993). Agendas and Instability in American Politics. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
Bean, C. (2007). ‘The Meaning of ‘‘Internal Balance’’ Thirty Years On’. Speech at the James
Meade Centenary Conference, London, July 13.
BearingPoint (2005). Central Bank Modernisation. How to Plan and Implement Reforms.
London: Central Banking Publications.
Begg, I. (2006). ‘Real Convergence and EMU Enlargement: The Time Dimension of Fit with
the Euro Area’, in K. Dyson (ed.), Enlarging the Euro Area: External Empowerment and
Domestic Transformation in East Central Europe. Oxford, Oxford University Press, pp. 71–89.
—— (2007). ‘Contested Meaning of Transparency in Central Banking’, Comparative Euro-
pean Politics, 5, 1: 36–52.
Belaisch, A., Kodres, L., Levy, J., and Ubide, A. (2001). ‘Euro-Area Banking at the Cross-
roads’, IMF Working Paper, 01/28, March.
Bell, S. (2006). Australia’s Money Mandarins: The Reserve Bank and the Politics of Money.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Berg, C. and Jonung, L. (1998). ‘Pioneering Price Level Targeting: The Swedish Experience
1931–1937’, Working Paper 290, Stockholm: Stockholm School of Economics.
Berger, H. (2006). ‘Unfinished Business? The ECB Reform Ahead of Euro Area Enlarge-
ment’, CESifo Forum, 4: 35–41.
—— and De Haan, J. (1999). ‘A State within the State? An Event Study on the Bundesbank
(1948–1973)’, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 46, 1: 17–39.
—— de Haan, J., and Inklaar, R. (2004). ‘Restructuring the ECB’, in H. Berger and T. Moutos
(eds.), Managing European Union Enlargement. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, pp. 29–66.
Berger, P. and T. Luckmann (1966). The Social Construction of Reality. London: Penguin Books.
Berman, S. and McNamara, K. (1999). ‘Bank on Democracy: Why Central Banks Need
Public Oversight’, Foreign Affairs, 78, 2: 2–8.
Bernanke, B. (2004a), ‘Central Bank Talk and Monetary Policy’. Remarks at the Japan
Society Corporate Luncheon, New York, 7 October.
—— (2004b). ‘The Logic of Monetary Policy’. Speech to the National Economists’ Club,
Washington, DC, December 2.
—— (2007a). ‘Globalization and Monetary Policy’, speech at the Fourth Economic Sum-
mit, Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research, Stanford, California, March 2.
408
References
—— (2007b). ‘The Housing Market and Subprime Lending’. Speech to the 2007 Inter-
national Monetary Conference, Cape Town, South Africa, June 5.
—— (2007c). ‘Housing, Housing Finance and Monetary Policy’. Speech at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City’s Economic Symposium, Jackson Hole, August 31.
—— (2007d). ‘Federal Reserve Communication’. Speech to the Cato Institute 25th
Annual Monetary Policy Conference, Washington, DC, November 14.
—— and Mishkin, F. (1997). ‘Inflation Targeting: A New Framework for Monetary Policy?
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11, 2: 97–116.
—— Thomas, L., Mishkin, F., and Posen, A. (1999). Inflation Targeting. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Bernhard, W. (1998). ‘A Political Explanation of Variations in Central Bank Independ-
ence’, American Political Science Review, 92, 2: 311–27.
BGFRS (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System) (2007a). Annual Report 2006.
Washington, DC: Federal Reserve System.
—— (2007b). Annual Report: Budget Review. Washington, DC: Federal Reserve System.
Bini Smaghi, L. (2008). ‘Financial Stability and Monetary Policy: Challenges in the
Current Turmoil’. Speech at CEPS joint event with Harvard Law School on the EU-US
financial system, New York, 4 April.
Blinder, A., Goodhart, C., Hildebrand, P., Lipton, D., and Wyplosz, C. (eds.) (2002). How
Do Central Banks Talk? London: Centre for Economic Policy Research.
—— (2004). The Quiet Revolution: Central Banking Goes Modern. New Haven: Yale University
Press.
—— (1998). Central Banking in Theory and Practice. Cambridge, Massachusetts: The MIT
Press.
—— and Wyplosz, C. (2004). ‘Central Bank Talk: Committee Structure and Communica-
tion Policy’, prepared for the session on ‘Central Bank Communication’ at the ASSA
meetings, Philadelphia, January 9, 2005.
Blix, M., Daltug, S., and Heikensten, L. (2003). ‘On Central Bank Efficiency’, Economic
Review of the Riksbank, 3: 81–93.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve (2005). The Federal Reserve System: Purposes and
Functions. Washington, DC: Federal Reserve System.
Bohle, D. and Greskovits, B. (2006). ‘Europeanization and the Variety of Competition
States in Central-Eastern Europe’, in A. Ágh and A. Ferencz (eds.), Deepening and Widen-
ing in an Enlarged Europe: The Impact of Eastern Enlargement. Budapest: ‘Together for
Europe’ Research Centre of the Hungarian Academy of Sciences, pp. 245–86.
—— —— (2007). ‘Neoliberalism, Embedded Neoliberalism and Neocorporatism: Towards
Transnational Capitalism in Central-Eastern Europe’, West European Politics, 30, 3: 443–66.
Bollard, A. (2005). ‘Bank Regulation and Supervision in New Zealand: Recent and
Ongoing Developments’, address to the Australasian Institute of Banking and Finance,
23 March, Wellington: Reserve Bank of New Zealand.
Bönker, F. (2006). ‘From Pacesetter to Laggard: The Political Economy of Negotiating Fit in
the Czech Republic’, in K. Dyson (ed.), Enlarging the Euro Area: External Empowerment
and Domestic Transformation in East Central Europe. Oxford, Oxford University Press,
pp. 160–77.
Bordes, C. and Clerc, L. (2007). ‘Price stability and the ECB’s Monetary Policy Strategy’,
Journal of Economic Surveys, 21, 2, 268–325.
409
References
Bordo, M. (2007). ‘The Crisis of 2007: The Same Old Story, Only the Players Have
Changed’, paper presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago and International
Monetary Fund conference ‘Globalization and Systemic Risk’, Chicago.
Borish, M. and Company Inc. with Triumph Technologies Inc. (1998). ‘An Assessment
and Rating of the Polish Banking System’. Washington, DC: USAID.
Boston, J., Martin, J., Pallot, J., and Walsh, P. (1996). Public Management: The New Zealand
Model. Auckland: Oxford University Press.
Bowers, S. and Inman, P. (2007). ‘Bank of England Throws Northern Rock Another Lifeline
by Loosening Loan Terms’. The Guardian, 10 October.
Bremner, R. (2005). Chairman of the Fed. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Breuss, F., Fink, G., and Haiss, P. (2004). ‘How Well Prepared Are the New Member States
for the European Monetary Union?’ Journal of Policy Modeling, 26, 7: 769–91.
Broz, J. (1997). The International Origins of the Federal Reserve System. Ithaca: Cornell
University Press.
Bruszt, L., Oblath, G., and Tóth, A. (2003). ‘Összehangolt cselekvés’ (Coordinated action),
Népszabadság Online, September 27.
Buiter, W. (1999). ‘Alice in Euroland’, Journal of Common Market Studies, 37, 2: 181–209.
—— (2004). ‘To Purgatory and Beyond: When and How Should the Accession Countries
from Central and Eastern Europe Become Full Members of EMU?’ CEPR Discussion Paper
No. 4342.
—— (2006). ‘Rethinking Inflation Targeting and Central Bank Independence’, inaugural
Lecture, LSE, October 26.
Bulmer, S. (1994). ‘The Governance of the European Union: A New Institutionalist
Approach’, Journal of Public Policy, 13, 4, 351–80.
—— (1997). ‘New Institutionalism, the Single Market and EU Governance’, ARENA Work-
ing Papers WP 97/25, Olso.
Bundesministerium der Finanzen (2005). ‘Erfolgreiche Debatte um Reform des Stabilitaet-
spakt’, Pressemitteilung 36, Berlin, 21 March.
Busch, A. (2004). ‘National Filters: Europeanization, Institutions, and Discourse in the
Case of Banking Regulation’, West European Politics, 27, 2: 310–33.
Buyst, E. and Maes, I. (2008). ‘The Regulation and Supervision of the Belgian Financial
System (1830–2005)’, Working Paper, no. 77, June, Bank of Greece.
—— Maes, I., and Pluym, W. (2005). The Bank, the Franc and the Euro. A History of the
National Bank of Belgium. Tielt: Lannoo.
Calomiris, C. and Litan, R. (2000). ‘Financial Regulation in a Global Marketplace’. Brook-
ings-Wharton Papers on Financial Services, 283–339.
Capital Market Committee (2001). Annual Report 2000. Athens: CMC.
Castles, F. (1984). The Working Class and Welfare: Reflections on the Political Development of
the Welfare State in Australia and New Zealand, 1890–1980. Wellington: Allen and
Unwin/Port Nicholson Press.
—— (1988). Australian Public Policy and Economic Vulnerability. Sydney: Allen and Unwin.
Cecchetti, S., Flores-Lagunes, A., and Krause, S. (2005). ‘Assessing the Sources of Changes
in the Volatility of Real Growth’. Paper at the conference on ‘The Changing Nature of
the Business Cycle’, Reserve Bank of Australia.
Cerny, P. (1999). ‘Globalization and the Erosion of Democracy’, European Journal of
Political Research, 36, 1, 1–26.
410
References
Chandler, L. (1958). Benjamin Strong – Central Banker. Washington, DC: The Brookings
Institution.
Chappell, H., McGregor, R., and Vermilyea, T. (2005). Committee Decisions on Monetary
Policy: Evidence from Historical Records of the Federal Open Market Committee. Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press.
Chirac, J. (2000). Unser Europa, Rede vor dem deutschen Bundestag in Berlin am
27.6.2000, http://www.bundestag.de/geschichte/gastredner/chirac/chirac1.html
Ciampi, C. (1990). ‘L’ Autonomia della Banca d’Italia nella Conduzione della Politica
Monetaria’, Bancaria, 1, 1: 65–70.
Ciocca, P. (2000). La Nuova Finanza in Italia. Torino: Bollati Boringhieri.
Claessens, S., Demirgüc-Kunt, A., and Huizinga, H. (1998). How Does Foreign Entry Affect
the Domestic Banking Market? Washington, DC: The World Bank.
Cohen, B. (1998). The Geography of Money. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Collins, H. (2007). Rethinking Expertise. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Commissiariat Général du Plan (ed.) (2004). Perspectives de la coopération renforcée dans
l’Union européenne. Paris: Commissiariat Général du Plan.
Commission of the European Communities (2005). White Paper: Financial Services Policy
2005–2010, SEC(2005) 1574. Brussels: Commission of the European Communities.
Council of the European Union (2000). Council Decision 2000/604/EC of 29th September
2000 on the Composition and the Statutes of the Economic Policy Committee, Brussels:
Council of the European Union.
—— (2006). Council Recommendation to the United Kingdom with a View to Bringing an End to
the Situation of an Excessive Government Deficit – Application of Article 104(7) of the Treaty,
5367/06, ECOFIN 12, UEM 17, Brussels: Council of the European Union.
Cours des comptes (1996). La Banque de France, January.
—— (2005). La Banque de France, March.
Cukierman, A. (1992). Central Bank Strategy, Credibility, and Independence: Theory and
Evidence. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
—— Miller, G., and Neyapti, B. (2002). ‘Central Bank Reform, Liberalization and Inflation
in Transition Economies – An International Perspective’, Journal of Monetary Economics,
49, 2: 237–64.
Cullen, M. (2007). ‘The Role of Tax in Transforming the Economy’, Speech notes for
address to Ernst & Young Tax Partners/Managers Breakfast. Clearwater Resort, Christ-
church, 16 July.
Czech National Bank (2003). Czech National Bank, 1993–2003. Prague: Czech National
Bank.
Dahrendorf, Ralf (2008). ‘Europa – oder die irische Frage. Plädoyer für die Rückkehr zu den
Quellen und für einen Neubeginn’, Neue Züricher Zeitung, 2nd July 2008.
Davies, H. (1997). Speech at the Futures and Options Association International Deriva-
tives Week Conference, 4 June.
De Haan, J. (2000). History of the Bundesbank: Lessons for the European Central Bank.
London: Routledge.
—— and Amtenbrink, F. (2000). ‘Democratic Accountability and Central Bank Independ-
ence: A Response to Elgie’, West European Politics 23, 3, 179–90.
—— and Eijffinger, S. (2000). ‘The Democratic Accountability of the European Central
Bank: A Comment on Two Fairy Tales’, Journal of Common Market Studies, 38, 3: 393–407.
411
References
De Haan, J., Eijffinger, S., and Waller, S. (2005). The European Central Bank: Credibility,
Transparency, and Centralization. Boston: MIT Press.
De Haas, B. and van Lotringen, C. (2003). Wim Duisenberg: Van Friese Volksjongen to
Mr. Euro. Amsterdam: Business Contact.
De Nederlandsche Bank (1997). Monetaire Stabiliteit en Bestendigheid. Smalle Marges Opti-
maal Benut 1981–1996. Amsterdam: De Nederlandsche Bank.
—— (1999). Annual Report 1998. Amsterdam: Kluwer.
—— (2000a). Jaarverlag De Nederlandsche Bank 1999. Amsterdam: De Nederlandsche Bank.
—— (2000b). Quarterly Bulletin. March. Amsterdam: De Nederlandsche Bank.
—— (2002). ‘Smooth Euro Changeover, Higher Prices? Results of a Survey among Dutch
Retailers’, DNB Research Memorandum No. 682.E.
—— (2003). Jaarverslag De Nederlandsche Bank 2002. Amsterdam: De Nederlandsche Bank.
—— (2007). Annual Report 2006. Amsterdam: De Nederlandsche Bank.
—— (2008a). Jaarverslag De Nederlandsche Bank 2007. Amsterdam: De Nederlandsche Bank.
—— (2008b). Overview of Financial Stability in the Netherlands. Amsterdam: De Neder-
landsche Bank.
Deane, M. and Pringle, R. (1994). The Central Banks. London: Harmish Hamilton.
Delors, J. (2004). Mémoires. Paris: Plon.
Dennis, B. (1998). 500%. Stockholm: Bokförlaget DN.
Dermine, J. (2006). ‘European Banking Integration: Don’t Put the Cart Before the Horse’,
Financial Markets, Institutions and Instruments, 15, 2: 57–106.
Deutsche Bundesbank (1992). ‘Die Beschluesse von Maastricht zur Europaeischen
Wirtschafts- und Waehrungsunion in Europe’, Monatsbericht, 2: 45–54.
—— (2003). ‘The Monetary Constitution under the Constitution for Europe’, Monthly
Report, November: 65.
—— (2004). ‘Die Deutsche Bundesbank als integraler Bestandteil des Eurosystems’, Die
Europaeische Wirtschafts- und Waehrungsunion, Frankfurt, February: 57–8.
—— (2005a). ‘The Changes to the Stability and Growth Pact’, Monthly Report, April:
15–21.
—— (2005b). ‘Deficit-limiting Budget Rules and a National Stability Pact in Germany’,
Monthly Report, April: 23–37.
—— (2005c). ‘Stabilitaets- und Wachstumspakt entscheidend geschwaecht’, Pressenotiz,
Stellungnahme der Deutschen Bundesbank, Frankfurt, 21 March.
—— (2005d). ‘Establishment of a Centre for Technical Central Bank Cooperation’, Press
Release, Frankfurt, 20 July.
—— (ed.) (1999). Fifty Years of the Deutsche Mark. Central Bank and the Currency in Germany
since 1948. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
DIE ZEIT (2007). ‘Jetzt wird’s ungemütlich. Der Euro steigt und steigt. Eine ungewöhn-
liche Reisegruppe soll für Abhilfe sorgen’, 18 October: 28.
Dincer, N. and Eichengreen, B. (2007). ‘Central Bank Transparency: Where, Why, and
With What Effects’? NBER Working Paper Series, no 13003, Cambridge: National Bureau
of Economic Research.
Dougherty, C. (2008). ‘In Europe, Central Banking Is Different’, The New York Times,
6 March.
Douglas, M. (1986). How Institutions Think. Syracuse: Syracuse University Press.
Downs, A. (1957). An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper and Row.
412
References
Draghi, M. (2008). ‘How to Restore Financial Stability: Bundesbanl Lecture 2008’, Aus-
zuege aus Presseartikeln, Deutsche Bundesbank, 17 September: 7–11.
Duckenfield, M. (1999a). ‘The Goldkrieg: Revaluing the Bundesbank’s Reserves and the
Politics of EMU’, German Politics, 8, 1: 106–30.
—— (1999b). ‘Bundesbank-Government Relations in Germany in the 1990s: From GEMU
to EMU’, West European Politics, 22, 3: 87–108.
Duisenberg, W. (2000a). ‘Hearing before the Committee on Economic and Monetary
Affairs, European Parliament’, March 20.
—— (2000b). ‘The Role of the ECB at the International Level’. Speech at the Annual
meeting of the Institute of the International Finance, Inc. (IIF), Prague, 23 September.
—— (2002). ‘The Role of the Eurosystem in Prudential Supervision’, speech at the con-
ference organized by the De Nederlandsche Bank on the occasion of the 50th anniver-
sary of Dutch bank supervisory legislation, Amsterdam, 24 April.
Dumke, R. and Sherman, H. (2000). ‘Exchange Rate Options for EU Applicant Countries
in Central and Eastern Europe’, in B. Granville (ed.), Essays on the World Economy and its
Financial System. London: The Royal Institute of International Affairs, pp. 153–95.
Duval, R. and Elmeskov, J. (2005). ‘The Effects of EMU on Structural Reforms in Labour and
Product Markets’, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, no. 438, Paris: OECD.
Dyson, K. (1980). The State Tradition in Western Europe. Oxford: Martin Robertson.
—— (1994). Elusive Union. London: Longman.
—— (1998). ‘Chancellor Kohl as Strategic Leader: The Case of Economic and Monetary
Union’, in C. Clemens and W. Paterson (eds.), The Kohl Chancellorship. London: Frank
Cass, pp. 37–63.
—— (1999). ‘German Economic Policy after 50 Years’, in P. Merkl (ed.), The Federal
Republic of Germany at Fifty. The End of a Century of Turmoil. New York: New York
University Press, pp. 219–30.
—— (2000). The Politics of the Euro-Zone. Stability or Breakdown? Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
—— (ed.) (2002a). European States and the Euro: Europeanization, Variation and Convergence.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
—— (2002b). ‘Introduction: EMU as Integration, Europeanization, and Convergence’, in
K. Dyson (ed.), European States and the Euro. Europeanization, Variation, and Convergence.
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1–27.
—— (2006). Enlarging the Euro Area: External Empowerment and Domestic Transformation in
East Central Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
—— (2007). ‘Euro Area Entry in East-Central Europe: Paradoxical Europeanization and
Clustered Convergence’, West European Politics, 30, 3: 417–42.
—— (2008a). ‘The Treaty of Rome at Fifty: The ‘Hard and Stony’ Road to Economic and
Monetary Union’, in D. Phinnemore and A. Warleigh-Lack (eds.), Reflections on European
Integration. London: Palgrave, pp. 143–173.
—— (ed.) (2008b). The Euro at 10. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
—— (2008c). ‘The European Central Bank: Enlargement as Institutional Affirmation and Dif-
ferentiation’, in E. Best, T. Christiansen, and P. Settembri (eds.), The Governance of the Wider
Europe: EU Enlargement and Institutional Change. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, pp. 120–40.
—— and Featherstone, F. (1999). The Road to Maastricht: Negotiating Economic and Monetary
Union. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
413
References
Dyson, K. and Goetz, K. (eds.) (2003). Germany, Europe and the Politics of Constraint.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
—— and Quaglia, L. (2009). European Economic Governance and Policies: Commentary on Key
Documents. 2 vols. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
—— Featherstone, K., and Michalopoulos, G. (1995). ‘Strapped to the Mast: EC Central
Bankers between Global Financial Markets and Regional Integration’, Journal of Euro-
pean Public Policy, 2, 3: 465–87.
Eckstein, H. (1975). ‘Case Study and Theory in Political Science’, in F. Greenstein and
N. Polsby (eds.), Handbook of Political Science. vol. 7, Strategies of Inquiry, Addison-Wesley
Publishing Company, pp. 79–137.
Economic and Financial Committee (2007a). Developing EU Financial Stability Arrange-
ments: Final Report. 5 September, ECFIN/CEFCPE(2007)REP/53990, Brussels: EFC.
—— (2007b). Press Release (15698/07), 4 December.
Égert, B., Gruber, T., and Reininger, T. (2003). ‘Challenges for EU Acceding Countries’
Exchange Rate Strategies after EU Accession and Asymmetric Application of the
Exchange Rate Criteria’, Focus on Transition, 2: 152–72.
Eichbaum, C. (1999). Reshaping the Reserve: A Political Economy of Central Banking in
Australasia. PhD dissertation, Massey University, New Zealand.
Eichengreen, B. (1985). ‘Editor’s Introduction’, in B. Eichengreen (ed.), The Gold Standard
in Theory and History. London: Methuen, pp. 1–35.
—— (2003). ‘The Accession Economies’ Rocky Road to the Euro’, East-West Conference
2003. Vienna: National Bank of Austria.
Eijffinger, S. (2006). ‘Change at the ECB Executive Board’, Intereconomics, 41, 2: 93–9.
—— and Geraats, S. (2006). ‘How Transparent Are Central Banks?’, European Journal of
Political Economy, 22, 1: 1–21.
—— Hoeberichts, M., and Schaling, E. (2000). ‘Why Money Talks and Wealth Whispers:
Monetary Uncertainty and Mystique’, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 32, 2: 218–35.
Eijffinger, S. C. W. (2006). ‘Change at the ECB Executive Board’, Intereconomics, March/
April: 93–9.
Einecke, H. (2004). ‘Bundesbank in der Krise’, Sueddeutsche Zeitung, 10 April.
EIROnline (2004). ‘National-level Tripartism and EMU in the New EU Member States and
Candidate Countries’. www.eiro.eurofound.eu.int/2004/03/study/tn0403102s.html
accessed on 7/23/2004.
Elgie, R. (1998). ‘Democratic Accountability and Central Bank Independence’, West Euro-
pean Politics, 21, 3: 53–77.
—— (2001). ‘Democratic Accountability and Central Bank Independence: A Reply to
Various Critics’, West European Politics, 24, 1: 217–21.
Emminger, O. (1986). D-Mark, Dollar, Waehrungskrisen. Erinnerungen eines ehemaligen Bun-
desbankpraesidenten. Stuttgart: Deutsche Verlags-Anstalt.
Engelen, K. (2002a). ‘Central Bank Losers: The Inside Story of How the ECB and the
Bundesbank Are Being Pushed Aside as Financial Regulators’, The International Economy,
Summer.
—— (2002b). ‘Buba’s Internal Politics’, The International Political Economy, 16, 3: 22.
Ennuuste, U., Kukk, K., Pyss, T., and Viies, M. (2004). A Political Economy Analysis of
Estonian 1987–2006 Capitalist Market Reform Process. Estonian Institute of Economics
at Tallinn University of Technology. Unpublished Manuscript.
414
References
415
References
Federal Reserve Bank of New York (2008). ‘Domestic Open Market Operations During
2007’. A Report for the Federal Open Market Committee by the Markets Group, February.
Federal Reserve System Study Group on Alternative Instruments for System Operations
(2002). ‘Alternative Instruments for Open Market and Discount Window Operations’.
Washington, DC: Federal Reserve System.
Federal Trust (2005). Flexibility and the Future of the European Union. London: Federal Trust.
—— (2005). Flexibility and the Future of the European Union. London.
Feldmann, M. (2006). ‘The Baltic States: Pacesetting on EMU Accession and the Consoli-
dation of Domestic Stability Culture’, in K. Dyson (ed.), Enlarging the Euro Area: External
Empowerment and Domestic Transformation in East Central Europe. Oxford: Oxford Uni-
versity Press, pp. 178–96.
FFIEC (Federal Financial Institutions Examination Council) (2006). Annual Report 2006.
Washington, DC.
Finocchiaro, A. and Contessa, A. (2002). La Banca d’Italia e i Problemi della Moneta e del
Credito. Roma: Bancaria.
Fischer, B., Lenza, M., Pill, H., and Reichlin, L. (2006). ‘Money and Monetary Policy: The
ECB Experience 1999–2006’, paper presented at the ECB Central Banking Conference,
Frankfurt, November 6.
Fischer, J. (2000). Vom Staatenbund zur Föderation – Gedanken über die Finalität der Euro-
päischen Integration, speech given on 12 May at the Humboldt-University Berlin, in
M. Hartmut (ed.), Die neue Europadebatte. Leitbilder für das Europa der Zukunft. Bonn:
Europa Union Verlag, pp. 41–54.
Fischer, S. (1990). ‘Rules Versus Discretion in Monetary Policy’, in B. M. Friedman and
F. H. Hahn (eds.), Handbook of Monetary Economics. vol. 2. Amsterdam: North Holland,
pp. 1169–78.
—— (1994). ‘Modern Central Banking’, in F. Capie, C. Goodhart, S. Fischer, and
N. Schnadt (eds.), The Future of Central Banking. The Tercentenary Symposium of the
Bank of England. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 262–308.
—— (2001). ‘Exchange Rate Regimes: Is the Bipolar View Correct?’, Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 15, 2: 3–24.
Fourcade, M. (2006). ‘The Construction of a Global Profession: The Transnationalization
of Economics’, American Journal of Sociology, 112, 1: 145–94.
Franzese, R. (2002). Macroeconomic Policies of Developed Democracies. New York: Cambridge
University Press.
Franzese, R. J. and Hall, P. A. (2000). ‘Institutional Dimensions of Coordinating
Wage Bargaining and Monetary Policy’, in T. Iversen, J. Pontusson, and D. Soskice (eds.),
Unions, Employers, and Central Banks. Macroeconomic Coordination and Institutional Change
in Social Market Economies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 173–204.
Fraser, B. (1994). ‘The Art of Monetary Policy’, Reserve Bank of Australia Bulletin, Sydney:
Reserve Bank of Australia, October.
—— (1996). ‘Reserve Bank Independence’, Reserve Bank of Australia Bulletin, Sydney:
Reserve Bank of Australia.
Freeman, J. (2002). ‘The Political Economy of Monetary Institutions’, International Organ-
ization, 56, 4: 889–910.
Fry, M., Julius, D., Mahadeva, L., Roger, S., and Sterne, G. (2000). ‘Key Issues in the Choice
of Monetary Policy Framework’, in L. Mahadeva and G. Sterne (eds.), Monetary Policy
Frameworks in a Global Context. London: Routledge, pp. 1–216.
416
References
Gaiotti, E. and Rossi, S. (2003). ‘La politica monetaria italiana nella srolta degli anni ’80’,
in S. Colaziri, P. Craveri, S. Pons, G. Quagliariello (a cura di) Gli anni ’80 come storia,
Rubettino.
Gaithner, T. (2008). ‘Statement Regarding Actions by the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York in Response to Liquidity Pressures in Financial Markets’, before U.S. Senate Com-
mittee on Banking Housing and Urban Affairs, April 3.
GAO (Government Accountability Office) (2007). Financial Regulation: Industry Trends
Continue to Challenge Federal Regulatory Structure. GAO-08–32, October.
Garganas, N. and Tavlas, G. (2001). ‘Monetary Regimes and Inflation Performance: The
Case of Greece’, in R. C. Bryant, N. C. Garganas, and G. S. Tavlas (eds.), Greece’s
Economic Performance and Prospects. Athens: Bank of Greece-The Brookings Institution,
pp. 43–95.
George, E. (2000). ‘Britain and Europe’, speech to British Swiss Chamber of Commerce
Lunch, 12 September.
Geraats, P. (2002). ‘Central Bank Transparency’, Economic Journal, 112, 483: 532–65.
—— (2005). ‘Transparency and Monetary Policy: Theory and Practice’, on-line paper,
December; http://www.econ.cam.ac.uk/faculty/geraats/tpmptp.pdf, accessed 24 March
2008.
—— (2006). ‘Transparency of Monetary Policy: Theory and Practice’, CESifo Economic
Studies, 52, 1: 111–52.
—— (2007). ‘The Mystique of Central Bank Speak’, International Journal of Central Banking,
3, 1: 37–80.
Gerschenkron, A. (1965). Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective. New York:
Praeger.
Geršl, A. (2006). ‘Political Pressure on Central Banks: The Case of the Czech National
Bank’, Finance a úverˇ- Czech Journal of Economics and Finance, 56, 1–2: 18–39.
Giavazzi, F. and Giovannini, A. (1989). Limiting Exchange Rate Flexibility: The European
Monetary System. Massachusetts: MIT Press.
—— and Pagano, M. (1988). ‘The Advantage of Tying One’s Hands. EMS Discipline and
Central Bank Credibility’, European Economic Review, 32, 5: 1055–82.
—— Micossi, S., and Miller, M. (eds.) (1988). The European Monetary System. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Giblin, L. (1951). The Growth of a Central Bank: The Development of the Commonwealth Bank
of Australia. Melbourne: Melbourne University Press.
Giering, C. (2007). ‘Flexibilisierung’, in W. Weidenfeld and W. Wessels (eds.), Europa von A
bis Z. Taschenbuch der europäischen Integration, 10. Auflage. Baden-Baden: Nomos,
pp. 257–60.
Gilardi, F. (2002). ‘Policy Credibility and Delegation to Independent Regulatory Agencies:
A Comparative Empirical Analysis’, Journal of European Public Policy, 9, 6: 873–93.
Godeaux, J. (1989). ‘The Working of the EMS: A Personal Assessment’, in Committee for the
Study of Economic and Monetary Union, Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of
the European Communities.
Goodfriend, M. (1986). ‘Monetary Mystique: Secrecy and Central Banking’, Journal of
Monetary Economics, 17, 1: 63–92.
—— (1999). ‘The Role of A Regional Bank in a System of Central Banks’, Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond Working Paper, 99–4.
417
References
Goodfriend, M. (2000). ‘The Role of a Regional Bank in a System of Central Banks’. Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond, Economic Quarterly 86 (Winter), 7–25.
—— (2003). ‘Inflation Targeting in the United States?’ in B. Bernanke and M. Woodford
(eds.), The Inflation-Targeting Debate. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 311–37.
—— (2005). ‘The Monetary Policy Debate Since October 1979: Lessons for Theory and
Practice’. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 87 (March/April, part 2), 243–62.
—— König, R., and Repullo, R. (2004). ‘External Evaluation of the Economic Research
Activities of the European Central Bank’, Frankfurt: ECB.
Goodhart, C. (2009). ‘The Political Economy of Inflation Targets: New Zealand and the
U.K.’, in R. Leeson (ed.), David Laidler’s Contribution to Macroeconomics. Basingstoke:
Palgrave Macmillan, p. 243.
—— (2005). ‘Dear Jean-Claude’, Central Banking, 16, 1: 32–6.
—— and Persaud, A. (2008). ‘A Party Pooper’s Guide to Financial Stability’, Financial
Times, 5 June, 15.
—— Capie, F., and Schnadt, N. (1994). ‘The Development of Central Banking’, in F. Capie,
C. Goodhart, S. Fischer, and N. Schnadt (eds.), The Future of Central Banking. The Tercenten-
ary Symposium of the Bank of England. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 1–231.
—— (2006). ‘The ECB and the Conduct of Monetary Policy: Goodhart’s Law and Lessons
from the Euro Area’, Journal of Common Market Studies, 44, 4: 757–78.
Goodman, J. (1992). Monetary Sovereignty: the Politics of Central Banking in Western Europe.
Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Gouldner, A. W. (1979). The Future of Intellectuals and the Rise of the New Class. London: The
MacMillan Press Ltd.
Gramlich, E. (2004). ‘Subprime Mortgage Lending: Benefits, Costs, and Challenges’.
Remarks at the Financial Services Roundtable Annual Housing Policy Meeting, Chicago,
Illinois May 21.
—— (2007). Subprime Mortgages: America’s Latest Boom and Bust. Washington, DC: Urban
Institute Press.
Grauwe, P. de (2006). ‘A Central Banking Model for Neither Gods Nor Monkeys’, Financial
Times, 26 July.
Green Cowles, M., Caporasa, J., and Risse, T. (eds.) (2001). Transforming Europe: European-
ization and Domestic Change. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Greenspan, A. (2007). The Age of Turbulence: Adventures in a New World. New York: Penguin.
Gregory, R. (2007). ‘New Public Management and the Ghost of Max Weber: Exorcised or
Still Haunting?’, in T. Christensen and P. Lægreid (eds.), Transcending New Public
Management. Aldershot: Ashgate, pp. 221–44.
Greiber, C. and Lemke, W. (2005). ‘Money Demand and Macro-Economic Uncertainty’
Deutsche Bundesbank Discussion Paper Series 1, No. 26.
Greider, W. (1987) Secrets of the Temple: How the Federal Reserve Runs the Country. New York:
Simon and Schuster.
Greskovits, B. (2001). ‘Brothers-in-Arms or Rivals in Politics? Top Politicians and Top
Policy Makers in the Hungarian Transformation’, in J. Kornai, S. Haggard, and
R. Kaufman (eds.), Reforming the State. Fiscal and Welfare Reform in Post-Socialist Countries.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 111–41.
—— (2006). ‘The First Shall Be the Last? Hungary’s Road to EMU’, in K. Dyson (ed.),
Enlarging the Euro Area: External Empowerment and Domestic Transformation in East Cen-
tral Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 127–44.
418
References
Grilli, V., Masciandaro, D., and Tabellini, G. (1991). ‘Political and Monetary Institutions
and Public Financial Policies in the Industrial Countries’, Economic Policy, 6, 13: 342–92.
Grimes, A. (2001). ‘Review of New Zealand Monetary Policy’, Agenda, 8, 4: 303–20.
Gros, D. (2003). ‘Reforming the Composition of the ECB Governing Council in View of
Enlargement. How Not to Do It!’, Briefing Paper for the Monetary Committee of the
European Parliament. Brussels: Centre for European Policy Studies, February.
H.M. Treasury (2003). UK Membership of the Single Currency: An Assessment of the Five
Economic Tests. London: Cm 5776, June.
Haas, E. (1990). When Knowledge is Power. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Haas, P. (1992). ‘Introduction: Epistemic Communities and International Policy Coord-
ination’, International Organisation, 46, 1: 1–36.
Habermas, Jürgen (2008). ‘Ein Lob den Iren’, Süddeutsche Zeitung, 17th June 2008, http://
www.sueddeutsche.de/ausland/artikel/310/180753/
Haggard, S., Kaufman, R. R., and Shugart, M. (2001). ‘Politics, Institutions, and Macroeco-
nomic Adjustment: Hungarian Fiscal Policy Making in Comparative Perspective’, in
J. Kornai, S. Haggard, and R. R. Kaufman (eds.), Reforming the State: Fiscal and Welfare Reforms
in Post-Socialist Countries. Cambridge and N.Y.: Cambridge University Press, pp. 75–110.
Halikias, D. J. (1978). Money and Credit in a Developing Economy: The Greek Case. New York:
New York University Press.
Hall, P. (1993). ‘Policy Paradigms, Social Learning and the State’, Comparative Politics, 25,
3: 275–96.
—— (ed.) (1989). The Political Power of Economic Ideas: Keynesianism Across Nations. Prince-
ton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
—— and Taylor, R. (1996). Political Science and the Three New Institutionalisms, Max-Planck-
Institute for the Study of Societies, MPIfG Discussion Paper 96/6, Cologne.
Hallerberg, M. (2002). ‘Veto Players and the Choice of Monetary Institutions’, Inter-
national Organization, 56, 4: 775–802.
Hawke, G. (1977). Between Governments and Banks: A History of the Reserve Bank of New
Zealand. Wellington: Government Print.
Hawtrey, R. (1932). The Art of Central Banking. London: Longman.
Hay, C. (2000). ‘Globalization, Regionalization and the Persistence of National Variation:
The Contingent Convergence of Contemporary Capitalism’, Review of International
Studies, 26, 4: 509–31.
Hayo, B. and Hofmann, B. (2006). ‘Comparing Monetary Policy Reaction Functions: ECB
versus Bundesbank’, Empirical Economics, 31, 3, 645–62.
Heikensten, L. (2005). ‘Monetary Policy and the Academics’, inaugural lecture at Umeå
University, October 28. Umeå, Sweden.
—— and Vredin, A. (2002). ‘The Art of Targeting Inflation’, Penning- och valutapolitik,
Stockholm: Risksbanken, 5–34.
Heipertz, M. (2001). ‘How Strong was the Bundesbank: A Case Study in the Making of
German and European Monetary Union’, Working Document No. 172. Brussels: Centre
for European Policy Studies.
—— and Verdun, A. (2004). ‘The Dog that Would Never Bite? On the Origins of the
Stability and Growth Pact’, Journal of European Public Policy, 11, 5: 773–88.
—— —— (2005). ‘The Stability and Growth Pact – Theorizing a Case in European Inte-
gration’, Journal of Common Market Studies, 43, 5: 985–1008.
419
References
Heisenberg, D. (1999). The Mark of the Bundesbank. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Press.
Helleiner, E. (1999). ‘Denationalising Money? Economic Liberalism and the ‘National
Question’, in Currency Affairs’, in E. Gilbert and E. Helleiner (eds.), Nation-States and
Money. The Past, Present and Future of National Currencies. London and New York:
Routledge, pp. 139–58.
—— (2003). The Making of National Money. Territorial Currencies in Historical Perspective.
Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Henning, C. R. and Padoan, P. C. (2000). Transatlantic Perspectives on the Euro. Washington,
DC: Brookings/Pittsburg: ECSA.
Hibbs, D. (1977). ‘Political Parties and Macroeconomic Policy’, American Political Science
Review, 71, 4: 1467–87.
Hierlemann, D. (2008). ‘Irish Vote, Europe’s Future: Four options after the ‘‘No’’ ’, Spotlight
Europe, special edition 2008/06.
Hill, C. (2006). ‘The Directoire and the Problem of a Coherent EU Foreign Policy’, CFSP
Forum, 4, 6: 1–4.
Hirschman, A. (1970). Exit, Voice, Loyalty. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Hix, S., Hoyland, B., and Vivyan, N. (2007). ‘From Doves to Hawks: A Spatial Analysis of
Voting in the Monetary Policy Committee of the Bank of England, 1997–2007. London
School of Economics: Unpublished.
Hochreiter, E. (2000). ‘The Current Role of National Central Banks in the Eurosystem’,
Atlantic Economic Journal, 28, 3: 300–8.
Hoffmann, B. (2006). ‘Do Monetary Indicators Still Predict Euro Area Inflation?’, Deutsche
Bundesbank Discussion Paper Series 2.
Hoffmeyer, E. (1993). Pengepolitiske problemstillinger 1965–1990. Copenhagen: Danish
Central Bank.
—— (2000). ‘Decision-making for European Economic and Monetary Union’, Occasional
Paper, 62, Washington, DC: Group of Thirty.
Holmes, F. (2002). ‘An Anzac Union?’ IPS Policy Paper, Institute of Policy Studies, Victoria
University of Wellington.
Howarth, D. (2001). The French Road to European Monetary Union. Basingstoke: Palgrave.
—— (2007). ‘Running an Enlarged Euro-Zone – Reforming the European Central Bank:
Efficiency, Legitimacy and National Economic Interest’, Review of International Political
Economy, 14, 5: 820–41.
—— and Loedel, P. (2004). ‘The ECB and the Stability Pact: Policeman and Judge?’, Journal
of European Public Policy, 11, 5: 832–53.
—— —— (2005). The ECB: the New European Leviathan. Basingstoke: Palgrave, revised
second edition.
Hufton, O. (1986). ‘Fernand Braudel’, Past and Present, 112: 208–13.
Hunt, C. (2005). ‘A Fresh Look at the Merits of a Currency Union’, Reserve Bank Bulletin,
68, 4: 16–30.
IMF (1998). ‘International Capital Markets’, September, Washington, DC: IMF.
Ingves, S. (2007). ‘Regulatory Challenges of Cross-border Banking: Possible Ways
Forward’, speech at Reserve Bank of Australia, Sydney, July 23.
Ip, G. (2006). ‘Columbia Economist Is Considered for Fed Board’, Wall Street Journal,
April 10.
—— and Hilsenrath, J. (2007). ‘How Credit Got So Easy and Why its Tightening’, Wall
Street Journal, August 7.
420
References
Issing, O. (1998). ‘Crisis Prevention: IMF Surveillance, Need for New Teeth?’, Statement at
the IMF conference on the role of the IMF in the world economy, held in Frankfurt am
Main on July 2.
—— (1999). ‘The Eurosystem: Transparent and Accountable or ‘‘Willem in Euroland’’ ’,
Journal of Common Market Studies. 37, 3: 503–19.
—— (2008). Der Euro. Geburt – Erfolg – Zukunft, München: Verlag Franz Vahlen.
—— (2005a). ‘Communication, Transparency, Accountability: Monetary Policy in the
Twenty-First Century’, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, March/April, part 1, 65–84.
—— (2005b). Imperfect Knowledge and Monetary Policy. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
—— (2006). ‘The ECB’s Monetary Policy Strategy: Why Did We Choose a Two-pillar
Approach?’ Paper presented at the 4th ECB Central Banking Conference, Frankfurt,
November 10.
—— (2008). The Birth of the Euro. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
—— Gaspar, V., Angeloni, I., and Tristani, O. (2001). Monetary Policy in the Euro Area.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Iversen, T. and Pontusson, J. (2000). ‘Comparative Political Economy: A Northern Euro-
pean Perspective’, in T. Iversen, J. Pontusson, and D. Soskice (eds.), Unions, Employers,
and Central Banks. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 1–37.
Jabko, N. (2003). ‘Democracy in the Age of the Euro’, Journal of European Public Policy, 10,
5: 710–39.
Jachtenfuchs, M. and Kohler-Koch, B. (2004). ‘Governance and Institutional Develop-
ment’, in T. Diez and A. Wiener (eds.), European Integration Theory. Oxford: Oxford
University Press, pp. 97–115.
Jacobsson, B., Lægreid, P., and Pedersen, O. K. (2004). Europeanization and Transnational
States. Comparing Nordic Central Governments. London: Routledge.
Jacobsson, E. E. (1979). A Life for Sound Money. Per Jacobsson – His Biography. Oxford:
Clarendon Press.
Janning, J. (1997). ‘Dynamik in der Zwangsjacke – Flexibilität in der Europäischen Union
nach Amsterdam’, integration, 20, 4, 285–91.
Johnson, J. (2006). ‘Post-communist Central Banks: A Democratic Deficit?’, Journal of
Democracy, 17, 1: 90–103.
—— (2006). ‘Two-track Diffusion and Central Bank Embeddedness: The Politics of Euro
Adoption in Hungary and the Czech Republic’, Review of International Political Economy,
13, 3: 361–86.
—— (2008). ‘The Remains of Conditionality: The Faltering Enlargement of the Euro
Zone’, Journal of European Public Policy, 15, 6: 826–42.
Johnson, P. (1998). The Government of Money – Monetarism in Germany and the United States.
Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Jones, E. (1998). ‘The Netherlands: Top of the Class’, in E. Jones, J. Frieden, and F. Torres
(eds.), Joining Europe’s Monetary Club. The Challenges for Smaller Member States. New York:
St Martin’s Press, pp. 149–70.
Jonung, L. (2000). ‘Från guldmyntfot till inflationsmål—svensk stabiliseringspolitik under
det 20:e seklet’, Ekonomisk Debatt, 28, 1: 17–32.
Junge, K. (2006). ‘Differentiated European Integration’, in M. Cini (ed.), European Union
Politics. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 391–404.
421
References
Juppé, A. (2000). ‘Pioniergruppe als Übergang. Ein Gespräch mit Alain Juppé über das
Europa von Morgen’, Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung, 8 July, 7.
Kahn, C. and Santos, J. (2004). ‘Allocating Lending of Last Resort and Supervision in the
Euro Area’, in A. Volbert, J. Mélitz, and G. von Furstenberg (eds.), Monetary Unions and
Hard Pegs – Effects on Trade, Financial Development, and Stability. Oxford: Oxford Univer-
sity Press, pp. 347–60.
Kaltenthaler, K. (1998). Germany and the Politics of Europe’s Money. Durham, NC: Duke
University Press.
Katzenstein, P. (1987). Policy and Politics in West Germany. Philadelphia: Temple University
Press.
—— (2003). ‘Small States and Small States Revisited’, New Political Economy, 8, 1: 9–30.
Kayser, M (2005). ‘Who Surfs, Who Manipulates? The Determinants of Opportunistic
Election Timing and Electorally Motivated Economic Intervention’. American Political
Science Review, 99, 1: 17–27.
Keefer, P. and Stasavage, D. (2003). ‘The Limits of Delegation: Veto Players, Central Bank
Independence, and the Credibility of Monetary Policy’, American Political Science Review,
97, 3: 407–23.
Kenen, P. B. (1995). Economic and Monetary Union in Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge Univer-
sity Press.
Kennedy, H. (1991). The Bundesbank: Germany’s Central Bank in the International Monetary
System. London: Pinter Publishers, Chatham House Papers.
Kettl, D. (1986). Leadership at the FED. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Kindleberger, C. and Aliber, R. (2005). Manias, Panics and Crashes: A History of Financial
Crises. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
King, M. (2004). ‘The Institutions of Monetary Policy’, American Economic Review Papers
and Proceedings, 94, 2: 1–13.
Klaus, V. (2000). ‘Three Years after the Exchange Rate Crisis: Recapitulation of the Events
and Their Consequences’, Politiká Ekonomie, 48, 5: 595–604.
Knodt, M. (2005). Regieren im erweiterten europäischen Mehrebenensystem. International
Einbettung der EU in die WTO. Baden-Baden: Nomos.
Koch, H. (1983). Histoire de la Banque de France et de la monnaie sous la IVe re´publique. Paris:
Dunod.
Kohn, D. (2005). ‘Globalization, Inflation and Monetary Policy’, remarks at the James
R. Wilson Lecture Series, The College of Wooster, Wooster, Ohio, October 11.
—— (2006). ‘Monetary Policy and Asset Prices’, paper given at the ECB conference on
‘Monetary Policy: A Journey from Theory to Practice’, Frankfurt, March 16.
Kornai, J. (1996). Paying the Bill for Goulash-Communism. Hungarian Development and Macro
Stabilization in a Political-Economy Perspective. Discussion Paper 23. Budapest: Collegium
Budapest/Institute for Advanced Study.
Krehbiel, K. (1998). Pivotal Politics: A Theory of US Lawmaking. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Krenzler, H. and Senior Nello, S. (1999). ‘Implications of the Euro for Enlargement: Report
of the Working Group on the Eastern Enlargement of the European Union’, RSC Policy
Paper, 99, 3, Florence: Robert Schuman Centre.
Kydland, F. and Prescott, E. (1977). ‘Rules Rather Than Discretion: The Inconsistency of
Optimal Plans’, Journal of Political Economy, 85, 3: 473–91.
422
References
Kynaston, D. (2002). The City of London: Club No More, 1945–2000, Vol. 4 (History of the
City). London: Pimlico.
Laar, M. (2002). Little Country that Could. Centre for Research into Post-Communist
Economies. London: St. Edmundsbury Press.
Lagerspetz, M. and Vogt, H. (2004). ‘Estonia’, in S. Berglund, J. Ekman, and F. H. Aarebrot
(eds.), The Handbook of Political Change in Eastern Europe. Cheltenham, U.K.: Edward
Elgar, pp. 57–94.
Lamfalussy, A. (2003). ‘Central Banks and Financial Stability’, 2nd Pierre Werner Lecture,
Luxembourg: Banque Centrale du Luxembourg.
—— (2001). Committee of Wise Men on the Regulation of European Securities Markets (Lamfa-
lussy), Final Report (February 15th). Brussels: Commission of the European Communities.
Landes, D. (1991). ‘Does It Pay to Be Late?’, in J. Batou (ed.), Between Development and
Underdevelopment. Geneve: Publications du Centre D’Histoire Économique Internatio-
nale de L’Université de Geneve, pp. 43–66.
Le Horen, E. (2007). ‘The New Governance in Monetary Policy: A Critical Appraisal of the
FED and the ECB’, in P. Arestis, E. Hein, and E. Le Heron (eds.), Aspects of Modern
Monetary and Macroeconomic Policies. Houndmills/Basingstoke: Palgrave, pp. 146–71.
Lee, R. (2005). Politics and the Creation of a European SEC: the Optimal UK Strategy –
Constructive Inconsistency. Washington, DC: AEI Brookings Joint Centre.
Leiner-Killinger, N., Lopez Perez, V., Stieger, R., and Vitale, G. (2007). ‘Structural Reforms
in EMU and the Role of Monetary Policy’, ECB Occasional Paper, No. 66, Frankfurt:
European Central Bank.
Lidegaard, B. (2005). I Kongens navn. Henrik Kauffmann i dansk diplomati 1919–58. Køben-
havn: Samlerens Forlag.
Lindahl, R. and Naurin, D. (2005). ‘Sweden: The Twin Faces of a Euro-Outsider’, Journal of
European Integration, 27, 1: 89–110.
Lindstrom, N. and Piroska, D. (2007). ‘The Politics of Privatization and Europeanization in
Europe’s Periphery: Slovenian Banks and Breweries for Sale?’ Competition and Change,
11, 2: 117–35.
Loedel, P. (1999a). Deutsche Mark Politics: Germany in the European Monetary System. Boul-
der, CO: Lynne Rienner Press.
—— (1999b). ‘The Lasting Legacy of the Bundesbank: Fifty Years of Deutschmark Politics’,
in P. Merkl (ed.), The Federal Republic of Germany at Fifty: The End of a Century of Turmoil.
New York: New York University Press: pp. 231–42.
Lohmann, S. (1998). ‘Federalism and Central Bank Independence: The Politics of German
Monetary Policy, 1957–92’, World Politics, 50, 3: 401–46.
Lombardelli, C., Proudman, J., and Talbot, J. (2005). ‘Committees versus Individuals: An
Experimental Analysis of Monetary Policy Decision Making’, International Journal of
Central Banking, 1, 2: 181–205.
Louis, J.-V. (2002). Euro in the National Context. London: BIICL.
Lucchetti, A. (2008). ‘As Housing Boomed, Moody’s Opened Up’, Wall Street Journal,
April 11.
Ludlow, P. (1982). The Making of the European Monetary System. London: Butterworth.
Lukes, S. (2005). Power: A Radical View. 2nd edition. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Maes, I. (2002). Economic Thought and the Making of European Monetary Union. Chelten-
ham, UK: Edward Elgar.
423
References
Maes, I. (2006). ‘The Ascent of the European Commission as an Actor in the Monetary
Integration Process in the 1960s’, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 53, 2: 222–41.
—— (2007). Half a Century of European Financial Integration. From the Rome Treaty to the 21st
Century. Brussels: Mercatorfonds.
—— and Périlleux, V. (1993). ‘De Prudentiële Controle van de Kredietinstellingen’, Econ-
omisch en Sociaal Tijdschrift, 47,4: 611–34.
—— and Verdun, A. (2005). ‘Small States and the Creation of EMU: Belgium and the Nether-
lands, Pacesetters and Gatekeepers’, Journal of Common Market Studies, 43, 2: 327–48.
Magnette, P. (2000). ‘Towards ‘‘Accountable Independence’’? Parliamentary Controls of
the European Central Bank and the Rise of a New Democratic Model’, European Law
Journal, 6, 4: 326–40.
Mahadeva, L. and Sterne, G. (2000). Monetary Policy Frameworks in a Global Context.
London: Routledge.
Majone, G. (1989). Evidence, Argument and Persuasion in the Policy Process. New Haven,
Conn.: Yale University Press.
Mamou, Y. (1988). Le Tresor: Une machine de pouvoir, la Direction du Trésor. Paris: Editions la
Decouverte.
Mansbridge, J. (2003). ‘Rethinking Representation’, American Political Science Review, 97, 3:
515–28.
March, J. and Olsen, J. (2005). ‘Elaborating the ‘‘New Institutionalisms’’ ’, ARENA Working
Papers 05/11, Oslo: ARENA.
Marcussen, M. (2000). Ideas and Elites. Aalborg: Aalborg University.
—— (2002). ‘EMU: A Danish Delight and Dilemma’, in K. Dyson (ed.), European States and
the Euro – Europeanization, Variation, and Convergence. Oxford: Oxford University Press,
pp. 120–44.
—— (2005a). ‘Central Banks on the Move’, Journal of European Public Policy, 12, 5: 903–23.
—— (2005b). ‘Denmark and European Monetary Integration: Out but far from Over’,
Journal of European Integration, 27, 1: 43–63.
—— (2006a). ‘Institutional Transformation? The Scientization of Central Banking as
Case’, in T. Christensen and P. Lægreid (eds.), Autonomy and Regulation: Coping with
Agencies in the Modern State. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, pp. 81–109.
—— (2006b). ‘The Basel Committee as a Transnational Governance Network’, in
M. Marcussen and J. Torfing (eds.), Democratic Network Governance in Europe. Hampshire:
Palgrave-Macmillan, pp. 214–31.
—— (2006c). ‘The Transnational Governance Network of Central Bankers’, in M.-L. Djelic
and K. Sahlin-Andersson (eds.), Transnational Governance. Institutional Dynamics of Regu-
lation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 180–204.
—— (2007a). ‘Handling Euro-Outsiderness’, Working Paper 2007:6, Roskilde University:
Center for the Study of Democratic Network Governance.
—— (2007b). ‘Central Banking Reform Across the World: Only by Night Are All Cats
Grey’, in T. Christensen and P. Lægreid (eds.), Transcending New Public Management: the
Transformation of Public Sector Reforms. Aldershot: Ashgate, pp. 135–53.
—— (2008). ‘The Danish Central Bank – The Reluctant European’, CEP Working Paper
Series, 2008/1, Copenhagen University: Department of Political Science.
—— (2009). ‘Leading Central Banking in Europe’, in J. A. Raffel, P. Leisink, and
A. E. Middlebrooks (eds.), Public Sector Leadership: International Challenges and Perspec-
tives. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing, pp. 73–90.
424
References
Marsh, D. (1992). The Bundesbank: The Bank That Rules Europe. London: Heinemann.
Mataj, J. and Vojtı́šek, P. (1992). ‘Právnı́ a ekonomické aspekty nového zákona o SBČS
(Legal and Economic Aspects of the New Law on the SBCS)’, Finance a úverˇ- Czech Journal
of Economics and Finance, 42, 3, 109–15.
Maxfield, S. (1997). Gatekeepers of Growth: The International Political Economy of Central
Banking in Developing Countries. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Mayes, D. G. (1998). ‘Evolving Voluntary Rules for the Operation of the European Central
Bank’, Current Politics and Economics of Europe, 8, 4: 357–86.
—— (2000). ‘Independence and Co-ordination – The Eurosystem’, paper presented at the
UACES 30th Anniversary Conference and 5th UACES Research Conference, Central
European University, Budapest, 6–8 April.
—— and Virén, M. (2007). ‘The SGP and the ECB: an exercise in asymmetry’, Journal of
Financial Transformation, 19: 159–75.
Mazower, M. (1991). Greece and the Inter-War Economic Crisis. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
McDermott, G. (2007). ‘Politics, Power, and Institution Building: Bank Crises and Super-
vision in East Central Europe’, Review of International Political Economy, 14, 2: 220–50.
McNamara, K. (1998). The Currency of Ideas: Monetary Politics in the European Union. Ithaca:
Cornell University Press.
—— (2002a). ‘Rational Fictions: Central Bank Independence and the Social Logic of
Delegation’, West European Politics 25, 1: 47–76.
—— (2002b). ‘State Building, Territorialization, and the Creation of American Currency’,
in D. Andrews, C. Randall Henning, and L. Pauly (eds.), Governing the Word’s Money.
Ithaca: Cornell University Press, pp. 128–47.
—— (2006). ‘Managing the Euro. The European Central Bank’, in J. Peterson and
M. Shackleton (eds.), The Institutions of the European Union. Oxford: Oxford University
Press, pp. 169–89.
—— and Meunier, S. (2002). ‘Between National Sovereignty and International Power:
What External Voice for the Euro?’, International Affairs 78, 4: 849–68.
Meade, E. and Stasavage, D. (2008). ‘Publicity of Debate and the Incentive to Dissent’,
Economic Journal, 118, 525: 695–717.
Mencinger, J. (2004). ‘Transition to a National and a Market Economy: A Gradualist
Approach’, in M. Mrak, M. Rojec, and C. Silva-Jáuregui (eds.), Slovenia: From Yugoslavia
to the European Union. Washington, DC: The World Bank, pp. 67–82.
Mendzela, J. (2002). ‘Leadership and Management in Central Banking’, Central Banking,
13, 2: 40–6.
—— (2003). ‘Leadership and Management of Central Banks’, Central Banking, 13, 3: 59–66.
—— (2006). ‘How to Manage the 21st-Century Central Bank?’, Central Banking, 16, 4: 31–9.
Meyer, L. (1998). ‘Issues and Trends in Bank Regulatory Policy and Financial Modernization
Legislation’. Remarks at the Bank Administration Institute, Finance and Accounting
Management Conference, Washington, DC, June 9.
—— (2004). A Term at the Fed – An Insider’s View. New York: Harper Business.
Mikkelsen, R. (1993). Dansk pengehistorie 1960–1990. Copenhagen: Danmarks National
Bank.
Milesi, G. (1998). Le Roman de l’Euro. Paris: Hachette.
Mishkin, F. (2002). ‘Inflation Targeting’, in B. Snowdon and H. R. Vane (eds.), An Encyclo-
pedia of Macroeconomics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 361–65.
425
References
Mishkin, F. (2004). ‘Can Inflation Targeting Work in Emerging Market Countries?’ NBER
Working Paper, no. 10646, Cambridge, MA.
—— (2007a). Monetary Policy Strategy. Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press.
—— (2007b). ‘Globalization, Macroeconomic Performance, and Monetary Policy’. Speech
at the ‘Domestic Prices in an Integrated World Economy’ Conference, Board of Gover-
nors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington, DC, September 27.
—— and Schmidt-Hebbel, K. (2001). ‘One Decade of Inflation Targeting in the World’.
NBER Working Paper, no. 8397, Cambridge, MA.
Mohácsi Nagy, P. (2006). ‘Financial Market Governance: Evolution and Convergence’, in
K. Dyson (ed.), Enlarging the Euro Area: External Empowerment and Domestic Transform-
ation in East Central Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 237–60.
Moran, M. (1984). The Politics of Banking. London: Macmillan.
Morgan Stanley (2004). Central Bank Directory 2004. London: Central Banking Publica-
tions Ltd.
Morris, I. (2000). Congress, the President and the Federal Reserve: The Politics of American
Monetary Policy-Making. Ann Arbor, MI.: University of Michigan Press.
Morriss, P. (2002). Power: A Philosophical Analysis. Manchester: Manchester University Press.
—— (2006). ‘Steven Lukes on the Concept of Power’, Political Studies Review, 4, 2: 124–35.
Munchau, W. (2006). Financial Times, 5 June.
Neyapti, B. (2001). ‘Central Bank Independence and Economic Performance in Eastern
Europe’, Economic Systems, 25, 4: 381–99.
Nicholls, A. (1994). Freedom with Responsibility. The Social Market Economy in Germany,
1918–1963. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Nye, J. (2004). Soft Power: Means of Success in World Politics. New York: Public Affairs Press.
OECD (1995). Economic Surveys: Greece 1995. Paris: OECD.
—— (2007). ‘Economic Survey of the Euro Area, 2007’, Policy Brief, January. Paris: OECD.
Offe, C. (1991). ‘Capitalism by Democratic Design? Democratic Theory Facing the Triple
Transition in East Central Europe’, Social Research, 58, 4: 865–92.
Olsen, E. and Hoffmeyer, E. (1968). Dansk pengehistorie 1914–1960. Copenhagen: Dan-
marks Nationalbank.
Orr, A. (2006). ‘Towards a Framework for Promoting Financial Stability in New Zealand’,
Speech to the Institution of Professional Engineers New Zealand, 22 March. Wellington:
Reserve Bank of New Zealand.
Østergaard, H. (1998). At tjene og forme den nye tid. Finansministeriet 1948–1998. Copen-
hagen: Ministry of Finance.
Padoa Schioppa, T. (1999a). ‘EMU and Banking Supervision’, lecture at the London School
of Economics, Financial Markets Group, 24 February.
—— (1999b). ‘EMU and Banking Supervision’. International Finance, 2, 2: 295–308.
—— (1999c). ‘The External Representation of the Euro Area’, introductory statement at
the Sub-Committee on Monetary Affairs, European Parliament, Brussels, 17 March.
—— (2000). ‘An Institutional Glossary of the Eurosystem’, ZEI Policy Paper, B 16.
—— (2005). ‘Es ist eine gute Sache, die Bankenaufsicht den Zentralbanken zu ueberant-
worten’, interview in Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung, 25 May.
—— (2007). ‘Europe Needs a Single Financial Rulebook’, Financial Times, 10th December.
Pagoulatos, G. (1999). ‘European Banking: Five Modes of Governance’, West European
Politics, 22, 1: 68–94.
426
References
—— (2003a). Greece’s New Political Economy: State, Finance and Growth from Postwar to
EMU. London and New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
—— (2003b). ‘Financial Interventionism and Liberalization in Southern Europe: State,
Bankers, and the Politics of Disinflation’, Journal of Public Policy, 23, 2: 171–99.
Papademos, L. (2005). ‘Banking Supervision and Financial Stability in Europe’. Speech by the
Lucas Papademos, Vice-President of the ECB, delivered at the Conference: ‘Supervision
of International Banks: Is a Bank Crisis still Possible in Europe?’ organized by the
European Banking Federation, Brussels, 28 October 2005, http://www.ecb.eu/press/
key/date/2005/html/sp051028_2.en.html
—— (2007). ‘The Financial Market Turmoil, the European Economy, and the Role of the
European Central Bank’, speech by the Vice President of the ECB at an event organized
by The European Institute, New York, 27 September.
Parker, G. and Strauss, D. (2008). ‘Interview Transcript: Alistair Darling, January 3’, www.
ft.com/cms/s/0/ec63ba08-ba27–11dc-abcb-0000779fd2ac.html
—— Larsen, P., Giles, C., and Saigol, L. (2007). ‘Darling Caught off Guard by First Big Test’,
Financial Times, 18 September.
Passacantando, F. (1996). ‘Building an Institutional Framework for Monetary Stability:
The Case of Italy (1979–92)’, BNL Quarterly Review, 196: 3–37.
Patat, J.-P. (2003). L’ere des banques centrals. Paris: Harmattan.
—— and Lutfalla, M. (1986). Histoire monetaire de la France au XXe siècle. Paris: Economica.
Pauly, L. (1997). Who Elected the Bankers? Surveillance and Control in the World Economy.
Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Pedersen, E. (2006). ‘Danmarks Nationalbank’s Operating Costs and Number of Employees in
International Comparison’, Working Papers no. 35. Copenhagen: Danmarks Nationalbank.
Pepelasis, M. I. (1998). ‘Transplanting Institutions: The Case of the Greek Central Bank’,
Greek Economic Review, 19, 1: 33–64.
Peters, B. (2000). ‘Institutional Theory: Problems and Prospects’, Political Science Series 69,
Institute for Advanced Studies, Vienna.
Pisani-Ferry, J., Aghion, P., Belka, M., von Hagen, J., Heikensten, L., Sapir, A., and Ahearne,
A. (2008). Coming of Age: Report on the Euro Area. Blueprint No. 4, Brussels: Bruegel.
Pitkin, H. (1967). The Concept of Representation, Berkeley: University of California Press.
Plenderleith, I. (1997). ‘London as a Financial Centre after EMU’, speech at a conference
organized by the International Center for Monetary and Banking Studies on ‘The
International Monetary System after the Decision on EMU’, Geneva, 7 November.
Polányi, K. (1957). The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time.
Boston: Beacon Press.
Polillo, S. and Guillén, M. (2005). ‘Globalization Pressures and the State: The Worldwide
Spread of Central Bank Independence’, American Journal of Sociology, 110, 6: 1764–802.
Pollitt, C. and Bouckaert, G. (2000). Public Management Reform. A Comparative Analysis.
Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Posen, A. (1995). ‘Declarations Are Not Enough: Financial Sector Sources of Central Bank
Independence’, NBER Macroeconomics Annual. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Pospı́šil, J. (1996). ‘Inflation and Central bank Independence – Do We and Can We Have
Experience in the Czech Republic?’ in A Collection of Lectures from the Conference in
Honour of the 70th Anniversary of Central Banking in the Czech Republic. Prague: Czech
National Bank.
427
References
Prate, A. (1987). La France et sa monnaie: Essai sur les rélations entre la Banque de France et les
gouvernements. Paris: Julliard.
Puetter, U. (2006). The Eurogroup. How a Secretive Circle of Finance Ministers Shape European
Economic Governance. Manchester: Manchester University Press.
Quaden, G. (2007). Foreword. Annual Report 2006 – Part II: Activities, Governance and Annual
Accounts. Brussels: National Bank of Belgium.
Quaglia, L. (2004). ‘Italy’s Policy towards European Monetary Integration: Bringing Ideas
Back In?’, Journal of European Public Policy, 11, 6: 1096–111.
—— (2005a). ‘An Integrative Approach to the Politics of Central Bank Independence:
Lessons from Britain, Germany and Italy’, West European Politics, 28, 3: 549–68.
—— (2005b). ‘Civil Servants, Economic Policies and Economic Ideas: Lessons from Italy’,
Governance, 18, 4: 545–66.
—— (2007a). ‘The Politics of Financial Services Regulation and Supervision Reform in the
European Union’, European Journal of Political Research, 46, 2: 269–90.
—— (2007b). ‘Committee Governance in the Financial Sector in the European Union’.
Brighton: University of Sussex European Institute, Working Paper No. 96.
—— (2008a). Central Banking Governance in the European Union: A Comparative Analysis.
London: Routledge.
—— (2008b). ‘The Reform of the Supervisory Authorities: the Case of the Bank of Italy’, in
M. Donovan and P. Onofri (eds.), Italian Politics. Oxford: Berghahn Books, pp. 141–156.
Reich, R. (1997). Locked in the Cabinet. New York: Knopf.
Reinhart, C. and Rogoff, K. (2008). ‘This Time is Different: A Panoramic View of Eight
Centuries of Financial Crises’, Working Paper, 13882, March.
Remsperger, H. (2002). ‘The Role of the Deutsche Bundesbank in the European System of
Central Banks’, Journal of Asian Economics, 13, 2: 137–56.
—— (2004). ‘Research Matters’, Auszuege aus Presseartikeln, 51, 1: 7–8. Frankfurt am Main:
Deutsche Bundesbank.
Rentzow, S. (2002). ‘The Power of Ideas: How Bundesbank Ideas Have Influenced the
Reconstruction of the National Bank of Poland’, German Politics, 11, 1: 173–90.
Reserve Bank of Australia (2007). Reserve Bank Board—New Arragements for Communication,
Media Release No: 2007-252, 5 December 2007, Sydney: Reserve Bank of Australia.
Reserve Bank of New Zealand (2007). Opinion Article by Reserve Bank Deputy Governor Grant
Spencer. Wellington: Reserve Bank of New Zealand, 27 June.
Rhodes, M. and Keune, M. (2006). ‘EMU and Welfare State Adjustment in Central and
Eastern Europe’, in K. Dyson (ed.), Enlarging the Euro Area: External Empowerment and
Domestic Transformation in East Central Europe. Oxford, Oxford University Press,
pp. 279–300.
Roberts, R. and Kynaston, D. (eds.) (1995). The Bank of England: Money, Power and Influence,
1694–1994. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Rogoff, K. (1985). ‘The Optimal Degree of Commitment to an Intermediate Monetary
Target’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 4: 1169–90.
Rood, J. Q. Th. (1990). ‘The Position of the Netherlands: A Lesson in Monetary Union’, in
H. Sherman, R. Brown. P. Jacquet, and D. Julins (eds.), Monetary Implications of the 1992
Process. London: Pinter/Royal Institute of International Affairs, pp. 124–47.
Rose, A. (2007). ‘A Stable International Monetary System Emerges: Inflation Targeting is
Bretton Woods, Reversed’, Journal of International Money and Finance, 26, 5: 663–81.
428
References
429
References
430
References
—— (2001). De Euro. Politieke Achtergronden van de Wording van een Munt. Amsterdam:
Mets and Schilt.
Taylor, C. (2000). ‘The Role and Status of the European Central Bank: Some Proposals for
Accountability and Cooperation’, in C. Crouch (ed.), After the Euro: Shaping Institutions
for Governance in the Wake of European Monetary Union. Oxford: Oxford University Press,
pp. 179–202.
Tekin, F. and Wessels, W. (2008). ‘Flexibility within the Lisbon Treaty: Trade Mark of
Empty Promises?’, EIPASCOPE 2008/1, 25–31.
The Economist (1997). ‘Mr Brown and EMU’, November 1: 31.
Tilly, C. (1975). The Formation of National States in Western Europe. Princeton: Princeton
University Press.
Tinbergen, J. (1952). On the Theory of Economic Policy. Amsterdam: North Holland
Publishing Co.
Toniolo, G. (2005). Central Bank Cooperation at the Bank for International Settlements, 1930–
1973. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Townend, J. (1997). ‘The UK and the Euro’, the Bank of Wales lecture, Pamphlet, Cardiff
Business School, 29 October.
Treasury Committee (2008). House of Commons Treasury Committee: The Run on the Rock.
Fifth Report of Session 2007–8: volume 1: Report together with formal minutes. HC 56–1.
Trichet, J.-C. (2007a). Letter to Manuel Lobo Antunes, President of the Council of the European
Union on the Clarification of the Institutional Status of the ECB, 2 August. Frankfurt:
European Central Bank.
—— (2007b). ‘The role of Research in Central Banks and at the ECB’, Award of the
Germán Bernácer Prize, Madrid, 21 May.
—— (2008). ‘Introductory Statement with Q and A’, Transcript of Press Conference, 8 Feb-
ruary. Frankfurt: European Central Bank.
Tucker, P. (2006). ‘Reflections on Operating Inflation Targeting’, Bank of England Quarterly
Bulletin, Summer: 212–24.
Tůma, Z. (2004). ‘Speech at CMC Graduation School of Business’, December 4.
Valach, V. (2004). ‘44 Years in Banking, Part 3’ BIATEC, 12, 12: 19–22.
Valance, G. (1996). La Legende du franc. Paris: Flammarion.
Van Apeldoorn, B. (2002). Transnational Capitalism and the Struggle over European Integra-
tion. London: Routledge.
Vandeputte, R., Abraham, J.-P., and Lempereur, CL. (1981). Les institutions financières
belges, Tome I – Le secteur public. Namur: Éditions Érasme.
Vanhuysse, P. (2006). Divide and Pacify: The Political Economy of the Welfare State in Hungary
and Poland, 1989–1996. Budapest: Central European University Press.
Vanthoor, W. (2004). De Nederlandsche Bank 1814–1998. Van Amsterdamse Kredietinstelling
naar Europese Stelselbank. Amsterdam: Boom.
—— (2005). The King’s Eldest Daughter. A History of the Nederlandsche Bank 1814–1998.
Amsterdam: Boom.
Verdun, A. (1990). ‘Naar een Economische en Monetaire Unie (1970–1990): een analyse
van de politieke beleidsruimte in Nederland’, Mimeo, University of Amsterdam.
—— (1996). ‘An ‘‘Asymmetrical’’ Economic and Monetary Union in the EU: Perceptions
of Monetary Authorities and Social Partners’, Journal of European Integration, 20, 1:
59–81.
431
References
Verdun, A. (1999a). ‘The Logic of Giving up National Currencies: Lessons from Europe’s
Monetary Union’, in E. Gilbert and E. Helleiner (eds.), Nation-States and Currencies.
London: Routledge, pp. 199–214.
—— (1999b). ‘The Role of the Delors Committee in Creating EMU: An Epistemic Com-
munity?’ Journal of European Public Policy, 6, 2: 308–28.
—— (2000). European Responses to Globalization and Financial Market Integration: Perceptions
of Economic and Monetary Union in Britain, France and Germany. Basingstoke: Macmillan/
New York: St. Martin’s Press.
—— (2002). ‘The Netherlands and EMU: A Small Open Economy in Search of Prosperity’,
in K. Dyson (ed.), European States and the Euro. Europeanization, Variation, and Conver-
gence. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 238–54.
—— (2008). ‘The Netherlands and EMU: A Turning Point in Dutch-EU Relations?’, in
K. Dyson (ed.), The Euro at Ten. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 222–42.
Véron, N. (2007). Is Europe Ready for a New Banking Crisis? Brussels: Breugel.
Vifell, Å. (2006). Enklaver i staten. Internationalisering, demokrati och den svenska statsför-
valtningen. Stockholm Studies in Politics 113, Stockholm University: Department of
Political Science.
Visser, J. (2005). Patterns and Variations in European Industrial Relations. Report Prepared for
the European Commission.
Voridis, H., Angelopoulou, E., and Skotida, I. (2003). ‘Monetary Policy in Greece 1990–
2000 through the Publications of the Bank of Greece’, Economic Bulletin, Bank of Greece,
No. 20, January.
Weber, A. (2005a). ‘Bundesbank erfuellt vielseitige Funktionen’, Boersen-Zeitung, 11 June.
—— (2005b). ‘Wirtschaftliche Perspektiven in Deutschland’, Auszuege aus Presseartikeln,
Deutsche Bundesbank, 8 December.
—— (2006a). ‘Die Aufgaben und Geschaeftsfelder der Deutschen Bundesbank, Auszuege
aus Presseartikeln, Deutsche Bundesbank, 47, 8 November: 3–5.
—— (2006b). ‘The Role of Interest Rates in Theory and Practice’, Auszuege aus Pressearti-
keln, 12, Deutsche Bundesbank, 16 March: 7–13.
—— (2007). ‘Wir muessen uns keine neuen Aufgaben suchen’, Auszuege aus Presseartikeln,
Deutsche Bundesbank, 8 August.
—— (2008a). ‘The Eurosystem and its Prospects – History in the Making’, Auszuege aus
Presseartikeln, 23, Deutsche Bundesbank, 4 June.
—— (2008b). ‘Financial Markets and Monetary Policy’, Auszuege aus Presseartikeln,
Deutsche Bundesbank, 1 October: 3–6.
Wellink, A. H. E. M. (2008). ‘Wim Duisenberg’s Legacy as President of De Nederlandsche
Bank’. 28 February, Universiteit van Amsterdam.
Werner, P. (1991). Itinéraires Luxembourgeois et Européens. Paris: Éditions Saint-Paul.
White, L. (2005). ‘The Federal Reserve System’s Influence on Research in Monetary
Economics’, Economic Journal Watch, 2, 2: 325–54.
Wood, D. (2005). Governing Global Banking. Aldershot: Ashgate.
Woodford, M. (2003). Interest and Prices. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
—— (2005). ‘Central Bank Communication and Policy Effectiveness’. Paper prepared for
the conference on ‘Inflation Targeting: Implementation, Communication and Effect-
iveness’. Sveriges Riskbank, Stockholm, 10–12 June.
—— (2007). ‘The Case for Forecast Targeting as a Monetary Policy Strategy’, Journal of
Economic Perspectives, 21, 4: 3–24.
432
References
Woods, N. (2002). ‘Global Governance and the Role of Institutions’, in D. Held and
A. McGrew (eds.), Governing Globalization. Oxford: Polity Press, pp. 25–45.
Woodward, B. (1997). Maestro: Greenspan’s Fed and the American Boom. New York: Touch-
stone.
—— (2001). Maestro: Alan Greenspan and the American Economy. New York: Simon and
Schuster.
Woolley, J. (1984). Monetary Politics: The Federal Reserve and the Politics of Monetary Policy.
New York: Cambridge University Press.
—— (1985). ‘Central Banks and Inflation’, in L. N. Lindberg and C. S. Maier (eds.), The
Politics of Inflation and Economic Stagnation. Washington, DC: Brookings, pp. 318–51.
—— (1998). ‘Exorcising Inflation-Mindedness: Changing the Politics of Macroeconomic
Policy in the 1970s’, Journal of Policy History, 10, 1: 130–52.
—— (2007). ‘Institutional Structure and the Politics of Monetary Policy since 1979’.
Prepared for delivery at the 2007 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science
Association, August 30–September 2.
World Bank (1997a). Implementation Completion Report, Poland: Enterprise and Financial
Sector Adjustment Loan, Report No. 16743. Washington, DC: World Bank.
World Bank (1997b). Poland Country Assistance Review, Volume I, Report No. 16495.
Washington, DC: World Bank.
Wrong, D. H. (1970). Max Weber. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice Hall, Inc.
Wyplosz, C. (2001). ‘The Fed and the ECB’, Briefing Notes to the Committee for Economic and
Monetary Affairs of the European Parliament, May 28.
Zeitler, F.-C. (2007). ‘Wir stolzieren nicht wie Dagobert Duck’, Auszuege aus Presseartikeln,
Deutsche Bundesbank, 8 August.
Zubek, R. (2006). ‘Poland: Unbalanced Domestic Leadership in Negotiating Fit’, in
K. Dyson (ed.), Enlarging the Euro Area: External Empowerment and Domestic Transform-
ation in East Central Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 197–214.
Zysman, J. (1983). Governments, Markets and Growth. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
433
This page intentionally left blank
Index
435
Index
436
Index
437
Index
438
Index
439
Index
440
Index
441
Index
442
Index
443
Index
444
Index
Financial Stability Forum 37, 292 Holland Financial Centre (HFC) 108
fiscal policy: Horn, Gyula 216
and Eurosystem 64 Hungary, see National Bank of Hungary
impact on insiders/outsiders 64–5
and monetary policy 357, 371 inflation:
Flemming, John 244 and management of 34
France: and persistence of differences in 12
as core insider 55 and threat of 38–9
and opposition to bank independence 112, inflation targeting:
113 and Bank of England 242–3, 364
and politicization of monetary policy 112, and Bank of Greece 173
114 and central banking 382–4
and prudential supervision 119–21, 128–9 and criticism of 367, 371
see also Bank of France and European Central Bank 363, 364
Freddie Mac 316, 330 n12 and features of 360–1
Freeman, John 405 and Federal Reserve System 308–9, 322–5,
Friedman, Benjamin 383 329, 363, 365
Friedman, Milton 381 debate over 398–400
and form of target 363–4, 371
G7/G8 group of countries 37 and International Monetary Fund 383
George, Eddie 243, 244, 245, 251, 363 and performance of 369–70
Gérard, Jean-Pierre 115 and Reserve Bank of Australia 288, 296,
Germany: 300, 301
as core insider 55 and Reserve Bank of New Zealand 14, 297,
and prudential supervision 78 301, 360, 383, 399
and soft power 2 as reverse of Bretton Woods 361
see also Bundesbank and Riksbank 276, 364, 384
Gjedrem, Svein 382 and rise of 360
global financial markets, and central banks 10 and scepticism over 383
globalization: and scientization of central banking 382–4
and Banca d’Italia 198 and voluntary adoption of 361
and central banks 30–4 instrumental rationality 380
and Federal Reserve System 325 interest rates:
Godeaux, Jean 92 and European Central Bank 87
Goldman Sachs 317 and national loss of control over 39
Gonzalez, Henry 319 see also monetary policy
Goodfriend, Marvin 391 international financial system, and Eurosystem
Goodhart’s Law 358 representation 67–8
Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act (USA, 1999) 315 European Central Bank 79–80
Greece, see Bank of Greece International Monetary Fund (IMF) 17, 37,
Greenspan, Alan 16, 30, 314–15, 316, 319, 224
324, 329, 355, 363, 377, 379, 388, and European Central Bank’s role 79–80
397–8, 399 and inflation targeting 383
Greider, William 397 Issing, Otmar 141, 143
Grimes, Arthur 305 n6 and European Central Bank:
Gronkiewicz-Waltz, Hanna 226, 227, 232 monetary policy 75
Gros, Daniel 85 research capacity 84
Guillen, Pierre 115 scepticism over 1
Gyurcsány, Ferenc 215 Italy, as core insider 55
see also Banca d’Italia
Hammarskjöld, Dag 275 Ittner, Andreas 344
Hampl, Mojmir 235
Hannoun, Hervé 117 Jacobsson, Per 274–5
Hansson, Ardo 210 Járai, Zsigmond 216
Havel, Václav 229, 230, 234 Joint Vienna Institute 224
Heikensten, Lars 382 Jouyer, Jean-Pierre 117
Hoffmeyer, Erik 268 Juncker, Jean-Claude 403
445
Index
446
Index
447
Index
448
Index
449
Index
scientization of central banking (cont.) Tosovsky, Josef 209, 228, 229, 230, 234
and relationship between science producers Townend, John 245, 251, 252, 253–4
and consumers 390 Trans-European Automated Real-time Gross
and research bias 386 settlement Express Transfer (TARGET)
and role of the state 389 System 43, 65
and transnationalization of governance 385 and Banca d’Italia 196
and transparency 381–2 and Bundesbank 155
Séguin, Phillipe 115 and central banks 78
Sette, Gilbert 127 transparency 25
Simeonov, Rumen 344 and balance of power consideration 391
Simitis, Costas 172 and Banca d’Italia 195
Simor, András 218 and Bank of France 114
Single European Payment Area (SEPA) 65 and central banks 381–2
and Bundesbank 154, 155 and consensus on 391
Skrzypek, Sławomir 233 as contested concept 393
Slovenia, see Bank of Slovenia and Danish Central Bank 271–2
Smets, Jan 95 and De Nederlandsche Bank 105, 108
socialization, and central banker and definition of 392
preferences 24, 32–3 difficulties with 393–4
Société Général 119–20 and economic rationale for 392
sovereignty: and European Central Bank 76, 83, 400–1
and central banks 27 absence of policy debate 404–5
and European integration 41 development of 402
Spain, as core insider 55 impact of bank’s mandate 403–4
Špidla, Vladimı́r 235 role of central bankers 404
Stability and Growth Pact 40 self-interested motivations 402–3
and Bundesbank 155, 157 and Federal Reserve System 318–19, 395–6
and European Central Bank 84 Congressional pressure 398, 400
and fiscal policy 64 development of 396–7
Stark, Jürgen 135, 137, 143, 145, 147, 156, 157, inflation targeting debate 398–400
303 internal pressure for 398
state, the: and monetary policy 364, 371–2
and central banks 25–8, 49 and political rationale for 393
and European integration 41–2 and prudential supervision 405
state building, and central banks 26–7 and Reserve Bank of Australia 297, 301
state capacity, and central banks 22–3 and Reserve Bank of New Zealand 301
Steinbrück, Peer 134, 152, 159 and Riksbank 276–7
strong states, and central banks 23 and sources of variations in:
Strycker, Cecil de 92 executive policy leadership 395
subprime mortgages 316–17, 330 n13, 347 legislative oversight power 395
Surányi, György 216 solidity of central bank independence
Svensson, Lars 298, 361, 372, 380–1 394–5
Sweden: and techniques enhancing 392
and euro entry: Trichet, Jean-Claude 82–3, 231, 302–3, 350, 355
elite support for 263 and background of 117
rejected in referendum 263 and criticism of government policy 117–18
as euro outsider 41 and reform of European Central Bank 85
and European Union: trust, and financial system 8–9
diplomatic activity within 263–4 Tůma, Zdenek 230, 234, 236
relationship with 263
and innovative economy 282 Ukraine 223
and New Public Management 14, 42, 44 Unipol 194
see also Riksbank United Kingdom:
and euro entry, five economic tests for
Tabaksblat, Morris 104 247–50
Tietmeyer, Hans 133, 138, 141, 143, 144 as euro outsider 41
Topolanek, Miroslav 235 and financial crisis (2007–8) 348–50, 352
450
Index
and prudential supervision 78 Weber, Axel 44, 133, 144, 146–7, 150,
see also Bank of England; London, City of 152, 159
United States, and financial and monetary Weber, Max 374, 389
ascendancy 29–30 Wellink, Nout 106, 108
see also Federal Reserve System Welteke, Ernst 133, 144, 145–6, 148
United States Agency for International Werner, Pierre 92
Development (USAID) 224, 226 Werner Committee 138
United States Supreme Court 396–7 Woodward, Bob 397
World Bank 224
Valach, Vladimir 228–9 and Enterprise and Financial Sector
Verplaetse, Alfons 99 Adjustment Loan 226
Vesala, Jukka 344 and Financial Institutions Development
Vocke, Wilhelm 140 Loan 226
Volcker, Paul 30, 309, 382, 383, 396, 397, 399
Yellen, Janet 400
Waigel, Theo 138, 139
Walker, David 242 Zeitler, Franz-Christoph 147, 157–8
weak states, and central banks 23 Zeman, Miloŝ 229
451