Public Economics - All Lecture Note PDF
Public Economics - All Lecture Note PDF
Public Economics - All Lecture Note PDF
Part 1: Introduction
Harvard University
Fall 2012
1 Practical Relevance
2 Academic Interest
3 Methodology
Obama: Romney’s proposal will worsen health outcomes and raise costs
Public economics is typically the end point for many other sub…elds
Theory often makes weak predictions: optimal tax rate between 0 and
100%
When do weak instrument problems arise and how can they be …xed?
β=0.5 (0.12)
Earnings ($1000)
5 0 10
0 5 10 15 20
Years of Schooling
β=0.5 (0.12)
Earnings ($1000)
5 0 10
0 5 10 15 20
Years of Schooling
β=0.5 (0.12)
Earnings ($1000)
5 0 10
0 5 10 15 20
Years of Schooling
β=0.5 (0.12)
Earnings ($1000)
5 0 10
0 5 10 15 20
Years of Schooling
80
60
40
20
80
60
40
20
Employer ID
College attendance
Geographical location
$21,200
$21,000
Earnings at Age 28
$20,800
1 SD TVA = $182
(73)
$20,600
$20,400
3 Very large sample sizes: 2,000 times the size of the CPS
4k
This income level maximizes tax refund
EITC Credit Amount ($1000)
3k
2k
1k
0k
Family Earnings
5%
4%
Percent of Tax Filers
3%
2%
1%
0%
4.1 – 42.7%
2.8 – 4.1%
2.1 – 2.8%
1.8 – 2.1%
1.5 – 1.8%
1.2 – 1.5%
1.1 – 1.2%
0.9 – 1.1%
0.7 – 0.9%
0 – 0.7%
4.1 – 42.7%
2.8 – 4.1%
2.1 – 2.8%
1.8 – 2.1%
1.5 – 1.8%
1.2 – 1.5%
1.1 – 1.2%
0.9 – 1.1%
0.7 – 0.9%
0 – 0.7%
4.1 – 42.7%
2.8 – 4.1%
2.1 – 2.8%
1.8 – 2.1%
1.5 – 1.8%
1.2 – 1.5%
1.1 – 1.2%
0.9 – 1.1%
0.7 – 0.9%
0 – 0.7%
4.1 – 42.7%
2.8 – 4.1%
2.1 – 2.8%
1.8 – 2.1%
1.5 – 1.8%
1.2 – 1.5%
1.1 – 1.2%
0.9 – 1.1%
0.7 – 0.9%
0 – 0.7%
4.1 – 42.7%
2.8 – 4.1%
2.1 – 2.8%
1.8 – 2.1%
1.5 – 1.8%
1.2 – 1.5%
1.1 – 1.2%
0.9 – 1.1%
0.7 – 0.9%
0 – 0.7%
3.5%
3.0%
2.5%
2.0%
1.5%
R2 = 0.6
1.0%
-2 0 2 4 6
log (Number of EITC Filers Per Square Mile)
50
Revenue and spending (% of GDP)
40
30
20
10
0
Revenue Expenditure
Source: Office of Management and Budget, Historical Tables, FY 2011
60
Sweden
50
Percent of GDP
Canada
40
OECD Avg.
30
United States
20
Other
Other 4.2% Excise
4.2%
2.7%
Excise
12.6%
Income Income
44% Payroll 45.4% Payroll
15.9% 37.5%
Corporate
23.2% Corporate
12.1%
1960 2008
Source: Office of Management and Budget, historical tables, government receipts by source
Income Tax
5.9%
Federal Grants
9.4%
Property Income Tax
Tax 15.7% 14.3%
Property
Tax Federal
Other Grants
38.2% Sales Tax
17.7% 19.1%
17.9%
Sales Tax
Other
28.8%
33%
1960 2007
Source: U.S. Census Bureau, 2007 Summary of State & Local Government
Other
Other 11.2%
Social 12.4%
Social
Security Security
13.5% 19.5% Health
Health, 2.9% 23.1%
UI and Net Interest Net
Disability 8.3%
Interest
8.9% 12.3%
UI and Disability, 6.3%
1960 2001
Source: Office of Management and Budget, historical tables, government outlays by function
1 How can govt. improve e¢ ciency when private market is ine¢ cient?
Amy’
s
Consumption
Bob’
s Consumption
Amy’
s
Consumption
Bob’
s Consumption
Amy’
s
Consumption
Bob’
s Consumption
1 No externalities
2 Perfect information
3 Perfect competition
When some agents have more information than others, markets fail
When markets are not competitive, there is role for govt. regulation
Why does govt. know better what’s desirable for you (e.g. wearing a
seatbelt, not smoking, saving more)
Even when the private market outcome is e¢ cient, may not have
good distributional properties
Amy’
s
Consumption
Bob’
s Consumption
2 Optimal Taxation
4 Corporate Taxation
5 Social Insurance
Harvard University
Fall 2012
6 Capitalization
7 Mandated Bene…ts
Tax incidence is the study of the e¤ects of tax policies on prices and
the distribution of utilities
If capital taxes ! less savings and capital ‡ight, then capital stock
may decline, driving return to capital up and wages down
Some argue that capital taxes are paid by workers and therefore
increase income inequality (Hassett and Mathur 2009)
Public Economics Lectures () Part 2: Tax Incidence 5 / 140
Overview
Only one relative price ! partial and general equilibrium are same
∂D q ∂ log D
Let εD = ∂q D (q ) = ∂ log q denote the price elasticity of demand
Price-taking …rms
c 0 (S ) > 0 and c 00 (S ) 0
∂S p
Let εS = ∂p S (p ) denote the price elasticity of supply
Equilibrium condition
Q = S (p ) = D (p + t )
de…nes an equation p (t )
dp
Goal: characterize dt , the e¤ect of a tax increase on price
Price
C
$27.0
Consumer
Burden = $4.50 A
$22.5
Supplier
Burden = $3.00 D
$19.5
$15.0 B
$7.50
D+t D
Price
S+t
$7.50 S
B
$30.0
C
$27.0
Consumer
Burden = $4.50 A
$22.5
Supplier
Burden = $3.00 D
$19.5
Price D S+t
S
$27.0
Consumer
burden
$22.5
$7.50
1500 Quantity
Price S+t
S
$7.50
$22.5 D
Supplier
burden
$15.0
1500 Quantity
D (p + t ) = S (p )
to obtain:
dp ∂D 1
=
dt ∂p ( ∂S
∂p
∂D
∂p )
dp εD
) =
dt εS εD
Incidence on consumers:
dq dp εS
= 1+ =
dt dt εS εD
1 –excess supply of E
P1 1 created by imposition of tax
dp = E/Ý /S
/p
? /D
/p
Þ 2 2 –re-equilibriation of market
P2 through producer price cut
/D /S /D
ö dp/dt = /p
/Ý /p
? /p
Þ
D1
D2
Q
/D
E = dt × /p
Public Economics Lectures () Part 2: Tax Incidence 18 / 140
Tax Incidence with Salience E¤ects
Chetty, Looney, and Kroft (2009) test this assumption and generalize
theory to allow for salience e¤ects
Tax-inclusive price of x is q = (1 + τ )p
∂ log x ∂ log x εx ,1 +τ
θ= / =
∂ log(1 + τ ) ∂ log p εx ,p
Public Economics Lectures () Part 2: Tax Incidence 21 / 140
Chetty et al.: Two Empirical Strategies
Two strategies to estimate θ:
Di¢ cult to rule out all mechanisms, but helpful to present evidence
that mechanism of interest is very powerful
Mean Median SD
Original Price Tags:
Correct tax-inclusive price w/in $0.25 0.18 0.00 0.39
Quasi-experimental di¤erence-in-di¤erences
Treatment group:
Control groups:
CONTROL STORES
Period Control Categories Treated Categories Difference
CONTROL STORES
Period Control Categories Treated Categories Difference
But may not hold in settings where policy changes are endogenous
(p + t )x (p, t, Z ) + y (p, t, Z ) = Z
D (p, t, Z ) = S (p )
DÝp|t S Þ S ( p)
1 –excess supply of E
p0 1
created by imposition of tax
/S /D
dp = E/Ý /p
? /p
Þ 2
p1 2 –re-equilibriation of market
/D /S /D
ö dp/dt = S
/t S
/Ý /p
? /p
Þ through pre-tax price cut
S,D
E = tS /D//t S
dp ∂D/∂t εD
= = θ
dt ∂S /∂p ∂D/∂p εS εD
Intuition: Producers need to cut pretax price less when consumers are
less responsive to tax
Then formulate a feasible design and analyze its ‡aws relative to ideal
design
Why develop an explicit design rather than simply use all available
variation in tax rates?
yi = α + βTi + εi
Ti = αT + βT Xi + η i
Must be some reason that one person got treated and another did not
even if they are perfectly matched on observables (e.g., twins)
But that same unobserved factor could also a¤ect outcome: no way to
know if cov (η i , εi ) = 0
Ex: a reform that a¤ects people above age 65 but not below
Total revenue of about $35 billion per year, similar to estate taxation
Since 1975, more than 200 state tax changes ! natural experiments
to investigate tax incidence
D = [PA1 PA0 ]
DD = [PA1 PA0 ] [ PB 1 PB 0 ]
Useful to plot long time series of outcomes for treatment and control
Pattern should be parallel lines, with sharp change just after reform
ERS have data for 50 states, 30 years, and many tax changes
Ex: states with higher taxes may have more anti-tobacco campaigns
Public Economics Lectures () Part 2: Tax Incidence 54 / 140
Fixed E¤ects
Note: common changes that apply to all groups (e.g. fed tax change)
captured by time dummy; not a source of variation that identi…es β
Regress price on state+year …xed e¤ects, covariates, and tax rate (in
cents)
P ∆Q
εD = = β̂/P
Q ∆T
with P (price) and Q (quantity) are sample means
Public Economics Lectures () Part 2: Tax Incidence 61 / 140
IV Estimation of Price Elasticities
How to estimate price elasticity of demand when tax and prices do
not move together 1-1?
DD before and after one year captures short term response: e¤ect of
current price Pjt on current consumption Qjt
Finds cigarette, gasoline and alcohol taxation are less regressive (in
statutory terms) from a lifetime perspective
High corr. between income and cons share in cross-section; weaker
corr. with permanent income.
Question: How does food stamps subsidy a¤ect grocery store pricing?
Food stamps typically arrive at the same time for a large group of
people, e.g. …rst of the month
Data from other states where food stamps are staggered across
month used as a control
Ex: inelastic demand for low-skilled labor and elastic supply ! wage
rate adjusts 1-1 with EITC
1 Employers
2 EITC-eligible workers
3 EITC-ineligible workers
Example: 100 short, 100 tall pre-reform and 200 short, 100 tall
post-reform
Then put 2/3 weight on tall and 1/3 on short when calculating wage
distribution after reform
To deal with this, repeats same analysis for 1989-1992 (no EITC
expansion) and takes di¤erences
Wage elasticity estimates: 0.7 for labor supply, 0.3 for labor demand
3 Short run vs. long run e¤ects; important due to evidence of nominal
wage rigidities.
Typical goal: trace out full incidence of taxes back to original owners
of factors
2 Dynamic
Output e¤ect reinforces subst e¤ect: K bears the burden of the tax
Subst. and output e¤ects have opposite signs; labor may bear some or
all the tax
Public Economics Lectures () Part 2: Tax Incidence 95 / 140
Harberger Model: Main E¤ects
Capital bears more than 100% of the burden if output e¤ect su¢ ciently
strong
With very elastic demand (two goods are highly substitutable), demand
for labor rises sharply and demand for capital falls sharply
Capital loses more than direct tax e¤ect and labor suppliers gain
Ex. Consider tax on capital in bike sector: demand for bikes falls,
demand for cars rises
Bottom line: taxed factor may bear less than 0 or more than 100% of
tax.
Public Economics Lectures () Part 2: Tax Incidence 97 / 140
Harberger Two Sector Model
r = F2K = (1 τ )F1K
Two strategies:
Need models with uncertainty, risk aversion to deal with other assets
Motivates regression:
In closed economy, β = 1
Ex. Europe: tax competition has led to lower capital tax rates
Could explain why state capital taxes are relatively low in the U.S.
Static analysis above assumes that all prices and quantities adjust
immediately
Examine pattern of asset prices or returns over time, look for break at
time of announcement of policy change
Problem: clean shocks are rare; big reforms do not happen suddenly
and are always expected to some extent
Public Economics Lectures () Part 2: Tax Incidence 112 / 140
Capitalization: Empirical Applications
Plot excess (market adjusted) returns for drug companies around FDA
approval of drugs
Methodology
1 De…ne "event time" as calendar time minus date of treatment for each
treated obs.
2 Plot means/medians, etc. of outcome variable by event time
Test whether excess returns for high Medicare share drugs is higher
after Medicare Part D is passed
Labor demand (D) and labor supply (S) are functions of the wage, w
Initial equilibrium:
D (w0 ) = S (w0 )
Now, govt mandates employers provide a bene…t with cost t
New equilibrium:
D (w + t ) = S (w + αt )
Wage S
Rate
w1 A
D1
L1 Labor Supply
Wage S
Rate
w1 A
$1
D2 D1
L1 Labor Supply
Wage S
Rate
$α
w1 A
B
C
w2
$1
D2 D1
L1 Labor Supply
where
η D = wD 0 /D < 0
η S = wS 0 /S > 0
Other applications
Wage S
Rate
w1 A
B
minimum wage
w2
D2 D1
L1 Labor Supply
Acemoglu and Angrist estimate the impact of act using data from the
Current Population Survey
ADA intended to help those with disabilities but appears to have hurt
many of them because of wage discrimination clause
Harvard University
Fall 2012
1 Marshallian surplus
4 Harberger Approximation
6 Empirical Applications
2 To redistribute income
Two assumptions:
2 Competitive production
max u (x ) + y s.t. (p + τ )x (p + τ, Z ) + y (p + τ, Z ) = Z
x ,y
c 0 (S ) > 0 and c 00 (S ) 0
pS c (S )
Q satis…es:
Q ( τ ) = D (p + τ ) = S (p )
Consider e¤ect of introducing a small tax d τ > 0 on Q and surplus
$30.0 A
1500 Quantity
B
Excess Burden
$36.0
$30.0 A
$t
P
S
P1
A
Q1 Q
P S+t1
S
B
P2
P1
A
$t1
D
Q2 Q1 Q
P S+t1+t2 S+t1
S
P3 E
B
P2
Change in EB
P1
A
$t2
C
Q3 Q2 Q1 Q
P P
S+t S+t
S S
B
P2
B
P2
P1 P1 A
A
C
D
$t $t C
Q 2 Q1 Q Q2 Q1 Q
With many goods, the most e¢ cient way to raise tax revenue is:
2 Spread taxes across all goods to keep tax rates relatively low on all
goods (broad tax base)
1
EB = dQd τ
2
1 0 ηD
EB = S (p )dpd τ = (1/2)(pS 0 /S )(S /p ) d τ2
2 ηS ηD
1 ηS ηD dτ
EB = pQ ( )2
2 ηS ηD p
ηD
Note: second line uses incidence formula dp = ( η ηD )d τ
S
Tax revenue R = Qd τ
EB 1 ηS ηD d τ
=
R 2 ηS ηD p
Public Economics Lectures () Part 3: E¢ ciency 18 / 106
Method 2: Distortions in Equilibrium Quantity
dQ p 0
De…ne η Q = dτ Q
dEB 1 d 2 EB
EB (τ + ∆τ ) = EB (τ ) + ∆τ + (∆τ )2
dτ 2 d τ2
First-order approximation is accurate when τ large relative to ∆τ
P S+τ+∆τ S+τ
Lost cons. S
surplus (2nd order)
B
Lost govt. revenue
(1st order)
τ A
∆τ
C
D Lost producer
surplus (2nd order)
Q2 Q1 Q
u (c1 , .., cN ) = u (c )
Individual’s problem:
max u (c ) s.t. q c Z
c
uci = λqi
Marshallian surplus does not answer this question with income e¤ects
u 0 = v (q 0 , Z )
CV = e (q 1 , u 0 ) e (q 0 , u 0 ) = e (q 1 , u 0 ) Z
e (q 0 , u 0 ) = e (q 1 , u 0 ) CV
Lump sum amount agent willing to pay to avoid tax (at pre-tax prices)
EV = e (q 1 , u 1 ) e (q 0 , u 1 ) = Z e (q 0 , u 1 )
EV is amount extra that can be taken from agent to leave him with
same ex-post utility:
e (q 0 , u 1 ) + EV = e (q 1 , u 1 )
Formulas are very messy and fragile (Auerbach 1985, Section 3.2)
If only one price is changing, this is the area under the Hicksian
demand curve for that good
p1
p0
x(p1,Z) x(p0,Z) x
p1
EV
p0
x(p1,Z) x(p0,Z) x
p1
CV
p0
x(p1,Z) x(p0,Z) x
p1
Marshallian Surplus
p0
x(p1,Z) x(p0,Z) x
But this is not true in general with multiple price changes because
Marshallian Surplus is ill-de…ned
EB (u 1 ) = EV (q 1 q 0 )h (q 1 , u 1 ) [Mohring 1971]
EB (u 0 ) = CV (q 1 q 0 )h (q 1 , u 0 ) [Diamond and McFadden 1974]
p1
EBEV EBCV
p0
x(p1,Z) xC(p1,V(p0,Z)) x
~ ~ ~
p1
Marshallian
p0
x(p1,Z) xC(p1,V(p0,Z)) x
~ ~ ~
EB (τ ) = [e (p + τ, U ) e (p, U )] τh1 (p + τ, U )
MEB = EB (τ + ∆τ ) EB (τ )
dEB 1 d 2 EB
' ∆τ + (∆τ )2
dτ 2 d τ2
dEB dh1
= h1 (p + τ, U ) τ h1 (p + τ, U )
dτ dτ
dh1
= τ
dτ
d 2 EB dh1 d 2 h1
= τ
d τ2 dτ d τ2
2
Standard practice in literature: assume dd τh21 = 0 (linear Hicksian); not
necessarily well justi…ed b/c it does not vanish as ∆τ ! 0
dh1 1 dh1
) MEB = τ∆τ (∆τ )2
dτ 2 dτ
Formula equals area of “Harberger trapezoid” using Hicksian demands
Ex: with an income tax, minimize total DWL tax by taxing goods
complementary to leisure (Corlett and Hague 1953)
1 No income e¤ects
2 Ignore interactions with commodities other than labor (other taxes are
small)
Step 1: consumption tax and labor income tax have equivalent e¤ects
Price increase in all consumption goods has the same e¤ect on labor
supply as an increase in tax on labor:
(1 + t ) ∑ pk ck = wl
k
dl
Find good at the mean level of d τk
A tax increase on this good has same e¤ect as an increase in sales tax
t on all consumption goods scaled down by sk
c (q, Z ) = γ + αq + δZ
dW K K
d ∑K k
k =1 x1 dx1
dt
= ∑ x1k + ∑ x1k + t
dt
=t
dt
k =1 k =1
Agents have value Vk for good 1; can either buy or not buy
R _∞
dW _ _ d V
dF (Vk )
= 1 F V + 1 F V +t
dt dt
dW dx1
) = t
dt dt
p = u 0 (x (p ))
c = (1 t )TI + e
Social welfare:
N
W (t ) = f(1 t )TI + e g (e ) ∑ ψi (li )g + tTI
i =1
max u (c, l, e ) = c ψ (l )
e,l
s.t. c = y + (1 t )(wl e) + e z (e )
W (t ) = fy + (1 t )(wl e) + e
z (e ) ψ(l )g
+z (e ) + t (wl e)
Estimate εLI and εTI to implement formula that permits transfer costs
dTI
Taxable income elasticity dt is large, whereas labor income elasticity
dLI
dt is not
c=r τ i
Tax reform in 1986 lowered tax rates for high income and raised user
cost of housing sharply
Rosen (1982): εH ,r = 1
Income elasticity: 0.75
Housing share: 0.25
3 1
) Compensated elasticity: 1+ ' 0.8
4 4
Intuition for large elasticity: broker calculates “how much house you
can a¤ord” if they spend 30% of income
Can “a¤ord” more with larger tax subsidy ! tax is e¤ectively salient
Tax reforms in 1980s reduced DWL from $12K to $2K for each
household earning $250K
Diesel fuel used for business purposes (e.g. trucking) is taxed, but
residential purposes (e.g. heating homes) is not
Use cross-state variation in tax rates and price variation from world
market
Danger of paternalism
Choice inconsistency if C (X , d ) 6= C (X , d 0 )
Tax-inclusive price of x: q = p + t S
(p + t S )x (p, t S , Z ) + y (p, t S , Z ) = Z
p = c 0 (S (p ))
∂S p
Let εS = ∂p S (p )
denote the price elasticity of supply
A2 When tax inclusive prices are fully salient, the agent chooses the same
allocation as a fully-optimizing agent:
x (p, 0, Z ) = x (p, 0, Z ) = arg max u (x ) + v (Z px )
x
A1 speci…es ancillary condition: tax rate and salience does not enter
utility directly
p0 + t S G D E
F /x//tS
/x//t S
EB p ? 12 Ýt S Þ 2 /x//p
/x//t S
tS /x//p
p0 A
B I H tS /x
/t S
x
x1* x1 x0
∂x
Without income e¤ects ( ∂Z = 0), excess burden of introducing a
S
small tax t is
1 S 2 ∂x /∂t S
EB (t S ) ' (t ) ∂x /∂t S
2 ∂x /∂p
1 S 2 εD
= (θt )
2 p + tS
1 S 2 ∂x c /∂t S c
EB (t S ) ' (t ) ∂x /∂t S
2 ∂x c /∂p
1 c S 2 εcD
= (θ t )
2 p + tS
1 S 2 ∂x c /∂t S c
EB (t S ) ' (t ) ∂x /∂t S
2 ∂x c /∂p
1 c S 2 εcD
= (θ t )
2 p + tS
With income e¤ects (dx /dZ > 0), making a tax less salient can raise
deadweight loss.
Tax smoothing
Harvard University
Fall 2012
What is the best way to design taxes given equity and e¢ ciency
concerns?
Mirrleesian approach: permit lump sum taxes, but model their costs
in a model with heterogeneity in agents’skills
pi = 1
) qi = 1 + τi
Captures idea that any one individual accounts for a small frac. of
economy
u (x1 , .., xN , l )
q1 x1 + .. + qN xN wl + Z
max V (q, Z )
∂ LG ∂V
) = + λ[ xi + ∑ τ j ∂xj /∂qi ] = 0
∂qi ∂qi |{z}
|{z} |
j
{z }
Mechanical
Priv. Welfare Behavioral
E¤ect
Loss to Indiv. Response
∂V
Using Roy’s identity ( ∂q i
= αxi ):
∂xj xi
∑ τj ∂qi =
λ
(λ α)
j
where θ = λ α ∂
λ ∂Z (∑j τ j xj )
1 ∂hi θ
xi ∑ τj ∂qj =
λ
j
Suppose revenue requirement E is small so that all taxes are also small
τi θ 1
=
1 + τi λ εii
Best policy is for govt to tax capital until it accumulates su¢ cient
assets to fund public goods and never tax capital again
Finitely-lived agents with …nite bequest elasts. (Piketty and Saez 12)
$50,000 $50,000
Tax credits:
Disposable Earnings
$30,000 $30,000
EITC+CTC
Earnings after
$20,000 $20,000 taxes
45 Degree Line
$10,000 $10,000
$0 $0
$0
$5,383
$10,765
$16,148
$21,530
$26,913
$32,295
$37,678
$43,060
$48,443
Gross Earnings (with employer payroll taxes)
L = [u (z T (z )) + λT (z )]h (z )
T (z ) : 0 = ∂L/∂T (z ) = [ u 0 (z T (z )) + λ]h (z )
0
) u (z T (z )) = λ
) z T (z ) = c constant for all z
) c = z̄ E
R
where z̄ = zh (z )dz average income
2 Marginal tax rate T 0 (.) should be zero at the top if skill distribution
bounded [Sadka-Seade]
But until late 1990s, had little impact on practical tax policy
τ
dM + dW + dB = Nd τ (1 ḡ )[z m z̄ ] ε̄ zm
1 τ
Note: this is not an explicit formula for top tax rate because zm /z̄ is
a fn. of τ
Public Economics Lectures () Part 4: Optimal Taxation 38 / 80
Public Economics Lectures () Part 4: Optimal Taxation 39 / 80
Optimal Top Income Tax Rate
High taxes reduce number of people in tail, but could leave thickness of
tail unchanged
a zm
With Pareto distribution (f (z ) = a k a /z 1 +a ), a 1 = z̄ )a=2
1 ḡ
) τ TOP =
1 ḡ + 2ε̄
dM = dzd τ (1 H (z ))
dW = dzd τ (1 H (z ))G (z )
Optimum dM + dW + dB = 0
T 0 (z ) 1 1 H (z )
0
= [1 G (z )]
1 T (z ) ε (z ) zh (z )
G (z ) ! ḡ , (1 H (z ))/(zh (z )) ! 1/a
∞ Z
T 0 (z (w )) 1 1 G 0 (u (s ))
= 1 + 1 f (s )ds,
1 T 0 (z (w )) ε wf (w ) w p
R
where p = G 0 (u (s ))f (s )ds is marginal value of public funds
Start with initial MTR schedule T00 and compute incomes z 0 (w ) using
individual FOCs
u ( c2 )
u h ( c1 , c2 , z ) = u ( c1 ) + ψ(z/w )
1+δ
The budget constraint is
c1 + c2 / ( 1 + ( 1 θ )r ) z T (z )
If low ability people have higher δ then capital income tax tK > 0 is
desirable (Saez 2004)
Costs: Paternalism (spend on the right things), ine¢ cient ordeal cost
Participation elasticity is
Social marginal welfare weight on low skilled workers > 1 (not true
with Rawlsian SWF)
Small tax cut dTi < 0 ) dci = dTi > 0. Three e¤ects:
FOC: dM + dB + dW = 0 )
τi Ti T0 1
= = (1 gi )
1 τi ci c0 ei
g1 > 1 ) T1 T0 < 0 ) work subsidy
Public Economics Lectures () Part 4: Optimal Taxation 64 / 80
Public Economics Lectures () Part 4: Optimal Taxation 65 / 80
Public Economics Lectures () Part 4: Optimal Taxation 66 / 80
Public Economics Lectures () Part 4: Optimal Taxation 67 / 80
Public Economics Lectures () Part 4: Optimal Taxation 68 / 80
Saez 2002: General Model
Calibrations show that average tall person (> 6ft) should pay $4500
more in tax
Public Economics Lectures () Part 4: Optimal Taxation 72 / 80
Problems with Tagging
Up = 2S .5W
Ur = S 1W
R has higher disutility from waiting and lower utility from soup
Social welfare
SWF = Up + Ur
With a total of $100 in soup to give away and no wait times, the soup
will be split between the two agents
Up = 100
Ur = 50
SWF = 150
Social welfare with in-kind transfer (wait time) greater than cash
transfer (no wait time)
Individual utility
U = Eu (z T (z )) e
Chooses e = e to maximize this utility
Harvard University
Fall 2012
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 1 / 220
Outline
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 2 / 220
References
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 3 / 220
Theoretical Issues in Estimation
log l
Optimal tax rate depends inversely on εc = ∂∂log w U =U , the
compensated wage elasticity of labor supply
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 4 / 220
Baseline Labor-Leisure Choice Model: Key Assumptions
1 One period
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 5 / 220
Static Model: Setup
1 +1/ε
Agent has utility u (c, l ) = c a l1+1/ε
Agent earns wage w per hour worked and has y in non-labor income
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 6 / 220
Labor Supply Behavior
log l = α + ε log(1 τ )w
log l = α + ε log(1 τ )w ηy
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 7 / 220
Problems with OLS Estimation of Labor Supply Equation
1 Econometric issues
Unobserved heterogeneity [tax instruments]
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 8 / 220
Econometric Problem 1: Unobserved Heterogeneity
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 9 / 220
Econometric Problem 2: Measurement Error/Division Bias
When hours are measured with noise, this can lead to “division bias”
e
Compute w = l where e is earnings
) log l = log l + µ
) log w = log e log l = log e log l µ = log w µ
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 10 / 220
Measurement Error and Division Bias
Mis-measurement of hours causes a spurious link between hours and
wages
log l = β1 + β2 log w + υ
Then
cov (log l, log w ) cov (log l + µ, log w µ)
Eb
β2 = =
var (log w ) var (log w ) + var (µ)
Problem: Eb
β2 6= ε because orthogonality restriction for OLS violated
Ex. workers with high mis-reported hours also have low imputed
wages, biasing elasticity estimate downward
This can bias OLS estimates: low wage earners must have very high
unobserved propensity to work to …nd it worthwhile
P = φ(α + ε log(1 τ) ηy )
Hours very hard to measure (most ppl report 40 hours per week)
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 15 / 220
Source: Congressional Budget O¢ ce 2005
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 16 / 220
Example 1: Progressive Income Tax
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 17 / 220
Example 2: EITC
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 18 / 220
Example 3: Social Security Payroll Tax Cap
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 19 / 220
Example 4: Negative Income Tax
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 20 / 220
Progressive Taxes and Labor Supply
In practice, most hours changes occur with job switches (Altonji and
Paxson 1992)
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 22 / 220
Optimization Frictions and Identi…cation
Agents can choose any xt that generates a utility loss less than
exogenous threshold δ:
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 23 / 220
Construction of Choice Set
151
150
Np t x D Ýp t Þ
149
148
147
Utility u( xt )
146
145
144
143
142
141
X Ý p t , NÞ
140
6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 24 / 220
Identification with Optimization Frictions
3.0
ε=1
2.8
log demand (log xt)
2.6
2.4
2.2
2.0
1.8
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 25 / 220
Identification with Optimization Frictions
3.0
ε=1
2.8
log demand (log xt)
2.6
2.4
2.2
2.0
1.8
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 26 / 220
Identification with Optimization Frictions
3.0
ε=1
2.8
log demand (log xt)
2.6
2.4
2.2
2.0
1.8
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 27 / 220
Identification with Optimization Frictions
3.0
ε=1
2.8
log demand (log xt)
2.6
2.4
2.2
2.0
1.8
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 28 / 220
Optimization Frictions and Identi…cation
One focus of current research: how to deal with such frictions and
recover ε?
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 29 / 220
Estimating Elasticities Using Variation in Tax Rates
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 30 / 220
Non-Linear Budget Set Methods
li = α + βwi (1 τ i ) + γyi + υi
w3
y3
w2
y2
w1
y1
-L L2 l* L1
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 32 / 220
NLBS Likelihood Function
Consider a two-bracket tax system
Individual can locate on …rst bracket, on second bracket, or at the
kink lK
Likelihood = probability that we see individual i at labor supply li
given a parameter vector
Decompose likelihood into three components
Component 1: individual i on …rst bracket: 0 < li < lK
li = α + βwi (1 τ 1 ) + γy 1 + υi
Error υi = li (α + βwi (1 τ 1 ) + γy 1 ). Likelihood:
Li = φ((li (α + βwi (1 τ 1 ) + γy 1 )/σ)
Component 2: individual i on second bracket: lK < li . Likelihood:
Li = φ((li (α + βwi (1 τ 2 ) + γy 2 )/σ)
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 33 / 220
Likelihood Function: Located at the Kink
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 34 / 220
Maximum Likelihood Estimation
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 35 / 220
Hausman (1981) Application
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 36 / 220
NLBS and Bunching at Kinks
Saez implements this method using individual tax return micro data
(IRS public use …les) from 1960 to 2004
Finds sharp bunching around …rst kink point of the EITC for
self-employed
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 41 / 220
Earnings Density and the EITC: Wage Earners vs. Self-Employed
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 42 / 220
Earnings Density and the EITC: Wage Earners vs. Self-Employed
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 43 / 220
Friedberg 2000: Social Security Earnings Test
Phaseout rate varies by age group - 50%, 33%, 0 (lower for older
workers)
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 44 / 220
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 45 / 220
Friedberg: Estimates
Find that degree of bunching and implied elasticities are 3 times larger
in data with less msmt error
!So the one kink where we do …nd real bunching is actually not real!
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 46 / 220
Why not more bunching at kinks?
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 47 / 220
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 48 / 220
Why not more bunching at kinks?
Ito (2012): empirical evidence that average price matters more than
marginal price
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 49 / 220
Ito (2012)
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 50 / 220
Consumption Density and Price Schedule in 2007: Bunching Around Kink Points
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 51 / 220
A Spatial Discontinuity in Electric Utility Service Areas in Orange County, California
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 52 / 220
Changes in Consumption from July 1999 to July 2000,
by Distance from the Utility Border
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 53 / 220
Changes in Consumption from August 1999 to August 2000,
by Distance from the Utility Border
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 54 / 220
Why not more bunching at kinks?
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 55 / 220
Chetty, Friedman, Olsen, Pistaferri: Model
Workers draw from this distribution and must pay search cost to
reoptimize
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 56 / 220
Chetty et al. 2011: Testable Predictions
Large tax changes are more likely to induce workers to search for a
di¤erent job
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 57 / 220
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 58 / 220
30000
.44
25000
.42
15000 20000
.4
(sum) cnt
NTR
.38 .36
10000
.34
5000
220000 240000 260000 280000 300000 320000
pig
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 59 / 220
Income Distribution for Wage Earners Around Top Tax Cutoff
100000
80000
Frequency
60000
40000
20000
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 60 / 220
Income Distribution for Wage Earners Around Top Tax Cutoff
100000
80000
Frequency
60000
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 61 / 220
Income Distribution for Wage Earners Around Top Tax Cutoff
100000
Excess mass (b) = 0.81
Standard error = 0.05
80000
Frequency
60000
40000
20000
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 62 / 220
Married Women vs. Single Men
30000
30000
Frequency (married women)
Married Women
Excess mass (b)= 1.79
Standard error = 0.10
20000
Single Men
Excess mass (b) = 0.25
10000
10000
0
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 63 / 220
Teachers vs. Military
4000
8000
Teachers
Excess mass (b)= 3.54
3000
Standard error = 0.25
6000
Frequency (military)
Frequency (teachers)
2000
4000
1000
2000
Military
Excess mass (b) = -0.12
Standard error = 0.21
0
0
-50 -40 -30 -20 -10 0 10 20 30 40 50
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 64 / 220
Taxable Income Distributions in 1994
3000
4000 6000 8000 10000 12000 14000
2000
Married Women
Excess Mass (b) = 1.03
Standard error = 0.14
1000
All Wage Earners
Excess Mass (b) = 0.61
Standard error = 0.08
0
210 220 230 240 250 260 270 280 290 300
Taxable Income (1000s DKR)
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 65 / 220
1995
3000
Frequency (married women)
Frequency (all wage earners)
12000
2000
b = 1.25
s.e. = 0.16
b = 0.41
8000
s.e. = 0.08
1000
4000
0
210 220 230 240 250 260 270 280 290 300
Taxable Income (1000s DKR)
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 66 / 220
1996
3000
Frequency (married women)
Frequency (all wage earners)
12000
b = 1.55
2000
s.e. = 0.17
8000
b = 0.66
s.e. = 0.09
1000
4000
0
210 220 230 240 250 260 270 280 290 300
Taxable Income (1000s DKR)
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 67 / 220
1997
3000
15000
b = 1.26
s.e. = 0.19
2000
10000
b = 0.58
s.e. = 0.01
1000
5000
0
210 220 230 240 250 260 270 280 290 300
Taxable Income (1000s DKR)
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 68 / 220
1998
3000
Frequency (married women)
Frequency (all wage earners)
12000
b = 1.71
s.e. = 0.18
2000
8000
b = 0.78
s.e. = 0.09
1000
4000
0
210 220 230 240 250 260 270 280 290 300
Taxable Income (1000s DKR)
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 69 / 220
1999
4000
Frequency (married women)
Frequency (all wage earners)
3000
12000
b = 1.49
s.e. = 0.16
2000
b = 0.62
8000
s.e. = 0.08
1000
4000
0
210 220 230 240 250 260 270 280 290 300
Taxable Income (1000s DKR)
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 70 / 220
2000
4000
14000
3000
b = 1.50
s.e. = 0.21
2000
10000
b = 0.72
1000
s.e. = 0.09
6000
0
210 220 230 240 250 260 270 280 290 300
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 71 / 220
2001
4000
14000
3000
b = 1.44
s.e. = 0.20
10000
2000
b = 0.55
1000
s.e. = 0.10
6000
210 220 230 240 250 260 270 280 290 300
Taxable Income (1000s DKR)
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 72 / 220
Married Women: Taxable Income Distribution at Middle Tax Cutoff
40000
30000
Frequency
20000
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 73 / 220
Observed Elasticity vs. Size of Tax Change
All Wage Earners
0.01
Observed Elasticities
0.005
-0.005
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 74 / 220
All Teachers
1500
1000
Frequency
500
0
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 75 / 220
Wage Earnings Distribution: Teachers with Deductions > DKr 20,000
10000
This group
starts paying
8000
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 76 / 220
(a) Electricians,
Electricians (3114),2000
2000 (b) Salesmen, 1996
300
80
60
200
Frequency
Frequency
40
100
20
0
0
-100 -50 0 50 100 -100 -50 0 50 100
Wage Wage Earnings
Earnings Relative
Relative to Topto Top Bracket
Bracket Cutoff Cutoff
(1000s DKr) Wage Wage Earnings
Earnings Relative
Relative to Topto Top Bracket
Bracket Cutoff Cutoff
(1000s DKr)
(c) Nurses and Midwifes, 2001 (d) Tellers and Clerks, 1998
150
400
300
100
Frequency
Frequency
200
50
100
0
0
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 77 / 220
Modes of Occupation-Level Wage Earnings Distributions
30
20
Frequency
10
0
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 78 / 220
Chetty et al. 2011: Lessons
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 79 / 220
Chetty, Friedman, Saez (2012)
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 80 / 220
Income Distribution For Single Wage Earners with One Child
Is the EITC having
an effect on this
3.5 distribution? 4k
3
Percent of Wage-Earners
3k
2.5
1
1k
.5
0 0k
$0 $5K $10K $25K $20K $25K $30K $35K
W-2 Wage Earnings
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 81 / 220
Empirical Analysis: Two Parts
First, develop a proxy for local knowledge about EITC schedule based
on income manipulation by self-employed individuals
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 82 / 220
Outline of Empirical Analysis
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 83 / 220
Earnings Distribution in Texas
5%
4%
Percent of Filers
3%
2%
1%
0%
5%
4%
Percent of Filers
3%
2%
1%
0%
4.1 –42.7%
2.8 –4.1%
2.1 –2.8%
1.8 –2.1%
1.5 –1.8%
1.2 –1.5%
1.1 –1.2%
0.9 –1.1%
0.7 –0.9%
0 –0.7%
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 86 / 220
Outline of Empirical Analysis
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 87 / 220
Movers: Neighborhood Changes
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 88 / 220
Event Study of Sharp Bunching Around Moves
5% Effect of Moving to
10th Decile = 1.93
(0.13)
4%
Sharp Bunching for Movers
Effect of Moving to
1st Decile = -0.41
(0.11)
3%
2%
1%
0%
-4 -2 0 2 4
Event Year
Movers to Lowest Movers to Middle Movers to Highest
Bunching Decile Bunching Decile Bunching Decile
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 89 / 220
Learning and Memory
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 90 / 220
Change in EITC Refunds vs. Change in Sharp Bunching for Movers
120
Change in EITC Refund ($)
100
β= 59.7
(5.7)
80
60
β= 6.0
(6.2)
p-value for diff. in slopes: p < 0.0001
40
-1% -0.5% 0% 0.5% 1%
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 91 / 220
Agglomeration: Sharp Bunching vs. EITC Filer Density by ZIP Code
3.5%
3.0%
Sharp Bunching
2.5%
2.0%
1.5%
R2 = 0.6
1.0%
-2 0 2 4 6
log (Number of EITC Filers Per Square Mile)
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 92 / 220
Outline of Empirical Analysis
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 93 / 220
Income Distribution For Single Wage Earners with One Child
3
Percent of Wage-Earners
3k
2.5
1
1k
.5
0 0k
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 94 / 220
Income Distribution For Single Wage Earners with One Child
High vs. Low Bunching Areas
3.5 4k
3
Percent of Wage-Earners
3k
2.5
1
1k
.5
0 0k
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 96 / 220
Child Birth Research Design
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 97 / 220
Earnings Distribution in the Year Before First Child Birth for Wage Earners
6%
Percent of Individuals
4%
2%
0%
6%
Percent of Individuals
4%
2%
0%
1900
Simulated One-Child EITC Amount ($)
1850
ß = 85.4
(7.2)
1800
1750
-4 -2 0 2 4
Age of Child
Lowest Sharp Middle Sharp Highest Sharp
Bunching Decile Bunching Decile Bunching Decile
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 100 / 220
Change in Simulated One-Child EITC Refund ($) Changes in Simulated EITC around Births for Wage Earners
200
β= 26.5
100
(1.97)
-100
0% 2% 4% 6% 8%
ZIP-3 Self-Employed Sharp Bunching
0 to 1 Child
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 101 / 220
Change in Simulated One-Child EITC Refund ($) Changes in Simulated EITC around Births for Wage Earners
200
β= 26.5
100
(1.97)
0
β= -0.13
(1.08)
-100
0% 2% 4% 6% 8%
ZIP-3 Self-Employed Sharp Bunching
0 to 1 Child 2 to 3 Children
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 102 / 220
Composition of Wage Earnings Responses
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 103 / 220
Impact of EITC on Income Distribution
No EITC
Counterfactual
13.7% 31.9% 54.3% 77.3%
EITC, No
Behavioral 9.4% 22.0% 42.1% 71.1%
Response
EITC, with
Avg. Behavioral 8.2% 21.0% 42.0% 71.3%
Response
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 104 / 220
Elasticity Estimates Based on Change in EITC Refunds Around Birth of First Child
A. Wage Earnings
B. Total Earnings
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 105 / 220
Traditional Labor Supply Elasticity Estimates
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 106 / 220
Negative Income Tax
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 111 / 220
Problems with Experimental Design
Estimates from NIT not considered very credible today for two reasons:
2 Selective attrition
After initial year, data was collected based on voluntary income reports
by families to qualify for the grant
Those in less generous groups/far above breakeven point had much less
incentive to report
Uses the Tax Reform Act of 1986 to identify the e¤ect of MTRs on
labor force participation and hours of married women
TRA 1986 cut top income MTR from 50% to 28% from 1986 to 1988
But did not signi…cantly change tax rates for the middle class
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 117 / 220
Eissa 1995: Caveats
Liebman and Saez (2006) show that Eissa’s results are not robust
using admin data (SSA matched to SIPP)
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 118 / 220
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 119 / 220
Bianchi, Gudmundsson, and Zoega 2001
Data: individual tax returns matched with data on weeks worked from
insurance database
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 120 / 220
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 121 / 220
Bianchi, Gudmundsson, and Zoega 2001
Note that elasticities reported in paper are w.r.t. average tax rates:
∑(L87 LA )/LA
εL,T /E =
∑ T86 /E86
∑ 87 EA )/EA
( E
εE ,T /E =
∑ T86 /E86
Estimates imply earnings elasticity w.r.t. marginal tax rate of roughly
0.37 (Chetty 2012)
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 122 / 220
Responses to Low-Income Transfer Programs
Particular interest in treatment of low incomes in a progressive tax
system: are they responsive to incentives?
Recent literature has focused on welfare reform in mid-1990’s
Reform modi…ed AFDC cash welfare program to provide more
incentives to work by
1 Requiring recipients to go to job training
2 Limiting the duration for which families able to receive welfare
3 Reducing phase out to 66 cents of bene…ts per $1 earnings instead of
100% cli¤
Variation across states because Fed govt. gave block grants with
guidelines
EITC also expanded during this period: general shift from welfare to
“workfare”
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 123 / 220
Monthly Welfare Case Loads: 1963-2000
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 124 / 220
Welfare Reform: Two Empirical Questions
2 Bene…ts: did removing many people from transfer system reduce their
welfare?
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 125 / 220
Meyer and Rosenbaum 2001
Study the …rst question: impact of welfare reforms and EITC on labor
supply
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 126 / 220
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 127 / 220
Employment Rates for Single Women with and without Children
1
Employment Rate
.9
.8
.7
Children No Children
Source: Meyer and Rosenbaum 2001
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 128 / 220
Meyer and Rosenbaum 2001
Problem: EITC expansion took place at same time as welfare reform
EITC
AFDC bene…ts
Medicaid
Waivers
Training
Child Care
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 129 / 220
Meyer and Rosenbaum 2001
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 130 / 220
Meyer and Sullivan 2004
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 131 / 220
Total Consumption: Single Mothers 1984-2000
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 132 / 220
Relative Consumption: single women with/without children
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 133 / 220
Meyer and Sullivan: Results
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 134 / 220
Changing Elasticities: Blau and Kahn 2007
Result: total hours elasticity (including int + ext margin) shrank from
0.4 in 1980 to 0.2 today
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 135 / 220
Summary of Static Labor Supply Literature
2 Larger responses for workers who are less attached to labor force
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 136 / 220
Intertemporal Models and the MaCurdy Critique
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 137 / 220
Life Cycle Model of Labor Supply
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 138 / 220
Dynamic Life Cycle Model: Policy Rules
λ = uc0 is the marginal utility of initial consumption
All other wage rates and initial wealth enter only through the budget
constraint multiplier λ (MaCurdy 1981)
wt ∂l
δ=( ) jλ
lt ∂wt
Experiment: change wage rate in one period only, holding all other
wages, and consumption pro…le constant
In separable case:
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 140 / 220
Dynamic Life Cycle Model: Three Types of Wage Changes
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 141 / 220
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 142 / 220
Frisch vs. Compensated vs. Uncompensated Elasticities
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 144 / 220
Frisch Elasticities Implied by Hicksian Elasticity of 0.33
d [wli ,t ] 2 Ai ,t
εF = ε + ρ ( )
dYi ,t wli ,t
(ρ) 0.80 0.33 0.35 0.38 0.44 0.53 0.64 0.77 0.70
1.00 0.33 0.35 0.39 0.47 0.58 0.71 0.88 0.75
1.20 0.33 0.35 0.41 0.50 0.63 0.79 0.99 0.79
1.40 0.33 0.35 0.42 0.53 0.67 0.87 1.10 0.84
Source: Chetty 2011
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 145 / 220
Structural Estimates: MaCurdy 1983 and Pencavel 2002
MaCurdy (1983)
Structural estimate using panel data for men and within-person wage
variation
Find both Frisch and compensated wage elasticity of around 0.15
But wage variation is not exogenous
Pencavel (2002)
Instruments with trade balance interacted with schooling and age
Frisch elasticity: 0.2
Uncompensated wage elasticity: 0-0.2
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 146 / 220
Card (1991) Critique of ITLS models
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 147 / 220
Blundell, Duncan, and Meghir 1998
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 148 / 220
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 149 / 220
Blundell, Duncan, and Meghir: Results
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 150 / 220
Manoli and Weber 2011
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 151 / 220
Lump-Sum Severance Payments at Retirement
1
.75
Fraction of Last Year's Salary
.5
.333
0
0 5 10 15 20 25 30
Years of Tenure at Retirement
Source: Manoli and Weber 2009
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 152 / 220
Distribution of Tenure at Retirement
Quarterly Frequency
6000
Number of Individuals
4000
2000
0
10 15 20 25
Years of Tenure at Retirement
Source: Manoli and Weber 2009
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 153 / 220
Taxable Income Elasticities
1 Convenient su¢ cient statistic for all distortions created by income tax
system (Feldstein 1999)
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 154 / 220
US Income Taxation: Trends
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 155 / 220
Feldstein 1995
Looks at how incomes and MTR evolve from 1985 to 1988 for
individuals in each group using panel
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 156 / 220
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 157 / 220
Feldstein: Results
Implication: we were on the wrong side of the La¤er curve for the rich
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 158 / 220
Feldstein: Econometric Criticisms
∆ log(z M ) = 0
∆ log(z H ) = e∆ log(1 τH )
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 159 / 220
Feldstein: Econometric Criticisms
Triple di¤erence that nets out di¤erential prior trends yields elasticity
<0.4 for top earners
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 160 / 220
Slemrod: Shifting vs. “Real” Responses
Looks like a supply side story but government is actually losing revenue
at the corporate tax level
Shifting across tax bases not taken into account in Feldstein e¢ ciency
cost calculations
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 161 / 220
18%
Wages S-Corp. Partner. Sole P. Dividends Interest Other
16%
14%
12%
10%
8%
6%
4%
2%
0%
1960
1962
1964
1966
1968
1970
1972
1974
1976
1978
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
FIGURE 7
The Top 1% Income Share and Composition, 1960-2000
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 162 / 220
Goolsbee: Intertemporal Shifting
Regression speci…cation:
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 163 / 220
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 164 / 220
Goolsbee 2000
Concludes that long run e¤ect is 20x smaller than substitution e¤ect
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 165 / 220
Gruber and Saez 2002
First study to examine taxable income responses for general
population, not just top earners
Use data from 1979-1991 on all tax changes available rather than a
single reform
Simulated instruments methodology
Isolates changes in laws (ft ) as the only source of variation in tax rates
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 166 / 220
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 167 / 220
Gruber and Saez: Results
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 168 / 220
Evidence from Danish Tax Reforms
Observed Earnings Responses to Small Tax Reforms
1
% Residual Change in Wage Earnings
0.5
0
-0.5
-1
-1.5
-4 -2 0 2 4 6
% Residual Change in Net-of-Tax Wage Rate ∆log(1-t)
Source: Chetty et al. 2009
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 169 / 220
Imbens et al. 2001: Income E¤ects
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 170 / 220
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 171 / 220
Taxable Income Literature: Summary
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 172 / 220
Macro Evidence
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 173 / 220
Prescott 2004
Uses data on hours worked by country in 1970 and 1995 for 7 OECD
countries
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 174 / 220
Aggregate Hours vs. Net-of-Tax Rates Across Countries (Prescott Data)
7.4
εPrescott=0.7 Japan 1970-74
Log Hours Worked Per Adult
Japan 1993-96
US.1970-74
UK 1993-96
7.2
Germany.1970-74
France 1970-74
UK 1970-74
Canada 1993-96 US 1993-96
Canada 1970-74
France 1993-96
6.8
Italy 1993-96
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 175 / 220
Business Cycle Fluctuations in Employment Rates in the U.S.
Log Deviation of Employment from HP Filtered Trend
.03
.02
.01
-.01
-.02
-.03
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 176 / 220
Reconciling Micro and Macro Estimates
L = Nh
d log L d log N d log h d log h
= + >
d (1 τ ) d (1 τ ) d (1 τ ) d (1 τ )
3 Optimization frictions: short run vs. long run [Chetty 2012]
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 177 / 220
Optimization Frictions
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 178 / 220
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 179 / 220
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 180 / 220
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 181 / 220
Setup
Consider a static demand model; results hold in dynamic model
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 184 / 220
Construction of Choice Set
151
150
Np t x D Ýp t Þ
149
148
147
Utility u( xt )
146
145
144
143
142
141
X Ý p t , NÞ
140
6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 185 / 220
Identification with Optimization Frictions
3.0
ε=1
2.8
log demand (log xt)
2.6
2.4
2.2
2.0
1.8
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 186 / 220
Bounds and Partial Identi…cation
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 187 / 220
Partial Identi…cation
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 188 / 220
Calculation of Bounds on Structural Elasticity
3.6
3.4
3.2
3
log demand (log xt)
2.8
2.6
2.4
2.2
1.8
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 189 / 220
a) Upper Bound on Structural Elasticity
3.6
3.4
3.2
3
log demand (log xt)
2.8
2.6
2.4
2.2
1.8
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 190 / 220
b) Lower Bound on Structural Elasticity
3.6
3.4
3.2
3
log demand (log xt)
2.8
2.6
2.4
2.2
1.8
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 191 / 220
Bounds on Elasticity with Optimization Frictions
4δ 4δ
[bε + (1 ρ),bε + (1 + ρ)]
(∆ log p )2 (∆ log p )2
1 bε
where ρ = (1 + (∆ log p )2 )1/2
2δ
Maps an observed elasticity bε, size of price change ∆ log p, and degree
of optimization frictions δ to bounds on ε.
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 192 / 220
Extensive Margin Responses
ui (x, y ) = y + bi x
4.0
Intensive Margin
3.5 Bounds
3.0
Elasticity (ε)
2.5
2.0
1.5
0
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0
Observed Elasticity ( ε )
^
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 194 / 220
Extensive vs. Intensive Margin Bounds
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 195 / 220
Application to Taxation and Labor Supply
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 196 / 220
Bounds on Intensive-Margin Hicksian Elasticities with δ = 1% Frictions
å å
se( P ) ∆log(1-τ) εL εU
Study Identification P
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)
A. Hours Elasticities
1. MaCurdy (1981) Lifecycle wage variation, 1967-1976 0.15 0.15 0.39 0.03 0.80
2. Eissa and Hoynes (1998) U.S. EITC, 1984-1996, Men 0.20 0.07 0.07 0.00 15.29
3. Eissa and Hoynes (1998) U.S. EITC, 1984-1996, Women 0.09 0.07 0.07 0.00 15.07
4. Blundell et al. (1998) U.K. Tax Reforms, 1978-1992 0.14 0.09 0.23 0.01 1.78
5. Ziliak and Kniesner (1999) Lifecycle wage, tax variation 1978-1987 0.15 0.07 0.39 0.03 0.80
Mean observed elasticity 0.15
B. Taxable Income Elasticities
6. Bianchi et al. (2001) Iceland 1987 Zero Tax Year 0.37 0.05 0.49 0.15 0.92
7. Gruber and Saez (2002) U.S. Tax Reforms 1979-1991 0.14 0.14 0.14 0.00 4.42
8. Saez (2004) U.S. Tax Reforms 1960-2000 0.09 0.04 0.15 0.00 3.51
9. Jacob and Ludwig (2008) Chicago Housing Voucher Lottery 0.12 0.03 0.36 0.02 0.84
10. Gelber (2010) Sweden, 1991 Tax Reform, Women 0.49 0.02 0.71 0.28 0.86
11. Gelber (2010) Sweden, 1991 Tax Reform, Men 0.25 0.02 0.71 0.12 0.54
12. Saez (2010) U.S., 1st EITC Kink, 1995-2004 0.00 0.02 0.34 0.00 0.70
13. Chetty et al. (2011a) Denmark, Top Kinks, 1994-2001 0.02 0.00 0.30 0.00 0.93
14. Chetty et al. (2011a) Denmark, Middle Kinks, 1994-2001 0.00 0.00 0.11 0.00 6.62
15. Chetty et al. (2011a) Denmark Tax Reforms, 1994-2001 0.00 0.00 0.09 0.00 9.88
Mean observed elasticity 0.15
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 197 / 220
Bounds on Intensive-Margin Hicksian Elasticities with δ = 1% Frictions
å å
se( P ) ∆log(1-τ) εL εU
Study Identification P
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 198 / 220
Bounds on Intensive-Margin Hicksian Elasticities with δ=1%
2.5
2
Elasticity
MaCurdy (1981)
1.5
0.5
0
0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 199 / 220
Bounds on Intensive-Margin Hicksian Elasticities with δ=1%
2.5
Goolsbee TRA86
2 Saez (2004)
Elasticity
MaCurdy (1981)
1.5
Prescott (2004)
1 Gelber (2010)
Davis and Henrekson Blau and Kahn
(2005) (2007)
0.5
0
0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 200 / 220
Bounds on Intensive-Margin Hicksian Elasticities with δ=1%
2.5
Goolsbee TRA86
2 Saez (2004)
Elasticity
MaCurdy (1981)
1.5
Prescott (2004)
1 Gelber (2010)
Davis and Henrekson Blau and Kahn
(2005) (2007)
0.5
0
0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 201 / 220
Bounds on Intensive-Margin Hicksian Elasticities with δ=1%
3 Feldstein (1995)
2 Saez (2004)
Elasticity
MaCurdy (1981)
1.5
Prescott (2004)
1 Gelber (2010)
Davis and Henrekson Blau and Kahn
(2005) (2007)
0.5
0
0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 202 / 220
Unified Bounds on Intensive Margin Elasticity vs. Degree of Frictions
1.2
1
Elasticity (ε)
.8
.6
.4
εδ−min=0.33
.2
0
δmin= 0.5% 1% 2% 3% 4% 5%
Optimization Frictions as a Fraction of Net Earnings (δ)
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 203 / 220
Bounds on Extensive-Margin Hicksian Elasticities with δ=1% Frictions
0.5
Meyer and Rosenbaum (2004)
Blau and
Kahn (2007)
Extensive Margin Elasticity
0.4
Chetty, Guren, Manoli, and Weber (2012): can frictions explain gap
between micro and macro elasticities?
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 205 / 220
Aggregate Hours vs. Net-of-Tax Rates Across Countries (Prescott Data)
7.4
εPrescott=0.7 Japan 1970-74
εmicro=0.58
Log Hours Worked Per Adult
Japan 1993-96
US.1970-74
UK 1993-96
7.2
Germany.1970-74
France 1970-74
UK 1970-74
Canada 1993-96 US 1993-96
Canada 1970-74
France 1993-96
6.8
Italy 1993-96
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 206 / 220
Table 2: Micro vs. Macro Labor Supply Elasticities
micro
Intertemporal Substitution
(Frisch)
macro
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 207 / 220
Business Cycle Fluctuations in Employment Rates in the U.S.
Log Deviation of Employment from HP Filtered Trend
.03
.02
.01
-.01
-.02
-.03
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 208 / 220
Table 2: Micro vs. Macro Labor Supply Elasticities
Intertemporal Substitution
micro 0.32 0.54 0.86
(Frisch)
macro [2.77] [0.54] 3.31
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 209 / 220
Labor Supply Elasticities: Implications for Preferences
Labor supply elasticities central for tax policy because they determine
e¢ ciency costs
u (c ) ψ (l )
wl εl ,y
γ= (1 + )
y εl c ,w
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 213 / 220
uc ,ul
Case A: γ < 1 -ul(w0l,l)
w0uc(w0l,l) -ul range with
w1uc(w1l,l)
complementarity
w1uc(w1l,l)
Case B: γ > 1
lB l0 lA l
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 214 / 220
Labor Supply Elasticities and Implied Coefficients of Relative Risk Aversion
Income Compensated γ γ
Study Sample Identification Elasticity Wage Elasticity Additive ∆c/c=0.15
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)
A. Hours
B. Participation
Eissa and Hoynes (1998) Married Men, Inc < 30K EITC Expansions -0.008 0.033 0.44 0.48
Married Women, Inc < 30K EITC Expansions -0.038 0.288 0.15 0.30
Average 0.29 0.39
C. Earned Income
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 215 / 220
Chetty 2006: Results
wl εl ,y
Formula γ = (1 + y ) εl c ,w useful in tax, insurance, and other
applications
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 216 / 220
Income Distribution
Third piece can be well measured using tax data, even for high
incomes (Piketty and Saez 2004)
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 217 / 220
Saez 2004: Long-Run Evidence
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 218 / 220
Bottom 99% Tax Units
40% $40,000
35% $35,000
30% $30,000
Marginal Tax Rate
25% $25,000
20% $20,000
15% $15,000
10% $10,000
0% $0
1970
1972
1974
1976
1978
1980
1984
1986
1988
1990
2000
1982
1998
1960
1962
1964
1968
1992
1994
1996
1966
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 219 / 220
Top 1% Tax Units
80% $800,000
70% $700,000
60% $600,000
Marginal Tax Rate
50% $500,000
40% $400,000
30% $300,000
20% $200,000
0% $0
1970
1972
1974
1976
1978
1980
1984
1986
1988
1990
2000
1982
1998
1960
1962
1964
1968
1992
1994
1996
1966
Public Economics Lectures ()Part 5: Income Taxation and Labor Supply 220 / 220
Public Economics Lectures
Part 6: Social Insurance
Harvard University
Fall 2012
2 Unemployment Insurance
3 Workers’Compensation
4 Disability Insurance
5 Health Insurance
Social
Health Security Income
0.4% 3.6% Security
5%
Health
National 9.4%
Defense
20.7% Social
Other Security
21.6% 20.7%
National Defense
69.4% Other Income
34.8% Security
14.5%
1953 2008
Source: Office of Management and Budget, historical tables, government outlays by function
% of Central % of Total
Government Government
% of GDP Expenditures Expenditures
120
100
Net replacement rate (%)
80
60
40
20
0
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60
Time (months)
Generate new distortions as you …x the problem you set out to solve
–> second-best solution
Key paper: Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976); see MWG Ch. 13 for a
good review
In good state (state 1), income is E1 for both types; in bad state,
income is E2 < E1 .
Vi ( α ) = ( 1 p i ) u ( E1 α 1 ) + p i u ( E2 + α 2 )
De…nition
An equilibrium is de…ned by a set of insurance contracts such that
(1) individuals optimize: both types cannot …nd a better contract than the
ones they chose
(2) …rms optimize: all …rms earn zero pro…ts
1 pi
Plugging in α2 = pi α1 , each type solves
1 pi
max(1 pi ) u ( w α1 ) + pi u (w + α1 ).
α1 pi
Solution
1 pi
Set MRS12 = pi , i.e. u 0 (c1 ) = u 0 (c2 ), i.e. full insurance
With contracts above, all the high risk types buy the low risk’s
contract and insurer goes out of business
1 p
Zero-pro…t condition requires α2 = p α1 but p > pL .
Creates an opportunity for a new insurer to enter and “pick o¤” low
risk types by o¤ering slightly less insurance at a better price: higher
c1 , lower c2
Intuition: in any sep. eq., both types are getting actuarially fair
insurance because of the zero-pro…ts condition
For H, no cost to …rm in providing full ins. (worst that can happen is
that L will join the pool, raising pro…ts)
But for L, full ins. would create an incentive for H to buy this
(cheaper) policy, forcing …rm into negative pro…ts
E1 = 100, E2 = 0
p 1 3
u (c ) = c, pL = , pH = , f = 10%
4 4
In candidate separating eq., type H gets perfect insurance:
r
1
EUH = u (100(1 pH )) = 100 =5
4
Solving gives αL1 = $3.85, αL2 = $11.55 – nowhere near full insurance
for low risk type.
Because there are relatively few high risk types, L types bene…t from
pooling with them and getting full insurance coverage.
What tool does the govt. have that private sector does not? Ability
to mandate
Public Economics Lectures () Part 6: Social Insurance 25 / 178
Adverse Selection: Empirical Evidence
Are those who buy more insurance more likely to …le claims?
2 Correlation does not clearly map into parameters that control welfare
costs of selection
Einav, Finkelstein, and Cullen (2010) develop “cost curve” tests that
map to measures of welfare costs
3 Only applicable in markets that exist, i.e. those that have not totally
unravelled
With such bu¤er stocks, still no need for large social safety nets to
insure against temporary shocks such as unemployment
Suggests 1st Welfare thm also does not hold due to individual failures
to optimize
Must take this distortion into account to …nd optimal level of social
insurance
Potential bene…ts
Potential distortions
(0.5 )w
1970: No tax ) r = (1 .18 .05 .07 )w = 72%
362 400
300
Weekly Benefits ($)
200
100
Static model with two states: high (employed) and low (unemployed)
Let wh denote the individual’s income in the high state and wl < wh
income in the low state
e t (b ) = (1 e) b
eu (A + wh t (b )) + (1 e )u (A + wl + b ) ψ (e )
max e (A + wh t ) + (1 e )u (A + wl + b ) ψ (e )
b,e
1 e
s.t. t = b
e
max eu (A + wh t ) + (1 e )u (A + wl + b ) ψ (e )
e
max V (b, t )
b,t
s.t. e (b )t = (1 e (b ))b
Problem
Optimal Social Insurance
max V (b, t (b ))
b
s.t. e (b )t (b ) = (1 e (b ))b
e (b ) = arg max e u (A + wh t ) + (1 e ) u (A + wl + b ) ψ (e )
e
dV /db (b ) = 0
V (b ) = max eu (A + wh t (b )) + (1 e )u (A + wl + b ) ψ (e )
e
dV (b ) dt 0
= (1 e ) u 0 ( cl ) eu (ch )
db db
∂e
Can ignore ∂b terms because of agent optimization
V (b ) = max eu (A + wh t (b ))
e,H
+(1 e )[u (A + wl + b + H ) g (H )] ψ (e )
dV (b )
Formula derived for db is una¤ected by ability to move home:
dV (b ) dt 0
= (1 e ) u 0 ( cl ) eu (ch )
db db
where cl is measured in the data as including home consumption (H)
u 0 ( cl ) u 0 ( c h ) ε
= 1 e,b
u 0 ( ch ) e
u 0 ( cl ) u 0 ( ch ) ε
0
= 1 e,b
u ( ch ) e
This equation provides an exact formula for the optimal bene…t rate
u 0 (c l ) u 0 (c h )
Implementation requires identi…cation of u 0 (c h )
u 0 (c l ) u 0 (c h )
Three ways to identify u 0 (c h )
empirically
u 0 ( cl ) u 0 ( ch ) u 00 (ch )(cl ch )
u 00 (c )c
De…ning coe¢ cient of relative risk aversion γ = u 0 (c )
, we can write
u 0 ( c l ) u 0 ( ch ) u 00 ∆c
ch (1)
u 0 ( ch ) u0 c
∆c
= γ
c
Gap in marginal utilities is a function of curvature of utility (risk
aversion) and consumption drop from high to low states
Theorem
The optimal unemployment bene…t level b satis…es
∆c ε1 e,b
γ (b )
c e
where
∆c ch cl
= = consumption drop during unemployment
c ch
u 00 (ch )
γ = ch = coe¢ cient of relative risk aversion
u 0 ( ch )
d log 1 e
ε1 e,b = = elast. of probability of unemp. w.r.t. bene…ts
d log b
∆c ε1 e,b
γ (b )
c e
WBAAmax
After Benefit Increase
WBABmax
Before Benefit Increase
WBAmin
E1 E2 E3 Previous Earnings
ht = αt exp( βX )
log ht = log αt + βX
d log ht
= β1 = εht ,b
d log b
Uses cross-state and time variation and uses drop in food consumption
as the LHS variable.
Gruber estimates
∆c b
= β1 + β2
c w
Finds β1 = 0.24, β2 = 0.28
Suggests that ins. markets are not perfect and UI does play a
consumption smoothing role, but estimates are imprecise
For a $100/wk increase in UI bene…t, wives work 22 hrs less per month
In the absence of UI, wives would work 30% more during the spell than
they do now
b ε /e 1 β1
= 1 e,b ( )
w β2 γ β2
b .43/.95 1 ( .24)
= ( )
w .28 γ .28
b
Results: w varies considerably with γ
γ 1 2 3 4 5 10
b
w 0 0.05 0.31 0.45 0.53 0.7
Do individuals who choose more insurance for health also choose more
insurance for long-term disability?
.05
Food and Housing Growth Rates
.025
0
-.025
-.05
-.075
-4 -2 0 2 4
Year relative to unemployment
.05
Food and Housing Growth Rates
.025
0
-.025
-.05
-.075
-4 -2 0 2 4
Year relative to unemployment
U (f , h ) = u (f ) + v (h ).
Then have to cut food cons by 20%, leading to larger welfare loss
γ 1 2 3 4 5 10
b
w 0 0.05 0.31 0.45 0.53 0.7
Since γ and ∆cc are hard to identify, recent work has sought
alternative ways of calculating optimal bene…t.
Two approaches
At +1 = At + yt ct
Asset limit: At L
2 No heterogeneity
cte = ct+1e = …
st
Period t
st+1 ct+1e
1-st
ctu
1-st+1
ct+1u
Value function for agent who does not …nd a job in period t:
ψ0 (st ) = Vt (At ) U t ( At )
Liquidity and total bene…t e¤ects smaller for agents with better
consumption smoothing capacity
If agent would not use money to extend duration, infer that only takes
longer because of price subsidy (moral hazard)
0 10 20 30 40 50
Weeks Unemployed
0 10 20 30 40 50
Weeks Unemployed
0 10 20 30 40 50
Weeks Unemployed
0 10 20 30 40 50
Weeks Unemployed
0 5 10 15 20
Weeks Unemployed
0 5 10 15 20
Weeks Unemployed
0 5 10 15 20
Weeks Unemployed
Welfare gain from raising bene…t level by 10% from current level in
U.S. (50% wage replacement) is $5.9 bil = 0.05% of GDP
0
0 36 60
Job Tenure
12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54 60
Previous Job Tenure (Months)
34
33
Mean Age
32
31
30
12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54 60
Previous Job Tenure (Months)
12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54 60
Previous Job Tenure (Months)
12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54 60
Previous Job Tenure (Months)
NOTE--All specs are Cox hazard models that include cubic polynomials with
interactions with sevpay and/or extended benefit dummy.
u (w̄0 t ) = W (b )
Government’s problem is
It follows that
dW d w̄0 dt
=
db db db
d w̄0 1 e 1
= (1 + ε1 e,b )
db e e
d w̄ 0
Implement formula using estimates of db reported by Feldstein and
Poterba (1984)
Find gains from raising UI bene…ts 5 times larger than Chetty (2008)
Note: all the formulas above take such match quality gains into
account via envelope conditions
12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54 60
Previous Job Tenure (Months)
12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54 60
Previous Job Tenure (Months)
12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54 60
Previous Job Tenure (Months)
12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54 60
Months Employed in Past Five Years
.1
.05
Wage Growth
0
-.05
-.1
12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54 60
Months Worked in Past Five Years
12 18 24 30 36 42 48 54 60
Months Worked in Past Five Years
The two could di¤er if workers transit o¤ of UI but are still jobless
.2
Unemployment Exit Hazard
.15
.1
.05
0
20 15 10 5 0
Weeks of Eligibility Left
Source: Meyer 1990
.2 .15
Weekly Hazard Rate
.05 .1 0
0 10 20 30 40 50
Weeks Elapsed Since Job Loss
.2 .15
Weekly Hazard Rate
.05 .1 0
0 10 20 30 40 50
Weeks Elapsed Since Job Loss
.1
Difference in Weekly Hazard UI20-UI30
.05
0
-.05
-.1
0 10 20 30 40 50
Weeks Elapsed Since Job Loss
10
8
UI Tax Rate (%)
6
4
2
0
0 2 4 6 8 10
Benefit Ratio (100*UI Benefits Paid/Payroll)
Washington’
s UI Tax Schedule Perfect Experience Rating
Source: Washington State Joint Legislative Task Force on Unemployment Insurance Benefit Equity 2005
First observation: more than half of …rms are above the max rate or
below the min rate
Feldstein does not directly show that imperfect exp rating is to blame
for more temp layo¤s b/c not using variation in experience rating itself
Variation in tax rate on …rms from min/max thresholds for exp rating
Finds that imperfect subsidization accounts for 31% of all temp layo¤
unemployment, a very large e¤ect
See Krueger and Meyer (2002) for review of more recent studies,
which …nd similar results but smaller magnitudes
Calculations imply that only 1/3 of spells will occur with negative
balances, so most people still have good incentives while unemployed.
Total tax payments are less than half what they are in current system.
Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q5
Present Value Gain: -$95 +$22 -$67 +$94 +$468
Takeup low in many govt. programs. (UI, food stamps, EITC, etc.)
Provision of UI raises availability of risky jobs (e.g. tech jobs) and can
raise e¢ ciency in equilibrium
So if workers are risk averse, tradeo¤ may not be very hard – both
raise output and insure them better.
Classic reference is Shavell and Weiss (1979), who solved for optimal
path of bene…ts in a 3 period model.
Recent literature that is very active in this area: “new dynamic public
…nance” – optimal path of unemployment and disability programs.
Shimer and Werning (2008) – with perfect liquidity and CARA utility,
optimal bene…t path is ‡at
We do not have a model consistent with the data that can explain
both savings behavior pre-unemployment and search behavior
post-unemployment
Card & McCall (1994): test if weekend injuries lead to Monday e¤ect.
Other explantations:
Duration of injuries
To max social welfare, not desirable for those with high ψi to work.
Parsons (1980)
OLS regression:
LFPi = α + βDIrepratei + εi
where DIreprate is calculated using wage in 1966
1 million observations
Public Economics Lectures () Part 6: Social Insurance 160 / 178
Source: Mullen, Maestas, Strand (2012)
First stage:
DIi = a + φi examineri + νi
Second stage:
yi = α + βDIi + εi
Note that …rst stage coe¤s. φi are average DI allowance rates by
examiner
y e = a + βDI e + εe
Important to recognize that this is a LATE for people who are at the
margin of getting DI
May not be the same people as those who are on the margin with
respect to examiner decision
Might still have people with disutility ϕi > wi working when rejected
Public Economics Lectures () Part 6: Social Insurance 166 / 178
Methodological Note: Weak Instruments
y e = a + βDI e + εe
Leave out own observation for each i when estimating DI e in …rst stage
yi = a + bDI j 6=i + εi
Ex: if car industry declines over a …ve year period, assign a negative
employment shock to Michigan
6
MS
4
E[DI Apps/Pop | X]
AL AR
WV GA LA
2 KY FL
MT MO AZ
NCTN ME
MA
MISC
OK
0 OHRI
PA VT CT IL TXDE NY CA NV
NJ VA MD
IN IA OR CO NM
MN KS WA
WI NE
SD ND
-2 UT
NH
WY ID HI
AK
-4
-6
Coefficient = -0.094, se = 0.062, t = -1.51
-8
-8 -6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6 8
E[Change in Employment/Pop | X]
Source: Autor and Duggan 2003
6
MS
4
E[DI Apps/Pop | X]
KY AR LA
WV
2 GA
OK MI MT
ME TX
MO SC AL NM
IN NC FL
SD KS TN WA RI
0 OH
PA DE IL VA CO
MA
NY
OR
CAAZ NV
WY IA VT WI MD
ND NE MN CT NJ ID HI
NH AK
-2 UT
-4
-6
Coefficient = -0.262, se = 0.067, t = -3.90
-8
-8 -6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6 8
E[Change in Employment/Pop | X]
Source: Autor and Duggan 2003
6 MS
WV KY
4 AR
E[DI Apps/Pop | X]
AL LA
2 SC TNNC MO
IA
ME MA NM
INGA TX CO FL
WA OR MI MT
0 NH OKAZ NV
DE NY
SD
OH WIIL MN
PA CA ID
VT VA UT
NJ RI MD
KS WY NE ND
-2 CT HI
AK
-4
-6
Coefficient = -0.343, se = 0.130, t = -2.64
-8
-8 -6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6 8
E[Change in Employment/Pop | X]
Source: Autor and Duggan 2003
8 MS
6
AR
WV
4 AL
KY
E[DI Apps/Pop | X]
SC NC
ME TN
2 OK MO DE FL RI
GA NM
LA MT IN
KS
PA VTNY MI MA
0 WY SD
NV
NEVA AZ
IDOR OH
CTNH
TX IL
IAHI CACO
WA MDNJ
WI
AK MN
-2 ND UT
-4
-6
Coefficient = -0.849, se = 0.164 t = -5.18
-8
-8 -6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6 8
E[Change in Employment/Pop | X]
Source: Autor and Duggan 2003
Trace decline in LFP to the rise in DI over the past two decades via:
Harvard University
Fall 2012
2 Correcting Externalities
5 Empirical Applications
u (x ) + y d P (x )
Social welfare is
W = u (x ) + Z c (x ) d x
max u (x ) + Z px
Demand satis…es
u 0 (x D ) = p
Supply satis…es
c 0 (x S ) = p
PMB equals PMC in equilibrium:
u 0 (x D ) = c 0 (x S )
SMC=PMC+MD
Price
S=PMC
P*
PM
MD
D = PMB = SMB
0 Q* QM Quantity
dW = u 0 (x )∆x c 0 (x )∆x d ∆x
= d ∆x > 0 if ∆x < 0
Price
S=PMC=SMC
PM
MD
P*
D = PMB
SMB=PMB-MD
0 Q* QM Quantity
3 Regulation
4 Permits (cap-and-trade)
1 Cost of bargaining
Ex: air pollution – would require millions of agents to coordinate and
bargain
Impose tax t = MD (Q )
Practical limitations:
SMC=PMC+MD
Price S=PMC+t
S=PMC
$t
P*
P2
P1
D = PMB = SMB
0 Q* Q2 Q1 Quantity
SMBQ
Q* Pollution Reduction
Social optimum:
max B (Q ) C (Q )
First order condition:
C 0 (Q ) = B 0 (Q )
With no uncertainty, can obtain optimum with either quantity or price
policy.
Marginal cost lies between MCLB and MCUB , with mean value given
by MCmean .
Eθ [ B (Q ) C (Q , θ )] >? Eθ [B (Q (p )) C (Q (p ), θ )]
For a given p, the government knows the Q that will result exactly
since p = C 0 (Q )
q1 x1 + .. + qN xN wl + Z
max W (q ) = v (q ) d (q )
q
s.t. ∑ τi xi R
Analogous to Ramsey tax problem, but here SWF di¤ers from private
sector objective
Let θ = marginal social welfare gain from $1 of a lump sum tax and
λ = marginal value of relaxing agent’s budget constraint
Main result: can express optimal tax rate as Ramsey rate plus
Pigouvian correction.
Ramsey tax will a¤ect level of cons, which a¤ects optimal Pigouvian tax
Two approaches
Contingent valuation
Externality is convex
Pi = α + Pollutioni + Xi β + ei
Econometric problems
Also study home prices but use Clean Air Act as an exogenous change
in pollution.
Clean air act increased house values by $45 bil (5%) in treated
counties
Standard model assumes that with price controls, still have allocative
e¢ ciency
Taxes reduce demand for each self; can partly correct the internality.
Many believe that people do not save enough for retirement because
of myopia, self-control problems, etc.
25-75K Below Top Tax Cutoff 25-75K Above Top Tax Cutoff
Public Economics Lectures () Part 7: Public Goods and Externalities 66 / 111
Impact of 1999 Capital Pension Subsidy Reduction on Distribution of
Capital Pension Contributions for Prior Contributors
60
Retirement savings rate can change sharply when workers switch …rms
-5 0 5
Year Relative to Firm Switch
Total Savings
Pass-Through Rate: β = 90%
-5
(0.9%)
-5 0 5 10
Percent Change in Employer Pension Contributions
Public Economics Lectures () Part 7: Public Goods and Externalities 72 / 111
Chetty et al. (2012): Active vs. Passive Savers
0 20 40 60 80 100
Percentage of Other Years with Change in Individual Pension Contributions
Public Economics Lectures () Part 7: Public Goods and Externalities 74 / 111
Pensions Pass-Through of Employer Pension Changes for Firm-Switchers
by Frequency of Active Changes in Other Years
Pass-Through of Emp. Pensions to Total Pensions
.98
.96
.94
.92
.9
.88
0 20 40 60 80 100
Percentage of Other Years with Change in Individual Pension Contributions
Public Economics Lectures () Part 7: Public Goods and Externalities 75 / 111
Heterogeneity in Response to Capital Pension Subsidy by Wealth/Income Ratio
25
% with Sharp Response in 1999
20
15
10
0 .5 1 1.5
Wealth/Income Ratio in 1998
0 .5 1 1.5 2
Wealth/Income Ratio in Year Prior to Switch
Tax subsidies tend to in‡uence the behavior of those who are already
saving
More general lesson: economic tools (prices) may not be the best way
to change the behavior of non-optimizing agents
2 Samuelson Rule
5 Alternative Instruments
∑ Xh X
h
Xh X 8h
Person 1’
s
Consumption
Person 2’
s Consumption
Person 1’
s
Consumption
Person 2’
s Consumption
Utility of h is U h = U h (X h , G )
Production possibility F (X , G ) = 0
max ∑ βh U h (X h , G h )
h
s.t. F (∑ X h , ∑ G h ) 0 [λ]
h h
Lagrangian:
L= ∑ βh U h λF
First order conditions
[X h ] : βh UXh = λFX
[G h ] : βh UGh = λFG
UGh F
h
= G
UX FX
h
MRSGX = MRTGX 8h
max ∑ βh U h (X h , G )
h
s.t. F (∑ X h , ∑ G h ) 0 [λ]
h h
FOC’s:
[X h ] : βh UXh = λFX
[G ] : ∑ βh UGh = λFG
h
Uh FG
∑[ UGh ] = FX
h X
∑ MRSGX
h
= MRTGX
h
Individual h solves
max U h (X h , G 1 + .. + G h + .. + G H )
s.t. X h + G h = Y h .
Individual h solves:
max U h (Xh , Gh + G h )
X h ,G h
s.t. Xh + Gh = Yh
max U (X h , Gh + G h + T)
h h h
s.t. X + G = Y th
max U (X h , Zh + Z h)
h h h
s.t. X + Z = Y
2 Lab experiments
Lab experiments may not capture important motives for giving: warm
glow, prestige
Public Economics Lectures () Part 7: Public Goods and Externalities 98 / 111
Hungerman 2005
Key …ndings:
Public Economics Lectures () Part 7: Public Goods and Externalities 102 / 111
Public Economics Lectures () Part 7: Public Goods and Externalities 103 / 111
Marwell and Ames 1981
Only one group free-rode a lot: 1st year econ graduate students (20%
donation rate).
Shows that contributions to public goods fall over time but remain
positive
Public Economics Lectures () Part 7: Public Goods and Externalities 104 / 111
Expanding the Policy Set: Social Prices
Public Economics Lectures () Part 7: Public Goods and Externalities 105 / 111
Social Pressure: Existing Evidence
Public Economics Lectures () Part 7: Public Goods and Externalities 106 / 111
Public Economics Lectures () Part 7: Public Goods and Externalities 107 / 111
Public Economics Lectures () Part 7: Public Goods and Externalities 108 / 111
Social Prices as a Policy Tool: Research in Progress
Public Economics Lectures () Part 7: Public Goods and Externalities 109 / 111
Public Economics Lectures () Part 7: Public Goods and Externalities 110 / 111
Figure 2b: Turnaround times, DFL reweighted on pre-experiment turnaround
75%
25%
Control = 4 week: p = 0.00
Control = Social: p = 0.01
4 week = Cash: p = 0.00
0%
0 20 40 60
Days since invitation