Rimini Report Sharinglimitedresources03
Rimini Report Sharinglimitedresources03
Rimini Report Sharinglimitedresources03
James Robertson spoke from the following text in the session on this topic at the XXIX
Annual Conference of the Pio Manzu International Research Centre in Rimini, Italy on
18-20 October, 2003. The overall theme of the conference was “THE ECONOMICS OF
THE NOBLE PATH: FRATERNAL RIGHTS, THE CONVIVIAL SOCIETY, FAIR
SHARES FOR ALL” . The conference was dedicated to the “essential figures of Ernst
Schumacher and Ivan Illich, amidst many of their present-day heirs”.
For his “remarkable contribution to the promotion of a new economics grounded in social
and spiritual values” James was one of a number of speakers from around the world
who were invited to speak at the conference and presented with gold medals.
Further information about the Pio Manzu Centre, the conference and the award winners
is in Appendix I immediately after the paper. The text of the Citation for James’ award,
which was signed by Mikhail Gorbachev, is at Appendix II. Finally, the Endnotes contain
information supporting the paper.
1. INTRODUCTION
Thank you for inviting me to this conference. I am honoured, and I am delighted you
have dedicated it to E.F. Schumacher and Ivan Illich. I knew both of them personally,
and I was one of many people who got great stimulus and support from their work in the
1970s.
Schumacher Circle organisations are now doing valuable work around the world. 1 But
we have to recognise that Schumacher’s ideas – and Illich’s insights into the
systematically disabling nature of today’s institutions and professions - have hardly
begun to influence mainstream agendas. The course of world development is still
based on what Illich saw as the erosion of “the conditions necessary for a convivial life” 2
and what Schumacher called the “onward stampede”.3
Why is this? Was their thinking lacking in some important respect? Or have we failed to
act on it?
Both Illich and Schumacher were criticised for not dealing with political and institutional
aspects of change. I remember Illich responding that his task was to explain what was
wrong; it was for others to take the necessary action. For him the ideas were pre-
eminent. Schumacher’s view that “the task of our generation is one of metaphysical
reconstruction” underlined that his priority too was to redefine the meaning of central
ideas - like work. It is true – and important – that he set up the Intermediate Technology
Development Group, and personally supported the Scott Bader “common ownership”
company and the Soil Association. He saw these as “lifeboat institutions” - examples of
reconstructed ideas in action in the spheres of technology, business and farming. But
1
for him, like Illich, systematic institutional reconstruction to support metaphysical
reconstruction, was not a personal priority.4
It doesn’t make much sense to criticise Illich and Schumacher for this. Nobody can do
everything. Both men knew themselves well enough to know how best to use their time
and energies. We need to ask ourselves:
• why have we, who share their vision of a more people-centred and ecological
world, failed to adapt the institutions of society to it? and
• what should we do about that now?
In this paper, taking government and the money system as a case study, I shall try to
outline a possible answer to that question.
Established institutions embody dominant ideas, and transmit them as norms of desired
behaviour. For example, today’s economic institutions embody the idea that work
means a job with an employer and that normal people should work that way. But, as
pioneer systems thinkers in the 1970s like Stafford Beer pointed out, institutions are
dynamic systems programmed for survival. 6 So they act as barriers to change,
obstructing the conversion of new ideas from thinkers like Illich and Schumacher into
new norms of behaviour for most people. In that respect established institutions in
society correspond to what business consultants used to call the “soggy middle layer” –
conservative middle managements obstructing communication between forward-looking
leaders who recognise the need for change and bright younger people eager to bring it
in.
The money system has a particular significance. The way it works rewards some
activities and penalises others - at personal, local, national and global levels, in every
sector of economy and society. In a monetised world this is the principal way of
allocating resources. Money is the scoring system for the game of economic life,
alongside the rules provided by laws and other legal instruments. The nature of any
game and how it is played reflects what the scoring system rewards and penalises.
The reconstruction of today’s money system is now urgent. More and more people are
experiencing it as perverse - in terms of economic efficiency, social justice,
environmental sustainability, and physical and spiritual health. They see it as
responsible:
• for the systematic transfer of wealth from poor people and countries to rich ones,
• for the money-must-grow imperative that compels people to make money in socially
and environmentally damaging ways,
• for the diversion of economic effort and enterprise towards making money out of
money, and away from providing useful goods and services,
• for its systematic bias in favour of the people, organisations and nations who should
be managing it on behalf of us all, and
• for eroding the credibility of political democracy after 200 years of progress. 7
2
One constructive response has been the spread of “alternative” and “complementary”
monetary and financial innovations.8 These unofficial initiatives will become more
important, as people and businesses look for new ways of using their money. But today
I shall concentrate on mainstream money -
• the existing ways in which states handle it on behalf of their peoples,
• the perverse outcomes of those, and
• the changes that are needed.
1) The 20th century showed that a centralised socialist economy cannot work efficiently,
justly or ecologically. On the other hand, the idea of a free market economy based on
objective prices is a fantasy. In developed countries today taxation takes a third of the
total value of the economy (GDP) out of some activities, and public spending puts it back
into others. The taxes add to the cost of what is taxed and the public spending reduces
the cost of what it supports. This affects relative prices all through the economy. So the
price structure of any economy is bound to be skewed in favour of some things and
against others. The proverbial ‘level playing field’ is a mirage.
2) So the framework provided by the state institutions that deal with money must be
designed to encourage ways of using money that serve, not damage, the interests of
citizens now and in the future. Within such a framework:
a) the market economy, freely responding to money values, would tend to deliver
outcomes which combine economic efficiency with social justice and
environmental care;
b) the government would be able to let the market economy operate more freely,
with less intervention, than most economies today; and
c) citizens , who wished to do so, would find it easier than now to reduce their need
for goods and services bought from the market economy, and also therefore to
reduce the amount of money they need to earn by working as employees.
3) The state’s new role towards the market and the citizen should thus be to decolonise
and empower. Whether to call this a basically capitalist or basically socialist approach is
a matter of personal choice. It will aim to integrate economic efficiency with economic
justice. So you could call it both capitalist and socialist or neither, whichever you prefer.
4) Milton Friedman’s teaching that “there ain’t no such thing as a free lunch”
(TANSTAAFL) is false. Starting with the enclosure of the common land, modern
economies have given massive free lunches to powerful individuals, organisations - and
also nations. I shall say more about this and list some of today’s common resources
shortly. Their value should be shared as a source of public revenue, in place of the
economically, socially and environmentally damaging taxes we have now.
5) This will involve a shift from the idea of redistribution to the idea of predistribution. 9
Whereas redistributive taxes aim to correct the outcomes of economic activity,
predistributive taxes and charges will share the value of essential inputs to economic
activity. Whereas redistribution is dependency-reinforcing, predistribution will be
empowering. It will correct an underlying cause of economic injustice, inequality,
exclusion and poverty.
3
6) In a globalised world economy, we need to evolve institutions of governance
embodying those five principles at supranational and subnational levels, as well as
national level.
What changes do these background points and principles imply - first nationally, and
then internationally?
3. PRACTICAL CONSEQUENCES –
for the Financial and Monetary Functions of the State
These growing pressures on the existing tax base reinforce the economic, social and
environmental arguments for taxing “bads”, not “goods”.
Existing tax structures all round the world are, in fact, absurdly perverse.
• They fall heavily on employment and rewards for work and enterprise, and lightly on
the use of common resources. So they encourage all-round inefficiency of resource
use - over-use of natural resources (including energy and the environment's capacity
to absorb pollution), and under-employment and under-development of human
resources.
• Today’s taxes are also unfair and illogical. They penalise value added - the positive
contributions people make to society. They fail to penalise value subtracted; they
4
don’t make people and businesses pay for the value of the common resources they
use or monopolise, thereby preventing other people from using them.
• The present tax system makes it easy for rich people and businesses to escape, or
at least minimise, their tax obligations, because they can afford to use tax havens,
family trusts, and a range of other devices set up by expensive bankers, lawyers and
accountants.
Common resources are resources whose value is due to Nature and to the activities and
demands of society as a whole, and not to the efforts or skill of individual people or
organisations. Land is an obvious example. 13 The value of a particular land-site,
excluding the value of what has been built on it, is almost wholly determined by the
activities and plans of society around it. For example, when the route of the London
Underground Jubilee line was published, properties along the route jumped in value.
Access to them was going to be much improved. So, as a result of a public policy
decision, the owners of the properties received a £13bn windfall financial gain. They
had done nothing for it; they had paid nothing for it; they had been given a very large
free lunch. 14 In 1994, based on 1990 values, I calculated that the absence of a site-
value tax on land was costing UK taxpayers £50bn to £90bn a year in lost public
revenue. 15
By contrast, the auction three years ago of twenty-year licences to use the radio
spectrum for the third generation of mobile phones raised £22.5bn for the UK
government. The governments of Germany, France and Italy also raised very significant
sums from that common resource. 16
In a democratic age one would expect money, created in offical currencies as part of a
national or supranational money supply backed by governments, to be created by
professionally independent central monetary authorities (like the European Central
Bank) and given to governments or international government agencies to spend into
circulation on public purposes.
5
But that is far from what happens now. In the UK, for example, less than 5% of today's
national money supply is created debt-free by the Bank of England and the Royal Mint
as banknotes and coins. Over 95% is created by commercial banks out of thin air as
profit-making loans to their customers. J.K. Galbraith commented, “The process by
which banks create money is so simple that the mind is repelled. Where something so
important is involved, a deeper mystery seems only decent.” UK commercial banks
make over £20 billion a year in interest from this arrangement, while UK taxpayers
benefit from less than £3 billion a year in public revenue from the issue of banknotes and
coins.20
Estimated additional public revenue of about £45bn a year could be collected in the UK,
• if the commercial banks were prohibited from creating new money,
• and if the Bank of England took on responsibility for creating it,
• and if the Bank of England gave the money debt-free to the government to spend
into circulation.
(Corresponding estimates of potential extra public revenue are: Eurozone 160bn; USA
$114bn; Japan Y17trillion.)
This reform would improve the sharing of resources in many ways. To take one
example, a debt-free money supply would help to reduce the costs of economic
transactions and the levels of public and private debt. These are now at least partly due
to the fact that almost all the money we use has been created as interest-bearing debt
which has to be repaid. 21
Some opponents of reform claim that money in current bank accounts isn’t really money,
it’s only credit. But official monetary statistics and monetary policy-makers recognise
that it constitutes the main part of the money supply. In fact, recognising it as money
exactly reflects what happened in the 19th century when paper banknotes, and not just
gold coins, were recognised to be money and commercial banks were no longer allowed
to create money by issuing them. The Bank of England’’s banknotes may still say "I
promise to pay... ". But that is just a historical survival. Everyone knows that banknotes
now are not just credit notes. They are cash.
6
Second, support for a basic income (or Citizen’s Income) continues to grow, especially
in Europe but in other countries too. 23 It would be paid to all citizens as of right, out of
public revenue. It would include state pensions and child allowances, it would replace
many other existing social benefits, and it would eliminate almost all tax allowances, tax
reliefs and tax credits. It would recognise that, in a society of responsible citizens, some
of the public revenue arising from the value of common resources should be shared
directly among them. Politicians and government officials now pay huge sums in
contracts and subsidies to private-sector business and finance to provide public
services. Much of that public money could be distributed directly to citizens to spend for
themselves in a market economy responsive to their needs – and also to make it easier
for them to develop paid or unpaid work of their own, if they wished to reduce their
dependence on earnings as employees. 24
The development of international institutions for dealing with world public revenue, public
spending, and monetary management should be based similarly on sharing the value of
common resources.
In 1995 the Commission on Global Governance recognised the need for global taxation
“to service the needs of the global neighbourhood”. 25 It proposed making nations pay for
use of global commons, including:
• ocean fishing, sea-bed mining, sea lanes, flight lanes, outer space, and the
electro-magnetic spectrum; and for
• activities that pollute and damage the global environment, or cause hazards
beyond national boundaries, such as emissions of CO2 and CFCs, oil spills, and
dumping wastes at sea.
The Commission also recognised the urgent need for international monetary reform in a
globalised world economy. 26
Since then there has been growing criticism of the present international monetary
system based on the 'dollar hegemony' of the United States. Here are two examples
from recent reports, one from Asia and one from Ireland.
1) "The dollar is a global monetary instrument that the United States, and only
the United States, can produce. .... World trade is now a game in which the
US produces dollars and the rest of the world produces things that dollars
can buy.27
2) The rest of the world pays a total annual subsidy (or 'tribute'!) to the US of at
least $400bn a year for using the dollar as the main global currency. A
Pentagon analyst has justified this as payment to the US for keeping world
order. Others see it as a means by which the richest country in the world
compels poorer ones to pay for its unsustainable consumption of global
resources. 28 29
7
prevent national governments manipulating the value of their currencies in order to
distort the terms of international trade in their own favour.
Revenue from global taxes and global money creation would then provide stable
sources of finance for global expenditures, including international peace-keeping
programmes. Some of the revenue could also be distributed to all nations according to
population size, reflecting the right of every person in the world to a global “citizen's
income" based on fair shares of the value of global resources.
This approach:
• would encourage environmentally sustainable development worldwide;
• it would generate a much needed source of revenue for the United Nations;
• it would provide substantial financial transfers to developing countries by right and
without strings, as payments for the rich countries’ disproportionate use of world
resources;
• it would help to liberate developing countries from dependence on grants and loans
from institutions like the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund which the
rich countries now dominate;
• it would help to solve the problem of Third World debt;
• it would recognise the shared status of all people as citizens of the world; and
• by helping to reduce the spreading sense of injustice in a globalised world, it would
contribute to global security.
5. IN CONCLUSION
Support for all the reforms I have mentioned has been growing. But up to now it has
been fragmented. Different people have promoted each on its own merits, and different
interests have opposed each because, by itself, it would disadvantage them. These
reform proposals now need to be developed as integrated parts of a bigger project, to
reconstruct the role of money in world society.
I hope that this suggests the nature and the scale of the challenge for all our institutions.
The ancient Greek poet Archilochus said: “The fox knows many things, but the
hedgehog knows one big thing”. 30 Our institutionalised society today has too much of the
fox. It splits our ways of life and thought into separate specialisms, careers, academic
disciplines, professions, and departments of government.31 Above all, it doesn’t know
how to reintegrate politics and economics and science with ethics.
That is why, in these critical breakthrough years, the initial drive for worldwide
institutional reconstruction is coming from active citizens and citizen groups. But, if we
are to change course successfully to what Schumacher called “the one and only
direction of development that would give sense and meaning to our life on Earth”, 32 a
bolder and more constructive response must come from leading people in all the
established institutions and professions .
8
APPENDIX I
The Centre's primary objective is to design and conduct global investigations into
specific issues, drawing upon a broad range of expertise which it seeks to make
available to those in the public, private and non-profit sectors whose task it is to devise
prompt, effective action strategies.
The main aims of the Pio Manzù Centre are thus to act as:
• a promoter of specific research projects, through the implementation of forms of
synergistic collaboration between researchers of different cultural and
professional backgrounds
• a link between the world of research and the practical socio-political decision
makers, providing a forum for a free and frank exchange of views and expertise
on both sides.
Founded in 1969 by a group of avant-garde scholars, the Pio Manzù Centre has set up
its own network of specialists, a pool of researchers operating in Bologna, London,
Darmstadt, Frankfurt, Boston and Moscow.
As a non-profit-making organization, the efforts of the Centre today are mainly targeted
at making a major contribution towards the up-to-date, functional study of the
interactions between technological and industrial development and its impact on the
human and cultural environment.
Over the years, the Centre has designed and conducted studies of major innovative
significance in the fields of scientific and technological research.
From this penchant for cultural exchanges and confrontation stems the true mission of
the Pio Manzù Centre which, through the constant quest for common interdisciplinary
languages across a whole range of spheres of interest, seeks above all to establish the
centrality of man, both in terms of his creative and spiritual capabilities and in the setting
of a meaningful relationship with nature and the environment.
The Pio Manzù Centre thus offers public and private decision-making centres a complex,
well-differentiated framework of collaboration and integration, much appreciated by a
highly authoritative international clientele.
Every year, the work of analysis and design conducted by the Centre's own research
staff with invaluable contributions from scholars and researchers from numerous
academic institutions is presented in the context of the Pio Manzù International
Conference.
9
This prestigious conference, which is held every year in Rimini in October, marks the
culmination of the Centre's collaborative research effort and offers an opportunity for
joint reflection on the changes taking place in the global context and on the prospects of
mankind.”
The theme of the XXIX Annual Conference in October, 2003 was “The economics of the
noble path: fraternal rights, the convivial society, fair shares for all”. The conference was
dedicated to the “essential figures of Ernst Schumacher and Ivan Illich, amidst many of
their present-day heirs”. Its four Workshop sessions were on “Sharing limited resources
and a change of course”; “Assets and hardships: proposals for the invention of a
fraternal sharing of benefits”; “Water or oil? The assets of living nature are not up for
sale”; and “Surviving and being truly human”. The proceedings will be published by the
Pio Manzu Centre in due course.
Gold medals were presented to the following, nominated by the Pio Manzu Centre’s
International Scientific Committee (President: Mikhail Gorbachev):
Samir Amin, Franco Abruzzo, Zygmunt Bauman, Lester Brown, Ernesto
Cardenal, Diego Della Valle, Emma Nicholson, Martha Nussbaum, Corrado
Passera, James Robertson, Dominick Salvatore, Enzo Tiezzi, Mario Vargas
Llosa, Giancarlo Elia Valori, Derek Walcott, Jean Zeigler, and posthumously the
late Sergio Vieira De Mello.
10
APPENDIX II
[Citation]
---------------------------------------------------------------------------
James Robertson
After working as an aide to Prime Minister Harold Macmillan on
his “Wind of Change” African tour in 1960, and as a director of
interbank research, James Robertson came to see that
“decolonising” today’s overpowerful institutions must be part of
the transition to a democratic, environmentally benign post-
modern world.
[signed]
Mikhail Gorbachev, President
Rimini, 19 October 2003
Endnotes
1
Schumacher Circle organisations in the UK include the Schumacher Society, Schumacher Book Service,
Schumacher College, Centre for Alternative Technology, Intermediate Technology, Soil Association, New
Economics Foundation, Resurgence Magazine, Green Books, and India Development Group. There are
also a Schumacher Society and an Intermediate Technology in the USA. Schumacher Briefings Nos 1, 4, 5
and 9 all deal with questions about money and the sharing of resources – Schumacher Society, The Create
Centre, B-Bond Warehouse, Smeaton Road, Bristol BS1 6XN, England - www.schumacher.org.uk
2
The Right to Useful Unemployment, page 8.
3
I am grateful to Diana Schumacher for confirming that Schumacher used this phrase, and the variant
“forward stampede”, in a number of lectures and talks.
11
4
It has been pointed out - by Peter Etherden in “The Schumacher Enigma”, Fourth World Review, 1999:93 -
that the institutions dealing with money are a conspicuous example of this. Working with John Maynard
Keynes and J.K. Galbraith after the second World War, Schumacher was seen as an up-and-coming
authority on international finance and currency reform. So why in later life, in Small Is Beautiful and other
books, did he say so little about how the present money system ties most people to unreconstructed ways of
living and working and thinking?
5
For fuller background see:
• James Robertson, The New Economics of Sustainable Development: A briefing for policy-makers
(written for the European Commission), published 1999 by:
Kogan Page, London,
Editions Apogee, Paris (as Changer d’Economie: ou la Nouvelle Economie du
Developpement Durable ), and
Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg.
• James Robertson,Transforming Economic Life: A Millennial Challenge, Schumacher Briefing No1,
Green Books, 1998 - www.greenbooks.co.uk (Publication of the Russian edition was organised
by Dr Tanya Roskoshnaya, Land and Public Welfare Foundation, St Petersburg, now with UN
Habitat in Nairobi; and publication of the Japanese edition was organised by Dr Takashi Iwami,
Japan Renaissance Institute .)
6
Stafford Beer, Designing Freedom , John Wiley, 1974, p.2.
7
The following two books provide good background.
• David Korten, When Corporations Rule the World (second edition), Kumarian Press and Berrett-
Koehler publishers, 2001. Part IV is on “A Rogue Financial System”.
• Frances Hutchinson, Mary Mellor and Wendy Olsen in The Politics of Money: Towards
Sustainability and Economic Democracy, Pluto Press, 2002, provide a constructive response.
8
These include:
• “complementary”, “parallel” and “community” currencies like LETSystems and time banks;
• the development of “digital” payment systems in support of those and other currencies, using the
internet, mobile phones etc;
• local community financial enterprises like community development funds, community banks, credit
unions and microcredit banks (eg Grameen Bank); and
• the socially responsible and ethical use of private money, such as fair trading, and ethical and
green consumption and investment.
9
I owe this thought to Joseph Huber, co-author of “Creating New Money” (see Note 20).
10
In technical terms, functions 1) and 2) comprise the fiscal functions of the state, and function 3) is the
monetary function.
11
The state is also responsible for regulating private financial enterprises. Scandals in recent years (e.g.
Enron, Arthur Andersen, WorldCom, Merrill Lynch) have underlined the importance of this task. But it is not
a topic that this paper is discussing.
12
See Tax Justice Network (www.taxjustice.net).
13
Sources of information on Land Value Taxation include:
• Fred Harrison, Centre for Land Policy Studies, 7 Kings Road, Teddington, TW11 0QB, England.
• Peter Gibb, Henry George Foundation, 58 Haymarket Terrace, Edinburgh EH12 5LA, UK,
www.HenryGeorgeFoundation.org
• Alanna Hartzok, Earth Rights Institute, Box 328, Scotland, PA, 17254, USA. www.earthrights.net
• Jeffery Smith, Geonomy Society, www.progress.org/geonomy
14
Don Riley,Taken for a Ride: Trains, Taxpayers and the Treasury, Centre for Land Policy Studies,
2001(see note 13).
10
James Robertson, Benefits and Taxes: A Radical Strategy, New Economics Foundation, 1994.
16
In “Manna from Heaven: Radio Rent Windfalls and the Tax Conversion Fund” in Geophilos 03(1), Spring
2003, from Centre for Land Policy Studies (see note 13), Fred Harrison celebrates the thinking of Nobel
prize-winning economist William Vickrey as the origin of this auction, and points out that the socialisation of
community-created rental values combined with the full privatisation of untaxed earned wages and saving s
could remove the ceiling artificially imposed on the capitalist economy by deadweight taxes.
17
A great deal of work has been done in recent years on energy and environmental taxation. Much of it
points towards shifting the burden of taxes away from useful enterprise and employment on to the use of
energy and the capacity of the environment to absorb pollution. For example, the EU carbon/energy tax
proposal of the 1990s would have used revenue from taxes on fossil fuels to reduce taxes on employment.
Valuable sources of information include:
12
• Paul Ekins, Head of Environment Group, Policy Studies Institute, 100 Park Village East,London
NW1 3SR. www.psi.org.uk
• Green Budget News: European Newsletter on Environmental Fiscal Reform www.foes-ev.de
• Timothy O’Riordan (ed), Ecotaxation, Earthscan, 1997.
• Durning A. and Bauman Y, Tax Shift, Northwest Environment Watch, Seattle, 1998.
• Hamond, M.J. et al, Tax Waste, Not Work: How Changing What We Tax Can Lead To A Stronger
Economy And A Cleaner Environment, Redefining Progress, San Francisco, 1997.
18
Useful sources include:
• Michael Rowbotham, The Grip of Death: A study of modern money, debt slavery and destructive
economics, Jon Carpenter Publishing, Oxfordshire, 1998,
• David Boyle, The Money Changers: currency reform from Aristotle to e-cash, Earthscan, 2002, and
19
• Bernard Lietaer, The Future of Money, Random House, 2000.
The creators of money can spend this profit into circulation, as medi eval monarchs and local rulers spent
the “seigniorage” from minting and issuing coins. Or they can give it away, as the Bank of England and the
Royal Mint now give the UK government a proportion of the value of new banknotes and new coin. Or they
can lend it at interest, as today’s commercial banks lend their customers money they have created for that
purpose. Or they can lend it interest-free to finance public investment, as recent UK parliamentary motions
have proposed the Bank of England should do.
20
For this and the following paragraphs see Joseph Huber and James Robertson, "Creating New Money: A
monetary reform for the information age", New Economics Foundation, London, 2000 -
www.neweconomics.org. (Prof. Dr. Joseph Huber is at the Institut für Soziologie, Martin-Luther-Universität,
D - 06099 Halle, Germany.)
21
A fuller list of the benefits of monetary reform would include the following:
1) Existing taxation and government debt could be reduced, or public spending could be increased.
2) The value of a common resource - the national money supply - would become a source of public
revenue rather than private profit. That would remove an economic injustice.
3) Withdrawing this hidden subsidy to the commercial b anks would result in a freer market for money,
a more competitive banking industry, and a more efficient economy.
4) A debt-free money supply would help to reduce the costs of economic transactions and the levels
of public and private debt. These are now at least partly due to the fact that almost all the money
we use has been created as interest-bearing debt which has to be repaid.
5) The economy would become more stable. Banks want to lend more and bank customers want to
borrow more at the peaks of the business cycle and less in the troughs. When, as now, the money
in circulation depends on how much the banks lend, the results are “pro-cyclical”. Booms and
busts are automatically amplified.
6) Central banks would be better able to exert “anti-cyclical” monetary control if they themselves
created the new money entering the economy. Controlling inflation indirectly, as now, by raising
the costs of borrowing from banks, is itself inflationary - as well as damaging to many people and
businesses.
22
Norman Myers, Perverse Subsidies: Tax $s Undercutting Our Economies and Environments Alike, IISD,
Winnipeg, Canada, 1998.
23
Sources of information about basic income include:
• Basic Income European Network (BIEN), Prof. Philippe Van Parijs, Chaire Hoover d'éthique
économique et sociale, Université catholique de Louvain, Place Montesquieu 3, B-1348 Louvain-
la-Neuve, Belgium. e-mail: bien@basicincome.org
• South African New Economics Foundation (SANE), Aart Roukens de Lange and Margaret Legum,
web: www.sane.org.za, e-mail: sane@sane.org.za
• CORI Justice Commission, Fr Sean Healy, Bloomfield Avenue, Dublin 4, Ireland,
www.cori.ie/justice
• Citizen's Income Trust, Malcolm Torry, P.O. Box 26586, London SE3 7WY web:
www.citizensincome.org, e-mail: info@citizensincome.org
24
A connected point is about spending the revenue from particular sources on specified purposes. The
technical term for this is “hypothecation”.
• An example was the EU proposal to spend revenue from fossil fuel energy taxes on reducing
employment taxes.
• Road traffic congestion charges are expected to be more acceptable if the revenue is spent on
improving public transport.
13
• An energy tax hits poor people relatively harder than rich people. That regressive effect can be
reversed by distributing the revenue as “ecobonuses” to everyone in the area covered by the tax.
(For examples see Ecological Tax Reform Even If Germany Has To Go It Alone, German Institute
for Economic Research, Economic Bulletin, Vol.37, Gower, Aldershot, 1994; and E.U. von
Weizsacker, Earth Politics, Zed Books,1994.) Such ecobonuses could contribute to a Citiz en’s
Income.
25
Commission on Global Governance, Our Global Neighbourhood, Oxford University Press, 1995.
26
Another important contribution is Hazel Henderson, Beyond Globalization: Shaping a Sustainable Global
Economy, Kumarian Press (for the New Economics Foundation), 1999.
27
Henry C K Liu , US Dollar Hegemony Has Got To Go, Asia Times Online Co Ltd, 2002.
28
Richard Douthwaite, Defense and the Dollar, 2002 and Feasta, Climate and Currency: Proposals for
Global Monetary Reform , 2002, prepared for the Johannesburg World Summit on Sustainable Development.
Details of both from The Foundation for the Economics of Sustainability, 9 Lower Rathmines Road, Dublin 6,
Republic of Ireland; e-mail: feasta@anu.ie; web: www.feasta.org
29
Two further quotations in similar vein are:
• "To build up reserves, poor countries have to borrow dollars from the US at interest rates as high
as 18% and lend it back to the US in the form of Treasury Bonds at 3% interest." Romilly Greenhill
and Ann Pettifor, The United States as a HIPC (heavily indebted prosperous country) - how the
poor are financing the rich, New Economics Foundation, London, 2002; www.neweconomics.org
• “At the root of this new form of imperialism is the exploitation of governments by a single
government, that of the United States via the central banks and multilateral control institutions of
intergovernmental capital... [This] has turned the older form of imperialism into a super
imperialism”. Michael Hudson, Super Imperialism: The Origin and Fundamentals of World
Domination, Pluto Press, 2003, pp23-24.
30
In a celebrated essay on “The Hedgehog and the Fox” in Russian Thinkers, 1978, the political philosopher
Isaiah Berlin discussed Tolstoy as an example of the tension between the monist and pluralist visions of the
world.
31
The British Prime Minister, Tony Blair, has found it difficult to achieve his proclaimed aim of “joined-up
government”.
32
E.F. Schumacher, A guide for the perplexed , Jonathan Cape 1977, p. 147.
14