Fiscal Regime in Spain
Fiscal Regime in Spain
Fiscal Regime in Spain
A MARKOV-SWITCHING APPROACH
Working Paper
This version: October 2014
Julián RAMAJO-HERNÁNDEZ
Alejandro RICCI-RISQUETE
Universidad de Extremadura
Departamento de Economía
06006 Badajoz (España, UE)
Tel.: +34 924 28 93 00 / Fax: +34 924 27 25 09
E-mail: ramajo@unex.es ; alericci@unex.es
Francisco DE CASTRO
European Commission
DG EFIN
Unit F4
CHAR 12/204
B-1049 Brussels/Belgium
Tel.: +32 2 298 02 53
E-mail: francisco.de-castro@ec.europa.eu
Abstract: In this paper we study fiscal regime shifts for the Spanish Economy, using a new quarterly
dataset of Spanish public finance variables for the period 1986-2012 (De Castro et al., 2014), within a
Markov-Switching framework. First, we estimate fiscal policy rules to characterize the behavior of
Spanish fiscal policymakers and, second, we estimate a vector autoregressive model to analyze the effects
of a shock to the primary deficit-to-GDP ratio on the Spanish economy.
Our results indicate that fiscal policymakers do not seem to track the state of public finances and the
evolution of economic activity in both identified regimes; however, they appear to focus on the level of
extraordinary expenditure, the responsiveness to which is higher in the first regime than in the second
one. Increases in the primary deficit do not succeed in stimulating economic activity; rather, unexpected
upsurges in the primary deficit-to-GDP ratio harm economic activity (non-Keynesian effect) in the second
regime, which prevails since the ratification of the Maastricht Treaty.
Keywords: Fiscal regimes, Fiscal rules, Markov-Switching, VAR, Spain
1 Introduction
Traditionally, both politicians and economists have agreed on the important role of
fiscal policy as an effective tool in issues such as tax collection, income redistribution
and macroeconomic stabilization. Regarding the latter objective, how can fiscal policy
be employed as a stabilizing instrument in the short run without compromising the
sustainability of public finances in the long run? If so, what is the best mode to achieve
both of them: discretionary measures or fiscal rules? If found, do the effects of
discretionary or regulated fiscal policy measures depend on the expansionary or
recessionary state of the economy?
Contrary to what it might seem, the fiscal performance of the EU has been
slightly better than that of some advanced economies as the USA or Japan since the
beginning of the current international financial and economic crisis. In Table 1, we
present some data on that matter in the European Union of Fifteen (EU15), the USA and
Japan between 2007 and 2012, which can corroborate our statement. In that period, the
annual deficit-to-GDP ratios and the annual debt-to-GDP ratios of the EU15 were lower
than those of the USA and Japan. In the same vein, the increase in the debt-to-GDP
ratio amounted to around 31 percentage points in the EU15 for that period, which again
contrasts favorably with the rise of about 38 percentage points in the USA.
Given these reasons, why is the perceived fiscal vulnerability of the EU higher
than that of other advances economies as the USA or Japan? Following Campa (2012),
the EU as a whole and each of its Member States are more vulnerable to a sustainability
analysis of their public finances because of three distinctive concerns: (1) notable
differences in debt levels across the EU15, (2) debt financing and its interest payments
in the short term, and (3) poor growth prospects for diluting the debt burden.
—2—
The EU has tried to provide convincing answers to those concerns by several
ways. According to the orientation of economic policy measures, the responses to the
crisis can be divided in two groups: a first one, which ranges from 2007 to 2009,
defined by Keynesian-inspired measures; and a second one, which extends from 2010
on, characterized by a more comprehensive approach. In an attempt to classify the
measures contained in that second broad group, three areas can be distinguished:
mechanisms to provide financial support to individual EU countries, measures to
enhance fiscal policy coordination among EU Member States, provisions aimed to
foster fiscal discipline and adopt fiscal consolidation packages, and country-specific
measures to boost sustainable growth.
—3—
public finances and macroeconomic stability in the medium to long term
simultaneously.
The objective of this paper is twofold. On the one hand, we analyze the fiscal
behavior of the Spanish economy by estimating fiscal policy rules in which the
government reacts to the public debt and the business cycle. Following Afonso and
Toffano (2013), we apply Markov-Switching techniques to allow for a shift in the
parameters of the fiscal policy rules in order to account for the non-linearity of fiscal
policy and its relation to different political preferences. On the other hand, we study the
response the Spanish economy to fiscal shocks by estimating a Markov-Switching VAR
model that includes macroeconomic, fiscal and financial variables.
Table 1. Fiscal performance in some advanced economies. Deficits and debt as a ratio of GDP.
2007-2012
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
General Government Overall Balance (% GDP)
Austria -1.0 -1.0 -4.1 -4.5 -2.5 -2.5
Belgium -0.1 -1.1 -5.6 -3.9 -3.9 -4.0
Denmark 4.8 3.3 -2.8 -2.7 -2.0 -4.2
Finland 5.3 4.3 -2.7 -2.8 -1.1 -2.3
France -2.8 -3.3 -7.6 -7.1 -5.3 -4.9
Germany 0.2 -0.1 -3.1 -4.2 -0.8 0.1
Greece -6.8 -9.9 -15.6 -10.8 -9.6 -6.3
Ireland 0.1 -7.3 -13.8 -30.5 -13.1 -7.6
Italy -1.6 -2.7 -5.4 -4.3 -3.7 -2.9
Netherlands 0.2 0.5 -5.6 -5.1 -4.4 -4.1
Portugal -3.2 -3.7 -10.2 -9.9 -4.4 -6.4
Spain 1.9 -4.5 -11.2 -9.7 -9.6 -10.8
Sweden 3.5 2.2 -1.0 0.0 0.0 -0.7
United Kingdom -2.8 -5.0 -11.3 -10.0 -7.8 -7.9
EU-15 Average -0.2 -2.0 -7.1 -7.5 -4.9 -4.6
United States -2.7 -6.5 -12.9 -10.8 -9.7 -8.3
Japan -2.1 -4.1 -10.4 -9.3 -9.9 -10.1
General Government Gross Debt (% GDP)
Austria 60.2 63.8 69.2 72.3 72.8 74.1
Belgium 84.0 89.2 95.7 95.6 97.8 99.8
Denmark 27.1 33.4 40.7 42.7 46.4 45.6
Finland 35.2 33.9 43.5 48.7 49.2 53.6
France 64.2 68.2 79.2 82.4 85.8 90.2
Germany 65.4 66.8 74.5 82.4 80.4 81.9
Greece 107.2 112.9 129.7 148.3 170.3 156.9
Ireland 24.9 44.2 64.4 91.2 104.1 117.4
Italy 103.3 106.1 116.4 119.3 120.8 127.0
Netherlands 45.3 58.5 60.8 63.4 65.7 71.3
Portugal 68.4 71.7 83.7 94.0 108.4 123.8
Spain 36.3 40.2 54.0 61.7 70.4 85.9
Sweden 40.2 38.8 42.6 39.4 38.6 38.3
United Kingdom 43.7 51.9 67.1 78.5 84.3 88.8
EU-15 Average 57.5 62.8 73.0 80.0 85.4 89.6
United States 64.4 73.3 86.3 95.2 99.4 102.7
Japan 183.0 191.8 210.2 216.0 230.3 238.0
Note: EU15 averages exclude Luxembourg data.
Sources: IMF Fiscal Monitor, October 2013; Own calculations.
—4—
The rest of the paper is structured as follows. In Section 2, we briefly review the
recent literature on fiscal rules that focuses on European countries. In Section 3, we
explain the methodology used in this paper, both the analytical and empirical
framework and the database. In section 4, we present the results for the different fiscal
regimes. Finally, in Section 5, we summarize our findings and conclude.
2 Literature review
Since the publication of the famous article “Discretionary versus Policy Rules in
Practice” by John Taylor in 1993, where he proposed a simple monetary policy rule
which gives interest rates as a function of inflation and output deviations, much has
been said about the use of rules in policymaking, especially on the monetary side.
Among the advantages of policy rules are their simple specification, their potential to
differentiate between discretionary and rule-based policy behavior and their use as a
benchmark for policy evaluation (Thams, 2007). Nevertheless, their main disadvantage
follows from one of their benefits: their simplicity may not be adequate to deal with
complex situations like the current international economic crisis. All in all, policy rules
are tools that can guide the action of economic policymakers, as they explicitly link the
instruments to the objectives, but the instruments, the objectives and the links can
change over time.
On the fiscal side, many advanced countries introduced fiscal rules over the last
25 years, in the form of golden rules, balanced budget rules or deficit and debts targets;
the EU’s Maastricht criteria and the SGP are usually put as examples. Following
Badinger (2009), two basic reasons support the introduction of fiscal rules: on the one
hand, to ensure sustainability of fiscal policy through avoiding excessive deficits and
unsound policies and, on the other hand, to improve macroeconomic stability by
limiting the room for discretionary fiscal policy. Both academics and policymakers
acknowledge that the Maastricht criteria together with the SGP led to fiscal
consolidations in many EU countries in the nineties and thus served as a discipline
device for fiscal authorities.
This move towards “rules rather than authorities” (in the terminology of
Friedman, 1948) reflects a fundamental shift in the paradigm of fiscal policy. In this
sense, according to the behavior of fiscal authorities, we can distinguish two types of
fiscal policies: an “active” (non-Ricardian) fiscal policy and a “passive” (Ricardian)
fiscal policy (Leeper, 1991). Fiscal policy is said to be “active” when is does not
stabilize public debt, and “passive” when it does stabilize government debt. In this latter
case, primary budget balances react to changes in public debt to safeguard fiscal
solvency, in a way that future fiscal receipts cover the cost of current outstanding
government liabilities.
The applied study of fiscal rules has been methodologically developed from two
different perspectives: panel analysis and Markov-Switching regressions. Those papers
—5—
present and test some kind of fiscal policy reaction functions where the primary budget
balance reacts not only to the public debt, in order to ensure fiscal sustainability, but
also to the output gap, in order to smooth business cycle fluctuations. In this section, we
briefly review those recent studies that focus on European countries.
Marneffe et al. (2011) analyze the effects of fiscal rules on the fiscal stance by
estimating panel-regressions for the 16 euro-area countries for the period 1995-2008.
They conclude that an increase in debt gives rise to lower total balances, but also to
higher primary balances, which reflects a stabilizing mechanism.
The second group of studies allows for the endogenous estimation of changes in
fiscal policy regimes, which may occur over time, by means of Markov-Switching
regressions. Several types of fiscal rules have been estimated: first, a fiscal rule whereby
the primary deficit-to-GDP ratio adjusts to stabilize the debt-to-GDP ratio; second, a
fiscal rule whereby one fiscal instrument (public expenditure-to-GDP ratio or public
receipts-to-GDP ratio) reacts to the other, the government debt-to-GDP ratio and the
output gap, and; third, a fiscal rule which combines the two last approaches, i.e. the
primary deficit-to-GDP ratio responds to changes in the public debt-to-GDP ratio, the
output gap and other variables.
For several EU countries, in the aim of the first branch, Claeys (2006) test the
fiscal sustainability of Germany, France, Italy, Great Britain, Spain, the Netherlands and
Austria, as well as the United States and Japan, with annual data from the 60s or 70s to
2003. He finds a significant stabilizing reaction to debt, although the model is not able
to reject insolvency for Germany, France and Japan. Moreover, he observes that fiscal
policy shifts are mainly related to debt.
—6—
Within the second strand of Markov-Switching regression papers, Thams (2007)
investigate the relationship between fiscal instruments and public debt for Germany
(1970Q1-2003Q4) and Spain (1986Q1-2003Q4). He finds that both Germany and Spain
generally exhibit a positive relationship between government revenues and debt, and
that both countries changed their policy behavior at the end of the nineties because of
rising debt-to-GDP ratios. However, this change in policy behavior differs between the
two countries and seems to be non-permanent in the case of Germany.
In terms of the third strand, Afonso and Toffano (2013) assess the existence of
fiscal regime shifts in the UK, Germany and Italy, using a new quarterly fiscal data set
for the periods 1970Q4-2010Q4, 1979Q4-2010Q3 and 1983Q3-2010Q4 respectively.
Their results prove that in the UK fiscal policy tended to be more active for the periods
1992-1996 and as of 2007, in Germany fiscal regimes have been overly passive,
supporting more fiscal sustainability throughout the sample period, and in Italy a more
passive fiscal behavior is unveiled in the run-up to EMU.
3 Methodology
—7—
yt 0 1 yt 1 (1 1 ) Et yt 1 2[it Et t 1 ] 3bt 4 pdt ty (1)
where yt is the output gap, t the inflation rate, it the nominal interest rate,
[it Et t 1 ] the real interest rate, bt the stock of public debt, and pdt the primary (i.e.
net of interest payments) deficit defined as public spending minus receipts. The latter
two fiscal variables are defined as a ratio of GDP. ty is an i.i.d. distributed demand
shock. Et is the expectation operator. According to that specification, the output gap is
explained by a weighted average of its past and futures values, the contemporary real
interest rate, the public debt-to-GDP ratio and the primary deficit-to-GDP ratio.
where the variables are defined as above and t is an i.i.d. distributed inflation shock.
According to that equation, the inflation depends on its lagged and expected values and
the output gap. Note that fiscal policy does not affects inflation, contrary to what
happens in the IS curve, where monetary and fiscal policies influence the evolution of
the output gap.
where the variables are defined as above and t is the rate of return on public debt.
The fourth equation is the Taylor-type monetary policy rule, whose form is:
where the nominal interest rate depends on past, present and expectations on the future
values of inflation and the output gap. In the words of Leeper (1991), monetary policy is
said to be “active” when real interest rates rise in response to higher inflation, that is,
when the sensitivity of nominal interest rates to inflation is higher than one
( 1 2 3 1); on the contrary, it is “passive” when 1 2 3 1 . According to
Svensson (1999), since output is usually considered a good predictor of future inflation,
interest rates usually rise in response to a positive output gap ( 4 5 6 1 ).
The fifth equation is a simple fiscal policy rule, which can be expressed as:
where the primary deficit-to-GDP ratio depends on past debt-to-GDP ratio, the current
output gap and inflation. Again, in the words of Leeper (1991), fiscal policy is said to be
“active” (non-Ricardian) when it does not stabilize the public debt, that is, when the
—8—
reaction of fiscal policy to debt dynamics ( 1 ) is negative or smaller than the real
interest rate, monetary policy will have to reduce interest rates in response to an
inflation shock in order to stabilize the public debt; on the contrary, it is “passive”
(Ricardian) when the reaction of fiscal policy to debt dynamics ( 1 ) is positive and
higher than to the real interest rate.
where pdt is the nominal primary deficit-to-GDP ratio, bt the nominal debt-to-GDP
ratio, pg t the primary expenditure (i.e. net of interest payments) to GDP ratio gap
defined as the current expenditure minus the trend expenditure, yt the output gap
calculated as the current output minus the trend output, t the year-on-year inflation,
and t a normal mean zero-constant variance error term. For computing the gaps, the
trend components are obtained applying the Hodrick-Prescott filter (smoothing
parameter equals to 1600) to the log of real expenditure and the log of real GDP
respectively, whereas inflation is calculated by using the GDP deflator.
The selection of the variables that are contained in our fiscal rule is not trivial.
According to Thams (2007), the inclusion of the lagged debt-to-GDP ratio is
compulsory for econometric and economic reasons: on the one hand, there would be an
endogeneity problem if the current debt-to-GDP ratio were considered and, on the other
hand, it would be difficult to empirically detect a contemporaneous reaction of fiscal
policy to changes in public debt because of implementation lags. Referring to the
optimal taxation theory by Barro (1984), the incorporation of the expenditure gap is
based on the fact that temporary rises of government expenditure do not compromise
debt stabilization, and the inclusion of the output gap is justified on the grounds that
fiscal policy usually follows a countercyclical motive. In this sense, 2 would be positive
because during exceptional circumstances (e.g. in war times) public expenditure
increases and therefore deficit grows, and 3 would be negative because in bad economic
times (i.e. when output is below trend) automatic stabilizers run and so deficit goes up.
—9—
Finally, as explained in Claeys (2006), the addition of the inflation rate is founded on
that fiscal policy can play an inflation-stabilizing role allowing for interaction with
monetary policy.
Nevertheless, we should bear in mind that economic time series are not linear, as
Hamilton (1989) states in his seminal paper, wherein Markov-Switching models in time
series econometrics are introduced. Essentially, nonlinearity is especially pronounced in
the asymmetric business cycle, which can be described by a sequence of long but
gradual expansions and short but sudden recessions. The way to estimate Markov-
Switching models and its several applications are thoroughly described in Krolzig
(1997), and Kim and Nelson (1999). Since fiscal policy is highly influenced by the
current phase of the economic cycle and the political sign of the government, we will
not only estimate the fixed fiscal policy rule explained in equation (6), but also state-
dependent ones, whose parameters change endogenously. In detail, the Markov-
Switching fiscal policy rule takes the following form:
where StF 1,..., M denotes the state of fiscal policy at time t, which follows a first
order Markov chain with transition matrix P F pij with elements
pij Pr[st i, st 1 j ] , for all i, j 1,..., M , and the other parameters, defined as
above, can take different values depending on the fiscal regime of the moment. We
should also highlight that the variance of the error term is state dependent. As we have
mentioned earlier, fiscal policy is “active” in the sense on Leeper (1991) when the
behavior of the fiscal authority targets several objectives other than debt stabilization
( 1 0 ), and it is “passive” when the fiscal authority aims to stabilize public debt and
therefore decreases the primary deficit in response to public debt increases ( 1 0 ).
pd t 0 1bt 1 2 pg t 3 yt 4 t 5 pd t 1 t (8)
— 10 —
and the Markov-Switching “standard” fiscal policy rule given in equation (7) becomes
The VAR model that we consider as a basic empirical specification can be seen as the
reduced form of a standard structural macroeconomic model or, more generally, as an
approximation to the conditional solution (without the restrictions imposed by the
theory) of a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model like the augmented
New Keynesian structural model described above. Since the behavior of agents is not
constant over time and is affected by the prevailing economic environment, the usual
VAR representation is replaced by a Markov-Switching VAR model (MS-VAR) whose
more general form is as follows:
Xt a0 (StF ) A1 (StF )Xt 1 ... Ap (StF )Xt p a p 1 (StF )bt 1 (StF )1 2 t (10)
— 11 —
new quarterly dataset of Spanish public finance variables fit for economic analysis (see
De Castro et al., 2014). The sample period ranges from the first quarter of 1986 to the
fourth quarter of 2012 and so includes some facts that are very important for the
analysis of the behavior of fiscal policy in Spain: (a) the accession of the country into
the European Economic Community in 1986, (b) the construction of its welfare state in
the second half of the eighties, (c) the entry into force of the Treaty on European Union
(the “Maastricht Treaty”) in November 1993, which created the Economic and
Monetary Union (EMU) and forced Member States to respect financial and budgetary
discipline, (d) the Spanish economic crisis of 1993-1994, (e) the adoption of the
Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) in 1997, which constrains Member States to apply
sound budgetary policies (basically, a deficit-to-GDP ratio below 3 per cent and a debt-
to-GDP ratio below 60 per cent) from the time they enter the third stage of EMU (1
January 1999 for Spain), (f) the international financial and economic crisis, whose
beginning dated back to the bankruptcy of one of the largest global financial services
firms Lehman Brothers in September 2008, and the burst of the housing bubble in
Spain, whose climax was marked by the collapse of the country’s leading real estate
company Martinsa-Fadesa in July 2008, and (g) the intensification of the sovereign debt
crisis in the euro area since May 2010.
As Afonso and Toffano (2013) stated, “the choice of using quarterly data is
given by the fact that, even if the budget is set annually, infra-annual discretionary
adjustments are commonplace in the implementation of fiscal policy”.
Output gap (deviation from a HP trend) Annual inflation rate
4 12
3 10
2
8
1
6
0
4
-1
2
-2
0
-3
-4 -2
86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12
Figure 1. Output gap and inflation rate. Spain vs. the euro area. 1986Q1-2012Q4
Note: All variables are expressed in percentage terms.
Source: Own calculations based on De Castro et al. (2014) and Paredes et al. (2014) databases.
Figure 1 shows the Spanish output gap and the year-on-year inflation rate for the
analyzed period. For completeness, we also depict the euro area counterparts, calculated
from Paredes et al. (2014) euro area quarterly fiscal database. Note that the estimation
of the output gap offers information about the evolution of the economic activity that
can be different from the analysis of the economic cycles. Roughly speaking, the
country grew above trend from the third quarter of 1987 to the third quarter of 1991,
from the second quarter of 1999 to the fourth quarter of 2001 and from the first quarter
of 2004 to 2007, growing below trend over the remaining period. Regarding inflation,
— 12 —
this indicator has essentially decreased thorough the sample period, from two-digit
values in the mid-eighties to around zero in the most recent period.
Spain's nominal primary deficit to GDP ratio and its components Euro area's primary deficit to GDP ratio and its components
48 50
44
48
40
6 46
36
12
4 44
8 32
2
4 42
0
0
-4 -2
-8 -4
86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12
Nominal General Government debt to (annual) GDP ratio Primary expenditure gap (deviation from a HP trend)
100 8
6
90
4
80
2
70 0
60 -2
-4
50
-6
40
-8
30 -10
86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12
Figure 2. Primary deficit-to-GDP ratio and its components, debt-to-GDP ratio and primary expenditure
gap. Spain vs. the euro area. 1986:Q1-2012:Q4
Note: All variables are expressed in percentage terms.
Source: Own calculations based on De Castro et al. (2014) and Paredes et al. (2014) databases.
In Figure 2 we present the Spanish primary deficit-to-GDP ratio, the public debt-
to-GDP ratio and the primary expenditure gap for the period under scrutiny. For
completeness, we also graph the corresponding euro area counterparts, computing from
Paredes et al. (2014) euro area quarterly fiscal database. Spain registered a primary
surplus in three periods only: first, from the third quarter of 1987 to the second quarter
of 1988; second, in the third and fourth quarters of 1989; and, third, from the fourth
quarter of 1996 to the first quarter of 2008. That third phase of primary surplus to GDP
ratio was accompanied by a reduction of the debt-to-GDP ratio, as we can see from the
graph. Both facts are related to the commitment of the Spanish government to meet the
convergence criteria set out in the Maastricht Treaty to regulate access to the Third
Stage of EMU. However, proper fiscal consolidation does not apply to the whole 1996-
2007 period. While expenditure retrenchment took place in the second half of the
nineties, the reduction in the public deficit achieved thereafter was mainly due to
buoyant government receipts linked to a large extent to the housing boom.
A somewhat similar picture emerges for the euro area as a whole. Primary
surpluses are registered between 1988 and 1993 and from 1995 till the outbreak of the
— 13 —
Great Recession in 2008. However, while the Maastricht criteria might have been
instrumental to promote greater fiscal discipline, it also seems that positive fiscal
outcomes are mainly the result of good economic times, rather than structural
improvements in fiscal discipline. In this regard, contrary to what was observed in
Spain, only limited reductions in the public debt ratio were observed in the euro area
between 2001 and 2008.
4 Results
We report the Ordinary Least Squares estimation results for the fiscal rule
denoted in equation (6) for the Spanish primary deficit-to-GDP ratio in the left side of
Table 2. All coefficients are statistically significant, except the parameter associated to
the output gap. We observe that the coefficient estimate on lagged debt is negative and
statistically significant. Thus, fiscal policy seems to be “passive”, suggesting that past
debt-to-GDP ratio increases lead to lower primary deficits. As we expected, the primary
— 14 —
deficit-to-GDP ratio responds positively to the expenditure gap. Moreover, fiscal policy
is “acyclical”, since the parameter related to output gap is not statistically different from
zero. Finally, the coefficient estimate on the inflation rate is negative, implying that
higher inflation helps reduce primary deficits.
0.8 0.8
0.6 0.6
0.4 0.4
0.2 0.2
0.0 0.0
88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12
Residual, actual and fitted primary deficit to GDP ratio. Spain. 1986:Q1-2012:Q4
12
0
3
-4
2
1 -8
-1
-2
-3
88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12
We also show in the right side of Table 2 the Maximum Likelihood estimation
results of the Markov-Switching model with two regimes (and constant transition
— 15 —
probabilities) for the fiscal reaction function specified in equation (7) for the Spanish
primary deficit-to-GDP ratio.1 We observe that all parameters are statistically
significant, except the constant and the parameters related to lagged debt, the output gap
and the inflation rate in regime 1 and the coefficient associated to the output gap in
regime 2. Fiscal policy seems to be “passive” in regime 2, as the primary deficit-to-
GDP ratio decreases in response to higher lagged debt. By contrast, although this
coefficient is also negative in regime 1, such effect is not statistically significant. Hence,
fiscal policy would be neither active nor passive in this regime.
To sum up, we can distinguish the existence of two fiscal regimes in Spain:
regime 1, which spans between the end of 1990 and the middle of 2002, between the
end of 2003 and around the middle of 2007 and from the third quarter of 2010 onwards,
characterized by a neither active nor passive and acyclical fiscal policy, and regime 2,
which prevails in the remaining quarters, defined by a passive and acyclical fiscal
policy.2
1
Preliminary analysis indicates that a fiscal rule with three regimes was difficult to estimate with a
number of local roots exhibiting coefficient singularity.
2
Following the suggestion of Diebold, Lee, and Weinbach (1994), and Filardo (1994), who argue that the
probability of switching from one regime to the other cannot depend on the behavior of underlying
economic fundamentals, but the transition probabilities can and should vary with fundamentals, we
estimate the Markov-Switching two-regime fiscal policy rule denoted in equation (7), using variable-
dependent transition probabilities for the case of Spain. The results are very close to those reported in the
main text for constant transition probabilities.
— 16 —
“passive”, and extraordinary expenditure is somewhat higher in Spain (especially in
regime 2).3
Table 3. Markov-Switching standard fiscal policy rules for Spain and the euro area
Spain (see Table 2) Euro area
Regime 1 Regime 2 Regime 1 Regime 2
0.0434 13.8128*** 0.3912 0.8660
Constant
(0.5970) (3.0296) (1.1575) (1.8072)
Lagged -0.0027 -0.2582*** -0.0133 -0.0092
(debt/GDP) (0.0087) (0.0622) (0.0147) (0.0190)
(expenditure/GDP) 0.3373*** 1.3931*** 0.2370*** 0.5241**
gap (0.1010) (0.4563) (0.0872) (0.2584)
0.0620 -0.1683 -0.0400 -0.1098
GDP gap
(0.0691) (0.3221) (0.0602) (0.1257)
0.0051 -0.4430*** 0.0821 0.3698
Inflation rate
(0.0469) (0.1543) (0.0717) (0.5609)
Lagged 0.9501*** 0.4228*** 0.7326*** 0.5813***
(deficit/GDP) (0.0246) (0.1066) (0.0628) (0.1461)
-0.7638*** -0.0742 -1.2117*** -1.6058***
Log(sigma)
(0.0948) (0.1482) (0.0819) (0.1724)
Transition P(1 | 1) = 0.9625 P(1 | 2) = 0.0919 P(1 | 1) = 0.9922 P(1 | 2) = 0.0173
probabilities P(2 | 1) = 0.0375 P(2 | 2) = 0.9081 P(2 | 1) = 0.0078 P(2 | 2) = 0.9827
Exp. duration (Q) 26.6969 10.8754 127.4635 57.8184
Log likelihood -103.2588 -20.6588
AIC 2.2934 0.6789
SC 2.7003 1.0762
HQC 2.4583 0.8400
Notes: The dependent variable is the primary deficit-to-GDP ratio. Standard errors in brackets. Q –
Quarters. AIC – Akaike information criterion. SC – Schwarz criterion. HQC – Hannan-Quinn criterion.
*, **, ***, indicates statistical significance at a 10%, 5%, and 1% level.
Source: Own calculations based on De Castro et al. (2014) and Paredes et al. (2014) databases.
3
See Afonso and Toffano (2013) for estimation results of the Markov-Switching standard fiscal policy
rules, with two regimes (constant transition probabilities), for the German, British, and Italian cases
respectively. We should note that the specification of those fiscal rules is similar to that defined in
equation (7), except for the lagged dependent variable, but database sources and sample periods are
different. In an attempt to combine results from both papers, we can conclude that the German fiscal
policymakers are the most concerned about debt stabilization because both regimes are “passive”,
although regime 2 is marginally less passive than regime 1. The behavior of British fiscal policymakers is
somehow between that of Germany and Italy and Spain, in the sense that it can be “passive” or “active”
depending on the fiscal regime that prevails at every moment. The behavior of Italian and Spanish
policymakers can be “passive” or neither active nor passive. The passive behavior of euro area countries
is deemed to derive from European issues such as the need to comply with Maastricht criteria and the
SGP rules, whereas British fiscal policymakers follow a different pattern.
— 17 —
Table 4. Cyclically-adjusted fiscal policy rules for Spain
Fixed Markov-Switching fiscal rule
fiscal rule Regime 1 Regime 2
0.0765 0.6498 -0.0513
Constant
(0.6638) (1.3599) (0.5960)
-0.0026 -0.0043 -0.0004
Lagged (debt/GDP)
(0.0105) (0.0237) (0.0082)
0.7371*** 1.3237*** 0.2458**
(expenditure/GDP) gap
(0.1475) (0.2933) (0.1238)
0.1000 0.1721 -0.0794
GDP gap
(0.0943) (0.2022) (0.0692)
0.0067 -0.0743 0.0246
Inflation rate
(0.0480) (0.0944) (0.0421)
Lagged cyclically- 0.5778*** 0.4477*** 0.5388***
adjusted (deficit/GDP) (0.0775) (0.1316) (0.0748)
-0.0542 -0.9582***
Log(sigma) —
(0.1247) (0.1151)
P(1 | 1) = 0.9313 P(1 | 2) = 0.0649
Transition probabilities —
P(2 | 1) = 0.0687 P(2 | 2) = 0.9351
Expected duration (Q) — 14.5459 15.4077
Log likelihood -124.8465 -101.7174
Akaike info criterion 2.5163 2.2638
Schwarz criterion 2.6688 2.6706
Hannan-Quinn criter. 2.5781 2.4286
Notes: The dependent variable is the cyclically-adjusted primary deficit-to-GDP ratio. Standard errors
in brackets. Q – Quarters. *, **, ***, indicates statistical significance at a 10%, 5%, and 1% level.
Source: Own calculations based on De Castro et al. (2014) database.
The left side of Table 4 presents the Ordinary Least Squares estimation results
for the fiscal rule described in equation (8) for the Spanish cyclically-adjusted primary
deficit-to-GDP ratio. None of the coefficients is statistically significant, except the
parameters associated to the primary expenditure gap and the lagged cyclically-adjusted
primary deficit-to-GDP ratio. While the sign of the debt coefficient would be consistent
with a “passive” fiscal policy, such effects are statistically non-significant. As we
expected, the expenditure gap pushes up the primary deficit-to-GDP ratio. Moreover,
fiscal policy is “acyclical”, because the coefficient estimate on output gap is not
statistically different from zero.
— 18 —
Filtered Regime Probabilities
P(S(t)= 1) P(S(t)= 2)
1.0 1.0
0.8 0.8
0.6 0.6
0.4 0.4
0.2 0.2
0.0 0.0
88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12
Residual, actual and fitted cyclically-adjusted primary deficit to GDP ratio. Spain. 1986:Q1-2012:Q4
8
6
4
2
3 0
2 -2
-4
1
-6
0
-1
-2
-3
88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12
— 19 —
effect is stronger in regime 1. In turn, the Spanish fiscal stance is not affected by the
evolution of the inflation rate. In both regimes, the coefficient estimate of the lagged
primary deficit-to-GDP ratio is positive and significant, which suggests that this
variable shows a high degree of persistence.
Table 5. Markov-Switching cyclically-adjusted fiscal policy rules for Spain and the euro area
Spain (see Table 4) Euro area
Regime 1 Regime 2 Regime 1 Regime 2
0.6498 -0.0513 0.2282 0.2176
Constant
(1.3599) (0.5960) (0.5612) (0.7479)
Lagged -0.0043 -0.0004 -0.0027 -0.0051
(debt/GDP) (0.0237) (0.0082) (0.0066) (0.0091)
(expenditure/GDP 1.3237*** 0.2458** 1.0292*** 0.2206**
) gap (0.2933) (0.1238) (0.1008) (0.0907)
0.1721 -0.0794 0.1046** -0.0742
GDP gap
(0.2022) (0.0692) (0.0520) (0.0539)
-0.0743 0.0246 0.0661 0.0134
Inflation rate
(0.0944) (0.0421) (0.0475) (0.0530)
Lagged cadj. 0.4477*** 0.5388*** 0.1706*** 0.6909***
(deficit/GDP) (0.1316) (0.0748) (0.0559) (0.0889)
-0.0542 -0.9582*** -2.0214*** -1.2688***
Log(sigma)
(0.1247) (0.1151) (0.1597) (0.0930)
Transition P(1 | 1) = 0.9313 P(1 | 2) = 0.0649 P(1 | 1) = 0.8881 P(1 | 2) = 0.0451
probabilities P(2 | 1) = 0.0687 P(2 | 2) = 0.9351 P(2 | 1) = 0.1119 P(2 | 2) = 0.9549
Exp. duration (Q) 14.5459 15.4077 8.9330 22.1502
Log likelihood -101.7174 -6.7690
AIC 2.2638 0.4216
SC 2.6706 0.8190
HQC 2.4286 0.5828
Notes: The dependent variable is the cyclically-adjusted primary deficit-to-GDP ratio. Standard errors
in brackets. Q – Quarters. AIC – Akaike information criterion. SC – Schwarz criterion. HQC –
Hannan-Quinn criterion. *, **, ***, indicates statistical significance at a 10%, 5%, and 1% level.
Source: Own calculations based on De Castro et al. (2014) and Paredes et al. (2014) databases.
4
Once again, we follow the recommendation of Diebold, Lee, and Weinbach (1994), and Filardo (1994),
and therefore estimate the Markov-Switching two-regime fiscal policy rule denoted in equation (9), using
variable-dependent transition probabilities for the case of Spain. The results are very close to those
described in the main text for constant transition probabilities.
— 20 —
third quarter of 2008 to the second quarter of 2012, and regime 2, which extends from
the beginning of 1986 to the start of 1990, from the last quarter of 1990 to the first half
of 2001, from the third quarter of 2005 to the first half of 2008, and from the third
quarter of 2012 onwards. Both regimes can be described by a neither active nor passive
fiscal policy; however, regime 1 is procyclical whereas regime 2 is acyclical, and
extraordinary expenditure is higher in regime 1. Comparing these euro-area results with
those of Spain explained above, the time paths of fiscal regimes in Spain and the euro
area are partly synchronized, Spanish fiscal policymakers always behave in a neither
active nor passive and acyclical way whereas euro-area fiscal policymakers sometimes
act in a neither active nor passive but procyclical manner, and the responsiveness to
extraordinary expenditure is somewhat higher in Spain (especially in regime 1).
The balance between the advantages and disadvantages of GIRFs makes them
especially suitable for our analysis. On the one hand, GIRFs are invariant to the order of
the variables in the VAR model. In particular, GIRFs do not require the
orthogonalization of the residuals of the system and, therefore, any economic-based
restrictions, since they take the historical correlations among the variables included in
5
The estimates of the Markov-Switching VAR model with 2 regimes (states) were obtained by
Maximum Likelihood (ML). The Hamilton filtering algorithm was used to estimate the regimes. The
numerical optimization to compute the ML estimates was based on the block-wise algorithm of Sims,
Waggoner and Zha (2008).
6
Because we are interested in comparing the impulse responses of diverse regimes, we need to compute
“regime-dependent impulse responses” (Ehrmann et al., 2003), which are conditional on the regime
prevailing at the time of the disturbance continuing to prevail throughout the duration of the responses.
— 21 —
the estimated variance-covariance matrix. On the other hand, GIRFs do not provide
information about the causal relationships among the variables. In this regard, the
GIRFs do not require the identification of shocks, so that they cannot be used for
economic policy simulations. Thus, it is impossible to interpret those economic shocks
in a structural sense, with labels such as “supply shock”, “demand shock” or “policy
shock”. In any case, the analysis of the effects of an unanticipated change in one of the
observable variables on the other endogenous variables of the model is an essential step
to be considered.
1.0
0.8
0.6
Filtered.probs
0.4
0.2
0.0
Time
— 22 —
The generalized impulse responses of output gap to a (one standard deviation)
positive shock to the cyclically-adjusted primary deficit-to-GDP ratio are displayed in
Table 7 and Figure 6. In regime 1, which spans from the first quarter of 1986 to the
second quarter of 1992, an unanticipated increase in the cyclically-adjusted primary
deficit causes an instantaneous decrease of about 0.41 percent in the output of the
country. In any case, output gap responses are not significant, for which regime 1
cannot be described as Keynesian.
.8 .4
.6 .3
.2
.4
.1
.2
.0
.0
-.1
-.2
-.2
-.4
-.3
-.6 -.4
-.8 -.5
5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50
Regime 1 Regime 2
In regime 2, which spans from the third quarter of 1992 to the fourth quarter of
2012, the shock leads to a fall of the output gap between the second and the ninth
quarters after the shock, reaching a minimum of 0.29 percent in the sixth quarter. As of
the tenth quarter the effect of the shock on the output gap is diluted. In sum, from the
results of our simulations, in regime 2 we observe a non-Keynesian effect during the
first two and a half years and non-significant effects on activity thereafter.
5 Conclusions
In this paper we study fiscal regime shifts for the Spanish Economy, using a new
quarterly dataset of Spanish public finance variables fit for economic analysis (see De
Castro et al., 2014). In a first step, we characterize the behavior of Spanish fiscal
policymakers by means of fiscal policy rules in which the government reacts to the
public debt and the business cycle. Those fiscal reaction functions are not ad-hoc;
rather, they are derived as optimal rules from an augmented New Keynesian structural
model. In a second step, we estimate a vector autoregression model that includes
macroeconomic, fiscal and financial variables and present the effects of an increase in
the primary deficit-to-GDP. The VAR specification can be seen as an approximation to
the conditional solution of an augmented New Keynesian structural model. In both
steps, we apply Markov-Switching techniques to allow for a shift in the parameters of
— 23 —
the fiscal policy rules and to account for the non-linearity of fiscal policy and its relation
to different political preferences.
As expected by the analysis of previous literature, our results are very sensitive
to the specification of the fiscal rule. Moreover, they can be conditioned by the
inaccuracy of the HP filter we use to calculate the output gap at the beginning and the
end of the sample. The results of the experiments carried out in our paper are
summarized in Figure 7. In an attempt to combine the solutions of the standard and the
cyclically-adjusted fiscal policy rules, we can conclude that Spanish fiscal policy tends
to be acyclical throughout the analyzed period, but it is “passive” or neither active nor
passive depending on the prevailing regime. To put in other words, some “automatic
mechanism” embedded in the Spanish fiscal legislation tries to reduce the primary
deficit-to-GDP ratio in response to past debt increases.
MS Standard Fiscal Rule: Regime 1 MS Standard Fiscal Rule: Regime 2 MS CAdj. Fiscal Rule: Regime 1
MS CAdj. Fiscal Rule: Regime 2 MS VAR: Regime 1 MS VAR: Regime 2
Non-Keynesian during the first two and a half years / Non-significant effects from that point forward
— 24 —
preferences, such as the Barcelona 1992 Summer Olympic Games and the Seville 1992
Universal Exposition (period 1987-1990), the early-2000s downturn and the Iraq War
(period 2002-2003), and the social reforms under Zapatero’s government and the late-
2000s Spanish economic and financial crisis (period 2005-2009). Conforming to the
results of our MS-VAR model, increases in the primary deficit do not succeed in
stimulating economic activity; rather, unexpected upsurges in the primary deficit-to-
GDP ratio harm economic activity (non-Keynesian effect) in the second regime, which
prevails since the ratification of the Maastricht Treaty.
6 References
Afonso, A. (2008), “Ricardian Fiscal Regimes in the European Union”, Empirica 35: 313-334.
Afonso, A., and P. Toffano (2013), “Fiscal Regimes in the EU”, European Central Bank Working Paper
Series, No. 1529, April 2013.
Afonso, A., P. Claeys, and R. Sousa (2011), “Fiscal Regime Shifts in Portugal”, Portuguese Economic
Journal 10: 83-108.
Badinger, H. (2009), “Fiscal rules, discretionary fiscal policy and macroeconomic stability: an empirical
assessment for OECD countries”, Applied Economics 41: 829-847.
Ballabriga, F., and C. Martinez-Mongay (2005), “Sustainability of EU public finances,” European
Commission Economic Papers, No. 225, April 2005.
Barro, R. (1984), “The Behavior of U.S. Deficits”, NBER Working Papers 1309, National Bureau of
Economic Research, Inc.
Beetsma, R., M. Giuliodori, and F Klaassen (2006), “Trade spill-overs of fiscal policy in the European
Union: a panel analysis”, Economic Policy, October 2006, 639-687.
Blanchard, O.J., and R. Perotti (2002), “An empirical characterization of the dynamic effects of changes
in government spending and taxes on output”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (4): 1329-
1368.
Bohn, H. (1998), “The Behavior of U.S. Public Debt and Deficits”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 113:
949-963.
Bohn, H. (2005), “The Sustainability of Fiscal Policy in the United States”, CESifo Working Paper Series
1446.
Castañeda-Fernández, J.E. (2009), “Reglas fiscales activas: el caso de España”, Papeles de trabajo del
Instituto de Estudios Fiscales. Serie economía, No. 4/09.
Claeys, P. (2004), “Monetary and Budgetary Policy Interaction: An SVAR Analysis of Stabilisation
Policies in Monetary Union,” Economics Working Papers ECO2004/22, European University
Institute.
Claeys, P. (2006), “Policy mix and debt sustainability: evidence from fiscal policy rules”, Empirica 33:
89-112.
Claeys, P. (2008), “Rules, and their effects on fiscal policy”, Swedish Economic Policy Review 15: 7-48.
Clarida, R., J. Gali, and M. Gertler (1999), “The Science of Monetary Policy: A New Keynesian
Perspective”, Journal of Economic Literature 37: 1661-1707.
De Castro, F. (2006), “The macroeconomic effects of fiscal policy in Spain”, Applied Economics 38: 913-
924.
De Castro, F., F. Martí, A. Montesinos, J.J. Pérez, and A.J. Sánchez Fuentes (2014), “Fiscal policies in
Spain: main stylized facts revisited”, Research Department, Banco de España, Documentos de
Trabajo No 1408.
Diebold, F.X., J.H. Lee, and G. C. Weinbach (1994), “Regime Switching with Time-Varying Transition
Probabilities,” in C. Hargreaves (ed.), Nonstationary Time Series Analysis and Cointegration,
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 283-302.
— 25 —
Ehrmann, M., M. Ellison, and N. Valla (2003), “Regime-dependent impulse response functions in a
Markov-switching vector autoregression model”, Economics Letters 78: 295-299.
Filardo, A.J. (1994), “Business-Cycle Phases and Their Transitional Dynamics”, Journal of Business and
Economic Statistics 12: 299-308.
Friedman, M. (1948), “A Monetary and Fiscal Framework for Economic Stability”, The American
Economic Review 38: 245-264
Gali, J., and R. Perotti (2003), “Fiscal Policy and Monetary Integration in Europe”, NBER Working
Papers 9773, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
Golinelli, R., and S. Momigliano (2008), “The cyclical response of fiscal policies in the euro area. Why
do results of empirical research differ so strongly?”, Banca d’Italia Temi di Discussione, No.
652, January 2008.
Hamilton J.D. (1990), “Analysis of time series subject to changes in regime”, Journal of Econometrics
45: 39-70.
Hamilton, J.D. (1989), “A New Approach to the Economic Analysis of Nonstationary Time Series and
the Business Cycle”, Econometrica 57(2): 357-84.
Kim, C.J., and C.R. Nelson (1999), State-Space Models with Regime Switching, Cambridge,
Massachusetts: MIT Press.
Kirsanova, T., S. Stehn, and D. Vines (2006), “Five-Equation Macroeconomics: A Simple view of the
Interactions between Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy”, CEPR Discussion Paper 5464.
Koop, G., M.H. Pesaran, and S.M. Potter (1996), “Impulse Response Analysis in Nonlinear Multivariate
Models”, Journal of Econometrics 74: 119-147.
Krolzig, H.-M. (1997), Markov Switching Vector Autoregressions. Modelling, Statistical Inference and
Application to Business Cycle Analysis, Berlin: Springer.
Leeper, E. (1991), “Equilibria under ‘active’ and ‘passive’ monetary and fiscal policies”, Journal of
Monetary Economics 27: 129-147.
Marneffe, W., B. van Aarle, W. van der Wielen, and L. Vereeck (2011), “The Impact of Fiscal Rules on
Public Finances in the Euro Area”, CESifo DICE Report Journal for Institutional Comparisons
9, 18-25.
Paredes, J., D.J. Pedregal, and J.J. Pérez (2014), “Fiscal policy analysis in the euro area: Expanding the
toolkit”, Journal of Policy Modeling, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jpolmod.2014.07.003.
Perotti, R. (2005), “Estimating the effects of fiscal policy in OECD countries”, CEPR Discussion Paper,
No. 4842.
Pesaran, M.H., and Y. Shin (1998), “Generalized Impulse Response Analysis in Linear Multivariate
Models”, Economics Letters 58: 17-29.
Reade, J.J. (2011), “Modelling Monetary and Fiscal Policy in the US: A Cointegration Approach”,
University of Birmingham Department of Economics Discussion Paper 11-02.
Sims, C.A., D.F. Waggoner, and T. Zha (2008), “Methods for inference in large multiple-equation
Markov-switching models”, Journal of Econometrics 146: 255-274.
Svensson, L.E.O. (1999), “Inflation Targeting As a Monetary Policy Rule”, Journal of Monetary
Economics 43: 607-654.
Taylor, J.B. (1993), “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice”, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series
on Public Policy 39: 195-214.
Thams, A. (2007), “Fiscal Policy Rules in Practice”, mimeo.
— 26 —