Ipr and Comp Law NLS Journal
Ipr and Comp Law NLS Journal
Ipr and Comp Law NLS Journal
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
Student Advocate Committee is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend
access to National Law School of India Review
This content downloaded from 14.139.214.181 on Thu, 26 Mar 2020 09:43:45 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
4
Jfžltllfc
NLSIR
SECTION 3(5)(i) OF THE COMPETITION
ACT -AN ANALYSIS
- Paramjeet Berwal
There is economy.1 There are people.2 There are conflicting interests and
ities.3 Then, there is competition in the system.4 Law is the only tool in the
of the state to manufacture and sustain any system.5
1 Karl Marx referred to the economic structure of the society as the real foundation on wh
and political superstructure arises. Karl Marx, Preface to A Contribution To The Cri
Political Economy (Moscow, Progress Publishers Moscow 1977).
2 Karl Marx, Critique of Hegel's Philosophy in General, in Economic And Philosophical
Manuscript Of 1844 ("That is to say, the objects of his [man's] instincts exist outside him, as
objects independent of him; yet these objects are objects that he needs - essential objects, indis-
pensable to the manifestation and confirmation of his essential powers."); In order to under-
stand the contemporary change in human behavior, see Robert D. Putman, Bowling Alone: The
Collapse And Revival of American Community (New York, Simon and Schuster 2000).
3 Friedrich Engels, Ludwig Feuerbach And The End Of Classical German Philosophy, 4 & 5 Die
Neue Zeit part 4, (1886) ("That which is willed happens but rarely; in the majority of instances
the numerous desired ends cross and conflict with one another, or these ends themselves are from
the outset incapable of realisation, or the means of attaining them are insufficient. Thus the con-
flict of innumerable individual wills and individual actions in the domain of history produce a
state of affairs entirely analogous to that prevailing in the realm of unconscious nature.").
4 See John Bellamy Foster, Robert W. McChesney and R. Jamil Jonna, Monopoly and Competition
in the Twenty-First Century Capitalism, 62(11) Monthly Review (April, 2011); see also Maurice
E. Stucke, Is Competition Always Good?, 1(1) J. Antitrust Enforcement 162,162 (2013).
5 Though, recently, the studies have proved that it really is the economically affluent people who
influence the law-making. See Martin Gilens & Benjamin I. Page, Testing Theories of American
Politics: Elites, Interest Groups, and Average Citizens, 12(03) Perspectives on Politics, 564, 575-
577 (2014).
6 Shamsher Kataria ,In re, 2014 SCC OnLine CCI 95 (" Kataria ").
This content downloaded from 14.139.214.181 on Thu, 26 Mar 2020 09:43:45 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 27 SECTION 3(5)(i) OF THE COMPETITION ACT - AN ANALYSIS 169
I. INTRODUCTION
7 Prof. John F. Duffy is Samuel H. McCoy Professor of Law and Armistead M. Dobie Professor of
Law, University of Virginia School of Law.
8 John F. Duffy's comments at National Lawyers Convention organized by The Intellectual
Property Practice Group of The Federalist Society for Law and Public Policy Studies, November
14, 2013, Yoi/I'jbe (Nov. 15, 2013) https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=TmBJknoGKSM; see also
Shubha Ghosh, Intellectual Property Law and Competition, International Scholars Conference on
Intellectual Property Law, University of Wisconsin Law School, 16-17th September,, 2014.
9 Competition Commission of India, Advocacy Booklet, Intellectual Property Rights Under the
Competition Act, 2002 ".
10 Paramjeet Singh Berwal, Articles 3(a) and 3(b) of the SPC Regulation - An Analysis , 36(1)
European Intellectual Property Review, 29, 33 (2014).
11 Joseph Drexl, Research Handbook On Intellectual Property And Competition Law (Edward
Elgar Publishing Limited, 2008); Jaoquin Almunia, Vice President, European Commission
Responsible for the Competition Policy, Speech at the IP Summit, Paris: Intellectual Property
and Competition Policy (Dec. 9, 2013).
12 National IPR Policy submitted by IPR Think Tank, First Draft, at p. 23, (19th December 2014).
13 Draft National Competition Policy Statement of India- 2011, drafted by the Committee consti-
tuted by the Ministry of Corporate Affairs.
14 This is true even in the case of 'free-market economy' because there is no such thing as a free
market. In fact, this is the very first truth Ha Joon Chang, Reader in the Political Economy of
Development at Cambridge University, reveals in one of his books. He writes that every market
has some rules and government is always involved. Ha-Joon Chang, 23 Things They Don't Tell
You About Capitalism (Allen Lane ed., London, Penguin, 2010).
This content downloaded from 14.139.214.181 on Thu, 26 Mar 2020 09:43:45 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
170 NATIONAL LAW SCHOOL OF INDIA REVIEW 27 NLSI Rev. (2015)
15 WIPO, http://www.wipo.int/about-ip/en/.
16 IP holders can include people and corporations. However, corporations hold more IPRs than
people do. See 1 Wenche Barth Eide (Ed.) & Uwe Kracht (Ed.), Food and Human Rights in
Development - Legal and Institutional Dimensions and Selected Topics 434 (Intersentia 2005).
17 What is Intellectual Property ?, WIPO, available at http://www.wipo.int/edocs/pubdocs/en/int-
property/450/wipo_pub_450.pdf.
18 WTO, https://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/trips_e/intell_e.htm.
19 The phrase 'may be' is very crucial in the context of understanding the importance of IPRs in
serving a larger interest, directly or indirectly.
20 R.S. Khemani & D.M. Shapiro, Glossary of Industrial Organisation Economics and Competition
Law , commissioned by the Directorate for Financial, Fiscal and Enterprise Affairs, OECD (1993).
21 Cf. Justin Huges, The Philosophy of Intellectual Property Rights , 77 Georgetown Law Journal
287 (1988) (citing, Zacchini v. Scripps-Howard Broadcasting Co., 53 L Ed 2d 965 : 433 US 562,
576 (1977) "The protection [of publicity] provides an economic incentive ... to make the invest-
ment required to produce a performance. . . . This same consideration underlies the patent and
copyright laws long enforced by this Court"; Goldstein v. California , 37 L Ed 2d 163 : 412 US
546, 555 (1973) "to encourage people to devote themselves to intellectual and artistic creation,
Congress may guarantee to authors and inventors a reward"; cf. United States v. Paramount
Pictures Loew's, 92 L Ed 1260 : 334 US 131, 158 (1948) "It is said that reward to the author or
artist serves to induce release to the public of the products of his creative genius").
This content downloaded from 14.139.214.181 on Thu, 26 Mar 2020 09:43:45 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 27 SECTION 3(5)(i) OF THE COMPETITION ACT - AN ANALYSIS 171
IPRs are private rights.22 The business houses across the world are increa
ingly becoming dependent on IPRs for profit-making.23 Though many claim
that IPRs act as incentive to innovate24, others say that they are merely a tool t
commercialise the innovation that would have been there, sooner or later, ev
if there were no IPRs.25 It is also often said that IPRs are ultimately direct
towards the welfare of consumers.26 Theories should be tested by the utilities th
afford in explaining the practical situations occurring in reality.27
22 Keith Eugene Maskus, Private Rights And Public Problems: The Global E
Intellectual Property In 21st Century (Washington, DC, Peterson Institute Pr
Harms, The Enforcement of Intellectual Property Rights: A Case Book , (WIP
Christopher May, A Global Political Economy Of Intellectual Property Rig
Enclosures? (London, Routledge 2000).
23 William W. Fisher, Theories of Intellectual Property , New Essays In The Le
Theory Of Property (Cambridge University Press 2001).
24 Sunil Kanwar and Robert E. Evenson, Does Intellectual Property Protection Sp
Change?, Center Discussion Paper No. 831, Economic Growth Center, Yale Uni
(June 2001) available at http://www.econ.yale.edu/growth_pdf/cdp831.pdf.
25 See Innovation and Growth - Rationale for an Innovation Strategy , OECD, 10 (20
26 Pamela Samuelson & Suzanne Scotchmer, The Law and Economics of Reverse E
Yale Law Journal1575 (2002).
27 See Richard A. Posner, Economic Analysis of Law (Aspen, 8th ed, 2011).
28 Competition Bill (H.L.), H L Deb October 30, 1997, Volume 582 Column 1156.
29 Sandra Marco Colino, Introduction To Competition Law (Oxford University Press
30 Klaus Schwab, The Global Competitiveness Report 2014-15 (World Economic F
31 This is called 'dynamic competition'.
32 This is called 'static competition'.
33 Richard Whish, Competition Law (London, LexisNexis UK, 5th edn. 2003) 734;
Balancing Proprietory and Public domain Interests: Inside or Outside of Propr
Expanding the Boundaries of Intellectual Property: Innovation Policy for the Knowledge
This content downloaded from 14.139.214.181 on Thu, 26 Mar 2020 09:43:45 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
172 NATIONAL LAW SCHOOL OF INDIA REVIEW 27 NLSI Rev. (2015)
Generally, this, that the IPRs and Competition law seek to achieve c
welfare, is what the mainstream organisation and experts around the wor
pose.35 IPRs act as an incentive to innovate and, thereafter, cause the
ination and commercialization.36 On the other hand, competition laws
innovation and consumer welfare by prohibiting anti-competitive practic
regard to the existing and the new ways of serving consumers.37 How
text that immediately follows the definitions of IPRs as provided by vari
national organizations like WIPO, WTO, OECD etc.38 clearly highlights
or financial significance of IPRs for the IPR holders and not for the cons
the absence of any strong evidence39, attributing consumer welfare40 to
be said to be merely a distorted hindsight approach in a desperate attemp
tify IPRs in the context of overall consumer welfare.41
This content downloaded from 14.139.214.181 on Thu, 26 Mar 2020 09:43:45 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 27 SECTION 3(5) fi) OF THE COMPETITION ACT - AN ANALYSIS 173
believed that the two disciplines operate against each other.44 But the percep-
tion is considered to have changed now with a prevailing mindset that the goals
of competition law and intellectual property are similar.45 But the pseudo-shift
in the academic discourse is a common consequence of the conditioning of the
academia by the existing power structures 46 There is one school of thought that
seeks to separate the competition law from the intellectual property law and
maintains that the job of the competition law should only be limited to the "use
and abuse of property rights that are sources of monopoly power"47.
as Natural Monopoly: Towards a General Theory of Partial Property Rights , Paper at Fall 2004
Workshop of the Center of Law, Business, and Economics of the University of Texas.
44 See, eg, Image Technical Services, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co ., 125 F 3d 1195, 1215 (9th Cir 1997)
("[o]ne body of law creates and protects monopoly power while the other seeks to proscribe it.').
45 Atari Games Corpn. v. Nintendo of America Ine , 897 F 2d 1572 (Fed. Cir. 1990); Thomas C.
Vinje and Ashwin van Rooijen, Chapter 17: The Relationship between Intellectual Property
Rights and Competition Laws , in Overlapping Intellectual Property Rights 368 (Neil Wilkof
& Shamnad Basheer eds., Oxford University Press 2012); The competition law/IP 'interface'- an
introductory note , in The Interface Between Intellectual Property Rights and Competition
Policy 1 (Steven D Anderman ed., Cambridge University Press 2007); William K Tom & Joshua
A. Newberg, Antitrust and Intellectual Property: From Separate Spheres to Unified Field,
66 Antitrust Law Journal 167, 167 (1997); Mark A. Lemley, A New balance between IP and
Antitrust, 13 Southwestern Journal of Law and Trade in the Americas 237 (2007).
46 See Interview with Ha Joon Chang, Reader, University of Cambridge, Old economics, new stir-
rings , Frontline (March 6, 2015).
47 Pierre Regibeau & Katherine Rockett, The Relationship Between Intellectual Property Law and
Competition Law: An Economic Approach, Discussion Paper, University of Essex and CEPR
(June 2014).
48 See Ashwin van Rooijen, The Soft ware interface between copyright and competition laws, 104
(Kluver Law International, 2010).
49 Commission Notice Guidelines on the application of the Article 81 of the EC Treaty to technol-
ogy transfer agreements, European Commission, 7 Section Official Journal C-101/2 (2004).
50 Friedrich A. Hayek, The Fatal Conceit- The Errors of Socialism 6 (W.W. Bartely, 3rd ed.,
Chicago, University of Chicago press, 1991); see Robert P. Merges and Richard R. Nelson,
On the Complex Economics of Patent Scope, 90 Columbia Law Review 839; S.N.S. Cheung,
Property Rights and Invention , 8 Res. L. & Econ. 5, 6 (1986) (referring to F.W. Taussig,
Inventors and Money-Makers (1930)); see generally Rochelle Drey fuss & Susy Frankel, From
Incentive to Commodity to Asset: How International Law is Reconceptualizing Intellectual
Property (New York University Public Law and Legal Theory Working Papers- 478, 2014).
51 Padraig Dixon & Christine Greenhalgh, The Economics of Intellectual Property: A Review to
Identify Themes for Future Research , at p. 31, University of Oxford, Discussion Paper Serious
This content downloaded from 14.139.214.181 on Thu, 26 Mar 2020 09:43:45 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
174 NATIONAL LAW SCHOOL OF INDIA REVIEW 27 NLSI Rev. (2015)
This content downloaded from 14.139.214.181 on Thu, 26 Mar 2020 09:43:45 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 27 SECTION 3(5)(i) OF THE COMPETITION ACT - AN ANALYSIS 175
Regardless of the fact that IP regimes should not be conceived and applied i
isolation to the competition law60, the existing IP laws do not protect competition
There is an argument that IP law promotes dynamic competition.61 But, doubts do
exist whether IPRs should take all the credit for being the champion of dynamic
competition.62
58 See Copyright, Competition and Development, A Report By Max Planck Institute for Intellectua
Property and Competition Law, Munich, at p. 6 (December 2013), http://www.ip.mpg.de/files
pdf3/Report_Copyright-Competition-Development_December-2013.pdf.
59 Shamsher Kataria ,In re , 2014 SCC OnLine CCI 95.
60 Carlos Correa, A Competition Approach to the Intellectual Property Protection , Internation
Center for Trade and Development (November 1, 2007) available at http://www.ictsd.org
bridges-news/bridges/news/a-competition-approach-to-intellectual-property-protection.
61 Josef Drexl, Intellectual Property and Antitrust Law- IMS Health and Trinko- Antitrust Placebo
for Consumers Instead of Sound Economics in Refusal-To-Deal Cases' 35 IIC: Internationa
Review of Intellectual Property and Competition Law, 788, 802 -et sq (2004); Research
Handbook on Intellectual Property and Competition Law, 16 (Joseph Drexl ed., Edward Elga
Publishing Limited 2008); see also Josef Drexl, Do we always favor dynamic competition ove
static price competition when excluding Imitation ?, Presentation, 13th EIPIN Congress (March 3
2012).
62 See Keith E. Maskus, Conlcusion to Intellectual Property Rights And Economic Development ,
Prepared for the series "Beyond the Treaties: A Symposium on Compliance with International
Intellectual Property Law", organized by Fredrick K. Cox International Law Center at Case
Western Reserve University (Revised Draft: February 6, 2000).
63 Section 3(5)(i), The Competition Act, 2002.
64 "The existence of IP rights restricts competitive market forces for a set period", IP Australia,
http://www.ipaustralia.gov.au/understanding-intellectual-property/why-use-ip/value-of-ip-rights/.
This content downloaded from 14.139.214.181 on Thu, 26 Mar 2020 09:43:45 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
176 NATIONAL LAW SCHOOL OF INDIA REVIEW 27 NLSI Rev. (2015)
(c) the Trade and Merchandise Marks Act, 1958 (43 of 1958)
Trade Marks Act, 1999 (47 of 1999);
The section regulates the effect of competition law on IPRs and is positive in
nature in the sense that it is only when the situation65 stated therein emerges that
the competition law, though not failing to follow its due course, will not bother
to restrict the happening of the said situation.66 However, this is not true.67 The
section will come into play only if the application of the Competition Act will
restrict the right68 of a person to restrain infringement of and to impose condi-
tions for protecting his rights69 that have been or may be conferred upon him
under the specific IP statutes70 mentioned therein.
Thus, technically, it is not the IPRs as such that are protected by the virtue of
Section 3(5)(i); rather, it is the right to protect IPRs that is protected.71 The right
65 The 'situation', here, refers to what has been provided for in the Section 3(5)(i) of the
Competition Act.
66 This highlights how the way a law is written serves the purpose that it doesn't expressly seek to
serve.
67 The following sections of the article will highlight and explain the point.
68 The words used in the section are "the right" of a person. It means that the se
particular right.
69 Here and until this stage of the flow of the section 3(5)(i), the Competition Ac
IPRs in a general sense. It is yet not talking about the source of these rights.
70 Here, it becomes clear that the rights that are sought to be protected by the r
unrestricted by the Section 3(5)(i) of the Competition Act are the IPRs that ha
conferred by the IP Statutes specifically mentioned therein.
71 But, this is merely a technicality of the language of section 3(5)(i). The conseq
ation of this section is inherently linked to the substance of the section.
This content downloaded from 14.139.214.181 on Thu, 26 Mar 2020 09:43:45 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 27 SECTION 3(5)(i) OF THE COMPETITION ACT - AN ANALYSIS ill
that is unrestricted by the operation of this section is, in fact, the right to exe
cise72 the IPRs.73
Per Section 3(5)(i), a person has a right to protect the rights that have been
or may be conferred upon him under the specific IP statutes mentioned there-
in.78 This he can do by restraining infringement of his IPRs or imposing certain
conditions as may be necessary for the protection of his IPRs. IPRs are, gener-
ally79, considered to be negative right i.e. the right to stop the third parties from
their commercial exploitation. The existence of IPRs, the negative rights, is the
exercise80 of the IPRs. Therefore, if one is trying to do any of the two things
- restraining infringement of IPRs or imposing conditions to protect them-
72 The right to exercise IPRs, here, refers to the right to do the things that come under the charac-
terization of the IPRs as negative rights.
73 It is the right to exercise IPRs that the CCI's official Advocacy Booklet on Intellectual Property
Rights claims to assailed if the same goes contrary to the principles of competition.
74 The legislative realities reflect the proposition.
75 CCI Advocacy Booklet Intellectual Property Rights under the Competition Act, 2002.
76 Id.
77 Supra note 74.
78 For the sake of brevity, let the rights, both, the conferred and those that may be conferred, be
called IPRs.
79 There are a few academicians who really think that the IPRs being considered as negative rights
is a matter of hyper-technicality that crops up from the language of the statutory instruments. In
my opinion, IPRs are positive rights when we notice the purpose they serve and the functions
they have when they are in operation.
80 Canada Competition Bureau, Competition Bureau, Intellectual Property Enforcement Guidelines,
paragraph 4.2.1 ("The Bureau defines the mere exercise of an IP right as the exercise of the own-
er's right to unilaterally exclude others from using the IP. The Bureau views an IP owner's use of
the IP also as being the mere exercise of an IP right.").
This content downloaded from 14.139.214.181 on Thu, 26 Mar 2020 09:43:45 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
178 NATIONAL LAW SCHOOL OF INDIA REVIEW 27 NLSI Rev. (2015)
WHAT IS PROTECTED?
As we have seen, the right that has not been allowed to be restrict
of Section 3(5)(i) is only the right to restrain the infringement o
certain restrictions to protect rights that have been conferred or may
by the IP statutes; and, not the rights conferred or that may be con
IP statutes itself. Technically, a person has a right to restrain in
per the IP statute. Therefore, for a moment, the use of 'the' before
taken to mean that the right that is sought to be unrestricted is som
has been borrowed from the IP statutes by the Competition Act.
language of the section provides for is not this. Though the operatio
tion seeks to address the issue of exercise of IPRs and does recognize
cific right82 to restrain infringement and impose conditions, the la
section is silent about the source of the said right.
What rights can be protected by exercising the right that is allowed unr
stricted under the section have been left to the specific IP statutes by using
arrangement of words "have been or may be conferred upon him under" in
section. According to the Merriam Webster dictionary, the meaning of "con
ferred" is "to give (as property or characteristic) to someone or something".
implies that even if certain rights can, generally, be termed as "IPRs", they will
not be, for the purpose of this section, as long as they have not been or may no
be conferred under the specific IP statutes mentioned therein. Only the 'confer-
ment' has been subjected to the specific IP statutes. The subject matter - "a
of his rights" - in relation to which infringement can be restrained and the rea-
sonable conditions can be imposed is rooted in the IP statutes. Hence, per th
81 Illustration: In case of patents, the section 48 of the Patents Act provides for the right of
patentee and the same include the exclusive right to prevent third parties, who do not have h
consent, from the act of making, using, offering for sale, selling or importing for those purpo
Therefore, restraining the infringement of the patent rights under the Patents Act will include no
allowing third parties to make, use, etc. the product that is the subject matter of the patent. T
restraining the infringement is, thus, the exercise of the IPRs as the IPRs are negative rights
Therefore, technically, only restraining the infringement would amount to exercising the IPR
If the IPRs were positive rights, then their use by the IPR holder to produce his own goods a
services would have constituted exercise of IPRs. But, the later is not the case.
82 By using "the" before "right" in the language of Section 3(5)(i).
This content downloaded from 14.139.214.181 on Thu, 26 Mar 2020 09:43:45 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 27 SECTION 3(5)(i) OF THE COMPETITION ACT - AN ANALYSIS 179
structuring of the section 3(5)(1), the list of the specific IP statutes mentioned
the section has a very limited purpose.
X. INFRINGEMENT
This content downloaded from 14.139.214.181 on Thu, 26 Mar 2020 09:43:45 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
180 NATIONAL LAW SCHOOL OF INDIA REVIEW 27 NLSI Rev. (2015)
CCI took into consideration the failure on the part of the OEMs to confirm
the status of the IPRs held by them in India along with necessary details to sup-
port their contention that Section 3(5)(i) is applicable to their case.87 There was
no documentary evidence afforded by the OEMs to establish the grant of IPRs in
relation to their spare parts, in India.88
According to CCI, the applications of Section 3(5)(i) was consequent upon the
fulfilment of the condition that IPRs have been conferred or may be conferred
upon the "IPR holder".89 It observed that: " The Commission is of the opinion
under section 3(5)(i) allows an IPR holder to impose reasonable restrictions
to protect his rights ' which have been or may be conferred upon him under '
the specified IPR statutes mentioned therein. The statute is clear in its require-
ment that an IPR must have been conferred (or may be conferred) upon the IPR
holder prior to the exception under section 3(5)(i) being available. Therefore,
before the OEMs are permitted to seek the exemption under section 3(5)(i) they
must establish that their IPRs have been granted protection (or that the OEMs
have initiated the process of being granted protection) under the specified IPR
statutes in India [Emphasis Added]
While interpreting ' which have been or may be conferred upon him under ,
CCI concluded that either the OEMS should prove that either their IPRs have
been granted protection or the OEMs have initiated the process of being granted
protection under the specified IP statutes in India90.
85 Supra note 6, ļ[ 20.6.15; It is not understandable what relevance the investment function of IPRs
has in the context of application of Section 3(5)(i) of the Competition Act.
86 Supra note 6, ļ 20.6.16.
87 Supra note 6, at ļ| 20.6.16.
88 Supra note 6, at ļļ 20.6.16.
89 Supra note 6, at ļ 20.6.16.
90 CCI imposed the geographical limitation on the characterisation of certain rights as IPRs, though
the relevant section was silent on this.
This content downloaded from 14.139.214.181 on Thu, 26 Mar 2020 09:43:45 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 27 SECTION 3(5)(i) OF THE COMPETITION ACT - AN ANALYSIS 181
First , the word that has been used by CCI is the "IPR holder" which is total
absent from the language of Section 3(5)(i). Can a person upon whom the r
under a specific IPR statute have not yet been conferred and may be conf
be called an 'IPR holder'? No. A person becomes an IPR holder only after
rights have been conferred upon him under the specific IP law.91 The issue un
consideration here is not whether the IP has been registered for the creator or
owner to be declared as an IPR holder; the issue is whether IPRs have been
ferred upon a person by the application of any specific IP statute.
Second, CCI mistook the right that "may be conferred" to mean that
party seeking application of Section 3(5)(i) should have initiated the proce
being granted protection. This interpretation is inherently wrong as it provid
no line of thinking or argument that made CCI interpret "the right that may
conferred" into "therefore, before the OEMs are permitted to seek the exemp
under Section 3(5)(i) they must establish that their IPRs have been granted
tection (or that the OEMs have initiated the process of being granted pro
tion) under the specified IPR statutes in India." [Emphasis applied] The Se
does not, in any way, require that the person evoking Section 3(5)(i) must
initiated the process of being granted the protection under the IP statute to b
his rights under the purview of "may be conferred". The language of the prov
sion does cover a situation in which certain rights under the specific IP sta
may be conferred upon a person even if he hasn't applied for it. It is not a
cedural requirement; rather, it is a substantial requirement, in the context of
Competition Act.92
91 See the proviso to Section 11 A (7) of the Patents Act 1970 mentioning the t
92 CCI's only discretion, in this regard, is to acknowledge whether the said IPR
or may be conferred upon a person.
93 Supra note 6, at ļ 20.6.16.
This content downloaded from 14.139.214.181 on Thu, 26 Mar 2020 09:43:45 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
182 NATIONAL LAW SCHOOL OF INDIA REVIEW 27 NLSI Rev. (2015)
CCI noted that the OEMs contended that the some of the I
tion were validly held by their overseas parent companies and wer
through technology transfer agreements. Responding to this su
OEMs, CCI stated that the IPRs were territorial in nature and the
be vested upon the IPR holder only in a given jurisdiction. Though, on
this observation of CCI totally discarded the relevance of those IP-
national instruments which mandated the internationalisation of c
pertaining to IPRs, it also highlighted that the contracts could not m
sal what is territorial in nature; especially, in the context of competi
specifically stressed on the need of the conferment of the IPRs as pe
IP statutes. CCI observed that the OEMs held, under a TTA, the r
mercially exploit IPRs that was held by their parent companies an
right itself.94 Therefore, also, the application of Section 3(5)(i) was de
This content downloaded from 14.139.214.181 on Thu, 26 Mar 2020 09:43:45 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 27 SECTION 3 (5) (i) OF THE COMPETITION ACT - AN ANALYSIS 183
CCI held that "selling a diagnostic tool in the open market doe
the IPRs of the OEMs in such tools and equipment"104 Regardless of
the Section does, technically, include within its scope the scen
sales restrictions can be imposed in order to protect IPRs, the h
This content downloaded from 14.139.214.181 on Thu, 26 Mar 2020 09:43:45 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
184 NATIONAL LAW SCHOOL OF INDIA REVIEW 27 NLSI Rev. (2015)
issue by the CCI is not understandable when it held that the restrictions
upon the OESs from selling spare parts directly into the were not w
ambit of exemptions granted by Section 3(5)(i). By the implication of the
if an agreement causes protection of IPRs and anti-competitive behaviour,
still be allowed to get into effect.
XVII. CONCLUSION
105 Orange Book Standard case KZR 39/06 May 6, 2009 [BGH].
106 Articles 8.2 and 40 TRIPS.
107 Paramjeet Singh Berwal, Comment The Need to balance moral rights and public utility, in
WIPO Magazine Letters and Comments. (April 2008).
108 Paramjeet Singh Berwal, Articles 3(a) and 3(b) of the SPC Regulation - An Analysis , 36(1)
European Intellectual Property Review 29, 37-38 (2014).
This content downloaded from 14.139.214.181 on Thu, 26 Mar 2020 09:43:45 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms