Topic 24: Frontiers of Microeconomics
Topic 24: Frontiers of Microeconomics
Topic 24: Frontiers of Microeconomics
Frontiers of microeconomics
ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION
• It is generally assumed all parties to a
transaction have access to the same information.
1
ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION
• A seller may have better information than buyer
– when buying a second-hand car, vendor knows more
than buyer.
ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION
• Labour Market
– Workers may have better information than employer &
may undersupply effort if their effort is unobserved.
• Insurance Market
– Having purchased insurance a consumer may
undersupply effort in taking care of the insured object
if the insurer cannot observe this.
2
TYPES OF ASYMMETRIC
INFORMATION
• Info asymmetries can have effects before a
transaction is done by hidden information.
– Taking advantage of private information before a deal
is done is called pre-contractual opportunism or
adverse selection.
3
ADVERSE SELECTION – EXAMPLE 2
• The market for labour
– Workers (sellers of labour) vary in their abilities and
they may know their own abilities better than do the
firms that hire them.
– When a firm cuts the wage it pays, the more
talented workers are more likely to quit, knowing
they are better able to find other employment.
– Conversely, a firm may choose to pay an above-
equilibrium wage to attract better workers.
4
ADVERSE SELECTION – SUMMARY
• Nature of the Problem
– In these examples one side of the market (buyer or
seller) has incentives to conceal info from the other
(seller or buyer).
• Thus it is a hidden information issue.
– One side of the market won’t know the hidden info but
assume the other side has incentives to conceal it.
• Implications
– In extreme situations the market may disappear
completely even though buyers want to buy at prices
sellers would be willing to accept.
– A market fails to exist.
5
ADVERSE SELECTION – SOLUTIONS
• Screening is an action taken by an uninformed
party to induce an informed party to reveal
information.
– A person buying a used car may ask that a mechanic
check it over before the sale.
• A seller who refuses this request reveals that the car is most
likely a lemon.
– An insurance company may require medical
examination or exclude claims for a certain period
• A buyer refusing to comply reveals that he has pre-existing
health issues
6
MORAL HAZARD – EXAMPLE 2
• Property insurance
– People who fully insure property may not ‘take care’
of the property sufficiently.
• Firms with fire insurance may be less likely to buy fire
extinguishers
• Similarly households may locate their homes near rivers
with a risk of flooding or near forests with bushfire risks
because insurance companies / governments contribute to
disaster relief while they enjoy the scenic views
• Persons with car insurance may drive more recklessly or
leave their cars unsecured more often
• Implications
– Again the side of the market subject to the info
disadvantage will change the way they do business &
in extreme cases may not do business at all.
7
MORAL HAZARD – SOLUTIONS
• Better monitoring
– Firms checking on workers through technology such
as spy cams, biometrics, etc
– Parents hiring babysitters have been known to plant
hidden video cameras (nanny cams) in their homes
• Efficiency wages
– Employers may choose to pay their workers a wage
that is above the equilibrium wage
– A worker who earns an above-equilibrium wage is less
likely to shirk, because if they are caught and fired it
will be very hard for them to find a similar high-paying
job.
8
IN GENERAL
• Asymmetric information gives new reasons to
be wary of markets.
– When some people know more than others markets
may not put resources to their best uses.
• Sellers of high quality cars find it hard to sell their cars
• People with good health may have trouble buying low-cost
insurance
– Indeed, in extreme cases, markets may fail to exist.
POLITICAL ECONOMY
• The application of economic concepts and
methods to the study of how government
works.
9
DESIRABLE PROPERTIES FOR A
VOTING SYSTEM
• Transitivity
– if A is preferred over B, and B is preferred to C, then
A is also preferred to C.
10
CONDORCET VOTING PARADOX
• Following the majority voting system
– Star Wars is majority preferred over Harry Potter.
• Kirk and McCoy both have this ordering
– Harry Potter is majority preferred over Police
Academy.
• David and Spock both have this ordering
– But Police Academy is majority preferred over Star
Wars.
• Spock and McCoy both have this ordering)
11
CONDORCET VOTING PARADOX
– Conducting a vote (Pairwise)
• Now compare Star Wars with Police Academy
12
CONDORCET VOTING PARADOX
– Conducting a vote (Pairwise)
• Now compare Harry Potter with Star Wars
BEHAVIOURAL ECONOMICS
• Recently, behavioural economics has emerged
– economists make use of psychology to examine
how people actually make decisions rather than
relying on the assumption of rationality.
13
BEHAVIOURAL ECONOMICS
• Experiments by psychologists and economists
have shown that people are not always rational
– there are a number of systematic mistakes that
many people make
• People are overconfident – favour positive outcomes over
negative outcomes; e.g. creation of bubbles in housing
markets
• People give too much weight to a small number of vivid
observations ; e.g. fear of natural disasters
• People are reluctant to change their minds; they interpret
evidence according to their prior beliefs; considering
corona virus as being similar to earlier types of flu
BEHAVIOURAL ECONOMICS
• Another insight from behavioural economics is
that people care about fairness
• The ultimatum game demonstrates that players
care whether the outcome is ‘fair’ or not
– Structure of the game
• $100 is to be split between two people.
• Player A will propose to share the $100 with B.
• For example A might offer B $30 and keep $70 for herself.
• If B accepts the offer from A, the money is split as A
proposed.
• If B does not agree to the split then neither party gets
anything.
– Problem: How much should A offer B?
14
BEHAVIOURAL ECONOMICS
• Solution to the game
– Rationality suggests
• A should offer B the smallest amount possible amount (say
1 dollar) and keep the other $99 for herself.
• B should accept this since something is better than nothing
(which is what she gets after rejecting).
BEHAVIOURAL ECONOMICS
• Relevance to business decisions
– Assume I want to sell you my car.
• The minimum I will accept for my car is $5000 and
• the maximum you will pay is $6000.
– We should be able to agree at a price between
$5000-$6000.
– But suppose I will only sell for $5999 so I get $999
worth of surplus leaving you with $1. Will you
accept?
• You might but you might sense that I am getting an unfair
share of the surplus and not accept even though – as
person B in the ultimatum game – you would be better-off.
15
SUMMARY
• In many transactions, information is
asymmetric.
– With hidden actions, principals may be concerned
that they suffer from problems of moral hazard.
– With hidden information buyers (or sellers) may be
concerned about adverse selection.
SUMMARY
• The study of psychology & economics reveals
that human decision-making is more complex
than assumed in conventional economic
theory.
– People do not always reflect self-interest alone -
they care about the fairness of economic outcomes.
– Thinking about things in this way offers new insights
about a basic issue of economics – namely how
people do a deal & how they share the ‘gains from
trade’.
16