Location via proxy:   [ UP ]  
[Report a bug]   [Manage cookies]                

Land Law Project

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 15

DR.

RAM MANOHAR LOHIA NATIONAL LAW


UNIVERSITY

2019-2020

LAND LAW OF U.P.

FINAL DRAFT

LAND ACQUISITION IN INDIA

Submitted to: Submitted by:

Dr. Shakuntala Sangam Vaibhav Verma

Asssistant Professor(Law) Enroll No. 140101157

Sec-B, Sem-IX

1​ | ​Page
ACKNOWLEDGEMENT

I would take great pleasure in thanking my ​LAND LAW teacher, ​DR. SHAKUNTALA
SANGAM for her infallible support all through the course of this project. This endeavor would
not have been in its present shape had she not been there whenever I needed her. She has been a
constant source of support all the while.

Also I would like to extend my sincere thanks to the library staff for always helping me out with
finding excellent books and material almost every time I needed. They too have been a constant
support system in the completion of this project.

Last but surely not the least- I would like to thank my friends for their timely critical analysis of
my work and special feedback that worked towards the betterment of this work.

-​VAIBHAV VERMA

2​ | ​Page
TABLE OF CONTENT

1) INTRODUCTION
2) EMINENT DOMAIN
3) LEGISLATIVES CHANGES
4) MONETARY COMPENSATION
5) DELAYED PROJECTS
6) CONSEQUENCES
7) PROPOSED AMENDMENTS

3​ | ​Page
INTRODUCTION

Land acquisition in India refers to the process by which the union or a state government in India
acquires private land for the purpose of industrialisation, development of infrastructural facilities
or urbanisation of the private land, and provides compensation to the affected landowners and
their rehabilitation and resettlement.

Land acquisition in India is governed by the Right to Fair Compensation and Transparency in
Land Acquisition, Rehabilitation and Resettlement Act, 2013 (LARR) and which came into force
from 1 January 2014. Till 2013, land acquisition in India was governed by the Land Acquisition
Act of 1894. On 31 December 2013, the President of India promulgated an ordinance with an
official mandate to "meet the twin objectives of farmer welfare; along with expeditiously
meeting the strategic and developmental needs of the country". An amendment bill was then
introduced in Parliament to endorse the Ordinance. Lok Sabha passed the bill but the same is still
lying for passage by the Rajya Sabha. On 30 May 2015, President of India promulgated the
amendment ordinance for third time. Union Government of India has also made and notified the
Right to Fair Compensation and Transparency in Land Acquisition, Rehabilitation and
Resettlement (Social Impact Assessment and Consent) Rules, 2014 under the Act to regulate the
procedure. The land acquisition in Jammu and Kashmir is governed by the Jammu and Kashmir
Land Acquisition Act 1934.

EMINENT DOMAIN

The power to take property from the individual is rooted in the idea of eminent domain. The
doctrine of eminent domain states, the sovereign can do anything, if the act of sovereign involves
public interest. The doctrine empowers the sovereign to acquire private land for a public use,
provided the public nature of the usage can be demonstrated beyond doubt. The doctrine is based
on the following two Latin maxims, (1) Salus populi suprema lex (Welfare of the People Is the
Paramount Law) and (2) Necessitas publica major est quam (Public Necessity Is Greater Than

4​ | ​Page
Private Necessity). In the history of modern India, this doctrine was challenged twice (broadly
speaking) once when land reform was initiated and another time when Banks were nationalized.

The Constitution of India originally provided the right to property (which includes land) under
Articles 19 and 31. Article 19 guaranteed that all citizens have the right to acquire, hold and
dispose of property. Article 31 stated that "no person shall be deprived of his property save by
authority of law." It also indicated that compensation would be paid to a person whose property
has been taken for public purposes (often subject to wide range of meaning). The Forty-Fourth
Amendment of 1978 deleted the right to property from the list of fundamental rights with the
introduction of a new provision, Article 300-A, which provided that "no person shall be deprived
of his property save by authority of law" (Constitution 44th Amendment, w.e.f. 10.6.1979). The
amendment ensured that the right to property‟ is no longer a fundamental right but rather a
constitutional/legal right/as a statutory right and in the event of breach, the remedy available to
an aggrieved person is through the High Court under Article 226 of the Indian Constitution and
not the Supreme Court under Article 32 of the Constitution. State must pay compensation at the
market value for such land, building or structure acquired (Inserted by Constitution, Seventeenth
Amendment) Act, 1964, the same can be found in the earlier rulings when property right was a
fundamental right (such as 1954 AIR 170, 1954 SCR 558, which propounded that the word
"Compensation" deployed in Article 31(2) implied full compensation, that is the market value of
the property at the time of the acquisition. The Legislature must "ensure that what is determined
as payable must be compensation, that is, a just equivalent of what the owner has been deprived
of"). Elsewhere, Justice, Reddy, O Chinnappa ruled (State Of Maharashtra v. Chandrabhan Tale
on 7 July 1983) that the fundamental right to property has been abolished because of its
incompatibility with the goals of "justice" social, economic and political and "equality of status
and of opportunity" and with the establishment of "a socialist democratic republic, as
contemplated by the Constitution. There is no reason why a new concept of property should be
introduced in the place of the old so as to bring in its wake the vestiges of the doctrine of Laissez
Faire and create, in the name of efficiency, a new oligarchy. Efficiency has many facets and one

5​ | ​Page
is yet to discover an infallible test of efficiency to suit the widely differing needs of a developing
society such as ours" (1983 AIR 803, 1983 SCR (3) 327). The concept of efficiency has been
introduced by Justice Reddy, O Chinnappa, coupled with the condition of infallibility.

In India, with the introduction of ‘social’ elements to the property rights, a new phase had begun.
K. K. Mathew, justice of KesavanandaBharati vs State of Kerala stated this precisely: "Property
in consumable goods or means of production worked by their owners (use aspects of property)
were justified as a necessary condition of a free and purposeful life; but when property gave
power not only over things but through things over persons (power aspect of property) also, it
was not justified as it was an instrument of servitude rather than freedom."

LEGISLATIVE CHANGES

The 2013 Act focuses on providing not only compensation to the land owners, but also extend
rehabilitation and resettlement benefits to livelihood looser from the land, which shall be in
addition to the minimum compensation. The minimum compensation to be paid to the land
owners is based on a multiple of market value and other factors laid down in the Act. The Act
forbids or regulates land acquisition when such acquisition would include multi-crop irrigated
area. The Act changed the norms for acquisition of land for use by private companies or in case
of public-private partnerships, including compulsory approval of 80% of the landowners. The
Act also introduced changes in the land acquisition process, including a compulsory
social-impact study, which need to be conducted before an acquisition is made.

6​ | ​Page
The new law, also has some serious shortcomings as regards its provisions for socioeconomic
impact assessment and it has also bypassed the constitutional local self governments by not
recognizing them as "appropriate governments" in matters of land acquisition.

Purpose of LARR As per the Act, the union or state governments can acquire lands for its own
use, hold and control, including for public sector undertakings and for "public purpose", and
shall include the following purposes:

for strategic purposes relating to naval, military, air force, and armed forces of the Union,
including central paramilitary forces or any work vital to national security or defence of India or
State police, safety of the people;

for infrastructure projects as defined under the Act;

project for project affected families;

project for housing for such income groups, as may be specified from time to time by the
appropriate Government;

project for planned development or the improvement of village sites or any site in the urban areas
or provision of land for residential purposes for the weaker sections in rural and urban areas;

project for residential purposes to the poor or landless or to persons residing in areas affected by
natural calamities, or to persons displaced or affected by reason of the implementation of any
scheme undertaken by Government, any local authority or a corporation owned or controlled by
the State.

The land can be acquired for private bodies for certain purposes:

for public private partnership projects, where the ownership of the land continues to vest with the
Government, for public purpose as defined in the Act; for private companies for public purpose.

7​ | ​Page
MONETARY COMPENSATION

Major Indian infrastructure projects such as the Yamuna Expressway have paid about ₹2800
crore (US$500 million) for land,[19] or over US$25,000 per acre between 2007 and 2009. For
context purposes, this may be compared with land prices elsewhere in the world:

According to The Financial Times, in 2008, the farmland prices in France were Euro 6,000 per
hectare ($2,430 per acre; ₹1,09,350 per acre).[20]

According to the United States Department of Agriculture, as of January 2010, the average
farmland value in the United States was $2,140 per acre (₹96,300 per acre). The farmland prices
in the United States varied between different parts of the country, ranging between $480 per acre
to $4,690 per acre.[21]

A 2010 report by the Government of India, on labor whose livelihood depends on agricultural
land, claims that, per 2009 data collected across all states in India, the all-India annual average
daily wage rates in agricultural occupations ranged between ₹ [22] 53 to 117 per day for men
working in farms (US$354 to 780 per year), and between ₹41 to 72 per day for women working
in farms (US$274 to 480 per year). This wage rate in rural India study included the following
agricultural operations common in India: ploughing, sowing, weeding, transplanting, harvesting,
winnowing, threshing, picking, herdsmen, tractor driver, unskilled help, masonry, etc.

The compensation for the acquired land is based on the value of the agricultural land, however
price increases have been ignored. The land value would increase many times, which the current
buyer would not benefit from. Secondly, if the prices are left for the market to determine, the

8​ | ​Page
small peasants could never influence the big corporate tycoons. Also it is mostly judiciary who
has awarded higher compensation then bureaucracy.

DELAYED PROJECTS

Due to mass unrest have caused a damaging effect to the growth and development of companies
and the economy as a whole. Earlier states like Maharashtra, Tamil Nadu, Karnataka, and
Andhra Pradesh had been an attractive place for investors, but the present day revolts have
shown that land acquisition in some states pose problems.

CONSEQUENCES

The consequences of land acquisition in India are manifold.The empirical and theoretical studies
on displacement through the acquisition of land by the government for development projects
have so far focussed on the direct and immediate adverse consequences of land acquisition. Most
of the analytical as well as the descriptive accounts of the immediate consequences of land
acquisition for development projects draws heavily from Michael Cernea’s ‘impoverishment risk
model’, which broadly enumerated eight ‘risks’ or ‘dimensions’ of development-induced
displacement. These eight risks are very much direct and basic in nature which are (i)
landlessness, (ii) joblessness, (iii) marginalization, (iv) loss of access to common property
resources, (v) increased morbidity and mortality, (vi) food insecurity, (vii) homelessness and
(viii) social disarticulation. Recently L.K. Mahapatra has added ‘loss of education’ as another
impoverishment risk in situations of displacement (Mahapatra 1999).

But apart from these direct and immediate effects of land acquisition there are more subtle and
indirect effects of this coercive and centralized legal procedure, which have a bearing on various
decentralised and participatory democratic processes, and institutions of the state power. Land

9​ | ​Page
reforms and the Panchayati raj institutions are the two most important areas, which are being
vitiated by land acquisition. Of all the states of India, the consequences and controversies around
land acquisition in West Bengal has recently gained a lot of national and international attention.
The peasant resistances against governmental land expropriation in Singur(a place in the Hoogly
district) and Nandigram(a place in the East Medinipur district) has finally led to the fall of the
communist party (Marxist) led government in West Bengal, which ruled the state through
democratic election for 34 years.The communist led left front government of West Bengal under
the economic liberalisation policy adopted by the Central/Union government of the country
shifted from its pro-farmer policy and took to the capitalist path of industrial development, which
at the micro-levels endangered the food security of the small and marginal farmers as well as
sharecroppers who formed the vote bank of the left front government of West Bengal The new
anti-communist Trinamul Congress led government of West Bengal which came to power in the
state in 2011 through a massive electoral victory is yet to develop any comprehensive
resettlement and rehabilitation policy for the thousands of families affected by various
development projects. The new government has enacted a law on 14 June 2011, in the West
Bengal Assembly named ‘Singur Land Rehabilitation and Development Act, 2011’. With this
law, the West Bengal government has reacquired about 1000 acres of farmland from the Tatas
which was given to the company for building a small-car manufacturing factory in 2006 by the
then Left Front government. The Trinamul government’s intention was to return 400 acres of
farmland to the ‘unwilling’ farmers around whom the agitation against the Left Front
government was organised by the Trinamool Congress party. However, now the whole issue
seems to have fallen into a long legal battle between the present state government and the Tatas,
as the latter has challenged the ‘Singur Land Rehabilitation and Development Act’ in the court.
As a result, the Trinamul government has not yet been able to return the land to those ‘unwilling
farmers’ nor have they received any compensation (The Statesman, 12 January 2012).In another
case of governmental land acquisition for housing at North 24 Parganas district of West Bengal,
the farmers began to cultivate their farmland which were acquired but remained unutilised.
According to media report these farmers were assured by the Trinamool Congress party leaders
before the election that their land, which is about 1687 acres would be returned to them if the

10​ | ​Page
party could come to power. However, now these farmers are turning their backs to the Trinamool
Congress, since the party has not kept its pre-election promise (The Statesman, 11 February
2012). Under the above disturbing episodes, it may be worthwhile to narrate the glaring incident
of the opposition levelled by Mamata Banerjee, the present chief minister of West Bengal to the
draft Land Acquisition (Amendment) Bill 2007 in the Lok Sabha. At that time Miss Mamata
Banerjee was the Railway Minister of the Central Government. She opposed to a clause of the
bill which empowered private companies to acquire up to 70 per cent land directly from farmers
and landowners. The remaining 30 per cent could be acquired by the state government. Miss
Banerjee wanted private companies to buy 100 per cent of the land, according to a report (The
Statesman, 26 July 2009). It seemed that Miss Banerjee would have allowed the amended Bill to
be passed if the Lok Sabha agreed to modify the 70/30 proportion to 100 per cent purchase by
the companies under the principleof willing-buyer-willing-seller.

Eminent domain doctrine has been widely used in India since the era of Independence, with over
21.6 million people in the period of 1951-90.[30] They have been displaced with large-scale
projects like dams, canals, thermal plants, sanctuaries, industrial facilities, and mining (Pellissery
and Dey Biswas 2012, pp 32–54). These occurrences are generally categorized as
"development-induced displacement".

The process of land acquisition in India has proven unpopular with the citizenry. The amount
reimbursed is fairly low with regard to the current index of prices prevailing in the economy.
Furthermore, due to the low level of human capital of the displaced people, they often fail to find
adequate employment.

The draft of the government’s National Policy for Rehabilitation states that a figure around 75%
of the displaced people since 1951 are still awaiting rehabilitation. However, displacement is
only being considered with regard to "Direct Displacement". These rehabilitation policies do not

11​ | ​Page
cover fishermen, landless laborers, and artisans. Roughly one in ten Indian tribals is a displaced
person. Dam projects have displaced close to a million Adivasis, with similar woe for displaced
Dalits. Some estimate suggests 40 percent of displaced people are of tribal origins (Fernandes,
2008).

There have been a rising number of political and social protests against the acquisition of land by
various industrialists. They have ranged from Bengal, Karnataka, and Uttar Pradesh in the recent
past. The acquisition of 997 acres of land by Tata motors in Bengal in order to set up a factory
for the cheapest car in India was protested (Singur Tata Nano controversy).At least a decade
before the Singur episode similar events occurred in West Bengal, although the opposition
parties and other civil society organisations remained silent at that time. Similarly, the Sardar
Sarovar Dam project on the river Narmada was planned on acquired land, though the project was
later canceled by the World Bank (Bøås and McNeill 2003, pp 121-122, 125, 142-43 and more.

The Land Acquisition Act of 1894 allowed the government to acquire private lands. It is the only
legislation pertaining to land acquisition which, though amended several times, has failed to
serve its purpose. Under the 1894 Act, displaced people were only liable for monetary
compensation linked with market value of the land in question, which was still quite minimal
considering circle rates are often misleading.

PROPOSED AMENDMENTS

The current Narendra Modi led National Democratic Alliance government driven Land
Acquisition Amendment Bill in the Lok Sabha on 10 March 2015 has seen a tough resistance
from key position parties in India who have called the proposed amendments "anti farmer" and
"anti poor". The proposed amendments remove requirements for approval from farmers to
proceed with land acquisition under five broad categories of projects.While the bill was passed in

12​ | ​Page
Lok Sabha, it still needs approval from the Rajya Sabha, where the current government does not
have a majority, for the proposed amendments to become effective.

The following are the main "disputation points":

The Right to Fair Compensation and Transparency in Land Acquisition, Rehabilitation and
Resettlement Act, 2013(Land Acquisition Act, 2013) defines ‘consent’ clause as "land can only
be acquired with approval of the 70% of the land owners for PPP projects and 80% for the
private entities. But the proposed amendments by the Narendra Modi government does away
with consent clause for Industrial corridors, Public Private Partnership projects, Rural
Infrastructure, Affordable housing and defense projects.

Land Acquisition Act, 2013 states that land not utilised for 5 years should be returned to the
owner, but the amendment proposed by the NDA government intends to change to 5 years or any
period specified at the time of setting up the project.

While the Land Acquisition Act, 2013 allows private companies to acquire land but the proposed
amendment allows any private entity to acquire land.

According to the new amendment if any government official conducts any wrongdoing he or she
cannot be prosecuted without prior sanction from the government.

Land Acquisition Act, 2013 mandated the social assessment before land acquisition but the NDA
government’s proposed bill does away with this requirement.

The Government came under heavy attacks from opposition parties and farmer organization for
the proposed Land Acquisition bill amendments. The opponents of the Land acquisition bill
claim the bill to be "anti-farmer" and "pro corporate". They claim that the amendments are aimed
at "benefiting the large corporate houses".

13​ | ​Page
The opposition, including the Indian National Congress, has opposed the bill in and out of
Parliament. Sonia Gandhi, the chairperson of the United Progressive Alliance and Indian
National Congress, called the bill "anti-poor" and "anti-farmer". She alleged that the bill will
"break the backbone of India".

Samajwadi party leader Mulayam Singh Yadav said the Modi government is "taking anti-farmer
stand" and is "favoring industrialists".

Not only the opposition parties but also other organizations that traditionally supported Bharatiya
Janata Party such as Mazdoor Sangh, Bhartiya Kisan Sangh and Akhil Bhartiya Vanvasi Kalyan
Ashram have come heavily against the amendments proposed by the Narendra Modi led NDA
government. As per the Bharatiya Kisan Sangh, the Modi government’s land ordinance tweaks
the fundamentals of The Right to Fair Compensation and Transparency in Land Acquisition,
Rehabilitation and Resettlement Act, 2013 passed by the UPA government and supported by the
BJP two years ago.

CONCLUSION

One of the alternative proposals to land acquisition is leasing the land from landowners for a
certain lease period. Proponents cite how land acquisition policies by Governments unwittingly
encourage rampant land speculation making the projects expensive since huge portion of
investment would be need to be allocated for land acquisition costs.[46] According to them,
policies of land acquisition gave way to political cronyism where land is acquired cheaply by
securing favors from local governments and sold to industries at steep markup prices. Leasing
land, may also support sustainable project development since the lands need to be returned to the
landowners at the end of the lease period in a condition similar to its original form with out
considerable environmental degradation. When the land is leased then anybody who has to

14​ | ​Page
otherwise give up land or livelihood will be compensated for its growing valuation over time. In
this model, the landowner lends her land to the government for a steadily-increasing rent, or
through an annuity-based system as currently practiced in Haryana and Uttar Pradesh.

BIBLIOGRAPHY

● https://en.m.wikipedia.org/wiki/Land_acquisition_in_India#cite_note-46
● https://en.m.wikipedia.org/wiki/Land_acquisition_in_India#cite_note-40
● https://en.m.wikipedia.org/wiki/Land_acquisition_in_India
● https://www.google.com/url?sa=t&source=web&rct=j&url=https://www.prsi
ndia.org/uploads/media/Land%2520Acquisition/bill167_20080311167_The
_Land_Acquisition_Act__1894.pdf&ved=2ahUKEwinwYvLhNPlAhXZV3
0KHbGeAuAQFjAfegQIAhAB&usg=AOvVaw1Gvx-0yF5OmEQaPqA-K5
Ts&cshid=1572957622874
● https://www.google.com/url?sa=t&source=web&rct=j&url=http://www.mon
daq.com/india/x/860498/trials%2Bappeals%2Bcompensation/To%2BRecuse
%2BOr%2BNot%2BTo%2BRecuse%2BThe%2BSupreme%2BCourts%2B
Hamlet%2BMoment%2BIn%2BThe%2BRecent%2BRuling%2BOn%2BRe
cusal%2BOf%2BJudges&ved=2ahUKEwinwYvLhNPlAhXZV30KHbGeAu
AQxfQBMCF6BAgDEAg&usg=AOvVaw15UvBrPuBhUY5PtPahaEGy&c
shid=1572957622874

15​ | ​Page

You might also like