Navigating The Trilemma: Capital Flows and Monetary Policy in China
Navigating The Trilemma: Capital Flows and Monetary Policy in China
Navigating The Trilemma: Capital Flows and Monetary Policy in China
A Service of
zbw
Leibniz-Informationszentrum
Wirtschaft
Working Paper
Navigating the trilemma: Capital flows and monetary
policy in China
Suggested Citation: Glick, Reuven; Hutchison, Michael (2008) : Navigating the trilemma: Capital
flows and monetary policy in China, Working Paper, No. 08-11, University of California, Santa
Cruz Institute for International Economics (SCIIE), Santa Cruz, CA
Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your
Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes.
Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial
Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them
machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise
use the documents in public.
Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen
(insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open
gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you
genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated
licence.
www.econstor.eu
Navigating the Trilemma: Capital Flows and Monetary Policy in China
December 2008
Abstract:
The views expressed below do not represent those of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or
the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Hutchison’s work on this project was
started while a visiting fellow at the Hong Kong Institute for Monetary Research (HKIMR). We
thank Kenneth Chow and Katherine Chen for excellent research assistance and Dong He for data.
We also thank participants at the conference “Global Liquidity and East Asian Economies” held at
the HKMIR in Hong Kong on June 26-27, 2008, especially our discussants Hiro Ito, Hans Genberg,
and Dong He, as well as participants at the American Committee on Asian Economic Studies
(ACAES) conference “Asian Economic Integration in a Global Context” held in Rimini, Italy
on August 29-31, for helpful comments.
1. Introduction
The trilemma paradigm of open economy macroeconomics asserts that a country may not
simultaneously target the exchange rate, run an independent monetary policy, and allow full capital
mobility.1 In the mid to late 1980s most developing countries addressed the trilemma by
maintaining a combination of exchange rate stability and monetary independence, with relatively
closed capital accounts. In the late 1980s and early 1990s, some developing countries, such as
Mexico, Thailand, and Korea, embraced growing financial liberalization and openness. However,
as they opened more financially, many of these countries also tried to maintain some degree of
exchange rate stability and monetary independence, and failed to successfully navigate the
trilemma. Their inconsistent policy goals resulted in severe financial crises, in Mexico during
1994-95 and in Asia during 1997-98. In the early 1990s Argentina adopted another trilemma
configuration involving exchange rate fixity, supported by a version of a currency board, and
complete financial integration. Argentina also experienced a crisis when ceding monetary policy
independence to a currency board arrangement was no longer viable.
China has pursued a more cautious path towards greater financial openness. Although tax
benefits and other incentives have been used to promote inward foreign direct investment, other
forms of inflows, particularly portfolio capital and external debt, have been traditionally
discouraged. Capital controls have also played a role in protecting the banking system from
external competition by restricting the entry of foreign banks and by making it harder for capital to
flow out of the country. The limited development of debt and equity markets in the past preserved
the role of the state-owned banking system as the main international intermediary for Chinese
borrowers and savers.
As China slowly liberalizes its capital account, it faces a key challenge of maintaining
domestic monetary and price stability.2 To avoid the trilemma problem, China has allowed
somewhat more exchange rate flexibility in recent years. But growing balance of payments
surpluses through both the current and financial accounts have put upward pressure on the
currency. To limit appreciation of the domestic currency, the renminbi (Rmb), Chinese monetary
authorities have intervened in the foreign exchange market and accumulated massive amounts of
foreign reserve. As a result, China’s holdings of foreign reserves have risen from $140 billion in
1
See Obstfeld, Shambaugh, and Taylor, 2005 for further discussion and references dealing with the trilemma. Related
papers have raised the possibility that a pegged exchange rate is a trap in the era of greater financial integration (e.g.,
Eichengreen, 2001; Frankel, 1999; Edwards and Levy-Yeyati, 2005; Aizenman and Glick, 2008).
2
For example, China in recent years has permitted limited expansion of portfolio capital flows through “qualified
investment” programs. Moreover, unofficial flows into and out of China have grown over time.
2
1997 (15 percent of GDP) to over $1.5 trillion at the end of 2007 (more than 45 percent of GDP),
with two-thirds of this buildup occurring in the last three years.
This reserve buildup has raised concerns about monetary and inflation stability in China, as
both money aggregates and prices have grown faster. A not-so-distant memory is the excessive
expansion of the monetary base, money, and credit between 1991 and 1994 – when these
aggregates grew at times by over 40 percent per annum -- resulting in high inflation, with CPI
rising near 30 percent at its peak.3 The current foreign reserve boom has lead to similarly large
increases in the monetary base in recent quarters, threatening a return of higher inflation. In recent
quarters the monetary base has grown over 30 percent and CPI inflation has risen above 8 percent.4
As long as China continues to place a higher priority on exchange rate stability than on
using monetary policy as tool for macroeconomic control, China’s scope for an autonomous
monetary policy is constrained. Chinese monetary authorities have addressed this current
challenge by more aggressive open market sterilization operations as well as by raising reserve
requirement ratios and employing window guidance measures. The extent to which China will
successfully confront the trilemma problem depends on achieving the right balance of policy
objectives. As reserve accumulation continues, the conflict between monetary and exchange rate
objectives will become increasingly harder to resolve, particularly as remaining controls on capital
flow become more difficult to maintain.
In this paper we investigate the extent to which the rise in China’s foreign reserves has
affected the country’s monetary policy and been a source of monetary instability contributing to
higher inflation. We begin by characterizing the nature of China’s balance of payment flows and
the effectiveness of its capital controls. We find that pressure on China’s exchange rate regime
increased after its ascension to the World Trade Organization in 2001 and the emergence of
growing current account surpluses. These surpluses, together with large long-standing inflows of
foreign direct investment, have presented China’s authorities with a structural imbalance in the
country’s balance of payments. This imbalance, combined with bouts of “hot money” capital
inflows spurred by speculation on Rmb appreciation against a backdrop of greater capital account
openness, has led the People’s Bank of China (PBC) to engage in ever-increasing foreign exchange
market purchases and foreign asset accumulation to dampen appreciation of the currency.
3
This episode was also characterized by a sharp deterioration of asset quality, resulting in substantial increases in non-
performing bank loans.
4
Since much of this inflation has shown up as a sharp increase in food prices, attributable to food shortages caused by
bad weather and livestock disease, some have argued that the recent inflation is not monetary in origin. Rogoff (2008)
has described these alternative views as the “pork” vs. “money” debate and states that "Those who believe that the
cause of China's inflation is too little pork, rather than too much money, are seriously mistaken."
3
The second part of our analysis measures the degree to which the PBC has been able to
insulate reserve money growth from the liquidity effects associated with rapid foreign asset
accumulation. We present estimates of how China’s marginal propensity to sterilize the effects of
foreign asset accumulation on the monetary base has changed over time, rising until 2006 and then
sharply declining as the authorities found it increasingly more difficult to limit the liquidity effects
of massive foreign exchange asset accumulation.
The third part of our analysis addresses the broader monetary and inflationary impacts of
the foreign reserve buildup. We formulate and estimate a vector error correction model (VECM)
characterizing the evolution of reserve money, broad money, real GDP, and prices. Although each
variable individually appears to follow a stationary process in first differences, formal co-
integration tests suggest that two long-term stable relationships (co-integrating vectors)
characterize the system. We interpret these co-integrating relationships as long-run money demand
and money supply functions. Estimates of the VECM model, which captures both short-run
dynamics and long-term relationships in the data, allow us to carry out model simulations for
alternative paths of foreign reserve accumulation and sterilization. Under a scenario of rapid
foreign exchange reserve accumulation, limited exchange rate flexibility, and rapid economic
growth—the economic environment of recent years--the model predicts a rapid increase in
inflation if sterilization continues to have limited effectiveness. An extension of the model
incorporates increases in bank reserve requirements and predicts similar inflationary pressures.
However, an alternative scenario with slow economic growth but continued rapid reserve money
growth predicts a decline in inflation over a three year horizon.
The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the pattern of balance of payments
flows that underlie the surge in China’s accumulation of foreign reserves. Section 3 analyzes the
PBC’s efforts to sterilize the effects of the reserve inflows on the conduct of monetary policy.
Section 4 presents the VECM results capturing the dynamic interaction of reserve inflows and
monetary control in China. This section also presents alternative monetary policy simulations.
Section 5 concludes the paper.
5
This interpretation is standard in the literature, e.g. Prasad and Wei (2005b). Ma and MacCauley (2007) suggest that
hot money inflows also may occur through the current account, in the form of rising inward remittance transfers and
lagging dividend and interest payments, as well under- and over-invoicing of exports and imports in years when the
rmb is expected to appreciate.
6
Note that because GDP grew so fast between 2004 and 2005, reserves as a ratio of GDP fell slightly during that
period.
7
These figures do not incorporate adjustments that have been suggested in order to deal with the PBC's use of foreign
exchange reserves to recapitalize state banks in 2003 and 2005 (adding these in would increase the reported foreign
reserve inflows), the capitalization of the CIC at the end of 2007 and into 2008, and the PBC's "encouragement" of
state banks to use dollar assets to meet reserve requirements in 2007 and 2008.
8
The swing in the flow of securities between 2006 and 2007 amounted to $169 billion.
5
billion, $7 billion, and $27 billion, between 2001-04 and 2005-06; and then rose by $279 billion,
$81 billion, and $41 billion between 2005-06 and 2007.10
These swings in hot money illustrate the sensitivity of capital flows to market
considerations. The immediate post-Asia crisis period coincided with depreciation pressures on
the Rmb, prompting capital outflows. The increase in money inflows during the period 2001- 04
coincided with U.S. Federal Reserve interest rate cuts beginning in January 2001, relatively stable
Chinese interest rates, and expectations of an Rmb appreciation, as reflected in offshore markets
for non-deliverable forwards (NDF); see Figure 3. The unpegging of the Rmb to the dollar and
subsequent currency appreciation beginning in July 2005 temporarily curtailed these speculative
inflows and lead to the emergence of net outflows, particularly as U.S. interest rates rose.
Subsequently, the emergence again of a positive interest differential between China and the United
States combined with ongoing perceptions of an undervalued Rmb may have exacerbated the
speculative movement into Rmb-denominated instruments, by essentially creating the perception
of a one-way bet for investors, without an associated carrying cost.
We can gain further insights by investigating details about the subcomponents of “other”
net investment flows – trade credit, loans, currencies and deposits, and “other” -- as plotted in
Figures 4a and 4b. Observe that since 2001, loans and (foreign) currencies & deposits have been
the most volatile components, with both growing strongly since 2005. 11
Next we examine the evolution of gross flows of assets and liabilities of selected categories
of capital flows. These details help shed some light on how capital account liberalization has
affected different categories of financial transactions. Figures 5a and 5b show asset and liability
movements of equity and debt securities. Observe that capital account liberalization evidently lead
to sharply increased equity market inflows on the liability side in 2006, particularly as the stock
market boomed, and on the outflow (asset) side, to greater holdings of foreign debt securities. This
reflects limitations placed on Chinese investors in acquiring foreign stocks. Gross equity security
inflows increased from $2 billion in 2002, to $11 billion in 2004, $20 billion in 2005, and $44
billion in 2006, before declining to $31 billion in 2007. This reflects inflows attracted to China’s
9
Net securities inflows increased sharply from $5 billion in 2005 to $68 billion in 2006, before declining to $10 billion
in 2007. This reflects inflows attracted to China’s booming stock market in 2006, which fell off in 2007 as equity
prices fell.
10
Prasad and Wei (2005b) suggest that errors and omissions may reflect valuation changes of official foreign
exchange reserves (positive when the dollar falls against major currencies, leading to an errors and omission inflow),
rather than unrecorded capital inflows.
11
The interest rate differential and exchange rate expectations especially affected the evolution of Chinese foreign
currency deposits (Ma and McCauley, 2002, 2003, 2007), as the share of onshore foreign currency deposits as a
proportion to Rmb deposit held by Chinese households and firms in China’s banking system declined during the
period over the period 2002-2005 when the Rmb was expected to appreciate.
6
stock market that was newly reformed12 in 2005 and boomed through 2006, but then fell off in
2007 as equity prices fell. Gross outflows in the form of the acquisition of foreign debt securities
rose from $7 billion in 2004, to a remarkable $109 billion in 2006, which then fell to $20 billion in
2007. Figures 6a, 6b, and 6c show asset and liability movements of loans, currency &deposits, and
“other” other investment flows.
Capital controls, which prevent money from moving in an out of an economy easily, can
insulate domestic monetary policy to some extent. Since the start of China’s reform and open-door
policies, foreign direct investment (FDI) inflows have been encouraged, while other inflows and
capital outflows were initially heavily controlled. 13 Non-bank Chinese residents and institutions
had been prohibited from directly investing in overseas securities, though banks were permitted to
invest their own dollar assets in fixed income instruments
In recent years, China has liberalized controls on non-FDI capital flows very slowly.
Authorized banks were allowed to transact cross-border to accommodate onshore non-bank
depositors and borrowers wishing to deposit and borrow in foreign currency. China has sought to
institutionalize the management of two-way portfolio flows through programs for so-called
“qualified foreign institutional investors” (QFIIs) for portfolio inflows and “qualified domestic
institutional investors” (QDIIs) for portfolio outflows.14 Both programs involve pre-approval
procedures, quota management, foreign exchange conversion rules, instrument restrictions, and
intensive reporting requirements. With the introduction of the QDII plan in 2006, China opened an
official channel for Chinese households and firms to gain access to global financial markets.
Appreciation pressures on the Rmb have led China to encourage outflows through other channels,
for example, by relaxing restrictions on currency conversion by domestic residents.15 In addition,
firms and banks have been given flexibility to issue foreign-exchange denominated bonds in local
markets and to raise their direct overseas investment.
12
The main reform was the elimination of the “overhang” from nontraded government-owned shares.
13
The Rmb has been convertible for current account transactions since December 1996, when China satisfied the
IMF’s Article VIII criteria for membership.
14
In December 2002, QFIIs were allowed to invest in A shares and other domestic securities, subject to requirements
of at least $10 billion in assets under management and prior experience. Repatriation was limited by lock-up periods
on stocks of as long as one-year. New rules in September 2006 lowered the asset under management criteria to $5
billion, reduced the lock-up period to three months, lessened experience requirements, and also raised the quotas for
investment in Chinese equities. The QDII program, launched in July 2006, permitted qualified commercial banks,
securities firms, and insurance companies in China to make limited offshore investments in foreign-currency
denominated assets (restricted to fixed income securities in the case of banks and insurance companies).
15
In 2007 the PBC raised to $50 thousand the ceiling on the conversion between Rmb and foreign currency by
Chinese individuals.
7
Though China had tightly controlled portfolio flows and most external debts for a long
time,16 there is evidence that these capital controls were leaky and had tended to become less
effective over time even before the recent relaxation of capital controls. The sheer magnitude of
net and gross portfolio capital and “hot money” inflows clearly casts doubt on the effectiveness of
China’s capital control regime. Moreover, as the evidence presented in Section 2.1 and Ma and
MacCauley (2007) illustrate, despite the existence of remaining capital controls, there are many
indications that China’s capital account flows respond to market conditions, suggesting limits to
the effectiveness of these controls. “Hot money” flows have apparently been responsive to
expectations of Rmb appreciation. Similarly, foreign exchange deposits held by Chinese
households and firms onshore with banks in China have tracked exchange rate expectations, rising
as a share of total bank deposits when the Rmb was expected to depreciate and falling when the
Rmb was expected to appreciate.
Nevertheless, although permitted cross-border flows have helped reduce the effectiveness
of China’s remaining capital controls, they have not been large enough to eliminate the
onshore/offshore Rmb yield gaps. Sizable onshore-offshore yield gaps persist and substantial
evidence analyzing the relationships between implied forward rates, interest rates. and equity
prices indicate that Chinese capital controls continue to be effective in partly “decoupling” Chinese
financial markets from those in the U.S., Hong Kong, and elsewhere (see Cheung et al., 2006; Ma
and McCauley, 2007; and Liu and Otani, 2005).
16
Prasad and Wei (2005a) provide an extensive chronology of capital controls over the period 1980 - January
2005.
8
authorities rely on non-market instruments, such as transferring the deposits of government and
public financial institutions from the commercial banking system to the central bank or selling
foreign exchange reserves to the government (perhaps to allow it to reduce external sovereign
debt).17
Sterilized reserve purchases face no defined limits since the central bank can permit its net
domestic assets to fall below zero by issuing new liabilities. However, sterilized reserve purchases
come at a fiscal cost that depends on the difference between, on the one hand, the return paid on
central bank liabilities issued to sterilize domestic liquidity (or the opportunity cost from foregone
returns on domestic assets, such as government bonds, sold to the private sector) and, on the other
hand, the return earned on foreign reserve assets, as well as foreign exchange risk, if the domestic
currency appreciates. Thus monetary authorities that sell government bonds or central bank bills
to soak up liquidity must offer increasingly higher yields to convince domestic agents to hold
them.
17
Monetary authorities also may seek to sterilize the effects of reserve inflows, not just on the reserve money base, but
also on the broader money supply by, for example, increasing compulsory reserve requirements on bank deposits.
China, for example, has raised reserve requirements significantly in recent years.
18
Using four-quarter changes helps to smooth the data by eliminating much of the quarter to quarter noise.
19
Specifically, we define !NFAt % (S LC / $ )t " R$t - R$t -1 # - " FLt - FLt $1 # , where R$ (IMF line 1l.d), denotes the local
currency price of foreign exchange, FL denotes financial liabilities of the central bank (IMF line 16c), S LC / $ is the
local currency price of the dollar, and " ! " is the change operator. Accordingly, we define !NDA % !RM $ !NFA .
20
The exception is the period 1993 when China sterilized the effects of foreign reserve outflows by expanding the
reserve money stock by increasing domestic asset holdings.
9
central bank), implying the reserve inflows were being sterilized. The increase in the extent of
sterilization in the early 2000s implies a possible break from China’s prior sterilization behavior. 21
China’s high private saving rates, both for household and firms, have resulted in a vast flow
of liquidity into the banking system, as savers have lacked alternative investment opportunities
(until reform of the stock market in 2005).22 Thus, there has been a great deal of demand for PBC
bills even at relatively low interest rates. Consequently, through mid 2006 sterilization was
managed primarily through the sale of PBC bills; see Figure 8.
However, the sheer magnitude of PBC issuance made it harder and harder to place these
securities. As a result, since mid 2006 the PBC began to rely less on bond issuance through open
market operations and more on reserve requirement increases and greater window guidance as the
means to mop up excess liquidity and keep the broader money aggregates from growing
excessively. Figure 9 shows the increases in reserve requirements and corresponding decline in
the M2-reserve requirement multiplier. It also should be noted that, despite a number of recent
increases in the required reserves ratio, the banking system as a whole still has a sizeable amount
of excess reserves at the PBC; see Figure 10. The PBC has cut the rate of remuneration on excess
reserves (now at 0.99 percent) in order to discourage banks from holding these excess reserves; see
Figure 11.23
How successful has the PBC been in restraining overall money aggregate growth? Figure
12 plots 4-quarter growth rates of M2 and reserve money. Observe that reserve money growth,
after being "relatively" low (i.e. below 20 percent) through mid 2006, has suddenly shot up, to
above 30 percent. This is consistent with the story that the monetary authorities were successful
with sterilizing the effects of capital inflows on reserve money until recently, primarily through
open market operations.
21
Proper assessment of the pressure on China’s managed float versus the dollar and the need to sterilize depends on
measuring the foreign reserves held by the PBC as well as the foreign reserves that have been shifted to the balance
sheets of the banking system and the China Investment Corporation (CIC), newly created in September 2007. (The
foreign reserves held by the CIC are being financed by Ministry of Finance through the special issuance of foreign-
currency denominated bonds, implying that the money creation associated with the CIC’s reserve holdings is
effectively fully sterilized.) The foreign exchange managed by the state banks has increased as a result of the
recapitalization of the China Development Bank (CDB) and the increase in the amount of foreign exchange that the
state banks have borrowed from the PBC. As long as Chinese banks hold their foreign exchange offshore, the PBC
foreign reserves holdings are unaffected, also lessening the need for sterilization. State-owned enterprises also have
been encouraged to increase their foreign investment. See Setser (2008).
22
As Prasad (2007) notes, state commercial banks have also been aggressively trying to improve their balance sheets,
including meeting capital adequacy requirements set by the government, in order to attract strategic investors and
undertake successful IPOs. In this context, banks have had an incentive to hold PBC bills rather than increase their
lending since corporate lending carries a capital requirement of 100 percent while no capital needs to be put aside for
lending to the government.
23
The PBC has continued to raise the required reserve ratio through 2008. On June 7, 2008, it announced an increase
of 100 bp to 17.5 percent, the fifth increase of the year.
10
Figure 13 plots the growth rates of M2, domestic credit, and the CPI over time. Observe
that M2 and credit growth peaked in 2002-2003, receded somewhat, but have since risen again.
Moreover, inflation is at its highest since its 1994 peak.
We estimate the sterilization coefficient, ' , with OLS using 40-quarter rolling samples.25 A
unitary coefficient, i.e. ' = -1, on the variable !NFA / RM represents full monetary sterilization of
reserve changes, while ' = 0 implies no sterilization. The results are plotted in Figure 3.
Coefficient observations correspond to the calendar date of the 40th quarter in each rolling
sample.26
Observe that the sterilization coefficient began rising (in absolute value) from roughly 0.6
in 2000, a trend that accelerated in the latter half of 2002 and continued into 2006 when it peaked
at almost 1.5, suggesting the presence of a break in behavior. The plot also indicates a reversal of
China’s sterilization behavior beginning in the fourth quarter of 2006. The reduced degree of
sterilization, with a point estimate approaching 0.8 (significantly less than 1.0), indicates that at
least 20 percent of the growth in foreign reserves is translating into reserve money growth and that
this percentage rose in 2007. This finding is also evident in Figures 7 and 8. Limited sterilization,
24
We imputed quarterly GDP growth in our sample from a moving average of the prior year, current, and following
year observations.
25
Central bank balance sheet data for China is available only from 1985 Q3, implying that the first 4-quarter change
observation begins in 1986 Q2, and the first 40-quarter rolling sample period is 1986 Q2 – 1996 Q1. We then roll the
sample period to 1986 Q3 – 1996 Q2, etc., ending with 1998 Q1 - 2007 Q4.
26
For clarity, we omit standard error bands. It may be stated, however, that the coefficients are always significantly
different from 0. Our estimation procedure abstracts from several econometric issues. For example, it does not taken
account of possible simultaneity bias because net foreign asset changes may respond to domestic monetary policy,
particularly when the central bank intervenes and affects the exchange rate. However, prior work seeking to control
for the possible endogeneity of the explanatory variables in sterilization regressions through instrumental estimation
has not found much effect on coefficient magnitudes and their standard errors as compared to OLS (e.g., Ouyang,
Rajan, and Willett). We also abstract from any dynamics in the sterilization response. An alternative approach
employed by Mohanty and Turner (2006) includes the lagged dependent variable on the righthand side, enabling
estimation of short run and long run sterilization responses (though from an obviously very restricted specification; see
Glick and Hutchison (2003) for an unconstrained approach to estimating sterilization dynamics).
11
in turn, lies behind the surge in reserve money (RM) growth starting in 2006 Q4 and continuing
throughout 2007.
This recent sharp decline in China’s degree of sterilization can be attributed to two
possibilities. First, China’s foreign reserve accumulation in recent periods may be overstated to
the extent that the reported figures have not been adjusted to take account of swaps and shifts of
foreign reserve assets to China’s nascent sovereign wealth fund.27 Second, China may indeed have
reached limits to the extent of its ability to sterilize its massive reserve inflows.28
27
China’s sovereign wealth fund, the China Investment Corporation, was not formally established until the latter half
of 2007 with an initial capitalization of $200 billion out of China’s total reserve holdings of more than $1.3 trillion.
But there are indications of central bank asset shifts to its predecessor institution, Huijins Investment, and to some
Chinese commercial banks before then. Netting these amounts against reported foreign reserve holdings would reduce
the magnitude of foreign reserve inflows and raise the implied level of central bank domestic assets, resulting in a
lower estimated degree of sterilization. Thus, as Setser (2008) points out, China has continued to add to its foreign
assets, but less of the increase is showing up in formal reserves.
28
Aizenman and Glick (2008b) report formal regressions assessing the significance of breaks in China’s (and other
emerging market economies) sterilization behavior. Their methodology identifies an increase in sterilization for China
beginning in 2002 Q2, supporting the rolling regression result that sterilization behavior intensified over the period
2002 Q2 to early 2006. They also report a sharp decline in China’s degree of sterilization in late 2006 and 2007.
12
PBC has tightened bank reserve and lending requirements in an attempt to decouple the link
between reserve money growth and broad money growth, where the latter is more closely linked to
overall spending growth and inflation. On the other hand, our estimates of the sterilization
coefficients suggest that, until quite recently, the PBC has effectively offset the rise in foreign
assets on its balance sheet by corresponding reductions in domestic assets. In addition, increasing
bank reserve requirements have reduced the extent to which reserve money growth has led to
broad money growth. These two factors suggest that the PBC has maintained monetary control. On
the other hand, temporal instability in the sterilization coefficient, together with the surge in
reserve money growth (to over 30 percent in the second half of 2007 on a year over year basis) and
the PBC’s recent implementation of other measures to control broad money growth, suggest that
the sheer magnitude of foreign exchange reserve accumulation has been difficult to manage and is
compromising monetary control.
In this light, an additional issue is that the conventional estimates of sterilization
coefficients, including those reported above, are only partial equilibrium estimates of central bank
behavior and assume the main instrument of domestic monetary control on the central bank
balance sheet is domestic asset sales and purchases. A central bank may manage monetary control
primarily through foreign exchange operations rather than domestic assets, indicating that there is
no sterilization, but still maintain monetary control. For operational purposes, increases (decreases)
in the monetary base may be entirely controlled by foreign reserve purchases (sales) without
compromising domestic monetary control.
29
Foreign exchange assets are not included in the system since our preliminary statistical work shows that sterilization
coefficients vary over time, partly in response to a time-varying policy responses, and this would lead to instability in
the co-integrating relationships. Our strategy is to investigate model simulations under alternative paths of foreign
reserve accumulation and sterilization from which we are able to derive a path of reserve money growth.
13
4
Yt % d t ( X t , X t % + * i X t $i ( ) t
i %1
which is equivalent to
3 4
!X t % *X t $1 ( + , i !X t $1 ( -d t ( ) t , * % $ I 4 ( + * i
i %1 i %1
or
3
!X t % &' . X t $1 ( + , i !X t $1 ( -d t ( ) t
i %1
where Y is the vector consisting of deterministic (d) and endogenous (X) variables (RGDP, CPI,
M2, RM). The deterministic variables are intercept constants and three quarterly seasonal dummy
variables.
This is a four-dimensional vector process and the unit root tests, shown in Table 3, indicate
that each of the endogenous variable series contains a single unit root or is well approximated by
an I(1) process. The Johanson co-integration tests can not reject one or at most two co-integrating
vectors (see Table 4), indicating that two linear combinations of the variables in (log) level values
are stationary.
Given these preliminaries, we estimate a VECM model with two lags and with two co-
integrating vectors, one representing a long-run money demand (velocity) relationship between
M2, CPI and RGDP, and the second representing a monetary control/supply link between RM and
M2; the results are reported in Table 5. In the money demand equation, we estimate a value of 0.44
for price elasticity of money demand. We impose a coefficient restriction of 1.8 on the RGDP
coefficient in the money demand co-integrating vector, representing the long-run income elasticity
of money demand.30 In the money supply equation, we estimate a value of 1.2 for the long-run
elasticity of broad money (M2) to changes in reserve money (RM), indicating that changes in
reserve requirements, banking lending restrictions and so on may change the short-run response of
M2 to RM, but in the longer term M2 eventually responds very substantially to increases in the
reserve money. We report the cointegrating vector and VECM dynamic coefficients, as well as the
key statistical properties, in Table 5. We do not report the deterministic variables (intercept
constant and seasonal dummy terms) in the VECM equations for brevity.
30
This coefficient is taken from Gerlach and Kong (2005). They estimate a long-run money demand function using
co-integration methodology over the period 1980-2004. We did not have access to data for this length of time and
found estimating this coefficient over a shorter sample to be problematic.
14
4.3 Simulation Exercises
We estimate the model through 2007 Q4 and do out-of-sample simulations from 2008 Q1 to 2010
Q4 based on the assumption that the extent to which foreign reserve accumulation translates into
reserve money growth continues and two alternative assumptions of real GDP growth (growth
contimues at 10 percent and growth slows sharply to 5 percent). Given alternative paths of output
growth and reserve money growth, we are able to obtain model-consistent forecasts of the implied
broad money growth and CPI inflation rates over the simulation period. Specially, we consider two
scenarios:
Scenario 1: Continuation of current economic pattern
Foreign reserves continue to accumulate at a high rate, leading to 30 percent annual growth
in reserve money over forecast period. Real GDP grows at 10 percent annually over the
forecast period. We calculate the implications for M2 growth and CPI inflation.
15
percent by the end of 2010. The dynamic structure of the model indicates that the fall in real GDP
growth takes more than a year to translate into a decline in broad money growth and inflation.
In summary, under scenario 1 involving rapid foreign exchange reserve accumulation and
limited exchange rate flexibility, the model predicts a rapid increase in inflation if sterilization
continues to have limited effectiveness. However, a sharp slowdown in output growth (and
continued rapid base money growth) eventually leads to a large decline in inflation.
5. Conclusion
In recent years China has faced an increasing trilemma—attempting to pursue an
independent monetary policy and limiting exchange rate flexibility, while at the same time facing
large and growing international capital flows. We argue that China’s current account surpluses and
foreign direct investment inflows, and occasionally large non-FDI capital inflows, combined with
the objective of limiting exchange rate appreciation, have the potential to compromise China’s
monetary policy goal of limiting inflation.
China has sought to insulate its reserve money from the effects of balance of payments
inflows by sterilizing via the issuance of central bank liabilities. However, our empirical results
indicate that sterilization dropped precipitously in 2006 in the face of the ongoing massive buildup
of international reserves, leading to a surge in reserve money growth. Moreover, the central bank
has raised bank reserve requirements and imposed lending restrictions in an attempt to decouple
reserve money growth from broad money growth. To investigate these broader implications of the
trilemma for Chinese inflation, we estimate a vector error correction model linking foreign
exchange reserve accumulation to developments in China’s reserve money, broad money, real
GDP and price level. We employ the model to explore the inflationary implications of different
policy scenarios. Under a scenario of rapid foreign exchange reserve accumulation and limited
exchange rate flexibility, the model predicts a rapid increase in inflation if sterilization continues to
have limited effectiveness. Increasing reserve requirements has a temporary effect in dampening
inflationary pressures, but even in this environment inflation eventually rises. Only in the scenario
of a sharp decline in economic activity is the trilemma not binding and would inflation rates be
expected to decline.
33
Three of these banks were recently privatized by allowing independent minority stakes by foreign investors and by
issuing publically traded equity shares. However, there is every reason to believe that the government’s ability to
apply moral suasion on these banks remains high.
17
References
Aizenman, Joshua and Reuven Glick. (2008a) "Pegged Exchange Rate Regimes, A Trap?" Journal of
Money, Credit and Banking, June.
Aizenman, Joshua and Reuven Glick. (2008b). “Sterilization, Monetary Policy, and Global Financial
Integration,” NBER No. 13902.
Bouvatier, Vincent. (2006). “Hot Money Inflows in China!: How the People’s Bank of China Took up the
Challenge,” Centre d’Economie de la Sorbonne, UMR 8174, Université Paris, Nov. 2006
Cavoli, Tony and Ramkishen Rajan. (2005). “The Capital Inflows Problem in Selected Asian Economies in
the 1990s Revisited: The Role of Monetary Sterilization,” National University Of Singapore,
Singapore Centre for Applied and Policy Economics, December.
Cheung, Yin-Wong, Dickson Tam and Matthew S. Yiu (2006). “Does the Chinese Interest Rate Follow the
U.S. Rate?” Hong Kong Institute for Monetary Research Working Paper No. 19/2006 (December).
Edwards, Sebastian and Eduardo Levy Yeyati. (2005). “Flexible Exchange Rates as Shock Absorbers,”
European Economic Review 49, 8, 2079-2105
Eichengreen, Barry. (1999). “Kicking the Habit: Moving from Pegged Rates to Greater Exchange Rate
Flexibility.” Economic Journal, March, C1-C14.
Frankel, Jeffrey. (1999). “No Single Currency Regime is Right for all Countries or at all Times,” NBER
Working Paper 7338, September.
Gerlach, Stefan and Janet Kong. (2005). “Money and Inflation In China,” Hong Kong Institute for
Monetary Research Memorandum No. 04/2005, March.
Glick, Reuven and Michael M. Hutchison. (2000). “Foreign Reserve and Money Dynamics with Asset
Portfolio Adjustment: International Evidence,” Journal of International Financial Markets,
Institutions and Money 10, 229–247.
Green, Stephen., 2005. “Making Monetary Policy Work in China: A Report from the Money Market Front
Line. Stanford Center for International Development, Working Paper 245.
Johansen, S. (1991). “Estimation and Hypothesis Testing of Cointegration Vectors in Gaussian Vector
Autoregressive Models.” Econometrica, 59, 1551-1580.
Liu, Li-Gang and Ichiro Otani (2005). “Capital Controls and Interest Rate Parity: Evidences from China,
1999-2004.” Draft working paper, Hong Kong Monetary Authority.
Ma, G., and Robert McCauley. (2002). Rising Foreign Currency Liquidity of Banks in China. BIS Quarterly
Review, September 2002.
Ma, G., and Robert McCauley. (2003). “Opening China s Capital Account amid Ample Dollar Liquidity,”
BIS Papers 15
Ma, G. and Robert MacCauley. (2007). “Do China’s Capital Controls Still Bind? Implications for Monetary
Autonomy and Capital Liberalization, BIS Working Paper 233, August 2007.
Mohanty, M.S. and Philip Turner. (2006). “Foreign Exchange Reserve Accumulation in Emerging Markets:
What are the Domestic Implications? BIS Quarterly Review, September 2006
18
Obstfeld, M., J. C. Shambaugh and A. M. Taylor. (2005). ‘The Trilemma in History: Tradeoffs Among
Exchange Rates, Monetary Policies, and Capital Mobility,’ Review of Economics and Statistics 3,
423-438.
Ouyang, Alice, Ramkishen Rajan, and Thomas Willett. (2006). “China as a Reserve Sink: The Evidence
from Offset and Sterilization Coefficients,” October.
Pazad, Eswar and Shang-Jin Wei. (2005a). “Understanding the Structure of Cross Border Capital Flows:
The Case of China.” Mimeo.
Prasad, Eswar and Shang-Jin Wei. (2005b). “The Chinese Approach to Capital Inflows: Patterns and
Possible Explanations.” NBER Working Paper 11306.
Prasad, Eswar. (2007). “Monetary Policy Independence, the Currency Regime, and the Capital Account in
China.” Paper presented at the Conference on China's Exchange Rate Policy. Peterson Institute for
International Economics, October 19.
Setser, Brian. (2008). “What to Do with over a Half a Trillion a Year? Understanding the Changes in the
Management of China’s Foreign Assets,” Council on Foreign Relations, January 15.
World Economic Outlook. (2007). “Managing Large Capital Inflows,” Chapter 3, October 2007.
International Monetary Fund.
19
Navigating the Trilemma: Capital Flows and Monetary Policy in China
Figures and Tables
Figure 1a.
Decomposition of China's Reserve Accumulation
billions of $
600
500
400 Current Account
300 FDI inflows, net
200 Non-FDI Capital Inflows, net
100 Foreign Reserve Inflows
0
-100
1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007
Figure 1b.
Decomposition of China's Reserve Accumulation
percent of GDP
20
Current Account/GDP
15
10 FDI inflows, net/GDP
5
Non-FDI Capital Inflows,
0 net/GDP
-5 Foreign Reserve Inflows/GDP
-10
1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007
20
Figure 2a.
Decomposition of China's Non-FDI Capital Inflows
billions of $
150
100
Securities, net
50 Other investment inflows, net
0 Errors and Omissions
Non-FDI Capital Inflows, net
-50
-100
1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007
Figure 2b.
Decomposition of China's Non-FDI Capital Inflows
percent of GDP
6
Securities, net/GDP
4
2 Other investment inflows,
0 net/GDP
-2 Errors and Omissions/GDP
-4
-6 Non-FDI Capital Inflows,
net/GDP
-8
1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007
21
Figure 3.
US-China Interest Differential and
Expected Rmb Appreciation, in percent
15
10
5
0
-5
-10
-15
Jan-99
Jan-00
Jan-01
Jan-02
Jan-03
Jan-04
Jan-05
Jan-06
Jan-07
Jan-08
US-China interest differential Expected Rmb appreciation
Rmb asset return, net
22
Figure 4a.
Decomposition of Other Investment Inflows, net
$ billions
100
80
60 Trade Credit
40 Loans
20 Currencies & Deposits
0 Other
-20 Other Investment Inflows, net
-40
-60
1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007
Figure 4b.
Decomposition of Other Investment Inflows, net
percent of GDP
3 Trade Credit/GDP
2
1 Loans/GDP
0
-1 Currencies & Deposits/GDP
-2
-3 Other/GDP
-4
-5 Other Investment Inflows,
1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 net/GDP
23
Figure 5a.
Equity Securities
billions of $
50
40
30
20
10
0
-10
-20
1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007
Assets Liabilities
Figure 5b.
Debt Securities
billions of $
50
0
-50
-100
-150
1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007
Assets Liabilities
24
Figure 6a.
Other Investments: Currency and Deposits
billions of $
30
20
10
0
-10
-20
-30
1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007
Assets Liabilities
Figure 6b.
Other Investments: Loans
billions of $
30
20
10
0
-10
-20
-30
1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007
Assets Liabilities
Figure 6c.
Other Investments: Other
billions of $
30
20
10
0
-10
-20
-30
1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007
Assets Liabilities
25
Figure 7. Net Foreign Asset and Net Domestic Asset Changes of Central Bank,
(4 quarter changes relative to stock of reserve money lagged 4Q, in percent)
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
-0.2
-0.4
-0.6
-0.8
1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007
?NFA/RM ?NDA/RM
Note: positive values correspond to foreign reserve inflows or domestic asset increases.
Figure 8.
PBC Bond Issuance (4Q change)
and Bonds Outstanding, billions Rmb
1500 5000
4000
1000 3000
500 2000
1000
0 0
2003 2004 2005 2006 2007
Figure 9.
M2-Reserve Money Multiplier (12 month change)
and Required Reserve Ratio, percent
20
15
10
-5
-10
-15
2003 2004 2005 2006 2007
26
Figure 10.
Interest Rates on Reserves and Repos, percent
0
Jan-03
Jan-04
Jan-05
Jan-06
Jan-07
Figure 11.
Bank Reserve Ratios, percent
16
14 Required Reserve Ratio
12
Excess Reserve Ratio
10
8
6
4
2
0
Jan-03
Jan-04
Jan-05
Jan-06
Jan-07
27
Figure 12.
M2 and Reserve Money
4 quarter changes, percent
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
-10
1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006
Reserve Money M2
Figure 13.
M2, CPI, and Domestic Credit
4 quarter changes, percent
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
-10
1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006
28
Figures 14. Sterilization Coefficients from 40-quarter rolling regressions
CHINA
-0.2
-0.4
-0.6
-0.8
-1
-1.2
-1.4
-1.6
1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006
Note: Coefficient estimates from regression of net foreign asset change on net domestic asset change
and nominal GDP growth. Coefficient observation correspond to calendar date of 40th quarter of rolling
sample period.
29
Figure 15. Money Growth and Inflation Model, VECM Simulations
30
Table 1. China's Balance of Payments, 1985-2007 (billions of US$)
1985- 1990-
1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007
89 94
Foreign reserve
0.5 11.4 22.5 31.6 35.7 6.4 8.5 10.5 47.3 75.5 117.0 206.4 207.0 247.0 532.2
accumulation
as % of GDP 0.1 2.4 3.1 3.7 3.8 0.6 0.8 0.9 3.6 5.2 7.1 10.7 9.3 9.3 16.2
Current account -5.3 5.5 1.6 7.2 37.0 31.5 21.1 20.5 17.4 35.4 45.9 68.7 160.8 249.9 325.7
as % of GDP -1.6 1.4 0.2 0.8 3.9 3.1 1.9 1.7 1.3 2.4 2.8 3.6 7.2 9.4 9.9
Financial account 6.4 13.4 38.7 40.0 21.0 -6.3 5.2 2.0 34.8 32.3 52.8 110.7 58.9 6.0 177.4
as % of GDP 5.3 4.7 2.2 -0.6 0.5 0.2 2.6 2.2 3.2 5.7 2.6 0.2 5.4
Direct
1.8 13.6 33.8 38.1 41.7 41.1 37.0 37.5 37.4 46.8 47.2 53.1 67.8 60.3 101.8
investments, net
Securities
na 1.4 0.8 1.7 6.9 -3.7 -11.2 -4.0 -19.4 -10.3 11.4 19.7 -4.9 -67.6 -9.7
investment, net
Other
na -1.7 4.0 0.2 -27.6 -43.7 -20.5 -31.5 16.9 -4.1 -5.9 37.9 -4.0 13.3 85.2
investments, net
Errors and
-0.6 -7.5 -17.8 -15.6 -22.3 -18.7 -17.8 -11.9 -4.9 7.8 18.4 27.0 -16.8 -12.9 26.2
omissions
Memo: Non-FDI
financial account
3.9 -7.7 -13.0 -13.7 -42.9 -66.1 -49.6 -47.4 -7.4 -6.7 24.0 84.6 -25.7 -67.1 101.7
(including errors
and omissions)
as % of GDP 1.2 -1.5 -1.8 -1.6 -4.5 -6.5 -4.6 -4.0 -0.6 -0.5 1.5 4.4 -1.2 -2.5 3.1
Memo: Stock of
3.3 25.0 73.6 105.0 139.9 145.0 154.7 165.6 212.2 286.4 403.3 609.9 818.9 1066.3 1528.2
Foreign Reserves
as % of GDP 0.9 5.0 10.1 12.3 14.7 14.3 14.3 13.8 16.0 19.7 24.6 31.6 36.6 40.1 46.6
Notes: Sum of current account, financial account, and errors and omissions differs (slightly) from reserve accumulation by
omission of capital account. Change in stock of foreign reserves differs from reserve accumulation because of valuation and
other effects to holdings.
31
Table 2. China's Balance of Payments, 1998-2007 (billions of US$)
Errors and
-16.1 12.1 -14.8 26.2 28.2 -26.9 41.0
omissions
Memo: Non-FDI
financial account
-54.4 23.6 -46.4 101.7 78.0 -70.1 148.1
(including errors
and omissions)
32
Table 3. Money Growth and Inflation Model, Unit Root Tests
Notes:
Table reports augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistics (ADF) for null hypothesis of existence of unit root for
prices (CPI), real GDP (RGDP), reserve money (RM), and M2.
Equations include constant and 4 lags.
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Max-Eigenvalue 0.05
Hypothesized No. of CE(s) Eigenvalue Statistic Critical Value Prob.**
None * 0.575 52.230 27.584 0.000
At most 1 * 0.366 27.810 21.132 0.005
At most 2 0.091 5.850 14.265 0.633
At most 3 0.034 2.091 3.841 0.148
Notes:
Sample: 1992Q4-2007Q4, with 61 observations after adjustments.
System consists of prices (CPI), real GDP (RGDP), reserve money (RM), and M2, all in logs, with a
linear deterministic trend and two lags of variables in first differences. A constant and 3 quarterly
dummies not reported.
Trace test indicates 2 cointegrating eqn(s) at the 0.05 level.
Max-eigenvalue test indicates 2 cointegrating eqn(s) at the 0.05 level.
* denotes rejection of the hypothesis at the 0.05 level
**MacKinnon-Haug-Michelis (1999) p-values
33
Table 5. Money Growth and Inflation Model, VECM Estimates
A. Cointegrating Equations
CointEq1 CointEq2
Log(M2_t-1) 1.000 1.000
Log(CPI_t-1) -0.435 0.000
(-4.091)
Log(RM_t-1) 0.000 -1.166
(-14.550)
Log(RGDP_t-1) -1.800 0.000
B. Dynamics
34
Appendix: Simulations with Adjusted Reserve Money
Appendix Figure 1. Unadjusted and adjusted reserve money growth (12 month growth rates, in
percent)
50
40
30
20
10
-10
2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008
35
Appendix Figure 2. Money Growth and Inflation Model, VECM Simulations
Scenario 1A Rapid GDP Growth and Moderate Reserve Money (Adjusted) Growth Scenario 2A Growth Slowdown and Moderate Reserve (Adjusted) Growth
14 8
12 7
10 6
8 5
6 4
4 3
2 2
0 1
2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010
11
11.6
10
11.2
9
10.8 8
7
10.4
6
10.0
5
9.6 4
2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010
Adjusted Reserve Money (year % ch.) Adjusted Reserve Money Growth (year % ch.)
16 16
14 14
12 12
10 10
8 8
6 6
4 4
2 2
2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010
36
Appendix Table 1. Money Growth and Inflation Model, Cointegration Tests
Max-Eigenvalue 0.05
Hypothesized No. of CE(s) Eigenvalue Statistic Critical Value Prob.**
None * 0.535 46.674 27.584 0.000
At most 1 * 0.287 20.629 21.132 0.059
At most 2 0.152 10.035 14.265 0.210
At most 3 0.006 0.346 3.841 0.556
Notes:
Sample: 1992Q4-2007Q4, with 61 observations after adjustments.
System consists of prices (CPI), real GDP (RGDP), reserve money (RM), and M2, all in logs, with a
linear deterministic trend and two lags of variables in first differences. A constant and 3 quarterly
dummies not reported.
Trace test indicates 2 cointegrating eqn(s) at the 0.05 level.
Max-eigenvalue test indicates 2 cointegrating eqn(s) at the 0.05 level.
* denotes rejection of the hypothesis at the 0.05 level
**MacKinnon-Haug-Michelis (1999) p-values
A. Cointegrating Equations
CointEq1 CointEq2
Log(M2_t-1) 1.000 1.000
Log(CPI_t-1) -0.410 0.000
(-3.983)
Log(RM_t-1) 0.000 -1.418
[-33.398]
Log(RGDP_t-1) -1.800 0.000
37