The Model-Free Implied Volatility and Its Information Content
The Model-Free Implied Volatility and Its Information Content
The Model-Free Implied Volatility and Its Information Content
net/publication/5217049
CITATIONS READS
538 3,362
2 authors, including:
Yisong S. Tian
York University
51 PUBLICATIONS 2,286 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
All content following this page was uploaded by Yisong S. Tian on 16 May 2014.
Yisong S. Tian
Schulich School of Business, York University
Britten-Jones and Neuberger (2000) derived a model-free implied volatility under the
diffusion assumption. In this article, we extend their model-free implied volatility to
asset price processes with jumps and develop a simple method for implementing it
using observed option prices. In addition, we perform a direct test of the informa-
tional efficiency of the option market using the model-free implied volatility. Our
results from the Standard & Poor’s 500 index (SPX) options suggest that the model-
free implied volatility subsumes all information contained in the Black–Scholes (B–S)
implied volatility and past realized volatility and is a more efficient forecast for future
realized volatility.
We thank Yacine Aı̈t-Sahalia (the editor), an anonymous referee, Stewart Hodges, Chris Lamoureux,
Nathaniel O’Connor, Wulin Suo, Shu Yan, Hao Zhou, and seminar participants at the Federal Reserve
Board, the University of Toronto, and the University of Warwick for helpful comments and suggestions.
The financial support of the Social Sciences and Humanity Research Council of Canada is gratefully
acknowledged. Address correspondence to Yisong S. Tian, Finance Area, Schulich School of Business,
York University, 4700 Keele Street, Toronto, ON M3J 1P3, or e-mail: ytian@schulich.yorku.ca.
ª The Author 2005. Published by Oxford University Press. All rights reserved. For Permissions, please email:
journals.permissions@oupjournals.org
doi:10.1093/rfs/hhi027 Advance Access publication May 25, 2005
The Review of Financial Studies / v 18 n 4 2005
1306
The Model-Free Implied Volatility
1307
The Review of Financial Studies / v 18 n 4 2005
1
We are indebted to an anonymous referee for providing the idea and outline for the proof to Proposition 1.
1308
The Model-Free Implied Volatility
Proposition 2. The right and left truncation errors beyond the strike price
range [Kmin, Kmax] have the following upper bounds, respectively:
ð þ1 F " #
C ðT, KÞ maxð0, F0 KÞ F FT Kmax 2
2 dK E0 FT > Kmax ,
Kmax K2 Kmax
ð3Þ
and
ð Kmin " #
C F ðT, KÞ maxð0, F0 KÞ FT Kmin 2
2 dK E0F FT < Kmin :
0 K2 FT
ð4Þ
1309
The Review of Financial Studies / v 18 n 4 2005
Both upper bounds are quite intuitive as they reflect the local variations
in the tails of the return distribution. Although these upper bounds are
shown subsequently to be quite tight, they are not model free. We also
derive model-free upper bounds for truncation errors in the Appendix.
However, the model-free upper bounds are not as tight as the ones in
equations (3) and (4).
To illustrate typical truncation errors, we consider the following sto-
chastic volatility and random jump (SVJ) model:
1=2
dFt =Ft ¼ Vt dWt þ Jt dNt J dt,
1=2 ð5Þ
dVt ¼ ðv v Vt Þdt þ v Vt dWtv ,
2
The skewness and kurtosis of the daily return distribution implied by the first set of parameters are -0.03
and 7.43, respectively. The corresponding numbers for the second set are -2.22 and 41.87.
1310
The Model-Free Implied Volatility
Figure 1
Truncation errors in calculating the model-free implied volatility
The left and right truncation errors of the model-free implied volatility are plotted against the respective
truncation point (Kmin or Kmax). The stochastic volatility with random jump (SVJ) model is assumed for the
1=2 1=2 v
underlying asset price: dFt =Ft ¼ Vt dWt þ Jt dNt mJ ldt, dVt ¼ ðyv kv Vt Þdt þ sv V
t dWt , and
dWt dWtv ¼ rdt where Nt ~ i.i.d. Poisson (l) and lnð1 þ Jt Þ iid N lnð1 þ mJ Þ 12 s2J ; sJ . Two sets of
2
parameters are used: (I) kv = 1, sv = 0.25, r = 0, l = 4, mJ = 0, sJ = 0.0375, yv = 0.1854 kv, V0 = y/kv
and (II) kv = 1, sv = 0.25, r = 0, l = 0.5, mJ = 0.075, sJ = 0.075, yv = 0.18542kv, V0 = y/kv. The two panels
on the left (panels A and C) illustrate the shape of the Black–Scholes (B–S) implied volatility function for
one- and six-month maturities while the two panels on the right (panels B and D) show the truncation errors
at various truncation levels. The truncation points are stated in multiples of standard deviations (SDs).
1311
The Review of Financial Studies / v 18 n 4 2005
Figure 1
Continued
slower rate than the right truncation error does. With a fatter left tail, a
larger range of strike prices is needed on the left of F0 if we wish to have
identical truncation errors from both sides. Nevertheless, the differences
between left and right truncation errors are relatively small and conver-
gence is rapid in all cases. In general, the truncation error is negligible if
the truncation points are more than two SDs from F0.
Figure 1 also shows that the model-free implied volatilities calculated
from one-month and six-month maturities have similar truncation
errors. With a longer maturity, however, the same multiple of SDs
translates into a larger range of strike prices. This is because integrated
1312
The Model-Free Implied Volatility
ð6Þ
where DK = (KmaxKmin)/m, Ki = Kmin + iDK for 0 i m, and
gðT; Ki Þ ¼ ½C F ðT; Ki Þ maxð0; F0 Ki Þ=Ki2 : For a finite m (or DK >
0), the numerical integration scheme in Equation (6) leads to discretiza-
tion errors.
Figure 2 illustrates typical discretization errors at various levels of DK
We set the truncation points at 3.5 SDs from F0. As shown in Figure 1,
truncation errors are virtually zero beyond 3.5 SDs. We use the second
set of parameter values to plot Figure 2 since it exhibits a more severe
volatility smile or smirk pattern. Discretization errors are smaller if we
use the first set of parameter values. In order to provide a useful bench-
mark for discretization errors, we measure DK in SD units. As shown in
Figure 2, discretization errors diminish quickly as DK decreases. For
both one-month and six-month maturities, discretization errors are
negligible when DK 0.35 SDs (or m 20). With the initial asset
price at $100 and the annualized volatility of 0.2, 0.35 SD translates
into a strike price increment of roughly $2 and $5 for one-month and
six-month options, respectively. This is generally consistent with actual
strike price increments in the marketplace. Since we use a much smaller
DK (or larger m) in our empirical implementation, discretization errors
are unlikely to have any impact on the calculation of the model-free
implied volatility.
1.2.3 Spot prices versus forward prices. Equation (1) is stated in forward
prices. When applications require the use of spot prices, appropriate
1313
The Review of Financial Studies / v 18 n 4 2005
Figure 2
Discretization errors in calculating the model-free implied volatility
The discretization errors of the model-free implied volatility are plotted against strike price increment
(DK, measured in standard deviation [SD] units) for options with one- and six-month maturities. The
1=2
SVJ model is assumed for the underlying asset price: dFt =Ft ¼ Vt dWt þ Jt dNt mJ ldt,
1=2 v v
dVt ¼ ðyv kv Vt Þdt
þ s v V t dW t , and
dW t dW t ¼ rdt where N t i.i.d. Poisson (l) and
lnð1 þ Jt Þ iid N lnð1 þ mJ Þ 12 s2J ;sJ . The second set of parameters with a more pronounced volatility
skew is used: kv = 1, sv = 0.25, r = 0, l = 0.5, mJ = 0.075, mJ = 0.075, yv = 0.18542kv, V0 = y/kv. The
model-free implied volatility is calculated using the trapezoidal integration method. To minimize trunca-
tion errors, we choose truncation points sufficiently far from the forward price (3.5 SDs on both sides of
the forward price F0). The discretization error is the difference between the calculated volatility and the
true volatility.
1314
The Model-Free Implied Volatility
3
The choice of the sampling date is not important because we do not use observed option prices in our
implementation here. We only need the set of strike prices listed on that date to provide a sense of
availability of strike prices in the marketplace.
1315
The Review of Financial Studies / v 18 n 4 2005
4
For a more detailed review of curve-fitting and other methods, see the survey article by Jackwerth (1999).
1316
The Model-Free Implied Volatility
Table 1
Approximation errors in the calculation of the mode-free implied volatility
Maturity (days)
The approximation error is defined as the estimated annualized volatility minus the true volatility (0.2).
The SVJ model is implemented with the following parameters: kv = 1, sv = 0.25, = 0, l = 0.5, J =
0.075, sJ = 0.075, v = 0.18542 kv, V0 = yv/kv. The current asset price (S0) is 270 and the listed strike
prices range from 200 to 350, based on options listed on the Standard & Poor’s (S & P ’s) 500 index on
September 23, 1988. The discretization parameter (m) used is 100.
obtained over a wide range of parameters for the SVJ model. The accu-
racy and robustness of our extrapolation method is thus assured.
As shown in Table 1, the extrapolation method (panel B) leads to
smaller approximation errors than the truncation method (panel A)
does. The truncation method ignores strike prices beyond the truncation
interval, which leads to the underestimation of the true volatility. The
extrapolation method corrects the underestimation error by assuming a
flat implied volatility function beyond the truncation point. In other
words, implied volatilities outside the truncation interval are extrapolated
from the implied volatility at the respective truncation point. We further
argue that this correction mechanism in the extrapolation method is likely
to lead to smaller approximation errors in most empirical settings. Con-
sider, for example, the three most commonly observed shapes of the
implied volatility function: smile, smirk, and skew. With a volatility
smile, the implied volatility rises as the strike price increases or decreases
from the asset price. By extrapolating on the implied volatility at the
truncation points, the extrapolation method underestimates the true
volatility beyond the truncation interval. The underestimation is, how-
ever, less severe than that in the truncation method, leading to a more
accurate approximation. With a volatility smirk, the implied volatility
rises faster at low strike prices than at high strike prices. The extrapola-
tion method is again more accurate than the truncation method. In this
case, however, extrapolation creates a more severe kink at the left truncation
1317
The Review of Financial Studies / v 18 n 4 2005
point, which may lead to larger approximation errors if Kmin is too close
to S0. Numerical examples in Table 1 show that the extrapolation method
is, nevertheless, reasonably accurate even in the presence of a severe
volatility smirk. Finally, we consider a volatility skew. A typical volatility
skew exhibits high implied volatility for low strike prices and low implied
volatility for high strike prices. This means that the extrapolation method
underestimates the volatility beyond the minimum strike price but over-
estimates it beyond the maximum strike price. As the two effects offset or
partially offset each other, the extrapolation method should be more
accurate than the truncation method. Consequently, we adopt the extra-
polation method in our subsequent empirical tests.
1318
The Model-Free Implied Volatility
each day in our sample. As option quotes over a range of strike prices
and maturities are needed, we use all option quotes in the final trading
hour before the stock market closes. The last trading hour is used
because trading volume is typically higher than at other times of the day.
Our empirical tests require the construction of implied volatility surface
from available option prices. In theory, this is straightforward to do if the
set of traded options covers a sufficient range of strike prices and matu-
rities. For each available option, we use the B–S model to back out the
implied volatility from option quote. If option quotes are available for all
strike prices and maturities, the calculated implied volatilities naturally
form a surface. However, only a limited number of strike prices and
maturities are listed for trading. A curve-fitting method is needed to
extract the implied volatility surface from available option prices. To fit
a smooth surface to the available B–S implied volatilities, the curve-fitting
method is implemented in two steps. Cubic splines are first applied in the
moneyness dimension to fit a smooth curve to the B–S implied volatilities
as in Section 1.2.4. That is, implied volatility as a smooth function of
moneyness (x), s ^ðxjTÞ, is obtained for each option maturity (T). In the
second step, we fix moneyness and apply cubic splines in the maturity
dimension. The result is a smooth implied volatility surface, ðx;TÞ.
To avoid the telescoping overlap problem described by Christensen,
Hansen, and Prabhala (2001), we extract implied volatilities from the
implied volatility surface at predetermined fixed maturity intervals. The
model-free implied volatility is then calculated using the RHS of Equa-
tion (6) for fixed maturities of 30, 60, 120, and 180 (calendar) days. The
B–S implied volatility is extracted directly from the implied volatility
surface for the same fixed maturities and moneyness levels from 0.94 to
1.06.
In addition to implied volatilities, our empirical analysis also requires
monthly series of realized volatility and historical volatility. Realized
volatility is needed to assess the forecasting ability and information con-
tent of implied volatilities. We calculate the realized volatility over peri-
ods of 30 to 180 days, matching the maturities of the corresponding
implied volatilities. Historical volatility serves as a competing forecast,
to implied volatilities, for future realized volatility. We use the realized
volatility on the latest trading day as a proxy for historical volatility since
the latest day’s volatility is likely to contain the most relevant information
for future volatility. In other words, the lagged daily realized volatility is
our proxy for historical volatility.
Previous research adopts different sampling frequencies of asset returns
for the calculation of realized volatility. Some earlier studies such as
Canina and Figlewski (1993) and Christensen and Prabhala (1998) calcu-
lated these volatilities using daily returns. More recent studies argue that
realized volatility should be calculated using intraday returns instead of
1319
The Review of Financial Studies / v 18 n 4 2005
1320
The Model-Free Implied Volatility
the lagged daily realized volatility (our proxy for historical volatility). To
correct for the bias in estimated realized volatility due to autocorrelation
in intraday returns, we adopt a correction method suggested, in various
forms, by French, Schwert, and Stambaugh (1987), Zhou (1996), and
Hansen and Lunde (2004). In this correction method, the annualized
realized variance over the period [t, t + t] is calculated as:
l
1X n
2X n Xnh
Vt,t ¼ R2i þ Ri Riþh , ð8Þ
t i¼1 t h¼1 n h i¼1
where Ri is the index return during the i-th interval, n is the total number
of intervals in the period, and l is the number of correction terms
included.5 When the volatility (e.g, the lagged daily realized volatility) is
calculated with 5-minute returns, we use Equation (8) with one correction
term (i.e., l = 1). This is because 5-minute returns in our sample have a
first-order autocorrelation of 0.31 while higher-order autocorrelations are
much smaller. In contrast, we do not correct for autocorrelation if vola-
tility (e.g., the one-month realized volatility) is calculated with 30-minute
returns (i.e., l = 0). These less frequent returns have a first-order auto-
correlation of only 0.06 in our sample while higher-order autocorrelations
are all negligible. Although all reported results in this study are based on
realized volatility calculated this way, we do consider alternative correc-
tion terms subsequently in robustness tests and the results are not materi-
ally affected.
Table 2 provides summary statistics for the model-free implied volati-
lity, the B–S implied volatility and the realized volatility. All volatility
measures are estimated monthly on the Wednesday immediately follow-
ing the expiry date of the month. For the B–S model, implied volatility is
reported for at-the-money options only. For other moneyness levels, the
results are similar but exhibit the well-known smile pattern. The realized
volatility is calculated using 30-minute index returns for the period
matching the maturity of the corresponding option(s) in the implied
volatility calculation. As shown in Table 2, both the B–S and model-
free implied volatilities are on average higher than the realized volatility
over all horizons. These implied volatilities are thus likely biased forecast
for realized volatility, with a slightly larger bias for the latter. The larger
bias from the model-free implied volatility is expected as the B–S implied
volatility is known to be a downward biased measure of risk-neutral
expected variance under stochastic volatility by Jensen’s inequality. By
correcting this downward bias, the model-free implied volatility tends to
5
Dividends are ignored in the above calculation since daily dividends on the SPX are typically small and
much less volatile than the index itself. Unreported results confirm that adjustment for dividends does not
lead to material change to realized volatility estimates.
1321
The Review of Financial Studies / v 18 n 4 2005
Table 2
Summary Statistics of monthly volatility series
Standard Excess
t N Mean deviation Skewness kurtosis Minimum Maximum
Panel A: sBS
30 78 14.78 4.396 1.1258 2.0636 6.912 31.21
60 79 15.71 4.399 1.0210 0.9198 8.325 29.90
120 78 16.82 4.254 0.8038 0.6587 8.761 30.81
180 78 17.31 3.844 0.7213 0.3137 10.62 29.21
Panel B: sRE
30 79 13.96 4.078 1.4165 2.9300 6.953 28.78
60 79 14.08 3.751 1.2724 2.1930 7.350 26.92
120 79 14.10 3.682 1.3448 2.2043 8.248 26.54
180 79 14.13 3.241 1.1327 0.9593 9.208 25.32
Panel C: sMF
30 78 15.68 4.450 1.5966 3.8305 8.589 34.61
60 79 16.11 3.964 1.1685 1.3999 10.16 28.72
120 78 17.51 3.976 0.7028 0.1716 10.06 28.24
180 78 17.33 3.566 0.4522 0.1985 9.666 25.80
Panel D: ln(sBS)
30 78 2.653 0.284 0.1563 0.2628 1.933 3.441
60 79 2.719 0.264 0.3500 0.1444 2.119 3.397
120 78 2.792 0.246 0.1050 0.0401 2.170 3.427
180 78 2.828 0.216 0.1901 0.3050 2.363 3.374
Panel E: ln(sRE)
30 79 2.596 0.272 0.3959 0.6496 1.938 3.360
60 79 2.612 0.255 0.2439 0.0728 1.995 3.292
120 79 2.621 0.244 0.5847 0.3935 2.110 3.278
180 79 2.608 0.217 0.6220 0.0051 2.220 3.154
Panel F: ln(sMF)
30 78 2.718 0.255 0.6607 0.6865 2.150 3.544
60 79 2.752 0.229 0.5321 0.1377 2.318 3.357
120 78 2.838 0.221 0.1528 0.2150 2.308 3.341
180 78 2.832 0.205 0.0519 0.2103 2.368 3.250
sBS, sRE, and sMF are the at-the-money Black–Scholes (B–S) implied volatility, the realized volatility, and
the model-free implied volatility, respectively. t is the time horizon and N is the sample size. All
volatilities are expressed in annualized percentage terms.
be higher than the B–S implied volatility. In addition, the reported skew-
ness and excess kurtosis in Table 2 reveal that the log volatility is the most
conformable with the normal distribution. Regressions based on the log
volatility are thus statistically better specified than those based on vola-
tility or variance.
Table 3 summarizes the correlation matrix of the monthly 30-day
volatility series for the B–S implied volatility (from options with different
moneyness levels), the model-free implied volatility, and the realized
volatility. Correlations for monthly volatility series with longer maturities
have similar properties and are not reported. Overall, all B–S implied
volatility series are highly correlated with the model-free implied volati-
lity. As expected, the B–S implied volatility from at-the-money options
has the highest correlation with the model-free implied volatility (94.1%).
While all implied volatility series are highly correlated with the corre-
sponding realized volatility, the model-free implied volatility has the
1322
The Model-Free Implied Volatility
Table 3
Correlation matrix of monthly 30-day volatility series
Panel B: correlation matrix ln(sBS) (0.94) ln(sBS) (0.97) ln(sBS)(1.00) ln(sBS)(1.03) ln(sMF) ln(sRE)
of log volatility (N = 60)
ln(sBS) (0.94) 1.000 — — — — —
ln(sBS) (0.97) 0.847 1.000 — — — —
BS
ln(s )(1.00) 0.813 0.852 1.000 — — —
ln(sBS)(1.03) 0.828 0.829 0.872 1.000 — —
MF
ln(s ) 0.889 0.903 0.918 0.916 1.000 —
ln(sRE) 0.721 0.755 0.764 0.771 0.843 1.000
sBS, sRE, and sMF are the Black–Scholes (B–S) implied volatility, the realized volatility and the model-
free implied volatility, respectively. Numbers in parentheses after sBS are option moneyness. The sBS
(1.06) is excluded in the calculation of correlation matrix as it has fewer observations.
1323
The Review of Financial Studies / v 18 n 4 2005
Figure 3
Time-series plot of the model-free and at-the-money Black–Scholes (B–S) implied volatilities
The figure plots the time series of the 30-day model-free and at-the-money B–S implied volatilities over the
sample period from June 1988 to December 1994. The two implied volatilities are calculated using the
implied volatility surface. The implied volatility surface is constructed by interpolating implied volatilities of
traded options using cubic splines, first in the moneyness dimension and then in the maturity dimension.
1324
The Model-Free Implied Volatility
we fix the option maturity at 30 calendar days. Time series obtained this
way are neither overlapping nor telescoping.
Consistent with prior research [e.g., Canina and Figlewski (1993) and
Christensen and Prabhala (1998)], we employ both univariate and encom-
passing regressions to analyze the information content of volatility fore-
casts. In a univariate regression, the realized volatility is regressed against
a single volatility forecast. In comparison, two or more volatility forecasts
are used as explanatory variables in encompassing regressions. While the
univariate regression focuses on the forecasting ability and information
content of one volatility forecast, the encompassing regression addresses
the relative importance of competing volatility forecasts and whether one
volatility forecast subsumes all information contained in other volatility
forecast(s). Since a univariate regression is a restricted version of the
corresponding encompassing regression, we only state the encompassing
regressions. These regressions are specified as follows, in three alternative
specifications:
MF MF BS BS LRE LRE
sRE
t,t ¼ ax,t þ bx,t st,t þ bx,t st,x,t þ bx,t st,t þ et,x,t , ð9Þ
RE
Vt,t ¼ ax,t þ bMF MF BS BS LRE LRE
x,t Vt,t þ bx,t Vt,x,t þ bx,t Vt,t þ et,x,t , ð10Þ
MF BS LRE
ln sRE MF BS LRE
t,t ¼ ax,t þ bx,t ln st,t þ bx,t ln st,x,t þ bx,t ln st,t þ et,x,t , ð11Þ
where s and V are asset return volatility and variance, respectively. The
superscripts RE, MF, BS, and LRE stand for REalized, Model-Free,
Black–Scholes, and Lagged REalized, respectively. The subscripts t, x,
and t are observation date, moneyness, and maturity, respectively. Uni-
variate regressions are obtained if two of the three regressors are dropped.
Lagged realized volatility sLRE is our proxy for historical volatility.
Previous studies [e.g., Canina and Figlewski (1993) and Christensen and
Prabhala (1998)] adopted the realized volatility over a matching period
(30 calendar days here) immediately proceeding the current observation
date as the lagged realized volatility. As the volatility process is likely a
Markov process, the latest day’s realized volatility is the most relevant for
forecasting future volatility. Following this logic, we adopt the realized
volatility on the latest trading day as the lagged realized volatility. This
lagged realized volatility is calculated from 5-minute index returns using
Equation (8) with one correction term. The robustness of our results with
respect to alternative correction terms and other proxies for historical
volatility is examined subsequently.
Table 4 summarizes the OLS regression results from both univariate
and encompassing regressions using the monthly nonoverlapping sample
described previously. Results from the three specifications are presented
in separate panels in the table. While the estimate for the other two
volatility measures is only a function of maturity, the estimate for the
1325
1326
Panel A: st
78 2.49 (1.15) — 0.77 (0.080) — 0.64 1.98 14.85 (0.000) —
78 2.66 (1.16) — 0.70 (0.093) 0.06 (0.027) 0.65 2.04 — 11.91 (0.003)
78 10.8 (0.80) — — 0.23 (0.036) 0.15 1.65 204.6 (0.000) —
78 1.30 (0.79) 0.80 (0.053) — — 0.74 1.98 70.37 (0.000) —
78 1.36 (0.78) 0.83 (0.116) 0.04 (0.123) — 0.74 2.01 — 15.17 (0.001)
78 1.32 (0.80) 0.80 (0.060) — 0.01 (0.033) 0.74 2.00 — 15.12 (0.001)
78 1.39 (0.84) 0.84 (0.122) 0.05 (0.126) 0.01 (0.032) 0.74 2.02 — 16.21 (0.001)
Panel B: Vt
78 32.1 (18.9) — 0.75 (0.063) — 0.62 2.07 15.10 (0.000) —
78 32.8 (19.1) — 0.73 (0.104) 0.02 (0.029) 0.62 2.08 — 10.68 (0.005)
78 176.2 (16.6) — — 0.15 (0.037) 0.11 1.75 652.2 (0.000) —
78 19.9 (13.4) 0.71 (0.058) — — 0.73 1.95 67.86 (0.000) —
78 18.8 (15.9) 0.69 (0.119) 0.03 (0.152) — 0.73 1.90 — 48.11 (0.000)
78 20.4 (14.4) 0.73 (0.072) — 0.02 (0.020) 0.73 1.91 — 49.32 (0.000)
78 19.3 (14.7) 0.71 (0.121) 0.03 (0.152) 0.02 (0.025) 0.73 1.91 — 49.14 (0.000)
Panel C: In Vt
78 0.55 (0.22) — 0.77 (0.080) — 0.60 1.90 23.20 (0.000) —
78 0.40 (0.21) — 0.70 (0.082) 0.14 (0.051) 0.62 1.91 — 13.37 (0.001)
78 1.88 (0.18) — — 0.29 (0.071) 0.20 1.51 111.4 (0.000) —
78 0.10 (0.16) 0.92 (0.057) — — 0.75 1.94 71.21 (0.000) —
78 0.11 (0.16) 0.99 (0.135) 0.09 (0.120) — 0.74 1.96 — 2.262 (0.323)
78 0.09 (0.16) 0.89 (0.065) — 0.04 (0.042) 0.75 1.97 — 2.541 (0.281)
78 0.09 (0.16) 0.95 (0.147) 0.07 (0.123) 0.03 (0.043) 0.74 1.98 — 3.625 (0.305)
The at-the-money Black–Scholes (B–S) implied volatility and one-day lagged historical volatility are used in the regressions. The numbers in parentheses beside the parameter
estimates are the standard errors, which are computed following a robust procedure taking into account of the heteroscedast1icity [see White (1980)]. The w2 test(a) is for the joint
hypothesis H0: a = 0 and j = 1 (j = MF, BS, LRE) in univariate regressions, and the w2 test(b) is for the joint hypothesis H0: BS = 1 and LRE = 0 or H0: MF = 1, and
BS = LRE = 0 in encompassing regressions. The test statistics are reported with the p-values in the brackets beside the statistic.
, , and indicate that the leading term coefficient of the regressionis significantly different from one at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, and , , and indicate
that the coefficient of the remaining terms is significantly different from zero at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively.
The Model-Free Implied Volatility
1327
The Review of Financial Studies / v 18 n 4 2005
1328
The Model-Free Implied Volatility
4. Robustness Tests
Results from the previous section provide strong support for the informa-
tional efficiency of the model-free implied volatility. Unlike the B–S
implied volatility, the model-free implied volatility extracts information
from options across all available strike prices. By aggregating information
contained in individual options, the model-free implied volatility exhibits
superior forecasting ability and is informationally more efficient. These
findings are striking and provide new insight on volatility forecasting and
market efficiency. We now conduct robustness tests to ensure the general-
ity of our findings.
4.1 IV regressions
Christensen and Prabhala (1998) employ IV regressions to correct for
potential EIV problems. They recognize that the B–S implied volatility
(their volatility forecast) may contain significant measurement errors
due to either the early exercise premium in the American style S & P 100
index options, the possible nonsynchronous observations of option
quotes and index levels in their data set, or the misspecification error
of the B–S model. It is well known that the EIV problem tends to drive
the slope coefficient downward (biased toward zero). This may explain
why the coefficient of the B–S implied volatility in their univariate and
encompassing regressions is below one. Christensen and Prabhala (1998)
found substantial differences between the estimation results from the
OLS and IV regressions, supporting the existence of measurement errors
in the B–S implied volatility.
1329
The Review of Financial Studies / v 18 n 4 2005
1330
The Model-Free Implied Volatility
Table 5
Univariate and encompassing regressions of 30-day log volatility instrumental variable (IV)
The at-the-money Black–Scholes (B–S) implied volatility and one-day lagged historical volatility are used in the regressions. The numbers in parentheses beside the parameter
estimates are the standard errors, which are computed following a robust procedure taking into account of the heteroscedastic and autocorrelated error structure [see Newey and
West (1987)]. The w2 test(a) is for the joint hypothesis H0: = 0 & j = 1 (j = MF, BS, LRE) in univariate regressions, and the w2 test(b) is for the joint hypothesis H0: BS = 1 and
LRE = 0 or H0: MF = 1 and BS = 1 and LRE = 0 in encompassing regressions. The test statistics are reported with the p-values in the brackets beside the statistic. Durbin-
Watson (DW) denotes the Durbin-Watson statistic.
1331
The Review of Financial Studies / v 18 n 4 2005
1332
The Model-Free Implied Volatility
Table 6
Univariate and encompassing regressions of 60-, 120- and 180-day log volatility (OLS)
Panel A: In Vt (t = 60)
79 0.51 (0.21) — 0.76 (0.076) — 0.57 1.66 55.56 (0.000) —
79 0.41 (0.22) — 0.72 (0.073) 0.09 (0.051) 0.58 1.64 — 10.77 (0.004)
79 2.14 (0.20) — — 0.18 (0.085) 0.10 1.09 129.7 (0.000) —
79 0.03 (0.19) 0.93 (0.068) — — 0.70 1.61 114.6 (0.000) —
79 0.03 (0.19) 0.87 (0.127) 0.07 (0.108) — 0.70 1.62 — 1.313 (0.518)
79 0.01 (0.20) 0.92 (0.065) — 0.03 (0.038) 0.70 1.69 — 1.433 (0.488)
79 –0.00 (0.20) 0.85 (0.128) 0.07 (0.110) 0.03 (0.039) 0.70 1.72 — 2.401 (0.493)
Panel B: In Vt (t = 120)
78 0.77 (0.21) — 0.67 (0.076) — 0.50 1.51 67.57 (0.000) —
78 0.67 (0.22) — 0.63 (0.074) 0.08 (0.049) 0.50 1.49 — 19.55 (0.000)
78 2.21 (0.19) — — 0.16 (0.77) 0.08 0.83 160.4 (0.000) —
78 0.20 (0.19) 0.87 (0.097) — — 0.65 1.25 118.7 (0.000) —
78 0.18 (0.19) 0.80 (0.121) 0.08 (0.086) — 0.65 1.27 — 3.954 (0.138)
78 0.19 (0.21) 0.86 (0.091) — 0.01 (0.034) 0.65 1.25 — 3.499 (0.173)
78 0.18 (0.20) 0.79 (0.127) 0.08 (0.086) 0.01 (0.033) 0.64 1.27 — 4.251 (0.235)
Panel B: In Vt (t = 180)
78 0.62 (0.20) — 0.70 (0.073) — 0.45 0.91 142.8 (0.000) —
78 0.55 (0.21) — 0.68 (0.076) 0.05 (0.037) 0.44 0.89 — 12.82 (0.002)
78 2.29 (0.13) — — 0.13 (0.055) 0.06 0.53 354.0 (0.000) —
78 0.19 (0.27) 0.85 (0.092) — — 0.61 0.94 214.3 (0.000) —
78 0.20 (0.25) 0.79 (0.194) 0.06 (0.122) — 0.61 0.94 — 4.778 (0.091)
78 0.25 (0.27) 0.86 (0.096) — 0.04 (0.035) 0.60 0.98 — 4.341 (0.114)
78 0.21 (0.25) 0.82 (0.195) 0.05 (0.125) 0.03 (0.034) 0.60 0.96 — 4.423 (0.219)
The numbers in parentheses beside the parameter estimates are the standard errors, which are computed following a robust procedure taking into account of the heteroscedastic
and autocorrelated error structure [see Newey and West (1987)]. The w2 test(a) is for the joint hypothesis H0: = 0 and j = 1 (j = MF, BS, LRE) in univariate regressions, and the
w2 test(b) is for the joint hypothesis H0: BS = 1 and LRE = 0 or H0: MF = 1 and BS = LRE = 0 in encompassing regressions. The test statistics are reported with the p-values in
the brackets beside the statistic.
, , and indicate that the leading term coefficient of the regression is significantly different from one at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level and the ,,and indicate
that the coefficient of the remaining terms is significantly different from zero at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively.
1333
The Review of Financial Studies / v 18 n 4 2005
1334
The Model-Free Implied Volatility
6
Compared to the corresponding numbers of 40.0 and 31.1% reported in Longstaff (1995), these differ-
ences are negligible.
1335
The Review of Financial Studies / v 18 n 4 2005
1336
The Model-Free Implied Volatility
5. Conclusions
In this article, we empirically test the forecasting ability and information
content of implied volatility. Instead of relying on the B–S implied
volatility as in previous research, we implement the model-free implied
volatility derived by Britten-Jones and Neuberger (2000). This new
implied volatility has several advantages over its predecessor. First, it is
independent of any option pricing model, whereas the commonly used B–
S implied volatility is model-specific. Second, the model-free implied
volatility extracts information from options across all strike prices instead
of a single option as in the case of the B–S implied volatility. By aggregat-
ing information across options, the model-free implied volatility should
be informationally more efficient than the B–S implied volatility. Third,
tests based on the model-free implied volatility are direct tests of market
efficiency instead of joint tests of market efficiency and the assumed
option pricing model. Evidence on market efficiency from the model-
free implied volatility is thus not subject to model misspecification errors.
Our research makes several contributions to the related literature. We
provide a simpler derivation of the model-free implied volatility under
Britten-Jones and Neuberger’s (2000) diffusion assumption and then
generalize it to processes with jumps. We thus establish the validity of
the model-free implied volatility and ensure that it applies to general asset
price processes. In addition, we develop a simple method for implement-
ing the model-free implied volatility using observed option prices. We
provide theoretical bounds on truncation errors due to the finite range of
available strike prices and illustrate the minimum range of strike prices
required to control such errors. We show that the model-free implied
volatility can be calculated accurately using our implementation method.
Finally, we use univariate and encompassing regressions to investigate the
forecasting ability and information content of the model-free implied
volatility. Our findings from the SPX options support the hypothesis that
the model-free implied volatility subsumes all information contained in the
B–S implied volatility and past realized volatility and is a more efficient
forecast for future realized volatility. These results are robust to alternative
estimation methods, volatility series over different horizons, the choice of
actual or implied index values, and alternative methods for calculating
realized volatility. Our findings also provide theoretical and empirical
support for the recent decision by the CBOE to modify its widely watched
VIX index. The new VIX index is based on the model-free implied volatility
instead of the B–S implied volatility of at-the-money options.
Appendix
Proof of Proposition 1. We first prove that Equation (1) holds under the diffusion assump-
tion. The no-arbitrage argument implies that there exists a forward measure F such that:
1337
The Review of Financial Studies / v 18 n 4 2005
pffiffiffiffiffi
dFt =Ft ¼ Vt dWt , ðA1Þ
1 pffiffiffiffiffi
d ln Ft ¼ Vt dt þ Vt dWt :
2
ÐT
where the LHS is equivalent to E0F 0 dF
Ft
t . Thus we only need to prove that:
ð1 F
C ðT, KÞ maxð0, F0 KÞ
dK ¼ ln F0 E0F ðln FT Þ: ðA2Þ
0 K2
where CKF(T,K) is the partial derivative of option price with respect to strike price.
The first term on the RHS of Equation (A3) vanishes under the mild condition that
the density of the forward price distribution is bounded. Since CKF ðT; KÞ ¼
qmaxð0; FT KÞ
E0F ¼ E0F ð1FT > K Þ, the second term on the RHS of Equation (A3)
qK
can be simplified to:
ð1
CKF ðT, KÞ þ 1F0 > K
dK ¼ ln F0 E0F ðln FT Þ:
0 K
Equation (A2) thus holds. This completes the proof for diffusion processes.
We now consider processes with jumps. Under certain regularity conditions, the forward
price as a martingale can be decomposed canonically into two orthogonal components: a
purely continuous martingale and a purely discontinuous martingale [see Jacod and Shiryaev
(1987) and Protter (1990)]. Incorporating the discontinuous component (i.e., jumps), we
restate the forward price process as:
pffiffiffiffiffi
dFt =Ft ¼ Vt dWt þ Jt dNt t t dt, ðA4Þ
where Nt is a pure jump process with time-varying intensity lt, Jt, is the jump size
with instantaneous mean mt, and the jump component is uncorrelated with the diffusion
component.
Applying Ito’s lemma, we have:
1 pffiffiffiffiffi
d ln Ft ¼ Vt dt þ Vt dWt þ ln ð1 þ Jt ÞdNt t t dt:
2
1338
The Model-Free Implied Volatility
ð T
ð T
1
E0F d ln Ft E0F ðVt þ lt Jt2 Þdt ,
0 2 0
or equivalently:
ð T
E0F ðVt þ lt Jt2 Þdt 2 ln F0 E0F ðln FT Þ :
0
Since the LHS of the above equation is the integrated return variance, we now have:
"ð #
T
dFt 2
E0F 2 ln F0 E0F ðln FT Þ : ðA5Þ
0 F t
Note that Equation (A2) holds even when asset returns include jumps because its
derivation does not require any knowledge of the asset return process. Combining Equations
(A2) and (A5), we complete the proof for processes with jumps.7
where F(FT) is the density of the forward price. Using the properties of the Taylor series
expansion for the log function, we have the following upper bound for the right truncation
error:
ð þ1 ð þ1
C F ðT, KÞ maxð0, F0 KÞ FT Kmax 2
2 dK fðFT ÞdFT : ðA7Þ
Kmax K2 Kmax Kmax
where the RHS can be rewritten as E0F FT Kmax 2 F > K , which proves Equation
Kmax T max
(3). The upper bound for the left truncation error in Equation (4) is derived in a similar
fashion.
7
Note the Equation (A5) does not hold exactly. The approximation error is due to ignoring higher order
(3) terms in the ln (1+Jt) expansion, which are mainly determined by the third moment of the jump size
Jt. When the jump size is negatively skewed, the model-free implied volatility [the RHS of Equation (A5)]
tends to overestimate the asset price variance. However, our numerical evaluation suggests that the
approximation error is negligible in commonly encountered cases (see the results in Figure 1 and Table 1).
1339
The Review of Financial Studies / v 18 n 4 2005
References
Aı̈t-Sahalia, Y., and A. W. Lo, 1998, ‘‘Nonparametric Estimation of State-price Densities Implicit in
Financial Asset Prices,’’ Journal of Finance, 53, 499–547.
Aı̈t-Sahalia, Y., P. A. Mykland, and L. Zhang, 2003, ‘‘How Often to Sample a Continuous-Time Process
in the Presence of Market Microstructure Noise,’’ Review of Financial Studies, 18, 351–416.
Andersen, T. G., and T. Bollerslev, 1998, ‘‘Answering the Critics: Yes, ARCH Models Do Provide Good
Volatility Forecasts,’’ International Economic Review, 39, 885–905.
Andersen, T. G., T. Bollerslev, F. X. Diebold, and. H. Ebens, 2001, ‘‘The Distribution of Realized Stock
Return Volatility,’’ Journal of Financial Economics, 61, 43–76.
Andersen, T. G., T. Bollerslev, F. X. Diebold, and P. Labys, 2001, ‘‘The Distribution of Realized
Exchange Rate Volatility,’’ Journal of the American Statistical Association, 96, 42–55.
Andersen, T. G., T. Bollerslev, F. X. Diebold, and P. Labys, 2003, ‘‘Modeling and Forecasting Realized
Volatility,’’ Econometrica, 71, 579–625.
Barndorff-Nielsen, O. E., and N. Shephard, 2003, ‘‘Realized Power Variation and Stochastic Volatility
Models,’’ Bernouilli, 9, 243–265.
Bakshi, G., C. Cao, and Z. Chen, 1997, ‘‘Empirical Performance of Alternative Option Pricing Models,’’
Journal of Finance, 52, 2003–2049.
Bakshi, G., C. Cao, and Z. Chen, 2000, ‘‘Pricing and Hedging Long-Term Options,’’ Journal of Econo-
metrics, 94, 277–318.
Bates, D., 1991, ‘‘The Crash of ’87: Was it Expected? The Evidence from Options Markets,’’ Journal of
Finance, 46, 1009–1044.
Black, F., and M. Scholes, 1973, ‘‘The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities,’’ Journal of Political
Economy, 81, 637–659.
Blair, B., S. H. Poon, and S. J. Taylor, 2001, ‘‘Forecasting S&P 100 Volatility: The Incremental Information
Content of Implied Volatility and High Frequency Index Returns,’’ Journal of Econometrics, 105, 5–26.
Breeden, D. T., and R. H. Litzenberger, 1978, ‘‘Prices of State-Contingent Claims Implicit in Option
Prices,’’ Journal of Business, 51, 621–651.
Britten-Jones, M., and A. Neuberger, 2000, ‘‘Option Prices, Implied Price Processes, and Stochastic
Volatility,’’ Journal of Finance, 55, 839–866.
Campa, J. M., K. P. Chang, and R. L. Reider, 1998, ‘‘Implied Exchange Rate Distributions: Evidence
from OTC Option Markets,’’ Journal of International Money and Finance, 17, 117–160.
Canina, L., and S. Figlewski, 1993, ‘‘The Informational Content of Implied Volatility,’’ Review of
Financial Studies, 6, 659–681.
1340
The Model-Free Implied Volatility
Christensen, B. J., C. S. Hansen, and N. R. Prabhala, 2001, ‘‘The Telescoping Overlap Problem in
Options Data,’’ Working paper, University of Aarhus and University of Maryland,
Christensen, B. J., and N. R. Prabhala, 1998, ‘‘The Relation between Implied and Realized Volatility,’’
Journal of Financial Economics, 50, 125–150.
Day, T. E., and C. M. Lewis, 1992, ‘‘Stock Market Volatility and the Information Content of Stock Index
Options,’’ Journal of Econometrics, 52, 267–287.
Derman, E., and I. Kani, 1998, ‘‘Stochastic Implied Trees: Arbitrage Pricing with Stochastic Term and
Strike Structure of Volatility,’’ International Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance, 1, 61–110.
Derman, E., I. Kani, and N. Chriss, 1996, ‘‘Implied Trinomial Trees of the Volatility Smile,’’ Journal of
Derivatives, 3, 7–22.
Dumas, B., J. Fleming, and R. E. Whaley, 1998, ‘‘Implied Volatility Functions: Empirical Tests,’’ Journal
of Finance, 53, 2059–2106.
Ederington, L. H., and W. Guan, 2002, ‘‘Is Implied Volatility an Informationally Efficient and Effective
Predictor of Future Volatility?’’ Journal of Risk, 4, 29–46.
Fleming, J., 1998, ‘‘The Quality of Market Volatility Forecast Implied by S&P 100 Index Option Prices,’’
Journal of Empirical Finance, 5, 317–345.
French, K. R., G. W. Schwert, and R. F. Stambaugh, 1987, ‘‘Expected Stock Returns and Volatility,’’
Journal of Financial Economics, 19, 3–30.
Hansen, P. R., and A. Lunde, 2004, ‘‘Realized Variance and Market Microstructure Noise,’’ forthcoming
Journal of Business and Economic Statistics.
Harvey, C. R., and R. E. Whaley, 1991, ‘‘S&P 100 Index Option Volatility,’’ Journal of Finance, 46, 1551–
1561.
Harvey, C. R., and R. E. Whaley, 1992a, ‘‘Market Volatility Prediction and the Efficiency of the S&P 100
Index Option Market,’’ Journal of Financial Economics, 31, 43–73.
Harvey, C. R., and R. E. Whaley, 1992b, ‘‘Dividends and S&P 100 Index Option Valuation,’’ Journal of
Futures Markets, 12, 123–137.
Heston, S. L., 1993, ‘‘A Closed-Form Solution for Options with Stochastic Volatility with Applications to
Bond and Currency Options,’’ Review of Financial Studies, 6, 327–343.
Jackwerth, J. C., 1999, ‘‘Option-Implied Risk-Neutral Distributions and Implied Binomial Trees: A
Literature Review,’’ Journal of Derivatives, 6, 1–17.
Jacod, J., and A. N. Shiryaev, 1987, Limit Theorems for Stochastic Processes, Springer-Verlag, Berlin.
Jorion, P., 1995, ‘‘Predicting Volatility in the Foreign Exchange Market,’’ Journal of Finance, 50, 507–528.
Lamoureux, C. G., and W. D. Lastrapes, 1993, ‘‘Forecasting Stock-Return Variance: Toward an Under-
standing of Stochastic Implied Volatilities,’’ Review of Financial Studies, 6, 293–326.
Ledoit, O., and P. Santa-Clara, 1998, ‘‘Relative Pricing of Options with Stochastic Volatility,’’ Working
paper, University of California at Los Angeles.
Longstaff, F. A., 1995, ‘‘Option Pricing and the Martingale Restriction,’’ Review of Financial Studies, 8,
1091–1124.
Newey, W. K., and K. D. West, 1987, ‘‘A Simple Positive Definite Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrela-
tion Consistent Covariance Matrix,’’ Econometrica, 55, 703–708.
1341
The Review of Financial Studies / v 18 n 4 2005
Pong, S., M. B. Shackleton, S. J. Taylor, and X. Xu, 2004, ‘‘Forecasting Sterling/Dollar Volatility: A
Comparison of Implied Volatility and AR(FI)MA Models,’’ Journal of Banking and Finance, 28, 2541–2563.
Protter, P., 1990, Stochastic Integration and Differential Equations: A New Approach, Springer, Berlin.
Richardson, M., and T. Smith, 1991, ‘‘Tests of Financial Models in the Presence of Overlapping
Observations,’’ Review of Financial Studies, 4, 227–254.
Rubinstein, M., 1994, ‘‘Implied Binomial Trees,’’ Journal of Finance, 49, 771–818.
Stoll, H. R., and R. E. Whaley, 1990, ‘‘The Dynamics of Stock Index and Stock Index Futures Returns,’’
Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 25, 441–468.
White, H., 1980, ‘‘A Heteroskedasticity-Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimator and a Direct Test for
Heteroskedasticity,’’ Econometrica, 48, 817–838.
Zhang, L., P. A. Mykland, and Y. Aı̈t-Sahalia, 2003, ‘‘A Tale of Two Time Scales: Determining
Integrated Volatility with Noisy High-Frequency Data,’’ forthcoming Journal of the American Statistical
Assocation.
Zhou, B., 1996, ‘‘High-Frequency Data and Volatility in Foreign-Exchange Rates,’’ Journal of Business
and Economic Statistics, 14, 45–52.
1342